BRIASSOULIS 2003 - PI For Complex Problems
BRIASSOULIS 2003 - PI For Complex Problems
by
Abstract
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
Research reported in this paper was undertaken in the context of the EC-DG XII funded
research project MEDACTION (Policies for land use to combat desertification; Contract No.:
ENVK2-CT-2000-00085). A more extensive treatment of the issues tackled in this paper is
offered in Chapters 1 and 2 of the book: “Policy Integration for Complex Environmental
Problems; The Example of Mediterranean Desertification”, H. Briassoulis (editor), Ashgate
Publishing (forthcoming, May 2005).
Paper presented at the 2004 Berlin Conference “Greening of Policies: Interlinkages and Policy Integration”
Berlin, December 3-4, 2004.
1
POLICY INTEGRATION FOR COMPLEX POLICY PROBLEMS:
WHAT, WHY AND HOW
The rest of this section sketches briefly the changing context of policy making and the
quest for sustainable development that generates the need for PI, presents the
distinguishing characteristics of contemporary socio-environmental problems,
drawing on complexity and institutionalist thinking, and offers a brief account of
desertification and of the associated policy needs. The second section explores the
‘what’ and ‘why’ of PI; it provides a conceptual examination of the notion of PI,
proposes a particular conceptualization of PI and argues for its suitability in handling
complex policy problems especially at higher spatial/organizational levels such as the
EU. The third section addresses the ‘how’ of PI; it suggests a methodological
framework to analyze PI comprehensively and to serve as a basis for the development
of policy integration schemes. The last section offers preliminary ideas for the design
of PI schemes and suggests future research directions.
1.1. The changing context of policy making and the quest for sustainable
development
In the EU, the process of European integration and the Europeanization of several
policy areas have spurred decentralization and devolution of decision making power
to lower levels of government (Liefferink and Jordan, 2002) thus augmenting the
institutional complexity of contemporary policy problems as well as the territorial and
temporal reach of policy interventions. The state-centric, hierarchical model of
governance is being replaced by multi-level forms of governance (Marks et al., 1996;
Hooghe and Marks, 2001) where decision making authority and influence are shared
across multiple levels. Solutions to problems are devised and implemented in the
context of polycentric, highly complex and interdependent networks of formal and
informal actors, procedures and instruments, increasing accordingly the need for co-
ordination, development of horizontal cooperative structures, and participatory and
joint development and use of public intervention instruments (Hajer, 2003).
Finally, resources utilized in regional and sub-regional planning to address the needs
of specific client groups and lagging regions or to promote regional sustainable
development more generally originate in numerous policies and administering
organizations1. This requires that policies be organized not on the basis of function, as
it has been historically the case, but on the basis of client groups or of particular
regions (Peters, 1998; Hakkinen, 1999; Gibbs et al., 2003; Moss, 2004).
On the supply side, the nature of public policy making and the current performance of
the institutional and administrative apparatuses in the context of multi-level
governance do not appear to serve satisfactorily the demand identified before. For one
thing, policies are ‘moving targets’ (Wittrock and de Leon, 1986). They are not
discrete, disembodied events occurring in isolation from one another. On the contrary,
policy decisions and their impacts are interlocked making it increasingly difficult for
one policy area to function independently of other areas (Greenberg et al., 1977).
1
Such as regulations, economic instruments, and financial incentives.
Paper presented at the 2004 Berlin Conference “Greening of Policies: Interlinkages and Policy Integration”
Berlin, December 3-4, 2004.
3
Public policymaking follows diverse styles. Policy types differ from one area to the
other2 (Richardson, 1982; Vogel, 1986; Knill and Lenschow, 2000; Moss, 2003).
Historically, relatively autonomous policy sectors have dealt with policy issues,
leading to sectoral/functional specialization and vertical organization of
administration at both the EU and the national level (Avery, 2001; Robert et al., 2001;
Hertin and Berkhout, 2003; Zahariadis, 2003). The result is a well-documented,
general lack of coherence, coordination and cooperation among policies, generating
costs and inefficiencies, taxing limited government budgets and detracting from the
achievement of sustainable development (OECD, 1996a; O’ Riordan and Voisey,
1998; Peters, 1998; Persson, 2002; Shannon, 2002).
The diffusion of Complexity theory in the Natural, the Social and the Policy Sciences
since the 1980s has enriched greatly the study of contemporary socio-environmental
problems. A voluminous literature now documents the complexity of natural, social
systems and, more importantly, of human-environment systems, shedding light on
suitable policy making approaches to address them (Holling, 1986; Dryzek, 1987;
Waldrop, 1992; Berkes and Folke, 1998; Byrne, 1998; Marion, 1999; Levin, 1999;
Science, 1999; True et al., 1999; Zahariadis, 1999; Gunderson and Holling, 2002).
The dominant Newtonian-Cartesian, linear, equilibrium-centered view of nature and
society, that dissociates the environment from people, policies and politics, has not
been found to fit the evidence. Instead, complexity-informed, non-reductionist, co-
evolutionary, interdisciplinary, historical, and comparative systems approaches,
adopting integrative modes of inquiry and methodological pluralism, are more
suitable for studying these problems. The distinguishing characteristics of complex
systems that help comprehend and negotiate the complexity of socio-environmental
problems and its policy implications are briefly presented below.
2
Some being regulatory, others market-oriented, still others voluntary-sector oriented.
Paper presented at the 2004 Berlin Conference “Greening of Policies: Interlinkages and Policy Integration”
Berlin, December 3-4, 2004.
4
CAS are open systems whose boundaries are difficult to delineate precisely. They
comprise components, semi-autonomous, individual, self-interested agents3,
hierarchically nested (embedded) within larger aggregate systems4 (Berkes and Folke,
1998; Gibson et al., 1998; Levin, 1999; Gunderson and Holling, 2002). Agents, such
as, flora and fauna in ecosystems, individuals and organizations in social systems,
have different characteristics. Human agents5, in particular, have different socio-
economic features, viewpoints, preferences, goals, aspirations, emotions, possess
different amounts of resources6 (Detombe, 2001) and may belong to more than one
hierarchies (Manson, 2001) and groups. Thus, CAS possess an inherent variety and
flexibility that allow them to be creative, respond fast to unforeseeable events and to
try multiple options simultaneously to survive7 because functions and control are
decentralized, system components are linked in parallel through numerous, non-linear
feedbacks and their multiple memberships may generate redundancy and
contradictions but increase the strength and resilience of CAS to external and internal
shocks.
The connectivity of CAS, the particular ways in which agents connect and relate to
one another, is critical to their evolution and survival. The properties of CAS are
explained by an understanding of the relationships among their parts rather than by an
understanding of these parts separately (Gallagher and Appenzeller, 1999; Manson,
2001; Limburg et al., 2002). The non-linear nature of these relationships distinguishes
complex from simple, linear systems and defines their internal structure, behaviour
and mode of change (Manson, 2001).
Linear systems evolve smoothly and continuously towards a single equilibrium state.
Following a disturbance, negative feedback mechanisms bring linear systems back to
their initial equilibrium. On the contrary, non-linear systems possess multiple
equilibria, changing and co-evolving with their environment through self-organization
and adaptation to changing external conditions and “shocks”, a process based on
learning8 (Lee, 1993; Berkes and Folke, 1998; Manson, 2001; Wilson, 2002).
Following a large, external event or minor, random, and sometimes overtly
insignificant, changes, the transition to another state may be abrupt and discontinuous
as CAS spontaneously re-arrange, reorganize, redistribute and restructure their
components in different patterns, behaviour and structure to better interact with their
environment. This happens because mutually reinforcing, positive feedback
mechanisms amplify changes bringing the system to a new equilibrium state (Manson,
2001; Holling 1986, 2001)9.
3
Seeking to maximize some measure of goodness, or fitness, by evolving over time (Dooley, 1997).
4
Their characteristic hierarchical organization differs from top-down, serial, command-and-control
authoritative structures (Levin, 1999; Limburg et al., 2002).
5
Such as individuals, households, public and private formal and informal organizations, and resources
6
Money, know-how, power, etc.
7
For example, polycentric governance systems have proven less vulnerable to unexpected
contingencies than rigidly organized, centralized systems (Ostrom, 1990, 1998).
8
Through continuous exchanges of information with their environment (feedbacks), the system’s
agents are able to anticipate the results of their actions as well as to adapt to changing conditions.
9
The popularly known ‘butterfly effect’ (Gleick, 1994) signifies major changes precipitated by
amplification of an original minor disturbance.
Paper presented at the 2004 Berlin Conference “Greening of Policies: Interlinkages and Policy Integration”
Berlin, December 3-4, 2004.
5
among the multiple equilibria of a system (Holling 1978; Manson, 2001). Increasing
returns in economics (Arthur, 1989) explain several economic and spatial
phenomena10 and the path dependence of socio-economic and spatial development
(Anderson et al., 1988; Arthur et al., 1997), highlighting the contingent nature of their
evolution and the influence of the institutional settings within which they are
embedded (Liebowitz and Margolis, 1995; Henderson, 2001; Berkhout, 2002). Some
systems may be ‘locked in’ a particular state where change is irreversible (Arthur,
1989; Liebowitz and Margolis, 1995)11.
10
Such as technical standards (the "QWERTY" standard typewriter and computer keyboard), urban
sprawl and urban concentrations, clustering of economic activities, and so on.
11
For example, overgrazing or climate change can push (‘lock’) vegetated systems into a new stability
domain (desertification) that is reinforced by feedback loops that maintain high temperatures and low
water and nutrients (Limburg et al., 2002).
12
Their property of self-organized criticality means that they reach an equilibrium state that is not
stable but which is the most productive and creative, leading to new possibilities.
Paper presented at the 2004 Berlin Conference “Greening of Policies: Interlinkages and Policy Integration”
Berlin, December 3-4, 2004.
6
these problems ‘solved’; at best, they are ‘resolved’ (Patton and Sawicki, 1986) for
their ‘owners’ and over a finite time period.
13
Contemporary policy approaches gradually abandon the Newtonian-Cartesian, linear worldview and
espouse the complex, non-linear world model. The adoption of the precautionary principle, of learning-
based and strategic approaches and of the adaptive management paradigm, all signify the influence of
complexity-thinking in policy making (Wiman, 1991; Lee, 1993; Healey, 1997; Brown, 2000; Ascher,
2001; White, 2001).
14
I.e. generating environmental costs but not economic benefits (Berkes and Folke, 1998; Holling et
al,, 1998; Ascher, 2001).
15
I.e. changes in one policy area produced by changes in another area.
Paper presented at the 2004 Berlin Conference “Greening of Policies: Interlinkages and Policy Integration”
Berlin, December 3-4, 2004.
7
Desertification is an emergent phenomenon as it is a higher-level feature of the land
system, the cumulative outcome of numerous individual, local level inappropriate
land management practices induced by the intricate interplay of multi-scale
biophysical and societal forces that are mediated by a considerable number of formal
and informal nature-society institutions. Its occurrence is path-dependent, sensitive to
the initial conditions prevailing in particular spatio-temporal contexts. Once
unsustainable conditions set in an area, positive feedback mechanisms may intensify
degradation leading the land system to other equilibrium states. It is, thus, difficult to
disentangle its multi-scale biophysical and societal causes, predict its consequences
and reversibility and know with certainty whether and when an area will be ‘locked’
in an irreversibly desertified state.
Although interest in policy integration has a long history in several quarters, the
recent renaissance of the subject is associated mainly with the environmental
repercussions of economic activities that are not properly accounted for (if at all) by
sectoral policies; hence, the proliferation of policy activity and research on
environmental policy integration (EPI). In the European Union, Article 6 of the 1999
Amsterdam Treaty gave EPI its current political significance, constituting the official
statement for the integration of environmental concerns in sectoral policies:
“Environmental protection requirements must be integrated into the definition and
implementation of the Community policies and activities referred to in Article 3, in
particular with a view to promoting sustainable development” (Lenschow, 2002: 14).
Various policy developments aim to provide the necessary procedures to materialize
the injunction of Article 6. The focus on EPI has overshadowed, however, other
concerns. For example, in addition to environmental repercussions, sectoral policies
have spatial, social, cultural and other interdependent repercussions. Moreover,
16
Controversy centers on its causes and consequences. The problem is two-fold: “(a) whereas
desertification is most often attributed to a myriad of human activities, … it may be triggered or
exacerbated by climate variability, … so that the causes are not necessarily solely anthropogenic (at
least at the local land use level), (b) not all such ecological, biogeochemical and hydrological changes
have an immediate or direct economic impact on human activities” (Reynolds and Stafford-Smith,
2002b, 3)
Paper presented at the 2004 Berlin Conference “Greening of Policies: Interlinkages and Policy Integration”
Berlin, December 3-4, 2004.
8
neither environmental policies account adequately for their economic and social
impacts nor social policies account for their environmental and economic impacts.
The discourse on policy integration (PI) has met with the common problem of
confusion, loose (or no) definitions, differences in the meaning and multiple
interpretations (and mis-interpretations) of ‘policy’, ‘integration’ and ‘policy
integration’ in various policy contexts that lead to different operational expressions,
proposed designs, and so on. Proper and consistent analysis and design require,
however, clear definitions of ‘integration of what, by whom, where, when, why and
how’. Only then it can be judged how well PI facilitates the resolution of problems
and contributes to sustainable development.
The meaning of EPI and PI depend on how ‘policy’ and ‘integration’ are
conceptualized. According to Merriam-Webster’s Collegiate Dictionary, “integrate”
can mean either “to form, coordinate, or blend into a functioning or unified whole” or
“to unite with something else” or “to incorporate into a larger unit” (cited in
Persson, 2002, 9)17. Figure 118 schematically depicts the fine difference between
“blending into a unified whole” or “uniting with something else” and “incorporating
into a larger unit”.
Turning to the meaning of ‘policy’, public policies are defined as purposeful courses
of action, comprising a long series of more-or-less related activities, which
governments pursue to reach goals and objectives related to a problem or matter of
concern and to produce certain results (Friedrich, 1963; Lowi, 1964; Anderson, 1984;
Pressman and Wildavski, 1992). A policy is not a single, discrete, unitary,
disembodied phenomenon, but a series of decisions. It concerns what is actually done
(or not done) as opposed to what is proposed or intended, which is the case of
decisions; policy implementation and enforcement complete the actual policy process.
The main constituent elements of a policy are its object (the characteristics of the
problem considered and the theory about it), interested and/or involved actors, their
goals (reflecting their value systems), the available structures and procedures (for
formulation and implementation), and the instruments used to achieve the goals set.
17
The Oxford Combined Dictionary of Current English & Modern English Usage (1982, 129) leans
towards the latter interpretation (“To integrate is to combine components into a single congruous
whole”).
18
Inspired from Persson (2002).
Paper presented at the 2004 Berlin Conference “Greening of Policies: Interlinkages and Policy Integration”
Berlin, December 3-4, 2004.
9
Figure 1. The difference between unifying and incorporating parts
The OECD (1996a), focusing on the process side, defines EPI as: “Early co-
ordination between sector and environmental objectives, in order to find synergy
between the two or to set priorities for the environment, where necessary.” The
European Environment Agency sees EPI as a process of shifting the focus of
environmental policy away ‘from the environmental problems themselves to their
causes … [and] … from ‘end-of-pipe’ ministries to ‘driving force’ sector ministries’
(EEA, 1998, 283).
For Lafferty and Hovden (2002:15), EPI implies “(a) the incorporation of
environmental objectives into all stages of policy making in non-environmental policy
19
Lafferty and Hovden (2002) offer the integration of economic goals into several policies as an
example.
Paper presented at the 2004 Berlin Conference “Greening of Policies: Interlinkages and Policy Integration”
Berlin, December 3-4, 2004.
10
sectors, with a specific recognition of this goal as a guiding principle for the planning
and execution of a policy, (b) accompanied by an attempt to aggregate presumed
environmental consequences into an overall evaluation of policy, and a commitment
to minimize contradictions between environmental and sectoral policies by giving
principles priority to the former over the latter.”
Other authors (O’ Riordan and Voisey, 1998; Shannon, 2002; Hertin and Berkhout,
2003) emphasize the communicative dimension of EPI; intersectoral PI concerns
certain kinds of cooperative behaviour, forms of institutions, and kinds of
communicative action.
Finally, EEB (2003: 13, 14) offers a more holistic definition: “Environmental Policy
Integration is a long-term process that requires changes in administrative practice and
government culture, institutional adaptation and also specific tools… The integration
of environmental aspects into other policy areas must contribute to policies that
effectively lead us to higher environment protection and greater sustainability.”
To develop operational expressions for EPI and PI and measures to achieve them, it is
necessary to clarify (a) what should be integrated and (b) along which dimensions.
The answers are partly conditioned by the focus on PI as process, output or both, and
by the stage of the policy making process concerned. Two generic approaches to these
intertwined questions are suggested: the vertical/intrasectoral and the
horizontal/intersectoral (Lafferty and Hovden, 2002; Persson, 2002; Hertin and
Berkhout, 2003).
Vertical PI has a spatial dimension, which is mostly implicit in the literature, with
some exceptions to this author’s knowledge, so far (Buller, 2002; EEB, 2003). The
stages of the policy process span several spatial/organizational levels and different
actors are involved at each stage and level, influencing the ease and success of PI. At
higher levels, PI in terms of goals is easily achieved (Lenschow, 2002; Persson, 2002)
while getting formal and informal policy actors comply with ‘integrating’ procedures
and rules21 at lower levels proves difficult if not infeasible (O’ Riordan and Voisey,
20
Obviously, this may apply to any other kind of concerns such as social equity, gender equality, etc.
21
E.g. implement the EIA requirement.
Paper presented at the 2004 Berlin Conference “Greening of Policies: Interlinkages and Policy Integration”
Berlin, December 3-4, 2004.
11
1998). If linkages among the relevant spatial/organizational levels do not exist or are
not fully operational, the initial PI intentions never materialize on the ground.
The distinction between a vertical and a horizontal approach to EPI and PI is not
unambiguous or straightforward to make in practice (Persson, 2002). In the
perspective of promoting sustainable development, both approaches should be merged
through appropriate procedures for complete and effective PI extending beyond the
environmental field.
The preceding discussion suggests that PI is needed to hold the policy system
together, to overcome its tendencies towards disorder, and to manage the numerous
policy interconnections so that policy supply meets policy demand, supporting the
effective resolution of complex problems and the transition to sustainable
development. However, PI should be conceived and analyzed more broadly and
thoroughly along many more dimensions than it is currently the case.
Paper presented at the 2004 Berlin Conference “Greening of Policies: Interlinkages and Policy Integration”
Berlin, December 3-4, 2004.
12
It is proposed that PI should be construed as ‘integration of policies’, referring to a
process of sewing together and coordinating various policies, both over (horizontally)
and across (vertically) levels of governance, modifying them appropriately if
necessary, to create an interlocking, hierarchical, loosely-coupled, multi-level, policy
system that functions harmoniously in unity. The output of such an integration
process will be an integrated policy system aiming to achieve multiple
complementarities and synergies among policies. Although a perfectly integrated
policy system may be a utopian ideal, the more policies ‘talk to one another’ and the
right hand know what the left does, the more satisfactory will be the response of
policymaking to the demands of contemporary problems.
22
And, thus, reduce costs and waste of resources.
Paper presented at the 2004 Berlin Conference “Greening of Policies: Interlinkages and Policy Integration”
Berlin, December 3-4, 2004.
13
themselves; they are administered by specific administrative bodies, involve particular
policy actors and relate to other instruments23. It follows that essentially EPI
inevitably implies integration among policies in terms of their objects, goals, actors,
structures/procedures and instruments.
In analyzing the integration among two or more policies, the first question is “what
should be integrated”, i.e. the object of policy integration. PI can be approached from
a horizontal direction, on the same spatial/organizational level, and from a vertical
direction, across levels. The present discussion focuses on the horizontal direction
although a complete analysis should consider both directions.
23
E.g. environmental regulations cannot be properly enforced in the absence of financial instruments.
24
Starting from the definition of what constitutes a policy, the conceptualization of the policy process
and ending up with asking whether what is finally implemented on the ground bears any resemblance
to the policy as formulated and legislated (Sabatier 1999).
Paper presented at the 2004 Berlin Conference “Greening of Policies: Interlinkages and Policy Integration”
Berlin, December 3-4, 2004.
14
Figure 2. The object of policy integration
Relationships among policy objects. Two policies are integrated, or have chances of
being integrated, if they have common scope, treat common or complementary facets
(environmental, spatial, economic, social, institutional) of a problem situation in
congruent or unified manner25; or, equivalently, accommodate or respect variously
one another’s concerns about the social, economic, environmental, cultural and other
features of the issues studied26; i.e. frame environmental and other issues positively.
This implies that the policies draw on common or compatible and non-conflicting
theories and epistemological frameworks, reflecting common perceptions of the
problem and common outlooks of the actors involved, or adopt comprehensive,
interdisciplinary problem definitions and theories and define and operationalize
concepts similarly. Moreover, they most likely possess the same or compatible spatial
and temporal systems of reference and consider cross-scale integration (of global and
local issues).
The congruence of the theoretical and conceptual framings of two or more policies is
perhaps the necessary precondition and the sine qua non for their substantive, and not
only instrumental, sustainable integration.
Relationships among policy actors. Two or more policies are, or have chances of
being, integrated if they share common actors either by design27 or for reasons
unrelated to intentions to facilitate PI. Satisfactory PI among policies can be expected
if the relationships among actors are cooperative, collaborative, non-conflicting, and
non-adversarial in general, and if actors have shared values, common visions,
common goals and abide by the same rules even when these are not within their
organizational mandate (Shannon, 2002). This implies that the corresponding policy
25
Without, however, overlapping and duplicating one another.
26
I.e. rural development, regional development, etc.
27
Such as the integration correspondents, placed in each DG of the European Commission to liaise
with DG-Environment and ensure that environmental concerns are given proper account (Lenschow
2002), interministerial committees, special task forces, etc.
Paper presented at the 2004 Berlin Conference “Greening of Policies: Interlinkages and Policy Integration”
Berlin, December 3-4, 2004.
15
networks are somehow coordinated or intersect either spontaneously or by design. As
discussed below, formal rules of interaction among policy actors may be provided
even when PI is not a policy goal. Besides formal, institutionalised relationships,
however, several important relationships among formal and informal actors may be
informal, providing for inconspicuous routes towards PI even when this is not
required formally (Christiansen and Piattoni 2004).
Several relationships among actors, contributing or detracting from PI, emerge during
implementation where many more actors are activated, the stakes are clearer, and
winners and losers are identifiable (Pressman and Wildavsky 1992). This means that
even if PI is institutionalised at higher policy levels, it may break down during
implementation if formal and informal actors do not agree with the integration idea
and the related implementation arrangements.
When the objects of two or more policies exhibit commonalities it is likely that the
policies have common actors, with common interests and outlooks, established
tradition and lines of communication and collaboration, and a genuine interest in
some form PI (not necessarily generally approved and supported). If, however, actors
are closely tied to ‘favorite’ policies, PI efforts may founder (Shannon, 2002).
Use of integrative instruments is not necessarily an indication of PI. For example, the
requirement for EIA or SEA in transport or in regional policy complies more with the
notion of vertical, intrasectoral (EPI) rather than with the notion of horizontal,
30
The EU Water Framework Directive requires participation and cooperation of representatives from
all state agencies responsible for the various uses of water in drafting River Basin Management Plans.
Paper presented at the 2004 Berlin Conference “Greening of Policies: Interlinkages and Policy Integration”
Berlin, December 3-4, 2004.
17
intersectoral PI. Similarly, economic instruments are used with the purpose of
incorporating economic efficiency considerations in environmental policies and
creating markets for goods and services rather than integrating environmental with
economic policies. At best, integrative instruments assist the integration between
policies indirectly by (a) incorporating concerns of other policies in the object of a
policy, (b) inducing the harmonization of policies on theoretical grounds31, (c)
promoting the development and use of integrated assessment methods and data sets.
Integrative instruments may promote PI only if their use is reciprocal; i.e. not
asymmetric32. Moreover, reliance on integrative instruments only is not a long-term
solution to PI.
In sum, prescribed policy instruments and the rules of their use (implementation
procedures) reflect the definition of the policy object and the associated goals of the
actors participating in policy formulation. If the latter are dissociated, then the
relationships among policy instruments will suffer. The provision of integrative
instruments may be a technical solution that does not remove the fundamental
requirement of encouraging, facilitating and promoting proper relationships among
policy objects, goals and actors primarily. Moreover, during implementation, users
combine instruments to achieve their ends (i.e. solve the problems they perceive) in
context-dependent ways that can be neither anticipated nor specified precisely and
unambiguously during policy formulation. It can be argued that PI emerges during
implementation and as such it cannot be completely prescribed a priori.
Lastly, the variability of the object of PI with the stage of the policy process (agenda
setting, policy formulation and policy implementation) is briefly considered.
Integration among policy objects and goals is more relevant and essential during
agenda setting and policy formulation while integration among policy instruments is
critical at the implementation stage. Integration among policy actors is relevant
throughout the process. Nevertheless, as all constituents of a policy change in the
course of its development, a constant occupation with integration among policy
objects, goals, actors, procedures and instruments and an unending two-way
communication between formulation and implementation to facilitate as
comprehensive PI as possible and feasible are necessary.
The object of PI has several facets that should be analyzed not only in functional and
procedural terms, as it is mostly the case at present, but more deeply, in substantive
terms. Four broad interrelated and interdependent clusters of dimensions of PI –
substantive, analytical, procedural, and practical – are discussed in the following to
expand on the content of PI and to inform its operationalization (Table 1).
Cluster Components
Substantive Thematic
Conceptual
Value
Analytical Spatial
Temporal
Methodological
Procedural Structural
Procedural
Practical Practical
The need for thematic integration draws directly from the sustainable development
requirement that relationships among sectoral policies account for the relationships of
the characteristics of the issue considered. Hence, thematic integration is not limited
to environmental concerns; it extends to social and economic concerns as well as to
relationships between economic sectors; e.g., agriculture and transport, etc.
Related to the thematic, but acting on deeper levels, are the conceptual and value
dimensions of policy integration. Different policies frequently define differently
similar terms and concepts; such as ‘rural’, ‘social impacts’, ‘spatial impact’, ‘region’,
‘integrated’, ‘forest’, ‘pasture’, and so on. Frequently, also, the terms and
nomenclature used are not defined or they are defined loosely, opening thus the way
for a multiplicity of interpretations (and mis-interpretations). The conceptual
integration problem is rooted in socio-culturally determined differences in the value
systems of actors in the same or different policy contexts. Essential PI presupposes a
common frame of mind, common interest in and sense of collective responsibility both
for the causes and the solution of a policy problem among all those involved; or, at
least, a positive predisposition towards cooperation for the ‘common good’. From the
point of view of its analysis, common value systems among the actors involved are
manifestations or indications of some form of PI or of its likelihood.
The substantive dimensions of PI are directly related to its analytical, procedural and
practical dimensions as it is discussed next.
The spatial dimension concerns also cross-level relationships within and between state
and non-state actors involved in policy making. Lack of communication, cooperation
and coordination among those who define the policy problem and formulate the
relevant policy at higher levels, those charged with implementation and the ultimate
policy recipients (e.g. land owners, farmers, etc.) contribute to policy failures.
Similarly, the temporal dimension of PI concerns the congruence among the implicit
or explicit temporal systems of reference (temporal units, time intervals, time
horizons, and timing of actions) that policies adopt. Lack of temporal integration often
leads to ineffective and wasteful policy interventions.
Table 2 suggests a correspondence between the object and the dimensions of PI. A
complete analysis requires examination of all the components of the object of PI
along the appropriate dimensions because all are interrelated.
33
Although the literature concerns EPI mostly, the criteria can be generalized to PI because of their
predominantly procedural orientation.
Paper presented at the 2004 Berlin Conference “Greening of Policies: Interlinkages and Policy Integration”
Berlin, December 3-4, 2004.
21
of the object of PI and reflect the respective dimensions. General, cross-cutting
criteria are included also, considered as enabling conditions for the realization of PI.
The degree of PI achieved is difficult to assess in general. Ideally, if all criteria are
satisfied, then policies are perfectly integrated. The more criteria are satisfied the
higher the achievement of PI. Depending on the particular criteria being satisfied, it
can be gauged whether PI is substantive, analytical, procedural or practical. Lastly,
those criteria that are not satisfied may suggest what should be done to promote
integration between the policies examined.
General criteria
• Political commitment and leadership for PI in general34
• Need for compliance with international and EU commitments35
• Existence of long term SD strategy (or a relevant Report or Forum)
• The environmental, social, economic agendas of different sectors form a
consistent overall strategy (perhaps guided by a SD strategy)
• Favorable policy tradition and administrative culture (open, participatory,
horizontal)
• Shared core belief systems and communication across policy sectors
• Absence of intra-governmental power relations and of vertical alliances
hindering EPI/PI and horizontal networking
• Flexible general taxation.
34
I.e., existence of a formal policy framework for PI
35
Agenda 21, EU SDS, Article 6 of the 1999 Amsterdam Treaty, etc.
Paper presented at the 2004 Berlin Conference “Greening of Policies: Interlinkages and Policy Integration”
Berlin, December 3-4, 2004.
22
- Special unit for PI in the competent organization
- Officials charged with integration tasks
- Administrative reform (restructuring) in favor of PI
- Presence of horizontal administrative structures as opposed to vertical
and departmentalized structures; e.g. inter-ministerial committees and task
forces, issue-specific joint working groups, networking schemes, regular
circulation of staff between sectoral departments
• Formal/institutionalized interaction36 among policy actors and actor networks
• Informal interaction among formal policy actors and actor networks37
• Interaction among state and non-state policy actors38
• Consistent, compatible and coordinated procedures and rules of decision-
making in competent administrative bodies39
• Strengthening existing administrative units with regard to procedural rights
and rules relevant for coordination and joint problem-solving
• Joint decision making and joint responsibilities of the policy sectors
considered
• Provisions for implementing PI requirements (e.g. compliance, enforcement
and accountability mechanisms for PI among competent agencies)
36
Such as: (a) communication, consultation, routine early consultation on sector policies and projects,
cooperation, coordination and collaboration in implementation, etc., (b) policy formulation actors
interact formally with policy implementation actors and vice versa.
37
E.g. ad hoc meetings and informal discussions and consultations; environment or other issues are
regular agenda items in high-level meetings
38
For example, goal-related consultation and participation processes among them (from agenda setting
to policy implementation); partnerships between government and business on cross-cutting issues
39
These include the right to set formal agendas and develop PI proposals, participation by departments
or agencies in decision-making of other policy sectors, coordinated authorization procedures,
coordination/integration of sector approval/licensing processes, spatial planning, EIA, regulatory
review procedures, evaluation procedures.
40
The specific form depends on state political philosophy, ranging from regulating PI to using
persuasion and voluntary measures. It includes legal/institutional reforms in favor of PI (filling gaps in
legislation), administrative rights (rights and standing to intervene in other administrative bodies), etc.
41
Such as EIA, SEA and other provisions common in both policies; clear and common, or compatible
and congruent systems of resource rights for all resources (e.g. land, water, labor, etc.) in all policies;
rights to participate in decision making within and between policy areas for all types of actors.
42
For example, (a) use of legal provisions of one policy as an instrument to achieve goals of another –
e.g. Good Agricultural Practice codes used in rural policy to achieve water protection goals of the
EWFD, (b) adequacy of existing legal instruments as regards PI, (c) elimination of inconsistencies,
duplications, conflicts among instruments, (d) use of voluntary measures (e.g. negotiated agreements)
43
For example, biodiversity protection regulations may well serve water- or soil-related goals and vice
versa; financing transportation projects to promote regional development, etc.
44
(a) Use of economic instruments to internalize environmental costs of economic activity (e.g.
resource pricing, charges, fees), (b) economic instruments for behavior change, not for revenue raising.
Paper presented at the 2004 Berlin Conference “Greening of Policies: Interlinkages and Policy Integration”
Berlin, December 3-4, 2004.
23
• Environmental and/or Social Fiscal Reform
• Use of financial mechanisms/ incentives, such as, subsidies for PI
• Favorable budgetary process (e.g. for ‘greening’ budgets)
• Common or coordinated/compatible sector Action Plans (e.g. forest,
biodiversity, desertification, transport)
• Common, shared research resources
• Common, or compatible and consistent, data and information bases
• Common assessment and evaluation methodologies, and tools (PI indicators)
• Common monitoring programmes and infrastructure
• Use of communication instruments for PI
• Education and training services for civil servants, bureaucrats, etc. on PI issues
The ideal situation might be to design a grand scheme of horizontally and vertically
integrated policies, on the same and across levels, which can accommodate all
possible cases of crosscutting issues. However, the complex and elusive nature of
both socio-environmental problems and policies renders this option utopian and
infeasible and necessitates more flexible approaches that can be adapted to the
particularities of each case. Before proceeding to suggest one such approach, two
points are worth mentioning.
First, a PIS designed to address a given issue may provide for arrangements that also
address other issues. Of course, a PIS suitable for one problem may be unsuitable for
another. In any event, not all possible cases of crosscutting issues need to (or, can) be
considered but only a few strategic ones. This second point is supported by the
statement: “Clearly, everything is connected. But because everything is connected, it
is beyond our capacity to manipulate variables comprehensively. Because everything
Paper presented at the 2004 Berlin Conference “Greening of Policies: Interlinkages and Policy Integration”
Berlin, December 3-4, 2004.
24
is interconnected, the whole environmental problem is beyond our capacity to control
in one unified policy. We have to find … tactically defensible or strategically
defensible points of intervention” (Lindblom, 1973, 11-34). Therefore, the task is to
find which strategic policies should be integrated at each level to enable the
integration of policies on the same and on other levels.
The proposed approach builds on the adaptive management paradigm (Holling, 1978)
that has been developed to integrate uncertainty into decision-making for complex
systems. Adaptive management, based on learning-by-doing and experimentation, can
be viewed as an approach to managing risks associated with uncertainty. Resource
policies are considered as hypotheses and management as experiments from which
managers learn from their successes and from their failures. It stresses the importance
of two-way feedback between management and the state of the resource in shaping
policy, followed by further systematic experimentation to shape subsequent policy. Its
flexible, iterative, co-evolutionary and science-based character allows for institutional
learning; i.e. changing resource management institutions to fit the nature of the
system being managed (Berkes and Folke 1998).
The evolving, dynamic character of policy objects and of policy implementation and
the resulting uncertainty of policy outcomes justify the adoption of this paradigm for
designing PIS. Transferring its main ideas to the present case, the basic tenet of the
proposed approach is that any PIS is a hypothesis to be scientifically tested on the
ground and revised, through participatory approaches, by incorporating systematically
collected information obtained from PIS implementation. The policies to be integrated
at a given level should relate to critical, strategic factors associated with important
crosscutting issues and the sustainability of human-environment systems on and
across spatial levels45. Given the interconnectedness of policies, PI may start from the
most instrumental and pivotal policy, orchestrating all others around it (assuming that
the associated policy actors are willing to cooperate!), some of which inevitably will
originate in higher or lower levels. The main steps of the approach include:
• Design a PIS following a systematic and participatory approach along the lines
of analysis suggested in this study.
• Design a monitoring and evaluation scheme to gather data to address key
uncertainties.
• Implement the PIS
• Systematically monitor all aspects of implementation and record problems
such as overlaps, conflicts, inconsistencies, etc.
• Revise the PIS (policy objects, hypotheses, linkages) to fit better the particular
situations to which it applies based on feedback from implementation
• Implement the revised PIS; repeat the monitoring and revision cycle.
The adoption, implementation and success of this approach require that certain
conditions be satisfied, which usually depend on the spatial/organizational level
concerned and the scope of the PIS. The most critical requirement is interest in,
commitment to PI and a ‘commons’ mentality46 to satisfy the accountability criterion;
45
For example, economic policies and environmental, mainly water resources, policies.
46
I.e. a concern for the wise management of the wide range of natural, manmade and human Common
Pool Resources (CPRs) (Ostrom, 1990)
Paper presented at the 2004 Berlin Conference “Greening of Policies: Interlinkages and Policy Integration”
Berlin, December 3-4, 2004.
25
namely, ‘who will be responsible for the PIS?’ and ‘who will be charged with
coordinating the overall PI effort?’ (Peters 1998). It should be noted that context-
specific political expediencies, rejecting the idea of social experimentation that the
adaptive management paradigm somehow implies, may preclude the adoption of an
adaptive management approach to PI, irrespective of its plausibility and suitability.
Despite the above reservations, the proposed approach could serve as a conceptual
guide for designing and testing alternative PIS in diverse environmental and socio-
economic contexts and problem situations47. The PIS may be limited to simply
incorporating environmental, social or economic concerns in sectoral policies48 or
may move to more complete PI, ideally starting from the integration of policy objects
and moving to the integration of policy instruments, ensuring the consistency of the
overall process. As this order may be difficult to follow in reality, the process may
start from whichever component of the PI object is handy, convenient, and easy to
manipulate while trying to build reasonable linkages with the other components.
The study of PI is still in its early stages as one can glimpse from the literature. Future
theoretical and empirical research, used in combination, faces a long list of open
questions waiting to be explored. These include the study of:
• the complexity of contemporary policy problems, for a variety of issue areas such
as desertification, biodiversity protection, rural development, tourism
development, etc., and the contribution of PI to their management
• the appropriate scale for PI and the scope of the task as well as the choice between
intra-policy (vertical) versus inter-policy (horizontal) integration and the influence
of non-policy factors on the feasibility of particular types of PI
• the substantive integration of EU and national policies and its linkages to
procedural integration with emphasis on the actor networks involved in the
various EU policies at the EU and the national/subnational levels through suites of
empirical studies covering a variety of country and regional situations
• the analytical and practical dimensions of PI especially as they relate to the
substantive and procedural ones; integrated methodologies used in common by all
policies to provide compatible analyses of policy problems should be explored
• the integration of policy instruments with reference to particular issue areas so as
to effect or improve the integration of policy objects, goals and actors and the
consistency of the overall process as well as to provide guidelines for the
development of policy instrument mixes promoting substantive PI, considering
emerging new forms of governance, new kinds of market-based, and voluntary
instruments and assessment tools (such as sustainability appraisal)
• the special case of integrative instruments should be re-examined in the light of
the more essential need to promote the substantive in addition to the procedural PI
• the appropriateness of the adaptive management approach advocated here at
various scales and PI of various scope.
47
A first application of these ideas in the case of combating desertification, see Briassoulis (2004b).
48
An extension of the EPI idea.
Paper presented at the 2004 Berlin Conference “Greening of Policies: Interlinkages and Policy Integration”
Berlin, December 3-4, 2004.
26
REFERENCES
1. Anderson, J. E. (1984) Public Policy-Making. 3rd edition. New York: Holt, Reinhart and
Winston.
2. Anderson, P., Arrow K.J., and Pines D. (eds) (1988), The Economy as an Evolving Complex
System I, Addison-Wesley, Reading, Mass.
3. Arthur, B. (1989), ‘Competing technologies, increasing returns and lock-in by historical events’,
Economic Journal, 99, pp. 116-31.
4. Arthur, W.B., Durlauf, S.N., and Lane, D.A. (eds) (1997), The Economy as an Evolving
Complex System II, Addison-Wesley, Reading, Mass.
5. Ascher, W. (2001), ‘Coping with complexity and organizational interests in natural resources
management’, Ecosystems, 4, pp. 742-57.
6. Avery, G. (2001), ‘Policies for an Enlarged Union. Report of Governance Group 6’, White
Paper on European Governance Area no. 6, Defining the framework for the policies needed by
the Union in a longer-term perspective of 10-15 years taking account of enlargement, European
Commission, Brussels.
7. Baas, N.A. and Emmeche, C. (1997), ‘On emergence and explanation’, Intellectica, 25, pp. 67-
83.
8. Batty, M. and Torrens, P.M. (2001), ‘Modeling Complexity: The Limits to Prediction’, CASA
Paper 36, Centre for Advanced Spatial Analysis, University College London
(http//www.casa.ucl.ac.uk/paper36.pdf).
9. Berkes, F. and C. Folke, eds. (1998) Linking Social and Ecological Systems: Management
Practices and Social Mechanisms for Building Resilience. Cambridge, Ma. Cambridge
University Press.
10. Berkhout, F. (2002) ‘Technological regimes, path dependency and the environment’, Global
Environmental Change, 12, pp. 1-4.
11. Brown, M. L. (2000), ‘Scientific uncertainty and learning in European Union environmental
policy making’, Policy Studies Journal, 28(3), pp. 576-96.
12. Byrne, D. (1998), Complexity Theory and the Social Sciences: An Introduction, Routledge,
London.
13. Briassoulis, H. (2001) Policy-oriented integrated analysis of land use change: An analysis of
data needs. Environmental Management, 26(2): 1-11.
14. Briassoulis, H. (2004a), ‘The institutional complexity of environmental policy and planning
problems: The example of Mediterranean Desertification’, Journal of Environmental Planning
and Management, 47, No. 1, pp. 115-35.
15. Briassoulis, H. (2004b) Design of a Desertification Policy Support Framework (DPSF),
Deliverable 36, Module 4, MEDACTION. European Commission, DG-XII, Contract No.
ENVK2-CT-2000-00085 (www.icis.nl/medaction).
16. Bromley, D.W. (1991) Environment and Economy. Cambridge, Ma: Blackwell Publishers.
17. Christiansen, T. and S. Piattoni, eds. (2004) Informal Governance in the European Union.
Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.
18. Collier, U. (1994), Energy and environment in the European Union. Avebury, Aldershot.
19. Detombe, D.J. (2001), ‘Methodology for handling complex societal problems’, European
Journal of Operational Research, 128, pp. 227-30.
20. Dooley, K. (1997), ‘A complex adaptive systems model of organization change’, Nonlinear
Dynamics, Psychology and Life Sciences, 1(1), pp. 69-97.
21. Dryzek, J.S. (1987), Rational Ecology, Environment and Political Economy, Blackwell Publishing,
Oxford.
22. EEA (1998), Europe's environment. A second assessment, European Environment Agency,
Copenhagen.
23. European Commission (1998) Partnership for integration: A strategy for integrating
environment in EU policies. COM (98)0333 final.
24. European Commission (1999) Report on Environment and Integration Indicators to Helsinki
Summit. Commission Working Document, SEC (1999) 1942 final, Brussels.
25. European Commission (2000) Bringing our needs and responsibilities together-Integrating
environmental issues with economic policy. Communication from the Commission to the
Council and the European Parliament. COM(2000) 576 final. Brussels.
26. European Commission (2001) Policies for an Enlarged Union. Report of Governance Group 6.
June 2001, Brussels.
Paper presented at the 2004 Berlin Conference “Greening of Policies: Interlinkages and Policy Integration”
Berlin, December 3-4, 2004.
27
27. EC (2004) Third Report on Economic and Social Cohesion. COM(2004) 107. Luxembourg,
Office for Official Publications of the European Communities
28. EEB (2003), Environmental Policy Integration (EPI): Theory and Practice in the UNECE
Region, Background Paper of the European ECO Forum for the Round Table on Environmental
Policy Integration at the Fifth “Environment for Europe” Ministerial Conference, Kyiv, May 21-
23, 2003, European Environmental Bureau.
29. Finnigan, J. (2003), ‘Earth System Science in the Early Anthropocene’, Global Change
Newsletter, Issue 55, pp. 8-11.
30. Friedrich, C.J. (1963), Man and his Government, McGraw-Hill, New York.
31. Gallagher, R. and Appenzeller, T. (1999), ‘Beyond reductionism’, Science, 284, p. 79.
32. Gibbs, D., Jonas, A. and While, A. (2003), ‘Regional Sustainable Development as a Challenge
for Sectoral Policy Integration’, Paper presented at Workshop II of the EU Thematic Network
Project REGIONET, Regional Sustainable Development - Strategies for Effective Multi-level
Governance, Lillehammer, Norway, 29-31 January 2003.
33. Glasner, E and Weiss, H. (1993), ‘Sensitive dependence on initial conditions’, Nonlinearity, 6,
pp.1067-75.
34. Greenberg, G.D., J.A., Miller, L.B. Mohr, and B.C. Vladeck (1977) Developing public policy
theory: Perspectives from empirical research. The American Political Science Review, 7: 1532-
1543.
35. Gunderson, L.H. and Holling, C.S. (eds) (2002), Panarchy; Understanding Transformations in
Human and Natural Systems, Island Press, Washington, DC.
36. Hajer, M. (2003), ‘Policy without Polity; Policy analysis and the institutional void’, Policy
Sciences, 36, pp.175-95.
37. Hakkinen, L. (ed.) (1999), Regions – Cornerstone for Sustainable Development, Edita, Helsinki.
38. Healey, P. (1997) Collaborative Planning: Shaping Places in Fragmented Societies. Vancouver,
UBC Press.
39. Henderson, B. (2001), ‘Path dependence, escaping sustained yield’, Conservation Ecology, 5(1),
r3, [online] URL: http://www.consecol.org/vol5/iss1/resp3.
40. Hertin, J. and Berkhout, F. (2003), ‘Analysing Institutional Strategies for Environmental Policy
Integration: The Case of EU Enterprise Policy’, Journal of Environmental Policy and Planning,
5(1), pp.39-56.
41. Holland, J.H. (1995), Hidden Order: How Adaptation Builds Complexity, Helix, Reading, MA.
42. Holling, C.S. (1978) Adaptive Environmental Assessment and Management. New York, John
Wiley.
43. Holling, C.S. (1986), ‘The resilience of terrestrial ecosystems: local surprise and global change’,
in W.C. Clark, and R.E. Munn (eds), Sustainable Development of the Biosphere, Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge, pp. 292-317.
44. Holling, C.S., Berkes, F. and Folke, C. (1998), ‘Science, sustainability and resource
management’, in F. Berkes, and C. Folke (eds), Linking Social and Ecological Systems:
Management Practices and Social Mechanisms for Building Resilience, Cambridge University
Press, Cambridge, MA, pp. 342-62.
45. Holling, C.S. (2001), ‘Understanding the complexity of economic, ecological and social
systems’, Ecosystems, 4, pp. 390-405.
46. Hooghe, L. and Marks, G. (2001), Multi-level Governance and European Integration, Rowman
& Littlefield, Oxford.
47. Janssen, M., Walker, B.H., Langridge, J. and Abel, N. (2000), ‘An adaptive agent model for
analyzing co-evolution of management and policies in a complex rangeland system’, Ecological
Modeling, 131, p. 249-68.
48. Knill, C. and Lenschow, A. (eds) (2000), Implementing EU environmental policy. New
directions and old problems, Manchester University Press, Manchester/New York.
49. Lafferty, W.M. and E. Hovden (2002) Environmental Policy Integration: Towards an Analytical
Framework? PROSUS, Centre for Development and the Environment, University of Oslo, Oslo,
Report 7/02.
50. Langton, C.G. (1990), ‘Computation at the Edge of Chaos: phase transitions and emergent
computation’, Physica D, 42, 1-3, pp. 12-37.
51. Lee, K.N. (1993), Compass and gyroscope: Integrating science and politics for the environment,
Island Press, Washington, DC.
52. Lenschow, A. and A. Zito (1998). “Blurring or shifting of policy frames? Institutionalization of
the economic-environmental policy linkage in the European Community.” Governance 11(4):
415-442.
Paper presented at the 2004 Berlin Conference “Greening of Policies: Interlinkages and Policy Integration”
Berlin, December 3-4, 2004.
28
53. Lenschow, A., ed. (2002a) Environmental Policy Integration: Greening sectoral Policies in
Europe, London: Earthscan.
54. Lenschow, A., ed. (2002b) Dynamics in a multilevel polity: Greening the EU regional and
Cohesion Funds. In Environmental Policy Integration: Greening sectoral Policies in Europe, A.
Lenschow, ed. London: Earthscan, pp. 193-215.
55. Levin, S. (1999), Fragile dominion: Complexity and the commons, Perseus Publishing,
Cambridge, MA.
56. Lewanski, R. (2002), ‘Environmental policy integration in Italy: I a green government enough?
Evidence from the Italian case.’ in A. Lenschow, (ed.), Environmental Policy Integration:
Greening Sectoral Policies in Europe, Earthscan, London, pp. 78-100.
57. Liberatore, A. (1997). The integration of sustainable development objectives into EU policy-
making: Barriers and prospects. In The politics of sustainable development: Theory, policy and
practice within the European Union. S. Baker, M. Kousis, D. Richardson and S. Young, eds.
London, Routledge.
58. Liebowitz, S. and Margolis, S.E. (1995), ‘Path Dependence, Lock-In, and History’, Journal of
Law, Economics, and Organization, 11(1), pp. 205-26.
59. Liefferink, D. and Jordan A. (2002), ‘The Europeanisation of National Environmental Policy; A
Comparative Analysis’, University of Nijmegen, GAP, Working Paper Series 2002/14.
60. Limburg, K.E., O’Neill, R.V., Constanza, R. and Farber, S. (2002), ‘Complex systems and
valuation’, Ecological Economics, 41, pp. 409-20.
61. Lindblom, C. E. (1973) Incrementalism and environmentalism. In Managing the Environment.
Final Conference Report, Washington, DC, Environmental Research Center, US EPA.
62. Lowi, T.J. (1964), ‘American business, public policy, case studies, and political theory’, World
Politics, 16, pp. 677-715.
63. Manson, S.M. (2001), ‘Simplifying complexity: A review of Complexity Theory’, Geoforum,
32, pp. 405-414.
64. Marion, R. (1999), The Edge of Organization: Chaos and Complexity Theory of Formal Social
Systems, Sage, Thousand Oaks, CA.
65. Marks, G., Hooghe, L. and Blank, K. (1996), ‘European Integration from the 1980s: State-
Centric v. Multi-level Governance’, Journal of Common Market Studies, 34(3), pp. 341-78.
66. Metcalfe, L. (1994) “International policy coordination and public management reform.”
International Review of Administrative Sciences 60: 271-290.
67. Moss, T. (2003), ‘Regional Governance and the EU Water Framework Directive: a study of
institutional fit, scale and interplay’, Paper presented at the workshop of the EU Thematic
Network project REGIONET “Regional Sustainable Development – Strategies for Effective
Multi-Level Governance”, 29-31 January 2003, Lillehammer, Norway.
68. Moss, T. (2004), ‘Regional Sustainable development as a Cross Sectoral Task’, Discussion
paper presented at the REGIONET workshop “Cross fertilization and integration of results of
REGIONET”. Brussels, 14-16 January 2004.
69. OECD (1996a) Building policy coherence: Tools and tensions. Public management occasional
papers. No. 12. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Paris.
70. OECD (1996b) Globalisation: What challenges and what opportunities for government?
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Paris.
71. Opschoor, H. and J. van der Straaten (1993) Sustainable Development: An Institutionalist
Approach. Ecological Economics 7 (1993), pp. 203-222.
72. O’ Riordan and Voisey, 1998;
73. Ostrom, E. (1990) Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions of Collective Action.
Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.
74. Ostrom, E. (1998), ‘Scales, Polycentricity, and Incentives: Designing Complexity to Govern
Complexity’, in D.G. Lakshman and J.A. McNeely (eds), Protection of Global Biodiversity:
Converging Strategies, Duke University Press, Durham, NC., pp. 149-67.
75. Ostrom, E. (1999) Institutional rational choice: An assessment of the Institutional Analysis and
Development framework. In Theories of the Policy Process, P. Sabatier, ed. Boulder, Co.:
Westview Press, pp. 35-72.
76. Patton, C.V. and Sawicki, D. (1986), Basic methods of Policy Analysis and Planning, Prentice
Hall, Englewood Cliffs.
77. Persson, A. (2002) Environmental Policy Integration: An Introduction. PINTS - Policy
Integration for Sustainability, Background Paper (Draft). Stockholm Environment Institute.
Paper presented at the 2004 Berlin Conference “Greening of Policies: Interlinkages and Policy Integration”
Berlin, December 3-4, 2004.
29
78. Peters, G. B. (1998) Managing Horizontal Government: The Politics of Coordination. Canadian
Centre for Management Development. Research Paper No. 21. Catalogue Number SC94-61/21-
1998, ISBN 0-662-62990-6.
79. Pressman, J. L. & A. Wildavsky (1992) Implementation: How Great Expectations in
Washington Are Dashed in Oakland. Berkeley, CA, University of California Press.
80. Reynolds, J.F. and Stafford-Smith, M. (2002), ‘Do Humans cause deserts?’ in J.F. Reynolds and
M. Stafford-Smith (eds), Global Desertification: Do Humans Cause Deserts?, Dahlem
University Press, Berlin, pp.1-22.
81. Richardson, J.J. (1982), Policy styles in Western Europe, Allen and Unwin, Hemel Hempstead.
82. Robert, J., Stumm, T., de Vet, J.M., Reincke, C.J., Hollanders, M. and Figueiredo, M.A. (2001),
Spatial Impacts of Community Policies and the Costs of Non-Coordination, EC, DG-Regional
Policy, ERDF Contract 99.00.27.156, Brussels.
83. Sabatier, P., ed. (1999), Theories of the Policy Process. Boulder, Co.: Westview Press.
84. Sanderson, I. (2000), Evaluation in complex policy systems, Evaluation, 6(4), pp. 433-454.
85. Science, (1999), Complex Systems, Vol. 284, pp. 79-109 (April 2, 1999).
86. Shannon, M.A. (2002) Theoretical Approaches to Understanding Intersectoral Policy
Integration. Paper presented at the Finland COST Action meeting (European Forest Institute).
87. Thomas, D.S.G. (1997), ‘Science and the desertification debate’, Journal of Arid Environments,
377, pp. 599-608.
88. Thomas, E. (2003), ‘Sustainable development, market paradigms and policy integration’,
Journal of Environmental Policy and Planning, 5(2), pp. 201-16.
89. True, J.L., Jones, B.D. and Baumgartner, F.R. (1999), ‘Punctuated-equilibrium theory:
Explaining stability and change in American policymaking’, in P.A. Sabatier (ed.), Theories of
the Policy Process, Westview Press, Boulder, CO., pp. 97-116.
90. UNCCD (1994), United Nations Convention to Combat Desertification and Drought
(www.unccd.int).
91. Underdal, A. (1980) Integrated Marine Policy: What? Why? How? Marine Policy 4 (3): 159-
169.
92. Vogel, (1986), National Styles of Regulation: Environmental Policy in Great Britain and the
United States, Cornell University Press, Ithaca, NY.
93. Waldrop, M.M. (1992), Complexity; The Emerging Science at the Edge of Order and Chaos,
Penguin Books, London.
94. Weale, A. (1996) Environmental rules and rule-making in the European Union. Journal of
European Public Policy, 3(4): 149-167.
95. Wilson, J. (2002), ‘Scientific uncertainty, complex systems and the design of common-pool
institutions’, in E. Ostrom, T. Dietz, N. Dolsak, P. Stern, S. Stonich and E. Weber (eds), The
Drama of the Commons, Committee on the Human Dimensions of Global Change, National
Academy Press, Washington, DC, pp. 327-60.
96. Wiman, B.L.B. (1991), ‘Implications of environmental complexity for science and policy’,
Global Environmental Change, June 1991, pp. 235-47.
97. Wittrock, B. and de Leon, P. (1986), ‘Policy as moving target: A call for conceptual realism’,
Policy Studies Review, 6(1), pp. 44-60.
98. Wollin, A. (1999), ‘Punctuated Equilibrium: Reconciling Theory of Evolutionary and
Incremental Change’, Systems Research and Behavior Science, 16, pp.359-67.
99. Zahariadis, N. (1999), ‘Ambiguity, time and multiple streams’ in P.A. Sabatier, (ed.), Theories
of the Policy Process, Westview Press, Boulder, CO., pp. 73-95.
100. Zahariadis, N. (2003), ‘Complexity, coupling, and the future of European integration’, Review of
Policy Research, 20(2), pp. 285-310.
Paper presented at the 2004 Berlin Conference “Greening of Policies: Interlinkages and Policy Integration”
Berlin, December 3-4, 2004.
30