Capital Structure in The Modern World
Capital Structure in The Modern World
Capital Structure in
the Modern World
Anton Miglo
Nipissing University, Ontario, Canada
Capital structure is a very interesting and probably one of the most con-
troversial areas of finance. It is an area of permanent battles between dif-
ferent managers defending their favorite approaches, between theorists
and practitioners looking at the same problems under different angles,
and between professors and students since the area is complicated
and requires a superior knowledge of econometrics, microeconomics,
accounting, mathematics, game theory etc. Many of the results obtained
in capital structure theory over the last 50–60 years have been very influ-
ential and led their authors to great international recognition. Among the
researchers who contributed significantly to capital structure theory, note
Nobel Prize Award winners Franco Modigliani, Merton Miller, Joseph
Stiglitz, and most recently Jean Tirole. Although until recently capital
structure theories did not have strong support from practitioners and
were too complicated to teach at colleges and business schools, they are
quickly gaining recognition at universities and in the real world. This
field has become extremely intriguing to potential employees and stu-
dents. The roles of investment banker and corporate treasurer, which
require fundamental capital structure education, are very popular.
This book focuses on the microeconomic foundations of capital struc-
ture theory. Some areas are based on traditional cost-benefit analyses,
but most include analyses of different market imperfections, primarily
asymmetric information, moral hazard problems and, more recently
vii
viii Preface
Anton Miglo
North Bay, Ontario, Canada
References
Baker, H., & Martin, G. (Eds.). (2011). Capital structure and corporate
financing decisions, Robert W. Kolb series in Finance. John Wiley and
Sons, Inc.
Halpern, P. (Ed.). (1997). Financing growth in Canada. University of
Calgary Press.
Acknowledgements
xi
Contents
1 Introduction 3
1.1 The Capital Structure Problem 3
1.2 The Concept of Perfect Market and Some Stylyzed Facts 6
1.3 Capital Structure Choice Analysis: The Beginnings 9
References 17
xiii
xiv Contents
5 Debt Overhang 97
5.1 Debt Overhang 97
5.2 How Does the Type and the Level of Debt Affect
the Underinvestment Problem 100
5.3 Debt Overhang Implications and Prevention 102
5.4 Flexibility Theory of Capital Structure 107
5.5 Debt Overhang in Financial Institutions 108
References 111
Index 251
List of Figures
xvii
xviii List of Figures
xix
xx List of Tables
But I can’t help—I don’t have the flexibility—and end up giving up what
could be the most important asset the company needs in order to change
over the next 10 years. We believe there’s an opportunity cost of not
having that flexibility….”1 As we will later learn, Mr. Pichette is talking
about the relatively recent flexibility theory of capital structure. Usually
it means keeping the amount of debt low.
Conversely, famous fast-food chain McDonald’s does not mind using
more debt. In July 2007, according to an article entitled “McDonald’s
reviews capital structure, CFO retiring”, McDonald’s announced the
retirement of CFO Mr. Paull and at the same time announced that they
were issuing more debt. They argued that it will help increase the return
to shareholders.2 Just recently, in 2015, McDonald’s again used a similar
strategy.3 Unlike Google, McDonald’s assets structure has a much higher
fraction of tangible assets, which, as we will later learn, usually makes
debt financing more affordable and meaningful. McDonald’s business
relies significantly on franchising and a lot of their investments depend
on their franchisees. They have a limited ability to raise equity capital
and therefore debt financing is a logical choice. Using debt may also be
related to the problem of providing additional financial discipline. As we
will later learn, this idea is called “debt and discipline” theory.
In the last 10 years there has been a growing interest in the capital
structure of start-up and small companies. Traditionally, it was assumed
that most financing comes from entrepreneurs’ friends and relatives and
the rest possibly from venture capitalists and angel investors. The role of
banks and external debt financing was not important. Recently, it was
discovered that firms that use external debt perform better than those
who do not. Kauffman Foundation, dedicated to entrepreneurial research
and support, in a publication entitled “The Capital Structure Decisions
of New Firms,” suggests that contrary to widely held beliefs that start-
up companies rely heavily on funding from family and friends, outside
debt (financing through credit cards, credit lines, bank loans, etc.) is the
most important type of financing for new firms, followed closely by the
1
Manyika (August 2011).
2
Groom (July 24, 2007).
3
Gandel (December 4, 2015).
1 Introduction 5
“In summary, executives use the mainline techniques that business schools
have taught for years, NPV and CAPM,5 to value projects and to estimate the
cost of equity. Interestingly, financial executives are much less likely to follow
the academically prescribed factors and theories when determining capital
structure. This last finding raises possibilities that require additional thought
and research. Perhaps the relatively weak support for many capital structure
theories indicates that it is time to critically reevaluate the assumptions and
implications of these mainline theories. Alternatively, perhaps the theories are
valid descriptions of what firms should do—but many corporations ignore
the theoretical advice. One explanation for this last possibility is that business
schools might be better at teaching capital budgeting and the cost of capital
than teaching capital structure. Moreover, perhaps the NPV and CAPM are
more widely understood than capital structure theories because they make
more precise predictions and have been accepted as mainstream views for
longer. Additional research is needed to investigate these issues.”6
In the real world, we find empirical evidence that contradicts the pre-
dictions of a perfect market. For example, empirical evidence supports
the following:
3. Firms with positive NPV projects may have different levels of access to
credit.
Table 1.1 shows the average capital structure (debt to assets ratio)
of firms in different industries in the United States. One can observe
that capital structure does matter as firms with large amounts of tan-
gible assets (Trucking, Automotive, Air Transport, Water Utility) tend to
be financed with more debt than firms with large amount of intangible
assets (Computer Software, Internet, Educational Services, and Drugs).
The reasons behind this will be further covered in Chap. 2 in trade-off
theory.
Table 1.2 shows that prices of newly issued shares during IPOs (initial
public offerings) are below their market values. This creates a puzzle. If
the market prices correctly reflect the expected value of future earnings
why do firms leave money on the table? The latter is not consistent with
firm value-maximizing behavior. Also, prices that do not correctly reflect
the expected values of their earnings are not consistent with the price
efficiency prediction of the perfect market. There are many reasons for
this observation, which will be covered later in the book.
The pattern presented in Table 1.2 holds not only for US firms but
international firms as well (Table 1.3).
Table 1.4 demonstrates that firms that issue equity underperform,
ceteris paribus (same risk, size, etc.), comparable firms in their indus-
tries in the long term. If, as the perfect market concept predicts, capital
structure does not matter, a systematic relationship between firms’ capital
structures and their operating performances should not exist.
From Table 1.5, one can observe that smaller firms do not have the
same access to debt as larger firms. This is another piece of evidence that
cannot be easily explained using the perfect market concept.
1 Introduction 9
Table 1.4 Average long run operating underperformance of firms that issue
equity
Median industry-adjusted Median industry-adjusted
operating return on assets cash flow to assets ratio
Time change from year before from year before IPO to 3
Sample period IPO to 3 years after IPO (%) years after IPO (%)
682 US IPOs 1976– −6.8 −4.72
1988
555 IPOs by 1995– −3.44 −2.87
European 2006
firms
Sources of data: Jain and Kini (1994) and Pereira and Sousa (2015)
Year 0 1
A firm’s initial capital consists of $10 cash that was invested by the
firm’s founder who owns 1 share of stock, which currently means 100 %
of the company’s ownership. The firm has a project available. The project
is an expenditure that will generate future cash flows. It can be illustrated
using a timeline that indicates investments and revenues at different
points in time (Fig. 1.1).
The project costs 110 (throughout the text, if a currency is not indi-
cated then it is irrelevant). This amount represents investments in fixed
assets that will fully depreciate during the project. Aside from deprecia-
tion there are no other costs involved. The project will generate sales
in the amount of 200 at the end of the year. The firm has to find 100
to finance the difference between the total cost of the investment and
the amount of cash currently available. It has a choice of two strategies:
borrowing at an interest rate of 10% or issuing shares (10 shares of 10
each).
1. Under the first strategy, the following sequence of events occurs: bor-
rowing, investment, sales, payment to debtholders, and distribution
to shareholders. These events will be recorded using balance sheets and
income statements (recall that a balance sheet shows a firm’s assets (A)
and liabilities/capital (LC) at a given moment in time and an income
statement shows earnings/expenses for a given period of time).8 It is
illustrated in Fig. 1.2.
The above income statement shows the firm’s earnings between the
initial issue of shares (prior to undertaking the project) and the project’s
completion. Subtracting amortization from sales, we get the earnings,
8
For a review of accounting principles see, for example, Wild, Shaw, and Chiappetta (2014).
1 Introduction 11
Inial situaon A LC
Cash 10 Capital 10
Borrowing A LC
Cash 110 Loan 100
Capital 10
Investment A LC
Fixed Assets Loan 100
110
Capital 10
Sales A LC
Cash 200 Loan 100
Capital (initial 10
plus earnings 90)
100
Payment to debtholders A LC
Cash 90 Loan 0
Capital 90
A LC
Distribuon to shareholders
0 0
Income statement
Sales 200
Amortization 110
Earnings 90
Interest 10
Net Earnings 80
Dividends 80
Retained Earnings 0
Fig. 1.2 Balance sheet changes and final income statement under debt
financing
12 Capital Structure in the Modern World
which are 90. Then we subtract interest, which equals 10, and we are left
with 80 net earnings that are distributed as dividends to shareholders.
Inial situaon A LC
Cash 10 Capital 10
Issuing shares A LC
Cash 110 Capital 110
Investments A LC
Fixed Assets 110 Capital 110
Sales A LC
Cash 200 Capital 200 (ini-
tial 10 plus issue
100 plus earnings
90)
Distribuon to share- A LC
holders
0 0
Income statement
Sales 200
Amortization 110
Earnings 90
Net earnings 90
Dividends 90
Retained Earnings 0
Fig. 1.3 Balance sheet changes and final income statement under equity
financing
1 Introduction 13
12
10
8
Debt
6
payment
4
2
0
0 2.5 5 7.5 10 12.5 15
The firm's resources available
ple, Ewert and Niemann (2012), Horvath and Woywode (2005), Miglo
(2007) and Lindhe, Sodersten, and Oberg (2004)).
Recall that one of the major features of corporations is that sharehold-
ers have limited liability. This feature will frequently be used in the book
to demonstrate the patterns of payments of different claimholders in dif-
ferent scenarios.
In Fig. 1.4, the solid line represents the creditors’ payoffs and the
dotted line is the firm’s shareholders’ payoffs. The x-axis represents the
amount of available resources9 and the y-axis represents debt payments.
The original creditors have seniority and are entitled to payment up to
the value of the principal and interest (equal to 5 in Figs. 1.4 and 1.5). So
if the amount of available resources is less than 5, they belong to credi-
tors. However, if the firm’s revenue is greater than 5, the creditors will
receive 5 and the firm’s shareholders will receive the rest. In the case of
unlimited liability, the firm’s owners are mandated to pay creditors out of
their own pockets. This is illustrated in Fig. 1.5.
Assuming that the owners’ personal assets are sufficiently large, then
under unlimited liability the creditors will still be repaid fully regardless
of the firm’s resources. The owners’ net profit will be negative when the
firm’s resources are less than 5 and they will have to sell a part of their own
assets in order to repay the debt.
9
The amount of available resources depends on the specific debt contract. In most cases the pay-
ment of debt requires cash. However, the firm always has an opportunity to sell its assets. So in
most cases the amount of available resources is equal to the firm value as long it is expressed in
market values.
1 Introduction 15
8
6
4
Debt 2
payment 0
–2 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
–4
–6
The irm's ressources available
Debt
– No ownership interest
– Creditors do not have voting rights
– Interest is considered a cost of doing business and is tax deductible
– Creditors have legal recourse if interest or principal payments are
missed
– Excess debt can lead to financial distress and bankruptcy
Equity
– Ownership interest
– Common stockholders vote for the board of directors and other issues
– Dividends are not considered a cost of doing business and are not tax
deductible
– Dividends are not a liability of the firm and stockholders have no legal
recourse if dividends are not paid
– An all-equity firm cannot go bankrupt
In our example above, the founders may take into account that in
case of equity financing their control over the company will be reduced
16 Capital Structure in the Modern World
because new shareholders will get voting rights. Financing with debt may
bring tax advantage since interest is tax-deductible, etc.
References
Acharya, V., & Viswanathan, S. (2011). Leverage, moral hazard and liquidity.
Journal of Finance, 66, 99–138.
Bancel, F., & Mittoo, U. (2004). Cross-country determinants of capital struc-
ture choice: A survey of European firms. Financial Management, 33,
103–132.
Bancel F., & Mittoo, U. (2011). Survey evidence on financing decisions and cost
of capital. In H. K. Baker, & G. Martin (Eds.), Capital structure and corporate
financing decisions—Theory, evidence, and practice (pp. 229–248). Hoboken,
New Jersey: John Wiley, Ch. 13.
18 Capital Structure in the Modern World
Brounen, D., De Jong, A., & Koedijk, K. (2006). Capital structure policies in
Europe: Survey evidence. Journal of Banking & Finance, 30(5), 1409–1442.
Bulan, L., & Yan, Z. (2009). The pecking order theory and the firm’s life cycle.
Banking and Finance Letters, 1(3), 129–140.
Bulan, L., & Yan, Z. (2011). Firm maturity and the pecking order theory.
International Journal of Business and Economics, 9(3), 179–200.
Ewert, R., & Niemann, R. (2012). Limited liability, asymmetric taxation, and
risk taking—Why partial tax neutralities can be harmful. Finanzarchiv/Public
Finance Analysis, 68, 83–120.
Fisher, I. (1930). The theory of interest (1st ed.). New York: The Macmillan Co.
Frank, M., & Goyal, V. (2008). Profits and capital structure, AFA 2009 San
Francisco meetings paper. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/
abstract=1104886
Frank, M., & Goyal, V. (2009). Capital structure decisions: Which factors are
reliably important? Financial Management, 38, 1–37.
Gandel, S. (2015, December 4). McDonald’s Jumbo bond deal finds hungry
investors. Fortune. http://fortune.com/2015/12/04/mcdonalds-bond-deal/
Graham, J., & Harvey, C. (2001). The theory and practice of corporate finance:
Evidence from the field. Journal of Financial Economics, 60(2–3), 187–243.
Graham, J., & Harvey, C. (2002). How do CFOs make capital budgeting and
capital structure decisions? Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 15(1), 8–23.
Graham, J., & Leary, M. (2011). A review of empirical capital structure research
and directions for the future. Annual Review of Financial Economics, 3,
309–345.
Groom, N. (2007, July 24). McDonald’s reviews capital structure, CFO retir-
ing. Reuters/Markets. http://www.reuters.com/article/2007/07/24/
us-mcdonalds-results-idUSN2442330320070724
Harris, M., & Raviv, A. (1991). The theory of capital structure. The Journal of
Finance, 46(1), 297–355.
Hennessy, C., Livdan, D., & Miranda, B. (2010). Repeated signaling and firm
dynamics. Review of Financial Studies, 23(5), 1981–2023.
Horvath, M., & Woywode, M. (2005). Entrepreneurs and the choice of limited
liability. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics (JITE)/Zeitschrift
für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft, 161(4), 681–707.
Jain, B., & Kini, O. (1994). The post-issue operating performance of IPO firms.
Journal of Finance, 49(5), 1699–1726.
Khanna, S., Srivastava, A., & Medury, Y. (2014). Revisiting the capital structure
theories with special reference to India. The International Journal of Business
and Management, 8, 132–138.
1 Introduction 19
Klein, L., O’Brien, T., & Peters, S. (2002). Debt vs equity and asymmetric
information: A review. The Financial Review, 37(3), 317–350.
Lemmon, M., & Zender, J. (2010). Debt capacity and tests of capital structure
theories. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 45, 1161–1187.
Lindhe, T., Sodersten, J., & Oberg, A. (2004). Economic effects of taxing differ-
ent organizational forms under the Nordic dual income tax. International Tax
and Public Finance, 11(4), 469–485.
Loughran, T., Ritter, J., & Rydquist, K. (1994). Initial public offerings:
International insights. Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, 2, 165–199.
Manyika, J. (2011, August). Google’s CFO on growth, capital structure, and
leadership. McKinsey&Company. http://www.mckinsey.com/insights/corpo-
rate_finance/googles_cfo_on_growth_capital_structure_and_leadership
Miglo, A. (2007). A note on corporate taxation, limited liability and symmetric
information. Journal of Economics (Springer), 92(1), 11–19.
Miglo, A. (2011). Trade-off, pecking order, signaling, and market timing
Models. In H. K. Baker & G. S. Martin (Eds.), Capital structure and corporate
financing decisions: Theory, evidence, and practice (pp. 171–191). Wiley and
Sons, Ch. 10.
Modigliani, F., & Miller, M. (1958). The cost of capital, corporation finance
and the theory of investment. American Economic Review, 48(3), 261–297.
Pereira, T., & Sousa, M. (2015). Is there still a Berlin Wall in the post-issue
operating performance of European IPOs?. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.
com/abstract=2347535 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2347535
Ritter, J. (2014). Initial public offerings: Updated statistics. https://site.war-
rington.ufl.edu/ritter/files/2015/04/IPOs2013Un derpricing.pdf
Schiantarelli, F., & Jaramillo F. (2002). Access to long term debt and effects on
firms’ performance: Lessons from Ecuador No 3153, RES Working Papers
from Inter-American Development Bank, Research Department.
Shyam-Sunder, L., & Myers, S. (1999). Testing static tradeoff against pecking
order models of capital structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 51(2),
219–244.
Singh, P., & Kumar B. (2008). Trade off theory or pecking order theory: What
explains the behavior of the Indian firms? Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.
com/abstract=1263226
Wild, J., Shaw, K., & Chiappetta, B. (2014). Fundamental accounting principles.
McGraw-Hill Education, 22nd edition.
2
Modigliani-Miller Proposition and Trade-
off Theory
jurisdictions, which is consistent with the tax shield idea, as we will see
later in the chapter.1
The bankruptcy cost idea points out that increasing debt in a firm’s
capital structure increases its probability of bankruptcy. Since bankruptcy
is a very costly process, the incentive to increase debt should depend on
potential future bankruptcy costs. An interesting example represents the
situation in the US oil and drilling industry in 2014/2015. Oil prices fell
quickly in the middle of 2014, weakening the futures of many companies
in the industry. Gara (2015) described the situation in the industry and
noticed that ”…junk bond markets [were] decisively closed to the drill-
ing industry and stock prices [were] trading at levels that [made] equity
offerings extremely dilutive.”2 This is a classic example of indirect bank-
ruptcy costs that, as we will see later, reduce the incentive for firms to
issue debt. Even if a firm is not bankrupt, the market anticipates financial
difficulties, which results in decreased credit conditions, reduced share
price, loss of customer, etc.
Williams (1938) noticed that if a single individual or institutional
investor owned all the bonds, stocks and warrants issued by a corpora-
tion, it would not matter to this investor what the company’s capitaliza-
tion was. Modigliani and Miller (1958) further developed this idea, for
which they won the 1985 Nobel Price in Economics, by proving the
Modigliani–Miller (MM) theorem which states that when markets are
perfect (no taxes and no bankruptcy costs among other things), the capi-
tal structure does not have any impact on the value of the firm. For exam-
ple, a firm financed with 60 % equity and 40 % debt has the same value
as a firm financed with 30 % equity and 70 % debt. The idea behind
the MM theorem is that capital structure does not alter the total cash
flows produced by a firm’s assets (such as equipment, buildings, technol-
ogy, patents, etc.) or their riskiness, and that financial securities can only
redistribute value and not create it.
Proof
Suppose there are two identical firms with identical assets. The only dif-
ference between them is their capital structure. One firm is unlevered or
completely equity financed (firm U) and the other one has a mix of debt
and equity (firm L). Both firms produce the same earnings X. We will
prove MM by contradiction assuming that the firms’ values are different.
Two cases will be analyzed: Case 1, where the value of the unlevered firm
is greater than the value of the levered firm, and Case 2, where the value
of the levered firm is greater than the value of the unlevered firm.
Case 1
The value of the unlevered firm is greater than the value of the levered firm.
Vu > VL . Figure 2.1 shows the balance sheets of firms U and L using nota-
tions introduced in Chap. 1. Consider an investor that holds a fraction
α of firm U′s shares. What is his optimal strategy? Should he keep the
24 Capital Structure in the Modern World
αEU (note that since firm U does not have any debt, EU = VU ), buy a
α VU α VU
fraction of company L′s shares and buy a fraction of com-
VL VL
pany L ' s bonds. This strategy requires a net investment equal to
α VU αV
α VU − EL − U D . Since VL = D + EL the investment has zero cost.
VL VL
It also offers earnings from firm L ' s shares and interest on firm L ' s bonds
2 Modigliani-Miller Proposition and Trade-off Theory 25
α VU αV αV
that equal in total ( X − Dr ) + U Dr = U X . This is greater than
VL VL VL
αX (the investor’s expected earnings in the case of keeping firm U’s shares)
because by assumption VU > VL . Therefore, there is an arbitrage opportu-
nity. Thus, the assumption that VU > VL leads to a contradiction.
Case 2
The value of the levered firm is greater than the value of the unlevered firm.
Let VU < VL . Consider an investor holding a fraction α of firm L’s shares.
This investor can either choose to keep the fraction of the levered firm’s
shares or sell them and buy the unlevered firm’s shares.
Consider the following strategy: sell the shares for αVL, borrow αD,
buy a fraction αVL/VU of company U ' s shares. This strategy requires a net
α VL
investment equal to α (VL − D ) + α D − VU = 0 . It also offers earnings
VU
α VL V
equal to X − α Dr = α X L − rD . This is greater than α [ X − rD ]
VU VU
(the investor’s expected earnings in case of keeping firm L′s shares)
because by assumption VL > VU . Therefore, there is an arbitrage opportu-
nity. Thus, the assumption that VL > VU leads to a contradiction.
We have shown that any situation where VL Þ VU leads to a contradic-
tion. One can also show that if VL = VU then any strategy with zero invest-
ment cost does not produce extra profit. Examples would be the two
situations described above. In either case, if VL = VU , an investor using
the strategies described above will not increase profits. The irrelevance of
capital structure is the result of the investor’s ability to undo any effects of
the differences in the firms’ capital structures when operating in a perfect
financial market.
The following is a summary of the main ideas behind MM:
–– If the shares of levered firms are priced too high, investors will bor-
row on their own and use the money to buy shares in unlevered
firms. This is sometimes called homemade leverage.
26 Capital Structure in the Modern World
–– If the shares of unlevered firms are priced too high, investors will
buy shares in levered firms and buy bonds.
–– In order for capital structure to matter, there must be some market
imperfections that create friction in the process of either selling or
buying securities.
Example 2.1
Suppose two firms have the same assets that generate the same annual
earnings and differ only in how they are financed: Firm U is unlevered
(Vu = 220, 000 ). Firm L is levered; it has a long-term debt of 80,000. Thus,
the value of the equity is equal to: EL = VL − D = VL − 80, 000 . Next year,
there are two possible economic scenarios: if growth is slow, earnings
will be 4,000; if the economy/growth is strong, then earnings will be
120,000. The interest rate is 10 %. Suppose that Vu > VL = 200, 000 . Note
that debt is not risk-free (the firm will not be able to repay the debthold-
ers if growth is slow).
Consider two strategies of an investor holding 10 % of firm U’s shares.
Strategy 1: To keep 10 % of firm U ' s shares. Strategy 2: Sell the shares
for 0.1 ∗ 220, 000 = 22, 000 , buy 11 % of company L’s shares (the value is
0.11 ∗ 120, 000 = 13, 200 ) and buy 11 % of company L′s bonds (the value
is 0.11 ∗ 80, 000 = 8800 ).
As shown in Table 2.1, earnings from strategy 1 include earnings from
holding firm U′s shares. Earnings from strategy 2 include earnings from
holding firm L′s shares and interest on firm L′s bonds. One can see that
strategy 2 provides higher earnings in each scenario and thus is definitely
Table 2.1 Investments and earnings from strategies 1 and 2 in Example 2.1
Strategy 1 Strategy 2
Investment 0 22, 000 − 13, 200 − 8800 = 0
Earnings if 400 = 0.1∗ 4000 440 = 0.11∗ 4000
economy is weak
Earnings if 12, 000 = 0.1∗ 120, 000 13, 200 = 0.11∗ (120, 000 − 0.1∗ 80, 000 )
economy is strong
+0.1∗ 8800
2 Modigliani-Miller Proposition and Trade-off Theory 27
better than strategy 1.3 When the economy is weak, there are no earnings
from holding shares of firm U and interests on bonds are proportionally
split between the debtholders. In conclusion, there is an arbitrage oppor-
tunity, which means that the described situation is not an equilibrium.
Note that the arbitrage argument (and the MM proposition) still holds if
debt is not risk-free, assuming no bankruptcy costs.
debt from $12 billion to $5 billion, thus allowing the company to con-
tinue operating.6 This is not always the case: sometimes restructuring
fails and the company is liquidated. Ideally, a firm should continue if it is
worth more as a going concern than it would be in liquidation. However,
a conflict of interest between the lenders and the company may lead to
a failure.
2.4 C
orporate Income Taxes and Capital
Structure
Usually, interest on debt reduces a firm’s earnings and its amount of cor-
porate tax. There is a significant debate regarding the existence of cor-
porate taxes in the economy. In general, there are two major arguments
in favor of the tax. The first is a rent argument. The corporate tax can
principally capture the rent earned by owners of fixed factors without dis-
torting the investment decision. The second argument, the more popular
one in corporate finance literature, is that the corporate tax is the price
that corporations pay for limited liability of their shareholders. This leads
For more details about Enron’s story see Palepu and Healy (2003).
7
For more analysis of bankruptcy costs see, for example, Korteweg (2007).
8
2 Modigliani-Miller Proposition and Trade-off Theory 31
9
More recent discussions about the link between limited liability and corporate taxation can be
found, for example, in Miglo (2007).
32 Capital Structure in the Modern World
V = VU + TS ( D, I , T ) − BC ( D, I , B )
Here VU is the value of the unlevered firm (no debt), TS is the value
of the firm’s tax shield, which depends on the level of debt D, the firm’s
earnings I and the corporate tax rate T, and BC is the expected value of
the bankruptcy costs, which depend on the level of debt, the firm’s earn-
ings and parameter B that reflects the magnitude of bankruptcy costs
(B is low for example if the firm belongs to an industry with relatively
low bankruptcy costs and vice versa). TS usually equals the amount of
taxes saved from the fact that interests, in contrast to dividends, are tax-
deductible. In a dynamic version of this model, TS would represent the
present value of saved taxes over several periods of time. Usually it is
assumed that
10
For more about corporate tax rates across different countries see, for example, Devereux,
Lockwood, and Redoano (2008).
11
For a review see, for example, Frank and Goyal (2008), Miglo (2011) or Graham and Leary
(2011).
2 Modigliani-Miller Proposition and Trade-off Theory 33
have stronger effects since customers, banks, etc. tend to panic. The first
two conditions in (2.3) have a similar identity. An increase in the firm’s
income reduces the probability of bankruptcy. This explains the last two
conditions in (2.3).12
Figure 2.2 shows marginal TS and BC. When D exceeds D′ there is no
benefit from increasing debt (profit is zero and further reductions do not
make any contributions). The optimal level of debt D* is achieved when
the marginal benefit from a debt increase (marginal tax shield) equals the
marginal cost of a debt increase (marginal expected bankruptcy costs).
Example 2.2
Consider a firm that generates a random cash flow R that is uniformly
distributed between 0 and 100. The firm faces a constant tax rate of
0.3 on its corporate income. If the earnings are insufficient to cover the
promised debt payment, D, (for simplicity D represents interests only
and the principal is equal to 0) there is a deadweight loss of 0.1 ∗ D that is
used up in the process. This loss can include direct bankruptcy costs such
as fees paid to lawyers and indirect bankruptcy costs such as losses due
to a general lack of confidence in the firm. If earnings are large enough
( R > D ), equityholders receive ( R − D ) * (1 − 0.3). Otherwise, they receive
nothing.
The value of unlevered firm can be found as follows: VU = 50 * (1 − 0.3 ) = 35.
Here 100 / 2 = 50, which are the average earnings of the firm and 50 * 0.7
equals the expected net income.
100 − D D D 100 − D
TS = 0.3 * *D+ * . is the probability that
100 100 2 100
D
R > D and is the probability of default. If R > D , the debtholders
100
D
receive D (tax savings equal 0.3 * D) and they equal on average , if the
2
firm defaults.
12
See Van Binsbergen, Graham and Yang (2010) about more details in constructing TS and BC
using empirical data. In some of their graphs, there is a flat area of the marginal benefit curve when
the level of debt is very low and the tax rate is not affected by marginal debt changes. Qualitatively
it does not affect our conclusions.
2 Modigliani-Miller Proposition and Trade-off Theory 35
Fig. 2.3 Optimal level of debt under trade-off theory when B increases
100 − D D D D D * 0.1
V = VU + TS − BC = 50 * 0.7 + 0.3 * *D+ * − *
100 100 2 100 2
36 Capital Structure in the Modern World
2.6 T
heory Predictions and Empirical
Evidence
If B increases, then according to (2.3), the marginal cost of debt curve
moves up in Fig. 2.3 and the equilibrium level of D is lowered.
For empirical support of these predictions see, for example, Frank and Goyal (2009).
13
2 Modigliani-Miller Proposition and Trade-off Theory 37
Proposition 2.3 Firms with higher tax rates should have higher debt ratios
compared to firms with lower tax rates.
As mentioned in Miglo (2011), the empirical evidence regarding
Proposition 2.3 is mixed. More recent literature (Wright 2004; Philippon
and Reshev 2012; Strebulaev and Yang 2013; DeAngelo and Roll 2015)
began to closely analyze historical patterns in capital structure and
whether or not they can be explained by the traditional conclusions of
trade-off theory, described above. For example, asset tangibility declined
on average in the 20th century but at the same time the leverage ratio
increased (Graham et al. 2015). Taxes increased sharply between the
beginning of the 20th century (starting from 15 %) until 1950 when
they reached 50 % in the US. The leverage increase during that period
is consistent with the above predictions. In the 1980s, the corporate tax
rate reached around 35 % but leverage continued to grow. More research
is expected in this area.
As suggested in (2.3), if I increases, the marginal benefit curve moves
up, the marginal cost curve moves down and D should increase.
Fig. 2.4 Optimal level of debt under trade-off theory when I increases
2.4). If the marginal cost curve moves up and if this move is stronger than
that of the marginal benefit curve, optimal debt may go down, which can
explain the negative correlation between debt and profitability. In fact,
Van Binsbergen, Graham, and Yang (2011) find that the marginal cost
of debt is positively related to the firm’s cash, which is consistent with
the curve moving up in Fig. 2.4. Overall it seems that more research is
required regarding the marginal cost of debt curve.
The major challenge of classical trade-off theory remains empirical
evidence about the negative correlation between debt and profitability
because it does not directly follow from the standard model. On the
empirical side, papers addressing historical capital structure patterns over
large periods of time with trade-off theory look interesting and promising.
2 Modigliani-Miller Proposition and Trade-off Theory 39
The basic trade-off theory model does not include retained earnings,
transaction costs, and costs of raising funds. These factors are usually
important in what is called “dynamic trade-off theory.” Hennessy and
Whited (2005) analyze a model with equity flotation costs and show that
a negative correlation between debt and profitability may be observed
in some cases. Strebulaev (2007) analyzes a model where firms in dis-
tress have to sell their assets at a discount and therefore firms adjust their
capital structure infrequently. The model’s simulations can produce a
negative correlation between debt and profitability. Hackbarth, Miao,
and Morrellec (2006) and Bhamra, Kuehn, and Strebulaev (2010) pres-
ent costly adjustment models that can account for the dynamic relation
between leverage and macroeconomic characteristics. Danis, Rettl, and
Whited (2014) find that at times when firms are at or close to their opti-
mal level of leverage, the cross-sectional correlation between profitability
and leverage is positive. At other times, it is negative. Bolton, Cheng, and
Wang (2013) present a model of dynamic capital structure and liquidity
choice where debt adjustments are costly. The authors focus on the debt
servicing cost: debt payments drain the firm’s valuable precautionary cash
holdings and thus impose higher expected external financing costs on the
firm. The model can replicate a negative correlation between debt and
profitability.
In a recent review of empirical capital structure literature Graham and
Leary (2011) suggested the following directions for improving trade-
off theory results: fixing mis-measurement, for example calculations of
marginal tax benefits and marginal bankruptcy costs should be signifi-
cantly improved; new models are required in the area of partial adjust-
ment towards optimal capital structure; dynamic trade-off theory models
should still prove that they are indeed the primary drivers of capital
structure changes; and the methods of value estimation for transactions
related to capital structure changes should be more developed.
12. Suppose two firms have the same assets that generate the same earn-
ings and differ only in how the assets are financed: Firm U is unle-
vered (Vu = $100, 000). Firm L is levered; it has a debt of $40,000.
2 Modigliani-Miller Proposition and Trade-off Theory 41
References
Bhabra, G., & Yao, Y. (2011). Is bankruptcy costly? Recent evidence on the
magnitude and determinants of indirect bankruptcy costs. Journal of Applied
Finance & Banking, 1(2), 39–68.
Bharma, H., Kuehn, L., & Strebulaev, I. (2010). The aggregate dynamics of
capital structure and macroeconomic risk. Review of Financial Studies, 23(12),
4187–4241.
Bolton, P., Chen, H., & Wang, N. (2013). Market timing, investment, and risk
management. Journal of Financial Economics, 109, 40–62.
Bulan, L., & Sanyal, P. (2009). Is there room for growth? Debt, growth oppor-
tunities and the deregulation of U.S. electric utilities. Available at
SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=867004
Danis, A., Rettl, D., & Whited, T. (2014). Refinancing, profitability, and capital
structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 114(3), 424–443.
DeAngelo, H., & Roll, R. (2015). How stable are corporate capital structures?
Journal of Finance, 70(1), 373–418.
Devereux, M., Lockwood, B., & Redoano, M. (2008). Do countries compete
over corporate tax rates? Journal of Public Economics, 92(5-6), 1210–1235.
Fama, E., & French, K. (2002). Testing trade-off and pecking order predictions
about dividends and debt. Review of Financial Studies, 15(1), 1–33.
Faulkender, M., & Smith, J. (2014). Taxes and leverage at multinational corpo-
rations, western finance association, NBER Summer Institute, corporate
42 Capital Structure in the Modern World
line with Akerloff’s paper, with applications to credit markets with asym-
metric information.2 Applying this idea to the market for newly issued
shares, under asymmetric information, the market may collapse because
investors do not have enough information about the shares. Large com-
panies who are traded publicly in large organized public markets spend
a lot of money to inform the public about their companies: it is the
way they raise public equity. This is something that is fairly expensive
for small and private companies to do. NASDAQ’s idea is to help these
companies raise equity.
Another recent interesting topic is the IPO of a company called
Square. Square, Inc. deals with financial and merchant services; it is
an aggregator and mobile payment company based in California. The
company markets several software and hardware payment products,
including Square Register and Square Reader, and is expanding into
small business services such as Square Capital, a financing program,
and Square Payroll. The IPO price was $9. By the end of the day the
share price was $13. The $9 price was below the last round of funding
prices so it was a loss value for the company. Evan Niu discusses the
situation on Motley Fool.3 As he argues, the situation is not unusual for
IPO firms and by no means constitutes a sign of failure. As we will learn
later in the chapter, this phenomenon is caused by asymmetric informa-
tion between firms and investors and is called the “IPO underpricing”
phenomenon.
2
Akerloff and Stiglitz both won the Nobel Prize for their contributions to asymmetric information
research.
3
Niu (November 21, 2015).
3 Asymmetric Information and Capital Structure 47
Insiders may not be able to fully disclose their information to the firm’s
claimholders. Grinblatt and Titman (2001) argue that among the reasons
for this are that the information may be valuable to competitors; there is a
risk of being sued by investors if they make forecasts that later turn out to be
inaccurate;4 and managers may be reluctant to disclose “bad” information.
As a result, investors will try to incorporate indirect evidence in their
valuation, which is done through the analysis of information-revealing
actions (signals). These can include investment decisions, financing deci-
sions, dividend decisions, etc. This chapter discusses some of the major
ideas relating to the problem of asymmetric information.
See Stempel (December 18, 2013) for a recent example with Facebook’s IPO.
4
48 Capital Structure in the Modern World
Firms decide
Earnings are
Owners learn whether to
realized and
their irm's use internal
distributed to
type funds, issue
claimholders
debt or equity
knows that there are two firms on the market and one of them has poten-
tial earnings c1 and the other c2.
To solve this situation, game theory is typically used as the main tool.
Players are: Firm 1, Firm 2 and the Investor. Firm 1 and 2 represent
the existing shareholders of each firm’s type. The Investor can provide
financing or buy securities as long as the expected earnings cover the
investment. It is usually justified by the assumption that the investor is
risk-neutral and that the risk-free interest rate is zero.5 What are the pos-
sible outcomes of this game? Usually the Nash equilibrium concept is
used. Famous mathematician John Forbes Nash received a Nobel Prize
for his work on game theory. A Nash equilibrium is a situation where no
participants have any incentive to deviate from the equilibrium given the
strategies played by the other players.
Since both firms have large amounts of internal funds available, a pos-
sible equilibrium is one where both firms use internal funds to finance
their projects. The payoff for the owners of firm t will be equal to
i + ct − k, t = 1, 2. The same holds for the situation where both firms use
debt. Note that debt is risk-free in our model since firms have enough
internal funds that can be used as an insurance fund to cover the initial
investment. Now consider equity issues. Does the situation where both
firms issue equity represent an equilibrium?
To answer this question, first consider a hypothetical situation where
the Investor knows the firm’s type (perfect information case) and Firm 1
issues equity. Since the Investor knows the firm’s expected earnings, the
Investor purchases Firm 1’s shares at fair value. What fraction of the firm’s
k
shares will be sold? The Investor will receive α = . In this case the
i + c1
This assumption will be used in most models throughout the book unless otherwise specified.
5
3 Asymmetric Information and Capital Structure 49
k
Investor’s payoff equals: α ( i + c1 ) = ( i + c1 ) = k . This equals the ini-
i + c1
tial amount of investment. The initial owners’ profit for Firm 1 is
(1 − α ) ( i + c1 ) = i + c1 − k
It is the same profit that the owners of Firm 1 could get by using internal
financing.
Now consider the case with imperfect information. What if the
Investor believes that the firm is type 2 instead? Then the Investor will
k
demand a fraction of equity equal to α = . The Firm 1 owners' pay-
i + c2
k
off in this case is (1 − α ) ( i + c1 ) = 1 − ( i + c1 ) .
i + c2
As shown in Fig. 3.2 the payoff of the initial shareholders of Firm 1
depends on the expected earnings of Firm 2 and, respectively, the fraction
of shares the Investor will ask for in exchange for their investment in the
project. If c2 < c1, the Investor will perceive the firm to be of lower quality
than it really is. The Investor will ask for a large fraction of shares and the
payoff for the initial shareholders of Firm 1 will be lower than it would
be in the case of perfect information (that could be achieved for example
by using internal funds for financing the project).
Below we argue that a firm with higher expected earnings never issues
equity in equilibrium. First consider a situation where firms use different
strategies (separating equilibrium). Suppose that c2 > c1 and Firm 2 issues
equity and Firm 1 uses internal funds or risk-free debt. Firm 1 owners�
payoff equals i + c1 − k . However, if Firm 1 decides to mimic Firm 2, its
owners’ payoff will increase as follows from Fig. 3.2. Therefore, this situ-
ation is not an equilibrium.
Now consider a situation where both firms issue shares (also called
pooling equilibrium since both firms use the same strategy) and suppose
that c1 > c2. As was argued above, Firm 1 will issue equity only if the
k
Investor is willing to buy shares for no more than α = fraction of
i + c1
equity. In this case, however, the Investor loses money. The Investor will
buy shares of Firm 1 with probability 50 % and make no losses in this
case, but with probability 50 % the Investor will buy shares of Firm 2 and
this will bring: k ( i + c2 ) , which is less than k because c2 < c1 . Therefore,
i + c1
the situation where both firms issue equity is not an equilibrium.
So far, we have assumed that a firm can issue risk-free debt or equity
with no cost. If we relax one of these assumptions, in order to avoid any
loss of value, the higher quality firm needs to use internal funds. This
leads to the following result.
If good quality firms use internal financing and if bad quality firms
choose their financing randomly, then, on average, internal funds will be
a dominant source of financing. On a large scale, this result appears to be
true. If one considers the aggregate balance sheet of American corpora-
tions, one can see that internal funds represent about 60–70 % of all invest-
ment financing sources. What about the debt/equity choice? To attack this
question, let us assume that in the above model firms do not have internal
3 Asymmetric Information and Capital Structure 51
funds available or that i = 0 . Also, suppose that debt is still risk-free, i.e.
k < c2 < c1. Similarly to the previous case, one can show that there are no
equilibria where Firm 1 issues equity. In this case, Firm 1 will lose value.
Possible equilibria then include cases when both firms issue debt or Firm
1 issues debt and Firm 2 issues equity. This leads to the following result.
What if debt is not risk-free, which is usually the case in real life?
Assume for example that c2 < k < c1. In this case, Firm 1 cannot avoid
losing value. Since debt is not risk-free and since the firm’s type is private
information, the Investor will charge a positive interest rate when provid-
ing debt financing. If the Investor provides a loan with zero interest rate
assuming that it faces Firm 1 (which would be the case under perfect
information), Firm 2 will mimic this strategy and ask for a loan with
an interest rate equal to zero and then the Investor will sustain a loss on
average. So the only candidates left to be the equilibrium are cases when
both firms issue debt or both firms issue equity. Some articles argue that
equilibria with debt usually dominate ones with equity since value loss
for a good quality firm is typically smaller in the case of debt than in the
case of equity. Intuitively, debt is a security that is less sensitive to value
fluctuation (Nachman and Noe, 1994).
Propositions 3.1 and 3.2 lead to the so-called pecking order theory
or POT (Myers and Majluff 1984 and Myers 1984): under asymmetric
information firms prefer to use internal funds, then debt, and equity is
only a last resort.
Example 3.1
Consider a firm that has the opportunity to undertake an investment
project. The project’s cost is 70. The project will bring a revenue of 90
and the firm will be liquidated. The risk-free interest rate is 0. The firm
has issued 100 shares outstanding. The firm has 100 in cash when it
makes the decision about the project. Since the firm has enough money
52 Capital Structure in the Modern World
to pay the cost of the new project, it can do so. It can also issue additional
equity to finance the project.
If the firm decides to use internal funds, the shareholders’ final profit
will be 100 − 70 + 90 = 120. The shareholders will be interested in pursu-
ing this strategy since their payoff is higher than in the case when the firm
does not undertake the new project (120 > 100). In other words, the net
present value of the new project is positive: NPV = 120 − 100 = 20 .
Now consider the case when the firm issues equity. Outside investors
know the amount of cash the firm has (100) and they also know the value
of the earnings from the new project (90). When they buy equity and
get a fraction α of the firm, their payoff is α190, which should be equal
to 70 (investment cost), which implies: α = 70 / 190 = 7 / 19 . The initial
shareholders’ payoff is (1 − α )190 = 120. Note that the initial shareholders’
payoff is the same under any strategy (120). This is consistent with the
spirit of the perfect market concept (capital structure irrelevance).
Now let us look at the asymmetric information case. Assume that earn-
ings from the project can either be high (90) or low (30). Outside inves-
tors believe that its value will be 90 with a prior probability of 50 %. Does
a situation where both firms issue equity, or one firm issues equity and
the other one uses internal cash for the project, represent an equilibrium?
If the shareholders use cash to finance the project, their final payoff
for the high earnings firm is 100 − 70 + 90 = 120 and for the low earnings
firm is 100 − 70 + 30 = 60. Now consider the case where the high earnings
firm issues equity and the low earnings firm uses cash for the project. The
fraction of equity sold to investors equals 7/19. The initial shareholders’
payoff for the high earnings firm is (1 − 7 / 19 ) * (100 + 90 ) = 120. However,
it cannot be an equilibrium. If the shareholders of the low earnings firm
decide to issue equity as well (and “mimic” the high earnings firm), their
4
payoff will be: (1 − 7 / 19 ) * (100 + 30 ) = 82 . This is definitely greater
19
than what they can get by using cash for the project.
Now consider the case where both firms issue equity. Investors will
rationally anticipate that they will invest in the high earnings firm with
only a 50 % probability. So the minimum fraction of shares acceptable
for outsiders is
3 Asymmetric Information and Capital Structure 53
70 7
α= = d
100 + 0.5 * 30 + 0.5 * 90 16
We also have p∆n = k , where p is the price of newly issued shares. Along
with (3.1) it implies:
i + c2 − k (3.2)
p=
n
0.5 ∗ ( i + c1 − k ) + 0.5 ∗ ( i + c2 − k )
(3.3)
n
However, after the issue is announced, the share price is given by (3.2)
since only Firm 2 can issue shares in equilibrium. The price determined
in (3.2) is smaller than in (3.2) because c2 < c1.
the project (recall that the capital structure choice of the low quality firm
does not matter). When i < k, the high quality firm will issue debt. So
one should observe a negative correlation between the value of i and the
amount of debt issued in this model, which proves Proposition 3.4.
For example, if in the basic model c2 = c1 firms can issue equity without
the risk of being mis-valued: in this case, there is no negative reaction to
an equity issue announcement. However, when c2 Þ c1, Firm 1 will not
issue equity in equilibrium.
As mentioned in Miglo (2011), the empirical evidence regarding firms
following pecking order is mixed.6 The negative reaction to equity issues,
or in general to leverage reducing transactions, usually finds empirical
support. The negative correlation between debt and profitability usually
also finds empirical support as discussed in Chap. 2. The evidence regard-
ing the link between the extent of asymmetric information and capital
structure choice is mixed.
Among more recent articles note the following. De Jong et al. (2010)
test POT by separating the effects of financing surpluses, normal defi-
cits, and large deficits. Using a panel of U.S firms between 1971 and
2005, they find that POT works best for firms with surpluses and worst
for firms with large financing deficits. These findings highlight a puzzle
that small firms, although they have the highest potential for asymmetric
information, do not behave according to POT. The authors argue that
these results are consistent with the debt capacity in the pecking order
model. De Jong, Verbeek, and Verwijmeren (2011) test the static trade-
off theory prediction that a firm increases leverage until it reaches its
target debt ratio, and the prediction of POT that debt is issued until the
debt capacity is reached. It is found that POT is a better descriptor of
firms’ issue decisions than the static trade-off theory. Dong et al. (2012)
study market timing and pecking order in a sample of debt and equity
See, for example, Shyam-Sunder and Myers (1999), Frank and Goyal (2003), and Leary and
6
Roberts (2010).
56 Capital Structure in the Modern World
issues and share repurchases of Canadian firms from 1998 to 2007. They
find that only when firms are not overvalued do they prefer debt to equity
financing. Saumitra (2012) tests POT for an emerging economy through
a case study of the Indian corporate sector that includes 556 manufactur-
ing firms over the period 1997–2007. The study finds strong evidence in
favor of the pecking order hypothesis. Bhama et al. (2015) examine firms
(in India and China) with normal as well as large deficits and surpluses.
The study finds that Indian and Chinese firms frequently issue debt when
they have normal deficits. The pecking order results are less supportive
for Indian firms with large deficits. Mogilevsky and Murgulov (2012)
examine underpricing of private equity backed IPOs listed on a major US
stock exchange between January 2000 and December 2009. The authors
identify 265 private equity backed IPOs and compare these with concur-
rently listed venture capital (VC) backed and non-sponsored IPOs. The
results indicate that, on average, private equity backed IPOs experience a
significantly lower level of underpricing than venture capital backed and
non-sponsored IPOs.
3.4 W
hen Incumbent Shareholders Are
Risk-Averse
In traditional pecking order models, like the one discussed in the previ-
ous section, good quality firms are forced to use internal funds if available
to avoid adverse selection problems and a loss in value. If internal funds
are not available, these firms will issue debt. In the latter case, they are
mimicked by low quality firms. Therefore, in either case, good quality
firms cannot signal their quality by changing their capital structures. The
following sections discuss models in which capital structure choice will
indeed serve as a signal of a firm’s quality (Leland and Pyle (1977) and
Ross (1977)).
In Leland and Pyle (1977) the incumbent shareholders are risk-averse.
It will be shown that if a firm’s future is favorable, the shareholders may
accept a bigger risk or a bigger fraction of ownership. This leads to a “risk-
bearing” signaling idea.
3 Asymmetric Information and Capital Structure 57
Perfect Information
In this case, the entrepreneur definitely benefits from selling the firm to
an investor. Since the investors are risk-neutral and the risk-free interest
rate is 0, the price of the transaction (the entrepreneur’s return) is: P = θ .
If the entrepreneur does not sell the firm, he will still have θ in expecta-
tion but it will involve some risk because the firm’s return is stochastic. It
is always better to sell the project because of risk aversion. The entrepre-
neur’s wealth in this case is w = θ and the expected utility is θ.
since the information is perfect, the firm’s price correctly reflects the
firm’s expected earnings: P = αθ .
Thus, the entrepreneur’s expected utility is θ − 1 / 2 β (1 − α ) σ 2 . The
2
Example 3.2
To illustrate this idea, suppose there are two firms with the parameters of
return described in Table 3.1:
As was argued above, if the information about the expected profits were
public then Firm 1 would be sold for 100 and Firm 2 would be sold for
Investors
Entrepreneurs observe fractions
decide whether of equity offered
Entrepreneurs to sell the irm for sales by each
learn their irm's and what irm and select
type fraction of equity prices.
should be offered Entreprneurs
for sale expected utilities
can be calculated
200. Suppose that the entrepreneurs sell their firms even if the informa-
tion about expected returns is private. The price in this case will be 150.
The investors will be ready to buy the firm for an average expected return.
Consider the entrepreneurs’ expected utilities. The entrepreneur of Firm
1 will obviously benefit from selling the firm for 150. His expected util-
ity will be 150. If he keeps the firm, his expected utility is less than 100.
What about the entrepreneur of Firm 2?
1
If he does not sell the firm, his expected utility is 200 − ρ100 = 200 − 50 ρ .
2
If he sells, then it is 150. The entrepreneur is only interested in selling the
firm if ρ > 1. Otherwise, he will keep his shares.
An implication of this result is that firms in industries with a high
degree of asymmetric information (for example, research firms) are often
characterized by entrepreneurs owning large fractions of equity.
Suppose there are two firms with expected profits θ1 and θ2, θ2 > θ1.
The market only knows that θ = θ1 with probability π1 (Firm 1) and θ = θ 2
with probability π2 (Firm 2). Similar to the argument in the above exam-
ple, Firm 1 is always interested in selling the firm. Suppose Firm 2 is also
sold. Since the market cannot distinguish between the firms, it will pay
the “average” price: P = θ1π 1 + θ2π 2 .
The incentive to sell the firm depends on the following condition for
1
the entrepreneur from Firm 2: θ1π 1 + θ2π 2 ≥ θ2 − ρσ 2, which can be
2
1
written as follows: π 1 (θ2 − θ1 ) ≤ ρσ 2. This condition is not necessarily
2
1
satisfied. Firm 2 will not be sold if π 1 (θ2 − θ1 ) > ρσ 2.
2
The larger the difference between the firms’ expected profits then
the greater the probability of this condition being satisfied. This proves
Proposition 3.6.
Proposition 3.7 The entrepreneur’s fraction of the firm’s shares increases the
higher the expected return of the assets, the lower the firm’s risk, and the lower
the entrepreneur’s degree of risk aversion.
Signaling
How can the market inefficiency described above be resolved? The idea
for the high profit type is to find actions that will not be mimicked by the
low profit type. The market will thus be able to distinguish the types and
pay a higher price for the shares of the high profit type. Consider partial
selling of the project. Denote the fraction of ownership retained by the
entrepreneur with α. Suppose that Firm 1 sells its shares completely while
Firm 2 sells only (1 − α ) of its shares. The payoff for the entrepreneur from
Firm 1 is θ1 while the wealth of the entrepreneur from Firm 2 is
(1 − α )θ2 + α Rθ 2
= θ 2 − 1 / 2 ρα 2σ 2 (3.4)
tion (1 − α ) of Firm 1’s shares for a higher price. However, the remain-
ing shares will have to be held, which implies some risk-sharing with
other shareholders. The separation condition (incentive for Firm 1 not
to mimic Firm 2) is: θ1 ≥ (1 − α )θ2 + αθ1 − 1 / 2 ρα σ . This condition can
2 2
be written as
α2 2 (θ 2 − θ1 )
≥ (3.5)
1−α ρσ 2
Note that according to (3.4) the payoff for the entrepreneur from Firm 2
is decreasing in α. Therefore, the optimal α for this entrepreneur would
be minimal α which satisfies (3.5). It is given by
α2 2 (θ 2 − θ1 )
=
1−α ρσ 2
Since the left part of this equation increases with α, there is a positive
correlation between θ2 and α. Similarly, there is a negative correlation
between α and the firm’s risk (σ2) and the entrepreneur’s degree of risk
aversion ρ. This proves Proposition 3.7.
1−α ρ100
α 2
The condition becomes: = 4. Solving for α, given that 0 < α < 1,
1−α
gives: α ≈ 0.83. Therefore, the entrepreneur of Firm 2 should keep
approximately 83 % of the shares and sell 17 %.
8
See, among others, Eckbo (1986), Howton et al. (1998), Antweiler and Frank (2006) and Miglo
(2011).
62 Capital Structure in the Modern World
else happen?
It is easy to assume that we indeed have a market with asymmetric
information. In the primary market for mortgages, banks may not have
a complete picture of the “quality” of their borrowers since the analysis
of private borrowers is usually based on their credit history and does
not take many other factors into consideration. In the secondary market,
it is a pretty obvious assumption that financial institutions, including
banks, have more information about the quality of mortgages in their
portfolios than potential buyers. In the primary market, as in any other
credit market with asymmetric information, interest rates should remain
relatively high to limit the number of low quality borrowers.9 Any politi-
cally motivated downward pressure on interest rates or problems in the
screening process will result in lower interest rates and a high number
of low quality borrowers. In the secondary market, when the extent of
asymmetric information is significant enough, there is no equilibrium
where good quality items remain on the market (or good quality shares as
in the pecking order model, or good quality cars as in the used car market
of Akerloff). As the “lemon” model predicts, there are no deals for good
quality items (mortgages in this case) that are pushed off the market by
bad quality items.
How should the market solve the problems of asymmetric informa-
tion? First, any political pressure in markets with a high degree of asym-
metric information can be very damaging and thus should be avoided.
Second, as we know, in the market for used cars, sellers can purchase
independent warrants or certificates that will describe the quality of their
cars. Only good cars will be able to pass a test like this. In the market for
new shares, there is a sophisticated due diligence process that involves
professional underwriters, auditors, independent analysts, etc. Similar
systems should probably exist in the market for mortgages and mortgage-
backed securities.
Beltran and Thomas (2010) noted that a key feature of the 2007–
2008 financial crisis was that for some classes of securities trade ceased.
And where trade did occur, it appears that market prices were well below
their intrinsic values. The authors argue that one explanation for this is
the initial assets can take two values, $40 million and $160 mil-
lion. The true value of this is unknown in the beginning but is
soon known by the entrepreneur (insider). Outside investors have
a prior probability of 50 % that the value equals $160 million.
Analyze the situation where both types of firm issue equity and
invest.
(d) Now analyze the situation where only one type of firm issues
equity and invests.
(e) Describe the share price dynamics. Find the share price: (1) before
the information about the project is known to the public; (2) at
the moment when the market knows about the project but the
firms have not yet issued equity; (3) at the moment when the
firms issue equity.
(f ) Which two phenomena are illustrated here?
6. Consider a firm owned by a risk-averse entrepreneur. The entrepre-
neur’s expected utility is Ew − 1 / 2 ρVarw where w is the entrepreneur’s
wealth. The firm has assets-in-place that can bring a net return Rθ,
which is normally distributed with the mean θ and standard deviation
σ. θ is the entrepreneur’s private information and σ is the public infor-
mation. Potential investors are risk-neutral. The risk-free interest rate
is 0. There are two types of firms (the fraction of each type is 50 %):
one with θ = 20 (Firm 1) and the other with θ = 100 (Firm 2). σ 2 = 50
and it is publicly observable information.
References
Akerlof, G. (1970). The market for “lemons”: Quality uncertainty and the mar-
ket mechanism. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84(3), 488–500.
Antweiler, W., & Frank, M. (2006). Do U.S. stock markets typically overreact
to corporate news stories? Working Paper, University of British Columbia
and University of Minnesota.
Beltran, D., & Thomas, C. (2010). Could asymmetric information alone have
caused the collapse of private-label securitization? Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System International Finance Discussion Papers N. 1010.
Bhama, V., Jain, P., & Yadav, S. (2015). Does firms’ pecking order vary during
large deficits and surpluses? An empirical study on emerging economies.
Procedia Economics and Finance 30, 155–163. IISES 3rd and 4th Economics
and Finance Conference.
De Jong, A., Verbeek, M., & Verwijmeren, P. (2010). The impact of financing
surpluses and large financing deficits on tests of the pecking order theory.
Financial Management, 39(2), 733–756.
De Jong, A., Verbeek, M., & Verwijmeren, P. (2011). Firms’ debt–equity deci-
sions when the static tradeoff theory and the pecking order theory disagree.
Journal of Banking and Finance, 35(5), 1303–1314.
Dong, M., Loncarski, I., ter Horst, J., & Veld, C. (2012). What drives security
issuance decisions: Market timing, pecking order, or both? Financial
Management, 41(3), 637–663.
Eckbo, B. E. (1986). Valuation effects of corporate debt offerings. Journal of
Financial Economics, 15(1), 119–151.
Frank, M., & Goyal, V. (2003). Testing the pecking order theory of capital
structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 67(2), 217–248.
Frank, M., & Goyal, V. (2009). Capital structure decisions: Which factors are
reliably important? Financial Management, 38, 1–37.
Garcia, D. (2002). Retained equity, investment decisions and private informa-
tion. Tuck School of Business Working Paper No. 01–05. Available at SSRN:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=289801
Grinblatt, M., & Titman, S. (2001). Financial markets and corporate strategy
(2nd ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Howton, S. D., Howton, S. W., & Perfect, S. (1998). The market reaction to
straight debt issues: The effects of free cash flow. Journal of Financial Research,
21(2), 219–228.
3 Asymmetric Information and Capital Structure 67
Kaminska, I. (2015, October 30). If you call it a blockchain, it’s not an OTC
story anymore. FT Alphaville. http://ftalphaville.ft.com/2015/10/30/2143421/
if-you-call-it-a-blockchain-its-not-an-otc-story-anymore/
Kirabaeva, K. (2011). Adverse selection and financial crises. Bank of Canada
Review, 2010–2011(Winter), 11–19.
Leary, M. T., & Roberts, M. (2010). The pecking order, debt capacity, and
information asymmetry. Journal of Financial Economics, 95(3), 332–355.
Leland, H. E., & Pyle, D. (1977). Information asymmetries, financial structure,
and financial intermediation. Journal of Finance, 32(2), 371–378.
Miglo, A. (2011). Trade-off, pecking order, signaling and market timing models.
in H. K. Baker & G. S. Martin (Eds.) Capital structure and corporate financing
decisions: Theory, evidence, and practice (pp. 171–190). Hoboken, New Jersey:
Wiley, Ch. 10.
Mogilevsky, V., & Murgulov, Z. (2012). Underpricing of private equity backed,
venture capital backed and non-sponsored IPOs. Investment Management
and Financial Innovations, 9(3), 47–59.
Myers, S. C. (1984). The capital structure puzzle. Journal of Finance, 39,
575–592.
Myers, S. C., & Majluf, N. (1984). Corporate financing and investment deci-
sions when firms have information that investors do not have. Journal of
Financial Economics, 13(2), 187–221.
Nachman, D., & Noe, T. (1994). Optimal design of securities under asymmet-
ric information. Review of Financial Studies, 7(1), 1–44.
Niu, E. (2015, November 21). Did square underprice its IPO? The Motley Fool.
http://www.fool.com/investing/general/2015/11/21/did-square-underprice-
its-ipo.aspx
Ross, S. A. (1977). The determination of financial structure: The incentive sig-
naling approach. Bell Journal of Economics, 8(1), 23–40.
Saumitra, B. (2012). Why do firms issue equity? Some evidence from an emerg-
ing economy, India working paper MLPR.
Shyam-Sunders, L., & Myers, S. (1999). Testing static tradeoff against pecking order
models of capital structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 51(2), 219–244.
Stempel, J. (2013, December 18). Facebook, Zuckerberg, banks must face IPO
lawsuit: Judge. Reuters. http://www.reuters.com/article/us-facebook-ipo-
lawsuit-idUSBRE9BH0VD20131218
Stiglitz, J., & Weiss, A. (1981). Credit rationing in markets with imperfect
information. The American Economic Review, 71(3), 393–410.
Varas, F. (2014). Trading dynamics of financial assets under asymmetric infor-
mation. Duke University. Fuqua School of Business. Working Paper.
4
Credit Rationing and Asset Substitution
4.1 S
hareholders Versus Creditors: Capital
Structure Battle
Agency problems exist between shareholders and managers. In this rela-
tionship, shareholders are the principals and they do not have direct
control over the managers’ actions (agent). This chapter analyzes the
shareholder–creditor agency problems where creditors (principal) can-
not control the actions of the shareholders (firm’s owners) responsible for
major decisions.
Recall that in a perfect market the firm undertakes projects with posi-
tive NPVs. Also, in a perfect market, contracts are easily enforceable and
shareholders’ decisions are easy to contract. So creditors and shareholders
write a contract according to which the creditors will get their investments
back and shareholders will choose projects with positive NPVs or, when
projects are mutually exclusive, the shareholders will choose the project
with maximal NPV. Both shareholders and creditors have the same goal:
to maximize the value of their investment. This goal is achieved when
firms use the policy described above. But this mutual goal is the cause of
their conflicting interests when markets are imperfect. Throughout this
chapter, and the next chapter, we will discuss the reasons why creditors
and shareholders often support different corporate decisions in order to
maximize the values of their claims. Two kinds of distortions may arise
from agency problems between creditors and shareholders. This chapter
considers the shareholders’ tendency to invest in very risky projects, pos-
sibly even in projects with negative NPVs. The next chapter will look at
situations when the shareholder–creditor conflict leads to underinvest-
ment in positive NPV projects.
Potential conflicts between creditors and shareholders explain many
interesting phenomena in financial markets. One of them is called “credit
rationing.” Josef Stiglitz and Andrew Weiss described it in their 1981
article. Credit rationing is a situation where financial institutions, such as
banks, refuse to increase interest rates clearing the demand for loans, even
when the demand is coming from firms with profitable projects. This is
an unusual situation for market economies because, traditionally, prices
(interest rates in a market for loans) were supposed to be flexible enough
to equalize demand and supply. In November 2015, Ruth Simon pub-
lished an article in the Wall Street Journal entitled “Big Banks Cut Back
on Loans to Small Business.” The article argues that the biggest banks
in the US are making far fewer loans to small businesses than they did
a decade ago thus ceding market share to alternative lenders that charge
significantly higher rates. Together, 10 of the largest banks issuing small
loans to businesses lent $44.7 billion in 2014, down 38 % from a peak of
$72.5 billion in 2006, according to an analysis of the banks’ federal regu-
latory filings. The largest banks “have essentially abandoned the small
business market,” said Dr. Cole, DePaul University finance professor.
Some entrepreneurs had to borrow on-line where interest rates are as high
as 80%.1 This chapter will provide some insight into these phenomena.
Earnings are
A irm's Shareholders
realized and
capital select an
distributed
structure is investment
to
determined project
claimholders
The result was quite surprising for many analysts. Nabisco’s share price
went up and its bond’s price went down: reflecting the negative impact of
the risky investment on the creditors’ value.2
There are quite a few ways to measure risk. The main theoretical way is
with the mean preserving spread criterion (MPS) or increasing risk domi-
nance (IR).3 If one stochastic variable dominates another by the MPS or
IR criterion, then it is considered less risky.
To illustrate the idea of asset substitution, consider a company that is
deciding between two projects. A project j brings cash flow Rj, j = 1, 2 .
The company has debt with a face value D. R1 is distributed according to
the distribution function F and density function f and R2 is distributed
according to the distribution function G and density function g.
The timing of events in this situation (and most other situations con-
sidered in this chapter and Chap. 5) is shown in Fig. 4.1. The key aspect
of this model is that creditors do not have direct control over the share-
holders’ actions. Even if the firm gets financing from creditors, it is up
to the shareholders to make the final decisions. In contrast to the models
with asymmetric information from Chap. 3 this chapter and Chap. 5
analyze models with moral hazard.
The shareholders’ payoff is 0 when R < D and it is R − D otherwise.
Then the difference between the shareholders’ expected payoffs from
undertaking projects 1 and 2 are
2
See Warga and Welch (1993) about wealth shifting during 1980s buyouts. Also see http://www.
investopedia.com/articles/stocks/09/corporate-kleptocracy-rjr-nabisco.asp
3
See the Appendix for more information about stochastic dominance, mean-preserving spread
condition etc.
4 Credit Rationing and Asset Substitution 73
R R R
∆T = ∫ ( R − D ) f ( R ) dR − ∫ ( R − D ) g ( R ) dR = ∫ ( R − D ) ( f ( R ) − g ( R ) ) dR
D D D
Let v = R − D and du = ( f ( R ) − g ( R ) ) dR . Then
R
∆T = ( R − D ) ( F ( R ) − G ( R ) ) |R
D ∫ ( F ( R ) − G ( R ) ) dR
−
D
R
= ∫ ( G ( R ) − F ( R ) ) dR (4.1)
D
Example 4.1
The following example will illustrate the shareholders’ incentive to under-
take projects with low or even negative NPVs. Consider a company that
is deciding between two one-year projects, A and B. Both projects have
the same investment cost, 70,000, but are expected to generate different
earnings. The amount of earnings depends on the state of nature. There
are two states of nature: good (g) and bad (b), with equal probability. For
simplicity, assume that there are no bankruptcy costs. Also assume that a
banker exists that is ready to finance the firm’s investment by providing a
70,000 one-year loan with 5 % interest so the company has a debt due in
one year with a face value of 73,500.
The payoffs from the projects and their expected earnings are indicated
in Table 4.1. Clearly, Project B has higher expected earnings and a higher
NPV because both projects have the same investment cost. Furthermore,
the NPV of Project A is negative regardless of the interest rates because
the expected earnings are smaller than the investment cost. Nevertheless,
the project that is undertaken by the firm is the one that will yield the
greatest payoff to the shareholders (see Table 4.2).
Therefore, Project A will be chosen even though Project B has a higher
NPV. The reason is that Project A has more risk. Its cash flow is either
too high or too low. It is the “too high” situation that made this project
attractive to shareholders. The projects are such that given the firm’s debt,
both projects bring nothing to shareholders in bad times while in good
times Project A is definitely better.
Note that if Project A brings 25,000 in state b, Project B dominates
Project A by the MPS condition: the projects’ expected earnings are equal
but Project A has a higher risk. The shareholders will choose Project A,
which illustrates Proposition 4.2. Alternatively, suppose that in the initial
situation, Project B brings 125,000 in state g. One can check that in this
case Project B dominates Project A by FOD. One can also check that
See Gavish and Kalay (1983) and Green and Talmor (1986) for further analysis of this topic.
4
76 Capital Structure in the Modern World
This result implies that by changing the level of debt firms can con-
trol the incentive for an asset substitution problem. So one would expect
that firms with a greater potential to have an asset substitution problem
should have smaller debt.
Example 4.2
There are two states of nature: g with probability p and b with probability
1 − p . Consider a firm with two investment projects available with earn-
ings along with their expected earnings shown in Table 4.3.
Projects are mutually exclusive. We make the following assumptions:
(1) Y2 > X 2 > X1 > Y1 ; (2) X 2 + (1 − p ) X1 > pY2 + (1 − p ) Y1 (the interpreta-
tion of these assumptions is that Project A has a higher NPV and Project
B is riskier); and (3) The company has issued debt with a face value D.
If D < Y1 , the shareholders will select Project A. Their payoff in this case is
pX 2 + (1 − p ) X1 − D which is greater than Project B’s: pY2 + (1 − p ) Y1 − D.
Consider D such that X1 > D > Y1. The shareholder’s payoff if A is
chosen is pX 2 + (1 − p ) X1 − D and if B it is p (Y2 − D ) . The latter can be
written as: pY2 + (1 − p ) Y1 − D + (1 − p ) D − (1 − p ) Y1. This is greater than
pX 2 + (1 − p ) X1 − D because D > Y1. We can then conclude that Project B
will be chosen. The conclusion is the same for the case when X 2 > D > X1 .
The shareholder’s payoff if A is chosen is p ( X 2 − D ) and if B it is p (Y2 − D ) .
Project B will be chosen since Y2 > X 2. This illustrates Proposition 4.3.
Note that the case D > X 2 does not make too much sense since Project
A cannot be considered a safer project because the probability of bank-
ruptcy with Project A is 100 %.
In conclusion, we find that when the debt level is low there is no incen-
tive for asset substitution. When the debt level increases, then it changes.
b (Pr = 0.5) g (Pr = 0.5)
Table 4.4 New and exist- Existing Project 20 100
ing project earnings New Project 0 18
78 Capital Structure in the Modern World
on its value? First we need to understand that the problem arises not
because the shareholders are “bad” people by definition and do not care
about creditors’ money. The shareholders undertake actions from a ratio-
nal decision-maker point of view, i.e. actions that maximize the value
of their claims. A distortion here comes from the fact that markets are
imperfect, there is a moral hazard problem between different economic
agents, and it is virtually impossible to write comprehensive contracts
that cover all possible circumstances.
The asset substitution theory explains the usage of some financing strat-
egies. All strategies listed below help prevent asset substitution problems.
These strategies are: using debt with financing covenants, using debt with
dividend covenants, asset covenants or binding covenants, using loans
with protective loan covenants, using bank debt, and using convertible
debt or warrants (for more analysis of this issue see Green (1984)).
The idea of convertible debt is that if shareholders undertake a strat-
egy that can potentially shift value from creditors to shareholders, the
creditors can threaten to convert bonds into shares. Bank debt is usu-
ally accompanied by better monitoring from the lender: therefore, the
shareholders’ ability to undertake value diminishing projects decreases.
Some corporations have limited the asset substitution problem by issuing
warrants and options. In some cases, firms split off the safe part of the
business.
Protective loan covenants are restrictions placed on the firm by the
debtholders and can include: prohibition of new debt financing, the
maintenance of certain financial ratios, etc. Sometimes covenants restrict
firms from selling their assets, undertaking new businesses and taking
new loans. Firms that violate these covenants are in technical default and
debtholders are allowed to intervene in the company’s business. Loan
covenants make debts safer, and therefore increase their values. This
undermines the whole idea of asset substitution consisting of value shift-
ing from equityholders to debtholders.
There is evidence that risk-shifting incentives of insolvent banks can
significantly deplete assets. For example, Barrow and Horvitz (1993)
studied insolvent savings and loans operated by the, now defunct, Federal
Savings and Loan Insurance Corporation from 1985 to 1988. The firms
4 Credit Rationing and Asset Substitution 79
5
“BBC—Stimulus Package 2009”. BBC News. February 14, 2009. http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/
business/7889897.stm. Retrieved January 22, 2016.
80 Capital Structure in the Modern World
Consider a debt with face value 50. The shareholders’ payoffs are as
follows. If A: 0.5 * 40 + 0.5 * 40 = 40 . If B: 0.5 * (125 − 50 ) + 0.5 * 0 = 37.5.
Therefore, Project A will be chosen. The creditors will be interested in
providing the firm with the needed funds because debt is essentially
when the firm takes Project A.
Now suppose that the -free interest rate is 50 %. In order to be able
to raise debt, the firm needs to convince potential creditors that they can
earn at least 50 % (on average). Otherwise the creditors would prefer to
invest in risk-free government bonds. If the debt face value is 75 (the
debt face value plus 50 % interest), the shareholders’ expected payoffs
will be as follows. If A: 0.5 * 15 + 0.5 * 15 = 15. If B: 0.5 * 0 + 0.5 * 50 = 25.
Therefore, Project B will be chosen. In this case, the creditors’ expected
payoff is 0.5 * 75 + 0.5 * 0 = 37.5, which is less than the cost of the invest-
ment. As a result, they will not be willing to lend the money. In fact, the
maximal possible face value of debt is 125 (otherwise the shareholders
do not receive any profit). Therefore the maximal expected payoff to the
creditors is 0.5 * 125 = 62.5 < 75. So there is no equilibrium where credi-
tors can count on earning at least a minimal expected rate of return.
We have seen some positive NPV projects that were very attractive
from the creditors’ point of view but that were not undertaken in favor of
riskier projects. Creditors could charge higher interest rates on their debt.
This leads to a vicious cycle where creditors keep charging higher interest
rates and firms keep taking on riskier projects. Instead, some creditors
will refuse to lend to firms when interest rates are too high, regardless of
the interest payments the firm agrees to make. This phenomenon is called
credit rationing (it can also exist because of asymmetric information).6
6
It can also exist because of asymmetric information. Bester (1985) argues that collateral by high
quality borrowers can be used as a screening device by banks. Some recent papers analyze credit
rationing under both asymmetric information and agency problems and argue that adverse selec-
tion is less important (Coco 1997; Arnold and Riley 2009; Su and Zhang 2014).
82 Capital Structure in the Modern World
Date 1:
A irm's capital Shareholders Date 2:
Shareholders
structure and rollover can switch to Earnings are
initial exisiting debt another realized and
investment
Firms sell/buy investment distributed to
proejct/asset
existing project claimholders
are determined
projects/assets
When interest rates are below their equilibrium level, there is an exces-
sive demand for credit. Banks, however, will not necessarily increase
the interest rate in order to equalize demand and supply. Perhaps this
explains why bankers are often described as “very conservative people”.
Perhaps this also explains why the volume of credit seems to be much
less than necessary in developing countries where demand for credit is
very high but the average quality of borrowers is low. It can also explain
why more loans are collateralized when treasury rates rise (banks expect a
decrease in the quality of borrowers). The model of credit rationing was
also used by Kaufman (1996) to explain aspects of Argentina’s economic
crisis of 1995–1996.7
Acharya and Viswanathan (2011) build a model of the financial sec-
tor to explain why an adverse asset shock can lead to a sharp decrease in
the level of cash. Financial firms raise short-term debt in order to finance
asset purchases. When market conditions worsen, debt provides an incen-
tive for asset substitution, which can lead to credit rationing by banks.
Firms then may sell assets to better-capitalized firms in order to reduce
leverage. Short-term debt is relatively cheap to issue in good times. As a
result many firms with high leverage and low capital can be created in the
financial industry. The following illustrates this point.
We will continue with Example 4.2. This time suppose that each
project has its own probability of success denoted pA and pB and also
X=1 Y=
1 0 . We consider a firm that initially invested in Project A. The
cash flow from projects will be realized in Date 2. The sequence of events
is presented in Fig. 4.3.
See Hashi and Toçi (2010) for credit rationing analysis in south-European countries.
7
4 Credit Rationing and Asset Substitution 83
Also assume that initially the firm has some debt outstanding. On
Date 1, the firm has to rollover existing debt because liquidating projects
on Date 1 is not profitable. Also, on Date 1 the firm can switch to Project
B. Banks have no control over the project choice. As was mentioned in
the previous subsection, the project choice depends on the level of debt
after Date 1. The critical level of debt is determined by the following
pA X 2 − pBY2
equation: pA ( X 2 − D ) = pB (Y2 − D ). Let D* = . A firm with
p A − pB
a level of debt below this will not shift to a riskier project and vice versa.
What is then the critical level of debt in Date 1 that can be rolled over?
The bank will have to provide financing D to cover the firm’s period 1
debt but the expected payoff on Date 2 is D* pA (assuming that the firm
does not change projects). So the critical level of the Date 1 debt is D* pA.
As was mentioned above, the inability to rollover debt on Date 1 is
damaging to the firm. Assume that the firm can partially sell its assets/
projects on Date 1. Suppose that the asset price is p. If the firm can sell
the project for a price higher than a certain level, p, it would be able to
rollover the debt. Suppose the firm sells a fraction x of the project. Then
the firm’s debt capacity is xp + (1 − x ) D* pA . And it should be equal to the
initial debt: xp + (1 − x ) D* pA = D . It follows that the fraction of the proj-
D − D* p A
ect that should be sold is: x = . This fraction decreases with the
p − D* p A
price of asset p, and increases with the initial level of debt D. The latter
result leads to the point that although the probability of a financial crisis
is lower in good times, its severity in terms of potential asset sale and
evaporation of market liquidity can be greater. This is because in good
times the ability to accumulate debt is high.
strategy and it was looking for a sponsor to get through the recession.
Finally it received some support from the government.
Although the idea of liquidation resistence is appealing theoretically,
it seems that after the series of large-scale corporate scandals related to
the misuse of corporate funds and miscommunication of information to
investors, corporate managers of companies in financial distress are not
just trying to “fool” investors by investing in riskier and riskier projects
but are trying to deal with debt renegotiations and debt restructuring,
which we consider in the next chapter.
Brander and Lewis (1986) show that issuing risky debt induces firms
to be more aggressive in the product market. This effect of risky debt can
be considered a special form of the asset substitution effect. Brander and
Lewis consider the traditional Cournot model. The firms choose simul-
taneously their respective output levels and, given these quantities, the
price of the good is determined in the product market according to the
demand curve. Quantities in the Cournot model are strategic substitutes:
when firm 1 becomes more aggressive, firm 2 becomes softer, and vice
versa. It is beneficial for each firm to commit itself to an aggressive behav-
ior in the product market by adopting a strategy that will shift its reac-
tion curve outward (i.e. commit the firm to produce a larger quantity for
each quantity produced by the rival). Increasing output in equilibrium
also increases the variance of the firm’s profit. Since the marginal ben-
efit increases in a good state, the shareholders gain significantly in good
states. On the other hand, marginal losses are highest in bad states. It is
similar to the asset substitution effect where what matters most for the
shareholders are the gains in good states.
Brander and Lewis’ (1988) follow-up paper included bankruptcy costs
and produced similar results. Subsequent theoretical and empirical lit-
erature produced mixed results regarding connections between debt level
and a firm’s production strategy. Maksimovic (1988) argued that the
firms become more aggressive while Chevalier and Scharfstein (1996)
argued that they become less aggressive. Povel and Raith (2004) analyze
the interaction of financing and output market decisions in a duopoly in
which one firm is financially constrained. Unlike most previous work,
debt is derived as an optimal contract. Compared with a situation in
which both firms are unconstrained, the constrained firm produces less
86 Capital Structure in the Modern World
6. Consider two projects which cost 90 each but have different proba-
bilities of success and different cash flows. Projects’ cash flows and
the probabilities of success are shown in the table below. Which proj-
ect will the firm choose (assume risk-neutrality)?
Cash flow
Failure Success Pr(success)
Project A 80 130 0.8
Project B 0 140 0.2
Stochastic Variable
A stochastic (random, probabilistic) variable X is characterized by a
cumulative distribution function (CDF) F(x) such that F ( x ) = Pr ( X < x ) .
A discrete variable can take values x1, x2, … … xn with probabilities
p1, p2, … … pn, respectively. For a discrete variable, we have
F ( x ) = ∑ p ( xi )
xi ≤ x
1.2 F(z)
G(z)
1
0.8
G(z) F(z)
0.6
0.4
0.2
0 z
-10 -8 -6 -4 -2 0 2 4 6 8 10
F ( z ) ≤ G ( z ) , ∀z
The possible payoffs (z) are along the x-axis and the values of the
cumulative distribution functions are on the y-axis. The dotted line (G)
lies above F. Hence, X first-order dominates Y.
Example 4.3
Example with discrete variables. Consider the following projects X and Y,
which are subject to the following profit scenarios with the given prob-
abilities. How would one find which project dominates the other by first-
order dominance? (Table 4.6).
To compare X and Y, we build the following table (Table 4.7):
The probabilities for each value of z are taken from the previous table;
F(z) is the cumulative probability (or CDF) for X; G(z) is CDF for Y, and
92 Capital Structure in the Modern World
Second-Order Dominance
We saw that FOD is a very strong criterion. All investors immediately
chose options that dominate others by FOD. Unfortunately, not all cases
involve FOD between available alternatives. In order to solve the problem
where the differences between the two cumulative probability functions
can be both negative and positive, we have to rely on the second-order
stochastic dominance. The second-order stochastic dominance criterion
(SOD) helps rank distributions according to relative riskiness in terms of
the spread of the probability mass of the cumulative density functions.
Consider stochastic variables X with distribution function F(x) and Y
with G(y). X dominates Y in the second-order sense if
S ( x ) = ∫ F ( z ) − G ( z ) dz ≤ 0, ∀x
11
This method works if one keeps the same lag for values of z in the table.
4 Credit Rationing and Asset Substitution 93
Increasing Risk
Consider the stochastic variables X with distribution function F(x) and Y
with G ( y ) , X < b, Y < b . X dominates Y in the increasing risk sense (IR) if
S ( x ) = ∫ F ( z ) − G ( z ) dz ≤ 0, ∀ x
S ( b ) = 0
Example 4.4
Example with discrete variables. Consider the following projects X and Y,
which are subject to the following outcomes with the given probabilities
(Table 4.8).
To compare X and Y, we build the following table (Table 4.9):
Here, ∑F ( z )∑G ( z ) are sums of the numbers in columns F(z)
and
and G(z) and ∆ = ∑F ( z ) − ∑G ( z ). If ∆ is non-positive (non-negative),
then X dominates Y (Y dominates X) by SOD.
If ∆ is non-positive (non-negative) and ∆ ( zmax ) = 0 , then X dominates
Y (Y dominates X) by IR (note that it also dominates by SOD).
Finally note the following rules regarding the different types of sto-
chastic dominance: FOD implies SOD (compare definitions of SOD
and FOD); SOD does not imply FOD; IR implies SOD; SOD does not
imply IR.
For more analysis of the stochastic dominance approach see Abhyankar,
Ho, and Zhao (2006) and Levi (1992).
References
Abhyankar, A., Ho, K., & Zhao, H. (2006). Value versus growth: Stochastic
dominance criteria. Cass Business School Research Paper. Available at SSRN:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=793204
Acharya, V., & Viswanathan, S. (2011). Leverage, moral hazard and liquidity.
Journal of Finance, 66, 99–138.
Arnold, L., & Riley, J. (2009). On the possibility of credit rationing in the
Stiglitz-Weiss model. American Economics Review, 99, 2012–2021.
Barrow, J., & Horvitz, P. (1993). Response of distressed firms to incentives:
Thrift institution performance under the FSLIC management consignment
program. Financial Management, 22(3), 176–184.
Bester, H. (1985). Screening versus rationing in credit markets with imperfect
information. American Economic Review, 75, 850–855.
Brander, J., & Lewis, T. (1986). Oligopoly and financial structure: The limited
liability effect. American Economic Review, 76(5), 956–970.
Brander, J., & Lewis, T. (1988). Bankruptcy Costs and the Theory of Oligopoly.
The Canadian Journal of Economics / Revue Canadienne d'Economique 21(2),
221–243.
Chevalier, J., & Scharstein, D. (1996). Capital market imperfections and coun-
ter cyclical markups: Theory and evidence. American Economic Review, 86,
703–725.
Chowdhury, J. (2006). Limited liability effect with endogenous debt and invest-
ments. Working Paper. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=901080
Coco, G. (1997). Credit rationing and the welfare gain from usury laws.
Discussion Paper in Economics—University of Exeter, 15/97.
Galai, D., & Masulis, R. (1976). The option pricing model and the risk factor
of stock. Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 53–81.
Gavish, B., & Kalay, A. (1983). On the asset substitution problem. Journal of
Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 18, 21–30.
4 Credit Rationing and Asset Substitution 95
Graham, J., & Harvey, C. (2001). The theory and practice of corporate finance:
Evidence from the field. Journal of Financial Economics, 60(2–3), 187–243.
Green, R. (1984). Investment incentives, debt, and warrants. Journal of Financial
Economics, 13(1), 115–136.
Green, R., & Talmor, E. (1986). Asset substitution and the agency costs of debt
financing. Journal of Banking and Finance, 10(3), 391–399.
Grinblatt, M., & Titman, S. (2001). Financial markets & corporate strategy (2nd
ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Hashi, I., & Toçi, Z. (2010). Financing constraints, credit rationing and financ-
ing obstacles: Evidence from firm-level data in South-Eastern Europe.
Economic and Business Review, 12(1), 29–60.
Ikeda, M. (2005). Risk shifting incentive of the firm when its value is correlated
with interest rates. Waseda University working paper.
Jensen, M., & Meckling, W. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior,
agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3,
305–360.
Kaufman, M. (1996). An incursion into the confidence crisis-credit rationing-
real activity channel: Evidence from the Argentine “tequila” crisis. Working
Paper Central Bank of Argentina.
Kovenock, D., & Phillips, G. (1997). Capital structure and product market
behavior: An examination of plant exit and investment decisions. Review of
Financial Studies, 10, 767–803.
Levi, H. (1992). Stochastic dominance and expected utility: Survey and analy-
sis. Management Science, 38(4), 555–593.
Maksimovic, V. (1988). Capital structure in repeated oligopolies. Rand Journal
of Economics, 19, 389–407.
Opler, T., & Titman, S. (1994). Financial distress and corporate performance.
Journal of Finance, 49, 1015–1040.
Povel, P., & Raith, M. (2004). Financial constraints and product market compe-
tition: Ex-ante vs ex post incentives. International Journal of Industrial
Organization, 22, 917–949.
Simon, R. (2015, November 26). Big banks cut back on loans to small business.
Wall Street Journal. http://www.wsj.com/articles/big-banks-cut-back-on-
small-business-1448586637
Stiglitz, J., & Weiss, A. (1981). Credit rationing in markets with imperfect
information. The American Economic Review, 71(3), 393–410.
Su, X., & Zhang, L. (2014). A re-examination of credit rationing in the Stiglitz
and Weiss model. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1703428
96 Capital Structure in the Modern World
Date 1: A irm
Date 2: The
with debt has Shareholders If the project is
irm is
some cash and decide rejected,
liquidated and
receives whether to shareholders
its assets are
information accept or distribute the
distributed to
about an reject the available cash
the
investment project as dividends
cliamholders
opportunity
Proposition 5.1 In some cases, a firm with debt may pass up positive NPV
investments.
5.2 H
ow Does the Type and the Level
of Debt Affect the Underinvestment
Problem
In this section, we demonstrate how the level of debt influences the
underinvestment problem. Suppose a firm owns the following project
(project-in-place). At t = 1 , cash flow from the project may be equal to
R > 0 with probability p1 or 0 otherwise. At t = 0 , the firm is given the
opportunity to make an investment B that increases the probability of p1
to p2. This investment has a positive NPV, i.e. ( p2 − p1 ) R − B > 0 . The
firm has issued senior debt with total amount D. The timing of events is
presented in Fig. 5.2.
A irm with
debt and Shareholders
If the project is
project-in- decide Earnings are
accepted, the
place receives whether to realized and
irm issue new
information accept or distributed to
debt to inance
about a new reject the claimholders
the project
investment project
Example 5.1
A firm has a project-in-place that can generate earnings R = 10, 000 with
probability p1 = 0.5. There is a new project available. The cost of the proj-
ect is B = 1000. If the investment is undertaken, the probability increases
by 0.2. Will the new project be undertaken if the firm’s debt equals D?
First, note that the NPV of this project is positive for the firm. The
firm’s expected earnings increase by 10, 000 * 0.2 = 2000 which is greater
than the 1000 investment cost. So the NPV of the project for the firm
equals 10, 000 ∗ 0.2 − 1000 = 1000 .
The answer to the question in Example 5.1 depends on the value
of D. Consider two different debt levels: D = 3000 and D = 6000.
Proposition 5.2 predicts that the project will not be undertaken if
( p2 − p1 ) ( R − D ) − B < 0. Or 0.2 * D > 1000 . And this is the case when
D = 6000.
Without the new project, the shareholders’ earnings are:
(10, 000 − D ) * 0.5 . If D = 3000, the shareholders’ expected earnings are
(10, 000 − 3000) * 0.5 = 3500 . If the firm undertakes the new project the share-
holders’ expected payoff will be (10, 000 − 3000 ) ∗ 0.7 − 1000 = 3900 > 3500
so the project will be undertaken.
Consider D = 6000. Without the new project the sharehold-
ers’ expected earnings are (10, 000 − 6000 ) * 0.5 = 2000 . If the firm
undertakes the new project the shareholders’ expected payoff will be
(10, 000 − 6000) ∗ 0.7 − 1000 = 1800 < 2000 so the project will not be
undertaken.
Let us now analyze whether the debt overhang problem depends on
the type of the existing debt. Consider a firm with an amount D of debt
(senior) due at date 1. The firm’s cash flows at date 1 are stochastic and
depend on the state of nature. In the good state they will be R2; in the
bad state they will be R1, R2 > D > R1 ; the probability of the good state
102 Capital Structure in the Modern World
Proposition 5.3 In some cases a senior debt will lead to debt overhang but
junior debt will not.
5.3 D
ebt Overhang Implications
and Prevention
about other kinds of financing? The firm can, for example, ask existing
(incumbent) creditors for additional financing.
Proposition 5.4 In some cases a debt overhang problem can be solved via
renegotiation with existing creditors.
Example 5.2
Consider a firm with a 5000 debt (senior) due at date 1. The firm’s cash
flows in the good state will be 8000; in the bad state they will be 3000; each
state has an equal probability. The firm has the opportunity to undertake
a project costing 1500 that will generate cash flows of 2000 in both states.
is 1500 (since the total earnings are at least 2000 in both states). So
the shareholders’ expected payoff, if the new project is undertaken, is:
0.5 ∗ (10, 000 − 5000 − 1500 ) = 1750 . This is greater than 1500. So the new
project will be undertaken. This illustrates Proposition 5.3.
Now suppose the initial debt is senior but the incumbent debt-
holders agree to finance the new project with a new (junior) debt
with a face value (including principal and interests) of 1500. Recall
that without the new project, the shareholders’ expected payoff is:
0.5 * (8000 − 5000 ) + 1.2 * 0 = 1500. Now suppose the shareholders accept
financing from the incumbent creditors. The cost is 1500 and cash flow is
2000 in each state. The shareholders’ payoffs with the new project will be
0.5 ∗ (10, 000 − 5000 − 1500 ) = 1750. This is greater than 1500 and hence
the shareholders will be interested in making a deal with incumbent
creditors. Now consider the incentive for the creditors. Without the new
project their expected payoff is 0.5 ∗ 5000 + 0.5 ∗ 3000 = 4000. With the
project it is: 0.5 ∗ (5000 + 1500 ) + 0.5 ∗ 5000 − 1500 = 4250. So the deal is
beneficial for both the shareholders and the creditors.
Similarly, lenders can commit to additional financing when the first
loan is granted. This can also help resolve debt overhang problems.
Costly Renegotiation
Why can’t the firm always avoid costs of financial distress by renegotiating
with creditors? The firm could negotiate with creditors to write down a
new debt, postpone interest, or ease covenants in exchange for additional
interest or some equity in the company. However, these negotiations are
costly and sometimes not feasible.4 The reasons for this are that creditors
are often dispersed, making it hard for all of them to negotiate, and that
they face conflicts of interest among themselves. One other problem that
occurs is that creditors have doubts that their funds will be used for a
“good” project.
if the face value of the new debt is below 1500, for example, 1250. The
creditors’ expected payoff is 4125, in this case, which is still higher than
4000 in the case without the new project. However, if the number of
initial debtholders is large, then the free-rider problem can appear: it is
in the interest of the initial debtholders to put up the money collectively,
but it is not in the interest of any one of them to do it alone because the
new debt has a negative NPV (face value of debt is below the cost of
investment). So the shareholders may find it hard to convince the credi-
tors to invest in the new project.
Pawlina (2010) shows that the shareholders’ option to renegotiate debt
in a period of financial distress exacerbates the underinvestment problem
at the time of the firm's expansion. This result is a consequence of a
higher wealth transfer from the shareholders to the creditors occurring
upon investment in the presence of the option to renegotiate. This addi-
tional underinvestment is eliminated when the bargaining power belongs
to the creditors.
Favara et al. (2015) focus on connections between bankruptcy laws
and debt renegotiation frictions. They develop a model that includes
firms’ choices of investments, asset sales, and risk-taking. It is shown that
bankruptcy laws favoring debt renegotiation reduce underinvestment,
limit asset sales, and decrease incentives for risk-taking when firms are
near insolvency. The model is tested on a panel of 19,466 firms across 41
countries with different bankruptcy codes and finds and a good amount
of support.
profitable long-term project if the firm has issued long-term debt and
investing in long-term projects is more beneficial to creditors.
Opler and Titman (1994) suggest that highly levered firms lose market
share to their less levered rivals during industry downturns for several
reasons. Distressed firms that face underinvestment problems (debt over-
hang) are forced to sell off assets and reduce their selling efforts. Low
levered firms, assumed to have deep pockets, can engage in predatory
practices especially in a highly competitive environment designed to
financially exhaust highly levered rivals and drive them out of the market.
A highly levered firm might be vulnerable to predation from low levered
competitors because low levered competitors can purposefully reduce
their prices and keep this strategy for a long time to drive the highly
levered firm out of business.
A way to prevent inefficient dividend policy is to have dividend cov-
enants, which are restrictions that do not allow dividends to be paid until
the claim is paid to debtholders. Other ways to prevent a debt overhang
problem in general include using bank and privately placed debt and
using project financing and the debtor-in-possession rule in the US
Chapter 11 Bankruptcy Code. We will discuss this in detail in Chap. 9.
Firms can also use short-term debt to mitigate debt overhang.
Rajan (1992) argues that while informed banks make flexible financial
decisions that prevent a firm’s projects from going away, the cost of this
credit is that banks have bargaining power over the firm’s profits once
the projects have begun (the hold-up problem). Vilanova (2004) argues
that a bank with a senior claim at the onset of financial distress benefits
from having strong bargaining power in subsequent debt restructurings
and can exploit this enhanced power to hold up other claimants (the firm
and junior lenders). It allows the senior bank with an initial impaired
claim to rule out the repayment risk. The concentration of liquidation
rights in the hands of the bank also leads to more favorable debt restruc-
turings for low quality borrowers. On the contrary, the ex-post strong
bargaining power of a senior bank might lower its incentives to monitor
at the early stages of financial distress.
With regard to links between debt maturity and the debt overhang
problem, Gertner and Scharfstein (1991) show that, conditional on ex-
5 Debt Overhang 107
post financial distress, making a fixed promised debt payment due earlier
(i.e. shorter-term) raises the market value of the debt and thus the firm’s
market leverage, leading to more debt overhang ex-post. Diamond and
He (2015) show that reducing maturity may increase or decrease over-
hang. With an immediate investment, shorter-term debt typically imposes
lower overhang. Future overhang is more volatile for shorter-term debt.
The life cycle theory of capital structure argues that besides finan-
cial flexibility there are other factors that can explain financing patterns
of firms in different stages of their developments (Damodaran 2003).
Start-up firms do not have much profit, so the tax advantage of debt is
not as important to them as it is for a mature firm. Start-up firms do not
require incentives for managers since there is no large separation between
ownership and management as in the case of big public corporations.
This leads to the idea that mature firms value debt more than start-up
firms. To what extent the life cycle theory represents a separate theory of
capital structure rather than a combination of arguments from other the-
ories remains an open question. More discussions about life cycle theory
will be provided in Chap. 8.
Among recent papers note Sundaresan et al. (2015) who analyze a
growing firm that represents a collection of growth options and assets
in place. The firm trades off tax benefits with the potential financial dis-
tress and endogenous debt-overhang costs over its life cycle. The authors
argue that the firm consistently chooses conservative leverage in order to
mitigate the debt-overhang effect on the exercising decisions for future
growth options. It is also shown that debt seniority and debt priority
structures have both important implications on growth-option exercis-
ing and leverage decisions as different debt structures have very different
debt-overhang implications.
2. Consider a firm with a 6000 debt (senior) due at date 1. The firm’s
cash flows in the good state will be 10,000; in the bad state they will
be 4000; each state has an equal probability. The firm has an opportu-
nity to undertake a project costing 2000 that will generate cash flows
of 3000 in both states. The investors are risk-neutral and the risk-free
interest rate is 0.
5 Debt Overhang 111
3. Consider a firm with a 10,000 debt due at date 1. The firm’s earnings
at date 1 depend on the state of nature. In the good state they will be
18,000; in the bad state they will be 0; both states have an equal prob-
ability. The corporate tax rate is 40 %. The firm has an opportunity to
issue new shares in order to repurchase the existing debt. As usual,
assume that investors are risk-neutral and the risk-free interest rate is
0. Are shareholders interested in repurchasing the firm’s debt by selling
equity?
4. Debt overhang
References
Admati, A., DeMarzo, P., Hellwig, M., & Pfleiderer, P. (2012). Debt overhang
and capital regulation. Rock Center for Corporate Governance at Stanford
University Working Paper No. 114; MPI Collective Goods Preprint, No.
2012/5. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2031204
Admati, A., DeMarzo, P., Hellwig, M., & Pfleiderer, P. (2015). The leverage
ratchet effect. Preprints of the Max Planck Institute for Re-search on
Collective Goods, Bonn 2013/13; Rock Center for Corporate Governance at
Stanford University Working Paper No. 146. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.
com/abstract=2304969.
112 Capital Structure in the Modern World
This section covers such topics as capital structure choice and firm per-
formance, capital structure and corporate governance, capital structure
of small companies and start-up companies, corporate financing versus
project financing and others.
6
Capital Structure Choice and Firm’s
“Quality”
The focus of our analysis is on the firm’s choice of financing for stage
1. The big question is whether the firm with the higher value will issue
equity contrary to the prediction of the standard POT. Hence the focus
of our analysis is on the separating equilibrium where the higher valued
firm issues equity. In a separating equilibrium, all uncertainties about a
120 Capital Structure in the Modern World
firm’s type are resolved in stage 1, which means that the financing choice
in stage 2 is based on perfect information. For simplicity, suppose that a
firm issues debt for stage 2 with face value D. We get:
pg2 D = C2 (6.1)
s1 pg1 + s1 pg 2 (1 − D ) = C1 (6.2)
(1 − s1 ) pb1 + (1 − s1 ) pb2 (1 − D ) < pb1 + pb2 − C1 − C2 (6.3)
In order to analyze this equation, let us denote the total expected cash
flow for type j over both periods to be v j = p j1 + p j 2 . Also let rj denote
the rate of earnings growth (pj2/pj1). The probabilities of success at each
stage are then:
vj v j rj
p j1 = ; pj2 = (6.4)
1 + rj 1 + rj
4
In signaling models it is usually not a problem for a low value type of firm to find a strategy that
cannot be mimicked by a high value type. This can be some kind of debt with covenants, for
example, where the payoffs depend on the firm’s total earnings over two periods. Since g has higher
total value it would not be interested in mimicking b.
6 Capital Structure Choice and Firm’s “Quality” 121
−
C1 vb vr
+ bb 1 −
(
C2 1 + rg ) < v − C1 − C2
1 b (6.5)
v g − C
2 1 + rb 1 + rb vg rg
Miglo (2012) argues that this equation holds and a separating equilib-
rium, where g issues equity, exists if and only if the difference between the
firms’ values is sufficiently small, and the difference between the rates of
earnings growth is sufficiently high. It should also be true if pg1 > pb1 and
pg 2 < pb 2 . As an example suppose that vg = vb . Equation (6.5) becomes
pg 2 < pb 2 .
Proof Given vb and rb, the amount of earnings that firm b can get by
mimicking firm g (the left side of inequality (6.5)) depends on the frac-
C1
tion of equity sold at stage 1, which equals and the face value of
vg − C2
debt at stage 2, which equals
(
C2 1 + rg ) . Given r , the fraction of equity
g
vg rg
sold at stage 1 and the face value of debt at stage 2 both decrease with vg.
On the other hand, given vg, the fraction of equity sold at stage 1 does
not depend on rg and the face value of debt at stage 2 decreases with rg
(
C2 1 + rg
∂
)
vg rg
because < 0 . So in order to reduce the incentive for b to
∂rg
mimic g, both vg and rg need to be as small as possible. Since vg > vb , the
minimal incentive case is when vg is close to vb and when rg is as small as
possible compared to rb.
The pecking-order model arises as a special case here. Suppose
pg1 = pg 2 and pb1 = pb 2 . Then (6.5) becomes vg < vb . This does not hold.
122 Capital Structure in the Modern World
Hence a separating equilibrium does not exist.5 The result is not sur-
prising because the rates of growth are identical for every type of firm
( p=g 2 / pg 1 p=
b 2 / pb1 1 ) and Proposition 6.1 predicts that a separating
equilibrium can only exist if the difference between firms’ rates of growth
is large enough. In this case, however, the firms’ rates of growth are iden-
tical and the firms only differ in their overall values. Thus the case is
one-dimensional like the classical POT case. More generally, a separating
equilibrium will never exist and POT holds if pg1 > pb1 and pg 2 > pb 2 .
Also, POT holds if one considers a one-stage investment with short-term
(one stage) private information. This is the case with c2 = p j 2 = 0 .6
On an intuitive level, Proposition 6.1 is straightforward. First, it is well
known that in a separating equilibrium each financing strategy is chosen
by the worst possible type of firm for that strategy (from the investor’s
viewpoint).7 So if type g decides to issue equity in equilibrium and has
high earnings over two periods, with higher second-period earnings, other
firms would find it attractive to mimic this strategy. High total earnings
would imply a high share price at stage 1 and high second-period earn-
ings would imply a low face value of debt at stage 2. Proposition 1 makes
sure that it does not happen and a separating equilibrium exists.
Example 6.1 Consider the following example that is based on the model
described above and the sequence of events in Fig. 6.1. Let pg1 = 0.8 ,
pg2 = 0.3 , pb1 = 0.2 , pb2 = 0.85 and Ct = 0.2 , t = 1, 2 .
5
Cooney and Kalay (1993) demonstrate that POT can fail if projects have negative NPV.
6
In Goswami, Noe, and Rebello (1995) a firm receives earnings for two periods and private infor-
mation is long-term but investment is one-staged.
7
Brennan and Kraus (1987).
6 Capital Structure Choice and Firm’s “Quality” 123
6.3 C
apital Structure, Market Timing
and Business Cycle
The market timing theory of capital structure (MT) suggests that the
decision to issue equity depends on stock market performance (Lucas
and McDonald 1990; Korajczyk et al. 1992; Baker and Wurgler 2002).
Financial managers prefer to issue shares when prices are relatively high.
When the stock market is not doing well, firms do not issue equity. Since
the equity market performance often moves in unison with the economy
as a whole, an alternative interpretation of MT is that when the economy
is bad, firms do not issue equity. When the economy is average, some
firms will issue equity. When the economy is booming, equity issues are
large. Therefore there is a positive relationship between equity issues and
the business cycle. Miglo (2011) noticed that empirical evidence often
provides support for MT (see, for example, Choe et al. (1993) and Baker
and Wurgler (2002)).
An interesting question is whether investors overpay for shares or not.
Some researchers argue that investors tend to be excessively optimistic
during new issues of shares. Other researchers prefer “rational investor”
arguments. In recent research, note the following. Bolton, Chen, and
Wang (2013) combine the firm’s precautionary cash hoarding and mar-
ket timing motives. Firms value financial slack and build cash reserves
to mitigate financial constraints. The finitely lived, favorable, financing
condition induces them to rationally time the equity market. This mar-
ket timing motive may cause investments to decrease (and the marginal
value of cash to increase) in financial slack, and may lead a financially
constrained firm to gamble.
To illustrate the basic idea about the connection between capital
structure and macroeconomic conditions, consider the following simple
model with asymmetric information in the spirit of a standard POT. A
firm has an investment project. It has some assets in place that generate
earnings A. To finance the new project, the firm needs to raise B. The
cash flow of the firm is A + R if the investment is made ( R > B ), and A
if it is not. There are two types of firms. For type 1, A = A1 + m and for
type 2, A = A2 + m , A2 > A1 . The publicly available parameter m depends
on the macroeconomic situation. As usual, we assume that everybody is
risk-neutral and the risk-free interest rate is zero. The sequence of events
is presented in Fig. 6.2.
Entrepreneurs
learn their irms' Firms decide
Earnings are
types. whether to issue
realized and
equity and
Macroeconomic distributed to
undertake the
parameter m project
claimholders
becomes known
Suppose the market believes that the fraction of type 1 firms among
firms issuing equity is x. The investors’ expected return should be equal
to the investment cost. This implies that B = α ( xA1 + (1 − x ) A2 + m + R ) ,
where α is the fraction of equity requested by investors. We have
B
α=
xA1 + (1 − x ) A2 + m + R
(1 − α ) ( A + m + R ) (6.6)
Type 1 will issue shares regardless of the value of x. To see this, let’s
compare (6.6) for type 1 and earnings for type 1 if no new investment is
B ( A1 + m + R )
made that is A1 + m . Then (6.6) is greater if R > .
xA1 + (1 − x ) A2 + m + R
Example 6.2 To finance the new project, the firm needs to raise B = 0.16 .
For type 1, A = 0.2 + m and for type 2, A = 0.5 + m . The publicly avail-
able parameter m depends on the macroeconomic situation. Also R = 0.2 .
Suppose that the fraction of type 1 firms issuing equity is 0.5. Consider
a pooling equilibrium where both firms issue equity. We have
0.16 0.16
α= =
0.5 * 0.2 + 0.5 * 0.5 + m + 0.2 0.55 + m
Consider the incentives for type 2 firms. Their optimal choice depends
0.16 (0.7 + m )
on 0.2 > . This condition depends on m. It holds if
0.55 + m
0.02
m> = 0.5.
0.04
The model predicts that when the economy is bad (m is low), firms do
not issue equity. When the economy is booming (m is high), equity issues
are large. Empirical work by Choe et al. (1993), Bayless and Chaplinsky
(1996), and Baker and Wurgler (2002) suggest a positive relationship
between equity issues and the business cycle.
To relate MT to the evidence about operating performances, some lit-
erature focuses on non-rational aspects of investors’ behavior. However, as
mentioned above, the evidence related to investors’ irrationality is mixed.
The literature, based on rational investors, is able to argue why firms may
be interested in issuing equity in periods when market prices are high
but is not focused on explaining the link between the debt-equity choice
and the changes in the operating performance after the issue (long-term
versus short-term).
xA1 + (1 − x ) A2 + m + R
p= (6.7)
n
From the previous section we know that issuing equity is more likely
when m is large. From (6.7) it follows that equity issues are more likely
when the share price is high.
Another interpretation of this result looks at stock returns before the
equity issue. If the arrival of growth opportunities occurs independently
of price history, then firms issuing equity will have average performances
before the issue. Firms with a low share price will have above-average
performances as they wait for the price to improve before they issue
equity. Thus, on average, positive abnormal returns precede equity issues.
The evidence confirms this prediction (Korajczyk et al. 1990; Loughran
and Ritter 1995).
Choe, Masulis, and Nanda (1993) find that equity issues are more
frequent when the economy is doing well. Thus they predict that equity
issues are procyclical. Clementi (2002) provides a model predicting
that the IPO coincides with an increase in sales and capital expendi-
tures. Hackbarth, Miao, and Morellec (2006) find that for their base
parameters the value-maximizing leverage ratio is higher in a recession
than in a boom. Thus, Hackbarth et al.’s (2006) model predicts that debt
is counter-cyclical. In Bhamra et al. (2010) the risk-free rates of return
vary pro-cyclically and the optimal market leverage ratio evolves pro-
cyclically over the business cycle. In related work, Chen (2010) reaches
the same conclusion of pro-cyclical market leverage dynamics. Halling
and Zechner (2015) show that, on average, target leverage ratios evolve
counter-cyclically. These counter-cyclical dynamics are robust to differ-
ent subsamples of firms, data samples, empirical models of leverage, and
definitions of leverage.
130 Capital Structure in the Modern World
Angelo et al. (2010) analyze whether SEO decisions are better
explained by timing opportunities or by the lifecycle theory, where firms
sell stock primarily in the early stages of their lifecycle, when growth
opportunities exceed internally generated cash flow. It is found that both
timing and lifecycle theories have a significant influence, with the life-
cycle effect being quantitatively stronger, but neither adequately explains
SEO decisions.
Many MT predictions seem to be consistent across different countries.
For example, Chichti and Bougatef (2010) investigate the relevance of
market timing considerations on the debt-equity choice using a panel
of Tunisian and French listed firms. Consistent with the market timing
theory, they find that firms tend to issue equity when their market valu-
ations are relatively high and after a market performance improvement.
The impact of equity market timing on capital structure persists beyond
eight years. Dong et al. (2012) study market timing and pecking order
in a sample of debt and equity issues and share repurchases of Canadian
firms from 1998 to 2007. They find evidence that firms issue (repurchase)
equity when their shares are overvalued (undervalued) and that overval-
ued issuers earn lower post-announcement long-run returns only when
the firms are not financially constrained. Similarly, they find that firms
prefer debt to equity financing only when they are not overvalued. These
findings highlight an interaction between market timing and pecking-
order effects. Setyawan and Frensidy (2013) find that the market to book
ratio is negatively correlated with market leverage for Indonesian IPO
firms. This result is consistent with MT. On the other hand, Khanna
et al. (2015) analyze MT for Indian firms and find that firms rely more
on profitability than MT when issuing equity.
References
Axelson, U. (2007). Security design with investor private information. The
Journal of Finance, 62(6), 2587–2632.
Baker, M., & Wurgler, J. (2002). Market timing and capital structure. Journal of
Finance, 57, 1–32.
Bayless, M., & Chaplinsky, S. (1996). Is there a window of opportunity for
seasoned equity issuance? Journal of Finance, 51, 253–278.
Bessler, W., & Zimmermann, J. (2011). Acquisition activities of initial public
offerings in Europe: An analysis of exit and growth strategies. Midwest
Finance Association 2012 Annual Meetings Paper. Available at SSRN: http://
ssrn.com/abstract=1929060
Bhamra, H., Kuehn, L., & Strebulaev, I. (2010). The aggregate dynamics of
capital structure and macroeconomic risk. The Review of Financial Studies,
23(12), 4187–4241.
Bolton, P., Chen, H., & Wang, N. (2013). Market timing, investment, and risk
management. Journal of Financial Economics, 109(1), 40–62.
Brennan, M., & Kraus, A. (1987). Efficient financing under information asym-
metry. Journal of Finance, 42(5), 1225–1243.
132 Capital Structure in the Modern World
Celikyurt, U., Sevilir, M., & Shivdasani, A. (2010). Going public to acquire? The
acquisition motive in IPOs. Journal of Financial Economics, 96(3), 345–363.
Chen, H. (2010). Macroeconomic conditions and the puzzles of credit spreads
and capital structure. Journal of Finance, 65(6), 2171–2212.
Chichti, J., & Bougatef, K. (2010). Equity market timing and capital structure:
Evidence from Tunisia and France. Working paper. Available at http://www.
tn.refer.org/CEAFE/Papiers_CEAFE10/Fina_marche/Bougatef.pdf
Choe, H., Masulis, R., & Nanda, V. (1993). Common stock offerings across the
business cycle. Journal of Empirical Finance, 1, 1–29.
Clementi, G. (2002). IPOs and the growth of firms, NYU Stern 2004 Working
Paper No. 04–23. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=314277
Cooney, J., & Kalay, A. (1993). Positive information from equity issue announce-
ments. Journal of Financial Economics, 33, 149–172.
DeAngelo, H., DeAngelo, L., & Stulz, R. (2010). Seasoned equity offerings,
market timing, and the corporate lifecycle. Journal of Financial Economics,
95, 275–295.
Dong, M., Loncarski, I., ter Horst, J., & Veld, C. (2012). What drives security
issuance decisions: Market timing, pecking order, or both? Financial
Management, 41(3), 637–663.
Eldomiaty, T., & Mohamed, E. (2009). Is debt governance structure relevant to
firm operating performance in Egypt? A dynamic approach. International
Journal of Accounting and Finance, 1, 216–249.
Ficenec, J. (2015, December 21). Questor’s biggest investment mistakes of
2015. The Telegraph, Questor. http://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/markets/
questor/12059106/Questors-biggest-investment-mistakes-of-2015.html
Fulghieri, P., & Lukin, D. (2001). Information production, dilution costs, and
optimal security design. Journal of Financial Economics, 61, 3–42.
Goswami, G., Noe, T., & Rebello, M. (1995). Debt financing under asymmet-
ric information. Journal of Finance, 50, 633–659.
Hackbartha, D., Miaob, J., & Morellec, E. (2006). Capital structure, credit risk,
and macroeconomic conditions. Journal of Financial Economics, 82, 519–550.
Halling, M., Yu, J., & Zechner, J. (2015). Leverage dynamics over the business
cycle. AFA 2012 Chicago Meetings Paper. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.
com/abstract=1762289
Halov, N. (2006). Dynamics of asymmetric information and capital structure.
Working Paper, New York University.
Hennessy, C., Livdan, D., & Miranda, B. (2010). Repeated signaling and firm
dynamics signal. Review of Financial Studies, 23, 1981–2023.
6 Capital Structure Choice and Firm’s “Quality” 133
Jain, B., & Kini, O. (1994). The post-issue operating performance of IPO firms.
Journal of Finance, 49(5), 1699–1726.
Jiahui, M. (2015). Relationship between capital structure and firm performance,
evidence from growth enterprise market in China. Management Science and
Engineering, 9(1), 45–49.
Khanna, S., Srivastava, A., & Medury, Y. (2015). Is equity market timing the
sole criteria for capital structure decisions? An insight from Indian firms.
Indian Journal of Finance, 9(10), 48–64.
Korajczyk, R., Lucas, D., & McDonald, R. (1990). Understanding stock price
behavior around the time of equity issues. In R. Glenn Hubbard (Ed.),
Asymmetric information, corporate finance, and investment (pp. 257–278).
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Korajczyk, R., Lucas, D., & McDonald, R. (1992). Equity issues with time-
varying asymmetric information. Journal of Financial and Quantitative
Analysis, 27, 397–417.
Leland, H., & Pyle, D. (1977). Information asymmetries, financial structure,
and financial intermediation. Journal of Finance, 32, 371–378.
Loughran, T., & Ritter, J. (1995). The new issues puzzle. Journal of Finance, 50,
23–51.
Loughran, T., & Ritter, J. (1997). The operating performance of firms conduct-
ing seasoned equity offerings. Journal of Finance, 52, 1823–1850.
Lucas, D., & McDonald, R. (1990). Equity issues and stock price dynamics.
Journal of Finance, 45, 1019–1043.
Miglo, A. (2011). Trade-off, pecking order, signaling and market timing models.
In H. K. Baker & G. S. Martin (Eds.), Capital structure and corporate financ-
ing decisions: Theory, evidence, and practice (pp. 171–190). Hoboken, New
Jersey: Wiley. Ch. 10.
Miglo, A. (2012). Multi-stage investment, long-term asymmetric information
and pecking order revisited. Journal of Current Issues in Finance, Business, and
Economics, 4(4), 331–348.
Mikkelson, W., Partch, M., & Shah, K. (1997). Ownership and operating per-
formance of companies that go public. Journal of Financial Economics, 44,
281–307.
Morellec, E., & Schürhoff, N. (2011). Corporate investment and financing
under asymmetric information. Journal of Financial Economics, 99(2),
262–288.
134 Capital Structure in the Modern World
Myers, S., & Majluf, N. (1984). Corporate financing and investment decisions
when firms have information that investors do not have. Journal of Financial
Economics, 13, 187–221.
Ovide, S. (2015, December 10). A robust IPO, but no signal. Bloomberg Gadfly.
h t t p : / / w w w. b l o o m b e r g . c o m / g a d f l y / a r t i c l e s / 2 0 1 5 - 1 2 - 1 0 /
atlassian-bucks-trend-but-is-poor-barometer-for-tech-ipos
Pereira, T., & Sousa, M. (2015). Is there still a Berlin Wall in the post-issue
operating performance of European IPOs? Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.
com/abstract=2347535
Ross, S. (1977). The determination of financial structure: The incentive signal-
ing approach. Bell Journal of Economics, 8, 23–40.
Setyawan, I. R., & B. Frensidy. (2013). Empirical Tests for Market Timing
Theory of Capital Structure: The Case of IPOs in Indonesia Stock Exchange.
Working paper. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2207313
Shah, K. (1994). The nature of information conveyed by pure capital structure
changes. Journal of Financial Economics, 36, 89–126.
Sivy, M. (2012, May 30). Does Facebook’s floundering IPO signal a market top?
Time. http://business.time.com/2012/05/30/does-facebooks-floundering-ipo-
signal-a-market-top/
7
Capital Structure and Corporate
Governance
1
For a review see, for example, Becht, Bolton, and Roell (2003).
2
Some definitions use the term stakeholders to also include customers, employees, etc. http://www.
investopedia.com/terms/c/corporategovernance.asp
3
Hasselback and Tedesco (September 27, 2014).
4
http://buzzspotr.com/accounting-scandal-at-nortel/
5
Erman (March 13, 2007).
6
Gillies (June 20, 2009).
7 Capital Structure and Corporate Governance 137
Earnings If the
from the company is
A irm's Manager
project are not bankrupt,
capital selects an
realized and the manager
structure is investment
distributed receives
determined project
to private
claimholders. beneits.
manager’s official benefits are approximately equal for these projects. For
the sake of simplicity we assume that they are negligibly small. A possible
interpretation of these assumptions is that project 2 does not have the
same value for the firm as project 1 does but it extends the amount of
resources under the manager’s control. This phenomenon is often called
“empire-building”. Also, bankruptcy is very costly for the manager! If
the firm is bankrupt the manager’s total benefit is zero. For example, the
manager loses his job and his reputation, etc. The sequence of events is
presented in Fig. 7.1.
Proposition 7.1 Under equity financing, the manager will choose the inef-
ficient project. Debt financing may, in some cases, improve managerial
incentives.
Aghion and Bolton (1992), Dewatripont and Tirole (1994), and Hart (1995).
10
7 Capital Structure and Corporate Governance 141
found in empirical literature that real financial contracts are more com-
plicated than standard debt and equity. Also the parties involved usu-
ally make separate determinations for the allocation of various kinds of
property rights. These rights include residual cash flow rights, liquidation
rights, board rights, etc.11
Nobel Prize winners Maskin and Tirole (1999a, b) discuss the major
idea of the property rights approach, which is that some actions are
observable but non-contractable. They suggest that observable informa-
tion could be made verifiable by the use of cleverly designed revelation
mechanisms. That is, the contracting parties can agree in advance to play
a game where they have the appropriate incentives to reveal truthfully
their private information in equilibrium. However, these mechanisms are
rarely observed in practice. Aghion, Bloom and Van Reenen (2013) fur-
ther discuss the robustness of the incomplete contracts/property rights
approach and suggest possible avenues for future research.
Miglo (2009) suggests that in firms where moral hazard is an impor-
tant issue, a simple rule (“the rule of marginal revenues”) may exist that
describes the property rights allocation of the holders of securities based
on the analysis of cash flow patterns for different types of contracts (secu-
rities). To illustrate the idea, consider a firm with assets in place that are
expected to generate earnings in two periods. After observing the inter-
mediate earnings R10 and R20, the firm’s decision-maker makes a decision
(select I) that affects the final earnings in both periods. After the decision
is made, the firm’s earnings in period 1 are R1 = R10 − I and in period 2
they are R2 = R20 + I + R ( I ) . I may be interpreted as an amount of invest-
ment in a project. But in fact, I can be negative too. In this case it can be
interpreted as borrowing or increasing sales with discount.
A difference exists between period 1 and period 2 in terms of con-
tractability conditions (in the spirit of the property rights approach).
Period 1 earnings will be distributed according to contracts Tj(R1), which
may include a large variety of contracts (securities). However, the only
possible contract in period 2 is a property rights allocation that will be
contingeant on period 1 earnings. They are denoted αj(R1). We assume
See, for instance, Kaplan and Stromberg (2003) and Elfenbein and Lerner (2003) with regard to
11
Intermediate
earnings Final
Capital
become The earnings are
structure is
known and decision- realized and
selected and
property maker distributed
securities
rights selects to
are issued.
become claimholders
known
that the resulting fractions of ownership entitle each party to the right
corresponding to the fraction of the firm’s earnings period 2. Tj(R1) are
monotonic. Only piece-wise linear contracts are considered since they
are the most common type of contract observed in reality. Property rights
should provide the decision-maker with the optimal incentive to choose s.
The sequence of events is as shown in Fig. 7.2.
Optimal situations occur when property rights are distributed accord-
ing to the current marginal revenues of existing securities. For instance,
if the current marginal cash flow rights of the decision-maker are 10 %
(if the firm’s value increases by $ 1, the payoff to the agent will increase
by 10c), his optimal fraction of ownership in the future business should
also be 10 %. This provides decision-makers with the optimal incentives
to make decisions.
Let I* be the optimal decision from the firm’s point of view, i.e. R(I)
(total change in firm’s earnings after the decision is made) is maximized
when I* is selected. Assuming that R(I) is concave and differentiable, it
implies R′ ( I * ) = 0 . Suppose that claimholder j is the decision-maker. The
payoff of j equals Pj ( s ) = T j ( R10 − I ) + α j ( R10 ) ( R20 + I + R ( I ) ) .
( ) ( ) ( )( R
Pj (s ) = T j R10 − T j′ R10 I + α j R10 0
2 + I + R( I ) )
7 Capital Structure and Corporate Governance 143
value and only a small part of the potential continuation value, they have
more incentive to liquidate their firms than shareholders, who are often
reluctant to liquidate, as we saw in Chap. 4. The more dispersed the debt
of a firm is, the stronger the commitment to liquidate because it makes
debt restructuring in the event of continuation more difficult (similar to
the free-rider problem that we discussed in Chap. 5).
7.4 C
ostly Effort, Capital Structure,
and Managerial Incentives
Jensen and Meckling (1976) argue that when the decision-maker’s effort
is costly, then under equity financing the decision-maker should control
100 % of the equity in order to mitigate moral hazard problems. If the
decision-maker controls less than 100 % of equity, there will be a distor-
tion in the effort because the decision-maker bears 100 % of his effort’s
cost and receives less than 100 % of the benefits. Innes (1990) further
shows that debt financing can improve the manager’s effort.
Consider a firm totally financed with equity. The firm’s founder/man-
ager/entrepreneur (E) is risk-neutral. The firm’s expected first-period
earnings r depend on E’s effort e ∈[ 0,1] . For simplicity we assume that
the expected value of r equals e or Er = e . The cost of effort is e2.
E will choose the level of effort where his marginal revenue equals his
marginal cost. Since his individual marginal revenue is below the firm’s
marginal revenue, the chosen level of effort is less than first-best.
Proposition 7.3 If the manager owns less than 100 % of equity, the level of
effort is below the first-best level.
is our case. So the firm can be financed with debt with a face value 3/16
and the manager’s profit is 1/8 in this case.
One can see that under debt financing the manager chooses optimal
e = 1 / 2 . Innes shows that debt can be optimal if the distribution func-
tion for the firm’s earnings follows the MLRP condition,12 the manager is
risk neutral, and the contracts are non-decreasing.
Among the more recent interesting ideas note the following.
Berkovitch, Israel, and Spiegel (2000) investigate the interaction between
financial structure and managerial compensation. A three-period model
is considered. In period 0, a manager is hired. In period 1, the manager
takes actions that determine the firm’s future earnings and make the firm
more dependent on his ability. For example, the manager selects workers,
organizes production, chooses the firm’s strategy in the product market,
etc. After observing signals about the firm’s future earnings, sharehold-
ers may replace the manager. When the firm is leveraged, replacing a
manager whose ability is known with a new manager whose ability is
unknown shifts value from the debtholders to the shareholders (similar
to the asset substitution effect from Chap. 4). Consequently, risky debt
credibly commits the shareholders to an overly aggressive replacement
policy, and this may motivate the manager to exert more effort ex ante in
order to promote his chances of keeping his job.
Fairchild (2005) examines the combined effects of managerial over-
confidence (overconfidence in their model is interpreted as a bias esti-
mation of a firm’s investment project success probability), asymmetric
information, and the moral hazard problem on the manager’s choice of
financing (debt or equity). It is shown that the effect of overconfidence
on managerial moral hazard is ambiguous. It has a positive effect by
inducing higher managerial effort. However, it may lead to excessive use
of debt and higher expected bankruptcy costs.
Some research points out that, in many cases, a manager’s contract
looks like an inside debt (pension plans for example) that may align the
interests of managers and outside debtholders (Sundaram and Yermack
2007; Anantharaman et al. 2014). Some of these contracts are unfunded
and unsecured, while others are funded and secured to some extent, and
13
See, for example, Roychowdhury (2006).
150 Capital Structure in the Modern World
R10 = 0 and E uses EM, the final first period earnings R1 = R10 + s and
the second-period earnings R2 = R20 + s − c , where c is the cost of the
EM.
Under equity financing, E has no interest in EM since it does
not change E’s fraction of earnings nor does it change who controls
the company in period 2. As we saw in previous examples, optimal
e′ = k / 2 and it is below the socially optimal level of effort. Under debt
financing, E will use EM ( s = D ) if R10 = 0 . Otherwise, E loses control
of the firm and gets nothing at the second period. If R10 = 1 , earnings
will not be manipulated since any changes in second-period earnings
for E will just mirror the change in period 1 (opposite signs) minus the
cost of EM.
Figure 7.6 illustrates that if c < 1 , E’s level of effort is closer to the
socially optimal level and provides a better social surplus than the case
without EM.
This analysis also shows that Innes’s (1990) result can hold even if the
manager is subject to a double moral hazard problem: production effort
and earnings manipulation.
Among recent papers note the following. An, Li, and Yu (2013) exam-
ine the effect of earnings management on financial leverage and how this
relation is influenced by institutional environments by studying a large
panel of 25,798 firms across 37 countries spanning the years 1989 to
152 Capital Structure in the Modern World
2009. It was found that firms with high earnings management activities
are associated with high corporate leverage.
Gunny (2010) examines real earnings manipulation in firms that meet
two earnings benchmarks (zero and last year’s earnings). The results indi-
cate that real activity manipulations of expenses on R&D, SG&A,14 and
production are positively associated with firms just meeting the earnings
benchmarks. Also, it was found that firm-years reflecting real earnings
manipulation to just meet earnings benchmarks had higher subsequent
firm performances compared to firm-years that do not engage in earnings
manipulation and miss or just meet the earnings benchmarks.
Cohen and Zarowin (2010) examine earnings management behavior
around SEOs, focusing on both real activities and accrual-based manipu-
lation. They document that firms use real, as well as accrual-based, earn-
ings management tools around SEOs.
Alhadab, Clacher, and Keasey (2013) find that IPO firms engage in
real and accrual earnings management during the IPO and that big audit
firms constrain discretionary expenses-based and accrual-based manipu-
R&D: research and development, and SG&A: selling, general and administrative expenses.
14
7 Capital Structure and Corporate Governance 153
(a) Show that under equity financing, the manager will choose inef-
ficient project.
(b) Find the condition under which debt financing can improve man-
agerial incentives. What is the minimal face value of debt that
satisfies this condition?
(c) What is the real value of debt found in part (b)?
(d) What fraction of investment will be financed by equity and what
by debt?
3. Consider a firm that has to make an investment that costs 19/32. The
firm’s owner/entrepreneur (E) needs external financing from an out-
side investor (I). E and I are risk-neutral. If the investment is made,
the firm generates earnings R1 in period 1 and R2 in period 2. R1 equals
1 with probability e and 0 otherwise. The cost of effort is e2. I cannot
observe e. E can be involved in EM after observing intermediate earn-
ings R10 and R20. So if R10 = 0 and E uses EM, the final first-period
earnings are R1 = R10 + s and the second-period earnings are
R2 = R20 + s − c , where c = 1 / 8 is the cost of EM. Show that financing
with short-term debt and some degree of earnings manipulation can
be better than financing with equity.
7 Capital Structure and Corporate Governance 157
References
Aboody, D., & Kasznik, R. (2000). CEO stock option awards and the timing of
corporate voluntary disclosures. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 29,
73–100.
Aghion, P., & Bolton, P. (1992). An incomplete contracts approach to financial
contracting. Review of Economic Studies, 59(3), 473–494.
Aghion, P., Bloom, N., & Van Reenen, J. (2013). Incomplete contracts and the
internal organization of firms. NBER working paper.
Alhadab, M., Clacher, I., & Keasey, K. (2013). Effects of audit quality on real
and accrual earnings management and subsequent return performance:
Evidence from IPOs. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2225409
An, Z., Li, D., & Yu, J. (2013). Earnings management, capital structure and the
role of institutional environments. FIRN research paper. Available at SSRN:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2207804
Anantharaman, D., Fang, V., & Gong, G. (2014). Inside debt and the design of
corporate debt contracts. Management Science, 60(5), 1260–1280.
Baldwin, C. (1983). Productivity and labor unions: An application of the theory
of self-enforcing contracts. Journal of Business, 56, 155–185.
Bebchuk, L. A., Grinstein, Y., & Peyer, U. (2006). Lucky directors, Harvard
Law and Economics discussion paper no. 573.
Becht, M., Bolton, P., & Roell, A. (2003). Corporate governance and control.
In G. M. Constantinides, M. Harris, & R. Stulz (Eds.), Handbook of the
economics of finance (pp. 1–109). The Netherlands: Elsevier in Amsterdam,
edition 1 (1), Ch. 1.
Berglöf, E., & Rosenthal, H. (1999). The political economy of American bank-
ruptcy: The evidence from roll call voting, 1800–1978. Mimeo (Princeton
University).
Berglöf, E., & von Thadden, E.-L. (1994). Short-term versus long-term inter-
ests: Capital structure with multiple investors. Quarterly Journal of Economics,
109, 1055–1084.
Berk, J., Stanton, R., & Zechner, J. (2010). Human capital, bankruptcy, and
capital structure. Journal of Finance, 65(3), 891–926.
Berkovitch, E., Israel, H., & Spiegel, Y. (2000). Managerial compensation and
capital structure. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 9(4),
549–584.
Breuer W., Quinten, B., & Salzmann, A. (2015). Bank versus bond finance: A
cultural view of corporate debt financing. In B. Christiansen (Ed.), Handbook
158 Capital Structure in the Modern World
Erman, B. (2007, March 13). Ex-Nortel CEO John Roth says he’s cleared. The
Globe and Mail (Toronto). http://www.theglobeandmail.com/report-on-
business/ex-nortel-ceo-john-roth-says-hes-cleared/article1357907/
Fairchild, R. (2005). The effect of managerial overconfidence, asymmetric infor-
mation, and moral hazard on capital structure decisions. Available at SSRN:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=711845
Franks, J. R., & Sussman, O. (2005). Financial innovations and corporate insol-
vency. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 14(3), 283–317.
Fudenberg, D., & Tirole, J. (1991). Game theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Gale, D., & Hellwig, M. (1985). Incentive-compatible debt contracts: The one-
period problem. Review of Economic Studies, 52, 647–663.
Gillies, R. (2009, June 20). Nortel to sell itself off in pieces. PhysOrg. AP. http://
phys.org/news/2009-06-nortel-pieces.html
Gilson, S. (1990). Bankruptcy boards, banks and blockholders: Evidence on
changes in corporate ownership and control when firms default. Journal of
Financial Economics, 27, 355–387.
Graham, J., Harvey, C., & Rajgopal, S. (2005). The economic implications of
corporate financial reporting. Journal of Accounting and Economics, 40, 3–73.
Gramlich, J. D., & Sorensen, O. (2004). Voluntary management earnings fore-
casts and discretionary accruals: Evidence from Danish IPOs. European
Accounting Review, 13, 235–259.
Griffin, D., & Li, K. (2009). National culture and capital structure decisions:
Evidence from foreign joint ventures in China. Working paper.
Grossman, S., & Hart, O. (1982). Corporate financial structure and managerial
incentives. In J. McCall (Ed.), The economics of information and uncertainty
(pp. 107–140). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Grossman, S., & O.Hart (1986). The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A
Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration. Journal of Political Economy 94(4),
691–719.
Gunny, K. (2010). The relation between earnings management using real activi-
ties manipulation and future performance: Evidence from meeting earnings
benchmarks. Contemporary Accounting Research, 27(3), 855–888.
Hart, O. (1995). Firms, contracts and financial structure. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Hart, O., & Moore, J. (1990). Property rights and the nature of the firm. Journal
of Political Economy, 98(6), 1119–1158.
Hasselback, D., & Tedesco, T. (2014, September 27). The fate of once-mighty
Nortel’s last billions lies in the hands of two men. financialpost.com. National
160 Capital Structure in the Modern World
Post. http://business.financialpost.com/legal-post/the-fate-of-once-mighty-
nortels-last-billions-lies-in-the-hands-of-two-men
Hermalin, B. (2001). Economics and corporate culture. In C. L. Cooper,
S. Cartwright, & P. C. Earley (Eds.), The international handbook of organiza-
tional culture and climate. New York: Wiley.
Hilgen, M. (2014). The impact of cultural clusters on capital structure deci-
sions: Evidence from European retailers. Working paper.
Holmstrom, B. (1979). Moral hazard and observability. Bell Journal of Economics,
10, 74–91.
Innes, R. (1990). Limited liability and incentive contracting with ex-ante action
choices. Journal of Economic Theory, 52(1), 45–67.
Jensen, M. (1986). Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and take-
overs. American Economic Review, 76, 323–329.
Jensen, M. (1989). The eclipse of the public corporation. Harvard Business
Review, 67, 61–74.
Jensen, M., & Meckling, W. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior,
agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3,
305–360.
Kale, J., Ryan, H., & Wang, L. (2015). Outside employment opportunities,
employee productivity, and debt discipline. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.
com/abstract=1022067
Kaplan, S., & Stromberg, P. (2003). Financial contracting theory meets the real
world: An empirical analysis of venture capital contracts. The Review of
Economic Studies, 70(2), 281–316.
Kreps, D. (1990). Corporate culture and economic theory. In J. E. Alt & K. A.
Shepsle (Eds.), Perspectives in positive political economy (pp. 90–143).
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Lemmon, M., Roberts, M., & Zender, J. (2008). Back to the beginning:
Persistence and the cross-section of corporate capital structure. Journal of
Finance, 63, 1575–1608.
Maskin, E., & Tirole, J. (1999a). Incomplete contracts: Where do we stand?
Econometrica, 67(4), 741–781.
Maskin, E., & Tirole, J. (1999b). Unforeseen contingencies and incomplete
contracts. Review of Economic Studies, 66, 83–114.
Matsa, D. (2010). Capital structure as a strategic variable: Evidence from collec-
tive bargaining. The Journal of Finance, 65(3), 1197–1232.
Miglo, A. (2009). Property rights and earnings manipulation. International
Research Journal of Finance and Economics, 31, 116–128.
7 Capital Structure and Corporate Governance 161
Capital
Structure Flexibility Flexibility Tax shield
Factors
Credit Bankruptcy Free cash Free cash
rationing Costs theory theory
More
important
raising bank financing and in issuing shares publicly. Since these firms
have a lot of choice, the asset substitution problem is important but only
if the firm has a lot of debt. The credit rationing phenomenon is also very
important for these firms. Although this was explained using the asset
substitution effect it can also be explained with asymmetric information
between lenders and borrowers.2
Most factors point to the preference of equity over debt for start-up
firms. For many years this was used as an explanation for why start-up
firms often use the capital of their firms’ founders and managers, or
“sweet” equity from friends and relatives, and why they have difficulties
using bank financing. Closer analyses of start-up entrepreneurial firms,
however, reveal that many firms use convertible securities for financing.
Jacob Demitt, in a December 2015 article, described an $8 million financ-
ing for Textio via series A funding.3 It was led by Emergence Capital, one of
the top software-as-a-service investors, known for backing companies like
See, for example, Stiglitz and Weiss (1981) and Freixas and Rochet (1999).
2
Salesforce, Box, and Yammer. Textio was founded in 2014, after one of their
founders Snyder conducted research on gender bias in performance reviews
in the tech industry. Snyder is a linguistics expert who previously worked at
Amazon and Microsoft’s Bing unit. Co-founder and CTO Jensen Harris,
meanwhile, spent 16 years at Microsoft including stints running the user
experience teams for Outlook, Office, and Windows. The key to Textio’s
offering is the use of artificial intelligence to sift through job postings and
make recommendations for edits based on what kind of language is going
to appeal—or scare away—certain demographics. For instance, if you use
words like “manage a team” or “proven track record,” Texio says you’re going
to get more male applicants. Phrases like “passion for learning” and “develop
a team,” meanwhile, will attract more women. Wikipedia describes Series A
Preferred Stock as the first round of stock offered during the seed or early
stage round.4 Preferred stock is often convertible into common stock in cer-
tain cases such as an IPO or the sale of the company. Further in this chapter
we will consider a model that illustrates why a start-up firm may be interested
in using convertible securities.
Another issue in the financing of start-up and small firms is the revival
of debt financing. Emma Vins describes loan programs for start-ups.5
Debt financing for start-up and small companies is subject to credit
rationing, as we discussed in Chap. 4. Until recently, experts thought that
debt was not a major source of financing for start-up firms and instead
payed more attention to entrepreneurs own funds, venture funds, and
angel financing. In recent years the situation seems to have been chang-
ing. We will consider later why debt financing is important for start-up
firms and what the usage of debt signals about the firm’s quality.
http://www.investopedia.com/terms/s/seriesa.asp
4
Period 1
The first-best effort maximizes the firm’s value: e − e2 . Socially optimal
e* = 1 / 2. In the case of equity financing E will maximize ke − e2 , where
k is the fraction of equity that belongs to E. Optimal e ′ = k / 2 . For any
k < 1, e ′ < e* .
8 Capital Structure of Start-Up Firms and Small Firms 167
Entrepreneur
Entrepreneur
and Investor
chooses the
choose their
level of effort in
A irm raises level of effort in
period 1. Period
inancing for an period 2. Period
1 earnings
investment 2 earnings
become known
project become known
and are
and are
distributed to
distributed to
claimholders
claimholders
E’s profit is then k2/4. To find the optimal contract, we have to find k that
will maximize E’s profit under the condition that the investor’s expected
profit is not less than b. This condition is e (1 − k ) = k (1 − k ) / 2 ≥ 1 / 8 . The
left side of the inequality reaches its maximum when k = 1 / 2 . In this
case, I’s expected payoff is 1/8. E’s expected payoff is k2/4. It is increasing
on k. Hence the optimal k is the largest value of k that satisfies I’s budget
constraint, i.e. 1/2. The optimal e = 1 / 4 and E’s expected payoff is 1/16.
Now consider debt financing. Two cases are possible. First, e < D
. In this case the manager maximizes 1 / 3 ( 2e − D ) − e2 . So the optimal
e = 1 / 3 . E’s expected payoff is 1 / 9 − 1 / 3D . Second, e > D . In this case
the manager maximizes 1 / 3 (e − D ) + 1 / 3 (2e − D ) − e2 . So the optimal
e = 1 / 2 . E’s expected payoff is 1 / 4 − 2 / 3D . By comparing the man-
ager’s payoffs in each case we find that if D < 5 / 12 the optimal e = 1 / 2
and otherwise e = 1 / 3 . Now to find D, note that the investor’s payoff
should be greater than b. So in the second case D = 3 / 2b . It is possible
only if b < 5 / 18 , which is our case. So the firm can be financed with debt
with face value 3/16. The manager’s profit, in this case, is 1/8.
Period 2
The first-best effort maximizes the firm’s value: e1 + e2 − e12 − e22 . Hence,
socially optimal e1* = e2* = 1 / 2. Under equity financing, E has a fraction k
of the firm’s equity. So E will maximize k (e1 + e2 ) − e12 . Optimal e1 ′ = k / 2 .
Similarly we find e2 ′ = (1 − k ) / 2.
168 Capital Structure in the Modern World
1 − k (1 − k )
2
6
See, for instance, Kaplan and Stromberg (2003) and Elfenbein and Lerner (2003) with regard to
venture capital contracts and Gilson (1990) for corporate contracts.
8 Capital Structure of Start-Up Firms and Small Firms 169
7
Convertible preferred stock: Preferred stock that can be converted at the shareholder’s discretion
into common stock. Participating convertible preferred stock: A type of preferred stock that gives
the holder the right to receive dividends equal to the normally specified rate that preferred divi-
dends receive as well as an additional dividend based on some predetermined condition.
http://www.investopedia.com/terms/c/convertiblepreferredstock.asp, http://www.investopedia.
com/terms/p/participating-convertible-preferred-share.asp
170 Capital Structure in the Modern World
formance in the initial public offering (IPO) year, and post-IPO survival
rate, but only if the firm is located far away from the VC investor.
Talmor and Cuny (2005) analyze the choice between milestone financ-
ing and round financing when VC commits to future rounds upfront.
When the role of a venture capitalist’s effort is small, the incentivization
of the entrepreneur dominates the contractual relationship and round
financing is preferred to milestone financing. When it is the role of entre-
preneurial effort that is small, however, the need for contract flexibility
dominates, and milestone financing is preferred to round financing.
Häussler et al. (2012) develop a model where certification serves as a
signal about the quality of entrepreneurial firms. They derive and empiri-
cally test several hypotheses using a sample of British and German com-
panies that seek VC. They find that patent applications—as signals from
ventures—are positively related to VC financing. Moreover, applications
trigger institutionalized processes at the patent office, which can generate
valuable technological and commercial information via search reports,
citations and opposition procedures, and thus affect VC financing. The
results highlight the role of signaling, but additional information about
venture quality is generated via an institutionalized certification process.
Another recent trend in the financing of start-up firms is crowdfund-
ing. Crowdfunding is the practice of funding a start-up company or a
project by raising funds from a large number of people (“crowd”). It is
usually performed online.8 The concept can also be executed through
mail-order subscriptions, benefit events, and other methods. Moritz and
Block (2014) provide a review of the recent literature in this field.
8
See, for example, Schwienbacher and Larralde (2012).
9
For a detailed discussion of reasons for that and the role of the Kauffmann Foundation see, for
example, Robb and Robinson (2012) and Cole and Sokolyk (2014).
8 Capital Structure of Start-Up Firms and Small Firms 171
One of the issues that has been receiving a lot of attention is the usage
of debt by small companies (Robb and Robinson 2012; Cole and Sokolyk
2014). Some authors argue that recent findings about the importance of
outside (formal) debt for small companies are contradictory to common
opinion that small businesses, especially start-ups, rely heavily on internal
finance including the owner’s equity and funds from relatives and friends
(Robb and Robinson, 2012). Robb and Robinson (2012) also find that
the usage of outside debt by a start-up firm is indicative of its success a
few years after its creation. In particular, they find that firms that use
outside debt have better growth and have better chances of survival com-
pared to firms that do not use outside debt. Below we present a model
where entrepreneurs have a choice between outside debt, inside debt, and
the owner’s equity to finance their start-up firms.
Consider a set of entrepreneurs, indexed with j, with investment proj-
ects available. The projects require the same amount of external financing
equal to 1. In the case of success, a project generates a cash flow Fj and
a cash flow of zero otherwise. The probability of success is pj. There are
three types of financing available for the project. Full financing for the
project can be obtained via outside debt (OD). It is assumed that each
entrepreneur has collateral valued 1. Alternatively, the entrepreneur can
use inside debt (ID). Here, an entrepreneur borrows an amount β , β ≤ 1
from a friend or relative. If the project succeeds, the earnings are βFj.
Finally, the entrepreneur can use inside equity (IE).10 An entrepreneur
has an amount α available to finance the firm, α < β . If the project
succeeds, the earnings are αFj. Fj and pj are private information for each
entrepreneur. Entrepreneurs and investors are risk-neutral.
In this model the entrepreneurs’ choices of financing for their start-up
firms are based on the following trade-off. Entrepreneurs who do not use
OD are facing greater financial constraints during the first years of their
businesses. On the other hand the providers of OD have more experience
in enforcing debt payments compared to the providers of ID. Asymmetric
information between the entrepreneurs and the capital providers plays a
very important role in start-up firms, which affects the details of negotia-
tions including interest rates on loans and collateral. Robb and Robinson
10
Outside equity is ruled out. It does constitute a relatively small fraction of small firms’ capital
structure. Seven times as many firms report outside debt as report outside equity (Robb and
Robinson 2012).
172 Capital Structure in the Modern World
(2012) mentioned that outside debt providers, like banks, are more expe-
rienced in terms of controlling collaterals and enforcing debt contracts
(both for firms with unlimited liability and firms with limited liability)
compared to friends and relatives. Even if the firm is formally created as a
firm with limited liability, financing for start-ups often circumvents lim-
ited liability and requires personal guarantees from entrepreneurs. Often
entrepreneurs own levered equity in their firms. They borrow on their
own behalf and then invest in their start-up firms. If the firm fails, the
entrepreneur can lose a large part of the wealth that he or she pledged as
collateral.
We argue that in equilibrium entrepreneurs with business credit have
higher success rates and greater revenues than other firms. This is consis-
tent with empirical evidence.
Choice of Financing
We have the following set of equations that determine an equilibrium.
The choice between ID (the face value is D) and IE is given by:
p j ( β Fj − D ) = α p j Fj − α (8.1)
The left side of (8.1) shows the entrepreneur’s expected earnings for
ID. The probability of success is multiplied by the net earnings in the case
of success. The right side shows the entrepreneur’s expected earnings for
IE. The firm’s expected revenues are reduced by the amount of the initial
investment. Equation (8.1) can be rewritten as:
−α
pj = (8.2)
β Fj − D − α Fj
p j ( β Fj − D ) = p j ( Fj − D′ ) − (1 − p j )
−1 (8.3)
pj =
β Fj − D + D′ − 1 − Fj
∂p j − (1 − β )
We have = >0 and
∂Fj (β F − D + D′ − 1 − Fj )
2
j
2 (1 − β )
2
∂2 p j
= > 0.
∂Fj 2 (β F − D + D′ − 1 − Fj )
3
j
p j ( Fj − D′ ) − (1 − p j ) = α p j Fj − α
1−α
pj = (8.4)
Fj − D′ + 1 − α Fj
− (1 − α )
2
∂p j
We have: = >0. Also:
(F − D′ + 1 − α Fj )
2
∂Fj
j
2 (1 − α )
2
∂2 p j
= >0.
(F − D′ + 1 − α Fj )
3
∂Fj 2
j
174 Capital Structure in the Modern World
The analysis of (8.2), (8.3), and (8.4) reveals that the marginal entre-
preneur with Fj = F * and p j = p* is indifferent between every type of
financing where
− D + α D − α D′ + α
F* = (8.5)
− β + αβ
and
− β + αβ
p* = (8.6)
− D + α D + β D′ − α D′ − β + α
We can also check that the slope of (8.4) is larger than that of (8.3).
Figure 8.3 illustrates the equilibrium decision-making for the entrepre-
neurs. The thick lines represent equations (8.2), (8.3), and (8.4). Letters
IE, OD, and ID denote the areas where the entrepreneurs choose the
internal equity, the outside debt, or the inside debt respectively.
From Fig. 8.3, entrepreneurs with OD have a higher probability of suc-
cess for any value of Fj compared to entrepreneurs with IE and ID. Also,
The fact that equations (2), (3) and (4) have discontinuities does not affect this result. For example,
11
the line corresponding to equation (2) has a discontinuity in Fj = D / ( β − α ) . But the continua-
tion of this line after the disconnection lies below p j = 0 . So in the area above this line
entrepreneurs prefer ID to IE.
12
Cole and Sokolyk (2014).
176 Capital Structure in the Modern World
often created with unlimited liability. Using outside debt sends a strong
message about a firm’s quality.
Several strands of the existing literature discuss related problems. First
is the literature on debt financing of privately held firms (see, e.g. Ang
(1992), Berger and Udell (1998), Cole (2013), Brav (2009), Ang et al.
(2010), Robb and Robinson (2012), Cole (2013)). Secondly, the growing
literature that analyzes start-up firms using data from the Kauffman Firm
Surveys (see, e.g., Coleman and Robb (2009), Fairlie and Robb (2009),
Cole (2011), Coleman and Robb (2012), Robb and Watson (2012), and
Robb and Robinson (2012)). Thirdly, capital structure choice literature
that is based on asymmetric information (see, e.g., mentioned in Chap. 3
Myers and Majluf (1984); also DeMeza and Webb (1987), and Boadway
and Keen (2005)). Finally, the literature that analyzes the role of unlim-
ited liability in entrepreneurs’ decision-making (see, e.g., Becker and
Fuest (2007), Miglo (2007)).
Stiglitz and Weiss (1981) and de Meza and Webb (1987) focus on debt
financing under asymmetric information. They predict that when inter-
mediaries are unable to distinguish between high and low quality new
investment projects, they make an inefficient volume of loans. This may
create the possibility of welfare-improving interventions even by a gov-
ernment that is no better informed than the intermediaries themselves.
Boadway and Keen (2005) argue that the assumptions are too restrictive
in both of those papers (in terms of revenue distributions) which, on the
one hand leads to opposite predictions (too many loans vs. too few loans)
and on the other hand does not help understand the capital structure
choice. Internal funds are not a part of their models. They also lack the
other features of financing relating to small business.
There is also literature on the difference between firms with limited
liability and unlimited liability. To the best of our knowledge, there is no
paper that predicts that either type has a natural advantage in terms of
signaling the firm’s quality or survival opportunities. Some papers address
the issues close to ours. For example, Becker and Fuest (2007) and Miglo
(2007) use the asymmetric information framework to explain the link
between the limited liability/unlimited liability choice and corporate
taxation in situations when entrepreneurs can offset potential losses and
when asymmetric information exists regarding projects’ qualities.
8 Capital Structure of Start-Up Firms and Small Firms 177
Cole (2010) looks at data from the 1993, 1998, and 2003 SSBFs to
provide evidence about the types of firms that use the different types of
credit: trade credit, bank credit, both, or no credit. Only about one in
five firms use no credit and finance assets with 100 % equity. Robb and
Robinson (2012) use data from the Kauffman Firm Surveys to docu-
ment that newly founded firms rely heavily on formal debt financing
rather than on informal funding from friends and family. They document
that, contrary to the widely held view about entrepreneurial finance, the
largest part of total financial capital comes from outsiders’ debt. Cole
and Sokolyk (2014) confirm the importance of outside (formal) debt for
small companies. Robb and Robinson (2012) also find that firms that
use outside debt have better growth and chances of survival compared to
firms that do not.
References
Ang, J. (1992). On the theory of finance for privately held firms. Journal of
Small Business Finance, 1, 185–203.
Ang, J., Cole, R., & Lawson, J. (2010). The role of owner in capital structure
decisions: An analysis of single-owner corporations. Journal of Entrepreneurial
Finance, 14, 1–36.
Becker, J., & Fuest, C. (2007). Why is there corporate taxation? The role of
limited liability revisited. Journal of Economics, 92, 1–10.
Berger, A., & Udell, G. (1998). The economics of small business finance: The
roles of private equity and debt markets in the financial growth cycle. Journal
of Banking and Finance, 22, 613–673.
Berglof, E. (1994). A control theory of venture capital. Journal of Law, Economics
and Organizations, 10(2), 247–267.
Boadway, R., & Keen, M. (2005). Financing and taxing new firms Under asym-
metric information, Queen’s University working paper
8 Capital Structure of Start-Up Firms and Small Firms 179
Brav, O. (2009). Access to capital, capital structure, and the funding of the firm.
The Journal of Finance, 64, 263–308.
Cole, R. (2010). Bank credit, trade credit or no credit? Evidence from the
Surveys of Small Business Finances, U.S. Small Business Administration
Research Study No. 365
Cole, R. (2011). How do firms choose legal form of organization? U.S. Small
Business Administration Research Study No. 383
Cole, R. (2013). What do we know about the capital structure of privately held
firms? Evidence from the Surveys of Small Business Finances, Financial
Management (Winter), 777–813
Cole, R., & Sokolyk, T. (2014). Debt financing, survival, and growth of start-up
firms. European Financial Management Association Annual conference’,
http://www.efmaefm.org/0EFMAMEETINGS/EFMA%20ANNUAL%20
MEETINGS/2014-Rome/papers/EFMA2014_0612_fullpaper.pdf
Coleman, S., & Robb, A. (2009). A comparison of new firm financing by gen-
der: Evidence from the Kauffman Firm Survey data. Small Business Economics,
33, 397–411.
Coleman, S., & Robb, A. (2012). Capital structure theory and new technology
firms: Is there a match? Management Research Review, 35(2), 106–120.
Cornelli, F., & Yosha, O. (2003). Stage financing and the role of convertible
securities. Review of Economic Studies, 70(242), 1–32.
Cumming, D. (2005). Capital structure in venture finance. Journal of Corporate
Finance, 11(3), 550–585.
Damodaran, A. (2003). Corporate finance: Theory and practice. New Jersey:
Hoboken, Wiley Series in Finance
DeMeza, D., & Webb, D. (1987). Too much investment: A problem of asym-
metric information. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 102, 281–292.
Demitt, J. (2015, December 16). Textio raises $8M as major tech companies use
its tools to attract more diverse job applicants. GeekWire. http://www.gee-
kwire.com/2015/textio-raises-8m-as-most-major-tech-companies-
try-its-tools-to-attract-more-diverse-job-applicants/
Elfenbein, D., & Lerner, J. (2003). Ownership and control rights in internet
portal alliances, 1995–1999. RAND Journal of Economics, 34(2), 356–369.
Fairlie, R., & Robb, A. (2009). Gender differences in business performance:
Evidence from the characteristics of business owners survey. Small Business
Economics, 33, 375–395.
180 Capital Structure in the Modern World
Talmor, E., & Cuny, C. (2005). The staging of venture capital financing:
Milestone vs. rounds, EFA 2005 Moscow Meetings Paper. Available at SSRN:
http://ssrn.com/abstract=487414
Tian, X. (2011). The causes and consequences of venture capital stage financing.
Journal of Financial Economics, 101(1), 132–159.
Vins, E. (Updated: Dec 7, 2015 Published: Nov 26, 2015). How your business
could benefit from a Start Up Loan. Sturtups. http://startups.co.uk/
how-your-business-could-benefit-from-a-start-up-loan/
9
Corporate Capital Structure vs. Project
Financing
9.1 Introduction
This chapter discusses project finance. From my experience, when speak-
ing about project finance people think about different things. Often they
are confused because they do not understand why project finance should
be discussed as a separate topic since it is, seemingly, a part of almost
every other topic including general topics like investments, net present
value, etc. We will learn in this chapter that project financing has a very
special meaning in finance and is often related to terms like non-recourse
debt, limited recourse debt, asset-backed securities, and many others. To
begin, let us note that project financing has been used in many important
projects around the globe including many historical projects. Below we
will review some of them.
Lyonett du Moutier (2010) describes the famous Eiffel Tower construc-
tion, which was the world’s tallest structure at its completion in 1889.
Apparently, a project finance model was used. Public authorities awarded
a concession to the project’s private sponsor. The sponsor was financing it
with equity and limited-recourse debt. Lyonett (2010) a nalyzes how spe-
cific provisions in the Eiffel Tower project contracts helped reduce agency
costs, which are often very substantial in large projects.
The World Bank’s project finance and guarantees group describes on
its website (2005) the development of the Nam Theun 2 hydropower
project.1 Since 1995, it has been a top priority for the Government of
Laos. Electricité de France of France, Italian-Thai Development Public
Company Limited of Thailand, and Electricity Generating Public
Company Limited of Thailand sponsored the project. It is the largest ever
foreign investment in Laos, the world’s largest private sector cross-border
power project financing, the largest private sector hydroelectric project
financing, and one of the largest internationally financed projects in Asia.
The project has been structured as a limited recourse financing which,
the article argues, allows for an efficient allocation of multiple risks that
are usually involved in large construction projects including completion
risk, commercial and political risks, geological risk, and risk of timely and
within budget completion.
In a December 2015 article by Matthew Amlôt we find that the
National Central Cooling Company PJSC (Tabreed) announced its
completion of the signing of an AED 192.5 million long-term limited
recourse project finance facility with Emirates NBD for the district cool-
ing plant it is developing for Dubai Parks and Resorts.2 Jasim Husain
Thabet, Tabreed’s Chief Executive Officer, said, “Tabreed’s approach to
financing new projects is to utilize long-term project financing wherever
possible which we believe is the best way of financing our assets and max-
imizing value for all stakeholders. This loan facility with Emirates NBD
is a landmark deal as it is amongst the first district cooling transactions
completed in the UAE under a limited recourse project finance structure
for a Greenfield development.”
In 2004, project financing in the United States made up 10–15 % of
total capital investment.3 In 2007 the total volume of project financ-
1
http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTGUARANTEES/Resources/Lao_NamTheun2_Note.pdf
2
Amlôt (December 16, 2015).
3
Esty (2004).
9 Corporate Capital Structure vs. Project Financing 185
A irm with
debt and
Shareholders
assets-in-place
decide whether
receives
to accept or
information
reject the
about a new
project
investment
opportunity
If the project is
accepted, the Earnings are
irm issues realized and
new debt to distributed to
inance the claimholders
project
The firm issued senior debt with total amount D such that
R1 + C1 > D > R2 + C2
(9.2)
This means that in the good state the project’s payoff exceeds the
amount of debt but not in the bad state. The sequence of events is as in
Fig. 9.1.
p1 ( R1 − D )
(9.3)
If the firm invests in the new project, the shareholders’ expected profit
is: p1 ( R1 + C1 − D ) − K . This is equal to the firm’s expected cash flow (the
total earnings in state G reduced by the payment to the senior creditors
9 Corporate Capital Structure vs. Project Financing 189
K = d p1 + (1 − p1 ) C2 (9.4)
If B is realized, the debtholders get the cash flow from the new proj-
ect (C2). The shareholders’ expected payoff (note that the shareholders
get nothing if B is realized) is: p1 ( C1 − d + R1 − D ). This is greater than
(9.3) because it follows from (9.1) and (9.4) that d < C1. Hence, the
shareholders’ payoff with the new project is higher than it is without
it. So the project will be undertaken and it will be financed with non-
recourse debt.
The second situation is based on overinvestment: the shareholder’s
incentive to invest in negative NPV projects (similar to the asset substitu-
tion effect from Chap. 4). Consider the same firm with assets in place,
as described previously. This time, assume that the firm has a senior debt
with a face value
This implies that the change in the firm’s expected earnings (left side of
this inequality) is less than the amount of the investment, which means
that the new project has a negative NPV.
Example 9.1
Consider a firm with assets in place, an investment opportunity avail-
able, and outstanding senior debt with a face value of D = 5000. Existing
assets can produce: 8000 in state G (good state) with probability 1/2
and 3000 in state B with probability 1/2. The new project requires an
initial investment of 1500, and the firm will finance this investment by
issuing new debt. A new project’s cost is 1500. The new project generates
2200 in state G and 1000 in state B.
First note that the new project has a positive net present value (NPV)
because 1 / 2 ∗ 1000 + 1 / 2 ∗ 2200 > 1500 . Now suppose that to finance the
new project the firm issues a standard subordinated debt. The face value,
d’, of this debt can be found from the following equation:
1500 = d′ * 1 / 2 + 1 / 2 * 0
1500 = d ∗ 1 / 2 + 1 / 2 ∗ 1000
Here d = 2000 . The shareholders’ expected payoff (note that the share-
holders get nothing if B is realized) is: 1 / 2 * ( 8000 − D + 2200 − d ) = 1600.
This is greater than 1500 (the shareholders’ expected payoff without the
new investment), and thus the project will be undertaken and it will be
financed with non-recourse debt.
Now assume that the firm (with the same initial project) has a senior debt
with a face value of D = 10, 000. The new project requires an initial invest-
192 Capital Structure in the Modern World
ment of 100. The new project generates 4000 in state G and 0 in state B but
reduces the probability of G occurring by 30 %. Note that the new proj-
ect has a negative NPV because 0.3 ∗ 3000 − 0.3 ∗ 8000 + 0.2 ∗ 4000 < 100
(see condition 9.6)).
Suppose that to finance the new project the firm issues a standard
subordinated debt. The face value, d’, of this debt can be found from the
following equation:
This means that if G is realized, the new debtholders will receive the
face value of the debt; if, however, B is realized, the firm’s cash flow is
3000 + 1000 = 4000 , which is less than the face value of the senior debt,
leaving the new creditors with nothing. From 9.7), d ′ = 500 .
The shareholders’ expected payoff without the new investment is 0.
With the new project, it will be 0.2 ∗ (12, 000 − 10, 000 − 500 ) = 300 . Since
the expected payoff with the new project is more than that without the
project, it will be undertaken.
Now suppose that the firm uses project financing (non-recourse debt).
In this case, the debtholders’ payoffs depend only on the returns from the
new project and not on the returns from the assets already in place. Since
the NPV is negative, the firm will not able to finance the project.
John and John (1991) analyze project financing in the context of the
underinvestment problem in the spirit of Myers (1977). They also take
taxes into consideration. It is shown that a project financing arrange-
ment, where the debt is optimally allocated to the sponsor firm and the
new venture, increases the project’s value by reducing agency costs and
increasing the value of the tax shields (compared to the case of straight
debt financing).
There are several empirical papers that look for the existence of proj-
ect financing in capital structure and how it has worked to mitigate the
moral hazard problem.
For instance, Kensinger and Martin (1988) noted that because of
the number of large capital expenditures businesses are making, moral
9 Corporate Capital Structure vs. Project Financing 193
A irm's type
Earnings are
is detrmined. Securities
realized and
The irm are sold to
distributed
chooses its outside
to
capital investors
claimholders
structure
type gets their first-best value (expected earnings from the project minus
the investment cost). So for type 1 it is ER1 − B and for type 2 it is ER2 − B .
Consider a type 2 firm mimicking a type 1. The difference between the
shareholders’ expected payoff in this case and their equilibrium payoff is
∞ ∞ ∞
∆T = ∫ ( R − s ( R ) ) g ( R ) dR − ∫ ( R − s ( R ) ) g ( R ) dR = ∫ ( s ( R ) − s ( R ) )
−∞
1
−∞
2
−∞
2 1
g ( R ) dP
∞ ∞
We also know that
∫ s1 ( R ) f ( R ) dR = B and
−∞
∫ s ( R ) g ( R ) dR = B.
−∞
2
∞ ∞
We will show that ∆T > 0 or that ∫ s1 ( R ) g ( R ) dR < ∫ s ( R ) f ( R ) dR = B.
1
−∞ −∞
∞
Consider ∫ s ( R ) ( f ( R ) − g ( R ) ) dR.
−∞
1
= ∫ s1 ( R ) ( G ( R ) − F ( R ) ) dR
′
−∞
projects) and firms are allowed to issue securities with the projects’ con-
tingent payoffs rather than only with total cash flows contingent payoffs,
a separation may exist even if the firm’s total cash flows are ordered by
the first-order dominance condition. Possible interpretations are project
financing or financing with non-recourse debt, issuing asset-backed secu-
rities, and firms’ spin-offs. In all of these cases the firm creates securities
that represent claims on specific projects (assets).
To illustrate the idea, consider the following example. A firm has two
projects available, k = 1, 2. The return of project k is Rk. The project’s suc-
cess depends on the firm’s type j, j = h, l. Rk equals 1 with probability θkj
and equals 0 otherwise.
As in Brennan and Kraus, Rh first-order dominates Rl, which means
that the probability that Rh = 0 is less than the probability of Rl = 0 and
that the probability that Rh equals 0 or 1 is less than that of Rl. It implies:
d jk = bk / θ kj (9.10)
The non-deviation condition for l (i.e. the condition for which type l
will choose not to mimic type h) can be written as
θ θ
b1 1 − l1 ≤ b2 1 − l 2 (9.11)
θ h1 θ h 2
Example 9.2
Suppose that θh1 = 0.7, θh2 = 0.3, θl1 = 0.2, θl 2 = 0.6 and b=
1 b=1 0.2. We
can check that Rh first-order dominates Rl because conditions (9.8) and
(9.9) hold. From (9.10): dh1 = 2 / 7, dh2 = 2 / 3, dl1 = 1 and dl 2 = 1 / 3. The
non-deviation condition for l (i.e., the condition for which type l will
choose not to mimic type h) can be written as
1 − Pl ( 0 ) θ
b1 1 − ≤ b 1 − l2 (9.12)
1 − P ( 0 ) 2 θ
h h 2
If we consider the case when θh1 < θl1 and θl 2 < θh 2 then condition (9.12)
can be interpreted as follows. The likelihood that this condition is satis-
fied (and successful utilization of project finance by firm h) increases with
an increase in the amount of investment in project 2 (b2) maintaining that
b1 is sufficiently small. Secondly, if θl2 is sufficiently smaller than θh2 and/
or if 1 − Pl (0 ) is sufficiently close to 1 − Ph (0 ) . This means that a separat-
ing equilibrium exists when the asymmetry regarding the firm’s overall
quality (probability of default in both projects) is sufficiently small while
the asymmetry regarding the project, for which the firm issues project-
contingent securities, is large. A similar condition can be obtained for the
b1 b
case 1 < + 2.
1 − Ph ( 0 ) θ h 2
Example 9.3
Suppose that θh1 = 0.3, θh2 = 0.6, θl1 = 0.6, θl 2 = 0.2, b1 = 0.1 and b2 = 0.4 .
We can check that Rh first-order dominates Rl because conditions (9.8)
and (9.9) above hold.
As follows from our previous analysis: d = b2 / θh 2 . So d = 2 / 3 . Also
b1 b1
D= = = 5 / 36. The non-deviation condition
1 − Ph ( 0 ) 1 − (1 − θ h1 ) (1 − θ h 2 )
for l (i.e. the condition for which type l will choose not to mimic type h)
can be written as (1 − 2 / 3 − 5 / 36 ) ∗ 0.6 + (1 − 2 / 3) ∗ 0.2 ≤ 0.2 . After sim-
plifications we get 11 / 60 ≤ 0.2 which holds.
We can also see that h cannot do it the other way around, i.e. use
project financing for project 1. We have: d = b1 / θh1. So d = 1 / 3 and
b2
D= = 5 / 9. The non-deviation condition for l (i.e. the condi-
1 − Ph ( 0 )
tion for which type l will choose not to mimic type h) can be written as
its optimal capital structure. This helps explain why some firms have vir-
tually no debt while others have quite a lot. While there are many other
considerations behind a firm’s capital structure choice, this model helps
shed more light on the subject. It shows how the structure of project
financing contracts can help reduce agency costs and moral hazard dilem-
mas that plague firms even when there are informational asymmetries
between entrepreneurs and creditors.
As mentioned, project financing uses a complex series of contracts to
“distribute the different risks presented by a project among the various
parties involved in the project.”6 They are created to dictate the manage-
ment’s response to any number of issues. The large number of contracts
clearly reduces agency costs because there is less worry that the manag-
ers will not be acting in the best interests of the firm as a whole. With
corporate debt, there are a number of problems with creating contracts
to specify actions of shareholders and managers in response to market
stimuli. As Brealey, Cooper, and Habib (1996) note, there are simply too
many circumstances to consider.
It is very important that these contracts anticipate what may happen
and provide a solution. Some of the risks that a project finance company
may be subjected to include technological risk, construction risk, com-
pletion risks, inflation risk, environmental risk, regulatory risk, and polit-
ical and country risk. For example, the telecom sector showed a decline
in 2006 likely due to the technological acceleration and development in
the sector.7 The contracts are necessary to properly allocate the risks to
the counterparty best able to control and manage them. This is another
one of the primary reasons why firm managers will choose to separately
incorporate a new investment with project financing.
Marty and Voisins (2007) noted that since the shareholders may be
likely to sell off their stake well before the expiry date of the concession,
a professional evaluation of the project financed companies at different
stages of the project’s life seems increasingly important.
Kleimeier and Versteeg (2010) argue that project finance is designed
to reduce transaction costs arising from a lack of information on possible
Gatti (2008).
7
9 Corporate Capital Structure vs. Project Financing 205
4. The economy consists of two different types of firms. Each firm has
two projects: they produce 1 if they are successful and 0 otherwise.
The probability of success for firm j, j = 1, 2 and project k, k = 1, 2 is
given by θjk. We have θ11 = 0.75, θ12 = 0.25, θ22 = 0.6, θ 21 = 0.25. Both
projects require an investment 0.2. Outside investors don’t know the
type of the firm (there is 50 % of each type of firms in this economy)
but they can observe the interest rate for each contract signed by each
firm.
References
Amlôt, M. (2015, December 16). Tabreed finalises AED 192.5m loan facility
for district cooling plant for Dubai Parks and Resorts. CPI financials. http://
www.cpifinancial.net/news/post/34011/tabreed-finalises-aed-192-5m-loan-
facility-for-district-cooling-plant-for-dubai-parks-and-Resorts
Berkovitch, E., & Kim, E. (1990). Financial contracting and leverage induced
over and under investment incentives. The Journal of Finance, 3, 765–794.
Bonetti, V., Caselli, S., & Gatti, S. (2010). Offtaking agreements and how they
impact the cost of funding for project deals. A clinical case study of the
Quezon Power Ltd Co. Review of Financial Economics, 19(2), 60–71.
Brealey, R., Cooper, I., & Habib, M. (1996). Using project finance to fund
infrastructure investments. Journal of Applies Corporate Finance, 9(3),
25–38.
Brennan, M., & Kraus, A. (1987). Efficient financing under information asym-
metry. Journal of Finance, 42(5), 1225–1243.
Calomiris, C., & Mason, J. (2004). Credit card securitization and regulatory
arbitrage. Journal of Financial Services Research, 26, 5–27.
Chemmanur, T., & John, K. (1996). Optimal incorporation, structure of debt
contacts and limited-recourse project financing. Journal of Financial
Intermediation, 5, 372–408.
Corielli, F., Gatti, S., & Steffanoni, A. (2010). Risk shifting through nonfinan-
cial contracts. Effects on loan spreads and capital structure of project finance
deals. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 42(7), 1295–1320.
Esty, B. (2003). The economic motivations for using project finance. Working
paper. Harvard Business School.
Esty, B. (2004). Why study large projects? An introduction to research on proj-
ect finance. European Financial Management, 10, 213–224.
Flyvbjerg, B., Holm, M., & Buhl, S. (2002). Underestimating costs in pub-
lic works projects. Journal of the American Planning Association, 68,
279–295.
Gardner, D., & Wright, J. (2012). Project finance. In T. Rhodes (Ed.),
Encyclopedia of debt finance (2nd ed.). London: Euromoney Learning
Solution. Ch. 13.
Gatti, S. (2008). Project finance in theory and practice. London: Academic.
Gatti, S., Kleimeier, S., Megginson, W. L., & Steffanoni, A. (2013). Arranger
certification in project finance. Financial Management, 42(1), 1–40.
208 Capital Structure in the Modern World
Habib, M. A., & Johnsen, D. B. (1999). The financing and redeployment of
specific assets. The Journal of Finance, 2, 693–720.
Hainz, C., & Kleimeier, S. (2006). Project finance as a risk management tool in
international syndicated lending. Discussion paper no. 183. GESY.
Hainz, C., & Kleimeier, S. (2012). Political risk, project finance, and the partici-
pation of development banks in syndicated lending. Journal of Financial
Intermediation, 21(2), 287–314.
John, K., & John, T. (1991). Optimality of project financing: Theory and
empirical implications in finance and accounting. Review of Quantitative
Finance and Accounting, 1, 51–74.
Kensinger, J., & Martin, J. (1988). Project financing: Raising money the old
fashioned way. Journal of Applied Corporate Finance, 3, 69–81.
Kleimeier, S., & Megginson, W. (2001). An empirical analysis of limited
recourse project finance. Working paper. University of Oklahoma.
Kleimeier, S., & Versteeg, R. (2010). Project finance as a driver of economic
growth in low-income countries. Review of Financial Economics, 19(2),
49–59.
Lyonnet du Moutier, M. (2010). Financing the Eiffel Tower: Project finance and
agency theory. Journal of Applied Finance, 20(1), 127–141.
Marty, F., & Voisins, A. (2007). The role of financial intermediaries in UK
Private Finance Initiatives. Working paper.
McGuinty, T. (1981). Project organization and finance. Cleveland: The Cleveland-
Cliffs Iron Company.
Merrow, E., McDonnell, L., & Arguden, R. (1988). Understanding the out-
comes of megaprojects: A quantitative analysis of very large Civilian Projects.
RAND Corporation publication series #R-3560-PSSP.
Miglo, A. (2010). Project financing versus corporate financing under asym-
metric information. Journal of Business and Economics Research, 8(8),
27–43.
Miller, R., & Lessard, D. (2000). The strategic management of large engineering
projects. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Myers, S. C. (1977). Determinants of corporate borrowing. Journal of Financial
Economics, 5, 147–175.
Myers, S., & Majluf, N. (1984). Corporate financing and investment decisions
when firms have information that investors do not have. Journal of Financial
Economics, 13, 187–221.
Nevitt, P. (1979). Project financing. London: Euromoney Publications.
9 Corporate Capital Structure vs. Project Financing 209
1
For capital structure analysis of internet companies as of 2011 see Lee, Liang, and Miglo (2014).
For capital structure analysis of some companies in the fertiliser industry see Khatik and Singh
(2006).
10.2 Methodology
A company’s capital structure is analyzed with the help of a spreadsheet
analysis, which is based on the trade-off between the tax advantages of
debt and the increased risk from debt financing.10 I mostly use data from
Yahoo! Finance and openly available data from companies’ own websites.
In addition to a traditional spreadsheet analysis I also add an estimation of
the value of financial flexibility.11 And I also add share price underpricing
estimation in case the firm issues new shares. In general, I believe capital
structure needs more analyses similar to the ones in this chapter (so called
case studies). This is an effective way to do research in areas that include
several layers of analysis and different approaches and theories. This book
suggests that capital structure management represents such an area. There
are a lot of competing theories of capital structure. Furthermore one of
our main objectives is to find firms’ optimal capital structure policies
and contrast them with existing policies. Some of the theories are better
formalized and are simpler to use in real life situations (such as trade-off
theory) while others are very complex (such as asymmetric information).
A case study is a good research strategy because the area of our research
is multilayered (Singleton et al. 1993; Mertens 1998). Campbell (1989)
advocates a case study design for investigating real-life events, including
organizational and managerial processes.
10
See Damodaran (2003); Fernandez (2015); and Lee, Liang and Miglo (2014) for examples of
spreadsheet analysis regarding optimal capital structure.
11
See, for example, A. Damodaran’s note: http://people.stern.nyu.edu/adamodar/pdfiles/country/
option.pdf
10 Capital Structure Analysis: Some Examples 215
12
“Facebook Reports First Quarter 2015 Results” (April 22, 2015). http://investor.fb.com/
releasedetail.cfm?ReleaseID=908022. Retrieved January 23, 2016.
13
Davis (July 13, 2015).
14
“Why you should beware of Facebook”. The Age (Melbourne). January 20, 2008. Retrieved
January 23, 2016.
15
Williams (October 1, 2007) and “Jim Breyer (via Accel Partners).” CNBC. May 22, 2012. http://
www.cnbc.com/id/47387334. Retrieved January 23, 2016.
16
“Facebook and Microsoft Expand Strategic Alliance” (Press release). Microsoft. October 24,
2007.
17
“Facebook to Establish International Headquarters in Dublin, Ireland” (Press release). Facebook.
October 2, 2008.
216 Capital Structure in the Modern World
Almost a year later, on September 2009, Facebook said that it had turned
cash-flow positive for the first time.18
Facebook filed their IPO documents with the Securities and Exchange
Commission on February 1, 2012. The company applied for a $5 bil-
lion IPO, one of the biggest offerings in the history of technology. The
IPO raised $16 billion, making it the third-largest in US history.19 On
May 22, 2012, the Yahoo! Finance website reported that Facebook’s
lead underwriters, Morgan Stanley, JP Morgan, and Goldman Sachs,
cut their earnings forecasts for the company in the middle of the IPO
process.20
On November 15, 2010, Facebook announced it had acquired the
domain name fb.com from the American Farm Bureau Federation for
an undisclosed amount. On January 11, 2011, the Farm Bureau dis-
closed $8.5 million in “domain sales income”, making the acquisition
of FB.com one of the 10 highest domain sales in history.21 Facebook has
acquired more than 50 companies, including Instagram and WhatsApp.
The acquisition of WhatsApp cost $19 billion: more than $40 per
WhatsApp user. It also purchased the defunct company ConnectU in
a court settlement and acquired intellectual property formerly held by
rival Friendster. The majority of the companies acquired by Facebook
are based in the United States; a large percentage of these companies are
based in or around the San Francisco Bay Area. Facebook has also made
investments in LuckyCal and Wildfire Interactive. Most of Facebook’s
acquisitions have been ‘talent acquisitions’ and acquired products are
often shut down. Mr. Zuckerberg has stated: “we have not once bought a
company for the company. We buy companies to get excellent people…
In order to have a really entrepreneurial culture one of the key things
is to make sure we’re recruiting the best people. One of the ways to do
this is to focus on acquiring great companies with great founders.”22 The
18
“Facebook ‘cash flow positive,’ signs 300M users.” CBC News (Toronto). September 16, 2009.
19
“Facebook Officially Files for $5 Billion IPO.” KeyNoodle. February 1, 2012. Archived from the
original on October 18, 2013. Retrieved February 1, 2012; and Rusli and Eavis (May 17, 2012).
20
Blodget (May 22, 2012).
21
“FB.com acquired by Facebook.” NameMon News. January 11, 2011.
22
“Why Facebook buys startups.” Youtube https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=OlBDyItD0Ak
10 Capital Structure Analysis: Some Examples 217
Capital Structure
23
Darby III (May 15, 2007).
10 Capital Structure Analysis: Some Examples 219
24
Taylor (June 11, 2015).
25
Womack (2012, October 24).
220 Capital Structure in the Modern World
holders received 1.05 shares of UAL stock for each Continental share,
effectively meaning Continental was acquired by the UAL Corporation;
at the time of closing, it was estimated that United shareholders owned
55 % of the merged entity and Continental shareholders owned 45 %.26
Once completely combined, United became the world’s largest airline, as
measured by revenue passenger miles.27
UCH has major operations at Chicago–O’Hare, Denver, Guam,
Houston–Intercontinental, Los Angeles, Newark (New Jersey), San
Francisco, Tokyo–Narita, and Washington–Dulles. UCH’s United Air
Lines, Inc. controls several key air rights, including being one of only two
American carriers authorized to serve Asia from Tokyo-Narita (the other
being Delta Air Lines). Additionally, UCH’s United is the largest US
carrier to the People’s Republic of China and maintains a large operation
throughout Asia.
Both airlines took losses in the recession and expected the merger to
generate savings of more than $1 billion a year.28 Combined revenues
were projected to be about $29 billion.29 Unlike Facebook, revenues have
not been significantly growing in UCH for the last four years. Employer-
worker relationships are of significant importance.
Susan Carey (2012) describes the pilot strike at UCH in 2012.30 Pilots
at United Continental Holdings Inc., frustrated that nearly two years
of negotiations at the merged airline had failed to yield a joint contract,
concluded a strike vote in July 2012 with 99 % of the voters approving
a plan to withdraw their services, if allowed by federal mediators. Pilots
wanted raises and other improved terms, and insisted that the merger
26
“United Continental Holdings, Inc.—Investor Relations – News.” Ir.unitedcontinentalholdings.
com.
27
“United, Continental create world’s biggest airline.” The Sydney Morning Herald. May 4, 2010.
http://www.smh.com.au/business/world-business/united-and-continental-create-worlds-biggest-
airline-20100503-u426.html. Retrieved January 23, 2016.
28
“United and Continental Airlines to merge.”. BBC News. May 3, 2010. http://www.bbc.com/
news/10095080. Retrieved January 23, 2016.
29
“United, Continental create world’s biggest airline.” The Sydney Morning Herald. May 4, 2010.
http://www.smh.com.au/business/world-business/united-and-continental-create-worlds-biggest-
airline-20100503-u426.html. Retrieved January 23, 2016.
30
Carey (July 17, 2012).
222 Capital Structure in the Modern World
Capital Structure
United uses a much higher debt ratio than Facebook. In 2015 it was
about 51 % (see Table 10.3).
Trade-off theory based spreadsheet analysis suggests that United’s opti-
mal debt ratio was 45.0 % in 2015, which is lower than what its actual
debt ratio was that year. Unlike Facebook, UCH assets are mostly tan-
gible, which helps explain why its debt ratio is higher.
The pecking-order theory implies that the company should use inter-
nal funds before using debt and equity and should use external debt
before external equity. It seems that this is consistent with United’s strat-
egy since it does not issue new shares publicly and when the cash situa-
31
Levine-Weinberg (October 13, 2015).
10 Capital Structure Analysis: Some Examples 223
tion improves (for example, as happened in 2015) UHC plans to buy its
shares back. It is not clear, however, why shares were not purchased back
using borrowing during the times when the cash flow was not as high as
in 2015! The answer can be provided by spreadsheet analysis or trade-off
theory since raising debt in bad times can be quite expensive.
On the one hand, the agency cost of debt theory (asset substitution,
debt overhang) favors keeping low debt. This is not consistent with
United’s policies. On the other hand, the agency cost theory states that
higher debt is good for a company because it can stimulate the manager
to perform better. This part is consistent with the United case. Compared
to Facebook, the conflict between the shareholders and managers has
greater importance as the company is struggling financially and the insid-
ers do not own as much equity as in Facebook’s case (see Table 10.4). At
the same time the total number of shareholders is quite large. A conflict
between the creditors and shareholders is likely to happen because United
is more concerned with the creditors as it has more debt.
As the flexibility theory and life cycle theory propose it is more natural
for UHC to use debt financing than it is for Facebook. UHC can be con-
sidered a mature business with a well established reputation, principles,
and traditions. Also, its expansion and growth plans are not comparable
with those of Facebook. Our calculations show that the value of flex-
ibility is 0.043 % of the assets value, which is smaller than in the case of
Facebook.
The signaling theory states that from the investors’ perspective, the
market reaction is neutral on the issuance of debt and negative on equity.
It may also explain why UCH does not issue shares publicly.
References
Blodget, H. (2012, May 22). Facebook bankers secretly cut Facebook’s revenue
estimates in middle of IPO roadshow, Yahoo! Finance. Yahoo!, Inc. http://
finance.yahoo.com/blogs/daily-ticker/facebook-bankers-secretly-cut-
facebook-revenue-estimates-middle-133648905.html
Campbell, D.T. 1989 “Foreword.” in Case Study Research: Design and Methods,
Robert K. Yin, ed., Newbury Park, CA: Sage Publications.
Carey, S. (2012, July 17). Pilots at United Continental Approve a strike. The
Wall Street Journal. http://www.wsj.com/articles/SB1000142405270230361
2804577533062188787068
Damodaran, A. (2003). Corporate finance: Theory and practice. Hoboken, New
Jersey: Wiley Series in Finance.
Darby, J. B. III. (2007, May 15). International tax planning: Double Irish more
than doubles the tax saving. Practical US/International Tax Strategies, 11(9).
http://www.gtlaw.com/portalresource/lookup/wosid/contentpilot-core-
2301-5813/pdfCopy.name=/darby07g.pdf?view=attachment
Davis, M. (2015, July 13). Facebook close sets speed record for $250 billion
market cap. Bloomberg.com. http://www.bloomberg.com/news/arti-
cles/2015-07-13/facebook-s-close-sets-speed-record-for-250-billion-
market-value
Fernandez, P. (2015). Optimal capital structure: Problems with the Harvard and
Damodaran approaches. Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=270833
Kazeniac, A. (2009, February 9). Social networks: Facebook takes over top spot.
Twitter Climbs, Blog.compete.com. https://blog.compete.com/2009/02/09/
facebook-myspace-twitter-social-network/
Lee, Z., Liang, S., & Miglo, A. (2014). Capital structure of Internet companies:
Case study. Journal of Internet Commerce, 13(3–4), 253–281.
Levine-Weinberg, A. (2015, October 13). United Continental Stock is flying
higher on strong guidance. The Motley Fool. http://www.fool.com/investing/
general/2015/10/13/united-continental-stock-is-flying-higher-on-stron.aspx
226 Capital Structure in the Modern World
Lunden, I. (2013, December 30). 73% of U.S. adults use social networks,
Pinterest passes Twitter in popularity, Facebook stays on top. TechCrunch.
http://techcrunch.com/2013/12/30/pew-social-networking/
Mertens, D. (1998). Research methods in education and psychology: Integrating
diversity with quantitative & qualitative approaches. Thousand Oaks: Sage
Publications.
Nowotarski, M. (2011, January 23). Don’t steal my Avatar! Challenges of social
network patents. IP Watchdog. http://www.ipwatchdog.com/2011/01/23/
dont-steal-my-avatar-challenges-of-social-networking-patents/id=14531/
Rusli, E., & Eavis, P. (2012, May 17). Facebook raises $16 Billion in I.P.O. The
New York Times. http://dealbook.nytimes.com/2012/05/17/facebook-raises-
16-billion-in-i-p-o/?_r=0
Singleton, R., Straits, B., & Straits, M. (1993). Approaches to social research.
New York: Oxford University Press.
Tynan, D. (2007, June 30). As applications blossom, Facebook is open for busi-
ness. Wired. http://www.wired.com/2007/07/facebook-platform
Williams, C. (2007, October 1). Facebook wins Manx battle for face-book.com.
The Register (London). http://www.theregister.co.uk/2007/10/01/facebook_
domain_dispute/
Womack, B. (2012, October 24). Facebook Shares Soar After Beating Estimates
on Mobile. Bloomberg News. http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/
2012-10-24/facebook-sharessoar-after-beating-estimates-on-mobile-gains
Answers/Solutions to Selected Questions/
Exercises
The first part of this book was focused on the major theories of capi-
tal structure: trade-off theory, pecking-order theory, asset substitu-
tion, credit rationing, and debt overhang. According to most empirical
research, none of these theories are able to fully explain real life decisions
made by companies. However, in most research related to capital struc-
ture, these basic ideas are used either as reference points or intermedi-
ate tools that help develop further ideas. The future of capital structure
theory is still uncertain, in my opinion. Will any theory(ies) emerge as a
clear “winner” (in terms of its ability to explain the reality) or will they
all combine into one “big” theory? Will any of these basic ideas be com-
pletely forgotten because the market imperfections used as a basis will no
longer be relevant in practice, or because empirical research consistently
rejects the results of a theory? In my opinion all of these possibilities are
still on the table. It seems that unlike other areas of finance, research-
ers of capital structure are still far from bridging the gap between its
theory and practical reality. Grahan and Harvey (2001) is a good refer-
ence point.
Part II discussed different topics of capital structure. As was men-
tioned earlier, the objective of the book was not to cover as many topics
Part I
Chapter 1
1. False
2. b
3. c
4. False
5. True
230 Answers/Solutions to Selected Questions/Exercises
Chapter 2
1. True
2. False
3. False.
4. False.
5. True.
6. True
7. True
8. True
9. False
12. Consider an investor holding 10 % of firm U′ s shares. Consider the
following two strategies for this investor:
Strategy 1: To keep 10 % of firm U′s shares
Strategy 2: Sell the shares for 0.1 ∗ 100, 000 = 10, 000 , buy 12.5 % of
company L′S shares (the value is 0.125 ∗ 40, 000 = 5, 000 ) and buy
12.5 % of company L′S bonds (the value is 0.125 ∗ 40, 000 = 5, 000 ).
1000
VU = (1 − 0.2 ) = 400
2
Tax shield:
1000 − D D D
TS = 0.2 * ×D+ ×
1000 1000 2
Bankruptcy costs:
D D * 0.2
BC = ×
1000 2
1000 − D D D
V = VU + TS − BC = 400 + 0.2 * ×D+ ×
1000 1000 2
D D * 0.2
− ×
1000 2
Chapter 3
1. False
2. True
3. True
4. b
5.
Answers/Solutions to Selected Questions/Exercises 233
(a) Outside investors know the value of the existing assets (100).
When they buy equity, if they get a fraction α of the firm, their
wealth in period 2 is α190, and of course in a competitive market
(remember no discounting) this will equal the cost, 70. Thus:
α = 70 / 190 = 7 / 19 .
Thus, the new shareholders will ask for 7000000 additional
shares and the share price will be 70 / 7 = 10 per share. The original
equity is worth (1 − α )190 = 120.
(b) Since 120 > 100, the new equity will clearly be issued and the new
project will be undertaken.
(c) The expected intrinsic value of the assets-in-place is
EX = p160 + (1 − p ) 40 = 100. If the project is not undertaken, the
entrepreneur’s wealth WNI is 40 or 160 depending on the firm’s
type.
Suppose now that equity is issued under any value of the asset.
A competitive capital market implies 70 = α (100 + 90 ) where
investors now break even only in expectation. The necessary
equity fraction required by outsiders is then
70 7
α= =
190 19
12
(160 + 90 ) ≈ 157
19
12
( 40 + 90 ) ≈ 82.1
19
So, a low-value type firm will invest because 82 > 40 while the
high-value type will not because 157 < 160.
234 Answers/Solutions to Selected Questions/Exercises
70 7
α= =
130 13
6
( 40 + 90 ) = 60
13
(e) In
the beginning, the share price is (based on average value of
assets-in-place)
100 1
=8
12 3
After the market knows that the firm has an opportunity to invest
in the new project the share price becomes the average between
the future share values for each type of firm: high-value type is
160/12 and low-value type is 5. So the price will be 9 and 1/6. The
price of shares sold during the issue is 70 / 14 = 5.
(f ) Lemon problem
6. If the information about the expected profits were public then Firm 1
would be sold for 20 and Firm 2 would be sold for 100.
Consider the case with asymmetric information. Suppose that the
entrepreneurs sell their firms. The price in this case will be 60. The
investors will be ready to buy the firm for an average expected return.
Consider the entrepreneurs’ expected utilities. The entrepreneur of
Answers/Solutions to Selected Questions/Exercises 235
Firm 1 will obviously benefit from selling the firm for 60. His expected
utility will be 60. If he keeps the firm, his expected utility is less than
20. What about the entrepreneur of Firm 2?
If he does not sell the firm, his expected utility is
1
100 − ρ 50 = 100 − 25ρ
2
α2 2 (100 – 20 )
=
1−α ρ 50
α2 16
=
1−α 5
Solving for α, given that 0 < α < 1, gives: α = 0.8. Therefore, the entre-
preneur of Firm 2 should keep approximately 80 % of the shares and
sell 20 %.
236 Answers/Solutions to Selected Questions/Exercises
Chapter 4
Earnings
b g Expected
(Pr=0.5) (Pr=0.5) earnings
Project F 60 60 60
Project S 20 90 55
(b) Project S
Payoff to shareholders
b g Expected
(Pr=0.5) (Pr=0.5) value
Project F 10 10 10
Project S 0 40 20
Payoff to creditors
b g Expected
(Pr=0.5) (Pr=0.5) value
Project F 50 50 $50
Project S 20 50 $35
In this case, the shareholders will make the firm choose project S
because it has a higher NPV of 20; it, however, leaves the creditors
with a payoff worth 35.
(c) Still S.
Shareholder payoff
b g Expected
(Pr=0.5) Pr=0.5) value
Project F 0 0 0
Project S 0 10 5
Answers/Solutions to Selected Questions/Exercises 237
Payoff to creditors
b (Pr=0.5) g (Pr=0.5) EV
Project F 60 60 60
Project S 20 80 50
Earnings
b g Expected
2. (Pr=1/2) (Pr=1/2) earnings
Project 1 10 10 10
Project 2 3 15 9
(a) It depends on D.
3. (a) D < 3. Project 1 will be chosen since it has higher expected earn-
ings and debt is risk-free.
(e) D > 6 . In this case Project 2 will be chosen. For creditors, the fol-
lowing should hold: ½ * D + 1 / 2 * 3 = 6. Since D = 9.
(f ) 1 / 2 * (15 − 9 ) + 1 / 2 * 0 = 3
(g) The shareholders’ expected payoff with the additional project is 3.
With the new project (assuming a new senior debt with face value
2 is issued): 1 / 2 * (15 + 3 − 2 − 9 ) + 1 / 2 * 0 = 3.5. The shareholders
will take the new project, which has a negative NPV:
3 * 1 / 2 − 2 = −0.5. The problem illustrated here is overinvestment.
4. D
Continuation (bank will accept a promise to pay 330 next year because
it will get 165 on average which will give the bank an average rate of
return of 10 %):
Year 1 Year 2
Good state Bad state
CF 0 1500 500
Senior debt payments –150 –1000 –500
Bank 150 –330 0
Shareholders’ profit 0 170 0
Since F has a higher NPV than S, the shareholders will choose F. For
example, the firm can issue a risk-free debt with face value 20.
Now suppose that the cost of the project is 50. Now the projects’
NPVs are: NPV ( F ) = 10; NPV ( S ) = 5. Project F still has a higher NPV
than S. Which project will be chosen by the shareholders?
Suppose the firm can raise the 50 by issuing a bond with a
face value of 50. The shareholders earnings from taking proj-
ect F are: 1 / 2 ( 60 − 50 ) + 1 / 2 ( 60 − 50 ) = 10. And those from S are:
1 / 2 ( 90 − 50 ) + 1 / 2 ( 0 ) = 20. Shareholders will prefer project S which leads
to an asset substitution problem. Note also that the lender’s expected cash
flow from project S is 1 / 2 ( 20 ) + 1 / 2 ( 50 ) = 35 which is less than 50 if the
shareholders choose project S.
What should the face value of debt D be in order for creditors to have
an incentive to invest in the project?
Suppose that D > 50. If F is chosen, the shareholders’ payoff is
1 / 2 ( 60 − D ) + 1 / 2 ( 60 − D ) = 60 − D if D < 60 . Otherwise, it is 0. If S is
chosen, the shareholders’ payoff is 1 / 2 ( 90 − D ) + 1 / 2 * 0 = 45 − 1 / 2 D.
Comparing F and S we find that, since D > 30, S will be chosen.
How do we find the minimal acceptable value of D for credi-
tors? Their expected cash flow should cover the initial investment 50:
1 / 2 * D + 1 / 2 * 20 = 50. This gives D = 80. So the equilibrium scenario in
this seemingly very simple problem is that the firm will borrow an amount
50 by promising to return 80 and the shareholders will undertake project
S which has a smaller value compared to project F. If the creditors miscal-
culate the shareholders’ incentives it may lead to their loss in equilibrium.
9. (a) Project A’s NPV is 40 (expected earnings minus cost) and Project
B’s is 15.
(b) Considering a debt with face value 40, the shareholders’ payoffs
are:
240 Answers/Solutions to Selected Questions/Exercises
If A: 1 / 2 * 40 + 1 / 2 * 40 = 40.
If B: 1 / 2 (110 − 40 ) + 1 / 2 * 0 = 35.
Chapter 5
1. (a) The firm’s expected earnings increase by 100, 000 * 0.4 = 40, 000
which is greater than the 30000 investment cost. So the NPV of
the project for the firm equals 100, 000 * 0.4 − 30, 000 = 10, 000.
(b) Without the new project, the shareholders’ earnings are:
(100, 000 − D ) * 0.4. If D = 20, 000, the shareholders’ expected earn-
ings are (10, 000 − 20, 000 ) * 0.4 = 32, 000 . If the firm undertakes
the new project the shareholders’ expected payoff will be
(100, 000 − 20, 000 ) * 0.8 − 30, 000 = 34, 000 > 32, 000 so the project
will be undertaken.
(c) Consider D = 60, 000. Without the new project the shareholders’
expected earnings are (100, 000 − 60, 000 ) * 0.4 = 16, 000. If the firm
undertakes the new project the shareholders’ expected payoff will
Answers/Solutions to Selected Questions/Exercises 241
be (100, 000 − 60, 000 ) * 0.8 − 30, 000 = 2, 000 < 16, 000 so the proj-
ect will not be undertaken.
(d) Debt overhang; higher debt increases the likelihood of debt
overhang.
(b) Without the new project, the shareholders’ expected payoff is:
1 / 2 (10000 − 6000 ) = 2000. Now consider the new investment
opportunity. Let F be the face value of the new debt. The expected
payoff to the new debtholders: 1 / 2 * F = 2000 , thus F = 4000. The
1
shareholders’ payoff is * (13000 − 6000 − 4000 ) = 1500. This is less
2
than the shareholders’ payoff without the new project. Thus, the
project will not be undertaken.
(c) Now suppose the initial debt is junior and the firm can issue a
senior debt to finance the new project. The face value of the new
senior debt is 2000 (since the total earnings are at least 2000 in
both states). So the shareholders’ expected payoff, if the new proj-
1
ect is undertaken, is: * (13000 − 6000 − 2000 ) = 2500. This is
2
greater than 2000. So the new project will be undertaken.
(d) Suppose the incumbent debtholders agree to finance the new proj-
ect with a new (junior) debt with a face value (including principal
and interests) of 2200. Suppose the shareholders accept financing
from the incumbent creditors. The shareholders’ payoffs with the
new project will be 0.5 * (13, 000 − 6, 000 − 2, 200 ) = 2400.
This is greater than 2, 000 and hence the shareholders will be inter-
ested in having a deal with the incumbent creditors. Now consider
the incentive for the creditors. Without the new project their
expected payoff is 0.5 * 6, 000 + 0.5 * 4, 000 = 5, 000 . With the proj-
ect it is: 0.5 * ( 6, 000 + 2, 200 ) + 0.5 * ( 7,000 ) − 2, 000 = 5, 600 .
So the deal is beneficial for both the shareholders and the creditors.
(e) Minimal for creditors: 1000. Maximal for shareholders: 3000.
Use the proof of Propositions 5.3 and 5.4.
(f ) Free rider-problem.
242 Answers/Solutions to Selected Questions/Exercises
3. Debtholders will sell the debt for 5000. To see this, note that in the
current situation debtholders will receive: 1 / 2 * 10000 + 1 / 2 * 0 = 5000 .
Will shareholders repurchase the debt? Currently, the shareholders’
expected payoff (given that corporate tax is 40 %) is:
1 / 2 (18000 − 10000 ) * (1 − 0.4 ) + 1 / 2 ( 0 ) = 2400. The new shareholders
will be able to pay 5000 for the newly issued shares if they get 25/27
of the firm’s equity. To see this note that the firm’s net income after the
debt repurchase in the bad state will still be 0 and that in the good
state it will be 18000 * 0.6 = 10800. Since this occurs with a 50 % prob-
ability, new shareholders will need 10000 in that state. So their frac-
tion should be equal to 25/27. The initial shareholders’ fraction of
equity is then 2/27 and their expected payoff is 2 / 27 * 10800 = 800,
which is less than 2400.
Part II
Chapter 6
1. True
2. True
3. True
4. Consider first financing for stage 2. We have 0.25 * D = 0.1. Hence
D = 2 / 5. In stage 1 investors require a fraction of equity s1 such that:
s1 * 0.7 + s1 * 0.25 * (1 − 2 / 5 ) = 0.1. Therefore s1 = 2 / 17. Now consider
the payoff of shareholders of b in case b decides to mimic g. This
equals 15 * 0.1 + 15 * 0.8 * 1 − 2 = 29 . If a signaling equilibrium
17 17 5 50
exists, the shareholders’ payoff for type b is pb1 + pb 2 − C1 − C2 = 0.7
(the present value of b). Thus, a separating equilibrium exists because
29 / 50 < 0.7.
5. Consider pooling equilibrium where both firms issue equity. We have
0.1 0.1
αe = =
0.3 * 0.3 + 0.7 * 0.1 + m + 0.12 0.28 + m
Answers/Solutions to Selected Questions/Exercises 243
Chapter 7
1. The expected earnings of project 1 equal 2.5 and they are greater than
that of project 2. So from the firm’s point of view, the manager should
choose project 1. The manager’s expected payoff if project 1 is chosen
equals 0.2 and 0.5 for project 2. If D = 0 the probability of bankruptcy
equals zero and the manager chooses project 2 since 0.5 > 0.2.
If D > 0, the manager’s expected payoff under project 1 is
0.2 * ( 5 − D ) / 5 and for project 2 it is 0.5 * ( 3 − D ) / 3. The manager will
choose project 1 if D > 45 / 19.
If D = 45 / 19, the real value of debt equals
45 / 19 * ( 5 − D ) / 5 + 45 / 38 * ( D / 5 ) = 6525 / 3610. This amount can be
provided by debtholders and in this case the rest should be raised by
selling equity.
2. (a) The first-best effort maximizes the firm’s value: 2e − 2e2. Socially
optimal e* = 1 / 2.
(b) E will maximize 2ke − 2e2 , where k is the fraction of equity that
belongs to E. Optimal e′ = k / 2 . For any k < 1, e′ < e*. If the man-
ager owns less than 100 % of the equity, the level of effort is below
the first-best level. The manager’s profit is then k2/2. To find the
optimal contract, we have to find the value of k that will maximize
the entrepreneur’s profit under the condition that the investor’s
expected profit is not less than b. This condition is
2e (1 − k ) = k (1 − k ) ≥ 1 / 8. The left side of this inequality reaches
its maximum when k = 1 / 2. In this case I′s expected payoff is 1/4.
E′s expected payoff is k2/2. It is increasing in k. Hence the optimal
k is the largest value of k that satisfies I’s budget constraint, i.e.
1/2. Optimal e = 1 / 4 and E′s expected payoff is 1/8.
(c) Two cases are possible. (1) 2e < D. In this case the manager maxi-
mizes 1 / 3 ( 4e − D ) − 2e2 . So optimal e = 1 / 3. The manager’s pay-
244 Answers/Solutions to Selected Questions/Exercises
(1 − k ) ( e + 2 ) = (1 − k )
k
+ 2 ≥ 19 / 32
2
Chapter 8
1. (a) Period 1. The first-best effort maximizes the firm’s value: 2e − 2e2.
Socially optimal e* = 1 / 2.
(b) In the case of equity financing E will maximize 2ke − 2e2 , where k
is the fraction of equity that belongs to E. Optimal e′ = k / 2 . For
any k < 1, e′ < e* .
E′s profit is then k2/2. To find the optimal contract, we have to
find k that will maximize E′s profit under the condition that the
investor’s expected profit is not less than b. This condition is
2e (1 − k ) = 2 k (1 − k ) / 2 ≥ 1 / 8. The left side of the inequality
reaches its maximum when k = 1 / 2. In this case, I′s expected pay-
off is 1/4. E′s expected payoff is k2/2. It is increasing on k. Hence
the optimal k is the largest value of k that satisfies I′s budget con-
straint, i.e. 1/2. Optimal e = 1 / 4 and E′s expected payoff is 1/8.
(c) Now consider debt financing. Two cases are possible. (1) e < D. In
this case the manager maximizes 1 / 3 ( 4e − D ) − 2e2 . So optimal
e = 1 / 3. E′s payoff is 2 / 9 − 1 / 3D. (2) e > D. In this case the man-
ager maximizes 1 / 3 ( 2e − D ) + 1 / 3 ( 4e − D ) − 2e2. So optimal
e = 1 / 2 . E′s payoff is 1 / 2 − 2 / 3 D. By comparing the manager’s
payoffs in each case we find that if D < 5 / 6 optimal e = 1 / 2 and
otherwise e = 1 / 3. Now to find D, note that the investor’s payoff
should be greater than b. So in the second case D = 3 / 2b . It is pos-
sible only if b < 3 / 8, which is our case. So the firm can be financed
with debt with face value 3/8 and the manager’s profit is 1/4 in
this case.
(d) Debt is better because E′s payoff is higher in this case.
(e) Period 2. The first-best effort maximizes the firm’s value:
2e1 + 2e2 − 2e12 − 2e2 2 . Hence e= 1 e=
2 1 / 2.
(f ) Under equity financing, E has a fraction k of the firm’s equity. So
E will maximize k ( 2e1 + 2e2 ) − 2e12 . Optimal e1′ = k / 2 . Similarly
we find e ′2 = (1 − k ) / 2. I′s payoff equals
246 Answers/Solutions to Selected Questions/Exercises
(1 − k ) . If
2
−0.3
pj =
0.2 Fj − D
−0.3
pj = .
0.2 Fj − D
p j ( 0.5Fj − D ) = p j ( Fj − D′ ) − 0.3 (1 − p j )
Answers/Solutions to Selected Questions/Exercises 247
−0.3
pj =
− D + D′ − 0.3 − 0.5Fj
D′ − 0.3
Fj =
0.7
D′ − 0.3
F* =
0.7
and
0.21
p* =
0.7 D + 0.2 D′ − 0.06
Chapter 9
1. True.
2. True
3. (a) The new project has a positive net present value (NPV) because
1 / 2 * 2, 000 + 1 / 2 * 5000 > 3500.
248 Answers/Solutions to Selected Questions/Exercises
(b) The face value, d′, of this debt can be found from the following
equation: 3000 = d ′ * 1 / 2 + 1 / 2 * 0. Therefore d ′ = 6000.
The shareholders’ expected payoff without the new investment
is 1 / 2 * ( 20000 − D ) = 6000. With the new project, it will be
1 / 2 ( 20000 + 5000 − D − d ′ ) = 5500. Since the expected payoff
without the new project is more than that with the project, it will
not be undertaken.
(c) The face value d can be found from: 3000 = d * 1 / 2 + 1 / 2 * 2, 000 .
Here d = 4000 .
The shareholders’ expected payoff is (note that the shareholders
get nothing if B is realized): 1 / 2 * ( 20000 − D + 5000 − d ) = 6500 .
This is greater than 6000 (the shareholders’ expected payoff with-
out new investment), and thus the project will be undertaken and
it will be financed with non-recourse debt.
(d) The new project has a negative net present value (NPV) because
0.4 * 4, 000 − 0.1 * 20000 + 0.1 * 2000 < 0.
(e) The face value, d ′, of this debt can be found from the following
equation: 1000 = d ’* 0.4 + 0.6 * 0. This means that if G is realized,
the new debtholders will receive the face value of the debt; if,
however, B is realized, the firm’s cash flow is 2000, which is less
than the face value of the senior debt, leaving the new creditors
with nothing. Therefore, d' = 2500. The shareholders’ expected
payoff without the new investment is 0.5 * ( 20000 − 15000 ) = 2500.
With the new project, it will be 0.4 * ( 24000 − 15000 − 2500 ) = 2600.
Since the expected payoff with the new project is more than it is
without the project, it will be undertaken.
(f ) In this case, the debtholders’ payoffs depend only on the returns
from the new project and not on the returns from the assets
already in place. Since the NPV is negative, the firm will not able
to finance the project.
4. (a) It is impossible because the face value of debt will be lower for
type 1 than it is for type 2 if the latter were to use it. It’s because
Answers/Solutions to Selected Questions/Exercises 249
Type 1 firms will not mimic type 2. Indeed, if they do, their pay-
off will be
E = 0.6 * 0.25 * (1 + 1 − 0.2 / 0.75 − 0.2 / 0.25 )
+ 0.6 * (1 − 0.25 ) * (1 − 0.2 / 0.25 ) + 0.4 * 0.25 * (1 − 0.2 / 0.75 )
+ 0.4 * 0.75 * 0 ≈ 0.31
D H
debtor-in-possession, 106 Habib, M.A., 193, 201, 203, 204
debt overhang, 97–111, 139, Hart, O., 137, 140
187, 189, 190, 205, 223, Harvey, C., 5, 79, 107
224 Hennessy, C., 6, 39, 118
Degeorge, F., 147, 150 Ho, K., 93
Dewatripont, M., 140, 143, 147 Horvath, M., 14
dividend policy, 105, 106
“double taxation”, 31
I
incumbent debtholders, 241
E Innes, R., 144, 146, 151
Eckbo, B.E., 61 insiders, 46–7, 64, 119, 131, 147,
“empire-building”, 136, 138, 148, 150, 194, 197
139 investment, vii, 4, 6, 10, 12, 23–6,
Esty, B., 184, 186, 193, 201 47–52, 61, 64, 69, 71–7, 80,
Ewert, R., 14 84, 86–8, 97–102, 105, 107,
exchange, 27, 49, 56, 104, 118, 166, 110, 111, 115, 116, 118, 119,
177, 215 122, 126, 127, 130–1, 135,
137, 145, 146, 148, 150,
154–6, 166, 171, 172, 176–8,
F 183, 184, 187, 189–94,
Fama, E., 37 197–200, 203–6, 215, 216,
Fisher, I., 6 228, 239, 240
Frank, M., 5, 32, 36, 37, 54, 55,
61
Franks, J.R., 139 J
“free cash-flow”, 116, 135, 137–40, Jaramillo, F., 9
190, 222 Jensen, M., 71, 137, 139, 144
French, K., 37 John, K., 192, 202
Johnsen, D.B., 203
G
Gatti, S., 185, 204, 205 K
Goyal, V., 5, 32, 36, 37, 54, 55 Kaplan, S., 141, 169
Graham, J., 5, 32, 34, 37–9, 79, Kaufman, M., 82
107 Kensinger, J., 193
Green, R., 73, 75, 78 Kim, E., 187
Grossman, S., 137, 140 Kleimeier, S., 185, 186, 193, 205
Index 253
Korteweg, A., 30 O
Kraus, A., 32, 122, 194, 196 Oberg, A., 14
outsiders, 46–7, 53, 64, 150, 177,
194, 219, 233, 234
L overinvestment, 77–9, 140, 175,
Leary, M.T., 5, 32, 39, 55 186, 190, 238
Lee, Z., 211, 214, 217, 218
Leland, H.E., 56, 61, 118
“lemon” problem, 53 P
Levi, H., 93 Patel, F., 147, 150
limited liability, 13–14, 16, 30–1, pecking-order theory, viii, 5, 47–56,
71, 172, 176 64, 107, 115, 117, 130, 175,
Lindhe, T., 14 218, 222, 227
Litzenberger, R., 32 preferred stock
Low, A., 154 convertible preferred stock,
169
participating convertible preferred
M stock, 169
Majluf, N., 117, 176, 197, 198, 199 present value, 32, 52, 120, 123, 203,
Martin, G., viii, 193 242
Meckling, W., 71, 144 project, 3, 47, 69, 97, 117, 137, 170,
Megginson, W.L., 186 183, 224
Miglo, A., 3, 5, 14, 31, 32, 55, 61, project financing, 183–206
117, 119, 121, 126, 143, 150, Pyle, D., 56, 61, 118
176, 197, 199, 211, 214, 217
Miller, M., vii, 6, 22, 40
Modigliani, F., vii, viii, 6, 22 R
Myers, S.C., 5, 32, 47, 51, 55, 97, Rajan, R., 37, 106
117, 176, 187, 192, 197, 198, Rajgopal, S., 149
199 risk, 8, 36, 47, 55, 57, 60, 61, 64,
71–4, 77, 79, 88, 93, 99, 106,
116, 139, 140, 146, 154, 166,
N 169, 184, 190, 193, 199,
Nachman, D., 51, 61 201–5, 214, 217, 219, 224
Niemann, R., 14 “risk-bearing” signaling, 56
Noe, T., 51, 61, 122 Roberts, M., 55, 154
non-recourse debt, 183, 186, Rosenthal, H., 139
189–93, 196, 199, 201–3, Ross, S.A., 56
205, 206, 248 Roychowdhury, S., 149
254 Index
S U
Schiantarelli, F., 9 underinvestment problem, 100–2,
Shah, K., 118 105, 106, 186, 187, 192–3, 199
Shah, S., 201 underpricing, 46, 56, 115, 198, 214
Shyam-Sunders, L., 5, 55 unlimited liability, 13–16, 172, 176
Sodersten, J., 14
Stiglitz, J., vii, 45–6, 70, 80, 164,
176, 229 V
stochastic dominance von Thadden, E.-L., 143
first-order stochastic dominance,
91
increasing risk, 93 W
second-order stochastic Weiss, A., 45, 70, 80, 164, 176
dominance, 88, 92 Wessels, R., 37
Strebulaev, I., 37, 39 Whited, T., 37–9
Sussman, O., 139 Woywode, M., 14
Wright, J., 185
Wright, S., 37
T
Thakor, A., 201
Tirole, J., vii, 140, 141, 143, Z
148 Zeckhauser, R., 147, 150
Titman, S., 37, 47, 84, 86, 99, Zender, J., 5, 143, 154, 168
106 Zhao, H., 93
Zingales, L., 37