Court Fees: Charging The User As A Way To Mitigate Judicial Congestion
Court Fees: Charging The User As A Way To Mitigate Judicial Congestion
net/publication/281641014
CITATIONS READS
3 271
1 author:
Rafael Mery
Universidad Diego Portales
4 PUBLICATIONS 11 CITATIONS
SEE PROFILE
All content following this page was uploaded by Rafael Mery on 10 September 2015.
2015
Recommended Citation
Mery Nieto, Rafael (2015) "Court Fees: Charging the User as a Way to Mitigate Judicial Congestion," The Latin American and Iberian
Journal of Law and Economics: Vol. 1: Iss. 1, Article 7.
Available at: http://laijle.alacde.org/journal/vol1/iss1/7
This Article is brought to you for free and open access by The Latin American and Iberian Journal of Law and Economics. It has been accepted for
inclusion in The Latin American and Iberian Journal of Law and Economics by an authorized administrator of The Latin American and Iberian Journal
of Law and Economics.
Court Fees: Charging the User as a Way to Mitigate Judicial
Congestion
Abstract: This paper studies the use of court fees on judicial litigation, which
aims both to regulate access to courts and reduce the congestion of the judicial
system, and cover part of the direct costs of the system. Moreover, it provides
resources to finance the administration of justice, and enables equitable access to
the court.
Assuming that the demand for legal services is not different of the demand for any
other good or service, the paper show a simple model to explain why and under
what conditions it is efficient to charge a court fee.
I. INTRODUCTION
The judicial system is a very costly social institution, whose funds come almost
entirely from public resources. The idea that judicial systems should be financed
with public funds is justified because there is a belief that justice should be free
and should guarantee the “right of access" to courts of all citizens. This fact and
the existing environmental incentives could induce people to litigate on courts to
suboptimal levels.
As shown in the comparative experience (Dakolias, 1999), the existing
environmental incentives can induce people to litigate in courts, rejecting other
substitute goods that could be socially preferable. This is especially true in civil
litigation, so court fees analysis is more relevant in civil and commercial
litigation. Therefore, our analysis focuses on this type of litigation.
The excessive litigation or court uses on suboptimal levels is a
consequence of a difference between private and social incentives to use the legal
systems (Shavell, 1997). This difference is attributable, according to Shavell
(1997), to two externalities.
First, a negative externality occurs when an individual decides to bring a
suit using the judicial system and does not take into account the legal costs he
∗
Address correspondence to this author at the Universidad Diego Portales, School of Law, Av.
República 105, Santiago, Chile. E-mail: [email protected]
110 THE LATIN AMERICAN AND IBERIAN JOURNAL OF LAW AND ECONOMICS [Vol. 1: 1
induces others to incur into. Indeed, when the plaintiff makes a decision to bring a
suit he does not take into account -when assessing the choice of litigating to
judgment or settling privately- the costs to be incurred by the defendant and the
administration costs of justice.
Second, a positive externality because the decision about the bringing of
suits, generates social benefits that the litigant does not take into account, for
example, the associated effects of deterrence that makes the system more
predictable and allows a more informed decision about going or not to courts.
Then, the main divergence between private and social incentives to use the
judicial system is the difference between private and social costs and benefits
associated with the use of the judicial system.
This is due, among other causes, to free cost litigation. Indeed, this
practice generates levels of litigation that are not optimal from social welfare
criteria, since the social costs are higher than the social benefits generated by
litigation. In other words, a free cost judicial system encourages levels of
litigation socially inappropriate, because people do not take into consideration all
the costs involved in a litigation process when deciding to bring suit. When costs
are underestimated, because they only consider private costs, the result is that
people litigate more. Private incentives to sue are misaligned with what is socially
optimal (Cabrillo & Fitzpatrick, 2008).
Excessive litigation increases congestion and delay in the resolution of
conflicts. Thus, the larger number of cases that enter the courts, the greater the
delay in the care of new claims and the proportion of cases solved decreases over
time. Congestion and delay is -in economic terms, the cost of litigation- making it
more expensive and excluding the poorest sectors of society who end up
subsidizing with their exclusion wealthier litigants who can afford the costs of
delays.
The duration of trials affect the individual’s decision to litigate. Indeed,
individuals decide to litigate if the expected benefits of litigation exceed the
expected costs. The law and economics literature identifies the duration of trials
as one of the factors affecting the individual decision to litigate. The duration is a
result of congestion. In congested courts, like congested roads, the trials take
longer to reach the end. Delay in a dispute reduces the present value of the
potential judgment for a plaintiff thus decreasing the likelihood of litigation
(Priest, 1989). Court delay also affects primary behavior. The longer the trials the
greater the incentives to breach contracts, as court delay gives the breaching party
the chance to postpone payments. Consequently, the number of potential cases
will be larger1 (Miller, 1989).
1
Other variable that affecting the longer the trials and can increase or decrease the likelihood
of litigation is the judicial interest rate. Acciarri & Garoupa (2013) show that the asymmetric
opportunity costs for each party in a case, judicial interest rates may lead to improper delay of
2015] COURT FEES 111
The first news about court fees can be found in the 13th century in England with
the enactment of the Statute of Gloucester during the reign of Kind Edward I in
England. This Statute came to introduce a system of tariffs for use of courts. The
reason for that was the need to raise funds for courts and discourage litigation
(National Center for States Courts, 1975).
Trough time, we can find different systems of court fees in many
countries. Indeed, today most American and European countries have systems of
court fees, and the same applies to some countries in Asia and Africa.
Design and system characteristics of court fees are specific to each
country. Comparative experience shows that the design of the optimal rate
requires a wealth of information for each particular case, which implies there is no
simple and universal "magic formula" to get the internalization of social benefits,
proceedings or the decoupling of damages from recovery. These potential results -according to
Acciarri & Garoupa- influence the number of settlements and suits.
112 THE LATIN AMERICAN AND IBERIAN JOURNAL OF LAW AND ECONOMICS [Vol. 1: 1
and the appropriate corrective policy depends on the social value of each case,
which is inherently complex (Esteller-Moré, 2002).
However, for these purposes, we understand that court fees are a monetary
charge to which litigants are obligated for provision of judicial services, in order
to contribute to cover the costs of the administration of justice.
As an example, in the U.S., the Superior Court of California for
complaints or other first papers in unlimited civil cases (amounts over US$
25,000) charges a court fee of US$ 435; US$ 370 for civil cases with amounts
over US$ 10,000 up to US$ 25,000; and US$ 225 for cases with amounts up to $
10,0002.Meanwhile, in Spain, the Law of Court Fees, approved on May 22 2012,
established a court fee as the sum of a fixed fee plus a variable fee which will
takes into account the total amount claimed in the proceedings. The fixed fee will
be € 300 for ordinary civil proceedings, € 800 when filing an appeal and € 1,200
for the cassation appeal. Meanwhile, the variable fee will be 0.5 per cent of the
total claim for claims ranging from € 0 to € 1,000,000, and 0.25 per cent for
claims € 1,000,000 onwards, with a ceiling of € 10,0003.
Both literature and comparative experience show that the objectives of court fees
have been mainly two: First, to regulate access to justice, creating the correct
incentives to achieve optimal levels of litigation, and to encourage or discourage
the use of alternative dispute resolution. And second, to provide resources for the
administration of justice. However, we can add a third objective or reason for
incorporating court fees: fairness and social redistribution of costs of justice.
The establishment of court fees seeks to regulate access to justice, get the
internalization by the litigant of all costs and benefits of their decision to bring
suit using the judicial system. A court fee is the price for the service. Thus, court
fees make more expensive the access to justice by establishing an explicit price on
the demand for justice. In this way, the number of cases should decrease, and
avoid the excessive use of courts.
This implies the assumption that the demand for legal services is not
different (in essence) of the demand for any other good or service, and is
subjected to the law of demand, as the price of a good or service increases, ceteris
paribus, consumer demand for the good or service will decrease, and vice versa.
2
Superior Court of California, Statewide Civil Fee Schedule, January 1 2014.
3
Law 10/2012, November 2012, modified for Law 3/2013, February 2013.
2015] COURT FEES 113
Then, only the suits where court intervention is justified will enter the
judicial system, and the frivolous suits will be left out.
In the words of Santos Pastor and Carmen Vargas (Pastor, S. & Vargas,
2001, pp. 45-46), the court fees are justified because:
"The general principle that operates in our societies implies that, if
the enjoyment of a benefit by a user means a cost, the user must pay a price
to offset that cost; that is socially appropriate, discourages excessive
consumption and prevents the injustice that others should pay for it"
For Santos Pastor, the court fees play an administrator role, as a price does
when managing scarce resources in a society.
In this sense, Alejandro Esteller-Moré (2002, p.527), says:
"The rate must discourage those trials unlikely to be favorable for
the litigant, in exchange for others to suffer a shorter delay or for the whole
of society to subsidize, through taxes, the access to justice for cases whose
social benefits are lower than their social costs, or for which there are
cheaper extrajudicial processes"
A court fees system is a potential deterrent mechanism that causes a
reduction of litigation by increasing the costs to the litigant, and so reducing court
congestion. Court fees are necessary to deter frivolous litigation or to channel
different types of cases to appropriate courts or other non-judicial dispute
resolution forms, such as counseling, mediation, or arbitration.
2.1.2. Provide funding for the administration of justice
A second objective of introducing court fees is to provide resources to
finance the administration of justice.
Court fees can help to increase the budget of the administration of justice,
without diverting funds from other items in state budgets or raise taxes on
citizens.
Given that courts are a limited and expensive public resource to operate, it
is appropriate to seek recovery from users of some of the costs of their operation.
Almost every country levies some charge for the use of its courts. Table 1, in
APPENDIX A, shows the percentages of contribution of court fees to judicial
budget for some European countries in 2008 or 2010, based on information
published by the European Commission for the Efficiency of Justice, and show
that the average of all countries of the Council of Europe is at 28.3%, and the
median at 27.9%.
banks and financial institutions), that go to courts with thousands of cases every
year, mainly for the payment of their debts.
Gratuitousness of justice can be seen like a benefit to rich users. Public
spending on justice would be an unfocused and/or regressive expenditure, because
it finances the richest sectors of society with public resources. The
underprivileged users are left out of the courts. They can't pay and the excessive
use of court produces congestion and delay, putting them at the end of the line.
Enabling equitable access to the court is a key consideration in structuring
court fees. Under principles of equity, the judicial system should be fair and
accessible for all, including those facing financial and other disadvantages. For a
well-functioning judicial system, access to the courts should not be dependent on
capacity to pay and vulnerable litigants should not be disadvantaged4.
Therefore, a system of court fees should consider matters that, for reasons
of fairness, should not pay fees. This occurs, for example, in cases of
constitutional protection, family law or criminal trials.
4
The court fee system is not incompatible with legal aid provided by public funds for those
that cannot afford the necessary legal advice and representation in litigation proceedings, besides
court fee's exemption.
2015] COURT FEES 115
certain fundamental rights such as the "effective judicial protection" and equality
before the law. In other words, the main question is: are court fees a limitation or
restriction on the guarantee of right to effective judicial protection?
The "right of access" to free justice, internationally recognized, is not an
absolute and unlimited right. It´s a state obligation and a legal right, whose
content and specific exercise is conditioned and therefore, delimited by
legislature, taking into account public and private interests involved, and budget
availability.
III.1. Incomplete Markets, Not Exclusion and the Tragedy of the Commons
1
[1]
where is the probability of winning the case; is the litigant income; is the
recovery on the claim; is the litigation costs; 1 is the congestion costs
(higher congestion cost, lower recover on the claim); and,
is the risk
aversion. The expression (1) establishes the private condition for litigation. The
left side is the expected value of litigation, and the right side is the value not to
litigate. This, if the expected value of litigation is greater than not, will be held.
The social condition will be given by:
1
∆
[2]
2015] COURT FEES 117
where and are the opportunity cost of litigation for the plaintiff and
defendant; ∆
is the economic assessment of the overall effects of increased
congestion in the judicial system; is the marginal cost of the new suit; and is
the social benefits of the precedent effect.
If we cleared the probabilities values from expressions (1) and (2), we
obtain the limits from which it is profitable -privately and socially- to initiate a
suit, like equations (3) and (4):
′
[3]
∆
[4]
′′
There will be an excessive litigation if′′ ′ . To solve this inefficiency a tax can
be charged on the suit, which is derived from expressions (3) and (4).
∆
[5]
where is the court fee. Solving equation (5), the value to be charged as court fee
is:
∆
[6]
Although this is the ultimate goal of a court fee, it also has desirable side effects,
like the decrease in incentives to initiate frivolous lawsuits.
We understand by frivolous lawsuits those who have a very low
probability of winning. This occurs when the expected benefits are much higher
than the legal costs, and it is convenient to risk. So then, court fees would reduce
the level of litigation, as can be seen in the next graph:
118 THE LATIN AMERICAN AND IBERIAN JOURNAL OF LAW AND ECONOMICS [Vol. 1: 1
The graph shows that with court fee () only cases that have a higher probability
of a win go to court. In other words, the court fee will discourage frivolous
lawsuits, unfounded, and with low probability of success, that in the absence of
court fees initially would go to courts.
In short, the court fee has the effect on litigation of discouraging frivolous
litigation; it must incorporate the marginal cost of the judicial service, and
negative externality valuation caused by the trial. Also, the court fee must
incorporate the social benefits (), excluding the costs incurred by the plaintiff
( ).
However the difficulties of assessing the social benefits, a good
approximation is the monetary amount claimed (). Thus, the court fee will be a
function of and other variables such as trial characteristics, plaintiff
characteristics (firm or person), etc.
IV. CONCLUSIONS
In a judicial system without court fees, the litigants only cover their private costs
and the State finances the system's costs. That generates excessive litigation,
increased congestion and delay in conflict resolution. The charges of court fees
permit the internalization of litigation costs, and serves as a barrier to entry into
litigation. This is achieved by approximating the social costs to the private costs.
In general, there are good reasons for using court fees: First, to achieve
internalization by the litigant of all costs and benefits that their decision causes on
2015] COURT FEES 119
CONFLICT OF INTEREST
The author confirms that this article content has no conflict of interest.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENT
The author wish to acknowledge the editor and the anonymous reviewers for their
detailed and helpful comments.
120 THE LATIN AMERICAN AND IBERIAN JOURNAL OF LAW AND ECONOMICS [Vol. 1: 1
REFERENCES
APPENDIX A