ECO1
ECO1
SEMESTER - I
ECONOMICS
BLOCK - 1
UNITS CONTRIBUTORS
Editorial Team
This Self Learning Material (SLM) of the Krishna Kanta Handiqui State University is
made available under a Creative Commons Attribution-Non Commercial-ShareAlike4.0 License
(International): http.//creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-sa/4.0.
Printed and published by Registrar on behalf of the Krishna Kanta Handiqui State Open University.
The university acknowledges with thanks the financial support provided by the
Distance Education Bureau, UGC, for the preparation of this study material.
This course introduces a learner to the field of Economics. Economics, according to the Oxford
English Dictionary is “the branch of knowledge concerned with the production, consumption and transfer
of wealth”. Economics can be broadly subdivided into two categories– Microeconomics and
Macroeconomics. Microeconomics is the branch of economics which studies the implications of individual
human action, especially about how these decisions affect the utilization and distribution of scarce
resources. Macroeconomics studies how the aggregate economy behaves. In macroeconomics, a
variety of economy-wide phenomena is examined– such as National Income, Gross Domestic Product,
changes in employment, etc.
This course comprises 15 units and has been divided in three blocks of five units each.
BLOCK INTRODUCTION
This first block of the paper ‘Introduction to Economic Theory I’ comprises five units. Unit I
describes the subject matter of Economics and its division into Micro and Macro. It also deals with the
concepts of stock and flow variables. Unit II deals with the concept of equilibrium and describes static
analysis, comparative static analysis and dynamic analysis. Unit III introduces the concept of demand
as understood in economics. The derivation of the demand curve is explained and situations of movement
along the curve and shift in the curve are also dealt with. The learner is introduced to the concept of
elasticity in this unit. Unit IV deals with the cardinal approach of Consumer Behaviour. Here the Law of
Diminishing Marginal Utility is explained along with the Law of Equi Marginal Utility. The learners also
come to know about the concept of Consumer’s Surplus in this Unit. Unit V explains the Ordinal Approach
to Consumer Behaviour. Here Indifference Curves and their properties are explained along with the
Budget Line. The Price, Income and Substitution Effect of a change in price is explained diagrammatically.
This block includes some along-side boxes to help you know some of the difficult, unseen
terms. Some “ACTIVITY’ have been included to help you apply your own thoughts. And, at the end of
each section, you will get “CHECK YOUR PROGRESS” questions. These have been designed to self-
check your progress of study. It will be better if you solve the problems put in these boxes immediately
after you go through the sections of the units and then match your answers with “ANSWERS TO
CHECK YOUR PROGRESS” given at the end of each unit.
1.2 INTRODUCTION
Factor Pricing: You know that there are four factors of production
namely land, labour, capital and organisation. These four factors
contribute towards the production process. So they get rewards in
the form of rent, wages, interest and profit respectively. Micro
economics deals with the determination of such rewards. This is
called factor pricing. It is an important scope of microeconomics.
So microeconomics is also called as ‘Price Theory’ or ‘Value Theory’.
Welfare Theory: Microeconomics also has its scope in welfare
aspects. It deals with the optimum allocation of available resources
to maximise social or public welfare. It provides answers of the
very crucial questions of economics viz. ‘What to produce?’, ‘How
to produce?’, ‘For whom it is to be produced?’. So we can say that
microeconomics as a branch of economics gives guidance for
utilising scarce resources of economy to maximise public welfare.
1) Ahuja, H.L. (2006); Modern Economics; New Delhi: S. Chand & Co.
Ltd.
2) Dewett, K.K. (2005); Modern Economic Theory; New Delhi: S. Chand
& Co. Ltd.
3) Koutsoyiannis, A. (1979); Modern Microeconomics; New Delhi:
Macmillan.
4) Sundharam, K.P.M. & Vaish, M.C. (1997); Microeconomic Theory;
New Delhi: S.Chand & Co. Ltd.
2.2 INTRODUCTION
LET US KNOW
the same. These other things which are assumed to be constant are: the
tastes or preferences of the consumer; the income of the consumer and
the prices of the related goods. This law of demand ensures the downward
slope of the demand curve. The figure 2.1 exhibits a typical downward
sloping demand curve for an individual consumer.
Fig. 1.1: Demand Curve of an Individual Consumer
Y
14
D
12
Price per Unit (Rs.)
10
8
6
4
2
D
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 X
Quantity (in units)
In the above figure 2.1, quantity demaned is measured along the
X-axis and price of the commodity is measured along the Y-axis. From the
figure it can be seen that when price of the commodity was Rs 12, the
demand for the commodity was 4 units only. When price fell to Rs 10,
demand for the commodity increased to 8 units. And finally, when price of
the commodity declined to Rs 4, demand for the commodity increased to
20 units. Thus, by plotting the various price-quantity combinations, a
negatively (or downward) sloped demand curve DD is obtained. The
downward slope of the demand curve indicates that when price rises, less
units are demanded and when the price falls, more quantity is demanded.
This negative slope arises basically because of the law of diminishing
marginal utility which states that as a person takes more and more of a
commodity, the utility derived from the subsequent unit falls.
Meaning of Supply: Supply is a fundamental economic concept
that describes the total amount of a specific good or service that is available
to consumers. Supply can relate to the amount available at a specific price
or the amount available across a range of prices if displayed on a graph. It
26 Introduction to Economic Theory-I
The Market Mechanism Unit 2
is the relation between the price of a good and the quantity available for
sale from suppliers (such as producers) at that price. Producers are
hypothesized to be profit-maximizers, meaning that they attempt to produce
the amount of goods that will bring them the highest profit.
Law of Supply: The law of supply states that supply shows a direct,
proportional relation between price and quantity supplied (other things
unchanged). In other words, the higher the price at which the good can be
sold, the more of it producers will supply. The higher price makes it profitable
to increase production. At a price below equilibrium, there is a shortage of
quantity supplied compared to the quantity demanded.
The supply schedule is the relationship between the quantity of
goods supplied by the producers of a good and the current market price. It is
graphically represented by the supply curve. It is commonly represented as
directly proportional to price. This has been shown in the following figure 2.2.
30
20
10
0 50 100 150
Quantity (in units)
The above figure depicts a normal supply curve. From the figure
we can see that when price of the commodity was Rs. 10, supply of the
good was 50 units. When price increased to Rs. 20, supply of the good
also increased to 100. Further increase of the price to Rs. 30 resulted in
the increase in the supply of the commodity to 150 units. Thus, we can see
that in case of a nomal good, the supply curve slopes upwards to the right.
This is because with a rise in the price of the good in question, more supply
of the good is available for sale.
Introduction to Economic Theory-I 27
Unit 2 The Market Mechanism
ACTIVITY 2.1
the aggregate buyers and sellers are satisfied with the current combination
of prices and the quantities of goods bought or sold, and so there is no
incentive to change their present actions.
At every moment, some people are buying while others are selling.
Foreign companies are opening production units in India while Indian
companies are selling their products abroad. In the midst of all this turmoil,
markets are constantly solving the problems of what to produce, how much
to produce, how to produce and for whom to produce. As they balance all
the forces operating in the economy, markets are finding a market
equilibrium of supply and demand.
Thus, the term ‘market equilibrium’ represents a ba!ance among
the different buyers and sellers. According to G. J. Stigler, “An equilibrium To know more about G.
is a position from which there is no tendency to move.”Equilibrium describes J. Stigler, please refer
to Appendix-B at the
a situation where economic agents or aggregates of economic agents such
end of the third block
as markets have no incentive to change their economic behaviour.
Depending upon the price, households and firms all want to sell or
buy different quantities. The market finds the equilibrium price that
simultaneously meets the desires of buyers and sellers. Too high a price
would mean a glut of goods with too much output; too low a price will on Glut: An excessively
the other hand lead to a deficiency of goods. Those prices for which buyers alrendant supply of
desire to buy exactly the quantity that sellers desire to sell yield an something.
1) Ahuja, H.L. (2006); Modern Economics; New Delhi: S. Chand & Co.
Ltd.
2) Dewett, K.K. (2005); Modern Economic Theory; New Delhi: S. Chand
& Co. Ltd.
3) Koutsoyiannis, A. (1979); Modern Microeconomics; New Delhi:
Macmillan.
4) Sundharam, K.P.M. & Vaish, M.C. (1997); Microeconomic Theory;
New Delhi: S.Chand & Co. Ltd.
3.2 INTRODUCTION
Y
D
6 a
b
5
c
4
d
Price
3
2 e
1 f
D
X
0 10 20 30 40 50 60
Commodity
Table 3.2: Demand Schedules for two Customers and the Market
Demand Schedule
Price Quantity Demanded (in Kgs)
(In Rs) Consumer 1 Consumer 2 Market Demand
(1) (2) (3) (4)
12 4 6 4 + 6 = 10
10 5 8 5 + 8 = 13
8 6 10 6 + 10 = 16
6 7 12 7 + 12 = 19
4 8 14 8 + 14 = 22
2 9 16 9 + 16 = 25
Fig. 3.2 (a): Demand Curve of Customer 1 Fig. 3.2 (a): Demand Curve of Customer 2
D1 D2
12 12
10 10
Demand
Curve of Demand Curve of Consumer 2
8 Consumer 1 8
Price
6 6
4 4
2 2
D1 D2
0 4 6 8 10 0 4 6 8 10 12 14 16
Quantity
D
12
10
8
6
Price
4
D
2
0 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 X
Quantity
D1
D
D2
0 X
Quantity
In the above figure 3.3, shift in the demand curve has been shown.
DD is the original demand curve. A decrease in demand is shown by
downward shift in the demand curve to the left (D 2D2), and an increase in
demand is shown by an upward shift in demand curve to D 1D1. This shift in
46 Introduction to Economic Theory-I
Demand Analysis Unit 3
demand may be caused by some factors other than price. This change
can be due to the taste and preference of the consumer, new innovation
and technology etc.
For certain commodities the law of demand does not hold, and
they exhibit a direct relationship between the price and quantity demanded.
The commodities that violates the ‘law of demand’ are mentioned
below:
Giffen Goods: Giffen Goods are special categories of inferior goods
which do not follow the ‘law of demand’. Thus, a fall in the price of
such a good will result in a decrease in the quantity demanded and
vice versa. Robert Giffen studied this paradox. This happens To know more about
because the income effect of the price change of a Giffen good is Robert Giffen please
refer to Appendix-‘B’.
positive and is greater than the negative substitution effect. This
results in a price effect which is positive, resulting in the price and
quantity demanded changing in the same direction.
Besides Giffen Goods, the law of demand may not operate in the
case of the following goods:
‘Status Symbol’ Goods: These goods are bought because they
confer a social prestige to the buyer. According to Torstein Veblen, To know more about
a fall in their prices will result in the curtailment in the quantity Torstein Veblem
demanded, resulting in the violation of the law of demand. This please refer to
Appendix-‘B’.
generally happens in case of luxury goods.
Speculative Consumption: Speculation of further rise in prices of
the very essential products may induce consumers to purchase
more of a commodity as its price increases, resulting in a temporary
failure of the law of demand. Suppose, the price of a very important
drug/medicine has started to increase very sharply. In such a
situation, in anticipation of further increase in prices in the coming
days, the consumers may find it more beneficial to purchase more
quantity of the drug than actually required.
Q
Q P Q
Thus, ep= P x
Q P
P
Introduction to Economic Theory-I 49
Unit 3 Demand Analysis
F
Price
D/
X
0 Q Quantity
D E=
a
E>1
b
E=1
Price
c
E<1
d
e E=0
X
0 D/ Quantity
Now,
a) If ep = 0, the demand is perfectly inelastic.
b) If ep = 1, the demand is perfectly elastic.
c) If ep < 1, the demand is relatively elastic.
Now, let us explain these situations in some detail.
a) If ep=0, the demand is perfectly inelastic. This implies that any
proportionate change in price will have no effect on the quantity
demanded. A perfectly inelastic demand is indicated in figure
3.6, which is a straight perpendicular on the horizontal axis.
Price
0 Quantity X
D
b) If ep= the demand is perfectly elastic. this implies that for a
small change in price there would be a infinitely large change
in quantity demanded. This gives us a demand curve which is
parallel to the horizontal axis as has been shown in the following
figure 3.7.
Fig. 3.7: Horizontal Demand Curve : Perfectly Elastic
D
Price
0 Quantity X
Y
D
P2
Price
P1
D
0 Q2 Q1 Quantity X
P1 A
ΔP
{
Price
P2 B
D
ΔQ
}
X
0 Q1 Q2 Quantity
In figure 3.9, the elasticity of demand in the AB segment of
the demand curve DD is indicated by the arc elasticity of demand.
Thus, the arc elasticity of demand is average elasticity of the
segment AB and is represented by the midpoint of the chord AB
joining the two points A and B of the demand curve DD.
Introduction to Economic Theory-I 53
Unit 3 Demand Analysis
ACTIVITY 3.1
When two goods are related to each other, then the change
in demand for one good in response to a change in the price of the
second good is indicated by the cross elasticity of demand. The
cross elasticity of demand is defined as the proportionate change
in the quantity demanded of x in response to a proportionate change
in the price of y.
Q x
Qx P Q x
Thus, exy = y x
P
y Q x Py
Py
1) Ahuja, H.L. (2006); Modern Economics; New Delhi: S. Chand & Co.
Ltd.
2) Jhingan, M.L. (1986); Micro Economic Theory; New Delhi: Konark
Publications.
3) Koutsoyiannis, A. (1979); Modern Microeconomics; New Delhi:
Macmillan.
4.2 INTRODUCTION
Let us ponder for a few minutes over this question : why do we buy
goods and services from the market? Well, the answer is obvious : they
satisfy our wants. Thus, in this sense, goods and services have want-
satisfying power. In Economics, we name this want-sarisfying power as
‘utility’. Thus, utility may be defined as the power of a commodity or a
service to satisfy the wants of a consumer. Alternatively, utility may also be
defined as the satisfaction that a consumer derives by consuming a
commodity or a service. Utility is a subjective concept and it is formed in
the mind of a consumer. It is important to note that the concept of utility is
not related to the concepts of morality or ethics. Let us take an example :
a drug addict person consumes drugs. In Economics paralance, the drug
addict is a consumer of drugs and drugs have utility for the person. While
dealing with the issue of utility, It is not considered if consumption of drugs
will have any harmful effects on the health of the drug addict. Another
important aspect of utility is that being a subjective concept, the level of
satisfaction from the consumption of goods and services varies among
different individuals. Suppose, you and one of your friends have gone to a
tea stall. You may like to take a hot samosa and tea, while your friend may
not like them so much. Thus, the satisfaction you will derive from the hot
samosa and the cup of tea will differ from what your friend will derive from
Total Utility
Total Utility
Curve
Marginal Utility
Marginal
Utility Curve
Quantity Consumed
Numismatics is the
to collect/ study varieties of such items, rather than a number of
study or collection of copies of the same item. The person, thus, finds it more pleasurable
currency, including to own different varieties of the product at their kitty. The law seems
coins, tokens, paper
to fail to operate in case of luxury and esteemed goods as well. For
money and related
example, rich and affluent people tend to prefer a diamond jewellery
objects.
of higher prices, rather than the lower one.
Now if :
MU MU
x y
i) P P , then the consumer will start substituting commodity Y
x y
MU MU
y x
will continue untill P equals P .
y x
MU MU
x y
ii) Conversely, if P P , then the consumer will substitute
x y
didn’t pay that price. For example, a person is looking for a rented house.
He is ready to pay a monthly rent of Rs. 2,000/- for it. However due to
competition in the market, the person gets the house at a rent of Rs. 1,500/
- per month. Thus, Rs. 500/- (the difference between the reservation price
of the consumer and what he actually pays) is the consumer’s surplus in
this case.
Fig. 4.2: Consumer’s Surplus
Consumer’s
Surplus
Supply Curve
Price
Demand Curve
Producer’s
Surplus
Quantity
1) Ahuja, H.L. (2006); Modern Economics; New Delhi: S. Chand & Co.
Ltd.
2) Chopra, P.N. (2008); Micro Economics; New Delhi: Kalyani
Publishers.
3) Dewett, K.K. (2005); Modern Economic Theory; New Delhi: S. Chand
& Co. Ltd.
4) Koutsoyiannis, A. (1979); Modern Microeconomics; New Delhi:
Macmillan.
5) Sundharam, K.P.M. & Vaish, M.C. (1997); Microeconomic Theory;
New Delhi: S.Chand & Co. Ltd.
5.2 INTRODUCTION
y
20 (x = 1, y = 20)
15 (x = 2, y = 15)
Commodity Y
10 (x = 3, y = 11)
(x = 4, y = 8)
(x = 5, y = 6)
5
(x = 6, y = 5)
IC1
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 x
Commodity X
Introduction to Economic Theory-I 77
Unit 5 Consumer Behaviour-Ordinal Approach
20
16
Commodity Y
12
IC3
8
IC2
IC1
4
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 x
Commodity X
78 Introduction to Economic Theory-I
Consumer Behaviour-Ordinal Approach Unit 5
y
20 (x = 1, y = 20)
15 (x = 2, y = 15)
Commodity Y
10 (x = 3, y = 11)
(x = 4, y = 8)
(x = 5, y = 6)
5
(x = 6, y = 5)
IC1
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 x
Commodity X
A
B
Commodity Y
15
10 C
IC1
5
IC2
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 X
Commodity X
A
Commodity Y
B
C
IC2
IC1
0 Commodity X x
X M 100 10
Px 10
b) and if he spends all his income on Y, then the number of units of y
that he can consume is:
Y M 100 5
Py 20
Thus, 10x and 5y are the two extreme limits of the consumer’s
expenditures. However, he usually prefers a combination of the two
commodities within these two limits. In fact, the budget line joins the two
extreme consumption limits of the consumer, and the points within those
Introduction to Economic Theory-I 83
Unit 5 Consumer Behaviour-Ordinal Approach
two limits indicate the combinations available to the consumer, given his
income and the prices of the two commodities.
The concept of budget line has been shown with the help of figure
5.5.
Fig. 5.5: Budget Line
y
A
Commodity Y 5
1 B
0 2 4 6 8 x
10
Commodity X
In the above figure 5.5, AB indicates the budget line. In this budget
line AB, the consumer has the option of consuming 10x(0B) or 5y(0A) or
some combination of the two.
The slope of the budget line is the ratio of the prices of the two
commodities. Geometrically,
M
Py
[Slope of the Budget Line] = M Px
Py
Px
a
Commodity Y
y b
IC3
c IC2
IC1
X
0 X B Commodity X
Thus, at equlibrium,
[slope of the indifference curve] = [slope of the budget line]
Symbolically, it can be expressed as :
Px
MRS xy
Py
Indifference Curve Technique vs Cardinal UtilityAnalysis: The
indifference curve technique is considered to be surperior to the cardinal
utility approach on the following grounds:
It avoids the unrealistic assumption of cardinal utility and instead
adopts the concept of ordinal utility.
It can be used to split the price effect into substitution effect and
income effect.
It is not based on the unrealistic assumption of constant marginal
utility of money.
Limitations of the Indiference Curve Technique: The indifference
curve technique has been crticised on the following grounds:
The indifference curve technique does not tell us anything new,
and it is only “old wine in new bottle”.
It assumes that the consumer is very familiar with his entire
preference schedule, which is not the case in actual life.
Introduction to Economic Theory-I 85
Unit 5 Consumer Behaviour-Ordinal Approach
A
Commodity Y
y2 e2
e1
y1
IC1
IC2
0 x2 B2 x1 Commodity X B1 X
From Figure 5.7 it can be seen that the consumer originally faces
the indifference curve IC1. His/her level of income has been depicted by
the budget line AB1. Thus, given this budget line, the consumer attains
equilibrium at point e 1, where the budget ine AB 1 is tangent to the
indifference curve IC1. In this point of equilibrium, the consumer consumes
0X1 of commodity X and 0Y1 of commodity Y. Now let us suppose, the
price of X increases. As a result, the real income of the consumer will be
88 Introduction to Economic Theory-I
Consumer Behaviour-Ordinal Approach Unit 5
A
IA’
y3 Ie3
Ie2
Commodity Y
y1 Ie1
IIC1
IIC2
0 x3 B2 x1 B3 B1 X
Commodity X
Please note that here we are trying to analyse what will happen if
the consumer is allowed to close combinations of commodities in his initial
indifference curve IC1, if we take into consideration the changing budget
Introduction to Economic Theory-I 89
Unit 5 Consumer Behaviour-Ordinal Approach
situation (or the changing relative prices of the two commodities). Thus,
we want to analyse given the new budget constraint AB 2, how the consumer
will behave if he is allowed to choose combinations of the two commodities
in his initial indifference curve IC1. In such situations, the budget line will
shift in parrellel to the new budget line AB 2. In figure, this has been shown
by the budget line A/B3 (the dark dotted line). This budget line A’B3 is tangent
to the original indifference curve IC1 at point e3. Thus, at this equilibrium
point e3, the consumer buys less of the commodity which is relatively
expensive (OX3 instead of OX1) and more of the commodity which is
relatively cheaper (OY3 instead of OY1). Thus, this shows that due a change
in the price, the consumers tends to sustitute relatively more expensive
commodity for the relatively cheaper commodity. This is the substitution
effect.
Income Effect: The income effect reveals how the consumer will
react to a change in his purchasing power given the new relative prices.
For analysing the income effect, we assume that the substitution effect
has already taken place. Thus, here we take into consideration the
behaviour of the consumer, when given the new relative prices, the
consumer faces a lower indiference curve (as his realincome has been
adversely affected, he no more remains on the same indifference curve).
In such a situation, given the new budget line and the lower indifference
curve, the consumer reacts by choosing less of both the commodities, as
compared to when he is allowed to remain in the same indifference curve
even when taking into consideration the new relative prices (this is what
we have considered in case of the substitution effect). This has been
explained with the help of figure 5.9.
From figure 5.9, it can be seen that with the subsitution effect already
in action the consumer buys less of both the commodities X and Y. The
income effect has been shown by the movement of the consumer from e 3
to e2.
A A1
y3 e3
Commodity Y
y2 e2
IC1
IC2
0 x2 x3 B2 B3 B1 X
Commodity X
A A1
y3 e3
Su
Commodity Y
Income
bs
titu
y2
e2
ati
e1
on
y1
IC1
IC2
0 x2 x3 B2 x1 B3 B1 X
Commodity X
e1 to point the point e2. This is the price effect. However, we can break up
this overall price effect into two components, viz., the substitution effect
and the income effect. The substitution effect is considered first. The
substitution effect has been shown by the movement of the consumer
from point e1 to point e3. The income effect is allowed, keeping in mind that
the substitution effect has already taken place. The income effect has
been shown with the help of movement of the consumer from point e 3 to
point e2.
Thus, on the overall, we can summarise that as the price of one
good increases, the real income of the consumer is adveresely affected.
Or, in other words, the budget line of the consumer is adveresely affected.
As a result, the consumer no more remains on the same indifference curve.
After the price effect is allowed to happen, and given his new budget line,
the consumer attains equilibrium on a lower indiference curve. In attaining
this new equilibrium, the consumer consumes less of the commodity which
is relatively expensive (in our case, commodity X) and more of the
commodity which is relatively cheaper (commodity Y).
The substitution effect and the income effect are the two
components of the price effect.
These two components can be derived using either the Hicksian
compensating variation method or the Slutsky’s cost - difference
method.
1) Ahuja, H.L. (2006); Modern Economics; New Delhi: S. Chand & Co.
Ltd.
2) Chopra, P.N. (2008); Micro Economics; New Delhi: Kalyani
Publishers.
3) Dewett, K.K. (2005); Modern Economic Theory; New Delhi: S. Chand
& Co. Ltd.
4) Koutsoyiannis, A. (1979); Modern Microeconomics; New Delhi:
Macmillan.
5) Sundharam, K.P.M. & Vaish, M.C. (1997); Microeconomic Theory;
New Delhi: S.Chand & Co. Ltd.
6.2 INTRODUCTION
seller will be very much concerned with the nature of demand for his product.
This is because the monetary value of demand of a consumer for the product
constitutes his revenue. Thus, the more the demand, the greater will be the
volume of revenue earned by the seller. The concept of revenue when viewed
from the viewpoint of a seller is classified into three types: average revenue,
marginal revenue and total revenue. In this unit, we shall discuss these
three concepts and their inter-relationships. Apart from this, we shall also
relate these concepts with the concept of price elasticity we have already
discussed in the previous block.
TR
Symbolically, AR =
Q
where, AR stands for average revenue, TR stands for total revenue
and Q stands for quantity.
With reference to the previous example, the average revenue of Rs.
12/- is obtained by dividing total revenue (Rs. 1800/-) by total quantity sold
(150 units).
From the above discussion, it seems that average revenue and price
are the same concepts. It may be, or it may not be. If the seller sells each
unit of the product at the same price, average revenue and price will be the
same. If on the other hand, the seller sells the different units of the product
at different prices, average revenue will not be equal to price. Let us consider
an example. Suppose our hypothetical seller sells two units of the product
to two different consumers, viz., consumer A and consumer B. Let us further
suppose that the seller sells one unit of the product to consumer A at Rs.12
while he sells the other unit of product to consumer B at Rs.10. Thus, the
average revenue earned by the seller comes out to be Rs.(12 + 10)/2 =
Rs.11/- while prices of the two units of the product were Rs.12/- and Rs.10/
- respectively.
In practice, we find that the seller sells the individual unit of the
product at the same price at a particular point of time. This is because, if an
individual seller tends to charge higher prices for the product, consumers
will move away from him and will purchase the product from other seller
who sells at a lower price. As against this, he cannot lower the price of the
product at his will. This is because, if the seller tries to sell the product at a
lower price, the other sellers will follow him and he will face competition in
the market. Ultimately, a single price will prevail in the market. As such, in
economics average revenue is taken as equivalent to the price of the product
except when we discuss the case of price discrimination. We shall discuss
this in detail later in the next block.
Another important point to be noted here is that as we have already
mentioned, the money value of demand of the consumer constitutes
revenue for the seller. As such, the demand curve of the consumer is same
as the total revenue curve of the seller.
Marginal Revenue: Marginal revenue is the net revenue earned by
selling an additional unit of the product. Thus, marginal revenue is obtained
when we calculate the changes in total revenue caused by the sale of an
additional unit of the product.
Thus, marginal revenue is represented as:
Change in total revenue
Marginal Revenue = Change in total units sold
TR
Symbolically, it is represented as: MR =
Q
where, MR stands for marginal revenue, TR stands for total revenue,
Q stands for total units sold, and stands for change in.
Let us consider the case of marginal revenue in the context of our
hypothetical seller who sells all units of pens at Rs.12/-. Suppose the seller
increase his sales from 150 units to 151 units. In this case, the total revenue
earning of the sellers will be Rs.1812/-. Thus, marginal revenue will be (Rs.
1812 – 1800) = Rs.12/-; this is same as average revenue.
However, if price charged in the extra unit of the product is different
from the price charged in the earlier units, marginal revenue will be different
from average revenue. For example, let us suppose that our hypothetical
seller sales the 151st unit at Rs.11.50/- while he sold all the previous units at
Rs. 12/-. Thus, the total revenue earned by the seller is Rs.1811.50/- and
marginal revenue is (Rs.1811.50 – 1800) = Rs.11.50/-.
From the above discussion, we are already familiar with the concepts
of average revenue, marginal revenue and total revenue. In this section, we
shall discuss the inter-relationships between these revenue concepts in
more detail. In doing this, we shall first have to deduce the graphical shapes
of the average revenue, marginal revenue and total revenue curves.
40
30
20
10
0 1 2 3 4 5 Quantity x
From the figure it is obvious that the total revenue curve of the firm is
an upward rising straight line. This curve, in fact represents the supply curve
of a firm.
Average Revenue and Marginal Revenue Curves: We have
already mentioned that under perfect competition, the market price for the
product is fixed and the seller has no influence to alter the same. Again, the
seller can supply any amount of the commodity at the prevailing market
price. Thus, the prevalent market price also becomes the average revenue
and marginal revenue of the firm. This is clear from the above table 6.1.
From the table it is clear that the prevalent market price, i.e., Rs.14 is also
102 Introduction to Economic Theory-I
Concepts of Revenue Unit 6
the average revenue and marginal revenue of the firm. Thus, the shape of
average revenue curve and the marginal revenue curve will be the same.
This has been shown with the help of the following figure 6.2.
Fig. 6.2: Average Revenue and Marginal Revenue Curve under
Perfect Competition
AR = MR = Price
Revemie
Quantity
It can be seen from figure 6.2 that the firm’s AR and MR curves are
the same. The slope of the curves is horizontal.
AR and MR and TR Curves of a Firm under Imperfect
Competition: Unlike perfect competition, a firm under imperfect competition
does not have to sell its entire amount of the product at a fixed market price.
This means that the firm can sell more units of the product as its price falls.
We have shown a hypothetical schedule of AR, TR and MR in table 6.2.
Table 6.2: Total, Average and Marginal Revenue Schedules of a
Firm under Imperfect Competition
(Revenue figures in Rs.)
Number of Price or Average Total Revenue Marginal
units sold (Q) Revenue (AR) (AR x Q) Revenue
1 20 20 20
2 19 38 18
3 18 54 16
4 17 68 14
5 16 80 12
6 15 90 10
7 14 98 8
8 13 104 6
9 12 108 4
10 11 110 2
11 10 110 0
12 9 108 –2
13 8 104 –4
3
2
1
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 Output
–1
–2
–3
–4
110 MR
100
90 TR
80
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13
From figure 6.3 it can be seen that unlike perfect competition, firm’s
AR and MR curves under imperfect competition are not the same. However,
both the curves are downward sloping. Again, the slope of the marginal
104 Introduction to Economic Theory-I
Concepts of Revenue Unit 6
e 1
MR AR
e
where, MR = marginal revenue, AR = average revenue and e = price
elasticity of demand.
Thus, from this formula we can know what would be the marginal
revenue if elasticity and AR are given to us.
Let us take the case when price elasticity of demand is 1.
1 1
Thus, MR AR
1
Thus, MR = AR X 0 = 0.
Again, from this formula we can find:
If e > 1, MR is positive, and MR<AR
If e < 1, MR is negative, and MR>AR.
This relationship among AR, MR, TR and price elasticity of demand
can also be shown graphically in figure 6.4.
From figure 6.4 it can be seen that C is the middle point of the average
revenue curve DD. At this point C price elasticity of demand is equal to one
. Corresponding to this point C of the DD curve, we can find that MR is
equal to zero (this is because, corresponding to C of the DD curve, the MR
curve cuts the x-axis at point N). Thus, at quantity 0N, price elasticity of
demand is 1, while MR is zero. At a quantity less than 0N, price elasticity of
106 Introduction to Economic Theory-I
Concepts of Revenue Unit 6
demand is greater than 1 (or positive) and at a quantity less than 0N, price
elasticity of demand is less than 1 (or negative). It has also be seen that
when the marginal revenue is positive, price elasticity of demand is also
positive and when marginal revenue is negative, price elasticity of demand
also becomes negative.
Fig. 6.4: Relationship between AR,MR, TR and price elasticity
of Demand
AR, MR
Output
MR
TR
TR
Output
Again, from the bottom panel of the figure it can be seen that total
revenue is maximum when price elasticity of demand equals one. It can be
further noticed that when the price elasticity of demand is greater than one
(or positive), TR tends to increase and when the price elasticity of demand
is less than one (or negative), TR tends to diminish.
1) Ahuja, H.L. (2006); Modern Economics; New Delhi: S. Chand & Co.
Ltd.
2) Dewett, K.K. (2005); Modern Economic Theory; New Delhi: S. Chand
& Co. Ltd.
3) Koutsoyiannis, A. (1979); Modern Microeconomics; New Delhi:
Macmillan.
4) Sundharam, K.P.M. & Vaish, M.C. (1997); Microeconomic Theory;
New Delhi: S.Chand & Co. Ltd.
Ans. to Q. No. 1: Under perfect competition, the market price for the
product is fixed and the seller has no influence to alter the same.
However, the seller can supply any amount of the commodity at the
prevailing market price. As a result, the prevalent market price also
represents the average revenue curve and marginal revenue of the
firm. Hence, both the curves are same.
Ans. to Q. No. 2: The shape of the total revenue curve is not same in perfect
competition and imperfect competition. This is because price
Introduction to Economic Theory-I 109
Unit 6 Concepts of Revenue
7.2 INTRODUCTION
Q = f (L, K)
where, Q is a dependent variable which represents output; and both
labour (L) and capital (K) are independent variables.
This relation simply states that output depends on inputs. To
get output Q, inputs can be combined in various proportions. But as
technology improves the same inputs can give more and more output
and the same output can be obtained by less and less input. In our
production function, there are only two variables. But there may be
other variables in the production function.
7.4.2 Iso-quant
1
2
Capital
4
5
0 Labour X
IQ 4
IQ 3
IQ 2
IQ 1
0 Labour X
Introduction to Economic Theory-I 115
Unit 7 Theory of Production
Y
A
B
Capital
C
D
E
IQ1 = 50
0 Labour X
A
Capital
C
B
IQ 2
IQ 1
0 X
Labour
In the above figure 7.4, IQ1 and IQ2 intersect at point C. Thus,
the point C lies on IQ1. Again, point A also lies on IQ . Therefore, it
1
means that at both the points (A and C) the level of output is the
same. On the other hand, point C lies on IQ 2 meaning same level of
output at point C and point B on the iso-quant.
Thus, we found that:
Output level at point A = Output level at point C.
Output level at point B = Output level at point C.
Thus, Output level at point A = Output level at point B. This is
completely ridiculous. So, it can be said that two iso-quants can not
intersect.
Y
Capital
IQ 4
IQ 3
IQ 2
IQ 1
0 X
Labour
LET US KNOW
Again, it can be seen from the above table 7.3 that total product is
the highest when marginal productivity of labour is zero. After this point both
total and average product fall and marginal product of labour becomes
negative. We can study the rise and fall of production with diagrams in three
stages.
Three Stages of the Law of Variable Proportions: From the above
table 7.3 we see the behaviour of output with varying quantity of labour and
fixed quantity of capital. The rise and fall of output can be divided into three
stages as has been shown in the following figure 7.6.
Fig. 7.6: The Three Stages of Law of Variable Proportions
H
Y
TP
1st Stage 2nd Stage 3rd Stage
Output
Point of
Inflexion
F
S
AP
0 N M X
Labour
Stage One: In the first stage the total output to a point increases at
an increasing rate. In the above figure 7.6 it can be seen that the total output
increases rapidly up to point F. This point is called ‘the point of inflexion’.
From this point onwards in stage one, total output increases but at a slower
rate. Therefore, the slope of the curve starts to fall slightly. Stage one ends
at the point where average product is the maximum. In this stage, the quantity
of the fixed factor (capital) is too much relative to the quantity of the variable
factor (labour) so that if some of the fixed factor is withdrawn, the total product
will increase. Stage one is known as the stage of increasing returns.
Stage Two: In stage two, the total product continues to increase at
a diminishing rate until it reaches its maximum point H (figure 7.6) where
the second stage ends. At the end of second stage marginal product becomes
zero. This stage is known as the stage of decreasing returns as both the
average and marginal products of the variable factor continuously fall during
this stage.
Stage Three: In stage three the marginal product becomes negative.
Therefore, both total product and average product declines. In this stage,
total product curve and average product curve slope downward and marginal
product curve goes below the X-axis. This is the opposite of first stage. In
stage three, variable factor (labour) is too much in relation to fixed factor
(capital). This stage is called the stage of negative returns.
A rational producer will always like to produce in stage two. The
producer will not choose stage one where marginal product of fixed factor
is negative. If he chooses this stage, he will not be utilizing completely the
opportunity of production by increasing variable factor. A rational producer
will never choose stage three also. Because, in this stage, he can always
increase output by reducing the quantity of variable factor whose quantity is
excess in proportion of fixed factor. Even when the variable factor is free,
the rational producer will stop at the end of second stage.
Significance of the Law of Variable Proportions:The law of
variable proportions is very important in the field of economics. Till Marshall
it was believed that the law was applicable in the field of agriculture only.
But the modern economists propound that the law is equally applicable to
industries and other productive activities. If the law actually does not occur,
we can produce any amount of food grain in a small size of holding by using
more and more amount of labour and capital. But in spite of the presence of
the law of variable proportions a country like India need not be pessimistic
where there is tremendous pressure of population and agricultural production
is not sufficient. Productivity in the field of agriculture can be increased by
making advancement in technology to avoid food crisis.
Under the law of variable proportions we have known that the changes
in total output as a result of change in variable factor keeping quantity of
other factors of production constant. But when all inputs are changed in a
fixed proportion, there is change in the scale of production. The study of
124 Introduction to Economic Theory-I
Theory of Production Unit 7
3K
Capital
IQ5 = 50
2K
IQ4 = 40
1K IQ3 = 30
IQ2 = 20
IQ1 = 10
0 1L 2L 3L Labour X
3K
IQ3 = 30
Capital
2K
1K IQ2 = 20
IQ1 = 10
0 1L 2L 3L Labour X
A
9K
IQ5 = 40
Capital
IQ4 = 30
3K
IQ3 = 20
1K IQ2 = 15
IQ1 = 10
0 3L 9L Labour X
1L
In the above figure 7.9, it can be seen that to increase output from
10 to 20 units inputs need to be increased more than twice. Similarly, to
raise the level output by four times from 10 to 40 units, the firm needs to
employ nine times of its initial inputs, i.e., 9 units of capital and labour
each.The common cause of diminishing returns to scale is diminishing
returns to management. As the output grows managers are overburdened
and become less efficient in rendering duties. Communication between
workers and managers can become difficult to monitor as the work place
becomes more and more impersonal. Decreasing returns to scale may
also arise due to exhaustible nature of natural resources.
Introduction to Economic Theory-I 127
Unit 7 Theory of Production
firm can buy with Rs. 300/-. Thus, an iso-cost line can be defined as the
locus of various combinations of factors which a firm can buy with a constant
outlay. The iso- cost line is also called the price line or outlay line.
Fig. 7.10: Iso-cost Line
Y
K 60
Capital
70
0 Labour L X
The iso cost line shifts when the total outlay which the firm wants to
spend on the factors changes. A greater outlay will cause the iso cost line to
shift to the right.
The equilibrium condition of the firm depends on its objectives. As
mentioned earlier, an isoquant map given the various factor combinations
which can yield various levels of output, every isoquant showing those factor
combinations which can produce a specified level of output. A family of iso-
cost line represents the various levels of total cost or outlay, given the prices
of two factors.
The entrepreneur may– i) minimise cost subject to a given output or
ii) maximise output for a given cost.
If the entrepreneur has already decided about the level of output, he/
Tangent : a tangent is
she will choose the combinations of factors which minimises the cost of
a straight line which
production, i. e. he/she will choose the least cost combination of factors.
touches a curve at a
We have already said that the point of least cost combination of single point. The point
factors for any level of output is where the iso-quant is tangent to an iso- where the straight line
quant. The point of tangency is the point where a straight line touches a touches the curve is
called the point of
curve. This has been explained with the help of the following figure 7.11.
tangency.
C
R
Capital B
E
K IQ = 100
S
0 L A B C D X
Labour
In the above figure 7.11, AA, BB, CC and DD are different iso-cost
lines. They show different levels of cost at which production can take place.
An important point to note here is that iso-cost lines are always parallel to
each other. The producer wants to produce 100 units of output and he has
to decide which level of cost will maximize his profit.
Profit will be maximum at point E where the iso-quant IQ touches
the iso-cost line BB. At this point the producer uses 0L amount of labour and
0K amount of capital. Points other than E can not be point of equilibrium as
other points cannot fulfil the condition of tangency. If we consider the point
R, cost is beyond the reach of the producer. Therefore, the producer will not
choose a combination other than E which is the least cost factor combination
for producing 100 units of output.
It should be remembered that the point of tangency between the iso-
cost and the iso-quant is not a necessary condition for producer’s equilibrium.
At the point of tangency, the iso-quant must be convex to the origin. In other
words, marginal rate of technical substitution of labour for capital must be
diminishing.
The second situation of output maximisation for a given level of cost
can be explained with the help of the following diagram.
K R
S
Capital
E
H
IQ4 (400)
IQ3 (300)
T
IQ2 (200)
J IQ1 (100)
0 N L Labour X
With the given outlay, there will be a single iso-cost line. The firm will
have to choose a factor combination lying on the given iso-cost line. The
producer will now be in equilibrium at point E where IQ 3 is tangent to KL
using ON units of labour and OH units of capital. The firm has the option of
producing at R, S, T and J but point E enables the firm to reach the highest
possible isoquant IQ3 producing 300 units of output.
B
Capital
A E4
E3 IQ4 = 400
E2 IQ3 = 300
E1 IQ2 = 200
IQ1 = 100
0 A B C D X
Labour
The expansion path may have different shape depending upon the
relative prices of the productive factors used and the shape of the iso-quant.
Since expansion path represents minimum cost combinations for various
levels of output, it shows the cheapest way of producing each output given
the relative prices of the factors.
It was first believed that the law was applicable in the field of
agriculture only. But the modern economists propound that the law
is equally applicable to industries and other productive activities.
The study of changes in output as a consequence of changes in the
scale is the subject matter of returns to scale.
Returns to scale may be constant, increasing or decreasing. Returns
to scale vary among different production functions. Normally returns
to scale is greater in the production function associated with larger
firms.
The law of variable proportions shows how output changes with
changes in the quantity of one input while other inputs are kept
constant. But in case of returns to scale, all inputs are changed in a
fixed proportion.
The condition of equilibrium is determined at the point of tangency
between iso-cost line and iso-quant. Iso-cost is a straight line which
shows various combinations of two factors that the firm can buy
with a given outlay.
It should be remembered that the point of tangency between the iso-
cost line and the iso-quant is not a necessary condition for producer’s
equilibrium. At the point of tangency, the iso-quant must be convex
to the origin. In other words, marginal rate of technical substitution
of labour for capital must be diminishing.
When a firm increases output, it moves from one equilibrium point
to another. Such change of equilibrium position form one to the other
is captured by expansion path.
Expansion path is the locus of the points of tangency between the
equal product curves and iso-cost lines as the firm expands output.
In other words, it is the locus of least cost combination points.
1) Ahuja, H.L. (2006); Modern Economics; New Delhi: S. Chand & Co.
Ltd.
134 Introduction to Economic Theory-I
Theory of Production Unit 7
8.2 INTRODUCTION
or not, whether there should be new acquisition and so on. In the language
of a layman, the sum of all expenditures incurred in the process of production
is called cost. The term ‘cost of production’ may be used in several senses.
We will discuss all of them.
The costs incurred on the production process may be studied in
both short-run and long-run. In the short-run, fixed cost cannot be changed.
Output can be increased only by varying the quantities of variable cost. The
short-run average cost curve has direct relationship with the short-run
marginal cost curve. But in the long-run there is hardly any fixed cost. A
period is called ‘long-run’ if all inputs can be changed with change in output.
In this unit, we will discuss how long-run average and long-run marginal
costs are derived. But the concept of cost discussed in this unit falls within
the purview of traditional theory of costs.
The short-run is a period in which the firm can not change its plant,
equipment and the scale of organization. To increase output, it can only
employ more variable factors with the same quantity of fixed factor.
constant whatever the level of output. Even if the firm does not
produce anything, the producer has to bear the total fixed cost. On
the other hand the total variable cost curve (TVC) will start from the
origin, meaning that if there is no production TVC will be zero.
Fig. 8.1: Shapes of Fixed Cost, Variable Cost and Total Cost Curves
Y
TC
st
co
le
iab
Var
l TVC
Cost
ta
To
Output X
From the above figure 8.1 it can be seen that the TVC moves
upward, showing that as output increases the total variable cost
increases. The vertical summation of total variable cost and total
fixed cost gives the total cost of the firm.
TC
ATC =
Q
TVC TFC
Or, ATC =
Q
TVC TFC
=
Q Q
= AVC + AFC
where, Q is the total output produced. It means that average cost is
the sum total of average variable cost and average fixed cost. The
shape of a short-run average cost curve is like U as shown in the
figure 6.2.
Average Fixed Cost: If the total fixed cost is divided by the total
number of units of output produced, we can arrive at average fixed
cost–
TFC
AFC =
Q
where, Q is the number of total output produced. The shape of the
average fixed cost curve is shown in figure 8.2.
Fig. 8.2: Shapes of Various Cost Curves
AC
AC
y MC MC
AVC
AVC
Cost
AFC
AFC
x
0 Output
and the AFC curve falls downward gradually. From column 6 of table
8.1, we can see that the amount of fixed cost is falling as production
is increasing.
Average Variable Cost (AVC): Average variable cost is the total
variable cost divided by the number of units of output produced. It
can be calculated in the following way:
TVC
AVC =
Q
where, Q stands for the total output produced. The average variable
cost will generally fall as output increases from zero to the normal
capacity output. But beyond the normal capacity of output it will rise
steeply because of the operation of the law of diminishing returns.
Average variable cost curve (AVC) is shown in the above figure 8.2.
Cost
Q Output x
From the above figure 8.3, it is clear that to the right of output
Q, MC is higher than AC and to the left of Q, MC is lower than AC.
But at output level Q, MC = AC. Thus, we find that:
If MC < AC, then AC will be falling as output increases.
If MC > AC, then AC will be rising as output increases.
At point Q where AC is minimum, we have AC = MC.
Q.5: What will be the variable cost when the output is zero?
(Answer in about 50 words)
............................................................................................
............................................................................................
Long-run is the period when a firm can change its plant size and
scale of organization. In the long-run all factors are variable. Now, the question
is how short is the short-run and how long is the long-run? This depends on
the industry and the production techniques used. The period length will vary
from firm to firm. If there are no transactions and no specialized inputs, then
all inputs can be quickly adjusted, and the long-run is not very long.
‘Envelope Curve’. The firm will produce 0M amount of output at the minimum
point E on the LAC curve. If the firm produces less than 0M, it is not
reaping fully the economies of production and if it produces beyond
0M, the firm’s profit will fall. In both the cases, the average cost of
production will be higher.
Fig. 8.4: Shapes of SAC Curves and the LAC Curve
y
LAC
SAC1
SAC5
SAC2
Cost
SAC4
Law of Returns to SAC3
Scale: This law
explains the rate at
E
which output changes
as the quantities of all
inputs are varied. 0 M Output X
Three laws of returns
The shape of the long-run average cost curve is like U. This
to scale exist:
shape reflects the law of returns to scale. According to this law,
Suppose, we increase
all the inputs of the unit costs of production decreases as plant size increases, due
production twice. Now, to the economies of scale, which the large plant sizes make
consequently: if output possible. It has been assumed that this plant is completely inflexible.
also increases twice,
There is no reserve capacity, not even to meet the temporary rise in
then we can say that
constant returns to demand. If this plant size increases further than this optimum size
scale exists; 2) if there are diseconomies of scale. The turning up of the LAC curve is
output increases by due to managerial diseconomies of scale when output is increased
less than twice, then
beyond the optimum size.
we can say that
decreasing returns to
8.5.2 Long-Run Marginal Cost Curve
scale exists; and finally
3) if output also The long-run marginal cost can be derived from the short-
increases by more
run marginal cost curves (SMC) but it does not envelope them like
than twice, then we
can say that the LAC curve. The LMC curve is formed from the point of intersection
increasing returns to of the SMC curves with vertical lines to the X axis drawn from the
scale exists.
148 Introduction to Economic Theory-I
Cost of Production and Cost Curves Unit 8
SAC2
we can say that a firm
p b SAC3 enjoys economies of
scale when it doubles
q c its output for less than
twice the cost.
Conversely, there are
X diseconomies of scale
0 A B C Output
when a doubling of
output requires more
In the above figure 8.5, let us start with the point ‘a’ which is
than twice the cost.
a point of tangency between SAC and LAC. From this point a vertical
line aA is drawn on the X axis and it cuts the SMC1 at point p. Similarly
‘b’ and ‘c’ are the other two points of tangency between other two
SAC curves and the LAC curve. Corresponding to these two points
of tangency, the point of intersection between vertical lines bB and
cC are q and c. After joining p, q and c we get the LMC curve. At this
minimum point c, the LMC curve intersects the LAC curve. Long-
run marginal cost bears direct relationship with the long-run average
cost. When both LAC and LMC fall, LMC is lower than LAC. But as
LAC and LMC both increase, LMC is higher than LAC. But the LMC
cuts the LAC at the lowest point. The same relationship between AC
and MC is true in the short-run as well.
The theory of cost may be approached from both short term and
long term perspectives. In the short-run, total cost is the sum of total
variable and total fixed cost.
The total variable costs are those expenses of production which
change with the changes in total output of the firm.
On the other hand, some components of production can not be varied
in the short-run. They are called fixed cost.
Average cost is derived by dividing the firm’s total cost by the level of
output.
Marginal cost is the increase in cost resulting from the production of
one extra unit of output.
There is a direct relationship between AC and MC. When AC falls
MC also falls but MC is below AC. When AC rises MC also rises and
MC is above it. AC is equals to MC at the lowest point on the AC
curve.
In the long-run, average cost curve is an envelope curve of the short-
run average cost curve. The shape of the LAC curve is like the U.
The U shape occurs due to the laws of returns to scale.
The long-run marginal cost can be derived from the short-run
marginal cost curves (SMC) but it does not envelope the short-run
marginal cost like the LAC curve.
The same direct relationship between average cost and marginal
cost curve which is applicable in the short is also applicable in the
long-run.
1) Ahuja, H.L. (2006); Modern Economics; New Delhi: S. Chand & Co.
Ltd.
2) Dewett, K.K. (2005); Modern Economic Theory; New Delhi: S. Chand
& Co. Ltd.
3) Koutsoyiannis, A. (1979); Modern Microeconomics; New Delhi:
Macmillan.
Introduction to Economic Theory-I 151
Unit 8 Cost of Production and Cost Curves
Ans. to Q. No. 6: Short-run is the period, when a firm cannot change all its
factors of production; neither can change its plant size and scale of
operation. Thus, some factors of production in the short-run are fixed
while others are variable. And in the short-run, while the cost of fixed
factors of production remain the same, the cost of the variable factors
of production varies according to the volume of production. On the
other hand, long-run is a period when a firm can change its plant
size and scale of operation. In the long-run all factors are variable.
Ans. to Q. No. 7: The LAC looks like the shape of ‘U’, because the laws of
returns to scale operate in the long-run.