Benefit-Cost Analysis and Risk
Benefit-Cost Analysis and Risk
Scott Farrow
Abstract
Motivated by the US Government context with particular attention to the Department of
Homeland Security, this chapter presents issues in meta-model choice and the implementation of
risk empirics for benefit-cost analysis. Many of the meta-methods considered rise from a shared
economic framework but with altered preference or aggregation assumptions. With different
assumptions come different measures and values. The methods evaluated include those of
impact statements akin to Environmental Impact Statements, Economic Impact or Consequence
analyses, standard and advanced decision analysis, and standard and advanced benefit-cost
analysis. If benefit-cost is selected as an appropriate modeling framework, then numerous
subsidiary issues exist and are discussed concerning the conceptualization and implementation of
risk metrics.
Acknowledgments: The author thanks Center on the Risk and Economic Analysis of Terrorism
Events at the University of Southern California for funding and participants at the benefit-cost
workshop at the Toulouse School of Economics for comments. Several people provided the
impetus for this study in including Ali Abbas and Debra Elkins.
1
Introduction
Many government organizations seek risk informed decisions. Evaluating and managing risk is
clearly central to the mission of some agencies such as the Environmental Protection Agency
(EPA) or the Department of Homeland Security (DHS) while risk lurks behind the issues and
mission of other agencies such as the financial viability of Medicare or the management of
offshore oil and gas resources. However, the risk assessment community has tended to separate
itself from management issues by attempting to draw a line between the “scientific” aspects of
Managers however, request analytical metrics to inform their decisions which often aggregate,
weight or transform multiple risk metrics from their natural units such a probability and
The choice of analytical metrics--the raw quantity of risk information, ranked risks, “rational” or
“behavioral” utility metrics, monetized risks, pain indices or others measures--are either
explicitly or implicitly framed by a model. Such models may be “mental” and reside within a
decision-maker or explicitly incorporate a formal structure for decision-making with risk. Each
This chapter first compares alternative risk metrics on the basis of their assumptions. No criteria
are used to select a “best” metric (although some biases may appear). The initial sections of this
chapter extend the concept of “meta-choice” analysis (Vining and Boardman, 2006). Those
authors argued that different types of analysis can be characterized along the two dimensions of
2
goal choice and monetization. Meta-choice analysis in their framework then consists of
matching the desired type of analysis with the analytical purpose. This chapter focuses on the
meta-analytic choices surrounding risk. Later sections focus on one type of analysis, benefit-cost
analysis, and more detailed analytic choices to be made about risk for that particular model. The
decision-making context is made more specific by focusing on the US Federal Government and
Guidance or requirements for risk informed decisions appear in numerous sources for the US
Government. Preeminent are laws passed by Congress. Some laws direct that risk in a particular
context be managed to a specific level, for example by requiring flood insurance for all within a
100 year flood plain for those with certain types of mortgages. Other laws may limit the
application of some metrics to inform risk, such as directing EPA to protect the health of
sensitive populations with an adequate margin of safety and to ignore cost in the development of
regulations which have the force of law. Other legislation requires agencies to consider benefits
In the absence of clear and direct guidance from Congress, the Executive Office of the President
provides guidelines for agencies managing risk. One recent guideline is the inclusion of
Enterprise Risk Management (ERM) elements in agency annual budget submissions (OMB, A-
11, 2014). This new task in budget preparation can be carried out using methods tailored to each
agency but states that one of the purposes of such analysis is to “Facilitate identification and
3
adoption of opportunities for improvement, including risk management” (OMB, A-11, 2014,
section 270.9). In the context of environmental, health and safety risks, OMB provides
additional guidance while noting that the guidance may also be relevant to other fields (OMB,
2007).
It is useful to consider whether the DHS risk context considered in this chapter falls within the
environmental, health, and safety (ERS) context? Might risks in the DHS domain such as
Might concern about terrorist attacks on people and the built environment be considered safety
and environmental? Less obvious might be issues about immigration or customs which has some
element of health and safety but other objectives as well. A restricted interpretation of DHS
activities might result in only some activities lying specifically within the EHS context. A
broader interpretation, including the OMB suggestion that the guidance may be relevant to other
fields, could permit the broader interpretation that the OMB risk guidance is relevant to DHS.
What do OMB’s risk principles state about risk management? The two management principles
distribution of the risks and the benefits and costs (both direct and indirect,
1
Text in italics is a restatement of 1995 principles, while plain type is the 2007 revision which highlights additional
guidance for regulatory purposes.
4
implementation of risk management strategies. Reasonably feasible risk
employ the best available scientific, economic and policy analysis, and such
Agencies should refer to Circular A-4 for updated guidance regarding agency
seek to offer the greatest net improvement in total societal welfare, accounting
distribution of benefits and costs (both direct and indirect, both quantifiable
and non-quantifiable).
Agencies should refer to Circular A-4 for updated guidance regarding agency
Risk management, as guided by OMB, focuses on risk, benefits and costs (although not all
interpret this to mean benefit-cost analysis as practiced by economists). Further, the objective is
the greatest net improvement in total societal welfare considered in as broad terms as possible.
and separately on benefit-cost analysis and discounting (OMB, A-94) but the risk guidance is not
5
uniquely focused on regulation, in fact, it specifically calls for non-regulatory approaches such as
DHS’ many components could be said to be focused on risk and the agency itself was a creation
of Congress shortly after the 9/11 terrorist attacks. DHS is charged with managing a wide range
of natural and human caused risks including those relevant to the Coast Guard, the Federal
DHS has regularly prepared risk assessments on an agency wide basis every four years and
numerous assessments on various combinations of risks. A strategic planning and risk office
exists within the office of policy as do other offices which support DHS wide efforts at risk
analysis.
6
Collectively, these external and internal risks have the potential to cause
Consider the problem faced in trying to synthesize risks across the many components of DHS.
In public documents, DHS has recognized 23 types of strategic risk they seek to manage as
presented in Table 1 (DHS, 2011)2. They have also stated in the Strategic National Risk
Assessment that they are concerned about numerous kinds of consequences falling into six
categories of:
1. loss of life,
4. social displacement,
6. environmental impact
2
DHS clearly does not consider this list exhaustive as they state in the same source: “Additional threats and
hazards, such as droughts, heat waves, winter storms, rain storms, and different types of
technological/accidental or human-caused hazards, can also pose a risk to jurisdictions across the country and
should be considered, as appropriate, in preparedness planning. Non-influenza diseases with pandemic
potential and other animal diseases should also be considered. In addition, assessment participants identified a
number of events for possible inclusion in future iterations of the SNRA, including electric grid failure, plant
disease outbreak, and transportation system failure.” (DHS, 2011)
7
while recognizing other or more detailed consequences in other settings (DHS, 2011). To no
Table 1 DHS Threat and Hazard Types: National Strategic Risk Assessment
Threat/Hazard Type
Animal Aircraft as a
Earthquake
Disease Armed
WeaponAssault
Flood
Outbreak Biological
Human Chemical/Biolo
Terrorism
Hurricane
Pandemic Chemical
gical Food
Attack (non-
Space Weather
Outbreak Cyber
food) Attack
Terrorism
Contamination
Tsunami Cyber
against
Attack Attack
Data
(non-
Terrorism
Volcanic Explosives
against
food)
Attack
Eruption Terrorism
Physical
Wildfire Dam Failure
Attack
Infrastructure
Biological Radiological
Chemical
Food Nuclear
Substance
Substance
ContaminatSpill Radiological
Terrorism
Release
Source: DHS, 2011. or
ionRelease Terrorism
Attack
Attack
This context of a variety of risks, consequences and decision-makers will be used to make
specific some of the general implications of choosing different risk models and risk metrics.
8
Risk Management Models and Metrics
In this section, models are distinguished from metrics although some models will be uniquely
associated with some metrics. This approach complements that taken by Vining and Boardman
(2006) who distinguished among models based on their selection of goals (economic efficiency
or not) and monetization (or not) of impacts. That two way breakdown was determined to be too
aggregate for the purposes of this chapter and importantly, Vining and Boardman did not
Models as abstractions from reality are commonly used to inform decision-makers concerned
with risks. Such models occur at least in the political science, public policy, risk analysis,
The models chosen here are not from a comprehensive review of the literature but based on
experience in cross agency practices and academic experience in engineering, public policy, and
economics. Other researchers may wish to add additional models. The models considered here
are:
(CEQ, 2005),
9
“Standard” Decision Analysis as exemplified by expected utility or an expected outcome
analysis (Keeney and Raiffa, 1976; Clemen and Reilley, 2001; Haimes, 2005).
(Keeney and Raiffa, 1976; Clemen and Reilley, 2001; Haimes, 2005),
Cost Effectiveness Analysis as exemplified by the least cost to achieve a stated objective
While the lines between some of the analyses can be blurred, the attempt below is to identify
those assumptions, as standardly used, which distinguish the risk management alternative
framings.
Each model is built from conceptual assumptions, implemented with data and quantitative
procedures, and result in one or more performance measures. The performance measures may
integrate several elements, such as expected net present value which aggregates outcomes over
time and reports the probabilistically weighted average, the expected value. The purpose of this
section is to set out the assumptions that distinguish the several models and the standard
10
performance measures. Characteristics of various models as identified by the author are set out
in Appendix Table 1.
Areas in which the models were consistent as generally applied (exceptions may always exist),
included:
The distinguishing characteristics among the models, some of which are bundled together in the
discussion to follow for ease of presentation, are: a) whose preferences are being modeled, b)
the goal and associated metric, c) the method of aggregation, including weights if relevant, and
d) risk measures and preferences. Each is discussed briefly below with a focus on those models
1. Whose ultimate preferences are modeled? This assumption distinguishes most forms of
decision analysis from benefit-cost analysis. In decision analysis, the analyst is typically
modeling the preferences of one or a few people who are generally considered to be
benefit-cost analysis models the preferences of those in society who have standing. The
question of whose preferences are being modeled is ambiguous for a NEPA type impact
analysis.
2. The goal and associated metrics. The goal or objective function of some model types is
clear while others are more ambiguous. A NEPA type analysis has no unifying objective
11
function and reports metrics in their natural units (illnesses, crimes, health outcomes,
dollars). Impact analysis typically reports Gross Domestic Product but also dimensions
monetary or utility measures for the outcomes with the goal the maximization of the
common metric. The outcomes may be decomposed into attributes. Benefit-cost analysis
aspires to use surplus measures (measures of value taking into account different valuation
for the infra-marginal units) but standard benefit-cost analysis typically applies an
average value which may or may not be based on concepts of surplus. The goal is to
maximize total surplus (net benefits) which economists define as (economic) efficiency.
Advanced benefit-cost analyses often take into account measures of surplus possibly
descriptive or other statistics used, the expected value of the preferred measure is
3. Method of aggregation, including aggregation weights: There are often two dimensions
exist or 2) aggregating across individuals. Here the assumption is that social impacts,
broadly based, are the object of estimation in contrast to impacts on a select group such
individual impacts such as new jobs are typically aggregated equally across individuals
for impacts in a particular category but no attempt is made to aggregate across impact
analyses, are defined in monetary terms and typically aggregate equally within and across
12
economic impact categories. With decision analysis, numerous means exist to develop
weights to aggregate impacts for one individual but the standard application is without
reported but are seldom interpreted to represent the aggregate of society. An exception is
the aggregation of expected monetary values which may be little distinguished from a
monetary values to aggregate both for an individual and across individuals. The latter
typically assumes an equal social and individual value per incremental dollar to each
impacts to different groups in the aggregation process, often though not necessarily based
simultaneously for societal preferences across the different groups and for individual
4. Risk Preferences: Risk preferences are here taken to be any of risk neutral, risk loving,
risk averse, or some behavioral risk approach (Eeckhoudt et al., 2005). Such preferences
can be revealed at two stages of an analysis. The first are the risk preferences of
individuals and the second are the risk preferences in any social aggregation. Impact
analysis typically ignores such risk preferences. Some advanced types of economic
consequences analysis may include some behavioral risk effect, but the majority of
economic impact analyses assume a risk neutral approach on the part of both individuals
and in the aggregation process. Consequently the standard risk metric is an expected
value impact, often an expenditure or income. Basic decision analysis often assumes
13
risk neutrality by analyzing the expected value of a decision. Advanced decision
analyses can consider alternative risk preferences as measured by utility, and then may
analysis is carried out in the world of certainty for individual outcomes and the
aggregation of individual values is based on the risk neutrality, or expected value, of both
may take into account risk preferences in assessing the valuation of individuals, and then
typically although not necessarily present the expected value of such valuations (Arrow
An assumption which tends to but need not vary across model types includes the treatment of
impacts in different time period which is usually aggregated into a present value metric by
analyses.
These common and disparate dimensions among the models extends the two way monetization
and goal dimensions of Vining and Boardman (2006). The Vining and Boardman choice
problem is graphed is Figure 1 where various choices in the logic model, starting on the left, lead
the analyst to a chosen model on the right hand side and its associated metric. For example, the
sequence of the goal of efficiency and monetization leads to benefit-cost and net present value.
14
Figure 1: Meta-choice logic model of Vining and Boardman
Model choices involving aggregation and weighting refine the Vining and Boardman meta-
analysis. As the left hand side of Figure1 remains the same, Figure 2 highlights additional
choices beyond monetization which lead to finer characterization among the models.
15
Figure 2: Extended meta-choice including aggregation and risk preferences
The distinction among models can be investigated in greater detail should one desire. For
instance, Adler (2012) has developed a related sequence, reproduced as Figure 3, for standard
and non-standard methods of aggregation based on which of several axioms are met by social
welfare functions. The “tree” sequence however is not unique in the sense that some re-ordering
16
Figure 3: Axioms and social welfare functions
This section investigates the specific ways in which risk and uncertainty affect the choice of
issues are briefly highlighted from above focusing on benefit-cost analysis and while more
17
Risk and BCA
Risk appears in numerous guises in the design and implementation of a benefit-cost analysis
(Farrow and Viscusi, 2011). Risk is here interpreted broadly to include both known and
unknown statistical distributions and the several ways these concepts reveal themselves in
assumptions about metrics to be used and model specification. For instance, an incorrectly
applied constraint that cross price elasticities are zero among some markets introduces a kind
This section separates levels of benefit-cost analysis into deterministic BCA (DBCA) as that
standardly used in practice and BCA incorporating risk (RBCA) as a more advanced
version3. As will be shown, numerous issues which may appear relevant only in an RBCA
First, define a standard DBCA, with Consumer Surplus (CS) and Producer Surplus (PS) as
and other symbols as standardly used. The DBCA objective function, which is to be
3
Standard assumptions for a DBCA are in Appendix 2, see also Boardman, et al. (2011).
18
A standard RBCA objective function is defined as below where πi is probability (here
assumed constant over time, although this is not necessary), D(t) is a discount function, CSR,
PSR and ER are measures which may include risk adjusted values and εit is an additive error
Each of these terms and more that are implicit will be discussed for the way in which risk
affects their definition or measurement. The discussions will be arbitrarily divided into the
following categories:
Metrics, addressing issues of decision criteria and risk based preferences including
discounting
random error.
The first part of this chapter discussed the meta-choices between major classes of decision-
support models. Within a given analytical choice, such as benefit-cost analysis, there remain
19
several large specification or framing issues for the analysis. A “wrong” assumption on these
issues can create modeling error, or in statistical terms, impose a constraint or degenerate
distribution on the analysis. While assumptions are central to abstraction, they also introduce
specification risk to the extent they are incorrect. Standard macro level framing specification
General versus partial equilibrium: This choices defines the scope of the terms in the
general or partial equilibrium setting (Florio, 2013; Goulder and Williams, 2003).
carries out a general equilibrium analysis the functional specifications and parameters
may not be accurate; the difficult question is which is relatively more accurate compared
Aggregation across economic actors: This choice defines the weighting of impacts in the
equal and independent social weighting for each individual. This can be explained as
equal social weighting and equal marginal utility of income for all participants; or if one
assumes diminishing marginal utility of income, then equal weighting assumes society
more heavily weights impacts on the wealthy (Nyborg, 2012). The most frequent
income or other identified populations (e.g. Loomis, 2013). Other weighting approaches
can but seldom do include interdependent weights. A specification risk occurs with any
20
Metrics
Performance metrics for benefit-cost analysis are generally inferred from criteria for
optimization. The standard optimization problems involve a single social welfare optimizer and
implicitly or explicitly includes the aggregation function (social welfare function) and the risk
optimal solution being the largest present value of net benefits among mutually exclusive
alternative considered. Several variations of this problem exist although often ignored in
practice (Bellinger, 2007). One variation is when the scale of the project can be chosen
such that some benefits and costs vary with scale. In that case the decision criteria
equates the marginal (social) benefit with the marginal social cost or, if there is a budget
constraint, the net marginal benefits may be required to exceed a threshold when there are
multiple projects. Few organizations are without budget constraints which can lead to a
decision metric requiring that a critical ratio be exceeded, in this case the ratio of benefits
to costs must exceed a threshold (Weinstein and Zeckhauser, 1973; Bellinger, 2007).
performance metric based on equation 2. The standard approach is that a social decision-
maker who can pool risk across many projects will choose to maximize the expected net
present value (Arrow and Lind, 1970) as given by equation 2, either omitting the error
term or assuming that its expectation is zero. This metric may be used whether or not
21
risk based valuation has been used for the component measures, such as consumer or
option or level of stringency implies that a decision-maker will use their own risk
preferences, however created, to make a selection which may not be based on expected
value. Concern for dynamic uncertainty when there are irreversible commitments, as
with unknown prices but fixed long term investment, leads to decision criteria in which
there is a value of information which may be informed by waiting. The standard model
in such settings is stochastic, expected value optimization in which net benefits may need
to exceed a positive threshold, the option value of waiting, in order to take action (Dixit
Preferences and resulting behavioral responses are the core of benefit-cost analysis. The
monetized meta-choice implied in benefit-cost analysis means that values, sometimes revealed
through choices or surveys, are measured in monetary terms. The literature on the monetization
of values implicit in choices is vast, some of it under topics such as welfare economics (e.g. Just
et al., 2008) or benefit-cost analysis (Zerbe, 2008). Preferences and behavioral responses may be
modeled as rational, often using an expected utility approach (Boardman, et al., 2011). Much
expected utility approach where responses may be consistent but not be rational (Machina, 1987;
DellaVigna, 2009). Risk preferences can provide an important distinction between DBCA and
22
RBCA. In RBCA and its associated equation 2, consumer preferences are frequently modeled as
risk averse whereby some adjustment to expected cost or benefit is added to the valuation for a
consumer (or producer). While some functional forms are commonly used, there is little
agreement on the appropriate model and empirical parameters of risk for a consumer (Eeckhoudt
et al., 2005). At the same time, for some problems, risk based preference adjustment may or may
not be empirically significant (Farrow, 2014). Although the estimation and monetization of risk
preferences is a research frontier, advances in valuation have led to relatively standard values for
a statistical life in benefit-cost analyses as well as for other risk based outcomes (Boardman, et
al., 2011).
Preferences over time is a long standing dimension of concern. A declining exponential weight
on values in the future (discounted values) has long been standard but behavioral economics and
concern for uncertainty is altering that consensus. Behavioral economic studies have found that
people may overweight (relative to exponential discounting) the near term and also the distant
future (DellaVigna, 2009). Further, debate remains about the impact of incorporating
uncertainty into discount factors although a typical result with uncertainty is that the future is
discounted less than with exponential discounting (Arrow, et al., 2013; Gollier, 2012).
Variability in impacts and valuations are one source of risk in the outcome metric. For instance,
an unconditional mean value for an impact may ignore predictable conditionality of the mean on
socio-economic and other conditioning factors. This is discussed in the literature as the
23
usefulness of a benefit transfer function, which includes adjustments for varying conditions,
instead of an unconditional value (Boyle, et al., 2010). Similarly, if impacts are estimated
separately from values then the impacts may depend on various conditioning factors, such as
The impact of stochastic randomness or pure error in an RBCA appears in several ways.
Models for components of equation 2 are often build from parameterized models and sometimes
from regression coefficients. Perhaps clearest in the case of regression coefficients, those
coefficients have a statistical distribution based on the random error in the underlying estimation
equation. Such randomness can be included in Monte Carlo type analyses and adds risk to the
outcome measure even if the distribution is symmetric about its mean.
Seldom considered in an RBCA is the degree of model fit associated with a stochastic error term
which may be added as noted in equation 2. For instance, homeland security models may have a
larger random error component that a flood model. Such added variability is a component of the
24
risk of the dependent metric. When Monte Carlo simulation methods are used, analysts may be
able to include a measure of the pure error term in the RBCA if they are willing to place an
estimate on the accuracy of the model (Farrow, 2012).
Conclusion
This chapter emphasizes the ubiquity of risk in benefit-cost modeling. The meta-choice of
benefit-cost analysis itself implies a set of framing assumptions. It is useful to understand the
distinctions between the several major types of descriptive and prescriptive analyses used to
inform homeland security decisions. The model choice can introduce specification error. If a
benefit-cost analysis is chosen as the appropriate analysis, then risk, associated with variability in
outcomes, affects numerous components of the analysis. The analyst must choose whether or not
to: a) use a partial or general equilibrium setting, b) deviate from standard aggregation and
constraint assumptions, c) include conditioning factors which may shift impacts or values, c)
probability distributions, and f) incorporate the accuracy of the model itself in the variability of
the outcome. Taking all these elements into consideration in detail may lead to the paralysis of
analysis. The challenge to analysts is to incorporate those risk considerations that are central to
25
Appendix Table 1: Models and Assumptions
Assumptions Impact “Std” Advanced Std Benefit- Advanced Econ. Cost-Effect. Other models,
Analysis Decision Decision Cost Benefit-Cost Consequence Analysis Notes
Analysis Analysis Analysis Analysis Analysis
(eg
MCMA)
Who has Citizens or Citizens or Citizens Citizens or as Citizens or as Citizens or as Citizens or as
standing as otherwise as otherwise or as otherwise otherwise otherwise otherwise
defined defined otherwise defined defined defined defined
defined
Whose Not Decision- Decision- Society Society Not specified Society
preferences specified maker (s) maker (s)
DM
Aggregate Adding up None None or Equal weight Unequal weight Adding up of Equal weight
preferences of natural Some SWF SWF dollar impacts SWF (including
units; group with other quantity
impact may approach dimensions as outcome)
be mental model
distributiona
l info.
Weights None DM or DM “crowd dollar “crowd dollar Dollar Mixture dollar
crowd dollar weighted weighted” , weighted”, weighted by weighted and
weighted surplus surplus; price DM or expert
subjective weighted
distributional
Independent or Independent Independent Independe Independent Independent Independent Independent Taking account of
interdependent nt system risk or
personal interdependent
preferences preferences
Extent of None Limited Usually Usually Usually limited Often large, Usually limited
economic Limited limited but but can be large General Eq. but can be large
interaction but could can be large
across markets be large
Time Unlikely to Constant Constant Discounting Constant or Some static,
discount discounting or no (constant) Variable some
or no discount discounting dynamics/resili
discounting ency
26
Assumptions Impact “Std” Advanced Std Benefit- Advanced Econ. Cost-Effect. Other models,
Analysis Decision Decision Cost Benefit-Cost Consequence Analysis Notes
Analysis Analysis Analysis Analysis Analysis
(eg
MCMA)
Risk Analysis Impacts in Expected Weighted Monetized Risk preference Impacts in ESPV cost per Movement toward
metric (s) natural units Value cardinal social adjusted ESNPV monetary units unit (issue with estimation of
utility, expected net valued at price multiple statistical
non- present value outcomes) distribution of
expected ESNPV outcomes
utility
Risk Not Risk neutral Risk Risk Neutral Risk pref. of Risk neutral Usually risk Can apply to all of
preference specified or risk neutral or consumers or neutral consumers,
values of risk values firm producers, DM
DM of DM
Objective Not Max EV or Max EU Max expected Max risk Max expected Min Cost
(implicit or specified EU (or non Total surplus adjusted total dollar value,
explicit) EU surplus such as GDP
approache
s)
Risk Decision Decision- Choose Highest Choose Choose largest GDP and Choose least
rules maker or highest EV, expected largest sum of sum of “surplus possibly other cost (benefit
stakeholders EU utility “surplus” as as EV; possible dimensions assumed)
apply EV. to let decision-
mental maker choose
model to
aggregate
Social welfare Not None None Additive, Additive, Additive, Least cost of
function specified unweighted weighted unweighted reaching given
objective (or
most output for
given budget)
Green: all models tend but need not be consistent (for instance, all could apply standing to the same group of people).
Yellow: models vary relatively consistently across model types
Gray: models tend to but need not make different assumptions.
27
Appendix Table 2: Assumptions for deterministic (standard) benefit-cost analysis
Based on the first and second theorems of welfare economics being correct: 1) A PC society will be Pareto Optimal, 2) PO point is not unique.
Topic Assumptions
Consumer preferences and “Rational”
optimum Complete ordering
Transitive
Continuous
Non-satiation
Individual (no inter-personal
utility)
Max utility subject to budget
constraint
Firm optimum Given production function
Input prices
Output price
Max profit
Government activity Responds to market failures
including public goods; access
to either lump sum or optimal
taxation
Nature of goods or services Homogenous goods, no
externalities (see 2nd best), no
taxation that distorts markets.
Market equilibrium Perfectly competitive equi. In all
input and output markets
Time Discount at a constant rate
Risk Standard: none
Advanced: numerous concerns
for risk
28
Topic Assumptions
Scope of analysis (partial or Include those actions where
general equilibrium) dQi/DPj not equal to zero (could
lead to partial or GE analysis)
Social welfare function Additive in individual utility
dW/dUi = a (constant and
uniform)
dUi/dYi= b (marginal utility of
income a constant and uniform)
dUi/dUj = 0, no interpersonal
utility
29
References
Adler, M., Well Being and Fair Distribution, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 2012.
Arrow, K. and R. Lind, Uncertainty and the Evaluation of Public Investment Decisions,
Arrow, et al., Determining Benefits and Costs for Future Generations, Science, 341(6144):349-
Bellinger, W., The Economic Analysis of Public Policy, Routledge, New York. 2007.
Boardman, A., D. Greenberg, A. Vining and D. Weimer, Cost-Benefit Analysis, 4th ed., Prentice
Hall, 2011.
Boyle, K., N. Kuminoff, C. Parmeter and J. Pope, The Benefit-Transfer Challenge, Annual
Chetty, R., Sufficient Statistics for Welfare Analysis: A Bridge Between Structural and Reduced
Clemen, R.T. and Reilley, T., Making Hard Decisions. Belmont CA: Duxbury Press, 2001.
Elements of the National Environmental Policy Act.,40 CFR Parts 1500-1508, 2005.
DellaVigna, S., Psychology and Economics: Evidence from the Field, Journal of Economic
Dixit, A. and R. Pindyck, Investment Under Uncertainty, Princeton University Press, Princeton,
1994.
30
Dreze, J. and Stern, N., The Theory of Cost-Benefit Analysis, Chapter 14 in Auerbach, A.J. and
Eeckhoudt, L., C. Gollier, and H. Schlesinger, Economic and Financial Decisions Under Risk,
Farrow, S., The Economics of Homeland Security Expenditures: Foundational Expected Cost-
Farrow, S. and W. K. Viscusi, Principles and Standards for the Benefit-Cost Analysis of Safety,
Farrow, S. and R. Zerbe, Principles and Standards for Benefit-Cost Analysis. Edward Elgar,
Farrow, S., A Missing Error Term in Benefit-Cost Analysis, Environmental Science and
Farrow, S., A Comparison of Key Benefit Estimation Issues for Natural Hazards and Terrorism:
Security Focused Regulations, ed. C. Mansfield and V.K. Smith. Edward Elgar,
Cheltenham, 2014.
Florio, M., Applied Welfare Economics: Cost-Benefit Analysis of Projects and Policies,
Routledge, 2014.)
Gollier, C., Pricing the Planet’s Future: the Economics of Discounting in an Uncertain World,
31
Goulder, L. and R. Williams, The Substantial Bias from Ignoring General Equilibrium Effects in
111(4):898-927, 2003.
Just, R., D. Hueth and A. Schmitz, eds. Applied Welfare Economics, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham,
2008.
Keeney, R. L., & Raiffa, H. (1976). Decision making with multiple objectives preferences and
Standards for Benefit-Cost Analysis, ed. S. Farrow and R. Zerbe. Edward Elgar, 2012.
Mueller, J. and M. Stewart, Terror, Security and Money: Balancing the Risks, Benefits and Costs
Nyborg, K. (2012). The Ethics and Politics of Environmental Cost-Benefit Analysis. Routledge.
Office of Management and Budget (OMB), Principles for Risk Assessment. Washington, 2007.
Office of Management and Budget (OMB), Circulars A-94, A-4, A-11, Washington, 2013, 2014.
Policies and Rules”, in The Benefit-Cost Analysis of Security Focused Regulations, ed. C.
32
US Department of Homeland Security (DHS), Risk Management Fundamentals, Washington,
fundamentals.pdf .
Weinstein, M. and R. Zeckhauser, “Critical Ratios and Efficient Allocation”, Journal of Public
Zerbe, R., Jr., ed. Benefit-Cost Analysis, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, 2008.
33