0% found this document useful (0 votes)
59 views26 pages

Session 14 - Balasubramanyam, V N and Virmani, Swati - The Enigmatic Services Sector of India

This document summarizes a paper that examines India's large and growing services sector, which accounts for around 60% of GDP. The services sector has grown significantly since the early 1990s and now exceeds the shares of agriculture and manufacturing. This is unusual compared to other developing economies. The paper analyzes factors like India's economic history and policies that have promoted services sector growth. It argues that contrary to views, India's services sector can help lead the overall economy. The paper reviews the composition and growth of the services sector over time and its contribution to employment.

Uploaded by

Chahat Negi
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
59 views26 pages

Session 14 - Balasubramanyam, V N and Virmani, Swati - The Enigmatic Services Sector of India

This document summarizes a paper that examines India's large and growing services sector, which accounts for around 60% of GDP. The services sector has grown significantly since the early 1990s and now exceeds the shares of agriculture and manufacturing. This is unusual compared to other developing economies. The paper analyzes factors like India's economic history and policies that have promoted services sector growth. It argues that contrary to views, India's services sector can help lead the overall economy. The paper reviews the composition and growth of the services sector over time and its contribution to employment.

Uploaded by

Chahat Negi
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 26

Munich Personal RePEc Archive

The Enigmatic Services Sector of India

Balasubramanyam, V N and Virmani, Swati

Lancaster University Management School, University of Huddersfield

August 2018

Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/89174/
MPRA Paper No. 89174, posted 26 Sep 2018 15:08 UTC
The Enigmatic Services Sector of India

V N Balasubramanyam*
Swati Virmani**

* Lancaster University; [email protected]


**University of Huddersfield; [email protected]
Abstract
The share of services in India’s GDP, at round 60%, is much higher than that in other
emerging economies including China. Since the year 1991 Growth of services in the
economy has surpassed that of agriculture and manufacturing, a feature that defies
received wisdom on the growth pattern of economies. Received wisdom, grounded in the
Kuznets paradigm, is that growth in the productivity of agriculture and agricultural incomes
provides the manufacturing sector both low cost agricultural raw materials and a demand
for its output. In time, the continued growth in incomes promotes the growth of the
services sector both through a demand for consumer services and for services as growth
promoting inputs into manufacturing and agriculture. India’s services sector, though, has
grown alongside an agriculture sector that is none too productive, and a manufacturing
sector that accounts for a relatively low 20% of the GDP. This paper provides an explanation,
grounded in the country’s history and economic policies of the pre- liberalization era, for the
growth of the services sector and argues that, contrary to popular opinion, it can lead the
economy.

1. Introduction
At a recent seminar on services in the Indian economy a commentator observed that the
relatively high share of services in India’s GDP, at around 60%, is a wonder and cause for
dismay. Indeed, the share of services in India’s GDP is much above the norm for economies
with similar levels of per capita income. The share of services in India’s GDP was 8% above
the norm in the year 2005, whilst China’s share of services in GDP was 6% below the norm
(Ghani Ejaz, 2011), and the share of manufacturing in GDP is much lower than that in several
other emerging economies.

India’s services sector is heterogeneous, with a number of sub sectors from the traditional
ones such as transport services to the modern information technology (IT) oriented services.
Section 2 of the paper reviews the growth of the sector over time and its share in the
national product of the country. There are reasons for the significant share of services in
India’s GDP, grounded in India’s economic history and economic policies in the years soon
after independence. Section 3 of the paper analyses the factors that have promoted the
1
growth of the sector. Section 4 discusses the nature and growth of the sector and its
interrelationship with other sectors in some detail, all of which provides the basis for the
contention that the sector can lead the Indian economy. Section 5 sums up the main
conclusions of the paper.

2. Growth and Size of the Services Sector in the Economy


Services accounted for 55.2 % of the country’s Gross Value Added of $2038 billion in the
year 2017-18 up from 40 % in the year 1980, exceeding the share of both agriculture and
manufacturing (Table 1).

Table 1: Sectoral Shares in Gross Value Added (%)


Year Agriculture Manufacturing Services Total Value
Added (Rest
Million
2011-12 21.74 29.28 48.97 810,694,60
2012-13 20.94 28.76 50.83 920,269,20
2013-14 20.65 28.27 51.08 103,631,530
2014-15 19.64 28.21 52.24 114,817,940
2015-16 `18.51 28.38 53.11 124,586,420
2016-17 18.11 28.22 53.68 136,699,140
(estimate)

Source: Economic Survey 2016-17, Volume 2, Ministry of Finance, Government of India

Whilst the share of agriculture in GDP has declined over the years, that of manufacturing
has stayed more or less stagnant since the 1990s, whilst that of services has increased
steadily from less than 35% in the early years of economic planning to 58% in recent years
(Figure 1).

2
Figure 1: Share of Agriculture. Manufacturing and Services in GDP

70.00

60.00

50.00

40.00

30.00

20.00

10.00

0.00
1950-51
1953-54
1956-57
1959-60
1962-63
1965-66
1968-69
1971-72
1974-75

1977-78
1980-81
1983-84
1986-87

1989-90
1992-93
1995-96

1998-99
2001-02
2004-05
2007-08

2010-11
Agriculture Industry Services

Source: Ministry of Statistics and Programme Implementation, Planning Commission,


Government of India.

Services also account for a higher proportion of employment of the labour force at around
31% higher than that in manufacturing, agriculture though harbours a high proportion of
the labour force (Table 2).

Table 2: Sectoral Shares in Total Employment: 1987-2016

1991 1993- 1999-2000 2004-05 2009- 2016-


94 10 17

Agriculture 63.59 64.70 59.90 56.40 52.80 47.00

Manufacturing 14.81 14.8 16.3 18.8 10.54 22.00

Services 21.60 20.50 23.90 24.80 26.67 31.00

Total Labour 335.39 351.8 397.70 457.46 469.80 513.7

3
Force (Millions)

Source: National Sample Survey Organisation, Surveys on Employment

The rapid growth of the services sector and its relatively high share both in GDP and
employment is seen as a wonder. It is also a cause for dismay that services, most of which
are human capital intensive, may not generate the high volume of employment and incomes
that India, with its high level of poverty and regional economic disparities, requires.
Whether the composition of the sector should be a cause for concern is discussed in some
detail in section 4 of the paper.

3. Why do Services Dominate the Economic Structure of India?

The well- known Kuznets (1955) paradigm sketches the transition of a growing economy
from agriculture to a services oriented economy. The phenomenon, that underlies this
transition, is based on the relationship between growth and income distribution depicted in
the inverted U shaped curve, with income distribution on the vertical axis and income
growth on the horizontal axis. Growth of agriculture increases agricultural incomes as well
as inequality of incomes. These income effects generate not only a demand for
manufactures, but also a reduction in the price of agricultural inputs required by the
manufacturing sector. Both these effects promote the growth of the manufacturing sector,
with a further increase in income inequalities in the economy. These income effects in turn
promote a demand for services. The growth of the services economy and the accompanying
growth of incomes result in a reduction in income inequality. The growth process of most
developed countries, including the UK and the USA, seem to conform to the Kuznets
paradigm. India though is an exception, with the path of transition that has jumped from
agriculture to services with a nod towards manufactures. This phenomenon has an
explanation grounded in the country’s economic history and economic ideology.

Until recent years, the economy of India hardly experienced the sort of growth in incomes,
underlying the Kuznets paradigm. Growth of per capita incomes was virtually stagnant

4
throughout the colonial years. Growth in income though recognisable was none too
significant in the post-independence years until the decade of the nineteen eighties. Even
so, the structure of the economy more nearly resembles that of a developed country, with
services accounting for a relatively large share of GDP as noted in section 2 of the paper.

The present day economic structure of the economy of India has its roots in India’s history
and the structure of its society. For long, India has been an elitist society, with a hierarchical
caste system dominated by the Brahmins, the ruling class, and the merchant class; all three
commanding power and influence over education, trade and top-level administration. As
the reputable economic historian, Thirthankar Roy (2011) observes- “the historical pattern
of demand for education at all levels was biased towards certain castes and communities
because these people had an inherited association with literate services. Groups that had
contact with scribal professions, medicine, teaching, and priesthood, in the pre-colonial
times, entered education, medicine and public administration in the colonial times. These
classes and castes eagerly used the new schools and colleges, while other classes and castes
entered schools on a smaller scale, and dropped out more readily. The correlation between
family history of literate services, preference for service professions, and thus, preference for
education, was especially close in the three port cities – Madras, Bombay, and Calcutta”. The
city of Bangalore, home to India’s major software firms and software engineers, is a
twentieth century addition to the three port cities. The software industry is dominated by
members of the middle class, mostly upper castes, especially the Brahmins, that were
prominent in civil service jobs in the past (Upadhya, 2004).

This sort of a preference for administrative jobs on the part of the upper caste members has
its counterpart in the preference for careers in trade and finance on the part of leading
business communities, such as the Banias and the Marwaris, in the country. The business
houses of these communities financed foreign trade during the British colonial era. Each of
the business houses produced a diverse range of products but they all shared risks and drew
on a pool of finance and information. They were also traders in their own right. Another
group of entrepreneurs were the Parsis who had no religious affiliation with the Hindu
community and were on a class of their own. As Damodaran (2013) notes the Parsis had
special relationship with the British: “being part of neither the Hindu nor Muslim

5
mainstream, nursing no political ambition and exposed to commercial influences because of
their proximity to the ports of Bharuch, Surat, and Daman, the Parsis seemed ideal for
recruitment as native brokers, agents and shippers”. Again, as Thirthankar Roy writes: “the
factors that have promoted the growth of services sector may differ between the various
states of India, but two of them may be significant for all of them. First is the significance of
trade and finance in India’s economic history through the ages, but especially so from the
British colonial days. The ratio of trade to domestic product increased from a low of 1 to 2%
in 1800 to 20% by 1914” (Roy, 2011).

It is thus that history underlies the growth of the present day services sector. The
predominance of trade and finance in India’s economy over the years has shaped the
managerial class, as it exists today. Managers of the day in the private sector are “market
managers” rather than “man managers”. They are adept at identifying markets for the
products their firms produce, locating sources of finance and exploring ways and means of
acquiring technology and know- how. They are though not at ease in organising labour and
managing the production process. In other words, Indian managers excel in establishing and
promoting service oriented firms and the services side of the business, including finance and
marketing, but the engineering and production side of the business is not their forte. As
Hirschman, the reputable development economist from Yale University put it “labour-
intensive technologies by their very nature require much more intensive organisation and
supervision than capital-intensive technologies” (Hirschman, 1959). Indian entrepreneurs
seem not to be very well endowed with the sort of skills required to manage and organize
labour intensive production processes. Added to this is the widespread and significant
presence of the labour unions in the manufacturing sector. These labour unions of differing
hues and political attachments add to the problems posed by the ineptitude of the
entrepreneurs in managing labour and thus labour intensive industries. Hence, the absence
of a large number of inherently labour intensive firms and the relatively high capital
intensity of the production process of most manufacturing firms in the organised
manufacturing sector.

Economic policies pursued during the first four decades post- independence seem to have
sustained and strengthened the factors inherited from history in shaping the structure of

6
the economy. The strategy of industrialisation advocated by India is first Prime Minister
Jawaharlal Nehru, seems to have inadvertently promoted the service sector in the economy.
The Nehruvian strategy, grounded in ideology, had industrialization at its core. In the words
of the Prime Minister “the problems of poverty and unemployment, of national defence and
of economic regeneration in general cannot be solved without industrialisation. As a step
towards such industrialisation, a comprehensive scheme of national planning should be
formulated. This scheme should provide for the development of heavy key industries,
medium scale industries and cottage industries”.

National regeneration was to be achieved through self- sufficiency in investment goods that
would in time produce consumer goods. Capital goods production requires technology and
expertise. This was to be acquired at home through the promotion of science and
engineering education. Towards this end, a number of higher education institutions were
set up, and they did yield the sort of human capital that was desired. The Indian Institutes of
Management (IIMs) and Institutes of Technology (IITs), that were set up during the decade
of the fifties, now number 19 and 17 respectively. According to the data published in the
Statistical Abstract of India, there were a total of 15,703 degree awarding institutions of
higher education in the country at the end of the year 2001-02. It is noteworthy that the IITs
and IIMs stand apart from other institutions in the quality of graduates they produce. Why
have not these institutions served to promote the manufacturing sector? How come that
the substantial output of human capital failed to promote manufacturing on a scale similar
to that achieved by China?

Surprising as it may seem, the number of engineering graduates the country produced was
surplus to requirements. The industrial strategy formulated during the decade of the mid-
fifties and the sixties was oriented towards capital-intensive large-scale firms and projects
that did not require the vast number of engineers and technicians. A substantial proportion
of the engineers were surplus to requirements. There were two outlets for the surplus of
engineering graduates, both a result of fortuitous circumstances. First, there was a
substantial demand for trained technicians generated by space research and defence in the
USA during the decade of the sixties and the seventies. The relaxation of immigration
regulations and constraints by the USA, during the decade of the seventies and eighties,

7
referred to as a policy based on ‘skills rather than skin’, provided a vent for the surplus
graduates India’ s economic policy had produced. Second, the birth of the information
technology industry in the USA and its swift growth absorbed much of India’s surplus of
engineering graduates. The Indian diaspora in the US are a factor of significance in the
growth of the software sector in India. Many of them returned home to establish software
firms, some of them to this day are back and forth migrants; they manage investments in
India with frequent visits. Most of the graduates that emigrated were products of the Indian
Institutes of Technology (IITs); those that stayed home had to seek jobs that were not cut
out for engineers. Software though seems to have provided an alternative
(Balasubramanyam & Balasubramanyam, 2000). The present day Software industry stands
out as a human capital-intensive service industry, developed by Indian engineers, without
much assistance from the government or the multinationals.

Apart from the supply side factors that have promoted the growth of the services sector in
the country, there are also demand side factors that have contributed to the growth of
services. Indeed, much of the analysis of structural changes in the economy incorporates
both supply and demand side explanations. In the Kuznets model, for instance, increased
inequalities in incomes following growth in productivity of agriculture and manufacturing
feeds the demand for services. The structural change the Indian economy has experienced,
however, differs from the sort of transformation based on growth of productivity in
agriculture suggested by Kuznets. The increased inequalities in incomes since liberalisation
are a factor of significance in the growth of expenditures on services. Whilst growth has
contributed to increased incomes of the upper and middle income groups, they have also
benefitted from the policies of liberalisation initiated in the year 1991. Gaurav Nayyar’s
(2008) study, based on household survey data on expenditures shows that, as household
expenditures increase, the budget share allocated to services in general and to education,
health and tourism in particular, increase considerably. The growth of services in the
economy is no wonder. It is grounded in historical factors, the socio economic structure of
the country in the past and in the post- independence Nehruvian economic policies.

8
4 Services – The Leading Sector of the Economy.
Whilst there are explanations for the growth of services in the Indian economy, the issue of
concern is - “can services lead the economy, both as a sector on its own and as a
complement to other sectors?” The criteria for a sector to be a leading sector are several. It
should be heterogenous, it should be grounded in the country’s factor endowments, it
should possess a high level of productivity, it should be a participant in the country’s
international trade and factor flows, it should possess strong demand and supply links with
other sectors in the economy and it should bestow on other sectors externalities in the form
of technology and knowhow. India’s services sector displays these and other characteristics
in good measure. It is worth emphasizing that most services are inputs into the production
process of other sectors. The contribution of services as inputs facilitates the growth of
productivity in the manufacturing and agriculture sectors.

Heterogeneity
A leading sector should consist of heterogeneous sub- sectors that cater to the needs of a
variety of producers and consumers. High tech manufacturing firms may require IT services
and sophisticated financial services; semi-skilled manufacturing firms benefit from
marketing and trade services and the country, as a whole requires defence, civil service and
education services. India’s services sector consists of a mix of services that can be broadly
grouped into three: First group, termed as public services, consists of education, health and
defence, the second group includes trade, transport and hotels, and the third group consists
of business services including banking and insurance, IT services such as software and
communication and legal services. All three groups have grown in step with the growth of
the country’s GNP; the fastest growing one is the third group that is much more human
capital intensive in the production process than the other two groups (Table 3).It is the third
group that has grown faster than the other two. It is this group that caters to the services
requirements of high technology oriented manufacturing firms. In general, India’s services
sector is heterogeneous and is capable of catering to a variety of requirements of a growing
economy.

9
Table 3: Composition of the Services Sector
Community Trade, Hotels Financing, Insurance, Total Value of
Social and Transport and Real Estate and Services
Personal Communications Business Services
(Million Rest)
Services

2011-12 25.84 35.60 38.56 39,700,250

2012-13 24.88C 36.06 39.06 43,008,200

2013-14 24.00 35.67 40.33 46,302,630

2014-15 23.67 35.46 40.87 50,776,110

2015-16 23.68 35.70 40.72 55,722,220

2016-17 23.80 35.71 40.47 600,359,600


(Estimate)

Source: Economic Survey 2016-17, Volume 2, Ministry of Finance, Government of India.

Grounding in the Factor Endowments of the Country


The sector, with all its sub sectors, should draw upon the factor endowments of the country,
if it were to achieve high levels of factor productivity and growth over time. The presence
and growth of the three groups, referred to earlier, reflects their grounding in the factor
endowments of the country. The first group draws upon its endowments of labour with
tertiary education, mostly in the social sciences. The second group draws upon semi- skilled
labour and business oriented entrepreneurs discussed earlier. The third group draws upon
the large number of engineering and science graduates produced by the tertiary education
system. The Proportion of people in the relevant age group with tertiary education in India
was, until recently, higher than that in China, with the reverse being the case for secondary
education (Barro R and Lee J, 2000). The third group, that consists of business services,
including software, owes its birth and growth to factors discussed earlier. It is the third
group of services, intensive in human capital that has grown substantially in recent years

10
(Table- 3). The pattern of employment also reflects the growth of human capital and
technology intensive services.

Whilst services as a whole account for 28 % of total employment, a share that exceeds that
of manufacturing, information and communication technology services (ICT) account for a
high proportion of employment in market oriented services (Table 4) India is an economy
endowed with labour, but its labour consists of both skilled and semi- skilled labour. As
Eichengreen and Gupta (2011) note, the mix of skilled and semi-skilled labour in India’s
services sector is much the same as in the manufacturing sector. The composition of India’s
services sector that consists of both a relatively skilled services sector and a semi-skilled one
suggests that the sector draws upon the factor endowments of the country. The reasons for
the relatively large services sector in the economy as opposed to a manufacturing sector
have been discussed in section 2 of the paper.

Table 4: Labour Employment share by Service Industries, 1980-2010


Description 1980 1990 2000 2010

Total services 16.94 20.03 23.69 28.20

Market services 9.12 11.84 15.27 17.99

ICT intensive services 6.43 8.35 10.73 12.42

Trade 5.80 7.35 9.16 9.79

Financial Services 0.31 0.51 0.58 0.90

Post and Telecommunication 0.14 0.18 0.34 0.40

Business Services 0.18 0.30 0.66 1.33

ICT non-intensive services 2.70 3.50 4.54 5.57

Hotels and Restaurants 0.80 0.92 1.18 1.47

Transport and Storage 1.90 2.58 3.37 4.10

Non-market services 7.81 8.18 8.42 10.21

11
Public Administration and Defence 2.75 2.85 2.49 2.00

Education 1.58 1.63 2.17 2.79

Health and Social Work 0.58 0.56 0.72 0.91

Other services 2.90 3.15 3.04 4.51

Source: Das Debkusum et al. (2016)

Growth in Productivity
The detailed empirical analysis of the growth in the productivity of the sector analysed by
Krishna et al. (2016), utilizing KLEMS data base, confirms that the sector as a whole has
experienced a substantial growth in productivity, though the extent of the growth differs
between groups. First, share of services in gross value added of GNP increased substantially
while that of manufacturing was almost flat since the late 1990s (Figure 2)

Figure 2: Share of Services and Manufacturing in Gross Value Added

Source Krishna et al (2016) Working Paper 261, Centre for Development Economics. Delhi
School of Economics

The growth rate of value added in services over the period 1980-2011, at 7.37 per annum,
exceeded that of manufacturing estimated at 6.49%. Over the same period growth rate of
employment in services, at 3.39 % per annum, exceeded that of manufacturing estimated at
1.92%. Second, over the period 1980-2011 labour productivity in the services sector as a

12
whole increased at 3.98 % per annum, with market services and ICT intensive services
registering an annual growth rate of 4.37 and 4.90 percent per annum. In the sub period
2003-2011 growth in labour productivity of the sector was even more impressive; it
registered a growth rate of 5.93% per annum with market services and ICT services
registering 7.81 and 8.67 percent growth in labour productivity per annum. Non-market
services including public administration, health and social work were lower down the table
of productivity growth registering a 3.22% growth over the period 1980-2011.

An observation of significance in Krishna et al’s (2016) empirical analysis of the growth of


the services sector is that the main contribution to labour productivity growth across sectors
is to be found in total factor productivity (TFP), not in the increased inputs of labour and
capital. The contribution of services especially information technology services to the
growth in TFP of the sector as a whole could be substantial. Yet another significant finding
of the study is that growth in output of the services sector is mostly due to capital
deepening. It is suggested that the liberalization of policies governing imports into the
country, implemented in the year 1991, contributed to capital deepening by facilitating the
importation capital equipment required by information technology producing and utilising
firms.

International Dimensions of the Sector


The contribution of services sector to India’s foreign exchange earnings is substantial. The
growth of exports of the sector is impressive, from $1 billion in the year 1980 to $154 billion
in the year 2016. In the year, 2016 services accounted for 38% of India’s total exports of $
426 billion. Share of India’s services exports in world trade in services increased from less
than 1% in the 1990s to 3.32% by the year 2016, most of which, around 70%, was
accounted for by information technology and business process outsourcing The major
markets for India’s IT exports include the USA followed by the UK and the EU. Raychaudri
and De’s (2012) empirical estimates of revealed comparative advantage (RCA) of India’s
services trade shows that exports of computer and information services RCA increased from
28.19 in the year 2001 to 31.66 by the year 2007, a significant achievement.

13
A detailed empirical study of India’s services exports (Sahoo and Dash 2016) shows that
besides demand side factors, supply side factors including telecom density, human capital ,
financial development , FDI and R and D expenditures have all had a strong impact on
exports of services. The study also finds that domestic services content of manufactured
exports is substantial.

Gupta and Eichengreen’s (2013) detailed empirical analysis of the impact of the real
exchange rates on exports of services , based on data for a cross section of 66 countries of
differing income levels for the period 1980-2009, finds the impact of real exchange rate
variations on exports of services especially modern services to be significant. Modern
services include computer services, financial intermediation m business and legal services.
The dependence of these services on imported materials is relatively low and the demand
for modern services is fairly price elastic. The study by Eichengreen and Gupta also shows
that exports have made a significant contribution to the growth of the services sector
especially that of the software firms.

Services also attract a substantial volume of FDI inflows into the country. As the Economic
survey of India puts it, “the Indian IT and business process outsourcing is a global
powerhouse today and its impact on India and the world has been unprecedented”. Services
also attract a substantial volume of FDI inflows into the country. In recent years inflows of
FDI into services has exceeded 50 percent of the total inflows (Table 5).

Table 5: Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) Inflows into the Services sector (Million $ and
Percentages)
2012-13 2013-14 2014-15 2015-16 2016-17
Total FDI Inflows 18,286 16,054 24,748 36,068 36,317
FDI in Manufacturing 6,528 6,381 9,613 8,439 11,972
FDI in Services 9,699 8,365 13,720 25,678 22,482
Services % of Total 54.8 52.1 55.4 71.5 61.9
Share of Business, Computer 9.1 34.85 43.06 37.64 50.4
& Financial Services in total
FDI in Services

14
Source: Annual Report, Reserve Bank of India, 2018.

In the year 2016-17 inflows of FDI into the services sector was 61% of a total inflow of $36
billion. It is of significance that the share of human capital- intensive services- financial
services, business services in total inflows of FDI into services has exceeded 10% in most
years (Table 5). The growing contribution of services to India’s exports and the attraction of
the services sector to foreign firms is yet another indicator of the ability of the sector to lead
the economy.

Interconnections with other sectors


The foremost criterion for a sector to be a leading sector is its interconnections with other
sectors and its contribution to their growth. There is adequate empirical evidence to
support the proposition that services complement manufactures and the concern that the
two are not related is fallacious.

An empirical exercise by Panagariya and Dehejia (2015) shows a link between


manufacturing and services. Growth of the manufacturing sector promotes the growth of
services through two channels: first through its increased demand for services- the so-called
direct effect, second through the demand for services induced by growth in incomes from
the growth of manufacturing, the so-called indirect effect. The analysis also suggests that
the indirect link is weak whilst the direct link is substantial for the large service firms.
Further, Panagariya and Deheija suggest that growth of manufacturing, especially so since
the year 1991, has promoted services. Whilst Panagariya and Dehija do not contribute to
the notion that services may not be able to lead the economy, they do not analyse the
impact of the growth of the services sector on manufacturing.

Banga and Goldar’s (2004) incisive econometric exercise confirms the contribution of
services to growth of output and productivity of the manufacturing sector, especially so
since the year 1990. They estimate a production function utilizing the KLEMS methodology
(Capital, Labour, Energy, Material and Services) and confirm that the contribution of services

15
to growth of manufacturing output increased considerably, from about one per cent in the
1980s to about 25 per cent in the 1990s.

Another detailed empirical study, (based on a set of reform indices) finds that India’s
reforms in the services sector have had a strong and significant impact on the productivity
of the manufacturing sector (Arnold et al 2014). Liberalisation of the banking and
telecommunications sector is reported to have had the strongest impact on the productivity
of the manufacturing sector.

The proximate impact of service inputs, especially the ICT services that analyse, transform
and transmit information including production methods to workers, is on the productivity of
labour. In this context, it is of significance that the wages paid to skilled workers has
increased considerably since the year 1980 whilst the number of skilled workers employed
shows little change (Figure3)

Figure 3: Changes in skill intensity and wages of skilled workers over the period 1981-2013
– All Industries

. a

Source: Authors’ calculations using data from Annual Survey of Industries data (2013-14)
Note: (i) Skilled workers= Total persons engaged- total number of workers.
(ii) Skilled Wages= Total Emoluments- Wages to workers

16
Number of Skilled workers in the year 1981=1788 thousand
Wages to Skilled workers= 23833 Million Rest

This suggests that the composition of the skilled workforce has changed over the years
reflecting the growth of IT experts who command relatively high wages. A study (Vashisht
and Dubey, 2018) on the composition of the workforce, or occupations as the study refers to,
suggests that the combined share of highly skilled occupations (managers, professionals and
associate professionals) in total employment was only 4.78 per cent in 1983, this increased to 13.41
per cent in 2011-12. Among highly skilled workers, the most staggering increase has been in the
share of managers. The share of managers in total employment went up from just 1.13 per cent in
1983 to 6.76 per cent in 2011- 12, registering a growth of roughly 500 per cent . The authors of this
empirical analysis of changes in the nature of occupations note that non-routine cognitive analytical
as well as the non-routine cognitive interactive task intensity of jobs has increased in India. Cognitive
tasks mostly consist of analysis of information and decision making, both of which utilise
information technology skills. These developments on the occupational structure of the labour force
have driven up wages of non- production workers relative to that of production workers (Figure 4)

Figure 4

These changes in the structure of occupations are bound to have an impact on the
productivity of the production process. Analysis of the impact of services on labour
prductivity reported below suggest as much. We estimate the impact of services on the
productivity of labour for the years 2001-02 to 2013-14 for a panel of 26 manufacturing

17
industries. We measure productivity of labour by the standard measure – output per labour
(O/L) and the efficiency wage defined as output per unit of total wage bill (O/W). Growth in
labour productivity would confer increased wages for the workers, but the measurement of
significance to entrepreneurs is the return per unit of wage. The efficiency wage measures
both the impact on productivity and associated wage increases of changes in the production
process. We use the ‘Principal Characteristics by Major Industry Group’ data obtained from
India’s Annual Survey of Industries (ASI). The data is disaggregated at the two digit National
Industrial (Activity) Classification (NIC). The estimated equations are:

In the above equations, O is the total output, L is total persons engaged (workers and
service personnel), W is the total emoluments (wages paid to all employees), S is the input
of services measured as the difference between total emoluments and wages to workers,

Table 6: Impact on Labour Productivity (O/L)


Fixed Effects (with
year dummies)
Ln (K/L) 0.2962**
(0.1152)
Ln (S/W) 0.7834**
(0.3181)
Constant 2.7351***
(0.3231)
R2 within 0.8264
R2 between 0.6340
R2 overall 0.6470
No. of observations 286

18
Note: (i) *** denotes significance at 1% level; ** denotes significance at 5% level; (ii)
Parentheses give standard errors – robust to heteroskedasticity.

Table 7: Impact on Efficiency wage (O/W)

Fixed Effects (with


year dummies)
Ln (K/L) 0.1697
(0.1041)
Ln (S/W) 0.4891***
(0.1520)
Constant 3.0979***
(0.2450)
R2 within 0.2595
R2 between 0.0972
R2 overall 0.1116
No. of observations 286
Note: (i) *** denotes significance at 1% level; (ii) Parentheses give standard errors – robust
to heteroskedasticity.

The estimated equations show that service inputs do have a significant impact on labour
productivity but a positive but relatively low impact on output per unit of wages. These
results suggest that whilst services do contribute to the growth in productivity of the
manufacturing sector their growth also increases the wage bill as is to be expected. In
general, the services sector satisfies most of the criteria required for it to be a leading
sector. However, for it to be effective in promoting employment in both the organised and
unorganised sectors, policy makers should facilitate the effective utilisation of services in
both manufacturing and agriculture.

19
It is essential to keep in mind the obvious fact that most, though not all, services are inputs
and not final products. This is especially so in the case of business services that includes
finance, insurance and the IT services. The effective utilisation of the inputs to produce final
goods and services is the central task facing policy makers. The response to the PM’s Call
“Make in India” requires the utilisation of the services sector inputs to produce final goods
that reflect the country’s endowments of human capital-intensive services.

It is encouraging to note that the model we advocate, though in its infancy, is gathering
momentum. Manufacturers of motor cars in Tamil Nadu are moving the production of parts
and components of industries to rural areas. In these cases, the utilisation of computer
technology facilitates the training of rural labour. It is of interest that an empirical study of
urbanisation of industry, across states in India, finds that there is a movement of plants in
formal manufacturing to rural areas, whilst informal sector firms are moving into urban
areas (Ghani et al., 2012). Some of these clusters, in Tamil Nadu with its significant industrial
sector, are well known: Sivakasi for safety matches, firecrackers and printing; Karur, Erode
and Salem for power looms and home textiles; Tirupur for knitted garments. Farming
communities in these locations have built these clusters with investments of agricultural
surpluses. The contribution of services such as finance and transport in the formation of
these clusters is likely to be considerable. The study by Eichengreen and Gupta (2011) cited
earlier notes that modern service sector jobs are migrating from urban centres to small
towns and rural areas creating employment for semi-skilled workers who are numerate and
literate.

5. Conclusion
The structure of the Indian economy, with services as the major sector contributing to
national income, are to be traced to India’s economic history, its emphasis on tertiary
education and the nature of the institutions that have facilitated the growth of services. The
paper also argues that services can be effectively utilised to promote both growth and
development in the economy. Itis not suggested that India should abandon or accord
manufacturing a secondary status. It is just that India is fortunate in possessing a services
sector that is capable of promoting efficiency and growth in both manufacturing and
agriculture. It is to be noted that the services sector, especially the ICT industry, though

20
buoyant is yet in its infancy. Its enormous potential for growth should be exploited with
appropriate policies including education and trade and FDI. The Historian Ramachandra
Guha’s observation that the highly diverse country is held together by Cricket, the English
language and Lata Mangeshkar (popular background singer from Bollywood), captures the
significance of services in India.

21
References
Arnold Jens Matthias, Javorcik Beata, Lipscomb Molly and Aaditya Mattoo (2014). “Services
Reform and Manufacturing Performance: Evidence from India”, The Economic Journal, Vol.
126, pp. 1-39.

Ark, B.V., Inklaar, R. and McGuckin, R.H. (2002). “Changing Gear Productivity, ICT and
Services Industries: Europe and the United States”, Economics Program Working Paper
Series #02, the Conference Board.

Balasubramanyam, V.N. and Balasubramanyam, A. (2000). “The Software Cluster in


Bangalore”, in Regions, Globalization and the Knowledge-Based Economy, Dunning J (ed.),
Oxford University Press, Oxford.

Barro, R and Lee, J. (2000). “International Data on Educational Attainment; Updates and
Implications”, Centre for International Studies, Working Paper number 42, Harvard
University.

Banga, R. and Goldar, B. (2004). “Contribution of services to output growth and productivity
in Indian Manufacturing; Pre and Post Reforms”, Working paper 139, Indian Council for
Research in International Relations, New Delhi.

Bhagwati, J. N. (2004). “Splintering and Disembodiment of Services and Developing


Nations”, The World Economy, June.

Damodaran, H. (2008). “India’s New Capitalists”, Permanent Black in collaboration with New
India Foundation.

Das Debkusum, Erumbau Abdul, Suresh Aggarwal, Pilai Chandradas (2015). “Productivity
Dynamics in India’s Service Sector: An Industry level Perspective”, KLEMS Project, Delhi
School of Economics.

22
Eichengreen, B. and Gupta, P. (2009). “Two Waves of Services Sector Growth”, Working
Paper Number 235, Indian Council for Research on International Economic Relations.

Eichengreen, B. and Gupta, P. (2011). “The Service Sector as India’s Road to Economic
Growth”, Working Paper number 16757, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Eichengreen B and Gupta P (2013). “The real Exchange rate and Export Growth; Are
Services Different” , Policy Research Working Paper, World bank Group.

Hill, T.P. (1977). “On Goods and Services”, Review of Income and Wealth, Vol. 23 no 4 pp.
315-338.

Hirschman, A. (1959). “Strategy of Economic Development”, Yale University Press.

India Brand Equity Foundation (2012). “Role of Manufacturing in Employment Generation in


India”, New Delhi.

Krishna K L, Deb Kusum Das, Abdul A Erumban, Suresh AggarwalL, Pilu Chandra Das, (2016).
“Productivity Dynamics in India’s Services Sector; An Industry Level Perspective”, Working
Paper No. 261, Centre for Development Economics, Delhi School of Economics, Delhi.

Kuznets Simon (1995). “Economic Growth and Inequality”, American Economic Review, Vol.
45(1) pp. 1 -28.

Moriki Ohara and Koichiro Kimura, (2010). “Automobile Industry in India: Emerging Conflicts
between Scale and Scope” in Industrial Development in China and India: Comparison of the
Clusters and Firms Institute of Developing Economies (IDE-JETRO), Japan.

Nayyar Gaurav (2009). “The Demand for Services in India; A Mirror Image of Engles Law For
Food”, Discussion Paper number 451,Department of Economics, Oxford University.

23
Nayyar, Gaurav (2014). “The Services Sector in India’s Development”, Cambridge University
Press.

Panagariya Arvind and Daheja (2015). “The Link between Manufacturing Growth and
accelerated services in India”, Economic Development and Cultural Change, November,
64(2).

Raychaudri and Dey Roy, T. (2011). “The Economic History of India, 1757-2010”, Third
Edition, Oxford University Press.

Roy, S. (2010). “Automobile Industry in India: Emerging Conflicts between Scale and Scope”
in Industrial Development in China and India: Comparison of the Clusters and Firms (eds.)
Moriki Ohara and Koichiro Kimura, Institute of Developing Economies (IDE-JETRO), Japan.

Sahoo Pravakar and Dash Ranjan Kumar (2016). “What Drives India’s Surge in Services
Exports”, The World Economy, Vol. 40, Issue 2.

Upadhya, C. (2004). “A New Transnational Capitalist Class? Capital Flows, Business Networks
and Entrepreneurs in the Indian Software Industry”, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol.
39(48), pp. 5141-5151.

24

You might also like