29 4540 Sample
29 4540 Sample
Contents
1 Introduction to the Module 2
2 Study Resources 3
3 Learning Outcomes 4
4 Study Advice 4
5 Module Overview 5
International Finance
2 University of London
Specimen Examination
2 Study Resources
This study guide is your central learning resource, it structures your learn-
ing unit by unit. Each unit should be studied within a week. It is designed in
the expectation that studying each unit and the associated readings will re-
quire 15 to 20 hours per week, but this will vary according to your
background knowledge and experience of studying.
Key text
The key text for this module is:
Keith Pilbeam (2013) International Finance. 4th Edition. Basingstoke UK:
Palgrave Macmillan.
This is a standard, good, modern textbook that gives a clear exposition of the
main theoretical, institutional and policy issues taught in this module. I will
refer to it simply as Pilbeam from now on.
Throughout this module, I will introduce you to the topic of each unit, set out
the main questions and direct you to the sections and chapters of Pilbeam
that deal with the material you are studying. I will explain concepts in
Pilbeam that appear difficult, and discuss with you the conclusions you could
draw from your reading. In some units, I will refer to articles instead of
Pilbeam or in addition to that text.
Module readings
You are also provided with some academic articles and other reports, which
are assigned as readings in the study guide. You are expected to read them
as an essential part of the module although you will find that some aca-
demic articles range more widely than the study guide or use more
advanced techniques and have a greater level of conceptual difficulty than
the textbook. That is the nature of academic articles, but I have selected arti-
cles and reports whose main arguments can be understood and appreciated
at the level appropriate to this module.
3 Learning Outcomes
When you have completed this module, you will be able to do the following:
• outline the decline of Bretton Woods and the rise of the Flexible
Exchange Rate Regime, 1973 to the present
• analyse and discuss fixed versus flexible exchange rate regimes
• explain the difference between hedging, arbitrage and speculation and
the interaction of hedgers, arbitrageurs and speculators
• discuss the parity relationships between spot and future exchange
rates
• demonstrate how a balance of payments is constructed with a series of
transactions, and show how transactions are recorded
• explain how the national income framework and elasticities
framework can be linked to the absorption framework.
• discuss the policy problem the Mundell–Fleming model is designed to
address, and the historical circumstances that made it relevant
• differentiate between the assumptions of the Polak model and those of
the Mundell–Fleming model
• assess the strengths and weaknesses of the monetary approach
• relate the traditional arguments for and against fixed and floating
exchange rates
• explain the rationale behind discretionary intervention in the foreign
exchange market
• give an account of the development of the European Monetary System
and the European Monetary Union.
4 Study Advice
The module units (or ‘study guide’) serve much as a lecture in a conven-
tional university setting, introducing you to the literature of the subject
under study and helping you to identify the core message of each reading
you are assigned. As you work through the units, you should study the
readings as suggested and answer the questions set. Where you are already
4 University of London
Specimen Examination
familiar with the particular topic introduced, you may find that skim-read-
ing is sufficient, as long as you can answer the relevant questions.
The objectives of each unit are set out in the introductory section of each unit,
and it’s a good idea to review these when you have finished that unit’s work
to make sure that you can indeed complete each task suggested. These are the
sorts of issues you are likely to meet in examination questions and your ability
to write on them should set you up well for success in the module.
You should always read your module materials critically and evaluate care-
fully the strengths and weaknesses of economic models that are being
presented. Remember that no model is perfect in its attempt to explain a par-
ticular aspect of economic behaviour. Train yourself, therefore, to adopt a
critical approach to all your module material, including these units.
During the scheduled weeks of the module, you must complete two assign-
ments in which you will be asked to write essays. The essays will be marked
by your tutor in London, who will send you detailed comments and advice.
The grades on your two assignments will account for 30% of your final mod-
ule grade. To complete the module, you will take an examination, according
to the University of London examination schedule, which will account for the
remaining 70% of your total module grade.
Please keep in mind that your essays, examination and study of the module
should reflect its principal themes and ways of reasoning. I hope that, by the
end of your study of the module, you will be able to
• identify and clearly define significant policy problems
• use an appropriate theoretical model to analyse policy problems
• and, when necessary, place the argument in the context of the
institutional setting.
The best marks will be awarded for essays and examination answers that in-
clude these elements. Moreover, we will give great weight to the use you
make of theoretical models in your essays. Recall that models presented in
diagrams or equations are usually the clearest. Your work in each unit will
be organised around one or two thematic questions relating to that unit.
The overall, broad question, which runs through the module as a whole, is:
• What policies and strategies can countries adopt to solve international
financial problems, and what are their strengths and weaknesses?
5 Module Overview
Unit 1 Evolution of International Financial Systems
1.1 Introduction to Unit 1
1.2 Bimetallism – before 1879
1.3 Classical Gold Standard – 1879–1914
1.4 The Interwar Period – 1914–1944
1.5 The Bretton Woods System – 1945–1972
6 University of London
Specimen Examination
Definitions
Some questions mainly require you to show that you have learned some concepts by setting
out their precise meanings. Such questions are likely to be preliminary and will be
supplemented by more analytical questions. Generally, ‘Pass marks’ are awarded if the answer
only contains definitions. These questions will contain words such as:
describe contrast
define write notes on
examine outline
distinguish between what is meant by
compare list.
Reasoning
Other questions are designed to test your reasoning, by asking you to explain cause and effect.
Convincing explanations generally carry more marks than basic definitions. These questions
will include words such as:
interpret
explain
what conditions influence
what are the consequences of
what are the implications of.
Judgement
Others ask you to make a judgement, perhaps of a policy or a course of action. They will
include words like:
evaluate
critically examine
assess
do you agree that
to what extent does.
Calculation
Sometimes you are asked to make a calculation using a specified technique; these questions
begin:
use indifference curve analysis to
using any economic model you know
calculate the standard deviation
test whether.
It is most likely that questions that ask you to make a calculation will also ask for an
application or interpretation of the result.
Advice
Other questions ask you to provide advice in a particular situation. This applies to law
questions and to policy papers where advice is asked in relation to a policy problem. Your
advice should be based on relevant law, applicable principles, and evidence of what actions
are likely to be effective. The questions may begin:
advise
provide advice on
explain how you would advise.
Critique
In many cases the question will include the word ‘critically’. This means that you are expected
to look at the question from at least two points of view, offering a critique of each view and
your judgement. You are expected to be critical of what you have read.
The questions may begin:
critically analyse
critically consider
critically assess
critically discuss the argument that.
Examine by argument
Questions that begin with ‘discuss’ are similar; they ask you to examine by argument, to
debate and give reasons for and against a variety of options. For example:
discuss the advantages and disadvantages of
discuss this statement
discuss the view that
discuss the arguments and debates concerning.
70–79 (Distinction). A mark in the range 70–79 will fulfil the following criteria:
• significant ability to plan, organise and execute independently a research
project or coursework assignment
• clear evidence of wide and relevant reading, referencing and an
engagement with the conceptual issues
• capacity to develop a sophisticated and intelligent argument
• rigorous use and a sophisticated understanding of relevant source
materials, balancing appropriately between factual detail and key
theoretical issues. Materials are evaluated directly, and their assumptions
and arguments challenged and/or appraised
• correct referencing
• significant ability to analyse data critically
• original thinking and a willingness to take risks.
60–69 (Merit). A mark in the 60–69 range will fulfil the following criteria:
• ability to plan, organise and execute independently a research project or
coursework assignment
• strong evidence of critical insight and thinking
• a detailed understanding of the major factual and/or theoretical issues and
direct engagement with the relevant literature on the topic
• clear evidence of planning and appropriate choice of sources and
methodology with correct referencing
• ability to analyse data critically
• capacity to develop a focused and clear argument and articulate clearly and
convincingly a sustained train of logical thought.
50–59 (Pass). A mark in the range 50–59 will fulfil the following criteria:
• ability to plan, organise and execute a research project or coursework
assignment
• a reasonable understanding of the major factual and/or theoretical issues
involved
• evidence of some knowledge of the literature with correct referencing
• ability to analyse data
• examples of a clear train of thought or argument
• the text is introduced and concludes appropriately.
70–79 (Distinction). A mark in the 70–79 range will fulfil the following criteria:
• clear evidence of wide and relevant reading and an engagement with the
conceptual issues
• development of a sophisticated and intelligent argument
• rigorous use and a sophisticated understanding of relevant source
materials, balancing appropriately between factual detail and key
theoretical issues
• direct evaluation of materials, and challenging and/or appraisal of their
assumptions and arguments
• original thinking and a willingness to take risks
• significant ability of synthesis under exam pressure.
60–69 (Merit). A mark in the 60–69 range will fulfil the following criteria:
• strong evidence of critical insight and critical thinking
• a detailed understanding of the major factual and/or theoretical issues and
direct engagement with the relevant literature on the topic
• development of a focused and clear argument, with clear and convincing
articulation of a sustained train of logical thought
• clear evidence of planning and appropriate choice of sources and
methodology, and ability of synthesis under exam pressure.
50–59 (Pass). A mark in the 50–59 range will fulfil the following criteria:
• a reasonable understanding of the major factual and/or theoretical issues
involved
• evidence of planning and selection from appropriate sources
• some demonstrable knowledge of the literature
• the text shows, in places, examples of a clear train of thought or argument
• the text is introduced and concludes appropriately.
UNIVERSITY OF LONDON
MSc Examination
Postgraduate Diploma Examination
for External Students
91DFM C229
91DFM C329
FINANCE (BANKING)
FINANCE (ECONOMIC POLICY)
FINANCE (FINANCIAL SECTOR MANAGEMENT)
FINANCE (QUANTITATIVE FINANCE)
International Finance
Specimen Examination
This is a specimen examination paper designed to show you the type of examination you will
have at the end of the year for International Finance. The number of questions and the
structure of the examination will be the same but the wording and the requirements of each
question will be different. Best wishes for success in your final examination.
The examiners give equal weight to each question; therefore, you are advised to
distribute your time approximately equally over three questions. The examiners wish
to see evidence of your ability to use technical models and of your ability to
critically discuss their mechanisms and application.
Section A
Answer at least ONE question from this section.
Section B
Answer at least ONE question from this section.
8. Answer either
In the light of a theory of capital flight from less developed
countries, discuss policies that could reverse it.
or
‘The absorption approach assumes that expenditure switching
policies such as devaluation cause an expansion of national
output, but in less developed countries devaluation may cause
a contraction.’ Explain and discuss that statement.
[END OF EXAMINATION]
Contents
Unit Overview 2
1.1 Introduction 3
1.9 Conclusion 18
References 18
International Finance
Unit Overview
One of the main learning objectives in this unit is to begin to analyse the
evolution of today’s international monetary system. In Unit 1, you will
examine the major operating principles, or ‘rules of the game’, of alternative
international monetary agreements and arrangements. You will see how the
rules of the game for the classical gold standard and the Bretton Woods
system for pegged exchange rates have operated in practice, whereby the
Bretton Woods system evolved into a US dollar standard. You will also
study the reasons advanced for the decline of Bretton Woods, and the
emergence of the Latin American debt crisis of the 1980s. Later in the mod-
ule, in Unit 8, you will return to the analysis of the evolution of the
international financial system following two major crises – the Asian Finan-
cial Crisis of 1997 and the severe global financial crisis beginning in 2007–08.
However, this first unit introduces and contextualises basic concepts and
issues relevant to the international monetary system and thus sets the scene
for your understanding of the models and approaches to analysing its
elements and its operation, in subsequent units.
Meantime, the overall question, which is the main learning objective of this
unit, may be expressed as follows:
• Under the Bretton Woods system, was international finance regulated
by public institutions rather than markets, and did the development of
the Eurodollar system reverse the situation to one in which markets
operated without regulation?
Learning outcomes
When you have completed your study of this unit and its readings, you will
be able to:
• relate how the international economy fared under bimetallism, before
1879
• account for the establishment of the classical gold standard, 1879–1914
• discuss the decline of world trade during the Interwar Period, 1915–44
• detail the creation of the Bretton Woods System, 1945–1972
• outline the decline of Bretton Woods and the rise of the Flexible
Exchange Rate Regime, 1973 to the present
• assess the influence of the Floating-Rate Dollar Standard, 1973–1984
• explain and discuss the Plaza-Louvre International Accords and the
Floating-Rate Dollar Standard, 1985–1996
• discuss the current exchange rate arrangements
• explain the international response to the Mexican Peso Crisis
• analyse and discuss fixed versus flexible exchange rate regimes.
2 University of London
Unit 1 Evolution of International Financial Systems
1.1 Introduction
As noted in the introduction to this module, in exploring problems of policy
within the international financial system, you need to understand the
institutional structure of modern international finance. In Unit 1, you will
learn about specific institutional structures and organisations such as the
International Monetary Fund (IMF), which is a highly specific executive
organisation that has been at the centre of the system.
Pilbeam (2013)
Reading 1.1 ‘Introduction: The
subject matter of
To put Unit 1 in context, please stop now and read quickly pages xxvi–xxviii of the key international finance’ in
International Finance.
text by Pilbeam, which gives a brief overview of the subject matter of international pp. xxvi–xxviii.
finance.
Foreign exchange markets and institutions, such as the IMF, are the frame-
work within which most of today’s policy problems in international finance
have to be considered. However, their present character is not accidental,
nor it is unchanging; but it is, instead, the result of historical developments.
Consequently, in order to fully understand the system, its problems and
policy options, we have to consider how it was formed and how it has
developed. This is the subject matter of this unit – the development of the
modern system of international finance from 1944 to the present (though we
shall return to consider further how crises in the late 20th and early 21st
century may have affected international monetary arrangements). Unit 2
then examines the system’s universal, basic, market institution – the foreign
exchange market – in general terms.
In this unit you will be introduced to the following main concepts:
• the Bretton Woods system
• the Eurodollar system (and other Eurocurrencies)
• the Latin American debt crisis
• fixed exchange rate system
• floating exchange rate system.
At the end of the unit, you should pause to check whether you have under-
stood all of them.
The unit summary page, which appears at the beginning of this text, shows a
more complete list of topics and issues that you will be learning during your
study of this unit. However, you are not expected to learn only by absorbing
information; instead, I expect you to question the ideas presented to you and to
read the module materials critically. At the start of each unit, I will set out the
main questions posed in it; keep these questions in mind as you read the
material and, at the end, consider your own answers to them.
However, let me reiterate the overall question, which is the main learning
objective of this unit:
• Under the Bretton Woods system, was international finance regulated
by public institutions rather than markets, and did the development of
the Eurodollar system reverse the situation to one in which markets
operated without regulation?
4 University of London
Unit 1 Evolution of International Financial Systems
equal to the country’s stock of gold (an assumption which was never exactly
valid but does simplify the analysis). Suppose that Britain is in the fortunate
position of having full employment, a stable price level and equality be-
tween exports and imports. Now imagine that for some reason British
imports increase without a change in British exports, and a balance of
payment deficit occurs. Under the gold standard, the deficit on the current
account of the balance of payments is temporary and self-correcting. The
deficit leads to an outflow of gold to pay for the net imports, and hence the
domestic money supply is reduced by an equal amount.
The reduction in the supply of money would lead to a fall in the domestic
price level according to the Quantity Theory of Money. This theory states
that MV = PT so that, with constant V and T (the Velocity of money and
Transactions), the reduction in M (the money supply) is matched by the
reduction in P (the price level). The fall in the domestic price level makes
home produced goods relatively cheap compared to foreign produced goods
and, therefore, imports will fall and exports rise. The process will continue
until the current account of the balance of payments is restored to balance
and the outflow of gold is halted. This adjustment mechanism is usually
known as the ‘price-specie–flow mechanism’, which is attributed to the 18th
century Scottish philosopher, David Hume.
In reality, the gold standard did not operate with such simple consistency,
and during the 19th century and early 20th century, politicians and econo-
mists were confronted by major difficulties over how to operate it and, in the
20th century, even over whether to adhere to the gold standard at all.
The debate of the early 19th century focused on the way the domestic money
supply worked if the currency was ‘inconvertible’, or separated from the
stock of gold, and upon the operation of the banking system. Those debates,
which became known as the ‘debate between the banking and currency
schools’, were among the most important debates of all time in monetary
theory, and have many modern parallels in theories of banking and financial
innovations, which you will probably meet in your later studies. Here,
however, I shall concentrate on the practical problems of the gold standard in
the 20th century, which are more relevant to your study of the evolution of
the modern system of international finance.
In the 19th century, the gold standard took a form best known as the ‘gold
exchange standard’. The stock of money in the country was not equal to the
stock of gold, and gold was not the only or main form of money used in
international transactions. In particular, the pound sterling developed into a
‘key currency’ as it was used to finance international trade, and it was held
as an international asset in the portfolios of foreign banks, central banks and
investors. Pounds were used for these purposes instead of gold, but the
pound was able to operate in this way because it was convertible into gold
at a fixed price. The system whereby sterling as a key currency was linked to
gold and exchangeable for the metal was known as the gold exchange stand-
ard. Its operation was more complex than the mechanism described by
Hume, but its underlying principle, the link between domestic price and
holdings of gold-backed money, was supposed to be the same.
In summary, the ‘rules of the game’ for the international gold exchange
standard were as follows:
• the establishment of an official gold price or ‘mint parity’ – for
example, the United States defined one US$ as 23.22 fine grains of
gold, equivalent to US$ 20.67 for one ounce of gold, when adopted as
the gold standard in 1879
• no restrictions could be placed on the imports or exports of gold
• only gold-backed national currency and coins were to be issued
• thus, price levels will be determined endogenously, based on the
world demand for gold.
6 University of London
Unit 1 Evolution of International Financial Systems
solve their balance of payments problems. For example, tariffs were raised
to reduce imports. Thus, the end of the gold standard was an element in a
period of shrinking world trade, with declining world markets for industrial
and agricultural products and rising unemployment in the major economies.
In 1939, at the outbreak of the Second World War, the existing system of
international finance and international trade broke down and was replaced
by one which could not really be called an international system. During the
following years, when each industrialised country was concentrating mainly
on fighting the war, the small amount of trade and remuneration that
existed was organised on the basis of bilateral deals organised by govern-
ments. These deals, in turn, reflected the balance of political power between
countries instead of being on equal or purely economic terms. In other
words, during the war the system of international finance broke down, and
arrangements constructed at the end of the war provided the beginning of
the modern system.
I would like you to pause for a moment to consider those questions, and write down
brief answers.
The way I would answer those questions is first to identify what the prob-
lem is: why are they serious questions? Why don’t governments simply give
an order that each exchange rate and the gold value of the US dollar should
be at a certain level? Then there would be no serious question to answer. The
reason the problem is serious can be seen by imagining what would happen
if, starting from a position of equilibrium on foreign exchange markets, there
is a fall in firms’ and banks’ demand for a currency or an increase in the
numbers of people wishing to sell it. The exchange rate of that currency
would fall as foreign exchange dealers mark it down on foreign exchange
markets. Similarly, if there is an increase in the demand for gold without an
increase in its supply, its price on the gold market will rise.
The second step is to identify how governments can prevent these changes
in exchange rates or the price of gold. The mechanism is to commit them to
buy or sell each currency at the fixed exchange rate; if there is an excess
private supply of pounds and an excess private demand for dollars, gov-
ernments must buy pounds and sell dollars at the fixed exchange rate to
equilibrate the market at that rate. Similarly, the US government had to be
willing always to sell (or buy) gold at the price of US$35 per ounce.
8 University of London
Unit 1 Evolution of International Financial Systems
discussion above:
What was the main source of IMF funds, and what qualifications and conditions
constrained the right to borrow under the IMF?
As you read in Pilbeam, the basic source of the IMF’s funds was the ‘quota’,
which each country subscribed to the Fund when it joined. The amount of a
country’s quota was calculated by a general formula agreed at Bretton
Woods. When a country joined the IMF it had to deposit 25% of its quota in
the form of gold and foreign exchange and 75% in the form of its own
currency. The country with the largest quota was the United States, which
remained the largest single source of the IMF’s funds throughout the dura-
tion of the Bretton Woods System. The quota system makes clear that the
IMF is not a bank; it cannot increase its resources by borrowing on capital
markets or money markets as a bank could (and as the World Bank can). In
principle, it is a club, for its basic resources come from the subscriptions
(quotas) of its members. As I have already indicated, those quotas also
determine the countries’ borrowing rights; the total amounts a country can
borrow under various headings are expressed as percentages of its quota
(and are more than 100%in total).
In answer to the second half of the question, two types of qualifications and
conditions on the right to borrow have been relevant.
The first, embodied in the initial principles of the Bretton Woods System,
was the distinction between a deficit considered to be a temporary disequilib-
rium and one that was judged to be a fundamental disequilibrium. In the case
of a temporary disequilibrium, it was expected that the country would
maintain its exchange rate and borrow foreign exchange from the IMF to
finance that intervention. But in the case of a fundamental disequilibrium,
the country would have to agree a realignment of exchange rates with the
IMF and accept a lower exchange rate that could overcome the deficit, and
borrowing would be subordinate to that policy.
The second type of condition for borrowing from the IMF is the requirement
that the country must adopt a stabilisation programme or, in other words, a
number of measures to improve the balance of payments and achieve
macroeconomic stability. A stabilisation programme includes more
measures than devaluation alone, for within such programmes states agree
to implement a number of restrictive monetary, fiscal and other policies.
This ‘conditionality’ applies when a country borrows more than a certain
amount. The gold tranche is an amount of credit, equal to 25% of the coun-
try’s quota, which could be borrowed without conditionality; the next 25%
of the quota, first credit tranche, could be borrowed with light conditions, but
higher amounts of credit, the upper credit tranches, could only be drawn upon
if the country agreed a stabilisation programme.
Conditionality in the form of stabilisation programmes is operated through
agreements to ‘stand-by arrangements’. The structure and operation of this
conditionality now follows almost standardised procedures which are an
integral part of the modern International Monetary Fund, but it was not always
so. Conditionality of this type was not established at Bretton Woods but
evolved gradually in the 1950s and 1960s. In Unit 2, you will study in greater
detail how stand-by arrangements and stabilisation programmes work.
10 University of London
Unit 1 Evolution of International Financial Systems
Bearing in mind that a major concern under the Bretton Woods System was whether
the stock of US dollars was a sound basis for an adequate growth of world liquidity,
make notes on the various alternatives proposed.
12 University of London
Unit 1 Evolution of International Financial Systems
market. This coordinated intervention was a clear signal of a new era influencing
foreign exchange markets. In anticipation of the dollar’s falling too far, the G-5
plus Canada and Italy (the G-7) made another attempt, in a meeting held at
the Louvre in Paris in 1987, to foster stability of exchange rates around their
target zones, although the zonal boundaries remained secret. However, the
Louvre Accord created what is known as the managed-float system.
Since June 2009, 69 countries, including the United States, the UK, Japan and
Canada, have independently adopted floating systems without pegging; a
majority of countries, including China, have accepted some form of ‘man-
aged-floating’ system, which combines market forces and government
controls. EMU members have adopted the Euro as a currency which floats
against other currencies externally. For details of individual countries’ ex-
change arrangements, study Pilbeam’s Table 11.9, on pages 286–87.
Pilbeam (2013) Section
Reading 1.6 11.22 ‘Conclusions’ from
Chapter 11 ‘The
Turn now to Pilbeam’s conclusions on the Bretton Woods era, the final section of Chapter international monetary
system’ in International
11 ‘The international monetary system’ on pages 296–97. Finance. pp. 296–97.
financial system. Eurodollar deposits and loans are truly international forms
of money and finance in a way that previous monetary and financial in-
struments were not.
That international character of Eurodollars can be seen from the definition of a
Eurodollar bank deposit. It is a deposit of US dollars held in a bank outside the
United States. Today, it may be physically in the United States, but held in an
‘international banking facility’, which is effectively outside that country
because it is exempt from the controls over ‘normal’ dollar accounts in the US.
The rapid growth of Eurodollar deposits held in banks in London and else-
where from 1973 was accompanied by new forms of bank lending by the
Eurobanks. From 1973 to 1982, they greatly expanded their loans of Eurodol-
lars to a group of third world countries, most prominently Brazil and
Mexico. These loans were sovereign loans (general credits to states rather
than to companies) and their growth was based on the development of new
lending techniques. These new techniques were crystallised in syndicated
loans with variable interest rates linked to LIBOR, the London InterBank
Offer Rate.
However, sovereign loans from banks to Third World countries are not the
only form of Eurodollar credits. Eurodollar loans from banks to large United
States and British companies to finance take-over activity became especially
important after 1982. And Eurodollar finance in the form of marketable
bonds instead of bank loans also grew in relative importance in the 1980s.
These provide some indication of the permanent change in international
finance created by the development of Eurodollars, but have Eurodollars
had wider effects on methods of banking and credit?
From the point of view of bank liabilities, the Eurodollar deposit in a bank is
at the base of the system and this has raised the question of whether these
deposits represent a net creation of new money. To what extent do Eurodol-
lars increase the stock of international money?
Pilbeam (2013) Chapter
Reading 1.7 12 ‘The Eurocurrency
and Eurobond markets’
I would like you now to read the whole of Chapter 12, pages 298–316, of Pilbeam. in International Finance.
pp. 298–316.
While you read it, I would like you to keep in mind those two questions and write
brief answers to them as you complete the reading:
what effects has the Eurodollar system had on the development of banks and
credit?
what is the relationship between Eurodollar banking and the stock of money?
14 University of London
Unit 1 Evolution of International Financial Systems
apparent from early 1982, but the real signal of its beginning was Mexico’s
declaration on 12 August 1982 that it could not meet its debt repayments.
Pilbeam discusses this international debt crisis in his Chapter 15. A good
discussion of the background to the debt crisis, including its origins and
emergence and the Mexican moratorium, is introduced in Sections 15.7 to
15.10. A good account of the definition of low- and middle-income develop-
ing countries, their typical financial characteristics and the measures of
indebtedness is also provided in the first sections of that chapter, which you
may read if you are interested in economic development.
Pilbeam (2013) Sections
Reading 1.8 15.7–15.10 from
Chapter 15 ‘The Latin
Please be sure to read now Sections 15.7 to 15.10 of Chapter 15 ‘The Latin American American debt crisis’ in
International Finance.
debt crisis’, pages 377–82, of Pilbeam. pp. 377–82; 370–77.
I think the problems created by the outbreak of the debt crisis and the way
the international financial community dealt with the problems and over-
came them represent a new, third, stage in the evolution of the modern
system of international finance. To understand the system of international
finance from the 1990s it is necessary, I think, to examine how the debt crisis
evolved in the previous decade. Let me identify two aspects that I think
were key.
One is that, as it faced the 1982 debt crisis of Mexico, the International
Monetary Fund linked its willingness to lend to Mexico with the willingness
of private banks to extend their lending to Mexico. Since that time, private
bank lending to less developed countries and lending by the International
Monetary Fund (and World Bank) have been explicitly linked. That is in
contrast to the earlier stages of the modern international system. Under the
arrangements established at Bretton Woods, it was envisaged that the
International Monetary Fund, as an official body of member states, would
stand above the banking system and, in the view of some, counteract its
operations on international money markets; but in the 1980s a partnership
was explicitly recognised.
On their part, before 1982, the banks generally preferred borrowers to have
an IMF stabilisation programme in place, but in those early days there were
major examples, such as Brazil, where the banks loaned money without an
IMF programme. After 1982, the precondition for all new or rescheduled
sovereign lending was an IMF programme. The new connection between
private banks and the IMF (and the World Bank) reached its peak with the
Baker Plan – a plan for solving the Latin American debt crisis, which was
promulgated by the US Secretary of the Treasury in October 1985.
A second key effect of that debt crisis on the international financial system
was that the banking system developed a different approach to risky loans. In
the popular view, and the view of bankers and economists in earlier periods,
the risk of lending to a state had previously been seen in terms of the probabil-
ities of two alternative extreme outcomes. It was seen as an ‘either/or’ risk –
either the debtor pays the interest and repays the principal without problems,
or the debtor defaults. In fact, the third world debtors did not formally default
on their loans; instead, bad loans were treated by the banks as ‘non-
performing’ but still recoverable, and a number of different arrangements
such as rescheduling through negotiations were set in motion. In the process,
the debt crisis of the 1980s led to the development of new types of markets,
and new regulations and forms of calculating and accounting for risk.
One such development was the creation of a market for the banks’ bad loans
to countries; banks could sell their bad debts at a substantial discount, which
reflected estimates of the probability of servicing and repayment. In other
words, a market assessment of the riskiness of bank loans to sovereign
borrowers became available, in contrast to previous times when the only
assessment was internal bank evaluation, and the market assessment, as
reflected in the price, covered a full range of probabilities.
Another development was that banks were forced to reappraise the adequa-
cy of their own capital base, the value of the equity capital shareholders had
put into the bank, relative to both the volume and riskiness of the loans they
made (and also relative to the variance of their deposit and debt liabilities).
The bad debts or ‘non performing loans’ resulting from the international
debt crisis caused banks to show losses which reduced their equity capital,
and in rebuilding their capital base they had to judge its adequacy in rela-
tion to those risk assessments in a more rigorous and explicit manner than
previously.
Pilbeam (2013) Sections
Reading 1.9 15.11–15.17 from
Chapter 15 ‘The Latin
To examine the Latin American debt crisis in more detail, now read pages 382–400 of American debt crisis’ in
International Finance.
Pilbeam now, concentrating particularly on the role and viewpoints of the actors in the pp. 382–400.
debt crisis (Section 15.13) and the management of the debt crisis (Section 15.14).
I would like you to bear in mind another point. The international debt crisis
that broke in 1982 was not the only modern crisis for the international
banking system. It led the Euro banks to reduce to almost nothing their
sovereign lending to less developed countries. Instead, they made large
scale loans available for real estate and property development in the major
industrialised countries, and for stock market take-over bids in the US and
16 University of London
Unit 1 Evolution of International Financial Systems
UK. The growth of these types of lending in the 1980s led to a new crisis of
bad loans by the end of the decade as they proved to have been based on
faulty risk assessments.
The 1990s saw the globalisation of capital markets and with it a resurgence of
lending to developing countries. However, this time around it was not only
governments and banks that resumed lending to developing countries. Private
sector financial flows shot up as lenders sought to invest in emerging market
assets. But the financial systems in many emerging economies were poorly
supervised, inadequately regulated and weak. In 1997, another crisis broke and
investors pulled out of Thailand, Indonesia, South Korea and Mexico.
With the globalisation of financial markets, panic set in as investors every-
where sought to sell their riskier holdings and cover their losses. The
turbulence on world markets continued in 1998 and people began to raise
questions about whether or not there was a need for some type of interna-
tional financial regulation or supervision. While capital markets may be
international in scope, supervision and regulation remained mainly a
national matter throughout the 1990s.
In the first decade of the 21st century, globalisation of financial markets
expanded further and with that, innovation in financial products and in the
business models of financial institutions. One outcome of this development
as well as of various nations’ economic policy choices, was a further infla-
tion of property and other asset prices in many developed economies. The
end of that boom saw another, deep and wide, global financial crisis which
arose in 2007–08 and whose seriousness reflected the size and the intercon-
nectedness of international financial institutions, reached through market
innovation and expansion.
The global crisis has provoked much urgent debate on the appropriate
national and international policy responses, as well as much reflection on
the balance of market mechanisms and regulation. International coordina-
tion of crisis management, of policy formation, and of regulating
international financial institutions, has very much put the international
financial system centre stage.
We shall return to debates about both the 1997 Asian financial crisis and the
2008 global crisis at the end of the module, considering financial innovation
and also returning to the questions posed in this unit including the merits of
fixed and floating exchange rates and of currency union arrangements,
particularly that of the Eurozone.
Meantime, the concepts and issues introduced here, have prepared you for
the study in the following units, of how international finance has been
understood, analysed and modelled – turning next to the foreign exchange
markets.
1.9 Conclusion
In this unit, we have surveyed the development of the modern system of
international finance. Can you now write a brief statement defining each of
the concepts I listed previously?
• Bretton Woods system
• Eurodollar system (and other Eurocurrencies)
• Latin American Debt Crisis
• Fixed Exchange Rate system
• Floating Exchange Rate system?
Exercise 1.1
Pause now and write two or three paragraphs on each.
Now that you have a clear understanding of each of those concepts, you
should be able to answer the question I posed at the beginning of the unit:
• Under the Bretton Woods system, was international finance regulated
by public institutions instead of markets, and did the development of
the Eurodollar system reverse the situation to one in which markets
operated without regulation?
Exercise 1.2
Please pause here and write a few paragraphs in answer to that question.
References
Baker JC (1998) ‘International monetary system’. International Finance:
Management, Markets, and Institutions. Harlow UK: Prentice-Hall
International. pp. 27–64.
18 University of London
Unit 1 Evolution of International Financial Systems