The Real Business Cycle Model: Ester Faia
The Real Business Cycle Model: Ester Faia
Ester Faia
Note 1: since markets are perfect, there are no market failures, and
fluctuations are the optimal responses of agents to the exogenous
shocks. Therefore:
There is no deterministic cycle (as in the Mitchell sense).
There is no scope for government intervention.
Note 2: here we consider a walrasian model of the aggregate
economy where fluctuations are generated by real shocks.
The current debate in the economic theory is about the fact that
walrasian models with real shocks are insufficient in explaining
aggregate economic fluctuations.
Later we will consider non-walrasian models of aggregate economic
activity where fluctuations are generated by nominal shocks.
Other strands of macroeconomics consider models with real shocks and
with non walrasian imperfections.
0<α<1
Capital depreciates at the rate δ:
K t + 1 = ( 1 − δ ) K t + It + 1 (2)
where It +1 is investment.
Ester Faia (Goethe University Frankfurt) RBC Fundamentals of Macro, WS 2021/22 6/
The Baseline RBC Model
The Firm (con’t)
−1 < ρ < 1
ε t is a white noise:
E (ε t ) = 0 (5)
cov (ε t , ε s ) = 0 for any t 6= s (6)
∂Πt
= αKtα−1 (At Lt )1−α − (rt + δ) = 0 (8)
∂Kt
∂Πt
= (1 − α) At Ktα (At Lt )−α − wt = 0 (10)
∂Lt
Ktα (At Lt )1−α
⇒ wt = (1 − α) (11)
Lt
The firm solves (8) and (10) with respect to Kt and Lt .
We can substitute Yt back in (8) and (10) and derive the equilibrium
interest rates and wages:
Yt
rt = α −δ (12)
Kt
Yt
wt = ( 1 − α ) (13)
Lt
0<β≤1 (15)
Ct is the level of consumption; Lt is the amount of time worked;
(1 − Lt ) is the amount of leisure time; β is the intertemporal discount
factor;
Ester Faia (Goethe University Frankfurt) RBC Fundamentals of Macro, WS 2021/22 11
The Baseline RBC Model
The Household (con’t)
The lower is β, the less future consumption and leisure are valued
with respect to present ones.
The utility function is assumed to be strictly concave in both
arguments:
Bt
lim t
≥0 (17)
t →∞
∏ (1 + rj )
j =0
∑t∞=0 βt (u (Ct , 1 − Lt )
L = E0 (18)
−λt +1 [(1 + rt +1 ) (Bt + wt Lt − Ct ) − Bt +1 ])
u1,t = (1 + rt +1 ) λt +1 (23)
λt = β (1 + rt +1 ) λt +1 (24)
First we substitute (23) in (24):
λt = βu1,t (25)
λt +1 = βu1,t +1 (26)
(27) is the Euler equation for consumption, which has also the
following interpretation:
u1,t
= 1 + rt +1 (28)
βu1,t +1
u2,t = wt (1 + rt +1 ) λt +1 (31)
λt = β (1 + rt +1 ) λt +1 (32)
First we substitute (31) in (32):
u2,t
λt = β (33)
wt
Update one period:
u2,t +1
λ t +1 = β (34)
wt + 1
Finally, substitute (33) and (34) back in (32):
u2,t u2,t +1
= β (1 + rt +1 ) (35)
wt wt + 1
Ester Faia (Goethe University Frankfurt) RBC Fundamentals of Macro, WS 2021/22 17
The Baseline RBC Model
The Household: Intertemporal substitution in labor supply
u (Ct , 1 − Lt ) = ln Ct − b ln (1 − Lt ) (40)
b>0
Therefore:
1 b
u1,t = ; u2,t = (41)
Ct 1 − Lt
The Euler equation for consumption:
u1,t Ct + 1
= = 1 + rt +1 (42)
βu1,t +1 βCt
βu2,t +1 1 − Lt 1 wt +1
= = (43)
u2,t 1 − Lt +1 β (1 + rt +1 ) wt
which becomes:
Ct wt
= (45)
1 − Lt b
When the salary goes up: income increases and the household can
consume more (income effect). On the others side it is more costly to
increase leisure as the opportunity cost, wt , has increased (hence to
reduce labour)
∑t∞=0 βt (u (Ct , 1 − Lt )
L = E0 (46)
+λt +1 [(1 + rt +1 ) (Bt + wt Lt − Ct ) − Bt +1 ])
Now suppose that cov 1 + rt +1, Ct1+1 < 0