Dissertation KaveriIychettira
Dissertation KaveriIychettira
DOI
10.4233/uuid:d247e271-3321-4661-b29a-08070ae9090f
Publication date
2018
Document Version
Final published version
Citation (APA)
Iychettira, K. (2018). National Renewable Policies in an International Electricity Market: A Socio-Technical
Study. Netherlands. https://doi.org/10.4233/uuid:d247e271-3321-4661-b29a-08070ae9090f
Important note
To cite this publication, please use the final published version (if applicable).
Please check the document version above.
Copyright
Other than for strictly personal use, it is not permitted to download, forward or distribute the text or part of it, without the consent
of the author(s) and/or copyright holder(s), unless the work is under an open content license such as Creative Commons.
Takedown policy
Please contact us and provide details if you believe this document breaches copyrights.
We will remove access to the work immediately and investigate your claim.
National Renewable
National Renewable Policies in an Policies in an
International
International Electricity Market:
TU Delft
Aula
Conference Center
Mekelweg 5
2628 CC Delft
The Netherlands
Dissertation
by
Master of Science in
Engineering and Policy Analysis
Delft University of Technology, the Netherlands
born in Bangalore, India.
This dissertation has been approved by the promotors.
Independent members:
Prof. dr. ir. R.W. Künneke Delft University of Technology
Prof. dr. ir. M.L. Rivier Abbad Comillas Pontifical University
Prof. dr. K. Blok Delft University of Technology
Dr. ir. M.R. Hesamzadeh KTH Royal Institute of Technology
Prof. dr. J. Watson University of Sussex
ISBN 978-94-6233-904-0
The doctoral research has been carried out in the context of an agreement on joint doc-
toral supervision between Comillas Pontifical University, Madrid, Spain, KTH Royal In-
stitute of Technology, Stockholm, Sweden and Delft University of Technology, the Nether-
lands.
Copyright © 2018 by K.K. Iychettira. All rights reserved. No part of the material protected
by this copyright notice may be reproduced or utilized in any form or by any means, elec-
tronic or mechanical, including photocopying, recording or by any information storage
and retrieval system, without written permission from the author.
Printed in the Netherlands
Thesis Supervisors:
promotor: Prof. dr. ir. M.P.C. Weijnen
copromotor: Dr. ir. R.A. Hakvoort
TRITA-EECS-AVL-2018:12
ISBN 978-94-6233-904-0
The Doctoral Degrees issued upon completion of the programme are issued by Comillas
Pontifical University, Delft University of Technology, and KTH Royal Institute of Technol-
ogy.
The Degree Certificates are giving reference to the joint programme. The doctoral candi-
dates are jointly supervised, and must pass a joint examination procedure set up by the
three institutions issuing the degrees.
This thesis is a part of the examination for the doctoral degree. The invested degrees are
official in Spain, the Netherlands and Sweden respectively.
SETS Joint Doctorate was awarded the Erasmus Mundus excellence label by the Euro-
pean Commission in year 2010, and the European Commission’s Education, Audiovisual
and Culture Executive Agency, EACEA, has supported the funding of this programme.
The EACEA is not to be held responsible for contents of the Thesis.
A CKNOWLEDGEMENTS
"It always seems impossible until it’s done," said Nelson Mandela. The same feeling per-
vades even as I write this. During the last four years however, there were a lot of people
in my life who thought it was possible. Some of whom, through their own challenges
showed me it was possible gracefully, and with perseverance. Others showed me the
way, and others still helped by making sure I knew that there was much more to life than
a PhD. I take this opportunity to acknowledge their contribution and care; they are the
village that it took to create this thesis.
I thank my pragmatic, witty, and insightful co-promotor, dr. ir. Rudi Hakvoort, for
giving me the opportunity to undertake this journey. Rudi was a mentor, advisor, and
friend, therefore so much more than the title ’supervisor’ implies. Through it all, he al-
lowed me the freedom to explore my mad ideas, helped keep my perfectionist tenden-
cies in check after first letting them run wild; his light-hearted approach, creative ideas,
and supportiveness ensured that I stayed positive, and kept trying when results didn’t
come through. I thank Prof. dr. ir., Margot Weijnen, my promotor, for her guidance,
especially during the later half of my PhD. I thank her for ensuring that I completed the
dissertation on time, by keeping my ambitiousness in check at the final stages. During
the many meetings with her, she was insightful and friendly, and I never left a meeting
without feeling encouraged. I especially thank both Rudi and Margot for their warmth
and understanding when my wrists gave in due to repetitive stress injury, as well as for
their interest and effort in helping me get to the next step in my career. I also thank
Prof. Pedro Linares at Comillas for the academic year I spent in Madrid, Spain. Weekly
meetings with him were instrumental in shaping my ideas during the early stages of my
dissertation.
I thank the several colleagues I collaborated and co-authored papers with, particu-
larly the EMLab community: Dr. ir. Laurens de Vries, dr. ir. Emile Chappin, Joern, Rob
de Jeu, Salman, and Prad. Laurens was also a mentor to me. I am grateful for the op-
portunities to collaborate with him on several projects, and for all the master students
he sent my way. I thank him for the memorable dinners he hosted, for the fun and lively
conversations, and for his advice on the process of PhD-ing. I thank Joern for teaching
me the ropes of EMLab, and for inspiring me to be a good supervisor and friend to my
master students.
I thank Wiebke, whose friendship was the most valuable outcome of the PhD Start-
Up course! I am incredibly grateful for her friendship, inspiration and counsel. I thank
Yesh for being the big brother he has been: when I had lost hope of ever getting sensible
results from EMLab, he managed to convince me that there was light at the end of the
tunnel. I thank Siddhartha Mukherjee for his friendship, the fantastic biryanis with Udai,
the fun conversations, and for introducing me to Vikram Seth!
I thank the wonderfully ’gezellige’ group at the E&I section. The atmosphere was
one of camaraderie, and a feeling that we all had each others’ backs. The Power Rangers
ix
x
meetings were especially useful, usually indirectly, for my own research. I’m also grate-
ful for conversations with Amineh and Igor, which have influenced ideas in this disser-
tation. I thank Elta for convincing me to take up the PhD programme, and for being the
supportive figure she was through the PhD! I thank Binod, Jorge, and Jose who made
my first year a very happy one. I thank Joao, Ben, Esther, Amineh, Arthur, Amit, Shan-
tanu, Ozge, Kasper, Tristan, Frank, Reinier, Cherrelle, Juliana, Chris, Dierdre, and my
officemates Victoria, Anna, and Graciela. Arthur, Joao, and Shantanu kept spirits in the
department high, and made sure we didn’t stay in the office too long after work hours! I
also thank Rishab and Ad for all the fun times in my final year. I’m glad I got to know you
before I left!
When I went to Madrid for the SETS mobility in Aug 2014, I was immediately made to
feel like a part of the Ricci-Spanish family. I thank Adela, Alessandro, Pablo, Checa, Luis,
Paco, Elena, Eva, and Zarrar. I also thank the SETS Spanish cohort in that year, Katia,
Peyman, Quentin. I thank Sara for her diligence and dedication in helping us get through
the various administrative SETS requirements during the 4 years. In KTH, Stockholm too,
I was very lucky to have met wonderful people like Francisco, Gudrun, Tin, Viktor, Ravi,
Fabian, and Aravind. Their friendship made even Swedish winters seem warm and fun.
I also met a very nice bunch of people from all over the world, in the SETS pro-
gramme, who made the journey easier together: Christian, Marcin, Nenad, German,
Paolo, Anna.
Towards the final stages, a lot of people helped proof-read my dissertation. Some of
them were acquaintances, and others family! I can’t thank them enough for offering to
help under tight time constraints, and doing diligent jobs too. My mum, Raunak Kalra,
Layla Abdulkarim, Vivek anna, Ranjani, Yeshambel, and Vikram Srinivas. I thank Wiebke
and Ozge for standing by my side as paranymphs. I also thank Prof. James W. Smith from
the university of Mc. Master, for letting me use his beautiful photograph for my thesis
cover.
I thank my friends from Bangalore - Ranjani Iyer, Chitwan Mahipal, Kaushik Ran-
garajan, Vidya Shree, Nisha Suresh, Roshan Rao, Santosh Harish, and Anil Kumar who
have all been by my side despite the distance. I thank Daddy for being an inspiration
in his pragmatic approach to life. He made sure that I didn’t let the PhD consume me,
and reminded me that there were more important things in life! I thank Mum for her
constant care, love, and support. She never let me feel like I lived too far away from fam-
ily. And finally I thank Vikram, my fiance, whose presence makes every moment more
joyful. He is a source of calm strength, and unconditional affection. I look forward to all
that life has in store for us!
Kaveri Iychettira
February, 2018
C ONTENTS
Acknowledgements ix
Summary xvii
Samenvatting xxi
Sammanfattning xxv
1 Introduction 1
1.1 Background . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1
1.1.1 A brief history . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1
1.1.2 When Renewables Arrived . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3
1.2 Problem Definition and Research Overview. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4
1.2.1 Research questions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5
1.2.2 Scientific contribution . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5
1.2.3 Research framework and thesis structure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9
2 Theoretical Foundations: Identifying the design space 13
2.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14
2.2 Theoretical Foundations and Methodology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15
2.2.1 Theoretical Foundations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15
2.2.2 A Policy Design Framework . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18
2.3 Applying the policy design framework to RES-E support design. . . . . . . 21
2.3.1 Identification of participants, action situations, and exogenous vari-
ables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21
2.3.2 Design Space: Design Elements of RES-E Support Schemes . . . . . 23
2.4 Empirical representativeness of design elements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26
2.5 Merits and limitations of the approach . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28
2.6 Conclusions and policy implications . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31
3 Modelling: EMLab Generation and Renewable Support 35
3.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36
3.2 System decomposition of Base Model in EMLab . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36
3.2.1 Model conceptualisation. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37
3.2.2 Model implementation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37
3.3 Electricity spot market and Investment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38
3.3.1 Market clearing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38
3.3.2 Dynamic determination of load duration curve . . . . . . . . . . . 39
3.3.3 Investment in generation capacity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40
xi
xii C ONTENTS
s Segment index
C FOp,g Expected cash flow for power plant g, during operation [in Eur]
n Number of years ahead of current tick, for which value is being computed
p s,t +n Electricity spot market price for segment s, estimated at time t, for a period n
years ahead
rD Rate of debt
rE Rate of equity
xv
xvi C ONTENTS
X ant e g Total subsidy per MWh of generation for plant g, discounted to present value
[in Eur/MWh]
X post g Total cost per MWh of plant g, discounted to present value [in Eur/MWh]
E XECUTIVE S UMMARY
The current regulatory framework under which the support schemes for Renewable en-
ergy sources specifically for electricity (RES-E) operate, is provided for by the Directive
2009/28/EC. It sets a 20% target for energy consumption, while relying on legally bind-
ing, national targets until 2020. The goal to promote RES-E, in the European context,
coexists with goals of ensuring a single internal market for electricity, and security of
supply in the European Union, and these simultaneous goals are not always congruent
with each other.
Today, significant amounts of intermittent RES-E in the energy mix have led to un-
intended effects. An important consequence is the so called ‘merit-order effect’, where
the spot market electricity price reduces to the extent by which the renewable electric-
ity generation displaces demand along the merit order. There is concern that part of
the merit order effect spreads across national borders. Vitally, implications of the merit
order effect on the effectiveness of RES-E support schemes are unclear. Another impor-
tant effect of the price reduction is that, the lower the average electricity market price,
the greater the costs of subsidies, making the phasing out of subsidies for renewable,
intermittent sources more difficult.
With respect to electricity from renewable sources, this achievement of the three ob-
jectives took the shape of "making renewable support schemes more market-based",
"ensuring renewables are driven by market signals". However, it is not often clear what is
meant by such statements in policy documents by the EC. What features of the support
scheme are being referred to? What would it mean for renewables solely to be driven
by market signals? How would features of support schemes impact for instance, the
merit order effect, and vice-versa? These issues are encapsulated in the first problem
addressed in the thesis: to unravel the interactions between renewable support scheme
design and a single isolated electricity spot market, with a long term perspective.
Since countries are now increasingly interconnected, the second major issue tackled
in this thesis concerns cross border effects due to different renewable support schemes be-
tween neighbouring countries in a common electricity market. This issue addresses con-
cerns about the merit-order effect spreading across national borders, and the ensuing
distributional implications.
The final issue addressed in this dissertation relates to the long term economic viabil-
ity of electricity from renewable sources given the current institutional and physical setting
they operate in. Costs of renewable technologies have dropped dramatically and yet ef-
fects such as their reducing market value lead to questions about whether it is possible
for them to attain economic viability in a decarbonised power sector. Accordingly, the
main research question in this dissertation is:
How do national renewable electricity support schemes interact with the electricity
xvii
xviii S UMMARY
market over the long term (20-30 years) as the European Union transitions to a decar-
bonized energy system?
larger neighbouring country. However, the increase in subsidy costs remains lower than
the reduction in costs of electricity, corroborating earlier, single country analyses on the
topic. Therefore, total costs in both countries reduce as interconnection increases, and
the invisible hand works its magic. As the share of RES-E increases, interconnection has
limited impact on reducing spillage of RES-E while storage becomes increasingly im-
portant. The results show that setting targets for RES-E, should not only take into to
account the targets of the interconnected neighbouring countries, but also capacity of
storage that exists in the system. They raise interesting questions about how subsidy
costs should be allocated between countries over the long term when electricity markets
they operate in are so intricately connected.
RES-E design in perspective of the energy transition:
Results from previous chapters are, in this penultimate chapter, regarded from the
standpoint of the EU energy transition. A literature review examines three major aspects
of the energy transition in Europe: the cost and revenue drivers of RES-E technologies,
the EU ETS, and finally, the role of flexibility. We find that at relatively high average elec-
tricity prices, their impact on subsidy costs is direct and clear; as prices increase, subsidy
costs decrease. However, as electricity prices on the spot market reduce on average, the
change in subsidy cost trends depend far more on cost curves of each RES-E technology.
With respect to the EU-ETS, it is clear that, even if EUA prices play a significant role on
the electricity prices today, their influence on electricity prices and RES-E subsidy costs
will reduce as the share of RES-E generation increases with time. From results in Chap-
ter 5, it is evident that at high shares of RES-E, interconnection will play a limited role in
providing flexibility while storage (long-term, seasonal) will play a pivotal role. Conse-
quently, costs of subsidy for RES-E at high shares substantially depend on the presence
of storage in the system.
Conclusion The central question addressed in this thesis is How do national renewable
electricity support schemes interact with the electricity market over the long term (20-30
years) as the European Union transitions to a decarbonized energy system?
Using an approach based on theoretical foundations of institutional analysis, design
theory, RES-E support schemes are broken down into their design elements from a wel-
fare economics perspective. A modelling framework is then introduced, using the mod-
eling paradigm of agent-based modelling, by which RES-E schemes are modelled in EM-
Lab Generation. EMLab Generation mainly comprises an electricity market clearing and
an endogenous investment module, enabling the researcher to study long term dynam-
ics of policy designs in the electricity sector. The model shows that the way electricity
prices are taken into account while designing subsidies makes a substantial difference
to welfare distributions. When multiple countries are considered, spreading of the merit
order effect from a larger country to a smaller one would cause the smaller country’s
subsidy costs to increase. This indicates that even if RES-E support can be designed to
be "market-based" at an operational level, designing them to be "market based" at an
investment level is far more complicated. It indicates that RES-E targets of countries
should take into account the targets of neighbouring countries, as well as the amount of
flexibility in terms of interconnection and storage in the system.
In terms of its scientific contribution, the thesis takes a step towards integrating in-
xx S UMMARY
stitutional analysis and design theory in order to complement the neo-classical school
of thought which arguably dominates energy policy design and analysis in Europe. The
framework introduced in Chapter 2 brings together two separate strands of literature:
the institutional analysis framework and design theory. The combination is shown to
also be coherent with and complementary to the modelling paradigm of agent based
modelling and simulation. While the framework does not provide causal relationships
which provide insight on why a certain actor behaves in a certain manner under cer-
tain conditions, it does make for a strong fundamental basis to simulate a test-bench on
which the real world can be represented, and theories or "speculations" tested. Although
this framework was applied and demonstrated using renewable support schemes in Eu-
rope, its fundamental nature makes it employable to other domains.
A major advantage of the model is that it is open source. Most models that are used
to inform the European Commission’s policy documents are black box simulations. The
assumptions, data, systems used to set policy are not publicly available. Making mod-
els open source allows for replicability, transparency, and debating their validity, which
are all basic tenets of the scientific method. The results from this dissertation also pave
the way towards new questions that need to be resolved as the shares of RES-E increase
in the elecricity system. In terms of methodology for long-term energy studies, it is
paramount that models employ high temporal resolution at high shares of intermittent
RES-E generation, while also being able to model endogenous investment. For instance,
they raise pressing questions about the need to further develop a methodology for shar-
ing the subsidy costs between countries. These questions need to be explored in greater
detail, and possible mechanisms to cope with the complexities should be evaluated.
S AMENVATTING
De Europese Richtlijn 2009/28/EC biedt het reguleringskader voor de groei van het aan-
deel duurzaam opgewekte energie, specifiek voor elektriciteit. De doelstelling is dat 20
% van het energiegebruik in 2020 uit duurzame bronnen wordt opgewekt, een en ander
te realiseren door middel van bindende nationale doelstellingen. Het bevorderen van
duurzame energie in de Europese context staat naast de andere doelstellingen van het
realiseren van een interne markt voor energie en het waarborgen van de leveringszeker-
heid in de Europese Unie. Deze doelstellingen zijn niet altijd met elkaar in lijn.
De grote hoeveelheden energie uit intermitterende bronnen in de energiemix heb-
ben geleid tot onbedoelde neveneffecten. Een van de belangrijkste is het zogenaamde
‘merit order effect’: de elektriciteitsprijs op de spotmarkt daalt naarmate energie uit
duurzame bronnen conventionele elektriciteitsproductie verdringt. Dit merit order ef-
fect kan zich over landsgrenzen heen verspreiden. De gevolgen hiervan op de effectiviteit
van beleid om duurzame energie te bevorderen zijn onduidelijk (en worden in dit proef-
schrift onderzocht). Een gevolg van de prijsdaling is verder dat hoe lager de gemiddelde
elektriciteitsmarktprijs, hoe hoger de kosten van de toegezegde subsidiëring worden. Dit
maakt het uitfaseren van subsidies voor duurzame energiebronnen moeilijker.
In de praktijk is geprobeerd om de drie hierboven genoemde doelstellingen met el-
kaar in lijn te brengen door “het meer markt-gebaseerd maken van de ondersteuning van
duurzame energie” en “het verzekeren dat duurzame energiebronnen worden aange-
dreven door marktsignalen”. Het is meestal niet duidelijk wat met dergelijke uitspraken
bedoeld wordt. Aan welke eigenschappen van het ondersteuningsmechanisme wordt er
gerefereerd? Wat betekent het dat duurzame energiebronnen alleen door marktsignalen
gestuurd worden? Welke eigenschappen van ondersteuningsregelingen hebben impact
op bijvoorbeeld het merit order effect, en omgekeerd? Deze kwesties worden in het eer-
ste vraagstuk geadresseerd dat in dit proefschrift aan bod komt: het ontrafelen van de
interacties tussen ondersteuningsregelingen voor duurzame energie in een enkele (geï-
soleerde) elektriciteitsmarkt, bekeken vanuit een langetermijnperspectief.
Aangezien de elektriciteitssystemen in de Europese landen onderling verbonden zijn,
gaat de tweede kwestie die in dit proefschrift wordt behandeld, over de grensoverschrij-
dende beïnvloeding van verschillende ondersteuningsregelingen voor duurzame ener-
gie tussen buurlanden in een gemeenschappelijke elektriciteitsmarkt. Deze kwestie adres-
seert het verspreiden van het merit order effect over nationale grenzen heen, en de daar-
uit volgende verdelingseffecten. Het laatste vraagstuk dat in dit proefschrift wordt be-
handeld, heeft te maken met de economische levensvatbaarheid op lange termijn van
elektriciteitsproductie vanuit duurzame bronnen gegeven de huidige institutionele en
fysieke omgeving. Hoewel de kosten van duurzame elektriciteitsproductie zijn afgeno-
men, leidt hun snel dalende marktwaarde tot vragen in hoeverre deze technologieën
economisch levensvatbaar blijven in een koolstofarme stroomsector. Bijgevolg is de
hoofdonderzoeksvraag in dit proefschrift:
xxi
xxii S AMENVATTING
Conclusie De centrale vraag die in dit proefschrift is geadresseerd is: Hoe interacteren
nationale ondersteuningsregelingen met de elektriciteitsmarkt op de lange termijn (20-
30 jaar) nu de Europese Unie overgaat naar een koolstofarm energiesysteem? Wanneer
we gebruik maken van een aanpak die gebaseerd is op theoretische grondslagen van
de institutionele analyse en design theory, worden de ondersteuningsregelingen voor
duurzame elektriciteitsproductie teruggebracht tot hun ontwerpelementen vanuit een
economisch welvaartsperspectief. Modelberekeningen in EMLab tonen vervolgens aan
dat de manier waarop elektriciteitsprijzen in het ondersteuningsmechanisme worden
ingepast, een substantieel verschil maakt voor de welvaartsverdeling. Wanneer verschil-
lende ondersteuningssystemen in buurlanden worden geïmplementeerd, zorgt het me-
xxiv S AMENVATTING
rit order effect in het grote land dat de subsidiekosten in het kleinere land kunnen stij-
gen. Dit leidt tot de conclusie dat zelfs indien een ‘marktgebaseerde’ ondersteunings-
regeling kan worden ontworpen op het operationele niveau, dit geen garanties biedt
dat ook het ‘marktgebaseerde’ ontwerp op een investeringsniveau is geborgd. Gecon-
cludeerd wordt dat bij het vaststellen van duurzame energiedoelstellingen in het ene
land, de doelstellingen in buurlanden in ogenschouw moeten worden genomen, net als
de beschikbare hoeveelheid flexibiliteit in termen van interconnectie en opslag in het
systeem. Wat betreft de wetenschappelijke bijdrage zet dit proefschrift een stap naar
het integreren van institutionele analyse en design theory om de neoklassieke denkrich-
ting (die het energiebeleid in Europa aantoonbaar domineert) te complementeren. Het
raamwerk uit hoofdstuk 2 brengt twee lijnen in de literatuur tezamen: het institutionele
analyse raamwerk en design theory. Er is aangetoond dat de combinatie coherent is met
en complementair is aan het modelleringsparadigma van agent-based modelleren en
simulatie. Hoewel het raamwerk geen causale relaties biedt die inzichten geven in de
redenen waarom een speler zich op een bepaalde manier gedraagt onder bepaalde om-
standigheden, biedt het wel een fundament voor het ontwikkelen van modelsimulaties
die theorieën en ‘speculaties’ kunnen analyseren. Hoewel dit raamwerk is ontwikkeld
en toegepast op het gebied van ondersteuningsregelingen voor duurzame energie in Eu-
ropa, maakt de fundamentele aard ervan het ook inzetbaar in andere domeinen. Een
voordeel van het gehanteerde EMLab model is dat het open source is. De meeste model-
len die gebruikt worden om de Europese beleidsmaatregelen te analyseren zijn black box
simulaties. De veronderstellingen, data en mechanismen om het beleid te parametrise-
ren zijn niet publiekelijk beschikbaar. Open source modellen zorgen voor een betere
reproduceerbaarheid, meer transparantie en voor meer inzicht in hun geldigheid van
de uitkomsten, alle fundamentele uitgangspunten van de wetenschappelijke methode.
Deze dissertatie leidt ook tot nieuwe vragen die geadresseerd moeten worden naarmate
het aandeel van duurzame energie in het elektriciteitssysteem toeneemt. Wat betreft
de methodologie voor langetermijns energiestudies is het van het belang dat de gehan-
teerde modellen een voldoende (tijds)resolutie aanbieden om de effecten van intermit-
terende duurzame elektriciteitsproducten voldoende nauwkeurig te kunnen weergeven.
Daarnaast moeten ook endogene investeringen kunnen worden gemodelleerd. Dit leidt
vervolgens tot prangende vragen over de noodzaak om (een methodologie te ontwikke-
len om) subsidiekosten te verdelen tussen buurlanden. Deze vragen blijven in dit proef-
schrift liggen om later door anderen te worden opgepakt.
S AMMANFATTNING
Målen med förnybar el, säkerställande av en inre elmarknad och elförsörjningstrygg-
het i EU är inte alltid förenliga med varandra. Nuförtiden har stora mängder av förny-
bar el i energimixen lett till oavsiktliga konsekvenser på elmarknaden. Detta är ett pro-
blem eftersom mål och stödsystem är utformade på nationell nivå, medan elmarknaden
i allt högre grad innebär en sammankoppling över nationsgränserna. Den centrala frå-
gan som tas upp i denna avhandling är hur interna nationella stödsystem för förnybar
el kommer att växelverka med elmarknaden på lång sikt (20-30 år) då EU övergår till ett
fossilfritt energisystem.
Baserat på teoretiska grunder för institutionell analys, designteori och agentbase-
rad modellering, är förnybar elproduktions stödsystem uppdelade, ur ett välfärdsekono-
miskt perspektiv, i sina designelementöch implementeras i en modell av en energimark-
nad. Energimarknadsmodellen heter Energy Market Laboratory, eller EMLab Generation
vilken huvudsakligen består av en elmarknadsklarering och en endogen investeringsmo-
dul, som gör det möjligt för forskare att studera policydesignens långsiktiga dynamik i
elsektorn.
Modellen visar att sättet att ta hänsyn till elpriserna vid utformningen av subven-
tioner skiljer sig betydligt från välfärdsfördelningen. När flera länder betraktas, skulle
spridningen av prioriteringsordningen från ett större land till ett mindre, leda till att det
mindre landets subventionskostnader ökar. Detta indikerar att även om stödet för för-
nybar el kan utformas för att vara marknadsbaseratpå operativ nivå, är utformningen av
marknadsbaseradestödsystem på investeringsnivå mycket komplicerad. Det indikerar
att ländernas mål för förnybar el bör ta hänsyn till målen i grannländerna, liksom flexi-
biliteten i elsystemet. Med tanke på det vetenskapliga bidraget tar avhandlingen ett steg
mot att integrera institutionell analys och designteori för att komplettera den nyklassiska
tankeskolan som förmodligen dominerar energipolitisk design och analys i Europa.
xxv
1
I NTRODUCTION
1.1. B ACKGROUND
Energy systems of the world are undergoing a major transformation. Over the last few
years, the sheer magnitude of declining costs of renewable energy technologies has taken
even the most optimistic of forecasters and analysts by surprise (Carrington, 2017). This
decline in costs could be attributed to leaps in technological advancements: increase
in capacity factors, decrease in manufacturing costs, and economies of scale. However,
such a view would miss the bigger picture, since political will and far-sighted policy-
making have been key driving forces. The European Union (EU) and many countries
within Europe have been amongst the first to adopt strong support mechanisms to pro-
mote CO2 abatement technologies. The demand created by Germany for instance, set
up a global production line for manufacturing of PV panels and consequently led to a
decline in costs the world over. Whilst a determined policy-driven effort towards decar-
bonisation was taking place, parallel efforts were being made to liberalize the electricity
sector across Europe. This liberalization meant ensuring competition and affordability
through a single market for electricity across the EU.
This dissertation comprises an analysis of RES-E policies and their design in the con-
text of a liberalized, multi-national electricity market in Europe. The following sections
in this chapter present a brief historical account of renewable electricity governance in
Europe, issues that unfolded as shares of RES-E began to become significant, and the
most recent questions on the topic.
1
2 1. I NTRODUCTION
Figure 1.1: Development in EU Renewable Energy policy from 1974-2009. Source: (Hildingsson et al., 2012)
was addressed as a policy priority for the first time. The progression of EU energy pol-
icy and the development of renewable energy policy through the decades is presented
succinctly in Figure 1.1.
The early 1990s saw the first steps towards the creation of a single internal energy
market. In 1995, the European Parliament called for an action plan to further the Eu-
ropean Union’s engagement in increasing the EU-wide RES share. Around this time,
renewable energy also came to be viewed as a solution to environmental and climate
change issues, as well as a means to help increase security of supply, and economic
competition. Taking a broad political economy perspective, Hildingsson argues that
although concern for the environment motivated the promotion of renewable energy,
"advancing a policy framework has to be seen against the backdrop of the EU’s longer-
term ambition to promote liberalised and integrated energy markets" (Hildingsson et al.,
2012). The policy entrepreneurship of the Energy Commissioner and the EC during the
early 1990s is credited with developing a comprehensive and ambitious proposal for a
single internal market in gas and electricity (Nylander, 2001). In the process, from the
mid 1990s onwards, the European Commission asserted that the triad of policy objec-
tives of energy security, efficiency, and climate change could be addressed through di-
versification of energy supply, the liberalisation of energy markets, and deployment of
renewable energy (Hildingsson et al., 2012).
The 1997 white paper titled "Energy for the Future: Renewable Sources of Energy"
(COM(97)599) (Commission, 1997) outlined a goal of increasing the renewable energy
share twofold by 2010. This could be considered the beginning of EU RES policy. As
the policy strategy began to transform into a regulatory framework, it met with substan-
tial Member State opposition, especially to the binding nature of the targets. The 2001
RES-E directive therefore only established indicative targets (21% RES-E by 2010) instead
of binding ones. In the course of preparing the 2001 RES directive, although proposi-
tions were made to harmonise national support schemes, they were strongly contested
by some member states (ex: Germany and Spain).
Finally, in January 2007, the European Commission proposed the establishment of
the current framework of regulations, which aimed at increasing the share of renew-
1.1. B ACKGROUND 3
able electricity to 20% by 2020. The current regulatory framework under which support
schemes for RES-E operate, is provided by the 2009 RES-E Directive (2009/28/EC). The 1
Directive sets a 20% target for energy consumption, while relying on legally binding, na-
tional targets until 2020. The goal to promote RES-E coexists with other goals: ensuring a
single internal market for electricity, affordability of supply, and security of supply in the
European Union. These simultaneous goals are not always congruent with each other.
During this process of proposing the current framework of regulations, the principle
of nationally differentiated and binding renewable electricity targets was broadly undis-
puted (Hildingsson et al., 2012). However, harmonization of policies, as with the intro-
duction of a "Guarantees of Origin" trading scheme, remained contentious throughout
the process of its making. This was resolved after much debate by introducing interstate
statistical transfers, joint support schemes, and other mechanisms for cooperation.
The above paragraphs presented a brief history of the governance of renewable en-
ergy sources in the European Union up to the late 2000s, in the context of liberalisation
of electricity markets. In the following section, a more recent history is presented using
both academic literature, and official consultations and reports, to highlight the issues
that emerged as renewable electricity began to form a significant share of the electricity
mix.
for renewables solely to be driven by market signals? How would features of support
schemes impact for instance, the merit order effect and vice-versa? These issues are en- 1
capsulated in the first problem: to unravel the interactions between renewable support
scheme design and a single isolated electricity spot market, with a long- term perspective.
Since countries are now increasingly interconnected, the second major issue tackled
in this thesis concerns cross- border effects due to different renewable support schemes be-
tween neighbouring countries in a common electricity market. This addresses concerns
about the merit-order effect spreading across national boundaries, and its ensuing dis-
tributional implications.
The final issue addressed in this dissertation relates to the long term economic vi-
abiliy of electricity from renewable sources given the current institutional and physical
settings they operate in. While costs of renewable technologies have dropped dramati-
cally, effects such as their reducing market value question whether it is possible for them
to attain economic viability in a decarbonised power sector. Accordingly, this research
tackles the research questions presented below.
How do national renewable electricity support schemes interact with the electricity
market over the long term (20-30 years) as the European Union transitions to a decar-
bonized energy system?
The following sub-questions together help address the aforementioned main research
question.
• How can policy design options for RES-E support in Europe be systematically and
comprehensively explored and modelled?
• How can the impact of various RES-E support design elements on the electricity
market be modelled and analysed?
• How do RES-E support policy design elements interact with a single isolated elec-
tricity market and what social welfare implications do they actualise?
• How could major developments in the energy transition such as RES-E technology
cost trends, the EU ETS, and flexibility influence RES-E support?
et al., 2014). The methods used to perform such analysis were largely based on assump-
1 tions of perfect competition and long-term equilibrium (Capros et al., 2014). Further-
more, most literature used an approach where comparisons were made between exist-
ing policies (Fais et al., 2014; Newbery, 2016; Dressler, 2016; Winkler et al., 2016; Reuter
et al., 2012). More recently, as authors began addressing interactions between electric-
ity markets and support schemes, they proposed the idea that the key to understanding
these interactions were design features of policies, rather than policies as a whole (Held
et al., 2014; Batlle et al., 2012; del Rio and Linares, 2014). However, they have been em-
pirical observations and classifications, rather than a formal approach to policy design.
The scientific contributions emerging from this thesis can be characterised as being of
two kinds: one method-oriented, and the other, application-oriented.
From a methodological perspective, this dissertation contributes to the science of
policy design, by introducing a new modelling framework based on institutional anal-
ysis, design theory, and agent-based modelling. The modelling framework helps struc-
ture, simulate, and analyze socio-technical systems, and consequently design policies
for such systems. Based on this framework, RES-E support schemes were implemented
in terms of their design features, on an existing, agent-based model of the electricity
market, called "EMLab", short for Energy Market Laboratory. EMLab is an initiative of
the Energy and Industry section of the faculty of Technology, Policy and Management in
TU Delft. By creating the RES-E policy analysis module in EMLab, the existing literature
on methods used to analyse RES-E policies using the agent-based modelling paradigm
was also expanded.
The application-oriented scientific contributions emerged when the aforementioned
method was employed to address the research questions mentioned above. The new
modelling approach enabled arriving at insights on the impact of design features of re-
newable electricity schemes on the various actors in the electricity market: consumers,
producers, and the government, thus adding to the exisiting literature in the field. Specif-
ically, cross-border impacts of disparate national renewable support schemes operating
in interconnected electricity markets have received little attention in literature. Chapters
4 and 5 describe the experiments conducted and the insights that emerged, in detail.
R EFERENCES 1
D. Carrington, ’Spectacular’ drop in renewable energy costs leads to record global boost,
The Guardian (2017).
J. De Jong, THE 2007 ENERGY PACKAGE: THE START OF A NEW ERA? in European energy
law report V, Energy & law series No. 7, edited by U. Hammer and M. Roggenkamp
(Intersentia ; Distribution for the USA and Canada [by] International Specialized Book
Services, Antwerp ; Portland, OR : Portland, OR, 2008) pp. 96–97.
R. Hildingsson, J. Stripple, and A. Jordan, Governing Renewable Energy in the EU: Con-
fronting a Governance Dilemma, European Political Science 11, 18 (2012).
E. Commission, Energy for the future: Renewable sources of energy, Tech. Rep.
COM(97)599 (European Commission, 1997).
J. Cludius, H. Hermann, F. C. Matthes, and V. Graichen, The merit order effect of wind
and photovoltaic electricity generation in Germany 2008–2016: Estimation and distri-
butional implications, Energy Economics 44, 302 (2014).
N. Ederer, The market value and impact of offshore wind on the electricity spot market:
Evidence from Germany, Applied Energy 154, 805 (2015).
A. O’Mahoney and E. Denny, Electricity prices and generator behaviour in gross pool elec-
tricity markets, Energy Policy 63, 628 (2013).
T. Traber and C. Kemfert, Impacts of the German Support for Renewable Energy on Elec-
tricity Prices, Emissions, and Firms, The Energy Journal 30, 155 (2009).
T. Traber and C. Kemfert, Gone with the wind? — Electricity market prices and incen-
tives to invest in thermal power plants under increasing wind energy supply, Energy
Economics 33, 249 (2011).
H. Weigt, Germany’s wind energy: The potential for fossil capacity replacement and cost
saving, Applied Energy 86, 1857 (2009).
L. Hirth, The market value of variable renewables: The effect of solar wind power variabil-
1 ity on their relative price, Energy Economics 38, 218 (2013).
E. Commission, Launching the public consultation process on a new energy market de-
sign, Tech. Rep. COM(2015) 340 final (Brussels, 2015).
European Commission and Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs, En-
ergy economic developments: investment perspectives in electricity markets. (Publica-
tions Office, Luxembourg, 2015) oCLC: 948760359.
C. Huber, T. Faber, R. Haas, G. Resch, J. Green, S. Olz, and S. White, Deriving optimal
promotion strategies for increasing the share of RES-E in a dynamic European electricity
market, Tech. Rep. (2004).
D. Most and W. Fichtner, Renewable energy sources in European energy supply and in-
teractions with emission trading, The Role of Trust in Managing Uncertainties in the
Transition to a Sustainable Energy Economy, Special Section with Regular Papers 38,
2898 (2010).
B. Fais, M. Blesl, U. Fahl, and A. Voß, Comparing different support schemes for renewable
electricity in the scope of an energy systems analysis, Applied Energy 131, 479 (2014).
L. Dressler, Support Schemes for Renewable Electricity in the European Union: Producer
Strategies and Competition, Energy Economics , (2016).
P. del Rio and P. Linares, Back to the future? Rethinking auctions for renewable electricity
support, Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 35, 42 (2014).
2
T HEORETICAL F OUNDATIONS :
I DENTIFYING THE DESIGN SPACE
Parts of this chapter have been published in Energy Policy 187, 228 (2017) Iychettira et al. (2017)
13
14 2. T HEORETICAL F OUNDATIONS : I DENTIFYING THE DESIGN SPACE
2.1. I NTRODUCTION
The outcomes of a certain policy depend on far more than variables such as price and
quantity. They depend on explicit or implicit institutions which may be part of the policy
or part of the environment surrounding the policy, that shape the socio-technical sys-
2 tem. As Polski and Ostrom (1999) point out, "Institutions delimit the capacity for social
change. They are important because they are intentional constructions that structure
information and create incentives ...thereby imposing constraints on the range of possi-
ble behaviour and feasible reforms." This makes institutional analysis paramount in the
study of policy design. In addition, such analyses lend to the policy maker, a structured
set of policy design characteristics which to operate on the socio-technical system. The
challenge then lies in identifying the most essential design characteristics of a policy or
set of policies, which are sufficiently informed by their institutional setting, and evaluat-
ing their impacts on the socio-technical system.
Some studies have tried to incorporate a more comprehensive approach to RES-E
policy design, see for instance work by Bergmann et al. (2008), and Batlle et al. (2012a).
Most literature uses a "policy analysis approach" where comparisons and categoriza-
tions are made between and across different existing policies; for examples refer to Batlle
et al. (2012b), Kitzing et al. (2012),Kitzing (2014), and Fagiani et al. (2013). It is proposed
here however, that the basic unit of analysis is not the policy itself, but a set of "design
elements". Design elements refer to the detailed components that make up a certain
policy; for instance, technology specificity, location specificity, duration of support etc.
Two seemingly different RES-E support policies can be designed such that they have an
equivalent effect on the market. This idea has been upheld by several authors such as
Batlle et al. (2012a), del Rio and Linares (2014), del Rio and Mir-Artigues (2014), and
Haas et al. (2011). However, they have been empirical observations, rather than a formal
approach to policy design.
The primary objective of this chapter is to introduce a formal, structured approach
to the design of policies for stimulation of RES-E in Europe. To achieve this, we decom-
pose the objective into the following sub-objectives: (1) to identify a set of necessary and
sufficient policy design elements to incentivise RES-E in Europe, and (2) to introduce
a modelling framework to analyze the impact of policy design elements on the socio-
technical system.
In order to accomplish the above sub-objectives we introduce a formal method based
on design theory and institutional analysis to identify a policy design space, i.e., a set of
necessary and sufficient design variables that we term ’design elements’. These design
elements are identified for a certain level of analysis1 , and for a selected set of partici-
pants in the socio-technical system. Following this, a modelling framework to facilitate
the analysis of the design elements, and identify the impact of each individual design
variable on the socio-technical system is presented. The modelling framework is imple-
mented using agent-based modelling and simulation. Such a formal approach would
not only help analyse existing policies and their impact on the socio-technical system,
but also help explore the full policy design space in a structured fashion, by incorporat-
1 In Chapter 2 of Ostrom (2005) ’levels of analysis’ are described thus: “All rules are nested in another set of
rules that define how the first set of rules can be changed. . . It is useful to distinguish levels of rules that
cumulatively affect actions taken and outcomes obtained in any setting.”
2.2. T HEORETICAL F OUNDATIONS AND M ETHODOLOGY 15
Figure 2.1: Generic Conceptual Design Framework from Herder and Stikkelman (2004)
In Taeihagh et al. (2009), an analogy has been drawn between process design and pol-
icy design, to inform transport policy. Their work is based on the theoretical frameworks
16 2. T HEORETICAL F OUNDATIONS : I DENTIFYING THE DESIGN SPACE
of Process System Engineering. The framework used in this work, the Generic Concep-
tual Design Framework (GCDF), also has its roots in Process System Engineering.
The Generic Conceptual Design Framework has been developed collaboratively at
the Carnegie Mellon University and Delft University of Technology. It is illustrated in
Figure 2.1. This work is based on the design framework (specifically the problem def-
2 inition and conceptual design aspects) initially developed by Westerberg et al. (1997),
which draws heavily from process system engineering, and is described in detail and ap-
plied in Herder and Stikkelman (2004) and Subrahmanian et al. (2003). The framework
comprises of the following main concepts, which together, structure the content of any
level in a design process: 1. design goals; 2. design objectives (selection of goals to be op-
timized); 3. design constraints (goals that need not be optimised); 4. tests for the goals;
and 5. design space.
One may contend, as Rittel and Webber (1973) did, that for most social planning
problems or ‘wicked problems’, the concept of design is a technocratic activity and is
not applicable to policy making, as policy-making is a value-laden activity, and therefore
its appraisal is highly dependent on each participant’s personal value-set. In response,
Howlett (2011) writes that there must be a distinction drawn between ‘design’ as a verb,
and that as a noun - instead of treating design as an outcome, he urges the reader to
view it as a process of "channelling the energies of disparate actors towards agreement
in working towards similar goals in specific contexts." And that is the viewpoint that we
wish to subscribe to.
A note on institutional economic theories: In this work the authors put forth a frame-
work while remaining agnostic with regard to the theory that should be used; whether
it should be transaction cost economics, neoclassical economics or a combination. We
emphasize that we present and apply a framework, and not a theory, for policy design
2
In order to demonstrate the framework’s application to a model, in this particular in-
stance we adopt thories based on neoclassical economics, and also incorporate strong
assumptions of imperfect information and bounded rationality. Imperfect information
and bounded rationality are assumptions common in the institutionalist perspectives.
2 We adopt the definitions of a theory and a framework presented by (Ostrom, 2005, chap .2); they are repro-
duced below.
The development and use of a general framework helps to identify the elements (and the relationships among
these elements) that one needs to consider for institutional analysis. Frameworks organize diagnostic and pre-
scriptive inquiry. They provide the most general set of variables that should be used to analyze all types of
settings relevant for the framework.
The development and use of theories enable the analyst to specify which components of a framework are rele-
vant for certain kinds of questions and to make broad working assumptions about these elements. Thus, theo-
ries focus on parts of a framework and make specific assumptions that are necessary for an analyst to diagnose
a phenomenon, explain its processes, and predict outcomes.
18 2. T HEORETICAL F OUNDATIONS : I DENTIFYING THE DESIGN SPACE
Drawing from the aforementioned frameworks, a new framework for policy design is
introduced in this section. This policy design framework maintains the basic structure
of the generic conceptual design framework, while allowing different components of the
IAD framework to inform it.
On the one hand, the design framework facilitates specification of goals and con-
straints of the policy maker, the specification of a design space, and provides a frame-
work to evaluate alternatives based on the goals. The IAD framework on the other hand
helps, decompose the socio-technical system, and specifications of interactions between
participants, and interactions between participants and the physical environment. The
latter therefore plays a paramount role in delineating the design space, understanding
and specifying possible behaviours of actors, understanding action-outcome linkages,
which can then be tested, while the former provides a structure to the process of formu-
lating the goals, and evaluating potential alternatives.
The policy design framework, called ‘A Generic Policy Design Framework’ is depicted
in Figure 2.3. The original design framework itself is depicted within dark, bold lines
in the figure, while the grey boxes and dashed lines indicate how the IAD framework
contributes to the design process. The Generic POlicy Design framework is explained
below.
1. Design goals: The intended goals of the policy to be designed are usually set by the
community itself. The concept of ’multiple levels of analysis’ described in Chapter
2 of Ostrom (2005), helps identify which participants at what level, frame these
goals, and/or constraints. According to Ostrom’s definition, the rules-in-use3 at
3 Rules which affect day-to-day behaviour of participants, in the context of the issue being analyzed.
2.2. T HEORETICAL F OUNDATIONS AND M ETHODOLOGY 19
an operational level are set one level deeper, at a ’collective’ level. This is shown
in Figure 2.4. In reality, the policy maker exists at least in two levels: the member-
state level, and at the European level. However, for the sake of illustration in Figure
2.4, it is assumed that values and objectives of the two entities are aligned. The
policy objectives therefore, are derived from the broad objectives of the European
Commission as mentioned in European Commission (2014). These objectives are 2
mentioned below. To improve the ease of associating between policy attributes
and overall objectives, we operationalize the objectives into specific ones.
2. Design space: Discerning the design space requires the policy analyst to make
decisions regarding which design variables are relevant. The action situation in
the IAD framework is defined thus, "whenever two or more individuals are faced
with a set of potential actions that jointly produces outcomes, these individuals
can be said to be "in" an action situation" according to Ostrom (2005). Therefore,
the action situation outlines potential actions that participants can take, and out-
comes an action could lead to, based on their perceived notions of which actions
lead to which outcomes, called ‘action-outcome linkages’. For instance, the energy
producer must make decisions regarding which technology to invest in, where to
place the power plant, and its size. The policy maker would, at the very least, have
20 2. T HEORETICAL F OUNDATIONS : I DENTIFYING THE DESIGN SPACE
3. Tests: The next step in the design framework calls for developing and executing
a test. This test would simulate patterns of interactions, based on design objec-
tives, constraints and design variables discerned in the previous steps. In order to
simulate patterns of interactions that lead to outcomes, tests must include specifi-
cations of action-outcome linkages. This would mean that simulations must spec-
ify behaviour that is theoretically or empirically supported, and that participants
are expected to show given certain setting of exogenous variables. The test should
help understand and explain which outcomes are created under what different
conditions of the design space,. Agent-based modelling is a suitable approach for
creating such simulations, as described in Section 2.2.1. A detailed description of
the modelling framework created in order to simulate the impact of RES-E design
elements is presented in section 3.4.
4. Outcomes and Selection: The outcomes from the simulation help identify which
configurations of design variables (design elements) lead to desired outcomes.
With the help of the goals identified in step one, it is possible to select a config-
uration of design elements that meet the objectives and constraints of the policy
issue to be resolved.
So far, a rather general overview of the Policy Design Framework has been provided.
Central to the objectives of this paper is the identification of a closed set of design ele-
ments. Therefore, it is befitting that this aspect of the policy design framework is paid
further attention.
2. variables which indicate whether the purview of one or more of the above decision
variables further apply to each decision variable at the operational level (Decision 2
Variables 1 and 2, in Figure 2.4); for instance whether the warranty could be tech-
nology neutral or specific, location neutral or specific, and size neutral or specific.
Depending on the objectives of, and assumptions underlying the analysis, not all
design elements may be considered for evaluation. The choice of design elements for
evaluation may be strongly influenced by the frame of analysis. In an exhaustive work,
Bobrow and Dryzek (1987) highlight the different frames of analysis within policy analy-
sis; two such frames are outlined here. A welfare economics perspective would assume
a benevolent policy-maker whose only interest is to increase social welfare. A public
choice perspective posits that politicians and bureaucrats are more interested in serving
their own interests, rather than that of the public. For instance, in the particular case
of designing RES-E support, the decision regarding whether the subsidy costs are borne
by the state budget versus electricity consumers, would be much more relevant in the
public choice perspective, rather than one of welfare economics. This idea is revisited
and clarified in Section 2.3.1 and critically examined in Section 2.5.
2011). In order to realize this level of decarbonisation, policy makers design schemes to
incentivize investment in RES-E sources.
The policy maker implementing a support scheme therefore forms one action-situation.
The second action situation involves producers of renewable electricity; they are as-
sumed to be boundedly rational actors attempting to maximize their profits via actions
2 such as investments in electricity producing technologies. Their strategy for investment
in RES-E generation capacity is to make a cost benefit analysis, i.e., a net present value
calculation for each investment decision, under uncertainty. This is a stylized represen-
tation of actors, to make the analysis tractable. It must be noted however that represen-
tation is only one instantiation of the modelling framework presented.
The disadvantage of this abstraction is that it does not consider actors who might
have other motives (to be autarkic, to self-consume, to create an energy community, to
produce green energy for its own sake). On the other hand, the largest share of current
energy production comes from utility companies whose primary motive is profitability,
irrespective of differences in ownership or corporate structure. Also, even if other own-
ership structures were in place, it is hard to imagine a scenario where an actor would not
be concerned with the profitability of the project. Therefore, in the current modelling
framework, we assume that the Energy Producer agent makes an investment only when
the cost-benefit analyses indicate profitability.
Ostrom (2005) defines an action situation in terms of the following elements: par-
ticipants, positions, actions, outcomes, action-outcome linkages, information about the
action situation, and payoffs or the costs and benefits. These elements have been de-
fined, and their corresponding values have been identified for the two action situations
presented above.
However, information about future prices, and therefore revenue, and therefore whether
the decision is a viable one, is notoriously difficult to predict. Uncertainty comes in the
form of other actors’ decisions on investment, regulatory uncertainty, fuel price uncer-
tainty which impact the electricity market price and therefore the revenue, and uncer-
tainty regarding future electricity prices. It is assumed that producers’ strategy is profit
maximising, while the government’s goal is to reach the renewable target (constraint) in
an affordable (cost-effective) manner. It is also assumed that regulators have as much
information as the energy producers. And that each energy producer is aware of others’
past decisions on investment.
The IAD framework, thus set-up for impacts of RES-E policies on energy investment,
is illustrated in Figure 2.5. The figure also illustrates how information from the IAD
framework feeds into the policy design framework, and populates the design space. In
the next section explanations of the design elements are provided.
participants at two levels can make: the operational (energy producer), and the collec-
tive (policy-maker) levels. As mentioned earlier, the assumption is that the actions are
of a benevolent policy maker concerned with welfare economics. This is shown in Fig-
ure 2.5. The design elements are based on insights from literature on renewable support
schemes. Looking at the problem from the lens of a welfare economics perspective nar-
rows down literature to that extent. The formulation of design elements is also an iter-
ative process, where comparisons are made with a set of existing policies implemented.
The comparisons with empirical experiences is presented in Section 2.4.
One could then wonder how the design elements below are different from those de-
termined based on neo-classical economics. While the design elements quantity or price
warranty do indeed originate directly from neoclassical economics, many others do not.
In a neoclassical firm, the only function of management is to select profit-maximizing
quantities of outputs and inputs, which means, determining the quantity and the conse-
quent price that is established; see North (1991). Other core assumptions of neoclassical
economics include rationality (utility maximization), and a focus on the existence of an
equilibrium; read Himmelweit et al. (2011).
Other design elements mentioned in the current paper however, are not typically
considered in neoclassical economics. In order to make analyses tractable, equilibrium
models frequently make abstractions regarding perfect knowledge of costs, revenues,
and competitive positions. Therefore, design elements such as contract duration and
frequency of change in warranty do not typically feature in partial or general equilibrium
models. Another important abstraction in neoclassical economics is that firms exist to
produce an already fully defined product. The idea of diversification or specification of
products as interchangeable depending on changing institutions (such as policies on as-
2.3. A PPLYING THE POLICY DESIGN FRAMEWORK TO RES-E SUPPORT DESIGN 25
set specificity) is difficult to incorporate into the analysis as the product has already been
defined. Therefore, design elements such as asset (technology, size, location) specificity
also do not typically feature in partial or general equilibrium models. Some argue that
the institutionalist perspective itself is characterised in terms of how it differs from the
neoclassical perspective Himmelweit et al. (2011). We provide a method to incorporate
these differences and operationalize their analysis. 2
Another aspect of the way the design elements are chosen, is that they are mutually
exclusive from another; if two actions are substitutable, then they become alternative
states for one design element. For instance, either a price warranty or a quantity war-
ranty must be chosen by the welfare maximizing policy-maker, he does not set both si-
multaneously. However, he can choose technology specificity in addition to say, quantity
warranty.
Table 2.2 below lists the complete set of design elements, and their possible impacts
on the socio-technical system, as hypothesized in literature. Their impacts on the socio-
technical system is referred to with the term "action-outcome linkages" as per the IAD
framework.
Table 2.2: Design Elements
Size specificity This element would Larger installations allow for economies of Batlle
allow the differentiat- scale, while incentivizing smaller sized ap- et al.
ing of support levels plications lead to more decentralized gen- (2012a)
by size. eration, and could reduce market power.
With greater smaller sized technologies,
Table 2.3: Existing RES-E Support Schemes in terms of Design Elements. Source: Commission (2012)
L IMITATIONS
Important assumptions have been made regarding characteristics of the participants
and the action situations that they might find themselves in. For instance, a producer
makes decisions mainly regarding economic and physical aspects of the technology. In
reality however, there are other action situations through which policy makers could be
eventually influenced. For instance, if a severe penalty or taxes were to be introduced,
workers could organize a protest. Or if a technology were to be completely banned, as
nuclear energy has been in Germany, producers could file a lawsuit against the govern-
ment like Vattenfall did. Therefore, the analysis is limited in that the design space does
not include say, the ’political man’ or the ’emotional man’, but mainly focuses on the
’rational man’, although boundedly so. In that sense, the analysis so far could be charac-
terised as being technocratic. Indeed, if the energy producer agent were to assume mul-
tiple identities, such as being politically active and strongly pushing for local autarky, the
design elements would be different. Another limitation of the approach as presented, is
2.6. C ONCLUSIONS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS 29
its computationally intensive nature; further attention could be paid to the process of
reducing the number of design elements to suit computationally constrained situations.
Despite the limitations, within the action situation and roles outlined in this analysis,
and from a welfare economics paradigm, the approach presented provides a methodol-
ogy for creating, simulating, and testing a complete policy design space.
2
2.6. C ONCLUSIONS AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS
Energy policy design in Europe is a complex issue: not least because of the co-existence
of a common European policy, along with very disparate policies at the member state
levels. The policy maker is faced with the daunting challenge of analysing multiple ac-
tors, multiple decision criteria, at multiple levels of operation and/or governance. Us-
ing a combination of design theory, institutional analysis, and agent-based modelling
(ABM), we provide a method to systematically explore policy design options for RES-E
support in Europe. This is done firstly by identification of decision variables, which then
lead to the design elements of a policy, and secondly by evaluating the impact of each
design element on the socio-technical system using an agent-based model.
Given a certain frame of analysis, we propose that it is theoretically possible to iden-
tify the complete policy design space. Crucially, this aspect potentially opens up to the
policy analyst new avenues for intervention, and allows her to explore, given a range of
uncertainties, which element(s) of intervention is(are) the most vital to achieve goals of
the community. The applicability of the approach is demonstrated by representing and
differentiating between six renewable electricity support schemes from Western Europe
in terms of the design elements. The applicability of the modelling framework using
ABM, and consequently the Design Element Approach, is demonstrated by evaluating
the long-term, dynamic impact of three design elements: price warranty versus quan-
tity warranty, technology neutrality versus specificity, and accounting for the electricity
market price ex-ante versus ex-post on the Dutch electricity sector. A vital result, demon-
strated in Chapter 4 and described in section 4.3.1, is that technology specificity leads to
making the scheme 60% more cost effective than technology neutrality.
It is important to note here that claims of completeness of the design space come
with limitations. For instance, if the energy producer agent were to assume multiple
identities, such as being politically active and strongly pushing for local autarky, the de-
sign elements would be different. The design framework published here therefore per-
tains mainly to an analysis which lies within the scope of welfare economics, although
founded firmly within an institutional framework and empirical experience. Other lim-
itations of the approach include its computationally intensive nature, and the need to
prudently select the most important design elements necessary for the analysis.
Avenues for future work are many. The foremost of these involve demonstrating
with modelling, the application of this framework to understand impacts of different re-
newable electricity policy designs in neighbouring countries sharing one common elec-
tricity market, on cross-border welfare effects. Such work would pave the way towards
quantitatively understanding whether and how renewable support scheme designs in
neighbouring member states should be harmonised, in view of the common electricity
market. This analysis is being performed for a forthcoming paper. Other possibilities
for future work include designing an endogenous policy-maker agent, who dynamically
30 2. T HEORETICAL F OUNDATIONS : I DENTIFYING THE DESIGN SPACE
changes values of design variables based on indicators in the model. The most challeng-
ing avenue for further exploration would be to identify a design space involving agents
with more than just economical considerations and identities, but are more complex
involving perhaps political and cultural considerations as well.
The implications of this work are, from the perspective of the authors, most useful
2 for policy makers of RES-E support schemes, at both the member-state and at European
levels. Given that governance of renewable energy support beyond 2020 at the European
level is still undefined, while a European target for renewables has been set, this work
paves the way for a more comprehensive, formal, empirically founded analysis of RES-E
policy design than what currently prevails.
R EFERENCES 31
R EFERENCES
K. K. Iychettira, R. A. Hakvoort, P. Linares, and R. d. Jeu, Towards a comprehensive policy
for electricity from renewable energy: Designing for social welfare, Applied Energy 187,
228 (2017).
M. M. Polski and E. Ostrom, An Institutional Framework for Policy Analysis and Design,
2
(Indiana University, Bloomington, IN, 1999).
P. del Rio and P. Linares, Back to the future? Rethinking auctions for renewable electricity
support, Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 35, 42 (2014).
P. del Rio and P. Mir-Artigues, Combinations of support instruments for renewable elec-
tricity in Europe: A review, Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 40, 287 (2014).
M. Howlett, Revisiting Policy Design: The Rise and Fall (and Rebirth?) of Policy Design
Studies, (Reykjavik, Iceland, 2011).
32 R EFERENCES
S. H. Linder and B. G. Peters, From Social Theory to Policy Design, Journal of Public Policy
4, 237 (1984).
M. Howlett and P. del Rio, Policy Portfolios and their Design: A Meta Analysis, (Grenoble,
France, 2013).
2
M. Considine, Thinking Outside the Box? Applying Design Theory to Public Policy, Politics
and Policy 40, 704 (2012).
N. Gilbert, Agent-based social simulation: dealing with complexity, The Complex Systems
Network of Excellence 9, 1 (2004).
B. Fais, M. Blesl, U. Fahl, and A. Voß, Comparing different support schemes for renewable
electricity in the scope of an energy systems analysis, Applied Energy 131, 479 (2014).
C. Huber, T. Faber, R. Haas, G. Resch, J. Green, S. Olz, and S. White, Deriving optimal pro-
motion strategied for increasing hte share of RES-E in a dynamic European electricity
market, Tech. Rep. (2004).
E. Commission, RES Legal Europe Database for Regulation on Renewable Energy Gener-
ation, (2012), rES LEGAL Europe is the website on regulations on renewable energy
generation. In the database you will find information on the important legislation on
the support schemes, grid issues and policies for energy from renewable sources cov-
ering all three energy sectors: electricity, heating & cooling and transport. The scope
of this database covers all the EU 27 Member States, the EFTA Countries and some EU
Accession Countries. The website offers links to all relevant original legislation, is free
of charge and is updated on a regular basis.
BEIS, Contracts for Difference: An explanation of the methodology used to set adminis-
trative CFD strike prices for the next CFD allocation round, Tech. Rep. (Department for
Business, Energy and Industrial Strategy, 2016).
J.-M. Glachant and S. Ruester, The EU internal electricity market : done forever?, Working
Paper (2013).
3
M ODELLING : EML AB G ENERATION
AND R ENEWABLE S UPPORT
Parts of this chapter have been published in Applied Energy 106, 169 (2017) Iychettira et al. (2017)
35
36 3. M ODELLING : EML AB G ENERATION AND R ENEWABLE S UPPORT
3.1. I NTRODUCTION
In the previous chapters the problem was described, and theoretical, conceptual foun-
dations to perceiving the problem and evaluating alternatives were established. The ob-
jective of this chapter is to describe the "testing enviroment", or the model that is used
to evaluate various policy options over the course of this dissertation.
The Energy Modelling Laboratory, known as EMLab, is an open source energy mod-
elling project initiated at the Energy and Industry section of the Technology Policy Man-
agement faculty at the Delft University of Technology. Multiple doctoral and master’s
3 students have learnt from and contributed to this project over the past several years. This
dissertation builds on the shoulders of those proverbial giants who have contributed to
EMLab before me, and have helped me render my own contributions to it.
The initial conceptualisation and implementation of EMLab-Generation was carried
out by de Vries et al. (2012). The AgentSpring agent-based modelling framework created
by Chmieliauskas et al. (2012) provided the software architecture platform for the model.
Work on power market transition models by Chappin (2011) also contributed to the con-
ceptualisation and implementation of the core modules of EMLab. Richstein (2015) fin-
ished its implementation and verified and validated the model. Several conceptual and
practical improvements were made: the investment algorithm was improved, banking
was incorporated into the CO2 market. This chapter seeks to describe in detail the parts
of existing EMLab that have been used for this work, and the additional parts that were
especially built to address the research questions of this dissertation.
To help the reader peruse relevant sections, a short reading guide is presented here.
Firstly, based on the analysis from the previous chapter, the system to be modelled is de-
lineated, and the main agents whose behaviours are modelled are presented in Section
3.2. Secondly, the parts of EMLab that existed prior to the start of this work, and that
are relevant to this work are descibed in Section 3.3. Finally, the parts of EMLab, that
were created by the author specially for the purposes of her doctoral programme, i.e.,
the models of the different RES-E support schemes are described in 3.4.
2 The word instantiation is used to mean: ‘(of a universal or abstract concept) have an instance; be represented
by an actual example.’
3.2. S YSTEM DECOMPOSITION OF B ASE M ODEL IN EML AB 37
• Domain classes are the definitions of things and their properties. Classes such as
Energy Producer and EnergyConsumer under package Agent, and classes such as
Bid and ClearingPoint under package Market are examples.
38 3. M ODELLING : EML AB G ENERATION AND R ENEWABLE S UPPORT
• Role classes capture behaviour, executed by specific classes from the domain pack-
ages. For instance, the agent EnergyProducer acts the SubmitOffersToElectricity-
MarketRole.
• Repository classes contain functions that deal with interaction of model code and
the database. They also assist in updating current information and storing new
information.
• Scenario xml files consist of all the data required to define and initialize a simula-
tion run. It contains data as well as relations between objects.
While this section described the what and the who, i.e., things, objects and agents,
the following sections are a description of the model narrative. The model narrative is
a story that relates the behaviours of the agents with time, i.e., it explains which agent
does what with whom and when.
order, and a uniform market clearing price is determined at the intersection of demand
and supply for that load segment. The two flowcharts in this section indicate the main
algorithmic processes in EMLab. Market clearing within one tick (year) is performed
using an annual load duration curve. The time resolution is indeed yearly. However, the
annual load duration curve, comprising 8760 hours of different loads, is approximated
into twenty segments in view of computational resource constraints. Each segment is
represented by a pair of values: a load (in MW), and period (in hours). For instance,
segment 1 is (8160.778 MW, 17h), segment 2 is (8390.36, 77h) and so on. For each load
segment, the electricity spot market is cleared individually according to uniform price
clearing, and price volume pairs are determined for each of the 20 load segments. 3
Start
Invest into new capacity
Determine expected
Run RES-E Support Scheme
revenues and costs for
future base year
Attractive
alternatives
exist
Select power
Stop plants with
Increment tick, update system data highest NPV
Choice
Is tick<40?
Create new power plant,
Yes
start construction, pay
No downpayment
End
Figure 3.3: Flowcharts showing the overall EMLab algorithm, and the investment algorithm.
This dynamic determination of the load duration curve is demonstrated in the flowchart
presented in Figure 3.4. The figure shows that the residual load duration curve is deter-
mined for each price zone separately. If spillage3 exists in all zones, there is no exchange
between the zones. If spillage exists in either zone, it is exported to the other country
upto the extent that the interconnector capacity allows it. Hourly values of load and
supply are then aggregated into twenty load segments and the electricity prices are de-
termined in each zone.
3 Spillage is the RES-E production that is greater than the sum of the demand and interconnection capacity.
3.3. E LECTRICITY SPOT MARKET AND I NVESTMENT 41
have a limited knowledge of the future is an important feature of the model, as it leads to
sub-optimal decisions being made. This corresponds to reality where expectations often
differ from actual outcomes, as explained by Richstein et al. (2014).
Based on the expected electricity market prices, marginal costs vc g ,t +n ,the fixed op-
eration and maintenance cost f c g ,t +n , segment-dependent available capacity of power
plant a g ,s , and the expected running hours r s,g ,t +n ,which is also calculated from the ex-
pected electricity prices and marginal cost per segment, the cash flow for reference year
t + n of operation for the power plant is calculated as follows.
3
C FOp,g = C I n f l ow Op,g −COut f l ow Op,g
∗
= Σs p s,t +n × r s,g ,t +n × a g ,s (3.1)
! "
− Σs vc g ,t +n × r s,g ,t +n × a g ,s + f c g ,t +n
The economic viability of each power plant of capacity K g , is then assessed with ini-
tial capital costs,I g , over the building period 0..t b , and the service period, t b +1...t b +t D .
The Weighted Average Cost of Capital (WACC) is used as the discount rate. The Net
Present Value (NPV), which discounts all future costs and benefits into present value, is
calculated by each energy producer for each technology in order to make an investment
decision:
# −I g
t
N PVg = Σtb=0
(1 + W ACC )t
(3.2)
t b +t D C I n f l ow Op,g COut f l ow Op,g $
+ Σt =t − /K g
b +1 (1 + W ACC r ev )t (1 + W ACC )t
Where D is the debt value, E is the equity value, V is the total value. The debt equity
ratio is set at 70:30. In Equation (3.2), risk aversion to price volatility is incorporated in
the inflow or revenue component by an adjusted W ACC , called the W ACC r ev . The rate
of equity component in the W ACC r ev , described in Equation (3.4), r E , is expressed as the
sum of a basic equity rate, r Eb set to 11%, and a price risk equity rate, r E p set to 3%.The
cost of debt, r D is set at 5.5%. This is based on data from DiaCore (2016).
Each agent thus iteratively computes the NPV for every technology, and invests in the
technology with the highest positive NPV. This algorithm is presented in Figure 3.3b. This
description so far forms the base model, on which RES-E support design elements have
been built. The conceptual model of RES-E policies is explained below. The model is
implemented in Java and the source code is openly accessible4 . It is important to note at
this stage, that economic decommissioning of the power plants has not been modelled;
the plants are operational through the whole of their technical lifetimes, even if their
marginal profits are negative.
4 https://github.com/Kaveri3012/emlab-generation/tree/feature/SocialWelfareAnalysis
42 3. M ODELLING : EML AB G ENERATION AND R ENEWABLE S UPPORT
Figure 3.5: Specification of Java class structures of Agents and RES-E scheme using design elements.
At the outset, it must be noted that three design elements have been modelled, while
keeping the others constant. A simplification to three design elements allows for clarity
in interpretation, is sufficient for demonstration of the framework, and is a strong first
step towards incorporating more design elements. Due to these reasons, and in order to
keep within time and other resource constraints, we settled with modelling only three
design elements.
ming. The design elements identified in the previous step together make up the proper-
ties of the RES-E class. This is represented in 3.5. The processes or behaviours related to
the different properties are the ’methods’ of the class. The source code is openly acces-
sible 5 .
Figure 3.7 shows four of the eight possible inherited RES-E Schemes for three design
elements. The quantity based schemes include a function or a method to organize auc-
tions based on the other design elements of the scheme, such as technology specificity,
location specificity, contract (ex-post or ex-ante). The price based schemes includes a
function to compute the remuneration, depending on specified design elements. A high-
level flow chart of the process flow in the model is presented in Figure 3.6. 3
Different representations of the RES-E Support Schemes are be inherited6 , and con-
tain processes that are functions of design elements. Other classes in the model repre-
sent the agents Energy Producer and Government, and their decision-making processes.
1. Quantitative targets for renewable energy generation are exogenously, for each
year, set by extrapolating the targets mentioned in the National Renewable Energy
Action Plan of Economic Affairs Agriculture and Innovation (2010). This comprises
the demand side of the auction.
2. The quantity warranty is implemented as a sealed bid uniform price auction, for
contracts that span a pre-decided period of years7 , like a tender 8
3. Depending on the specification of design element 3, technology specificity, annual
auctions are organized for each technology separately or for all technologies si-
multaneously.
3 4. Producer agents submit bids each year for new projects, by computing the ex-
pected cost and benefit of the project either by Equation (3.5) or (3.7), depending
on whether the scheme is designed ex-post or ex-ante.
5. The payments are then made annually for the winning bids for the duration of the
contract period (20 years) according to Equation (3.6) or (3.9).
technologies. In a price warranty scheme, the regulator agent is assumed to have infor-
mation regarding technology costs and technology potentials. With this knowledge and
given the exogenously set RES-E target, the agent constructs a supply-demand curve,
and computes a single quantity X for all technologies.
Ex-ante In this version, the revenue from the electricity market is taken into account
X ant e g
ex-ante for the calculation of the remuneration. In the first step, a quantity Σt =0..d (1+W ACC )t
equivalent to the total subsidy required by a plant is computed. As can be seen in Equa-
tion 3.5, this quantity is computed in the following way: the estimated revenue is sub-
tracted from the sum of the discounted value of investment cost and operating cost. The
annual payment to eligible power plants is organized by Equation 3.6. This way, the risk
of volatility of future electricity prices is relegated to the producer.
X ant e g t Ig
Σt =0..d = Σtb=0
(1 + W ACC )t (1 + W ACC )t
# C I n f l ow Op,g
t b +t D
− Σt =t (3.5)
b +1
(1 + W ACC r ev )t
COut f l ow Op,g $
+
(1 + W ACC )t
Ex-post In this version the electricity market prices are accounted for after the prices
have been realised in actuality. Since the subsidy is only paid once the electricity price is
known, the only quantity that needs to be published ahead is the ‘total cost per unit’of
the technology, variously known as the ‘base cost’or ‘strike price’in the different sup-
port schemes that implement ex-post remuneration. In the model, this is implemented
in two steps; in the first step, a quantity equivalent to the total discounted cost (fixed
X post g
and variable) of a plant, represented by the term Σt =0..d (1+W ACC )t is calculated in equa-
tion 3.7. In the second step, the annual payment to eligible power plants is organized
by equation 3.9. This shifts the price related uncertainty and risk from the electricity
producer to the government.
46 3. M ODELLING : EML AB G ENERATION AND R ENEWABLE S UPPORT
X post g t Ig
Σt =0..d = Σtb=0
(1 + W ACC )t (1 + W ACC )t
(3.7)
t b +t D COut f l ow Op,g
+ Σt =t
b +1 (1 + W ACC )t
where,
3.5. D ATA
This section consists of a description of the data used to model the electricity system.
It consists of assumptions regarding load duration curves and demand growth trend as-
sumptions. Characteristics of the technologies, their costs, availability of intermittent
technologies are also described.
D t +1 = αt × D t (3.10)
where, D is the demand at year t and α is the “growth rate” calculated from a trian-
gular distribution. A triangular distribution is a is a continuous probability distribution
with lower limit (min) a, upper limit (max) b and mode c, where a < b and a ≤ c ≤ b. The
values for a, b, and c are presented in Table A.1, in the appendix. The values are based
on the EU reference scenario of 2014 (European Commission and Direction générale de
la mobilité et des transports, 2014), which predicts a 1% growth rate. The trends are de-
picted pictorially in Figure A.1.
3.5. D ATA 47
15000
10000 3
5000
Figure 3.8: The initial load duration curve for the Netherlands split into 20 segments
80000
60000
Load [in MW]
40000
20000
Figure 3.9: The initial load duration curve for Germany split into 20 segments
48 3. M ODELLING : EML AB G ENERATION AND R ENEWABLE S UPPORT
a]
a]
a]
e[
e[
e[
tim
tim
tim
a]
]
MW
on
ion
e[
ife
y
im
cti
log
all
y[
t
cia
tru
it t
nic
cit
no
pre
rm
els
pa
ns
ch
ch
De
Co
Ca
Fu
Pe
Te
Te
Wind Offshore 600 1 0 20 20 -
PV 500 1 0 20 20 -
Wind Onshore 600 1 0 20 20 -
Coal Pulverised SC 758 4 1 50 20 Coal
Lignite 1000 5 1 50 20 Lignite
Nuclear 1000 5 2 40 25 Uranium
CCGT 776 2 1 40 15 Natural Gas
Fixed costs of technologies Costs of investment, costs of fixed operation and mainte-
nance, and efficiencies are specified for each technology for the duration of the simula-
tion. The learning curves for solar PV were created based on data from ISI (2015). The
learning curves for wind, and wind offshore were created based on data from IRENA re-
ports on costs of renewable technologies (IRENA, 2015). The yearly values for the learn-
ing curves, and the R code that was used to create them have been uploaded on a publicly
accessible data platform, cited in Iychettira (2015). The assumptions made regarding
fixed costs of conventional technologies are presented in Table A.3 in the appendix.
Simulation, characterises the process of model evaluation in the following way (Parker,
2008).
"...the question of whether the computer simulation model is an adequate represen-
tation of the target system, relative to the goals of the modelling study, is of utmost im-
portance. The activity of model evaluation (also sometimes known as ‘validation’) aims
to collect evidence regarding precisely this question. Depending on the goals of the mod-
elling study, the process of model evaluation might treat the simulation model as a black
box and focus only its output, or it might involve opening the black box to investigate
the accuracy of particular modelling assumptions and/or the adequacy of the process by
which solutions to the continuous model equations are estimated." 3
In her writing, she is also at pains to emphasize that model evaluation should be
perceived as "an investigation of the model’s adequacy for purpose, not an investigation
of its truth or falsity, whatever that might mean. A model that is constructed with the use
of a variety of false assumptions about a target system might nevertheless be an adequate
representation of that target system, relative to the goals of the modelling study. "
Drawing from the above, this section is split into two parts: Verification, where the
mathematical task of confirming whether the simulation code is implemented correctly
with respect to the conceptual model is discussed, and Validation, where the fitness of
purpose is discussed.
3.6.1. V ERIFICATION
In order to assess whether the simulation code of the agent-based model represents the
conceptual model, the following steps can be employed, based on the recommendations
in Dam et al. (2012).
2. Unit testing: In this procedure, small parts of the code are tested by predefining
inputs and providing expected outputs, after which they can be automated to eval-
uate individual units through various inputs. Two important parts of unit testing
are: 1) theoretical prediction and sanity checks 2) extreme value testing. The dis-
advantage of this method is that for a large code composed of a multitude of mod-
ules, they only provide insight on individual parts of the code, and not whether the
code works correctly together as a whole.
4. Multi-agent testing: In this step, the full model, with the complete number of
agents is tested for coherent behavioural patterns. In addition to sanity checks
described above, variability testing and timeline sanity check is also performed.
50 3. M ODELLING : EML AB G ENERATION AND R ENEWABLE S UPPORT
The above tests were applied the implemented model, as described below. In tables
3.2 and 3.3, each test, the module or role or agent behaviour to which they were em-
ployed, and outcomes are mentioned.
Table 3.2: List of checks performed to verify the correct implementation of quantity warranty schemes
Table 3.3: List of checks performed to verify the correct implementation of price warranty schemes
Feed in premium
as the power plant owner.
For a new elegible plant, • For ex-post policies, check whether Verified. 3
role. a contract is made. For annual subsidy = cost - revenue from
each eligible power plant, electricity market.
the support price is calcu- • For ex-ante policies, check whether
lated and payment made subsidy = tender clearing price * power
generated.
Full price war- • The investments should be upto the Verified.
ranty algorithm potential of the technology.
3.6.2. VALIDATION
Wendy Parker provides the following strategies to determine the internal and external
validity of a code10 (Parker, 2008). Although it is too early in the dissertation to discuss
the validity of the results, a framework for testing validity is presented, based on the
insights drawn from strategies in physical experiment validation to code evaluation. The
strategies and their application to the code presented is discussed below.
• Simulation output fits closely with observational data: In the context of the model
presented, this strategy would be similar to historical validation. When input data
such as demand, initial supply, and fuel prices match historical values, the outputs
such as electricity prices should also match their corresponding historical values.
While the analysis presented in Chapter 4 is indicative, historical data has been
used for the analysis presented in Chapter 5, and consequently a discussion is pre-
sented on the similarities of the results with observational data in that Chapter.
far more complicated than what neo-classical economics allows for. While deci-
sions are taken based on cost-benefit analyses, the outcome is rarely a long-term
equilibrium due to factors such as imperfect information. For such analyses, as-
sumptions that are face validated are used; assumptions that are validated by ex-
perts in the field - through peer review, presenting works at conferences, talking to
practitioners etc.
3.7. C ONCLUSION
Having laid down theoretical foundations in the previous chapter, this chapter concep-
tualized and formalized the algorithms employed, and the primary narrative embodied
in the simulation. The instrument used to perform the core of the analysis was described
in detail in this chapter. The process of gathering data was also briefly described: the
sources and means of obtaining the information on generation technologies, demands,
costs, plausible assumptions for trends related to expectations of future growth.
No simulation is complete without checking whether it is verified and validated. The
final section of this chapter therefore described what verification entails for an agent-
based model of investment in the power sector. The various checks performed to ensure
the code was built as intended were described. This was followed by a discussion on
the framework to assess its suitability for its intended purpose, and how that has been
implemented in the thesis. The following chapters present the experiments that were
conducted with the simulation described, the major analysis, and insights that follow.
R EFERENCES 53
R EFERENCES
K. K. Iychettira, R. A. Hakvoort, and P. Linares, Towards a comprehensive policy for elec-
tricity from renewable energy: An approach for policy design, Energy Policy 106, 169
(2017).
J. Richstein, Interactions between carbon and power markets in transition (Delft Univer-
sity of Technology, Netherlands, 2015).
DiaCore, The impact of risks in renewable energy investments and the role of smart poli-
cies, Work Package 3 Leader Organisation: ECOFYS IEE/12/833/SI2.645735 (Ecofys,
2016).
A.-R. Laali and M. Benard, French wind power generation programme EOLE 2005 Results
of the first call for tenders, Renewable Energy 16, 805 (1999).
F. ISI, Current and Future Cost of Photovoltaics. Long-term Scenarios for Market Develop-
ment, System Prices and LCOE of Utility-Scale PV Systems., Study on behalf of Agora
Energiewende. 059/01-S-2015/EN (Freiburg, 2015).
L. Hirth, The market value of variable renewables: The effect of solar wind power variabil-
ity on their relative price, Energy Economics 38, 218 (2013).
H. Lion, Hourly capacity factors for intermittent generation - Datasets - the Datahub,
(2013).
Parts of this chapter have been published in Applied Energy 187, 228 (2017) Iychettira et al. (2017)
55
56 4. R ENEWABLE SUPPORT INTERACTS WITH THE ELECTRICITY MARKET
4.1. I NTRODUCTION
4.1.1. M OTIVATION AND R ESEARCH O BJECTIVE
In a recent article on the transition towards a green economy, Newbery (2016) argues
for the merits of a renewable support policy comprising of a Contract for Differences
(CfD) with a standard Feed-in-Tariff (FiT) as opposed to a Premium FiT proposed by
the 2015 EU Energy Union Package (European Commission and Directorate-General for
Economic and Financial Affairs, 2015). It has been more a decade since the first Renew-
able Energy Sources (RES) directive, and the debate on how best to design support for
renewable electricity is still raging. The European Commission only specifies that there
will be no national level targets beyond 2020, and that most Renewable Energy Sources
for Electricity (RES-E) support schemes should take the form of competitive bidding. It
still remains to be seen whether these choices will lead to the triad of competition, sus-
4 tainability, and affordability being achieved in the energy sector.
Since the first RES-E Directive was released in 2001, there have been numerous works
that have evaluated renewable support schemes from theoretical and empirical stand-
points; refer for instance Batlle et al. (2012a); Couture and Gagnon (2010); Schmalensee
(2012); Neuhoff et al. (2013); (IEA) (2008). Such literature so far on renewable support
schemes has mainly focussed on comparing different policies1 or support schemes 2
that have been implemented in various member states of the European Union (EU). The
key here, however, is not a choice between policy A or B, but between how either pol-
icy instrument should be designed. This allows the policy maker such as the European
Commission to decide what design features are essential in an RES-E scheme, rather
than propose an entire scheme itself. This idea has been upheld by several authors such
as del Rio and Linares (2014); del Rio and Mir-Artigues (2014); Haas et al. (2011).
It was proposed in earlier chapters that any RES-E policy can be broken down into a
closed set of components that are common to all renewable electricity support schemes.
These components are referred to as ‘design elements’; the design elements now form
the smallest level of analysis. The objective of this chapter is to assess the impact of de-
sign elements of Renewable Energy Source – Electricity (RES-E) support schemes on a
single (isolated, uncongested) region modelled approximately similar to the power sec-
tor in the Netherlands, using a long-term agent-based model of the electricity market,
with endogenous investment. We introduce the design elements in Section 2.2.2, and
demonstrate that it is possible to model elements individually in Chapter 3. The policies
are then modelled as combinations of design elements. The design elements analysed
are price warranty versus quantity warranty, electricity market revenue accounted for ex-
post or ex-ante, and technology specificity versus technology neutrality. The performance
indicators in this study are effectiveness of policy in terms of cost and target achieve-
ment, and social welfare and distributional implications on producer, consumer, and
the government.
The following subsection comprises of a review of literature in the field, and outlines
how this work contributes to literature. This is followed by Section 4.2, which includes
a detailed description of the methodology used: the design elements considered, the
1 Policy is a general term used to describe a formal decision or a plan of action adopted by an actor, such as the
government, to achieve a particular goal.
2 The word policy is used interchangeably with the word scheme in this work.
4.1. I NTRODUCTION 57
model, the hypotheses and experiment design. The subsequent section includes the
results and their discussion, followed by the conclusion.
scenario analysis to account for certain types of uncertainties. However, even these sce-
narios or probability distributions need to be estimated by the analyst.
Such methods imply that investment decisions are made under the premise of min-
imisation of system expenditure across time. As Most and Fichtner (2010) and Olsina
et al. (2006) point out however, such assumptions imply that capacity or production de-
cisions can be taken instantaneously, under conditions of free entry and exit. These as-
sumptions can hardly be expected to hold in the real-world, especially in sectors where
investment decisions, which happen with knowledge of past trends, and imperfect fore-
sight, are a major determinant of welfare outcomes.
Figure 4.1: High level diagram of behaviour of agents and their interaction with environment in EMLab.
Adapted from Richstein (2015)
those of the future, and agents make decisions under imperfect foresight. Agents create
their own forecasts using regression techniques of past values of demand and fuel price
trends, much like in the real-world, to arrive at endogenous investment patterns. Such
real world representations help analyse how different designs of RES-E support affect in-
vestment incentives, and consequently affect the energy transition. The base model, on
which this work has been built, is described in detail in section 3.2, and with flowchart in
3.3, and is represented in Figure 4.1. The design elements, and consequently the RES-E
policies, that have been modelled as part of the current work, are described in Section
3.4.
This approach is markedly different from the aforementioned modelling methods
because of the following reasons. Firstly, since each agent makes individual investment
decisions based only with current knowledge of the system, we implement bounded ra-
tionality; this often leads to sub-optimal choices when assessed ex-post, much like re-
ality. Secondly, in equilibrium models, typically the policies are modelled close to how
they work in theory. It is implicitly assumed that the policy in place would achieve its
target, as modelled. However, this method does not help identify reasons that a policy
would not work as intended; interpretation is left to the analyst. Including uncertainties
and bounded rationalities in the model, helps pinpoint which micro decisions lead to
which macro outcomes in the model. Thirdly, unlike optimization models, the focus of
our model is not a final minimum cost state, but to analyse dynamics in the path of an
energy transition, while including specific uncertainties.
Such modelling takes us a step closer to representing the real world. The base model
has so far been applied to study long term dynamics of the electricity market in rela-
tion to security of supply and carbon trading, in various publications (Richstein, 2015;
Richstein et al., 2014; Bhagwat et al., 2014).
60 4. R ENEWABLE SUPPORT INTERACTS WITH THE ELECTRICITY MARKET
Sensitivity Analysis The impact of the design element ex-ante vs ex-post inter-alia de-
pends on how well the expectations of producers’ electricity price match actual prices.
The development of electricity prices in a system dominated by CCGT technology is in
turn largely dependent on gas prices. In order to understand this relationship better, a
sensitivity analysis is executed for increasing and decreasing gas prices. The gas price
for the base scenario is set constant at the current3 approximate price of 4 Eur/GJ. The
Gas High scenario has an annual growth rate of 2% while the Gas Low scenario has one
of -2%.
conclusions. This is because two runs of the same scenario are differentiated by ran-
domness in the following parameters such as a) randomised agent iteration in order to
prevent first-mover artefacts, b) stochastic demand growth trends, randomness in ini-
tial age of power plants, as the age is drawn from a uniform distribution between 0 and
the technical lifetime of a power plant, and finally c) randomness in initial power plant
ownership. After performing a simple descriptive statistical test for the variance of re-
sults, it was deemed that 40 repetitions were sufficient to obtain statistically significant
outcomes.
be very different from those expected. The next major assumption is that the regulator
agent has full knowledge of costs of technologies, and uses the same rates of return as
the energy producers. While this assumption may not hold in reality, it helps to isolate
and study the impacts of design elements better.
4.3. R ESULTS
This section comprises of two subsections: the first consists of the results as per the
performance indicators mentioned in the introduction to this chapter. The performance
indicators are effectiveness of policy, and social welfare and distributional implications.
The second consists of a discussion and interpretation in subsection 4.3.2, primarily in
4 terms of impacts of design elements. Condensing large sets of granular results to a few
key indicators is a challenging activity, and must be done carefully.
E FFECTIVENESS OF P OLICY
Effectiveness of policy is measured using two indicators: cost effectiveness and target off-
set. Cost effectiveness is defined as total subsidy cost per MWh of renewable electricity
generated6 , summed across all 40 years, in Eur/MWh. It is then averaged across all 40
repetitions of the scenario. Target offset measures the difference between the actual re-
newable energy generation and the exogenously specified target. It is expressed as per-
centage, and then averaged across all years and 40 repetitions per scenario.
% % (r Gen t ,r ep −t ar g et t ,r ep )×100
r ep t t ar g et t ,r ep
t ar g etO f f set = (4.1)
n r ep × n t i ck
Figure 4.2 indicates these values for each scenario. The evolution of capacity in each
of the scenarios is shown in Figure 4.3.
Figure 4.2: Policy effectiveness measured in subsidy costs and target achievement
At the outset, it is to be noted that the target has been grossly under-achieved in
scenarios P_Ante and P_AnteTS. This is a consequence of the regulator agent’s short-
sightedness with respect to expectations of future electricity prices7 . It is for the same
reason that this is visible only in the ex-ante scenarios, as there is no need to com-
pute expected electricity price in the ex-post scenarios. The effect is exacerbated in the
technology-specific scenario, as a price warranty is calculated for each technology, while
in the technology-neutral scenario, a price warranty is only calculated for the marginal
technology. It is useful to note here that target achievement has little relation to the Av-
erage Subsidy Cost/Unit, as the latter is normalized with respect to generation in MWh.
The results indicate the following:
a) Quantity-warranty schemes are on average 4.5% more cost-effective and meet
their targets more consistently than their price-warranty counterparts. This is because
price-warranty schemes induce investment in technologies up to the point at which the
realistic potential of a technology is reached, and not the administrative target which
is lesser than the potential. Greater the amount of renewables in the portfolio, greater
the spillage 8 and lower the generation. Therefore, unless there is an interconnector
7 This is because when the regulator agent calculates the required price warranty, her expectation of revenue
from the electricity price is calculated by taking into account all the electricity plants that are expected at
that moment. However, after this calculation if investments do incur in the same year, due to which the
expected electricity price drops, the regulator does not make a reassessment of revenue expected from the
electricity market for the same year. Therefore, the regulator’s assessment of revenue from the electricity
market becomes higher than it actually is, and the corresponding price warranty becomes lower than it needs
to be, at the time of investment.
8 Spillage can be defined as renewable capacity generating more than the demand at a certain hour
64 4. R ENEWABLE SUPPORT INTERACTS WITH THE ELECTRICITY MARKET
Figure 4.3: Capacity growth in GW per policy scenario with time (in years) on x-axis
nario. The change is computed by comparing each scenario with a base case, where no
policy is implemented. Change in consumer expenditure9 , change in producer costs,
and change in government expenditure are used as proxies for calculating the changes
in consumer, producer, and government surpluses.
Figure 4.4: Change in Surplus for producer, consumer, government, and society (total) in 40 years
Overall, the results indicate that the greatest increase in social surplus occurs in the
scenario Q_AnteTS, where a technology-specific, quantity-warranty, ex-ante scheme is
implemented. The results will now be detailed per group. In all scenarios, consumer
surplus increases; this is primarily caused by a fall in the average electricity prices due
to the merit order effect. Government surplus is only affected by the amount of subsidy
spent. The main design element affecting government welfare is therefore technology
specificity. Surplus is more negative in technology neutral scenarios, compared to their
corresponding technology-specific counterparts due to the windfall profits mentioned
earlier.
9 The Consumer agent in the model only spends on electricity costs, the subsidy is assumed to be borne entirely
by the government for the sake of the model. In reality the cost burden is either borne by only the consumers
of electricity or all tax payers.
66 4. R ENEWABLE SUPPORT INTERACTS WITH THE ELECTRICITY MARKET
Producer surplus is affected by costs (fixed and variable) and revenues (electricity
spot market revenue and RES-E subsidies) for various technologies. Figure 4.5 shows the
break up of producer surplus per technology and per policy scenario, for all 40 years.
In technology-neutral scenarios, as one would expect, producer surplus is high for non-
marginal renewable technologies. Furthermore, for a certain capacity of RES-E capacity,
the ex-ante scenarios show lower surpluses than their ex-post counterparts. This is again
due to the overestimating of revenue from the electricity market by either the producer
or the regulator. CCGT however shows a negative producer surplus in all scenarios10 .
The cost-benefit impacts of each policy scenario on a single technology, such as for
instance Wind Offshore, is illustrated in figure 4.6.
10 This is because fixed O&M and variable costs of CCGT are consistently higher than revenues from the elec-
tricity market. This is exacerbated by the fact that decommissioning of power plants is age based (40 years)
in the model, and not economic. In addition, reducing average electricity prices due to the merit order effect
also reduce their revenue.
4.3. R ESULTS 67
Figure 4.6: Cost, Revenue, Subsidy, and Profit for WindOffshore per MWh over 40 years
one11 . Another factor which could impact this result is if technology cost reductions are
different than assumed.
Ex-ante vs ex-post Two effects could contribute to the impact of this design element:
the first is that there is a component of higher risk to the producer in the ex-ante scenar-
ios, therefore increasing their cost of capital, and consequently their subsidy costs. The
second effect is that higher (lower) expectations of future electricity price than reality
lead to lower (higher) subsidy costs in ex-ante (ex-post) scenarios. The results indicate
that the second effect overtakes the first. The isolated impact of the second effect can
be seen in Figure B.2a. In this scenario set, the same risk aversion of 11% is assumed in
both ex-ante and ex-post scenarios (r E p is reduced to zero in ex ante scenarios), under
constant gas prices. The ex-ante scenarios show an average of 4% decrease in subsidy
4 costs in same risk set compared to the base case set. This effectively quantifies the im-
pact of extra risk in ex-ante scenarios in the base case set. Ex-post scenarios in the same
risk scenario set are however 18% more expensive than ex-ante scenarios to the govern-
ment due to the merit order effect. A comparison between base case scenario set and
the same-risk scenario set is shown in Table B.2.
This design element is highly sensitive to expectations of future electricity prices,
which in turn depend greatly upon the merit-order effect of RES-E, and long term gas
price development. Even so, the absolute impact of this design element on policy cost
effectiveness or social welfare is at most half as significant as technology-specificity vs
neutrality. Therefore, while highly uncertain, it does not impact the socio-technical sys-
tem as much as technology-neutrality does.
ing increasing concern (Glachant and Ruester, 2013). Among the primary concerns of
the European Commission now, is to be able to promote renewable electricity without
causing unintended cross border impacts (Commission, 2015). A part of their strategy
to address this seems to be to promote competitive bidding in member states. However,
it is possible that even competitive bidding, when designed differently in neighbour-
ing states (for instance in terms of technology-specificity), could result in unintended
cross border effects. The design element method has the potential to provide insight
into which aspects of the policies need to be harmonised (or not); and if yes, to what
degree. This method allows the analyst to examine, element-by-element, which of them
lead to cross-border interactions between two neighbouring countries in the same elec-
tricity market.
4.4. C ONCLUSIONS 4
Most ongoing policy discussions relating to RES-E support schemes, both within and
outside of academia, compare existing policies. However, two seemingly different poli-
cies can be designed in a way that they have an equivalent effect on the market: for
instance, a tradable-green-certificate market with a long term contract is similar to a
tender. Conversely, two similar policies could have very different impacts on the sys-
tem, if designed slightly differently; for instance competitive bidding organized specific
to a technology would yield very different results from one that is technology neutral.
Therefore the core idea is that, it is the design features that form the vital component
of analysis, and not the policies in their entirety. We employ core design elements and
combine them to systematically arrive at a set of possible RES-E policy scenarios, consid-
ered complete with respect to the design elements, thus exploring the complete policy
design space. The design elements modelled are quantity warranty vs. price warranty,
technology specificty vs. neutrality, and ex-ante vs. ex-post price setting. We employ this
design element view in combination with agent based modelling to quantitatively assess
impacts of individual design elements on the socio-technical system.
The results demonstrate that design elements, irrespective of the RES-E policy they
belong to, do have significant impacts on the energy system and on welfare distribution,
and therefore that the approach is a useful one. The agent-based modelling framework
enables modelling of bounded rationalities in investment decisions, allowing the mod-
eller to incorporate real-world uncertainties in agents’ behaviour. An important uncer-
tainty in the real world is that of long-term electricity price development. The model in-
terestingly demonstrates that accounting for future electricity prices ex-ante in the sub-
sidy calculation may reduce the overall cost of subsidy by about 15%, since the actors are
likely to overestimate the future electricity price. This is a consequence of underestimat-
ing the impact of the merit order effect on expected electricity prices over the long-term.
Other significant results are that technology specificity could reduce the cost of subsidy
by upto 60%. Results regarding the design element, quantity vs price warranty corrob-
orate established literature: quantity warranty helps achieve targets better. The design
element configuration that leads to the highest increase in social welfare is the combi-
nation of quantity-warranty, ex-ante accounting for electricity prices, and technology-
specificity.
With regard to policy implications, the State Aid Guidelines of the European Com-
70 4. R ENEWABLE SUPPORT INTERACTS WITH THE ELECTRICITY MARKET
4
R EFERENCES 71
R EFERENCES
K. K. Iychettira, R. A. Hakvoort, P. Linares, and R. d. Jeu, Towards a comprehensive policy
for electricity from renewable energy: Designing for social welfare, Applied Energy 187,
228 (2017).
European Commission and Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs, En-
ergy economic developments: investment perspectives in electricity markets. (Publica-
tions Office, Luxembourg, 2015) oCLC: 948760359.
I. E. A. (IEA), Deploying Renewables: principles for effective policies, Tech. Rep. (Paris,
2008).
P. del Rio and P. Linares, Back to the future? Rethinking auctions for renewable electricity
support, Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 35, 42 (2014).
P. del Rio and P. Mir-Artigues, Combinations of support instruments for renewable elec-
tricity in Europe: A review, Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 40, 287 (2014).
B. Fais, M. Blesl, U. Fahl, and A. Voß, Comparing different support schemes for renewable
electricity in the scope of an energy systems analysis, Applied Energy 131, 479 (2014).
L. Dressler, Support Schemes for Renewable Electricity in the European Union: Producer
Strategies and Competition, Energy Economics , (2016).
C. Huber, T. Faber, R. Haas, G. Resch, J. Green, S. Olz, and S. White, Deriving optimal pro-
motion strategied for increasing hte share of RES-E in a dynamic European electricity
market, Tech. Rep. (2004).
D. Most and W. Fichtner, Renewable energy sources in European energy supply and in-
teractions with emission trading, The Role of Trust in Managing Uncertainties in the
Transition to a Sustainable Energy Economy, Special Section with Regular Papers 38,
2898 (2010).
M. Ventosa, Baıllo, A. Ramos, and M. Rivier, Electricity market modeling trends, Energy
Policy 33, 897 (2005).
F. Olsina, F. Garcés, and H.-J. Haubrich, Modeling long-term dynamics of electricity mar-
kets, Energy Policy 34, 1411 (2006).
J. Richstein, Interactions between carbon and power markets in transition (Delft Univer-
sity of Technology, Netherlands, 2015).
R EFERENCES 73
P. Lako, Technical and economic features of renewable electricity technologies, Tech. Rep. 4
ECN-E–10-034 (ECN, 2010).
M. Ragwitz, G. Resch, C. Huber, and S. White, Dynamic Cost Resource Curves, Tech.
Rep. ENG2-CT-2002-00607 (Energy Economics Group, Vienna University of Technol-
ogy, 2003).
R. Anderson and L. Taylor, The social cost of unsupplied electricity: A critical review, En-
ergy Economics 8, 139 (1986).
P. Linares and L. Rey, The costs of electricity interruptions in Spain. Are we sending the
right signals? Energy Policy 39 (2013).
M. d. Nooij, C. Koopmans, and C. Bijvoet, The value of supply security: The costs of power
interruptions: Economic input for damage reduction and investment in networks, En-
ergy Economics 29, 277 (2007).
E. Commission, Guidelines on State aid for environmental protection and energy 2014-
2020 (2014).
J.-M. Glachant and S. Ruester, The EU internal electricity market : done forever?, Working
Paper (2013).
E. Commission, Launching the public consultation process on a new energy market de-
sign, Tech. Rep. COM(2015) 340 final (Brussels, 2015).
5
C ONGRUENCY BETWEEN NATIONAL
SUPPORT SCHEMES AND AN
INTERNATIONAL ELECTRICITY
MARKET
75
5. C ONGRUENCY BETWEEN NATIONAL SUPPORT SCHEMES AND AN INTERNATIONAL
76 ELECTRICITY MARKET
5.1. I NTRODUCTION
The European Union’s Renewable Energy Source (RES) Directive (2009/28/EC) intro-
duced legally binding national targets to meet 20% of final energy consumption from
renewable sources (Commission, 2009). The implementation of the directive seems to
be largely on track to realizing the targets, and electricity from renewable sources flour-
ished in many countries. However, the lack of harmonisation between individual Mem-
ber States to achieve targets led to concerns about fragmentation of the electricity mar-
ket (Glachant and Ruester, 2013). There were also concerns about cost-effectiveness of a
nationally determined strategy from a pan-European perspective (Commission, 2016).
The latest package of measures released by the European Commission proposes a
single Europe-wide target of 27% renewables by 2030, without translating them into
national-level targets. In addition, it proposes that support of renewables is opened
to other Member States to ensure cross-border tradability and address fragmentation
of the internal market. In this regard, it makes bold strides by specifying that support
for at least 10% of the newly supported capacity in each year between 2021 and 2025,
and 15% between 2026 and 2030, should be open to installations in other member states
5 (Commission, 2016). This is a major departure from its earlier strategy, which paid much
importance to nationally-determined policies.
Significant amounts of intermittent RES-E in the energy mix have led to unintended
impacts. One of the most significant consequences is the so-called merit-order effect,
where the spot market electricity price reduces to the extent by which the renewable
electricity generation displaces demand along the merit order curve (Sensfuss et al.,
2008). It has been empirically demonstrated by a number of studies (Cludius et al., 2014;
Ederer, 2015; Gelabert et al., 2011; O’Mahoney and Denny, 2013; Traber and Kemfert,
2009, 2011; Weigt, 2009). It is also possible that the presence of a huge share of renewable
electricity will lead to substantial changes in import and export, leading to the spreading
of the merit order effect across national borders (Sensfuss et al., 2008). The problem ad-
dressed in this research is to understand such cross-border impacts between the Nether-
lands and Germany. We also seek to understand the role that design elements of RES-E
support could play in such cross-border effects.
Relatedly, the future of nuclear and coal-fired power plants appears bleak in the
Netherlands and Germany. In 2011 it was mandated that nuclear power was to be phased
out by 2022 in Germany. The German Climate Action Plan 2050 mentions that ”the fed-
eral German government in its development cooperation does not lend support to new
coal power plants”, and includes a commission for ”Growth, Structural Change, and Re-
gional Development” (Federal Ministry for the Environment, 2016). Similarly, the Dutch
parliament voted for a 55% cut in CO 2 emissions by 2030, which would require the clo-
sure of all of the country’s coal-fired power plants (Neslen, 2016). In Germany and the
Netherlands, such a trend limits the options of flexibility primarily to gas-fired power
generation. Biomass and hydro-power are other options, but less prevalent in these two
countries
The objective of this work is to analyse the long-term, cross-border welfare impacts
of different renewable support schemes in Germany and the Netherlands, while taking
into account the proposed phase-out of nuclear and coal power. The performance in-
dicators for the assessment are average wholesale electricity price trends, the costs of
5.1. I NTRODUCTION 77
subsidies, and the income transfer between the producers and consumers under various
schemes, and different interconnection capacities. As outlined in the previous chapters,
the RES-E schemes are identified by their constituent design elements: price or quantity
warranty, technology specificity or neutrality and ex-post vs. ex-ante price setting.
5.2.2. D ATA
This section complements the data presented in Chapter 3. The data below is exclusive
to the experiments performed for this chapter.
Fuel costs For the purpose of the experiments here, the fuel costs are assumed to
remain constant at an average of the 2015 levels, through the length of the simulation.
The data sources and assumptions are listed in Table 5.1.
Technology targets and potentials At the official European level, targets for renew-
able electricity have not been set for individual member states beyond 2020. However
5
Figure 5.1: Experiment design for analysis of cross border effects
Table 5.1: Assumptions for fuel costs, and corresponding data sources
the European Union has set itself "a long-term goal of reducing greenhouse gas emis-
sions by 80-95%, when compared to 1990 levels, by 2050" (Commission, 2017). In view
of this, the targets have been set at a linearly increasing rate from 2015 levels in both
countries to 70% at 2050. The targets are shown pictorially in Figure A.4 and A.5 in the
appendix. The data points for ’realistic potentials’ at different years have been used to
linearly extrapolate trends for the whole time scope of the model. The data points and
their sources are mentioned in Table A.2.
Phasing out technologies As mentioned in the introduction, Germany announced
plans to phase out their nuclear power plants in 2022. Similarly, in 2015, Germany’s eco-
nomic ministry and energy companies agreed to take lignite fired power plants offline
(Environment, 2015). In the Netherlands too, a closure of all of the country’s coal-fired
power plants is expected to take place before 2030 (Neslen, 2016). The intial portfolio in
the simulation resembles the generation portfolios of the Netherlands and Germany in
2015 closely. The planned phasing out of coal and lignite is implemented in the model,
even if exact years for the decommissioning have not been proposed for all technologies.
Nuclear power plants in Germany are phased out in 2 stages of 5.GW each in 2018, and
5 2022. Lignite power plants are phased out in three stages: 8.18GW in 2020, 7.52GW in
2025, and 3.97GW in 2030. In the Netherlands, 1.1 GW of Lignite is assumed to be shut
down in 2020 (Maasvlakte 1 and 2 ), another 1.02 GW is assumed to be shut down in
2026, representing the closure of Centraale Maasvlakte 3. Furthermore, the model as-
sumes that there will be no additional investment in either Coal PSC, Lignite, or Nuclear
technologies in either country.
5.3. R ESULTS
5.3.1. I MPACTS OF INTERCONNECTION ON ELECTRICITY PRICES
The primary ‘medium’ so to say, by which electricity spot markets and renewable support
schemes interact is through the electricity spot market price. The fundamental mecha-
nism behind the interaction is as follows: the production of cheap variable renewable
electricity (VRE) causes a reduction in the average electricity prices. This has been doc-
umented and analysed by several studies (Sensfuss et al., 2008; Hirth, 2013). Depending
on the amount of interconnection with the neighbouring market, the relative size (ca-
pacity in MW) of the neighbouring price zone, and the design of the support scheme, the
reduction in electricity prices spread. That is to say, the average electricity price in the
neighbouring country also changes. And since subsidies are a difference between cost
of the technology and revenue from the electricity market, they are directly linked to the
electricity price, due to which, costs of renewable support schemes are also affected.
The spreading of the merit order effect between Germany and the Netherlands is
indicated in Figure 5.2. The figure shows the progression of average (annual) electric-
ity price in Germany and the Netherlands across time for each of the eight RES-E sup-
port schemes, at different interconnection capacities. At the outset, as one may ex-
pect, the electricity prices in both price zones converge as the interconnection capac-
ity increases, irrespective of support scheme design. At an interconnection capacity of
10GW, the prices have almost entirely converged under all scenarios of renewable sup-
port schemes.
5.3. R ESULTS 81
40
RES−E Policy
P_Ante
P_AnteTS
30 P_Post
P_PostTS
Q_Ante
Q_AnteTS
20 Q_Post
Q_PostTS
0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40
Time [in years]
Figure 5.2: Average electricity price plot across different interconnection capacities, for each RES-E policy sce-
nario, in both the Netherlands and Germany
5
Since European guidelines indicate that support schemes have to be ‘market-based’,
subsidies are designed to cover only the part of renewable electricity costs that is not
covered by the electricity market. Therefore, as the revenue from the electricity mar-
ket decreases due to the spreading of the merit order effect, the cost of subsidies in the
neighbouring country increases. This is explained in detail in the following section.
30
Germany
20
Subsidy Costs [Eur/MWh]
10
40
30
Netherlands
20
10
5
0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40
Time [in years]
Figure 5.3: Subsidy costs per MWh electricity generated in the Netherlands and Germany across time
however beyond year 30, subsidy costs decrease as interconnection capacity increases.
This is explained by the fact that beyond year 30, at low interconnection levels there is
substantial spillage in the system, i.e., the intermittent electricity production surpasses
demand frequently. This leads to an increase in costs per unit of production, thereby
increasing the subsidy costs. This is also corroborated by Figure B.5, and Figure B.6 in
the appendix, which show the spillage of RES-E production with time, per technology.
In the first phase of the simulation before year 30, where spillage does not play too great
a role, the following results are observed. In ‘Interconnection 10000’ scenarios, the sub-
sidy costs in the Netherlands are higher by a range of 10 - 2 Eur/MWh as compared to the
‘Interconnection 3950 MW’ scenarios (current levels), and by 18 - 2 Eur/MWh as com-
pared to the ‘Interconnection 0 MW’ scenarios. Since spillage substantially affects the
costs of subsidies beyond year 30, it is useful to see results separately until year 30, as in
Table 5.2, and for the full simulation as in Table 5.3.
The results demonstrate that greater interconnection capacities with Germany lead
to higher subsidy costs in the Netherlands, due to lowering of electricity prices, as long
as shares of RES-E production in the Netherlands remain lower than approximately 60%,
which is approximately the share of renewable electricity at year 30. As shares increase,
the level of interconnection plays a progressively higher role in the subsidy costs, due to
spillage.
The questions that follow are what factors these figures are sensitive to and why. The
amount of spillage is sensitive to the technology, the interconnection capacity, and the
5.3. R ESULTS 83
Table 5.2: Costs of electricity and subsidy, summed for the first 30 years [ticks], averaged across different RES-E
policy scenarios, in bn euros.
Table 5.3: Costs of electricity and subsidy, summed for the full simulation period [40 years], averaged across
different RES-E policy scenarios, in bn euros.
5
Country Interconnection Cost of Cost of Cost of Cost of
Capacity [in electricity electric- Subsidy Subsidy,
MW] in DE [in ity, SD, in in NL [in SD, in NL
bn Eur] DE [in bn bn Eur] [in bn
Eur] Eur]
Netherlands 0 209.46 5.11 99.12 2.75
Netherlands 3950 205.39 5.06 92.32 2.36
Netherlands 10000 168.50 5.14 101.16 3.77
Germany 0 730.38 15.99 508.29 51.90
Germany 3950 732.43 7.17 494.42 51.35
Germany 10000 741.72 6.62 488.87 49.52
Aside from impacts of support scheme design, other factors that impact subsidy
costs in Germany are i. the amount of interconnection and ii. the amount of spillage.
When capacity of interconnection increases the electricity price in the exporting zone
increases. An increase in the revenue from electricity prices implies a reduction in the
costs of the subsidy. On average, across all RES-E policy scenarios, as interconnection in-
creases, subsidy costs in Germany decrease, as is shown in both Tables 5.2 and 5.3. The
standard deviation of the costs of subsidy are quite high for Germany, primarily because
the technology neutral support schemes require much more subsidy than the technol-
ogy specific ones3 . This is evident in Figure B.4 which shows the sum of subsidy and
electricity costs through the full simulation for both countries.
Netherlands
500
Germany
1000
500
0
te S st tTS te S st tTS
An teT Po s An teT Po s
P_ An P_ Po Q_ An Q_ Po
P_ P_ Q_ Q_
Policy Scenario
scheme active in each scenario. As explained in the above sections, factors such as tech-
nology neutrality of support scheme, spillage, have an impact on the costs of subsidy
and electricity; the costs are reflected in Figure 5.4.
Germany Netherlands
0.15
0.10
CCGT
0.05
0.00
−0.05
−0.10
0.15
0.10
CoalPSC
0.05
0.00
−0.05
−0.10
0.15
0.10
Lignite
0.05
Producer Profit in Billion Eur
0.00
5 −0.05
−0.10
0.15
0.10
Nuclear
0.05
0.00
−0.05
−0.10
0.15
Photovoltaic
0.10
0.05
0.00
−0.05
−0.10
0.15
0.10
0.05
Wind
0.00
−0.05
−0.10
0.15 WindOffshore
0.10
0.05
0.00
−0.05
−0.10
IntLow IntMedium IntHigh IntLow IntMedium IntHigh
Interconnection Level
Figure 5.5: Total profit to producer per policy scenario and per technology across 40 years
5.4. D ISCUSSION 87
forseen4 decommissioning by the German government, also exacerbate their low overall
profits at low interconnection capacities.
As for renewable technologies, the subsidies are designed to just cover costs, and the
regulator is assumed to have the same cost information as the energy producer. This is
reflected in near-zero profits for Solar PV. Since it is the marginal renewable technology
due to its higher costs, the technology neutral and technology specific RES-E policies
both result in near-zero profits. Wind power plants (on-shore) earn-infra marginal prof-
its under technology neutral policy scenarios.
5.4. D ISCUSSION
5.4.1. M ERITS AND LIMITATIONS OF THE MODEL
The popular aphorism, "All models are wrong, but some are useful" seems especially
pertinent when models seek to simulate the next several decades. The uncertainties
in modelling such a timescale are innumerable. While a few of them have been taken
into account, such as bounded rationality of agents regarding future electricity prices,
and uncertainty in demand growth, assumptions have been made regarding many other
parameters. For instance, if costs of variable renewable electricity technologies were to 5
drop at a faster rate than assumed in this study, the costs of subsidy would be even lower,
strengthening the idea that decrease in electricity costs will be greater than the increase
in subsidy costs to the consumer in the neighbouring country. Costs of gas, coal, and
uranium are impacted by global trends and difficult to predict in the long-term. In this
work they have been assumed to be constant at 2015 levels. While this assumption helps
the analyst focus solely on the variables of interest, such as levels of interconnection and
renewable support scheme designs, in reality fuel costs might have an impact on the
results.
Despite its many limitations the model provides several insights on cross-border ef-
fects caused due to national support schemes alongside an international electricity mar-
ket. Results show that given a certain interconnection capacity, the designs of renewable
support schemes and their targets do lead to unintended effects on subsidy costs in a
neighbouring country. However, these effects are primarily caused by virtue of the in-
stalled capacity of intermittent renewable electricity that a support scheme design in-
centivizes, as against the design elements themselves.
The results also indicate that at high shares of RES-E production, interconnections
play an important but ultimately limited role in lending flexibility to the system, and
consequently in ensuring that each unit of intermittent electricity is consumed in an
efficient manner. They indicate that the presence of flexibility has strong implications
on the targets of intermittent renewable generation the European Union or individual
countries can set for themselves, without having to suffer costs of spillage in the form of
increased subsidies. The targets to be set each country must take into account, ceteris
paribus, firstly its interconnection capacities with neighbouring countries. At a later
point in time when spillage of intermittent renewable generation becomes inevitable
in the absence of storage, countries must also take into account the amount of storage
available to them while setting their targets. An ex-ante price setting scheme ameliorates
4 at the time of investment
5. C ONGRUENCY BETWEEN NATIONAL SUPPORT SCHEMES AND AN INTERNATIONAL
88 ELECTRICITY MARKET
Figure 5.6: EPEX-SPOT Data showing day ahead electricity prices and volume for 2015, for base load (grey) and
5 peak load (orange) in the DE/AT price zone. It also shows the 200 day average prices. (SPOT, 2015)
the impact of the merit order effect on subsidy costs, at the risk of renewable energy pro-
ducers incorporating their price risks into the cost of capital.
the ENTSO-E, which indicated that during 2015, the export to the Netherlands from Ger-
many accounted for an average of 29% [ranging between 16% and 45%] of its total ex-
ports (ENTSO-E, 2015).
5.5. C ONCLUSIONS
The primary objective of this chapter was to investigate cross-border effects due to na-
tional RES-E support schemes, operating in an international electricity market. In order
5. C ONGRUENCY BETWEEN NATIONAL SUPPORT SCHEMES AND AN INTERNATIONAL
90 ELECTRICITY MARKET
to carry out this research, EMLab Generation, a model comprising of both an electric-
ity market clearing module, and an endogenous investment algorithm was used. Price
zones based on Germany and the Netherlands were simulated, to test the effects of dif-
ferent support scheme designs in each country, and the common electricity market, on
distributional implications under differnent scenarios of interconnector capacities, over
a long term period of 40 years, starting from 2015.
As economic theory would predict it is found that subsidy costs increase in the smaller
country, due to spreading of the merit order effect from the larger neighbouring country.
Increasing the interconnection capacity between Germany and the Netherlands from
the current 3950 MW to 10000MW would lead to an increase of Eur 8.58 billion5 in Dutch
subsidy costs, under assumed cost structures until 2045. However, the increase in sub-
sidy costs remains lower than the reduction in costs of electricity (Eur 32.12 billion),
corroborrating earlier, single country analyses on the topic. Therefore, total cost in the
neighbouring country reduces as interconnection increases, as the invisible hand works
its magic. Another important insight is that as share of RES-E increases, interconnection
has limited impact on reducing spillage of RES-E while storage becomes increasingly im-
portant. The results show that targets for RES-E, depend not only on the targets of the
5 neighbouring countries, but also the capacity of storage that exists in the system.
Several policy recommendations follow from the results and analyses. The results
show that it is necessary that policy makers and researchers ponder over questions about
how subsidy costs should be allocated between countries over the long term when they
are so intricately connected with the electricity markets they operate in. This should
be part of the European Commission’s research agenda. Futher, it is evident that while
setting RES-E targets either for individual member states, or for several together, the ca-
pacity of flexible sources available to them should be explicitly taken into account. The
targets that can be set in a cost efficient manner are limited by the amount of intercon-
nection and storage available to that system.
This research also opens up several avenues for future work. The results indicate
that shares of RES-E greater than 60%, is not a cost efficient proposition without stor-
age. However this figure is accompanied by disclaimers of limited temporal resolution
in the model. In order to deduce a precise estimate of the point at which storage be-
comes essential, models with greater temporal resolution are necessary. Since costs of
RES-E technologies have been dramatically dropping over the last few years, a large sen-
sitivity analysis could help answer the question, "At what costs do subsidies become
redundant". Another interesting question is to evaluate cross border effects under other
institutional arrangements such as bilateral contracts, capacity markets, and perhaps
the EU-ETS.
R EFERENCES
E. Commission, Directive 2009/28/EC, Official Journal of the European Union 52 (2009),
10.3000.
J.-M. Glachant and S. Ruester, The EU internal electricity market : done forever?, Working
Paper (2013).
J. Cludius, H. Hermann, F. C. Matthes, and V. Graichen, The merit order effect of wind
and photovoltaic electricity generation in Germany 2008–2016: Estimation and distri-
butional implications, Energy Economics 44, 302 (2014). 5
N. Ederer, The market value and impact of offshore wind on the electricity spot market:
Evidence from Germany, Applied Energy 154, 805 (2015).
A. O’Mahoney and E. Denny, Electricity prices and generator behaviour in gross pool elec-
tricity markets, Energy Policy 63, 628 (2013).
T. Traber and C. Kemfert, Impacts of the German Support for Renewable Energy on Elec-
tricity Prices, Emissions, and Firms, The Energy Journal 30, 155 (2009).
T. Traber and C. Kemfert, Gone with the wind? — Electricity market prices and incen-
tives to invest in thermal power plants under increasing wind energy supply, Energy
Economics 33, 249 (2011).
H. Weigt, Germany’s wind energy: The potential for fossil capacity replacement and cost
saving, Applied Energy 86, 1857 (2009).
A. Neslen, Dutch parliament votes to close down country’s coal industry, (2016).
D. Finon and Y. Perez, The social efficiency of instruments of promotion of renewable en-
ergies: A transaction-cost perspective, Ecological Economics 62, 77 (2007).
S. Jacobsson and V. Lauber, The politics and policy of energy system transforma-
tion—explaining the German diffusion of renewable energy technology, Energy Policy
34, 256 (2006).
92 R EFERENCES
N. Johnstone, I. Haščič, and D. Popp, Renewable Energy Policies and Technological Inno-
vation: Evidence Based on Patent Counts, Environmental and Resource Economics 45,
133 (2010).
P. del Rıo, A European-wide harmonised tradable green certificate scheme for renewable
electricity: is it really so beneficial? Energy Policy 33, 1239 (2005).
5
C. Huber, T. Faber, R. Haas, G. Resch, J. Green, S. Olz, and S. White, Deriving optimal
promotion strategies for increasing the share of RES-E in a dynamic European electricity
market, Tech. Rep. (2004).
U. E. I. Administration, Annual Coal Report 2015, Tech. Rep. (US Department of Energy,
2016).
L. Hirth, The market value of variable renewables: The effect of solar wind power variabil-
ity on their relative price, Energy Economics 38, 218 (2013).
E. Commission, Launching the public consultation process on a new energy market de-
sign, Tech. Rep. COM(2015) 340 final (Brussels, 2015).
5
6
RES-E POLICY DESIGN IN
PERSPECTIVE OF THE ENERGY
TRANSITION
95
96 6. RES-E POLICY DESIGN IN PERSPECTIVE OF THE ENERGY TRANSITION
6.1. I NTRODUCTION
In auctions for wind offshore projects organised in Germany in April 2017, three of the
four winning projects bid at zero subsidy. In such auctions, we see mounting evidence of
dramatic reductions in technology costs, caused in part (for wind offshore) by advance-
ments in turbine technologies, standardization and optimisation of designs. At the same
time, governments have become increasingly optimistic that zero subsidy becomes the
norm; for instance, the Dutch government announced plans to organise subsidy-free
auctions in 2026, and the UK is not too far behind (Wind, 2017). Despite this optimism
from the wind offshore industry and governments, the question we ask is whether such
optimism is justified - not just in 2026, but also in the longer-term perspective of three
to four decades in the future, given the current institutional settings that we operate in.
In Europe, the energy transition comprises a multitude of policies and strategies
as multiple objectives simultaneously compete for attention: the EU ETS, demand re-
sponse measures, capacity mechanisms etc are a few. The recent package of measures
released by the European Commission, ‘Clean Energy for All Europeans’, further pro-
motes the objective of decarbonisation by proposing strict measures to ensure that at
least 27% of all energy consumed comes from renewable sources by 2030, while steadily
moving towards reducing emissions by 80-95% in Europe by 2050.Dramatically decreas-
ing costs of solar and wind generation technologies have aided the transition further, not
just in Europe, but the world over: costs of solar PV are half as much as they were in 2010,
6 and are expected to fall by a further 60% over the next decade (IRENA, 2016).
As has been a recurring theme in the preceding chapters, there have been unin-
tended effects caused by the huge influx of intermittent renewable electricity into the
electricity market. The first of these unintended effects is the "merit-order" effect, due
to which renewable electricity generation has a strong price reduction effect on whole-
sale electricity spot prices (Sensfuss et al., 2008). A second effect, which directly relates
the presence of variable renewable electricity (VRE) to its economic value, is the idea of
the "market value of VRE", as defined and quantified by Hirth (2013). Due to the simple
fact that VRE1 is inherently variable with time and has limited predictability, its eco-
nomic value in the spot market is heavily influenced by its own existence. As the share of
VRE increases, its economic value reduces. Due to this reason, it is questionable whether
support for renewables can be phased out as their share increases.
Three elementary aspects of the energy transition are especially important: the elec-
tricity spot market, the EU ETS, and finally, flexible resources. The electricity spot mar-
ket represents a set of institutions which form the essence of a well-functioning, liber-
alized market for electricity. They signal the value of electricity as a commodity, and
in principle, incentivize investment in the most cost-efficient generation sources. The
relationship of the cost of subsidies to VRE with the price of electricity is therefore, fun-
damental to the assessment of the economic viability of VRE. The EU-ETS is a pillar of
the European Union’s energy strategy. It was envisioned as a tool to price carbon-dioxide
emissions, and therefore incentivize low-carbon sources of electricity generation in the
power sector as well. It is, therefore, imperative to assess how this ETS mechanism will
impact the costs of subsidies as the share of RES-E in the system increases. Finally, tem-
1 For the purposes of this chapter, VRE and RES-E are used interchangeably
6.2. S UBSIDY COSTS AND ELECTRICITY PRICES 97
porally flexible resources such as storage, and locational-based flexible resources such as
interconnection are resources essential for controlling the variability, and consequently
the market value of VRE. The need for flexibility, and its impact on the possible cost of
subsidy is discussed.
The aim of this chapter is therefore to touch upon these three aspects of the energy
transition. In light of the intricate relationship between the subsidy designs and the in-
ternal electricity market, the first section comprises a discussion on the components that
drive RES-E subsidies. The second section of this chapter is a deliberation on the role the
EU-ETS could play in the interaction between subsidy costs and electricity price. The
third section reviews scientific literature regarding the role of flexible resources, such as
interconnection and storage, on the market value VRE, and juxtaposes it with results ob-
tained from the preceding chapters. Finally, the chapter culminates with a comparison
between factors which could influence subsidy costs over the short term versus the long
term.
C OSTS
The cost comprises three quantities: the technology costs, the operation and mainte-
nance costs, and the cost of capital. Technology costs have seen a rapid decline over the
last few years for solar, wind, and wind-offshore technologies.
In the case of solar, global utility-scale PV system costs have reduced by 62% between
2009 and 2015 (IRENA, 2016). The potential for further cost reduction is expected to be
large: the global average of installed-costs could reduce by 57% in 10 years from 2015 to
2025 (ire, 2016). The utility scale cost trends for solar are presented in Figure A.6.
Multiple sources report a similar cost decline in the wind industry: in the order of
60% between 2009 and 2016. For instance, Bloomberg New Energy Finance finds that in
Europe, the costs of building an offshore wind farm has fallen by 22% solely over 2016-17
(Finance, 2017a). They expect levelized costs of offshore wind to fall by a further 71% by
2040 (Finance, 2017b). A report from the Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory finds
that wind turbine prices in the USA have fallen between 20% and 40% from 2008 until
2016 (Wiser et al., 2016).
98 6. RES-E POLICY DESIGN IN PERSPECTIVE OF THE ENERGY TRANSITION
Figure 6.1: Comparison of electricity traded volumes in day-ahead, forward, OTC markets in the third quarter
of 2016. Source for Energy (2016)
R EVENUES
In western Europe, substantial shares of electricity are either traded on organised trad-
ing platforms such as the spot market or bilaterally on the so-called over-the-counter
(OTC) markets. In different countries the shares traded in each market might be differ-
6 ent. For an indication, see Figure 6.1. The day-ahead markets such as the EPEX-Spot
in the central western Europe region are transparent with data, and therefore provide a
useful source for analysing revenues from the electricity market. In this section, we seek
to understand what the current drivers of spot market electricity prices are.
In the body of literature on electricity price drivers, most existing studies are em-
pirical, and focus exclusively on the merit order effect of renewables; for instance Sens-
fuss et al. (2008); Cludius et al. (2014); Ederer (2015); Gelabert et al. (2011); O’Mahoney
and Denny (2013); Traber and Kemfert (2009, 2011); Weigt (2009); Würzburg et al. (2013).
Bublitz et al. (2017) provide a concise and insightful literature review of such studies. In
addition, unlike the aforementioned studies, they determine and compare price drivers
with the objective of ascertaining whether the merit order effect is indeed the biggest
cause of the price drop in the German electricity market (Bublitz et al., 2017). They
use two methods: a linear regression model and an agent-based model to test price
effects from different factors on the spot market price. Contrary to popular opinion,
they find that between 2011 and 2015 the impact of carbon and coal prices was twice as
high as the impact of renewable expansion. Other studies look at effects of other factors
such as the influence of neighbouring countries (Dehler et al., 2016), coal and gas prices
(O’Mahoney and Denny, 2013; Dehler et al., 2016), the nuclear moratorium (Thoenes,
2014), and of demand and fuel prices (Hirth, 2016a).
All the above studies are ex-post analyses and use empirical data. They have little
to say about future price trends or determinants of electricity prices in the presence of
high shares of renewable electricity generation. To gain insight into the drivers of elec-
tricity prices decades into the future, long-term energy models are commonly employed.
Given the uncertainties involved in such modelling, it is worth remembering Hamming’s
argument on computation: the purpose of computation is insight, not numbers (Ham-
6.2. S UBSIDY COSTS AND ELECTRICITY PRICES 99
ming, 1962). As a strategy to gain insight under uncertainty, scenario analysis has gained
immense importance since Rand Corporation first used it in the 1940s. For this disser-
tation, scenarios with at least 70% renewable electricity generation by 2055 are consid-
ered. There are few studies modelling such scenarios specifically for Germany and the
Netherlands which account for factors such as uncertainties in carbon prices, coal and
gas prices, demand growth, etc. on the electricity prices.
Simulations conducted for this dissertation provide some useful insights. In the fol-
lowing section, we look at results from the model to understand what could be major
electricity price drivers in the long-term period of 20-30 years, as the share of intermit-
tent renewable energy increases in the energy mix.
O BSERVATIONS
Trends in electricity prices (averaged per year) and subsidy costs per year, both expressed
in Eur/MWh, across the length of the simulation period - 0 to 40 years - are shown in Fig-
ure 6.3. The electricity price trends are, as expected, primarily impacted by gas prices.
However, interestingly, they are not impacted as much by the amount of renewable elec-
tricity generation in the mix. Figure 6.3 also demonstrates that the subsidy cost for solar
PV reduces over time, with the rate of reduction differing between scenarios depend-
ing on the electricity price trends. The scenarios differ only in their gas trends, which
are indicated in figure 6.2 as mentioned above. The corresponding fractions of renew-
able electricity generated are indicated in figure 6.5. At the outset, the following major
observations can be made with regard to the relationship between electricity price and
subsidy costs under different gas price trend scenarios:
• In the gas price trend: Constant scenario, a clear pattern does not emerge. There is
no direct relationship between electricity price and subsidy cost.
• In the gas price trend: High scenario, as electricity prices increase, subsidy costs
decrease for all technologies. This can be seen in figures 6.3 and 6.4. This relation-
ship is maintained as the share of renewable electricity in the mix increases.
100 6. RES-E POLICY DESIGN IN PERSPECTIVE OF THE ENERGY TRANSITION
6 Figure 6.2: Assumptions of gas prices made for Constant, Low, High scenarios.
• In the gas price trend: Low scenario, as electricity prices decrease and as the share
of renewable electricity increases, the subsidy costs do increase, but only slightly
more than in the gas price trend: Constant scenario. This increase is more clearly
visible in Figure 6.3 than in Figure 6.4. In addition, it is also evident that when
electricity prices fall, they cause modest increases in subsidy costs; but that rising
electricity prices cause larger reductions in subsidy costs.
Factors other than gas prices also impact the electricity price and subsidy cost within
the model. The subsidy costs are influenced by fixed costs of the technology, their capac-
ity factors, and the absence of storage or interconnection in the system. This last factor
leads to spillage of intermittent renewable electricity production. As the share of VRE
generation increases, there are more frequent instances of VRE generation being higher
than the demand, which leads to curtailment of RES-E or spillage. Increased spillage
manifests itself as an increase in the per unit (MWh) fixed operation and maintenance
cost of the technology.
The electricity prices in the model are also influenced by low granularity of time pe-
riods within a tick: all 8760 hours in a year are modelled in terms of 20 load segments as
described in Chapter 3 of this dissertation.
I NTERPRETATION
The main effects observed in each of the three scenarios investigated above are explained
here.
6.2. S UBSIDY COSTS AND ELECTRICITY PRICES 101
Figure 6.3: Electricity price and subsidy cost trends [in Eur/MWh] across time. The shaded region indicates
the 95% confidence interval. Source: Own illustration.
Figure 6.4: Electricity price (yearly average) versus subsidy costs [in Eur/MWh] under different gas price trend
scenarios for different technologies. Source: Own illustration.
102 6. RES-E POLICY DESIGN IN PERSPECTIVE OF THE ENERGY TRANSITION
Figure 6.5: Fraction of electricity generated by renewables per tick, and under the three gas price scenarios
Gas price trend: Constant We observe that when the gas price is constant, there is little
impact on the electricity prices, despite an increase in the share of renewables. The impli-
cation of this observation is that the merit order effect is not apparent in the electricity
price trends of these runs. One reason for this is that, for these runs, the Netherlands
is modelled as an isolated system with no interconnections or storage. The absence of
spatial or temporal flexibility in the system from these sources means that there are very
few instances in the model when the demand can be met entirely by intermittent renew-
6 able electricity, and since CCGT is the only flexible technology in the model, all flexibil-
ity is derived from the CCGT. This in turn ensures that the marginal cost of those plants
remain a prominent component in the electricity prices, even as the share of VRE in-
creases.
Gas price trend: High In the gas price high scenarios, under all conditions, the subsidy
costs reduce with increasing electricity prices, for all technologies. Even in the gas price
constant scenarios, when the electricity prices remain almost constant, after the first 7-8
years, the per-unit subsidy costs for solar and wind offshore reduce with time, albeit at
different rates. This is shown in Figure 6.3. This reduction is almost entirely a function
of the reducing cost curves of the technologies, combined with their capacity factors.
The cost curves are presented in Figures A.2 and A.3. For wind onshore, the reduction in
fixed costs takes place at a far slower rate than for PV and wind offshore. Furthermore,
the assumed average capacity factor for wind onshore is half as much as that of wind
offshore. This means that, as the share of renewables increases, curtailment for wind
onshore is much higher than that of wind offshore. This curtailment manifests itself as
increasing per-unit subsidy costs for wind onshore technology in the gas trend constant
scenarios. Interestingly enough, even this effect is trumped for wind offshore by the
relatively high electricity price in the gas trend high scenarios.
The observations suggest that high electricity prices have a significant and direct role
to play in reducing subsidy costs, especially in scenarios where fixed costs of technolo-
gies do not reduce with time, or when the absence of transmission and storage lead to
high amounts of curtailment.
6.3. EU-ETS IN RELATION TO S UBSIDY C OSTS 103
Gas price trend: Low Conversely, observations from Figure 6.3 indicate that low elec-
tricity prices do not directly translate to high subsidy costs as the share of renewables in-
crease. Instead, in the gas trend low scenario, when the electricity prices are relatively
low, the subsidy costs depend far more on the rate of reduction in the costs of technol-
ogy, relative to electricity prices. Therefore, if the rate of reduction in technology costs is
lower than the rate of reduction in electricity prices, as in the case of wind onshore, then
subsidy costs increase with time. The increase in per-unit costs are also bolstered by
the curtailment of wind onshore production as the share of VRE increases. In contrast,
if the rate of reduction of fixed technology costs is greater than the rate of reduction in
electricity prices, subsidy costs reduce.
6.2.3. I NSIGHTS
There are large uncertainties associated with cost developments of renewable technolo-
gies, amounts of interconnection, advancements in storage technologies, and their im-
pact on electricity prices. Therefore, the results above are not predictive, but rather pro-
vide insights on the relationship between electricity prices and subsidy costs under var-
ious conditions.
Despite the fact that the merit-order effect was not apparent in the results, the ob-
servations still provide interesting insights on different factors impacting subsidy costs
under various electricity price scenarios. The most interesting outcome, to the author,
is the difference between the factors affecting subsidy costs under low or high electricity 6
prices. Crucially, over a long-term period of 40 years, high electricity prices [appr. 30-
50 Eur/MWh] have a more substantial role to play in reducing subsidy costs, than low
electricity prices have in increasing it. Another important insight is that decreasing av-
erage electricity prices is only a problem for the attractiveness to invest in RES-E if the
technology costs do not reduce at a rate faster than the electricity prices.
This section comprises a brief discussion highlighting the major points in the afore-
mentioned debate. It further situates the results obtained in this dissertation within the
context of this debate. One notable discussion is the efficiency versus cost-effectiveness
debate, which is addressed in the first sub-section. There have been vigorous debates on
the economic logic behind simultaneously implementing renewable electricity support
schemes as well as the emission trading scheme. Another discussion, more directly rel-
evant to this thesis, is regarding the price effects of renewable support schemes on ETS
prices, and conversely, the effect of ETS prices on RES-E subsidy costs. This is addressed
in the second subsection.
• Positive externalities which arise from knowledge spillovers are not captured in the
above argument. Several authors demonstrate that the presence of both policies
simultaneously is justified when learning spillovers are accounted for (van Ben-
them et al., 2008; Fischer and Newell, 2008; Kalkuhl et al., 2012; Kverndokk and
Rosendahl, 2007).
• The true social costs of non-renewable energy sources cannot be completely in-
ternalised. From an economic perspective the cost of marginal damages from one
tonne of CO2 is subject to considerable uncertainty. Estimates range from zero to
€300 per tonne of CO2 . Furthermore, the emissions gap is the result of political
negotiation rather than efficiency considerations.
• Participants in the EU ETS are subject to policy-induced uncertainties caused by
6.3. EU-ETS IN RELATION TO S UBSIDY C OSTS 105
price fluctuations and the political nature of setting of the cap. Such uncertainties
are detrimental to investments, which are characterised by high initial costs and
long life-times.
• The path-dependent nature of investments in the electricity sector mean that sub-
optimal decisions taken today could render infrastructure changes towards a low
emission system much, much more expensive in the future. This is known as the
carbon lock-in.
In the policy-setting arena of the European Commission, the debate seems to have
been decisively resolved. Both the EU-ETS and the renewable electricity support schemes
coexist and are periodically revised in order to account for developments in abatement
technologies and related costs.
Study Methodology Regional and Tem- Objective Key Findings Reference case
poral Scope
Linares Analytical and sim- Spain, 2004 to 2020 Impact of renew- Reduction in EUA No RES-E Sup-
et al. (2008) ulation research able support pol- price per ton of CO2 : port
icy (Tradable Green 2008 to 2012: 1.32
Certificate) on EUA Eur/tCO2 (22%)
price 2013 to 2017: 5.28
Eur/tCO2 (42%)
2018 to 2020: 7.34
Eur/tCO2 (33%)
Weigt et al. Unit commitment Germany, 2006 to Reduction in de- Reduction by 33-57 No RE Policy
(2012) model 2010 mand for EUA Mton (10-16%) between
allowances due to 2006 and 2010
RE deployment in
German electricity
sector
Van den Partial equilibrium 2 EU Member The impact of RES- Reduction in EUA price No RE Policy
Bergh et al. model States in South- E deployment on per ton of CO2 : 15
(2013) ern and Western the EUA price and EUR/tCO2 in 2007, 46
Europe, 2007 to the CO2emissions EUR/tCO2 in 2008, 100
2010 in the European EUR/tCO2 in 2010
electricity sector
Koch et al. Econometric ex- EU, 2008-2013 To what extent can 0.11% to 0.14% (5% sig- No RES-E sup-
(2014) post analysis EUA price drop nificance level) port
be attributed to
renewable policies
6 quota for renewables is compared with a similar scenario which has the EU ETS system
added to the RES quota. Here, the reduction in subsidy costs ranges from 0 to appr. 12%.
However, since assumptions regarding the progression of renewables quota and of the
ETS caps through time are not clearly specified, it is difficult to assess the impact of ETS
prices on the subsidy costs as the quota increases. In the second paper De Jonghe et al.
(2009) however, the lowering of subsidy costs is clearly indicated at various assumptions
of RES-E quota as well as ETS allowance caps. All in all, it is evident from the analysis that
as the share of renewables increase, the EUA price itself, and the impact of EUA prices on
subsidy costs reduce. This is clearly indicated in Figure 6.6, from De Jonghe et al. (2009).
Of course, it is possible that if the cap were set to be increasingly stringent to ensure a
high CO2 price, the price could have an impact on the subsidy costs. However, such an
approach would defeat the purpose of a quantity-based instrument, while employing a
CO2 tax could achieve the same goal in a direct manner.
Study Methodology Regional and Tem- Objective Key Findings Reference case
poral Scope
Linares Analytical and sim- Spain, 2020 Impact of EUA Subsidy costs reduce No EU ETS
et al. (2008) ulation research price for emissions from 56.59 Eur/MWh
cap of 80Mt on VRE to 50.82 Eur/MWh
subsidy (by 10%) when ETS is
introduced
De Jonghe Simulation model France, Germany, Impact of CO2 For a relatively high No EU ETS
et al. (2009) and Benelux quota on RES-E quota on renewables
subsidy cost (>40%), the certificate
price is only depen-
dent on this quota, and
is independent from
the restriction on CO2
emissions.
6
Figure 6.6: (a) Tradable Geeen Certificate price as a proxy for subsidy cost and (b) allowance price for combina-
tions of TGC and CO2 allowances. Note that the X-axis has a reversed direction in panel (b). Source: De Jonghe
et al. (2009)
Nonetheless, even if the quota on CO2 reduction were to be increased as the share
of RES-E increased, the impact of a marginal increase in the quota on EUA prices and
RES-E subsidy costs would be far less at higher RES-E shares than at lower shares. This
is because carbon-intensive generation technologies themselves will set the marginal
price less often in a system with greater RES-E. If the main objective were to phase out
subsidy costs based on spot market prices, a tax on CO2 would be a more effective and
straightforward means to achieve it at high shares of RES-E in the generation mix.
bility (Brouwer et al., 2016; Budischak et al., 2013; De Jonghe et al., 2011; Jacobson et al.,
2015; Steinke et al., 2013). Other papers discuss the "integration costs of RES-E", where
they estimate, for instance, “an increase in power system operating costs” due to the
presence of VRE (Milligan and Kirby, 2009). While these are important questions in
themselves, they answer questions related to the ’ideal’ costs, or describe the changes
possible to system costs when renewables are integrated into the system and more flex-
ibility is required. They do not, however, provide insights on the effects of flexibility on
the economic value of variable renewables electricity itself. In the researcher’s effort to
assess the possibilities of phasing out of RES-E subsidy, this aspect is key, as it evaluates
the role of flexibility in the economic viability of VRE.
In a landmark paper, Hirth (2013), defined and quantified the concept of "market
value of VRE". Central to this concept is the idea that the availability of the primary
energy source, wind or solar irradiation, fluctuates over time in a manner that has limited
predictability. This, as Hirth describes, "affects the economics of power generation either
by increasing costs, for instance of balancing, or more significantly, reducing the value of
the power generated on the spot market." Several papers have quantified this reduction
in market value of renewables with an increase in their share. To the knowledge of the
author, only two papers however, clearly quantify the impact of flexibility stemming this
reduction of the economic value of intermittent renewable electricity. Their results are
presented below.
The first paper is a work from the Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory (Mills and
6 Wiser, 2015), which evaluates options to stem the reduction in the value of wind and PV
using a long-run equilibrium investment and dispatch model and simulating a region
loosely based on California in 2030. Interestingly, for this specific case, the authors find
that the largest increase in the value of wind comes from geographical diversity, while
the largest increase in the value of solar PV comes from low cost bulk storage.
The second paper, again by Hirth (2016b) comprises both empirical and numerical
analyses, to quantify how the flexibility provided by hydropower mitigates the reduc-
tion in market value of wind energy in Sweden and Germany. He finds that, as the share
of wind increased from 0% to 30%, hydropower mitigates the value drop by a third. As
a consequence, a unit of wind energy (in MWh) is 12%-29% more valuable in Sweden
than in Germany. The use of low wind speed turbines, carbon pricing, and greater hy-
dropower capacity are found to be able to accentuate the value added by flexible hy-
dropower. The author also finds that the positive impact of hydro-flexibility on the value
of wind tapers off as wind penetration increases beyond 20%.
It follows from the above literature that the specific features of a system play a sig-
nificant role in determining which source of flexibility might work the most to increase
the value of VRE. In conclusion, as the share of VRE increases in any electricity system,
the decision to invest in a VRE plant will depend on benefits accrued not just from the
primary resource itself, but also from the types and sources of flexibility in the system.
6.5. D ISCUSSION
In this section, insights from the three strands of literature discussed in this chapter are
brought together to expound on factors that influence RES-E subsidy costs. The time
scales that are analysed in this dissertation are spread over the long term (appr. 30 years),
6.5. D ISCUSSION 109
whereas a lot of the literature is focussed on past, current, or shorter future time scales.
The discussion therefore culminates in a comparison between factors which could influ-
ence subsidy costs over the short term versus the long term, when the share of RES-E is
expected to be substantially higher. An indicative representation is shown in Figure 6.7.
Costs have reduced dramatically over the last decade and are expected to reduce in
the near future, as explained in section 6.2. Learning curves or experience curves are
commonly used to forecast cost projections for new technologies. This is based on the
notion that the more times a task is performed, the less investment in effort is required
for each subsequent iteration2 . A common formulation of this effect is that unit costs de-
crease by a constant percentage for each doubling of experience or production. There-
fore, as technologies mature, cost reductions are also expected to decrease with every
extra unit of production (McDonald and Schrattenholzer, 2001). Based on this theory it
is reasonable to predict that further cost reductions will be far lesser in about 30 years
from now for technologies such as PV and wind.
Given the merit order effect, revenue from electricity spot prices would be lower in a
system with more RES-E generation than less. In a system with substantially higher RES-
E generation, the time during which coal/gas would set the marginal price would reduce,
as compared to a system with lower shares of RES-E generation. Therefore, a unit change
in fuel prices such as those of coal or gas, will have a lower impact on the revenue from
the electricity spot market for RES-E technologies, than it does today. This is true under
the assumption that coal and gas will still be part of the merit-order that far into the
future. A similar argument holds for the role of carbon prices in reducing subsidy costs 6
in the future. As the share of RES-E increases, and carbon-based generation decreases,
the influence of carbon prices on the spot market decreases.
Interconnection, as we know, provides spatial flexibility, while storage provides tem-
poral flexibility. At high shares of RES-E, weather conditions and consequently primary
energy supply across different locations should be diverse enough to supply demand.
In large parts of Europe, where seasonal weather and demand changes are drastic and
simultaneous, for instance, the supply of solar energy reduces substantially during the
winter, while demand remains the same or increases. Therefore, while interconnection
does help provide flexibility at low shares of RES-E and in the near future, it is unlikely
that it will be sufficient to increase the market value of VRE at high shares (>60%) of RES-
E in the long term. This was also a key finding in section 5.3.2, where we found that
interconnection plays a limited role in lending flexibility to the system, whereas stor-
age will play an increasingly important role as RES-E shares increase. These findings are
pictorially represented in Figure 6.7.
Figure 6.7: Impacts of various factors on subsidy costs in the short and long terms
6.6. C ONCLUSION 111
6.6. C ONCLUSION
The main research objective for this chapter was to identify the conditions under which
RES-E subsidies can be phased out. Given that some European countries are considering
a system in which subsidies will no longer be offered to RES-E technologies, this is a top-
ical question. This is also a vital topic in the context of the objective of this dissertation,
which is to help understand design of RES-E subsidies in the European institutional set-
ting. The objective was accomplished primarily by a literature review which examined
three major aspects of the energy transition in Europe: the cost and revenue drivers of
RES-E technologies, the EU ETS, and finally, the role of flexibility. In the course of this
literature review, work from the earlier chapters on designing RES-E subsidies was put in
perspective of the larger energy transition in Europe.
We find that at relatively high average electricity prices, the impact of electricity prices
on subsidy costs is direct and clear; as prices increase, subsidy costs decrease. How-
ever, as electricity prices on the spot market reduce, the change in subsidy cost trends
depends far more on the cost curves of each RES-E technology. With respect to the EU-
ETS, it is clear that, even if EUA prices play a significant role on the electricity prices
today, their influence on the electricity prices, and the RES-E subsidy costs will reduce
as the share of RES-E generation increases with time. From Sections 6.4 and 5.3.2, it is
clear that at high shares of RES-E, interconnection will play a limited role in providing
flexibility while storage (long-term, seasonal) will play a pivotal role. Consequently, the
costs of subsidy for RES-E at high shares are substantially dependant on the presence of
storage in the system. The chapter concludes with a discussion on which factors impact
6
subsidy costs the most in the short term, versus the long term, under certain institutional
settings.
The analysis is largely qualitative, and opens up several avenues for future research.
One interesting path is to analyze the costs at which auctions for long-term contracts are
better than the spot market at creating competition in RES-E and low-carbon flexibility
technologies. Another path for future research could be to use a high-resolution model
to compute the point at which the extra costs of subsidy due to spillage could be higher
than the cost of a certain amount of (large-scale)storage.
112 R EFERENCES
R EFERENCES
O. Wind, UK to Set Sail to Subsidy-Free Offshore Wind Farms, (2017).
L. Hirth, The market value of variable renewables: The effect of solar wind power variabil-
ity on their relative price, Energy Economics 38, 218 (2013).
REmap: Roadmap for a Renewable Energy Future., Tech. Rep. (IRENA, Abu Dhabi, 2016).
B. N. E. Finance, Wind Power Blows Through Nuclear, Coal as Costs Drop at Sea,
Bloomberg.com (2017a).
B. N. E. Finance, New Energy Outlook 2017, Tech. Rep. (Bloomberg Finance L.P., 2017).
J. Cludius, H. Hermann, F. C. Matthes, and V. Graichen, The merit order effect of wind
and photovoltaic electricity generation in Germany 2008–2016: Estimation and distri-
butional implications, Energy Economics 44, 302 (2014).
N. Ederer, The market value and impact of offshore wind on the electricity spot market:
Evidence from Germany, Applied Energy 154, 805 (2015).
A. O’Mahoney and E. Denny, Electricity prices and generator behaviour in gross pool elec-
tricity markets, Energy Policy 63, 628 (2013).
T. Traber and C. Kemfert, Impacts of the German Support for Renewable Energy on Elec-
tricity Prices, Emissions, and Firms, The Energy Journal 30, 155 (2009).
T. Traber and C. Kemfert, Gone with the wind? — Electricity market prices and incen-
tives to invest in thermal power plants under increasing wind energy supply, Energy
Economics 33, 249 (2011).
H. Weigt, Germany’s wind energy: The potential for fossil capacity replacement and cost
saving, Applied Energy 86, 1857 (2009).
R EFERENCES 113
A. Bublitz, D. Keles, and W. Fichtner, An analysis of the decline of electricity spot prices in
Europe: Who is to blame? Energy Policy 107, 323 (2017).
J. Dehler, F. Zimmermann, D. Keles, and W. Fichtner, Der Einfluss der Nachbarländer auf
den Schweizer Strommarkt, (Graz, Austria, 2016).
L. Hirth, What Caused the Drop in European Electricity Prices?, SSRN Scholarly Paper ID
2874841 (Social Science Research Network, Rochester, NY, 2016).
R. Hamming, Numerical methods for scientists and engineers (McGraw-Hill, New York,
1962).
C. Böhringer and K. Rosendahl, Green promotes the dirtiest: On the interaction between
black and green quotas in energy markets, Journal of Regulatory Economics 37, 316
(2010).
C. Fischer and L. Preonas, Combining Policies for Renewable Energy: Is the Whole Less
than the Sum of its Parts? SSRN Electronic Journal (2010), 10.2139/ssrn.1569634.
M. Frondel, N. Ritter, C. M. Schmidt, and C. Vance, Economic impacts from the promo-
tion of renewable energy technologies: The German experience, Energy Policy 38, 4048
(2010).
M. Frondel, N. Ritter, and C. M. Schmidt, Germany’s solar cell promotion: Dark clouds
on the horizon, Energy Policy 36, 4198 (2008).
J. Sijm, The interaction between the EU emissions trading scheme and national energy
policies, Climate Policy 5, 79 (2005).
E. S. Amundsen and J. B. Mortensen, The Danish Green Certificate System: some simple
analytical results, Energy Economics 23, 489 (2001).
114 R EFERENCES
S. Paltsev, J. Reilly, H. Jacoby, and J. Morris, The cost of climate policy in the United States,
Tech. Rep. 173 (2009).
J. Sonnenschein, Conditions for the Cost Effective Combination of Emissions Trading and
Renewable Energy Support Policies, Energy Procedia 88, 133 (2016).
C. Fischer and R. G. Newell, Environmental and technology policies for climate mitiga-
tion, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 55, 142 (2008).
S. Kverndokk and K. E. Rosendahl, Climate policies and learning by doing: Impacts and
timing of technology subsidies, Resource and Energy Economics 29, 58 (2007).
H. Weigt, E. Delarue, and D. Ellerman, CO2 Abatement from Renewable Energy Injections
in the German Electricity Sector: Does a CO2 Price Help?, Tech. Rep. CEEPR 2012-003
(MIT Center for Energy and Environmental Policy Research, 2012).
R EFERENCES 115
N. Koch, S. Fuss, G. Grosjean, and O. Edenhofer, Causes of the EU ETS price drop: Reces-
sion, CDM, renewable policies or a bit of everything?—New evidence, Energy Policy 73,
676 (2014).
M. R. Milligan and B. Kirby, Calculating wind integration costs: Separating wind energy
value from integration cost impacts, Tech. Rep. (National Renewable Energy Labora-
tory Colorado, 2009).
A. D. Mills and R. H. Wiser, Strategies to mitigate declines in the economic value of wind
and solar at high penetration in California, Applied Energy 147, 269 (2015).
L. Hirth, The benefits of flexibility: The value of wind energy with hydropower, Applied
Energy 181, 210 (2016b).
A. McDonald and L. Schrattenholzer, Learning rates for energy technologies, Energy Pol-
icy 29, 255 (2001).
7
C ONCLUSIONS AND REFLECTIONS
In this chapter, key findings of the thesis are summarised, and the findings are reflected
upon. In Section 7.1, answers to research questions are presented. The following section
7.2 presents a reflection on the usefulness and limitations of the approach, the model,
and the results presented. Section 7.3 then describes avenues for future work.
How do national renewable electricity support schemes interact with the electricity
market over the long term (20-30 years) as the European Union transitions to a decar-
bonized energy system?
117
118 7. C ONCLUSIONS AND REFLECTIONS
How can policy design options for RES-E support in Europe be systematically and
comprehensively explored and modelled?
Using a combination of design theory, institutional analysis, and agent-based mod-
elling (ABM), we provide a method to systematically explore policy design options for
RES-E support in Europe. This is done firstly by identification of the design elements2 of
a policy or set of policies, and secondly by evaluating the impact of each design element
on the socio-technical system using an agent-based model.
Given a certain frame of analysis, we propose that it is theoretically possible to iden-
tify the complete policy design space. Crucially, this aspect potentially opens up to the
7 policy analyst new avenues for intervention, and allows her explore, given a range of un-
certainties, which element(s) of intervention is(are) the most vital to achieve the goals of
the community. The applicability of the approach is demonstrated by representing and
differentiating between six renewable electricity support schemes from Western Europe
in terms of the design elements. The applicability of the modelling framework using
ABM, and consequently of the Design Element Approach, is demonstrated by evaluating
the long-term, dynamic impact of three design elements: price warranty versus quan-
tity warranty, technology neutrality versus specificity, and accounting for the electricity
market price ex-ante versus ex-post on the Dutch electricity sector.
It is important to note here that claims of completeness of the design space come
with limitations. For instance, if the energy producer agent were to assume multiple
identities, such as being politically active and strongly pushing for local autarky, the de-
sign elements would be different. The design framework published here therefore per-
tains mainly to an analysis which lies within the scope of welfare economics, although
founded firmly within an institutional framework and empirical experience. Other lim-
itations of the approach include its computationally intensive nature, and the need to
prudently select the most important design elements necessary for the analysis.
1 As in stochastic optimisation
2 Design elements of renewable electricity support policies are defined as a closed set of components which
a renewable electricity policy is comprised of, such that each component now forms the smallest level of
analysis.
7.1. A NSWERS TO R ESEARCH QUESTIONS 119
How do RES-E support policy design elements interact with a single isolated elec-
tricity market and what social welfare implications do they actualise?
We employ this design element view in combination with agent based modelling to
quantitatively assess impacts of individual design elements on the socio-technical sys-
tem. The results demonstrate that design elements, irrespective of the RES-E policy to
which they belong, have significant impacts on the energy system and on welfare dis-
tribution, and therefore that the approach is a useful one. The agent-based modelling
framework enables modelling of bounded rationalities in investment decisions, allow-
ing the modeller to incorporate real-world uncertainties in agents’ behaviour. An impor-
tant uncertainty in the real world is that of long-term electricity price development. The
model interestingly demonstrates that accounting for future electricity prices ex-ante
in the subsidy calculation may reduce the overall cost of subsidy by about 15%, since
the actors are likely to overestimate the future electricity price. This is a consequence
of underestimating the impact of the merit order effect on expected electricity prices
over the long-term. Other significant results are that technology specificity could reduce
the cost of subsidy by upto 60%. Results regarding the design element, quantity vs price
warranty corroborate established literature: quantity warranty helps achieve targets bet-
ter. The design element configuration that leads to the highest increase in social welfare
is the combination of quantity-warranty, ex-ante accounting for electricity prices, and
technology-specificity.
With regard to policy implications, the State Aid Guidelines of the European Com-
mission promote competitive bidding to incentivize investment, while largely support-
ing technology neutrality. At the outset, our results corroborate with the choice of com-
petitive bidding. They however indicate that the feature technology specificity has a sig- 7
nificant implication on welfare impacts, subject to the assumption of regulator’s knowl-
edge of real costs being the same as the energy producer. Differences in such features
of RES-E policy between member states could lead to unintended cross border effects.
The design element method has the potential to provide insight into which aspects of
the policies need to be co-ordinated at the European level.
The results show that setting targets for RES-E, should not only take into account
the targets of the neighbouring countries, but also the capacity of storage that exists in
the system. The results also raise interesting questions about how subsidy costs should
be allocated between countries over the long-term, especially when subsidy costs are so
intricately connected with the electricity markets they operate in.
How could major developments in the energy transition such as RES-E technology
cost trends, the EU ETS, and flexibility influence RES-E support?
The objective was accomplished primarily by a literature review which examined
three major aspects of the energy transition in Europe: the cost and revenue drivers of
RES-E technologies, the EU ETS, and finally, the role of flexibility. In the course of this
literature review, work from the earlier chapters on designing RES-E subsidies was put in
perspective of the larger energy transition in Europe.
We find that the impact of high average electricity prices on subsidy costs is direct
and clear; i.e., as prices increase subsidy costs decrease. However, as electricity prices
on the spot market reduce on average, the change in subsidy cost trends depend far
more on the cost curves of each RES-E technology. With respect to the EU-ETS, it is
clear that, even if EUA prices play a significant role on the electricity prices today, their
influence on the electricity prices, and the RES-E subsidy costs will reduce as the share
of RES-E generation increases with time. From Sections 6.4 and 5.3.2, it is evident that
at high shares of RES-E, interconnection will play a limited role in providing flexibility
while storage (long-term, seasonal) will play a pivotal role. Consequently the costs of
subsidy for RES-E at high shares are substantially dependent on the presence of storage
in the system.
7
7.2. R EFLECTIONS
As computer simulation methods are gaining more and more prominence across disci-
plines, ideas about their trustworthiness for generating new knowledge are being dis-
cussed in works on philosophy of science (Gilbert and Troitzsch, 2005; Parker, 2008;
Winsberg, 1999, 2001; Epstein, 1999). The reader’s confidence in a computer simula-
tion is instilled by evaluating the claim that a simulation is indeed fit for its purpose. The
science that deals with such evaluations is called the Epistemology of Computer Simula-
tions (EOCS) Winsberg (2015). The idea of external validation of a simulation is explored
in the subsequent paragraphs. The stage is set by a note on the role of simulations in sci-
ence. The uncertainties and assumptions involved in the model (EMLab) and how they
relate to the real world are explored in the following subsection. Finally, the usefulness
of the framework, model, and results are reflected upon.
market clearing process, the data is aggregated to 20 segments on both the demand and
supply side. At high shares of intermittent RES-E generation, it becomes is important to
represent the market clearing with a fine resolution, as otherwise the impact of renew-
ables on the market price will be under-represented.
Interconnections are represented in a limted manner in the model. In Chapter 4,
The Netherlands is represented as an isolated system, and in Chapter 5, only the inter-
connection between Germany and the Netherlands is represented. In reality the trans-
mission network is far more complex. As spatial heterogeneity in supply and demand
contributes to balancing, its absence in Chapter 4 leads to an inflated presence of CCGT
in the merit-order, increasing average electricity prices. Similarly in Chapter 5, if the in-
terconnections had been represented with greater accuracy, while taking into account
the electricity markets of the neighbouring countries, the effect of Germany’s electricity
prices on the Dutch RES-E subsidy costs would be lower than what has been presented.
The subsidy costs to the Netherlands would depend more on the interconnection capac-
ities and the supply curves of the other neighbouring zones.
Market mechanisms outside of the day-ahead market have not ben analyzed: for in-
stance, intra-day markets, or balancing markets. Interviews with officials from the EPEX-
SPOT indicates that the volumes traded in the intra day markets have been rapidly in-
creasing over the last few years, as shares of intermittent RES-E electricity increase. This
trend can be expected to continue, as the shares RES-E increase even further. Since the
subsidy costs are currently only tied to the spot market (day ahead) prices, the analy-
sis in the dissertation holds. However, as the intra-day and balancing markets will play
a greater role, it is imperative that their impact on revenues for RES-E technologies are
evaluated while setting RES-E targets in the future. Such an evaluation would be in-
7 tricately tied with the role such markets play in attracting options for flexibility in the
system as well.
Investor behaviour in EMLab is represented by incorporating bounded rationality -
a distinctive feature of the model. The advantages of such a modelling feature is that
it allows us to analyse and represent observed phenomenon such as investment cycles.
Through the model-building process, after many rounds of trial and error, it was evident
that the magnitude and period of the cycles were largely dependent on the "future-time-
period" of the investing agent, i.e., the future time step for which an agent evaluates
an investment decision vis-a-vis the current time period. The longer into the future an
agent looks to make an investment, the more mistakes he is bound to make, as there
are more unknowns, thus increasing the amplitude and period of the cycles. If different
technologies are given different permit times and construction times, this impacts the
features of cycles correspondingly.
which the real world can be represented, and theories or "speculations" tested. Although
this framework was applied and demonstrated using renewable support schemes in Eu-
rope, its fundamental nature makes it eminently employable to other domains. The
claim is supported by the fact that each of the foundational concepts that make up the
framework have been applied in thousands of publications and are being actively used
across sectors, geographies, communities.
One aspect of the modelling framework presented that needs further attention how-
ever is the fact that choosing a limited number of design elements for analysis is, to say
the least, challenging. How does a researcher tell whether a certain element is important
or not? While this dissertation sheds little light on the topic, others such as Taeihagh et al.
(2014) have proposed and demonstrated some interesting ways to reduce the policy de-
sign element set. One such method uses a combination of interviews with stakeholders,
combinatorics, and network theory, to design policies and aid decision making.
A major advantage of the model is that it is open source. Most models that are used
to inform the European Commission’s policy documents are black box simulations. The
assumptions, data, systems used to set policy are not publicly available. Making models
open source allows for replicability, transparency, and for debating their validity, which
are all basic tenets of the scientific method.
The model has provided interesting insights on impacts of design elements of RES-E
support and on the nature of cross border interactions. The results pave the way towards
new questions that need to be resolved as the shares of RES-E increase in the elecricity
system. For instance, they raise pressing questions about the need to further develop a
methodology for sharing the paying the investment costs behind the subsidies between
countries. These are explained in greater detail in the following section on future work.
7
7.3. F UTURE WORK
The framework presented in this work can be extended in several ways. Its reliability and
usefulness could be tested by applying it to other socio-technical systems. It could be ex-
tended methodologically by incorporating endogenous policy emergence and evolution
using policy process theories.
For modellers of long term energy systems, it is paramount that models employ high
temporal resolution at high shares of intermittent RES-E generation. Creative techniques
to accomplish this while having endogenous investment in the model need to be in-
vented. One way of accomplishing this, without compromising on the constraints of
computational resources, is to run high resolution optimization algorithms to compute
hourly market clearing at intervals of 3 or 5 years (ticks), given a certain generation mix.
In Chapter 5 it was evident that the costs of RES-E electricity will rise due to high
spillage, if adequate temporal flexibility is not provided. An interesting point of depar-
ture is to compute the tradeoff between marginal storage and the marginal unit of RES-E
generation: at what point does an extra unit of storage cost lesser than an extra unit of
intermittent RES-E without storage? This would be interesting to policy makers as it sig-
nals whether, and at what point, storage technologies might need regulatory support to
be able to increase the share of RES-E in the system.
Given that electricity markets are intricately connected across national borders, ques-
tions regarding burden sharing of subsidy costs are complex, as merit order effects spread
124 7. C ONCLUSIONS AND REFLECTIONS
across border. They should also depend on the neighbouring countries’ targets, genera-
tion mixes, and flexibilty sources. These questions need to be explored in greater detail,
and possible mechanisms to cope with the complexities should be evaluated.
7
R EFERENCES 125
R EFERENCES
G. N. Gilbert and K. G. Troitzsch, Simulation for the social scientist, 2nd ed. (Open Uni-
versity Press, Maidenhead, England ; New York, NY, 2005).
E. Winsberg, Simulations, Models, and Theories: Complex Physical Systems and Their
Representations, Philosophy of Science 68, S442 (2001).
A.1. D ATA
Growth Rate
Start value Mode Min Max
Electricity demand growth rate 1 1.1 0.99 1.03
Gas price - Basecase 4 1 1 1
Gas price - high 4 1.02 1.04 1
Gas price - low 4 0.98 0.96 1
127
128 A. D ATA AND A SSUMPTIONS
Figure A.1: Stochastic, annual demand growth factor trends for both Netherlands and Germany.
The assumptions for cost trends are based on data from IRENA reports and are in 2014
prices. The Solar PV investment costs are based on IRENA (2016), while cost trends for
wind offshore and onshore are based on IRENA and IEA-ETSAP (2016).
A.1. D ATA 129
Figure A.2: Assumed Investment cost trends per technology across the time period of the simulation
Figure A.3: Assumed operation and maintenance cost trends across the time period of the simulation
trapolate trends for the whole time scope of the model. The data points and their sources
A are mentioned in the table below.
4e+08
2e+08
4e+08
2e+08
0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40
Tick[Year]
Figure A.4: Assumed targets and potentials of renewable electricity technologies (all) in Germany in MWh.
A.1. D ATA 131
5e+07
1e+08
5e+07
0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40
Tick[Year]
Figure A.5: Assumed targets and potentials of renewable electricity technologies (all) in Netherlands in MWh.
s
Co
Co
M
y
nt
log
y
O&
me
nc
no
cie
est
ed
ch
Effi
Inv
Fix
Te
ur]
ur]
ate
ate
ate
nE
nE
hr
hr
hr
t [i
t [i
t
t
ow
ow
ow
t
r
r
Sta
Sta
Sta
Gr
Gr
Gr
Figure A.6: Global weighted average utility-scale installed solar pv system costs and breakdown, 2009-2025,
Source: IRENA (2016)
R EFERENCES
IRENA, Solar PV in Africa: Costs and Markets, Tech. Rep. (2016).
IRENA and IEA-ETSAP, Wind Power Technology Brief , Tech. Rep. E07 (2016).
P. Lako, Technical and economic features of renewable electricity technologies, Tech. Rep.
ECN-E–10-034 (ECN, 2010).
M. Ragwitz, G. Resch, C. Huber, and S. White, Dynamic Cost Resource Curves, Tech.
Rep. ENG2-CT-2002-00607 (Energy Economics Group, Vienna University of Technol-
ogy, 2003).
Y. Scholz, Renewable energy based electricity supply at low costs - development of the
REMix model and application for Europe, Ph.D. thesis, German Aerospace Institute,
Stuttgart (2012).
B
R ESULTS
B.1.1. F IGURES
Subsidy Cost in Eur/MWh
90 90
60 60
30 30
0 0
P_Ante
P_Post
P_AnteTS
P_PostTS
Q_Ante
Q_Post
Q_AnteTS
Q_PostTS
P_Ante
P_Post
P_AnteTS
P_PostTS
Q_Ante
Q_Post
Q_AnteTS
Q_PostTS
(a) Subsidy costs in Gas Low scenario (b) Subsidy costs in Gas High scenario
Figure B.1: Subsidy costs in scenarios with increasing or decreasing gas price trends
133
134 B. R ESULTS
60 60
B 30 30
0 0
P_Ante
P_Post
P_AnteTS
P_PostTS
Q_Ante
Q_Post
Q_AnteTS
Q_PostTS
P_Ante
P_Post
P_AnteTS
P_PostTS
Q_Ante
Q_Post
Q_AnteTS
Q_PostTS
Policy Scenario Policy Scenario
(a) Subsidy costs in scenario set with (b) Policy cost effectiveness in scenario
the same risk aversion set with constant RES-E target
Figure B.2: Subsidy costs of scenarios addressing each effect on price setting individually
B.1.2. TABLES
Table B.2: Comparison of Average Subsidy Between Base Case Set and Same Risk Scenario Set
200
150
B
100
50
200
150
100
50
0
0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40
Time [a]
Variable Subsidy per MWh Elec. market revenue per MWh Fixed cost per MWh
Figure B.3: Fixed costs, revenue from subsidy, revenue from spot market shown per MWh electricity generated,
across time.
136 B. R ESULTS
600
Netherlands
400
200
Cost in Billion Euros
600
Germany
400
200
0
m h m h
Lo
w diu Hig Lo
w diu Hig
Int Me Int Int Me Int
Int Int
Interconnection Level
Figure B.4: Electricity and subsidy costs summed across 40 ticks, per country, and per RES-E policy
B.2. C HAPTER 5: R ESULTS 137
B
Interconnection 0 MW Interconnection 3950 MW Interconnection 10000 MW
500
400
P_Ante
300
200
100
0
500
400
P_AnteTS
300
200
Spillage of electricity generation from RES−E in Germany [TWh]
100
0
500
400
P_Post
300
200
100 technology
0
500 Photovoltaic
400
P_PostTS
300 Wind
200
100 WindOffshore
0
500
400
Q_Ante
300
200
type of production
100
Actual Production
0
500
Expected Production
400
Q_AnteTS
300
200
100
0
500
400
Q_Post
300
200
100
0
500
400
Q_PostTS
300
200
100
0
0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40
Time [in years]
Figure B.5: Expected versus actual production of RES-E due to spillage across time in Germany in TWh
138 B. R ESULTS
B
Interconnection 0 MW Interconnection 3950 MW Interconnection 10000 MW
125
100
P_Ante
75
50
25
0
125
100
P_AnteTS
75
Spillage of electricity generation from RES−E in Netherlands [TWh]
50
25
0
125
100
P_Post
75
50
25 technology
0
125 Photovoltaic
100
P_PostTS
75 Wind
50
25 WindOffshore
0
125
100
Q_Ante
75
50
type of production
25
Actual Production
0
125
Expected Production
100
Q_AnteTS
75
50
25
0
125
100
Q_Post
75
50
25
0
125
100
Q_PostTS
75
50
25
0
0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40
Time [in years]
Figure B.6: Expected versus actual production of RES-E due to spillage across time in the Netherlands in TWh
L IST OF P UBLICATIONS
U NDER REVIEW
• K. Iychettira, M. Klein, R. Hakvoort, Can subsidies be phased out under high shares of RES-E?
Evaluating primary influencing factors, Working paper submitted for publication, (2017).
C ONFERENCE PROCEEDINGS
• K. Iychettira, Towards a comprehensive policy for electricity from renewable energy: A Struc-
tured Design Approach, 3rd International Conference on Public Policy, Singapore, 28-30
June 2017.
• K. Iychettira, R. Hakvoort, R. de Jeu, P. Linares, Designing the Right RES-E Support Schemes:
assessing impacts of design elements using an agent-based model., WholeSEM Annual Con-
ference 2016, Cambridge, UK, 4-5 July 2016.
• K. Iychettira, P. Linares, R. Hakvoort, Harmonising RES-E support schemes using design el-
ements, 12th International Conference on the European Energy Market, Lisbon, Portugal,
19-22 May 2015.
139
140 L IST OF P UBLICATIONS
Kaveri was born on the 30th of December 1989. She spent her early years in Mysore,
and later moved to Bangalore where she completed her secondary education and bach-
elor degree. Through school and early college, she showed a penchant for writing; she
wrote for and edited several community magazines and newsletters. In 2007 she gradu-
ated from pre-university college, and in 2011, obtained a Bachelor in Engineering, with
a specialization in Electrical and Electronics, from RV College of Engineering in Banga-
lore. During 2010-11 she also interned at the Centre for Science Technology and Policy in
Bangalore, where she worked on analysing the impact of India’s National Solar Mission.
She went to the Netherlands in 2011, to pursue a Masters in Engineering and Policy Anal-
ysis at Delft University of Technology. She was awarded the Justus van Effenfond Schol-
arship, a full funding of her Masters education, granted to only 8 students in 2011 across
the University. During her Masters, she specialized in the disciplines of Modelling and
Economics. She wrote a dissertation analysing the impact of capacity markets in the
electricity sector in The Netherlands and Germany. She was awarded the "Best Graduate
Award" for the Faculty of TPM at the Delft University of Technology for the year 2013.
In October 2013, she began an Erasmus Mundus Joint Doctorate in Sustainable Energy
Technologies and Strategies (SETS) at Delft University of Technology. As part of the SETS
programme, she spent 11 months at Comillas Pontifical University in Madrid, Spain, and
6 months at KTH Royal Institute of Technology in Stockholm, Sweden. During her doc-
toral programme, she published several peer-reviewed journal publications, supervised
4 master thesis projects, and presented at 5 international conferences. She also served
as the student representative for the 32 students across the three universities during
2015-16. She began working as a post-doctoral fellow at the Belfer Centre of the Har-
vard Kennedy School since September 2017.
141