Pietro Garibaldi - Personnel Economics in Imperfect Labour Markets (2006)
Pietro Garibaldi - Personnel Economics in Imperfect Labour Markets (2006)
Labour Markets
This page intentionally left blank
Personnel
Economics in
Imperfect Labour
Markets
Pietro Garibaldi
1
3
Great Clarendon Street, Oxford OX2 6DP
Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford.
It furthers the University’s objective of excellence in research, scholarship,
and education by publishing worldwide in
Oxford New York
Auckland Cape Town Dar es Salaam Hong Kong Karachi
Kuala Lumpur Madrid Melbourne Mexico City Nairobi
New Delhi Shanghai Taipei Toronto
With offices in
Argentina Austria Brazil Chile Czech Republic France Greece
Guatemala Hungary Italy Japan Poland Portugal Singapore
South Korea Switzerland Thailand Turkey Ukraine Vietnam
Oxford is a registered trade mark of Oxford University Press
in the UK and in certain other countries
Published in the United States
by Oxford University Press Inc., New York
© Pietro Garibaldi, 2006
The moral rights of the author have been asserted
Database right Oxford University Press (maker)
First published 2006
All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced,
stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means,
without the prior permission in writing of Oxford University Press,
or as expressly permitted by law, or under terms agreed with the appropriate
reprographics rights organization. Enquiries concerning reproduction
outside the scope of the above should be sent to the Rights Department,
Oxford University Press, at the address above
You must not circulate this book in any other binding or cover
and you must impose the same condition on any acquirer
British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data
Data available
Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication Data
Data available
Typeset by Newgen Imaging Systems (P) Ltd., Chennai, India
Printed in Great Britain
on acid-free paper by
Biddles Ltd., King’s Lynn, Norfolk
10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1
to Giulia Tommaso and Alessandra
This page intentionally left blank
b P R E FAC E
AUDIENCE
Students are the primary audience for the book. Specifically, the book is written
with three types of student in mind. First, all the material covered in the
book can be easily taught at the undergraduate level in programmes that
specialize in economics and business. Second, the book can be used in business
schools where human resource-oriented courses are taught by economists.
Third, labour economics courses taught in Europe will find many chapters
in the book a very useful reference, and can use it as a key reference in an
otherwise standard labour economics course. In addition, scholars in the field
are likely to find the book a useful reference text, and may wish to have it in
their personal library.
CASE STUDIES
An important feature of the book is the analysis of a few key case studies in
personnel economics. Such case studies rely on personnel data and analyse
key issues with an econometric perspective. They are a distinctive feature of
the book, and they should be analysed by all audiences, even though some
basic econometrics may be required. A first case study analyses the change in
overtime regulation in France in 1982. A second study refers to the introduction
of a performance pay plan in a window glass installer in the United States. A
third study analyses the role of the temporary help industry in the provision
PREFACE ix
COURSE ORGANIZATION
There are fourteen chapters in the book. Each chapter is written with a lecture
topic in mind. Most of the chapters can be easily taught in a two-hour meeting,
even though some chapters require marginally more time. The (marginally)
more technical material is left to the appendices, so that the interested reader
can find more details if needed. A thirty-hour course, with fifteen meetings,
can easily cover most chapters of the book and leave some hours for setting
and solving problems.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
The idea of this book started in the late 1990s at one of the first editions of
the European Summer Symposium in Labour Economics, a yearly CEPR con-
ference held in Amersee, Germany. Ed Lazear was one of the keynote speakers
and gave a lecture on the future and the challenges of personnel economics,
as both a research field and a teaching course. I was fascinated by the lecture,
and immediately realized that teaching ‘labour economics inside the firm’ or
‘personnel economics’ was an obvious opportunity for Bocconi, the university
that hired me back in 1999. Tito Boeri took me seriously, and immediately
gave me the opportunity to teach personnel economics in Bocconi University.
Personnel economics is now a mandatory course in the Economics and Man-
agement degree inside Bocconi. Another course has been recently introduced
at a graduate level. Without Tito, this project would have never seen the light.
I am highly indebted to him.
Teaching personnel economics to future European managers was immedi-
ately fascinating. In the first years I realized that a proper European course
had to seriously consider the institutional dimensions of the labour mar-
ket. In those years most of my research output was linked to the interplay
between labour demand and labour market institutions, notably employment
protection legislation. I realized that a proper European version of personnel
economics had to take this institutional dimension into consideration. I dis-
cussed the issue with Ed Lazear again in 2002 in Amersee. He encouraged me
to go forward with the project, and I am certainly indebted to him.
I am also indebted to my various research co-authors, since many ideas
brought forward in the various chapters have benefited from their insights,
notably Gianluca Violante, Giuseppe Bertola, Lia Pacelli, and Etienne Wasmer.
Michele Pellizzari, Marco Leonardi and Lorenzo Cappellari taught preliminary
chapters, and offered important comments.
x PREFACE
The role of students has obviously been crucial. Various versions of this
course were taught in Bocconi University, at the University of Turin, at the
State University of Milan, and at Brussels University. All these students saw
various drafts of the chapters, and accepted the inevitable mistakes that earlier
drafts incorporate. Paola Monti stands out among these students.
b CO N TE N TS
1.1 Introduction 1
1.2 The Job in an Imperfect Labour Market 2
1.2.1 Perfect Labour Market 3
1.2.2 Imperfect Labour Market with Wage Set by the Firms 4
1.2.3 Imperfect Labour Market with Surplus Splitting 4
1.2.4 Imperfect Labour Market with Exogenous Wage 5
1.3 Minimum Wage Constraints and Union Density 5
1.4 Employment Protection Legislation 7
2.1 Introduction 11
2.2 A General View on Personnel Policies
at the Hiring Stage 12
2.3 The Optimal Skill Ratio: Key Concepts 12
2.3.1 Skilled and Unskilled Labour Interdependent
(Interior Solution) 15
2.3.2 Skilled and Unskilled Labour Independent
(Corner Solution) 19
2.3.3 The Effects of Wage Compression 21
2.3.4 Independent Skilled and Unskilled Labour
Interacting with Costly Capital 22
Appendix 2.1. A Formal Expression of the General Problem 24
3.1 Introduction 27
3.2 A Formal Classification of Labour Costs 27
3.2.1 Non-recurring Fixed Costs 28
3.2.2 Recurring Fixed Costs 29
3.2.3 Variable Costs 29
xii CONTENTS
4 Temporary or Permanent? 45
4.1 Introduction 45
4.2 Permanent Contracts with Fixed Wages 46
4.2.1 A Numerical Example 47
4.2.2 Formal Derivation 49
4.3 Temporary Contracts as a Buffer Stock 52
4.4 The Buffer Stock Model with Interim Costs 53
4.5 Temporary Contracts with Costly Turnover: Costs and
Benefits 55
4.6 A Brief Look at the Evidence 58
Appendix 4.1. The Formal Derivation of the Buffer Stock Model 60
Appendix 4.2. The Formal Derivation of the Buffer Stock Model
with Costly Interim Agency 60
5.1 Introduction 62
5.2 Contingent Contracts 63
5.2.1 Piece Rate as a Contingent Contract 64
5.2.2 Temporary Contract with Probation Wage 67
5.2.3 Contingent Contracts with Minimum Wages 72
5.3 Use of Credentials and the Signalling Model of Education 74
5.4 Education Signalling 74
5.5 Education Signalling: A Formal Story 78
5.6 Rules of the Game 78
5.7 No Education Equilibrium (Pooling Equilibrium) 79
5.8 Education Equilibrium (Separating Equilibrium) 80
CONTENTS xiii
6.1 Introduction 82
6.2 A Formal Principal–Agent Model 84
6.2.1 The General Setting 84
6.2.2 The Problem of a Risk-Neutral Agent 89
6.2.3 The Problem of the Principal with a Risk-Neutral Agent 92
6.3 The Basic Scheme with Non-Negative Payments 98
6.4 The Basic Scheme when the Agent is Risk Averse 100
6.4.1 The Agent Preferences 100
6.4.2 The Problems of the Agent 101
6.4.3 The Problem of the Principal with a Risk-Averse Agent: The Optimal
Bonus Scheme 102
Appendix 6.1. What if the Principal and the Risk-averse Agent
Could Contract on Effort 104
7.6 Utility levels for different individuals when a bonus scheme is 119
introduced in a firm that was offering a fixed wage with minimum
output
8.1 Broiler production 141
8.2 Variability of grower performance and grower quality: tournaments 144
8.3 Variability of grower performance and grower quality: LPE contracts 145
8.4 Deferred wages 150
9.1 A two-period model on general training 157
9.2 Wage tenure profile with general training 159
9.3 Specific investment with ex post sharing 164
9.4 Wage tenure profile with firm-specific investment 165
10.1 A two period model of firm-sponsored general training 173
10.2 Marginal benefit and marginal cost of training to the firm with and 179
without wage compression
10.3 Worker financing of general training with imperfect labor markets 180
10.4 Firm-sponsored training with a minimum wage 181
11.1 Firm-initiated separation 191
11.2 Reservation job and firing costs 195
11.3 The timing of the events 196
11.4 Determination of job creation and job destruction 197
11.5 The effects of an increase in firing costs on job creation and job 200
destruction
12.1 Labor demand in good and bad times and threshold effects 217
13.1 Average Productivity and percentage of workers employed in teams 225
A.1 Production function with constant capital 234
A.2 The marginal product and labor demand 235
B.1 The Lagrange method 238
b L IS T OF TA B L E S
1.1 Introduction
Personnel economics analyses personnel issues inside the firm. Yet, each firm
operates inside a labour market, and the functioning of such a market has
important consequences for personnel economics. The view of personnel eco-
nomics analysed in this book is based on two key properties of the labour
markets:
• labour markets are imperfect and jobs are associated to rents;
• labour market institutions interact with personnel policies. Notably,
– wages are partly set outside the firm–worker pair (minimum wages and
collective agreements are widespread)
– job termination policies are affected by a sizeable and binding employ-
ment protection legislation.
In an imperfect labour market the traditional competitive view of the labour
market does not hold. In a competitive labour market, the wage is fully set by
market forces and firm–worker pairs have no control over its value. In addition,
in a perfect labour market the workers are just indifferent between working
for the firm or working for somebody else. The resulting equilibrium wage is
fully flexible, and whenever business conditions change, wages can be adjusted
in response.
Things are different when the labour markets are imperfect. When the
labour markets are imperfect, a job is associated with a market rent. This
means that a job brings some pure surplus to both the firm and the worker. In
other words, the firm and the worker are better off when they are together than
when they are separated, and if a given job were to be suddenly severed, both
parties would lose. The surplus can be thought of as some extra value that the
parties enjoy when they are together. Such extra value has to be split between
the firm and the employees. This brings the issue of wage determination, which
is one of the key topics in personnel policies. In the book we explore three basic
possibilities for wage determination: wage setting by the firm, wage bargaining
2 NON-COMPETITIVE LABOUR MARKETS
by the firm and the worker, and wage determination made outside the firm and
the worker, i.e. by collective agreements. The book uses these three possibilities
interchangeably.
In an imperfect labour market wages are also rigid and do not fully respond
to business fluctuations. This implies that firms have to use different instru-
ments (other than wages) to respond to changes in business fluctuations. And
when prices cannot easily move firms have to rely on quantities. The problem
is that in an imperfect labour market, interrupting an employment relation-
ship is far from straightforward. This is the case because there is pervasive and
abiding employment protection legislation.
The next section establishes the concepts introduced in this chapter in a
more formal setting, while sections 1.2 and 1.3 briefly discuss the nature of
labour market institutions introduced in these paragraphs.
Sπ = y − w
S>0
S =y −v
y>v
w≥v
which is a condition that implies that the worker will accept working for the
firm as long as the wage is larger than his or her outside option. In formula,
the firm problem is the following
Maxw Sπ = y − w
s.t . w ≥ v
w=v
Sπ = y − v
S>0
y>v
NON-COMPETITIVE LABOUR MARKETS 5
We now assume that the surplus is split between the firm and the worker,
and the worker gets a fraction β of the total surplus
wβ = v + βS
wβ = v + β(y − v)
wβ = (1 − β)v + βy
Wages are obtained as the weighted average between the worker’s outside
option and the marginal productivity on the job. The weight corresponds
to the worker’s bargaining share β.
The firm makes profits
Sπ = y − wβ
Sπ = y − v + β(y − v)
Sπ = (1 − β)(y − v)
and the worker enjoys a surplus vis-à-vis his or her outside option, since
Sw = β(y − v).
in the United States the difference between the trade union density and the
degree of coverage is not very important, for countries like France, Germany,
and Italy, the degree of trade union coverage is around 90 per cent. This means
that in Europe nine workers out of ten have their wage negotiated by trade
unions, even though only four out of ten are union members. Table 1.1 also
collects information on the degree of centralization of collective bargaining,
i.e. the level at which contracts are negotiated. While in the United States the
negotiation is mostly at the level of the firm, in Europe it takes place mostly at
the sectoral level. From the labour market point of view, strong trade unions
can have adverse effects on the costs of labour, and can ultimately reduce
employment. However, trade unions may also play a key role in society and
boost workers to improve workers’ morale and productivity.
The most traditional dimensions of EPL are the severance payments and
advance notice. Severance payments refer to a monetary transfer from the firm
to the worker to be paid in the case of firm-initiated separation. Advance notice
refers to a specific period of time to be given to the worker before a firing can
actually be implemented. Note that the severance payment and advance notice
that are part of EPL refer to the minimum statutory payments and mandatory
rules that apply to all employment relationships, regardless of what is estab-
lished by labour contracts. Beyond mandatory payments, collective agreements
may well specify larger severance payments for firm-initiated separations. Such
party clauses, albeit important, are not considered in this report.
Another important dimension of EPL consists of the administrative pro-
cedures that have to be followed before the lay-off can actually take place. In
most countries, the employer is often required to discuss the lay-off decisions
with the workers’ representatives. Further, the legislative provisions often differ
depending on business characteristics such as firm (or plant) size and industry
of activity. As this simple introduction shows, it is obvious that the EPL is a
multidimensional phenomenon.
In most countries the legislation distinguishes between individual and
collective dismissals. Individual dismissals should be further distinguished
between economic dismissals and disciplinary dismissals, with most EPL
clauses applying only to the former case. Disciplinary dismissals (i.e. worker’s
fault dismissals), do not typically involve monetary transfers. The procedure
for collective dismissal applies to large-scale firm restructuring, and requires
the dismissal of at least a specific proportion of the workforce. When a collect-
ive dismissal is authorized by the relevant authority (often a court) the firm
can then implement a large dismissal without a large transfer. Yet, such proced-
ure requires a much tighter administrative burden, in the form of prolonged
consultation with the workers’ representatives.
From the viewpoint of economic analysis, the multidimensionality of the
EPL can be reduced to two components. The first component is simply a
monetary transfer from the employer to the worker, similar in nature to the
wage. The second, instead, is more similar to a tax, because it corresponds
to a payment to a third party, external to the worker–employer relationship.
Conceptually, the severance payment and the notice period correspond to the
transfer, while the trial costs (the fees for the lawyers, etc.) and all the other
procedural costs correspond to the tax (in Italy, the transfer part corresponds
to approximately 80 per cent of the total cost of the lay-off).
Unavoidably, the complexity of the firing regulations is costly for the
employer. It is quite difficult to quantify the total cost of a lay-off, mainly
because its exact amount depends also on the probability of the worker filing
the case to a court, and on the probability of the court invalidating the firm’s
firing. In the Italian case, in particular, if the firing decision is overruled by the
judge, the firm can be forced to take the employee back on the payroll. Despite
NON-COMPETITIVE LABOUR MARKETS 9
the difficulty of carrying out precise calculations of the average cost of a lay-
off, a number of studies have tried to assign a reasonable value to such a cost.
Garibaldi and Violante (2006) estimate that an Italian employer with more
than fifteen employees who fires a worker and whose decision is overruled by
a court a year after the lay-off with 80 per cent probability will have to bear a
cost of fifteen months’ wages, i.e. a year and three months of wages.
From a cross-country perspective, it would be interesting to measure the
average cost of a lay-off in the various countries. Unfortunately, homogeneous
measures of such cost relative to the average wage do not exist for all countries.
In order to carry out international comparisons of the employment protec-
tion regimes, economists use the so-called method of the ‘hierarchies of the
hierarchies’. This method consists in assigning a number (say from 1 to 6) to
every country for any single feature of the protection regimes. Higher num-
bers denote more rigid regimes. Taking the average of the several components,
a single synthetic measure of the rigidity of the EPL is obtained.
The synthetic indicators, originally compiled by the OECD, are now avail-
able for transition economies as well as for Latin American countries. In order
to obtain the overall indicator of the rigidity of a country, it is necessary to
consider simultaneously (a) the rigidity of the individual firing regulation of
workers under permanent contract, (b) that of workers under temporary con-
tracts, and (c) the rigidity of collective dismissals. The average of these three
measures gives the overall indicator. Obviously, each of the three measures
is obtained, in turn, through an average of some other sub-measures. As an
example, consider the indicator for individual firings of workers under per-
manent contracts. Such a number is obtained as an average of 4 sub-indicators:
(1) the administrative procedures, (2) the length of the notice period, (3) the
amount of the severance payment (4) the severity of the enforcement (the
more or less important role of judges on firing disputes). Clearly, in order to
construct the synthetic indicators, it is necessary to consider a great number
of dimensions.
Table 1.2 displays the relative position of the six countries. The United
States turns out to be the most flexible country, while EPL is much tighter
in countries such as Italy, Spain, and Germany. The table also shows the EPL
rigidity indicators in the 1980s, thus allowing us to observe the evolution over
time of the firing regulations. As far as the ‘regular’ contracts are concerned, the
table clearly shows that the European countries have made very little change to
the firing regulations. As a matter of fact, the level of protection is practically
unchanged. Conversely, the regulation of temporary contracts has been eased
in most European countries.
These indicators are undoubtedly useful for the economic analysis, as they
are often used to empirically test the predictions of the economic models.
However, it is worth recalling the reasons why such indicators are not perfect.
First, it is very difficult to get time series of these indices (the latest OECD
10 NON-COMPETITIVE LABOUR MARKETS
numbers refer to three points in time). Second, the method of the ‘hierarch-
ies of hierarchies’ assigns the same weight to the various EPL sub-indicators.
An additional problem is the fact that they concern features of EPL that are
similar between countries, while they tend to ignore country-specific regula-
tions. Finally, it is most difficult to measure the degree of enforcement of the
norms. It is possible that some countries have rigid norms only softly enforced,
while in other apparently flexible countries the norms are enforced very strictly
(Boeri 1999).
2 The Optimal Skill Ratio
2.1 Introduction
Before entering into the details of personnel policies, the firm needs to have
a general view of the right balance of its workforce. Indeed, choosing the
right balance of the workforce is a key pre-requisite for sound personnel man-
agement. There are two key dimensions that should be considered: the skill
composition of the labour force and the hours/employment trade-off.
Labour is not a homogeneous quantity, and a highly skilled worker is a
very different factor of production from an unskilled worker. Highly skilled
workers are likely to be more profitable to the firm. But they are also likely to
be more costly. A trade-off emerges, and the firm has to find the right balance
between cost and productivity. In personnel economics, solving this problem
means finding the optimal skill ratio. This chapter shows that the solution to
this trade-off requires the analysis of relative costs and relative productivity,
where the word relative refers to different skill level. In general, we will see
that the best skill composition is not necessarily the cheapest skill composition
nor the most productive composition. Technological considerations are also
very important. In some firms, only one type of labour will be chosen, while in
other firms it will always be optimal to have a positive quantity of both types of
workers. This chapter will also give us the possibility of studying the impact on
the skill composition of wage compression, an important institutional feature
of imperfect labour markets.
Hiring a quantity of labour, irrespective of its skill level, involves a vari-
ety of costs, and only some of such costs vary with the hours worked. As
a consequence, total labour costs are much larger than the per hour wage
cost. Further, some of these costs do not even vary with the number of hours
worked. Thus, in real life organization a firm can adjust the quantity of a
given type of labour over the hours worked and the number of employees.
This is the hours/employment trade-off and will be the focus of the next
chapter.
The chapter is organized as follows. Section 2.1 briefly describes the general
hiring problem of a firm. Section 2.2 defines some key concepts for describing
a firm’s hiring behaviour. Section 2.2.1 describes the optimal skill ratio in the
case of a technology in which workers are interdependent in the production
process while Section 2.2.2 analyses the case of independent workers.
12 THE OPTIMAL SKILL RATIO
which can be thought of as graduate workers and non-graduate workers. We indicate with
L the quantity of low-skilled workers and with H the quantity of high-skilled workers. The
contribution to output stemming from each separate input, holding constant the quantity
of other input, is called marginal productivity. It is a key concept in most economics as well as
in personnel economics. The marginal product of unskilled labour is defined as the change
in output resulting from hiring additional workers, holding constant the quantity of other
inputs. The formal expression is
Y
FL =
L H =H̄ ,K =K̄
One additional unskilled worker yields an extra amount of output equal to FL where the
notation makes clear that we are holding fixed the amount of capital and of skilled labour.1
Similarly one
additional unit of skilled labour at constant quantity of unskilled labour yields
FH = H Y
. The only assumption that we make on these two marginal products
L=L̄,K =K̄
is that they are positive. This means that an additional unit of any type of labour (holding
constant the other type) increases total output. It is an obviously reasonable assumption,
since it just says that adding more workers to the firm increases output, other things
equal.
The salary of each type of worker depends on each skill level. The firm takes as given the
wage. The salary of a graduate worker is wH while the salary of an unskilled worker is wL .
The wage refers to the hourly labour costs. Obviously, wH ≥ wL . Skilled workers are more
expensive than unskilled workers.
The firm problem is to choose the skill combination that yields output Ȳ and minimizes
costs. In other words, the firm must select the combination of H and L that yields the lowest
possible labour costs, conditional on producing total output equal to Ȳ .
1 More formally, the marginal productivity of unskilled labour can also be thought of as the partial derivative of the
production function Y = F (K̄ , L, H ) with respect to unskilled labour and indicated with YL = ∂Y
∂L = FL .
Our analysis will show that two dimensions are very important. The first
one is the relative labour costs, or the ratio of the two wages. The other key
dimension will be the relative marginal productivity of the two factors. In
addition, careful consideration must be given to the way in which the two
types of labour enter the production function, and whether the two factors are
complements or substitutes in the production process.
The formal way to think about this problem is assuming that a firm
would like to minimize labour costs subject to the constraint that the quant-
ity of output is at least equal to some value Ȳ . If we let wH be the skilled
wage and wL the low-skilled wage, the total costs of production are simply
given by
TC = wL L + wH H ,
where TC is the total labour costs. The curve that describes the combination of
skilled and unskilled labour and yields the same amount of cost is called isocost.
It is easy to study the feature of the isocost in the H − L diagram displayed in
Fig. 2.1. The isocost is just a negatively sloped line with the slope equal to the
14 THE OPTIMAL SKILL RATIO
H
Isocost:
slope – wL / wH
TC2
TC1
H wL
=− slope of the isocost
L wH
Figure 2.1 plots two different isocosts. The curve labelled TC1 refers to a larger
total cost while the curve labelled TC2 refers to a smaller value of the cost. Note
that the two curves are parallel since the relative wage cost is the same in the
two curves.
The wage skilled premium is the percentage premium required by the market for hiring a
skilled worker versus an unskilled worker.
Y = F (K̄ , L, H )
Min (wL L + wH H )
s.t. F (K̄ , L, H ) = Ȳ .
É To formally derive the slope of the isocost in the H − L space simply write
wL TC
H =− L+
wH wH
As we will see in the rest of the chapter the solution depends on whether the
two types of labour are independent in the production process. We analyse two
cases. The first one is a case in which the two types of labour are interdependent
in the production process, while the second one is a case in which the two
factors are independent. The algebraic solution is derived in Appendix 2.1.
H
Isoquant:
slope – FL / FH H
Isocost:
slope – wL / wH
x
∆H y
∆L L
L
H Equilibrium:
slope isocost
= slope isoquant
Figure 2.2. The solution to the optimal skill ratio with interdependent production
L × FL + H × FH = 0
dY = FL dL + FH dH
dH FL
=− .
dL FH
THE OPTIMAL SKILL RATIO 17
The second property argues that isoquants cannot intersect. This is not
surprising, since if they did intersect, a combination of two types of labour
yields the same amount of output. Such a property cannot be consistent with
the definition of isoquant. The third property says that larger isoquants refer to
larger quantity of output. As we move to north-east in the diagram we obtain
larger output. Indeed, as we move north-east in the diagram we have a larger
amount of input, to which must necessarily correspond larger output (recall
that the marginal product is positive).
With interdependent production isoquants are convex to the origin. To
understand the convexity part think of how many skilled workers (H ) we need
in place of unskilled workers (L), and still obtain the same amount of output.
The top panel in Fig. 2.2 suggests that the fewer unskilled workers we have
relatively to high-skilled workers, the larger this substitution is. Formally, the
convexity assumption implies that we have a diminishing marginal rate of
technical substitution (or a flatter isoquant) as the firm substitutes unskilled
labour for skilled labour.
The firm wants to produce at the lowest possible isocost given the constraint
described by the isoquant. The solution is given by a tangency position, where
the slope of the isoquant is equal to the slope of the isocost. In other words,
the optimal skill ratio requires that the slope of the isocost is equal to the slope
of the isoquant. Equating the slope of the isoquant to that of the isocost we
have
wL FL
= (2.1)
wH FH
which is the fundamental condition for determining the skilled combination
of the labour force. The solution is clearly illustrated in the bottom panel of
Fig. 2.2. The firm could produce the quantity of output ȳ with other combina-
tions, but such a choice would yield a larger cost. In other words, the previous
condition says that the firm chooses the skill combination so that the relat-
ive marginal product is equal to the relative marginal costs. The optimal skill
composition crucially depends on two ratios: the ratio of marginal productiv-
ity and the ratio of wages, and in equilibrium it is obtained by equating the
two ratios.
Having determined the optimal skill ratio, we now study what happens if
there is a change in the skilled wage premium γ , a parameter that the firm
takes as given. Assume that the wage skill premium increases, and assume
that the firm needs to produce a quantity indicated by y ∗ , as indicated in
Fig. 2.3. The initial position of the firm is indicated by point A. The increase
in the skilled wage induces an anticlockwise shift of the isocost. Following
the increase in γ , the original isocost is no longer sufficient to guarantee a
production level y ∗ . This suggests that the output y ∗ will be more expensive
in the aftermath of the increase in γ . But what happen to the optimal skill
18 THE OPTIMAL SKILL RATIO
H A
1/(1 + g)
B
1/(1 + g⬘)
y = y*
ratio? The new equilibrium position will be at point B, a point at which the
slope of the new isocost (following the increase in γ ) is identical to the slope
of the isoquant. The optimal point will correspond to a lower skill ratio, and
the firm will tend to substitute low-skilled labour for high-skilled labour. With
interdependent production, an increase (decrease) in the skilled wage premium
decreases (increases) the optimal skill ratio.
The formal proof of this is obtained in the next section, but it can also be
seen graphically by the shift of the optimal skill ratio from point A to point B
in Fig. 2.3.
Finally note that in deriving the optimal skill ratio, we have not referred
to the financial position of the firm, nor whether a firm is making or losing
money. So, the optimal skill combination is independent of firm profitability.
The previous remark is important, since it says that the firm should hold
on to its optimal skill ratio independently of the current financial conditions.
In other words, savings on skilled workers in bad times can just do damage to
the firm’s profit outlook.
Suppose that the capital stock is equal to 1 and that the production function is Y = L β H α with
β > 0 and α > 0. This implies that the marginal product of labour is FL = ∂Y ∂L = βL
β−1 H α
∂Y
while the marginal product of skilled workers is FH = ∂H = αL H β α−1 . From these marginal
functions, it follows immediately that the marginal product of each type of labour depends
on the number of people of the other type that are currently hired. Further, the ratio of the
marginal product is
FL βL β−1 H α
=
FH αL β H α−1
FL βH
=
FH αL
THE OPTIMAL SKILL RATIO 19
wL βH
=
wH α L
Obviously we have wH = (1 + γ )wL so that γ is the skilled premium required. It is clear that the
optimal skill mix depends on three key parameters: α, β, and γ , as the following equation
shows:
∗
H α
=
L β(1 + γ )
The optimal skill ratio increases with α and decreases with γ and β.
Note that in this case we have an interior solution. It is always optimal to use some combina-
tion of skilled and unskilled labour regardless of the specific value of γ . Yet, a larger value of
γ reduces the optimal skill ratio.
Slope isocost: wL / wH
Hire unskilled L
a/b > wL / wH
Hire skilled H
Slope isocost: a/b < wL / wH
wL / wH Slope
isoquant: a/b
L L
This situation is also described in the graphical interpretation of Fig. 2.4, and
particularly in the top panel. Note that in this case both the isoquant and the
isocost are linear equations, so that in the equilibrium position only one type
of labour should be used. This is tectonically defined as a corner solution. In
the first panel, it is optimal to hire only unskilled workers, since ab > wwHL .
Further elaborating this inequality we can say that unskilled labour should be
used if
a wL
>
b wH
1 1
>
(1 + δ) 1+γ
γ >δ
In other words, unskilled labour should be used when the wage skill premium
is larger than the productivity skill premium. With independent workers, only
one type of labour should be used, and the solution is obtained by comparing
the value of the skilled wage premium to the productivity premium.
The condition is very intuitive. Suppose that δ = 0.05 and γ = 0.1, which
means that the market requires a premium of 10 per cent for hiring a skilled
worker while the productivity premium is only 5 per cent. In this situation,
it cannot be optimal to hire skilled workers since the proportional increase in
cost is larger than the proportional increase in productivity.
THE OPTIMAL SKILL RATIO 21
Notes: Relative expected earnings of the population with income from employment by education attainment
and gender.
Population aged 30–44 below upper secondary=100.
22 THE OPTIMAL SKILL RATIO
How can this result be explained? The intuition is as follows. To obtain one
additional unit of output using high-skilled labour requires that b1 more unit
of capital is installed, while using unskilled labour requires a1 unit of capital to
be used. Since b > a it may pay to use skilled labour and save on costly machinery
even if γ > δ. This depends on how costly machines are and on how costly
unskilled labour is.
24 THE OPTIMAL SKILL RATIO
Table 2.2. Optimal skill ratio with independent workers and costly capital
Machines A
Low-skilled 4 40 6 46 11.50
High-skilled 6 64 6 70 11.67
Prod. premium 0.5
Machines B
Low-skilled 8 40 10 50 6.25
High-skilled 12 64 10 74 6.17
Prod. premium 0.5
Consider the example in which a firm must choose between low- or high-
skilled labour with two different technologies which we summarize by their
different cost of capital. With the new technology capital is more costly but
both skilled and unskilled workers are more productive. Let’s see whether the
optimal skill choice changes with the new or the old technology. Let wL =
40, wH = 64, and the wage productivity premium γ is 0.6. Output per worker
of low-skilled workers is yL = 4 while output per worker of high-skilled
workers is yH = 6. If capital is not relevant in the production process, then
obviously low-skilled labour should be used. With the old-type technology
production requires costly capital (CK = 8), and such cost should be taken
into account. Nevertheless, the cost per output of low-skilled labour is still
lower (11.5 < 11.67) so that unskilled labour should be used even with this
wL
capital cost. With the new machine γ̃ = γ wL +C = 0.6 ∗ 40+10 40
= 0.48,
k
so that skilled labour should be used since δ > γ̃ . Indeed, Table 2.2 shows that
high-skilled workers are most cost effective in this case.
Output at the firm is indicated by Y . Consider two types of labour, high-skilled and
low-skilled, which we indicate respectively with H and L. The short-run production
function takes the form
Y = F (K̄ , L, H )
where K̄ is the fixed amount of capital, L is unskilled labour, and H is skilled labour.
Suppose that for each type of labour we have to choose the hours and the number of
people so that
L = L(El , hl ) H (Eh , hh )
where El is the number of low-skilled employees and hl is the number of hours per
unskilled employee. Eh and hh are similarly defined but with respect to the skilled and
THE OPTIMAL SKILL RATIO 25
where the total quantity of each type of labour can be obtained by changing either
employment or hours. In this chapter the distinction between El and hl (and between
Eh and hh ) was ignored, and the focus was on the choice between H and L. In the next
chapter the focus is mainly on the distinction between El and hl without considering
the distinctions between H and L. This is done for simplicity.
Interdependent Production. The problem in this case is formally studied by setting
up a Lagrangian so as to maximize the following function (see Appendix B for a simple
explanation of the Langrangian technique)
= wL L + wH H + λ[F (K̄ , L, H ) − Ȳ ]
wL = λFL (2.3)
wH = λFH (2.4)
F (K̄ , L, H ) = Ȳ
so that, taking the fraction between the two first-order conditions, one gets:
wL FL
= (2.5)
wH FH
which is the key condition for the optimal skill ratio.
Wage Compression with Interdependent Production. Using the wage skill premium
factor γ we have:
wH = wL (1 + γ )(1 − φ),
where φ is the wage compression factor. To see the effect of wage compression in the
case of interior production
∗
H α wL
=
L β wH
∗
H α (1 + φ)
=
L β (1 − φ)(1 + γ )
where it is easy to show that wage compression
∗ increases the optimal skilled ratio. To
see this note that the partial derivative of HL with respect to φ is positive. In formula
∗
∂ HL α 1 1
= >0
∂φ β (1 + γ ) (1 − φ)2
An example of Independent Production. The obvious example is the following
production function:
Y = [aL + bH ]z
26 THE OPTIMAL SKILL RATIO
where 0 < z < 1 can be thought of as managerial ability. Indeed, applying the standard
rule we have:
FL = azY z−1
and
FH = bzY z−1
3.1 Introduction
In imperfect labour markets, hiring labour involves a variety of costs, and
only some of such costs vary with the hours worked. In the previous chapter
labour costs were simply defined as the per hour (or per month) wage. In
reality, a variety of labour costs exist and most of such costs are independent
of the hourly wage cost. Some of these costs are paid only upon hiring, while
other costs are paid each month, but are independent of the hours worked.
The cost of advertising a vacancy refers to the first type, while paid vacations
are an example of the second one. This means that a real life organization
can adjust the quantity of labour over two different margins, which are called
the extensive margin and the intensive margin. The extensive margin refers
to the number of people hired by the firm while the intensive margin refers
to the average hours worked per employees. Choosing the right combination
between hours per workers and the number of employees means solving the
hours–employment trade-off.
Section 3.1 presents a formal, albeit simple, classification of total labour
costs. Section 3.2 presents the basic theory of the hours–employment trade-off
and derives the firm solution to the trade-off. Section 3.3 explicitly introduces
overtime salary into analysis and derives the employment effect of an increase
in overtime pay. Section 3.4 presents a case study on the employment effect of
an increase in overtime pay, or the effect of a reduction in the normal hours
of work. The case study is derived from France in 1982, when the government
suddenly decided to reduce the number of hours from 40 to 39. The results of
this change are exactly in line with those presented in the theoretical part of
the chapter.
advertising;
Non-recurring termination costs
(training)
Fixed cost
medical insurance;
Recurring
paid vacation
Normal wage
Variable costs
Overtime wage
as one-off costs, or set-up costs, and are costs that the firm incurs each time it
takes on a new worker; recurring fixed costs are paid by the firm on a regular
basis, as long as it continues to employ that worker, but do not vary with the
number of hours or the intensity with which an employee works. Second there
are variable labour costs. These are costs that vary according to the number of
hours, and the key distinction is the one between normal wage per hour and
overtime. The fact that most forms of employment combine elements of both
of these has led to a description of labour as a quasi-fixed factor of production.
Figure 3.1 reports a diagram with the classification that we just described.
one type of labour. Specifically, we let E be the number of people in the firm
and h the number of hours per worker.
Let us begin by properly defining E and h. Hours h are measured as hours
per unit of time, and the convention in this respect is to measure h as hours
per week. E is simply the number of people employed by the firm. As we
saw in the previous section labour costs are very diverse. Here we provide a
very parsimonious description of total labour costs, and we will (initially) just
distinguish between fixed and variable labour costs.
The problem we want to describe is the following.
To solve this problem, let’s first think of the total labour costs. There are two
dimensions to consider: the number of skilled workers, which we indicate with
E, and the number of hours per worker, which we indicate with h. We assume
that each worker hired involves a fixed cost equal to F . In this respect, we are
just focusing on non-recurring fixed costs. This implies that hiring E workers
involves a fixed cost of labour equal to EF , where F is the fixed cost per worker.
Let us assume that the wage rate per hour w is initially fixed at w so that the
fixed and variable costs can be written as
Fixed Cost = EF
Variable Cost = Ewh
The variable cost is equal to the weekly wage (wh) multiplied by the number of
employees. If we indicate with C the total budget allocation then we can write
C = EF + Ewh
Let’s solve the previous condition for E to obtain
C
E=
wh + F
The previous relationship highlights a key trade-off in the firm total costs.
There exists a combination of hours (intensive margin) and people (extensive
margin) consistent with a given total cost C. In other words, the firm can
obtain total costs C by choosing a point over the curve that we label isocost.
There are two key features of the isocost that we need to emphasize. First, the
THE HOURS–EMPLOYMENT TRADE-OFF 31
ȳ = f (h, E)
32 THE HOURS–EMPLOYMENT TRADE-OFF
isocost
X
isoquant
A
E*
Z
h* h
E A E
C
D
y⬘
B y
E** y E*
E* E**
h* h h* h** h
Figure 3.3. The effect of the hours–employment trade-off of an increase in the size of the
budget (left panel) and an increase in the fixed cost (right panel)
number of hours per week. The left-hand side of Fig. 3.3, and the formal
problem described in Appendix 3.1 captures such real life property:
Larger output leads to an increase in the number of employees. Conversely, the
choice of hours is independent of output, so that an increase in the budget does
not have an impact on the demand for hours.
This property is empirically consistent with the fact that the average hours
per worker is largely independent of the size of the firms, a property that
appears empirically true. Next consider the effect of an increase in the fixed
cost of hiring labour. The isocost shifts down, and as Fig. 3.3 shows, firms
reduce employees and increase hours.
An increase in the fixed costs of hiring increases the demand for hours.
THE HOURS–EMPLOYMENT TRADE-OFF 33
C = EF + wEh if h ≤ ho
If the firm does use overtime, two different wages apply to the firm: one for
normal hours and one for overtime hours. The isocost in this case is equal to
The slope of the isocost changes at the normal hours ho , with a steeper
curvature beyond the normal hours ho . Figure 3.4 plots the isocost. In cor-
respondence to the normal number of hours the isocost features a kink
point.
The isoquant for employees’ hours is the same as the one described in the
previous section, and the objective of the firm is still to minimize costs subject
to the isoquant constraint.
A firm can be in two different positions, depending on whether or not it
uses overtime.
Suppose that there are two firms, one that uses overtime and one that does
not use overtime. The situation is described in the top panel of Fig. 3.4. The
first panel describes a firm that is operating on the ‘normal’ number of hours,
and it positions itself on the kink point of the isocost. The firm in the second
panel, conversely, corresponds to a firm that is operating in the overtime range,
and positions itself to the right of the kink point ho .
THE HOURS–EMPLOYMENT TRADE-OFF 35
E
E
h0 h h0 h
Figure 3.4. Equilibrium position for a firm that uses and does not use overtime
h0⬘ h0 h
Figure 3.5. The reduction of the normal workweek and the isocost
E A
h0⬘ h0 h
E C
h0⬘ h0 h
Let us now consider a firm that before the overtime change is operating
below the normal workweek. In terms of Fig. 3.6, such a firm was operating in
point C in the figure. The change in the slope of the isocost involves a part of
the constraint that does not affect the position of the firm. This suggests that
such a firm will not change its equilibrium position, and will continue to hire
the same number of workers for the same workweek.
Combining the results of the two type of firms (described by Fig. 3.6), it is
clear that the effect of a reduction in the normal workweek is a reduction in
the number of workers hired. The following summarizes the findings:
A reduction in the normal workweek induces a reduction in the number of
employees.
The next section analyses a case study on workweek reduction in France, and
shows that the theoretical predictions are largely consistent with the empirical
evidence.
Fraction of employment
Working:
36 to 39 hours 2.2 2.1 2.5 2.4 2.6 2.4
40 hours 46.6 53.6 56.6 58.6 60.9 65.9
41 to 43 hours 18.8 18.8 19.5 19.3 17.5 15.2
44 hours 4.2 4.4 3.9 2.3 2.7 2.0
45 to 48 hours 28.2 21.1 18.6 17.4 16.4 14.5
The number of hours worked in France strongly decreased during the 1970s,
from 48 hours in 1974 to just above 40 hours in 1981 (Table 3.1). Since 1936, the
standard workweek in France was 40 hours. The French Socialist government
in 1982 reduced the workweek from 40 to 39 hours. In this section we study
the effects of such a change on the number of hirings.
François Mitterrand’s election in May 1981 induced a sudden decrease of
the standard workweek to 39 hours (16 January 1982 ordinance), and the new
39 law was imposed on 1 February 1982. The law mandated a maximum legal
workweek of 39 hours, whereas it was 40 hours previously. The overtime regula-
tion did not substantially change: the overtime premium remained 25 per cent
for the first four hours (i.e. from 40 to 43 hours), and 50 per cent above. Col-
lective agreements, specifying the terms of application of the decree, ensued in
the aftermath of the ordinance, starting with the larger firms in manufacturing
industries and spreading to smaller firms and other industries.
It is possible to show that workers directly affected by these changes—those
working 40 hours in March 1981 as well as those working overtime at the same
date—were more likely to lose their jobs between 1981 and 1982 than those
workers not affected by the changes—those working 36 to 39 hours in March
1981. The estimate of the impact of the one-hour reduction of the workweek
on employment losses varies between 2 per cent and 4 per cent.
The result is based on a comparison between workers who worked 36
to 39 hours before 1982 and workers who worked exactly 40 hours and
those who worked overtime (up to 48 hours). The result shows that workers
who were working exactly 40 hours per week in March 1981 as well as workers
who were working overtime (41 to 48 hours) per week in March 1981 were
less likely to be employed in 1982 than observationally identical workers who,
in 1981, were working 36 to 39 hours per week. The analysis uses econometric
techniques that allow the scholar to compare changes in labour market posi-
tion between 1981 to 1982, the period immediately after the implementation
of the decree, with those prevailing between 1978 and 1981, before the election
of François Mitterrand.
38 THE HOURS–EMPLOYMENT TRADE-OFF
should provide an empirical estimate of the size of the impact that we are
looking for. If the probability of losing the job for the treatment group increases
relatively to the probability of losing the job for the control group, then the
impact of the experiment is positive. This is called a natural experiment, and
it is a perfect application of our theory. Let’s see what the data said in the
French case.
36−9 40 is the
where JL82 is the job loss probability of the control group while JL82
job loss probability for the treatment group.
The idea is that the probability of job loss of the treatment group, in excess to
the job loss probability of the control group, describes a measure of the impact
of the policy change. In formula, a first measure of the potential impact is
given by
40 36−9
82 = JL82 − JL82
Table 3.2 suggests that a simple measure of 82 is 3 percentage points.
The value of α8140 is 2.6 per cent, which suggests that the reform increases
the chance of losing one’s job if working 40 hours by 2.6 percentage points.
The coefficient is reported in the first column of Table 3.3. Finally, note that the
same regressions calculated for the previous years in which no reform was
undertaken are not statistically significant. This can be done by looking at
THE HOURS–EMPLOYMENT TRADE-OFF 41
1 2 3 4 5
Non-employment at t + 2
Hours = 40 2.60 −1.26 1.29 −3.85 3.90
standard error 1.44 1.86 1.48 2.30 1.82
41<= hours<= 43 1.32 −2.40 1.06 −5.09 3.49
standard error 1.60 1.91 1.57 2.39 1.97
Hours = 44 2.50 −0.73 −0.32 −4.57 4.20
standard error 2.50 2.35 1.91 2.92 2.88
45<= hours<= 48 2.12 −2.14 1.50 −6.52 4.52
standard error 1.66 1.96 1.61 2.39 2.03
Notes: Regressions for the LFS panels of 77–9, 78–80, 79–81, and 80–2 (linear probability mod-
els). The dependent variable is non-employment in the exit year of the panel (79, 80, 81, and 82,
respectively)
Independent variables: indicator for the hours categories (only reported coefficients), industry,
region (Ile de France or other), skill level (3 categories), sex, diploma (6 categories), experience (4
categories), seniority (4 categories), labour market status (apprentice or not), and hours in first year
of the panel strictly below 40 and hours in first year of the panel strictly above 40. The population
includes all full-time workers in the private sector working between 36 and 48 hours in the median
year of each panel (78, 79, 80, and 81, respectively). Column 1 reports estimates for the panel 80–2,
columns 2, 3, and 4 report estimates for the panels 77–9, 78–80, and 79–81 respectively. Column
5 reports pooled estimates where all variables are interacted with the relevant year indicator except
for the hours categories for which we introduce pooled coefficients and coefficient specific to year
1981 (panel 80–2). These last coefficients are those reported in column 5 (pooled).
Source: Crépon and Kramarz (2002)
the other columns of Table 3.3 (those labelled 77–9, 78–80, etc.), where the
coefficient on 40 hours is not significant.
Initially we assume that if a typical worker is asked to work additional hours, he or she
will require a higher wage rate. The firm thus faces the following wage function
w = w(h) w > 0
where the positive slope can be thought of as the result of an upward-sloping labour
supply from the worker’s standpoint. The firm’s labour costs are
where the simple form labour costs LC = wE follows each time we assume that F = 0
and h = 1 fixed. The production function takes the form as
y = E α hβ
42 THE HOURS–EMPLOYMENT TRADE-OFF
and the problem can be thought of as one of minimizing total costs subject to a fixed
production input ȳ. Formally, this is equivalent to having
MinE,h Ehw(h) + EF
s.t. E α h β = ȳ
So that forming the Lagrangian one has
= Ehw(h) + EF − λ[E α h β − ȳ]
whose first-order conditions are
λαE α−1 h β = [hw(h) + F ]
λβE α h β−1 = [Ew(h) + Ehw (h)]
E α h β = ȳ
Taking the ratio of the first two we obtain
FE MCE
=
Fh MCh
αE α−1 h β hw(h) + F
α β−1
=
βE h w(h)E[1 + w(h)
h
w (h)εw,h ]
αh hw(h) + F
=
βE w(h)E[1 + εw,h ]
where εw,h is the elasticity of w(h) with respect to h.
The general rule is
FE MCE
=
Lh MCh
where FE is the marginal increase in output following an increase in total employment
while Fh is the marginal increase in output as more hours are worked. An important
property follows:
The choice of hours is independent of the scale of operation.
The proof is straightforward from the first-order conditions, since E is immediately
removed from the equations so that h is a function of only εw,h and F , so that
αhw(h)[1 + εw,h ] = βhw(h) + βF
from which it follows that
h = h(F , εw,h )
with
∂h
>0
∂F
∂h
>
∂εw,h
THE HOURS–EMPLOYMENT TRADE-OFF 43
C
E=
h(ε, F )w(h) + F
E = E(F , ε, C)
with
∂E
<0
∂F
∂E
>0
∂F
∂E
>0
∂C
C = EF + wEh if h ≤ ho
C = EF + wEho + w̃E(h − ho ) if h > ho
Let the production function be equal to y = Eh β . The firm can be in two possible
positions. It uses overtime or it does not use overtime. The two situations are depicted
in Fig. 3.4. Let’s first study a firm that uses overtime. The formal problem is
w̃
βh −1 =
F + who + w̃(h − ho )
βF + βwh0 + β w̃h − β w̃h0 = h w̃
βF + βh0 (w − w̃)
h= h > ho
w̃(1 − β)
44 THE HOURS–EMPLOYMENT TRADE-OFF
Substituting this into the production function and rearranging, the optimal E reads
βF + βh0 (w − w̃) −β
E = ȳ
w(1 − β)
A reduction in the normal workweek induces a reduction in the number of employees.
To see this simply take the partial derivative of the log to obtain.
∂ log E
= −β
∂ log h0
4 Temporary or
Permanent?
4.1 Introduction
One of the key issues at the hiring stage concerns the type of contract that
should be offered to the firm’s workforce. In this chapter, we discuss the key
decisions in terms of the length of the contract: open-ended versus fixed-
term contract. Alternatively, as such contracts are called in Europe, the firm
has to choose between a permanent or a temporary contract. This choice is
particularly relevant when two conditions hold. First, employment protec-
tion legislation is stringent, and terminating a contract is an expensive activity.
Second, uncertainty over business conditions plays an important role. If a con-
tract can be terminated at no cost, the difference between temporary contract
and permanent contract is irrelevant. Further, if business conditions do not
fluctuate, hiring decisions are not going to be followed by separation decisions,
and the type of contract is irrelevant.
In this chapter we assume that terminating a contract involves some costs
to the employer and that business conditions can be good or bad. We study
three scenarios. First, as a baseline scenario, we consider a firm that can offer
only permanent contracts that can never be broken. Business conditions can be
good or bad, but employment cannot be adjusted in response to such changes.
We study the optimal labour demand in this condition, and we compare it
with the employment decision of a firm that is fully flexible, and can hire at
will workers on a temporary basis. We find that the rigidity imposed on the
firm affects its profitability, but has no impact on the average employment.
Indeed, the average employment of the rigid firm is the same as the average
employment of a flexible firm.
Second, we consider what happens when a firm has the possibility of com-
bining temporary and permanent contracts. The idea in this scenario is that
a buffer of temporary contracts can be used in conjunction with a stock of
permanent contracts. We show that under these conditions the constrained
firm can do as well as the flexible firm.
Third, we study the buffer stock model under an additional real life phe-
nomenon, namely the fact that hiring a temporary worker requires the use of
a costly interim agency. This implies that the cost of temporary workers also
includes the mark-up paid to temporary firms. Such a phenomenon will show
46 TEMPORARY OR PERMANENT?
that the additional cost imposed by the interim agency has important effects
on the firm’s hiring strategy. We will see that in this scenario a firm can hire
an additional amount of permanent workers (with respect to a pure buffer
model), just to save on future agency costs.
In real life labour markets, some firms offer temporary contracts while other
firms offer permanent contracts. We want to understand how this choice is
determined when terminating permanent contracts is not illegal, but requires
some costs. We thus study the trade-off between temporary and permanent
contracts when labour turnover is costly. We assume that permanent contracts
can be terminated at some cost, while temporary contracts can be terminated at
no cost. Further, we assume also that workers under temporary contracts have
a higher probability of leaving the firm, and their replacement is not necessarily
immediate. We will see that under this condition a trade-off emerges, and it is
not always optimal to hire under temporary or permanent contracts. A brief
look at the evidence completes the chapter.
Y = A i log L,
É This is obtained by taking the derivative of the production function with respect to L. Notably,
∂A i log L i
∂L = AL .
TEMPORARY OR PERMANENT? 47
and firing can take place at no cost, and the firm can choose its employment
level after observing the realization of the value of A. The firm in the flexible
regime hires workers on a temporary basis. In the rigid regime, the firm can only
choose the average employment, so that there are only permanent contracts that
can never be broken. Firms can offer only permanent contracts, and firing is
impossible. Once employment is decided it can never be changed.
In the next section we consider an additional regime, mainly the buffer
regime, which involves the possibility that the firm combines temporary and
permanent contracts.
F 10 log L − WL if A = A h
=
4 log L − WL if A = A l
The solution to the firm employment should just be such that the marginal
product is equal to the wage in good and bad times, as in a simple and static
model of labour demand. Since the wage is 1, the optimal employment is equal
to 4 in bad times and 10 in good times. Figure 4.1 also plots the marginal
product curve and the wage. Since the probability of having good and bad
times is equal to 0.5, the average employment of the flexible firm is simply
7. The firm hires six workers when business conditions improve and fires six
workers when business conditions worsen.
Consider now the rigid firm. The firm should choose a level of employment
that maximizes average profits. Such a level of employment would never be
changed. The average profits are
The value of the profits function R is easily computed in the table, and the
optimal employment level corresponds to an employment level equal to 7.
Figure 4.2 shows clearly that this is the point at which profits are maximum.
We are now in a position to derive three important empirical implications on
the effect of the protection regimes.
48 TEMPORARY OR PERMANENT?
4
Marginal productivity in bad times
3
0
2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Employment
Flexible economy
14 in good times
12
10
Profits rigid economy
8
6
Flexible economy
4
in bad times
2
0
2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15
–2
–4
–6
Employment
Notes: Good times shifter Ah = 10; bad times shifter Al = 4; wage w = 1; probability p = 0.5.
profits of the flexible economy. Table 4.2 shows that profits are larger and
equal to 7.29 in the flexible case (the average between 13.03 and 1.55),
against 6.62 in the rigid case.
Let us now consider the buffer regime. The idea is that the firm can hire workers
under temporary contracts, and can use a combination of temporary and
permanent contracts. A stock of permanent contracts is hired in good and bad
times, while temporary workers are used as a buffer stock when conditions
improve. Table 4.2 shows that a firm that follows such a policy can reach a level
of profits identical to a flexible firm. Basically, the firm has four permanent
workers and six temporary workers when conditions improve.
Flexible
Employment 10.00 4.00 7.00
Profits 13.03 1.55 7.29
Rigid
Employment 7.00 7.00 7.00
Profits 12.46 0.78 6.62
Rigid with temporary
Permanent employment 4.00 4.00 4.00
Temporary employment 6.00 0.00 3.00
Profits 13.03 1.55 7.29
Rigid with costly interima
Permanent employment 5.00 5.00 5.00
Interim employment 3.00 0.00 1.50
Profits 12.04 1.44 6.74
Permanent employment 4.00 4.00 4.00
Interim employment 4.00 0.00 2.00
Profits 11.79 1.55 6.67
which implies, after taking the derivative of the profits with respect to L
Ai
=w i = h, l,
L
Ai
Li =
w
Al
if A = A l
L= w
Ah
w if A = A h
The flexible firm chooses the level of employment after having observed
the level of productivity. Since the wage is fixed and equal to w, the flexible
firm will fire (hire) L = A w−A when the economy moves from high (low)
h l
F (1 − p)A l + pA h
L =
w
Rigid Firm. Let us examine, now, the behaviour of the firm when it is forced to
hire only permanent contracts. In other words, an extremely strict employment
protection regime is in place, and it is not possible to change employment after
productivity changes. In this situation, the best thing the rigid firm can do is
TEMPORARY OR PERMANENT? 51
to choose the employment that maximizes the expected value of the profits. In
formulas, this implies that the employer R will resolve the following problem:
R = MaxL E A i log L − wL ,
where E indicates the expected value of the profits. The being wage fixed, to
eliminate the expected value from the previous expression it is sufficient to
replace the expected value of production, so that the problem of the employer
becomes:
R = MaxL [(1 − p)A l + pA h ] log L − wL .
R (1 − p)AL + pAH
L =
w
R
The value L is some average between the level of employment in the flexible
R
country during the expansions and its level during recessions. Moreover, L
coincides with A /W if the economy is always in low productivity (p = 0). If
l
lay-offs are not allowed, the firm in the rigid regime does not experience any
fluctuation as a result of variations in the productivity level.
We are now in a position to derive three important empirical implications
on the effect of the protection regimes.
The idea is that the firm can hire a stock of permanent contracts independently
of business conditions while it can hire workers under temporary contracts
when conditions are good, and dismiss such contracts when conditions are
bad. Following the algebra derived in Appendix 4.1, one can show that the
stock of permanent workers is equal to employment.
The firm has the following hiring policy:
Al
if A = A l
L = Al wAh −Al
w + w if A = A h
In the next section we analyse the role of specific additional costs associated
with temporary contracts.
TEMPORARY OR PERMANENT? 53
L perm if A = A l
L=
L perm + L interim if A = A h
where L perm are the permanent workers hired in bad times and L interim are
the interim workers hired when conditions turn good. The key question in
this context is how the existence of the interim fee modifies the employment
position of the firm with respect to a pure buffer stock model with µ = 0.
The firm’s position in good business conditions is not difficult to determine,
since it is simply obtained by the intersection between the marginal product in
good times (when A = A h ) and the marginal labour costs, which in this case
are equal to w(1 + µ). The position is described by point C in Fig. 4.3. In good
times the firm is hiring less labour than the case of µ = 0, indicated by point
B in the figure. This is not surprising, and it is simply linked to the increase in
the marginal labour cost.
The determination of employment in bad times is more subtle. In bad times
the firm is not going to hire interim workers. This should not be controver-
sial. The difficult question is how many permanent workers should be hired.
During bad times the firm knows that good times will eventually come in the
future, and that hiring of interim workers involves a mark-up µ on the wage.
As a way to partly avoid future hiring costs, the firm may have an incentive to
‘overhire’ permanent workers in bad times, or in any case to hire more perman-
ent workers than would be the case if µ were zero. Nevertheless, the firm is also
aware that permanent workers hired beyond L L in Fig. 4.3 are associated with
some loss, since for such workers the marginal product is lower than the wage.
A trade-off emerges in this situation, but it is likely that some overemployment
of permanent workers is going to take place. Indeed, the algebra derived in the
54 TEMPORARY OR PERMANENT?
W
MPLH
MPLL
C
w (1 + m)
D
B
LL L perm Lp + Lt LH L
= AH/ w = AH/ w
LR
=[ pAH + (1 – p)AL ]/w
From the previous condition one can immediately see that the employment
solution collapses to a simple buffer stock model whenever µ = 0. Further,
labour hoarding increases with the size of the interim fee: The larger the interim
fee, the larger is labour hoarding.
To formally establish this point one has simply to differentiate the employ-
ment level in bad times with respect to µ, and find that the result is
positive.Ê
∂ A l pw
= >0
∂L [(1 − p)w − pwµ]2
TEMPORARY OR PERMANENT? 55
3 Marginal productivity
in good times
2.5 Marginal
productivity
Wage with mark-up for
in bad times
temporary agencies
2
1.5
1
Labour
0.5 hoarding
0
2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Employment
The numerical example in Fig. 4.4 further confirms this point. Using the
same numerical assumptions analysed in the previous section, with the addi-
tional assumption that the mark-up wage for temporary workers under interim
is equal to µ = 0.25, the marginal wage in good times is equal to 1.25, so that
the firm should hire eight workers when business conditions are good. The
interesting dimension is to study what the optimal employment level is in bad
times, and thus the number of permanent and temporary (interim) workers.
emerges, and the firm will choose different types of contracts in different
circumstances. The model is described as follows.
There are two periods. A firm has to fill in a vacant job, and there is some
positive expected profit associated with the employment relationship. The key
choice of the firm is whether a temporary or a permanent contract should be
offered. A permanent contract in this context is a two-period contract, or a
long-term contract, while a temporary contract is a one-period contract. The
wage w is the same for both temporary and permanent contracts and it is set
outside the firm. This is a reasonable assumption for most imperfect labour
markets. The productivity in the first period is fixed at y. When the worker is
offered a temporary contract (which lasts one period), the job can terminate at
no cost at the beginning of period 2. When the worker is offered a permanent
contract (which is basically a two-period contract) the firm can terminate the
job at a cost equal to −T . The productivity in the second period is random.
With probability δ the productivity in the second period is very low and the job
needs to be destroyed. With probability (1 − δ) the productivity in the second
period stays at y. Jobs filled by temporary contracts terminate with probability
λ, since workers may quit and find another job somewhere else. If the worker
leaves, the firm has a chance to find a replacement. However, the firm’s ability
to replace the worker has some limit, and we assume that there is a positive
probability that a replacement is not found. We call q the probability that the
firm successfully finds another worker.
We focus on the present discounted value (PDV ) of having workers under
different types of contract. Let’s call J perm the PDV of filling the job with a
permanent job. The point of view that we take is the firm’s, but the problem is
dynamic. The formal expression of J perm reads
−δT + (1 − δ)(y − w)
J perm = y − w + ,
1+r
where in the second period, δ is the probability that the job ends because there
is a negative productivity shock. If the job is destroyed (at rate δ) the firm needs
to pay the cost T . If the job is continued (with probability 1 − δ), the firm nets
y − w in the second period. The PDV of a vacancy filled with a temporary job
is indicated by J temp and its expression reads
(1 − δ)[(1 − λ)(y − w) + λq(y − w)]
J temp = y − w + ,
1+r
where the job is continued only if the productivity in the second period remains
at y (an event which happens with probability 1 − δ). Conditional on the
productivity remaining high, and thus the job continuing, two possibilities
emerge. If the worker does not leave (which happens with probability (1 − λ))
production takes place and the firm nets y − w. If the worker leaves (which
happens with probability λ, the firm nets y − w if and only if the worker is
successfully replaced, an event that takes place with probability q.
TEMPORARY OR PERMANENT? 57
Ë Notable, ∂
perm (1−δ)λ(1−q)] perm (1−δ)(y−w)(1−q)] perm perm
∂(y−w) = 1+r > 0; ∂∂λ = 1+r ; and ∂∂r = − 1+r .
58 TEMPORARY OR PERMANENT?
Gender
Female 12.2
Male 10.5
Age groups
15–24 25.0
25–54 8.0
55+ 9.4
Educational attainment
Low 15.7
Medium 10.4
High 9.3
Industry
Agriculture 21.9
Manufacturing 9.6
Service 10.8
Occupation
White collar 7.7
Pink collar 10.6
Blue collar 9.2
Unskilled 15.3
temporary contract, whereas the overall percentage is around 11 per cent. This
is consistent with the view that youth workers entering the labour market are
offered a temporary contract. The fact that women are, on average, more likely
than men to hold a temporary contract is also consistent with this view, since
women have less labour market attachment than men.
Looking at other individual characteristics, it is clear that temporary con-
tracts are more likely among individuals with low educational attachment,
employed in agriculture, and in unskilled occupations.
An important and interesting dimension to consider is to ask what hap-
pens, in a dynamic perspective, to workers hired under temporary contracts.
Are such workers likely to transit into permanent jobs, or are they more likely
to stay in a temporary contract? Table 4.4 throws some light on this question.
The table reports the status of unemployed workers as well as workers hired
on temporary and permanent contracts twelve and thirty-six months after the
first observations. The evidence refers to different European countries. The
table should be read as follows. For each country (say France) the three rows in
the table indicate the employed status of workers in 1996; where the employ-
ment status can be ‘permanent’, ‘temporary’, and ‘unemployed’ respectively.
The columns labelled status in 1997 report the labour market position of such
workers twelve months after the first observation, while the columns labelled
status in 1999 report the labour market status at a three-year distance.
Let’s start with the unemployed workers. In most countries, and France
in particular, unemployed workers are much more likely to find a temporary
contract than a permanent contract. This is obviously consistent with the idea
that labour market entrance takes place through a temporary contract. Looking
at the row on temporary contracts, Table 4.4 suggests that workers hired on
60 TEMPORARY OR PERMANENT?
temporary contracts are much more likely to remain in such a situation than
to switch to a job with a permanent contract, even at a distance of three years
from the first observation.
5.1 Introduction
Throughout the hiring process, as long as a worker is not fully involved in
the firm’s activities, the firm is likely to have imperfect information about the
worker’s productivity. Such information is more likely to be known to the
worker. This implies that the hiring process is characterized by an asymmet-
ric information problem, since workers know more about their own ability
than the firm does. In the hiring process, the uninformed party is the firm,
while the informed party is the worker. This chapter analyses this asymmetric
information problem in detail, and studies which personnel policies can partly
overcome it.
The firm has a vacant job, and offers the possibility of applying for such
a job to a variety of workers. We are in a situation in which the uninformed
party (the firm) offers an option to the informed party (the worker). In the
economics of imperfect information, each time an uninformed party offers an
option to the informed party, the problem of adverse selection may arise. We
say that a firm has a problem of adverse selection each time the wrong type of
workers are attracted to the firm. Dealing with adverse selection in recruiting
means finding a set of policies that ensures that only the suitable candidates are
attracted to the firm. Dealing with the wrong type of candidates is a very costly
and time-consuming process. Conversely, a properly managed hiring strategy
can save costly resources.
There are two key ways of dealing with adverse selection in hiring. The first
way relies on wage flexibility and on the design of the labour contract. We
distinguish two such types of ‘contingent’ contract: piece rate, and temporary
contracts with a probation period. The second way of dealing with adverse
selection is the use of credentials (specify workers’ characteristics in detail).
We briefly describe these mechanisms.
The first part of the chapter introduces wage policies and contingent con-
tracts, and shows how the availability of wage flexibility can help the firm to
solve the adverse selection problem in hiring. The idea of a contingent con-
tract is to specify the wage rules of the job in such a way that only the ‘right’
type of worker is attracted to the job. We highlight these phenomena with two
types of contract that we label (i) piece rate and (ii) temporary contract with
probation wage.
MANAGING ADVERSE SELECTION IN RECRUITING 63
Piece rate is the simplest contingent contract, with pay that is strictly based
on output: the larger the output, the larger the total pay. What the firm must
do in this case is to select a wage per piece that will be attractive only to suitable
workers. A piece rate solves the adverse selection problem if ‘good’ candidates
are attracted by the firm wage and ‘bad’ candidates do not apply. The actual
implementation of a piece rate requires output to be perfectly measurable.
In most professional jobs, notably law firms or consulting firms, output is
difficult to measure, and a pure piece rate is a very difficult mechanism to
implement. In such cases firms may use probationary periods for dealing with
adverse selection. The idea of a probationary period is that firms take ‘some
time’ to learn the ability of the workers. High-ability workers are promoted and
tenured, while low-ability workers are dismissed. To deal with adverse selection,
the firm has an incentive to reduce the probationary wage (which is paid to both
suitable and unsuitable workers) and increase the promotion wage (which is
paid only to promoted workers). Under specific circumstances, which depend
also on the firm’s ability to perfectly monitor ‘bad’ workers at the end of the
probation, this multi-period wage can offer a solution to adverse selection.
In imperfect labour markets, the wage flexibility required to implement con-
tingent contracts is often not available to individual firms. As we have argued
several times, a large part of the wage is often decided outside the individual
firm. If this is the case, firms cannot rely on sophisticated wage contracts, and
other instruments need to be implemented. The chapter considers in some
detail the use of credentials, or the possibility of linking the wage offered to
the level of education. The idea explored in the second part of the chapter
is that education, the most widely used credential, can work as a signal of a
candidate’s productivity. Firms do not observe ability, but can and do observe
whether individuals obtain a degree. If the probability of acquiring the signal
(i.e. the probability of graduation) is correlated to the performance on the job,
a signalling equilibrium may arise. In such context, firms are willing to pay a
wage premium to individuals with a degree. In turn, high-ability individuals
have an incentive to undertake the costly signal, in expectation of future wages.
In a signalling equilibrium, the credential works and the problem of adverse
selection is alleviated.
The chapter proceeds as follows. In section 5.2 we analyse the two contin-
gent contracts: the piece rate and the probationary wage. Section 5.3 analyses
credentials, and presents the model of educational signalling in a formal and
an informal way.
A piece rate is a wage per unit of output. Let us assume that the firm can
choose the piece rate. The problem is to select a value of the piece wage wp
so that only skilled workers join. To solve for wage wp the firm should look at
the problem from the point of view of each worker. By properly solving the
problem faced by each different worker, the firm can then select the appropriate
piece rate.
Skilled Unskilled
outside option ws wu
output ys yu ys > yu
Ws/Ys Wu /Yu
Figure 5.1. Piece rate wage for solving adverse selection in recruitment
Obviously the condition for this scheme to work is that the two regions
in Fig. 5.1 do intersect. This is equivalent to saying that the left-hand side of
equation (5.1) is smaller than the right-hand side of equation (5.2):
ws wu
≤
ys yu
which can also be written as (inverting the ratio and changing the inequality
sign):
ys yu
≥
ws wu
ys ws
≥ .
yu wu
The last condition requires that the proportional increase in the productivity
of skilled workers is larger than the proportional increase in their respective
outside wage. Such a condition is very similar to the condition used for hiring
skilled workers in the case of independent production analysed in Chapter 2.É
Note that the piece rate is a very simple and effective way to solve the adverse
selection problem in hiring. Yet, for it to work at least three key conditions must
be satisfied.
1. Wages must be perfectly flexible and the firm must be able to apply
different wages to different workers.
2. Workers must correctly estimate their outside option. If they do not do
so (i.e. yu = ys ), there is no way you can use piece rate for hiring.
3. Output must be properly measured.
The first condition applies to any contingent contract, not only to piece
rate, and it is a serious limit to the use of these schemes in many imperfect
labour markets with serious institutional constraints. Similar comments can
É Note that if ys /yu = 1 + δ and ws /wu = 1 + γ , the condition is analogous to δ > γ .
MANAGING ADVERSE SELECTION IN RECRUITING 67
be applied to the second condition. The last condition is probably the most
important, and deserves few comments. Pure piece rate is more likely to be
applied in occupations in which the job output is easily identified. Obvious
examples are sales jobs or basic production activities, such as those found in the
garment industry (the case study on team production of Chapter 13 provides
such an example), or traditional manufacturing jobs. For professional jobs,
such as managing consultants or law firms, piece rates are very difficult to
implement. The next section considers an alternative scenario.
Numerical Example
Assume ws = 10, wu = 5, ys = 5, and yu = 2. The conditions for attracting
skilled workers require wp ∗ 5 ≥ 10, so that wp ≥ 2 and simultaneously
wp ∗ 2 ≤ 5 or a level of wp that is less than 2.5. This means that a piece wage
between 2 and 2.5 would solve the problem. Note that in this case ys /yu = 2.5
which is greater than ws /wu = 2, and a piece rate can be found.
which a tenured wage w2 is offered. In reality the second period, when the
worker is tenured, is much longer than the probationary period. While one
can certainly further complicate the problem and take into consideration the
length of the second period, in what follows we work with the simplest scheme.
There are two types of workers, skilled workers and unskilled workers, where
the word skilled refers to the ability of each worker to perform inside the firm.
Skilled and unskilled workers have different outside options, which we indicate
respectively with ws and wu . Finally, we assume that at the end of the first
period, the firm is not perfectly able to recognize a skilled worker. Specifically,
we assume that there is a probability p that an unskilled worker passes the
probationary period and it is tenured inside the firm. There is no discounting
of future wages. To summarize, we consider the following definitions
ws : skilled worker alternative wage
wu : unskilled worker alternative wage
w1 : probationary wage
w2 : post-probationary wage
p: probability that an unskilled worker passes the probationary stage
The problem of the firm is to select w1 and w2 so that only skilled workers
join the firm. We first solve the problem in assuming a perfect monitoring
technology, so that p = 0. In the second part of the section we consider the
problem with a positive probability of ‘wrong promotion’ p.
outside wage. The right-hand side is the cumulative wage obtained outside,
and it is simply the outside wage for two periods. The latter equation implies
that to keep unskilled workers out it suffices to have
w1 ≤ wu
or to set a wage under temporary contract lower than the unskilled worker’s
outside wage. Since the temporary wage will be offered also to permanent
workers, the condition (5.3) requires
w2 ≥ 2ws − w1
This condition says that the promotion wage must be larger than the cumu-
lative value of the outside wage (2ws ) net of the first period wage. If we satisfy
the two constraints with equality (in assuming that skilled workers do not
participate if indifferent and skilled workers do participate if indifferent), and
we indicate with w1∗ and w2∗ , the solution to this problem reads
w1∗ = wu
w2∗ = ws + (ws − wu )
The idea of the solution is simple. The first period wage should be as low
as the outside option of the unskilled workers, so that the job would not be
suitable for unskilled workers (who will be fired for sure at the end of the first
period). The confirmation wage conversely should be larger than the outside
option of the skilled worker. Indeed, in the second period a skilled worker
should get his outside wage, plus a compensation premium for the loss of
income obtained in the first period. This suggests that the high wage enjoyed
by the skilled workers in the second period corresponds to a compensation for
their income loss during the first period. Let’s define the pre-post probation
wage differential as the difference between the wage in the second period and
the wage in the second period, so that = w2∗ − w1∗ . The following applies:
The pre-post probation wage differential wage increases with the outside
skilled differential ws − wu .
This is immediately confirmed by substituting in the definition of the
expression w2∗ and w1∗ . It follows that = 2(ws − wu ). The larger the outside
skilled differentials ws − wu the larger the compensation that the firm must
provide to the skilled worker in the second period.
An extreme form of this type of contract is the internship, a type of contract
that is often offered to just-graduate students. The idea of an internship is that
the worker can work for the firm for wage equal to 0 for an initial short period,
and at the end of the internship obtain a large wage as a permanent contract.
The firm can then set a first period wage equal to w1 = 0 and a second period
70 MANAGING ADVERSE SELECTION IN RECRUITING
so that
2ws − (1 + p)wu
w2∗ =
1−p
from which it follows that the probationary wage is
2ws − (1 + p)wu
w1∗ = 2ws −
1−p
2ws − 2pws − 2ws + (1 + p)wu
=
1−p
(1 + p)wu − 2pws
=
1−p
The probationary wage is such that w1∗ < wu < ws and w2∗ > ws . In other
words the probationary wage requires that the initial wage is lower than the
outside unskilled wage while the post-probationary wage is larger than the
outside skilled wage.
First let’s check that w1∗ < wu . The latter condition is true as long as
(1 + p)wu − 2pws
< wu
1−p
(1 + p)wu − 2pws < wu − pwu
−2pws < −2pwu
ws > wu QED
Let’s define the pre-post probationary wage spread as or, in other terms,
= w2∗ − w1∗
2ws − (1 + p)wu (1 + p)wu − 2pws
= −
1−p 1−p
2(1 + p)(ws − wu )
=
1−p
72 MANAGING ADVERSE SELECTION IN RECRUITING
Numerical Example
Let us assume that wu = 2 and ws = 5 while the probability of passing the test
is p = 0.1. It is easy to check that the two conditions are
1.1 ∗ 2 − 2 ∗ (0.1) ∗ 5
w1∗ ≤
0.9
∗
w1 ≤ 1.33
w2∗ ≥ 10 − w1∗
so that if we offer w1∗ = 1.33 the corresponding w2∗ = 8.66. If the first period
wage is reduced (let’s say to w1∗ = 1) the second period wage must be increased
to 9.
longer perfectly obvious that a firm will be able to offer contingent contracts.
We now try to understand under which circumstances a contingent contract
with minimum wage is a viable option. We analyse this issue in the case of a
probationary period, under the assumption that the minimum wage is binding,
so that the wage of the first period must be equal to a minimum wage w̄. The
question we ask is whether it is still possible to have a wage profile w̄, w2 so
that unskilled workers do not join the firm. We initially assume that the best
alternative option of an unskilled candidate is larger than the minimum wage
(wu > w̄) and we analyse the alternative case at the end of this section. What
we want to show here is that a probationary scheme will work only if the
monitoring technology is sufficiently good, so that the probability of a wrong
promotion is sufficiently small. Let’s see the key conditions.
To attract skilled workers it is necessary that
w̄ + w2 ≥ 2ws
where the first period wage w1 is now identical to the minimum wage w̄. To
keep unskilled workers out, it is necessary that
w̄ + pw2 + (1 − p)wu ≤ 2wu
which is very similar to equation 5.2, with the only key difference being that
the first period wage is no longer an endogenous variable of the firm, but it is
set equal to w̄.
If we satisfy the first constraint with an equals sign (so as to make the
skilled workers just indifferent between working for the firm and their outside
option), the promotion wage is
w2 = 2ws − w̄.
Substituting this requirement into the second equation we see that the
condition is satisfied if
wu − w̄
p<
2ws − [wu + w̄]
from which immediately follows:
1. Only if the risk of wrong promotion (i.e. promoting an unskilled worker)
is sufficiently small (p < p ∗ ) does a probationary period with minimum
u −w̄
wage solve the adverse selection problem, where p ∗ = 2ws w−[w u −w̄]
.
2. If the outside option of the unskilled worker is exactly equal to the min-
imum wage wu = w̄, there is no way to use a probationary contract to
solve the adverse selection problem.
The last remark shows that wu > w̄ is a necessary condition for the pro-
bationary period to work. Indeed, if the outside wage is smaller than the
74 MANAGING ADVERSE SELECTION IN RECRUITING
k
c(s = 1, a) =
a
76 MANAGING ADVERSE SELECTION IN RECRUITING
where k is a positive constant. Since a can take only two values, the cost function
is equivalent to
The previous conditions imply that high-ability students have lower costs of
education, so that
cost of education for low ability > cost of education for high ability
Education attainment is observable to the firms. While firms are not able to
offer contracts that are linked to the ability of the candidates, they are able
to offer contracts that are linked to the educational attainment. A separating
equilibrium is a situation in which only high-ability individuals acquire the
educational signal and firms offer wage premia to educated individuals. If this
situation happens in the marketplace, then the use of credentials acts as a
device that solves the adverse selection problems of firms.
To see how a separating equilibrium may emerge suppose that firms expect
that only high-ability workers receive education and so they are willing to offer
a high wage to a candidate that has attained education. When this is the case
high-ability workers may have an incentive to acquire the signal in exchange
for future wage gains. Conversely, low-ability workers find such an option too
costly, and do not acquire the educational signal.
Figure 5.2 describes a signalling equilibrium. In the horizontal axis there is
the education level. Note that only two points are relevant, the origin s = 0
and the point s = 1, since we are assuming that only two types of education
are available in the marketplace. In the vertical axis we report the wage paid
for each educational level as well as the cost of education. The wage offered
by the firms is w = ah for individuals with high education and w = al for
individuals with low education attainment. The upward sloping line reports
the cost of education for the two types of workers. Low-ability individuals
have a steeper cost function, since acquiring the education signal involves a
larger cost.
How will each individual decide whether investing in education is worth
the cost? Let’s consider low-ability individuals first. If they do not acquire the
signal they enjoy a net return equal to the segment Ao in the figure, since
point A corresponds to the wage wl and the cost of education is zero. If they
acquire the signal they will get a wage wh but will have to pay the cost up to
point C so that the net value of utility will be equal to the segment BC. Since
the segment Ao is larger than BC, low-ability individuals will choose s = 0.
Let’s now consider the high-ability individual. By a similar argument the high-
ability individual should compare the segment BD (which is the value when
MANAGING ADVERSE SELECTION IN RECRUITING 77
Wage,
cost of education
Cost for
Slope low ability
k /al
B
WH = ah
C Cost for
high ability
A Wl = alow
D
o
S=1 s, educational
level
Slope
k /ah
he or she acquires education) with the segment Ao. It is clear that high-ability
individuals select the education signal. In other words, Fig. 5.2 describes a
separating equilibrium. Individuals do acquire the credentials and the firms
value such a signal in equilibrium. Under these circumstances the firm is able
to fully learn the worker type.
Things can be very different if the firm believes that an individual with
a degree has the same chances of being high or low ability. In other words,
the firm may expect that the possession of the credentials has no link to the
probability of finding a good candidate. Under such circumstances the firm
will post only a single wage and there will be no wage premium linked to better
educational attainment. This is called a pooling equilibrium, a situation that
is described in Fig. 5.3. In this situation, both individuals have no incentive
to acquire the costly signal, so that both types (high and low) choose not to
acquire the education signal. This discussion highlights the fact that firm’s
beliefs play a key role in shaping the emergence of a separating equilibrium.
The next section explicitly considers firm profits and the role played by firm’s
beliefs.Ê
Ê Note further that the nature of the separating equilibrium lends support to the claim that education
per se is useless or even pernicious, because it imposes social costs but does not increase total output.
Of course such a view is extreme, and education has a lot to do with human capital accumulation, as
Chapters 9 and 10 on training will show.
78 MANAGING ADVERSE SELECTION IN RECRUITING
Wage,
cost of education
Cost for
low ability
k/al
F Cost for
high ability
W
D
G
S=1 s, educational
o
S=0 level
k/ah
Let’s define the employers’ beliefs as the probability that the type is low,
conditional on being educated as p(a = Low|s = 1), and let us assume that
s(low) = s(high) = 0
w(0) = w(1) = 0.5
p(a = Low|s = 1) = 0.5
This implies that education is useless, since it does not yield any wage premium.
In this condition, the model reaches the unsurprising outcome that workers do
not bother to acquire unproductive education. Note that under this scenario
the beliefs are simple passive conjecture, since s = 1 is never observed in
equilibrium. It is clear that for the high-ability type it does not make sense for
him to educate himself, since the employer would not reward his effort through
higher wages. Further, firms make zero expected profits since the average ability
is equal to the average wage.
p(a = Low|s = 1) = 0
This leads to the separating equilibrium for which signalling is best known, in
which the high-ability worker acquires education to prove to employers that
he really has high ability. The separating equilibrium is such that
s(Low) = 0
s(High) = 1
w(0) = 2
w(1) = 5.5
How can we check that this is really an equilibrium? We need to check that the
separating contract maximizes the utility of the high and low types subject to
MANAGING ADVERSE SELECTION IN RECRUITING 81
two constraints:
Participation constraints that the firms can offer the contract without
making losses;
Self-selection constraints that the lows are not attracted to the high contract,
and the highs are not attracted by the low contract.
The participation constraints for the employer requires that
w(0) ≤ aL = 2
w(1) ≤ aH = 5.5
but competition between employers makes the expressions above hold as
equalities, so that the employers make zero profits.
The self-selection constraint of the lows is
UL (s = 0) ≥ UL (s = 1)
8∗1
w(0) − 0 ≥ w(1) −
2
2 ≥ 5.5 − 4
2 ≥ 1.5
which is satisfied.
The self-selection constraint of the highs is
UH (s = 1) ≥ UH (s = 0)
8∗1
w(1) − ≥ w(0) − 0
5.5
5.5 − 1.45 ≥ 2
4.05 ≥ 2
which is also satisfied.
Separation is possible because education is more costly for workers if their
ability is lower. If education costs the same for both types of worker, education
would not work as a signal, because the low-ability workers would imitate the
high-ability workers. The nature of the separating equilibrium lends support
to the claim that education per se is useless or even pernicious, because it
imposes social costs but does not increase total output.
6 Optimal Compensation
Schemes: Foundation
6.1 Introduction
Choosing an appropriate compensation mechanism is probably the core prob-
lem of human resource managers, and represents the heart of personnel
economics. Loosely speaking good compensation packages must be consistent
with profit maximization on the part of firms, but they should also provide
workers with the incentives to do as well as possible. If we pay the worker
independently of his or her performance, most likely we will not provide him
or her with the right incentives to act in the interest of the firm. In the jar-
gon of the economics of imperfect information, the problem with a fully fixed
salary is one of moral hazard. The term moral hazard arises in the insurance
market and refers to the fact that a person who has insurance coverage will
have less incentive to take proper care of insured objects than a person who
does not.
Here is an example. A worker who sells computers for a small company has
to decide how much effort to put into selling the hardware. The number of
computers sold certainly depends on how hard she works, but the total sales
will also depend on other factors, like customer willingness to buy computers.
Such factors are outside the worker’s control. At the end of the month the
company will observe the number of computers sold, but will not observe how
much effort she put into the task. A very good month’s volume of sales can
certainly depend on hard work (we will call it effort in this chapter) but can also
simply depend on a surge in demand totally unrelated to effort. The question
we need to ask is, how much effort will the worker put into her task? Such
effort will obviously depend on the structure of compensation. If the worker is
paid a fixed salary independent of the computers sold, she is much more likely
to take it easy. This is because with a fixed salary the worker is fully insured
against changes in the number of computers sold. Indeed, if the pay does not
depend on how hard a worker tries, why should she bother to exercise effort?
It seems that under straight salary (which corresponds to full insurance) the
worker, who in this chapter is called the agent, is doing something that the boss
would rather not do. Obviously, it is very difficult for the firm to prove that
OPTIMAL COMPENSATION SCHEMES 83
the worker did not work enough by simply looking at sales, since it is also
possible that the low sales were due to low customer demand. This conflict of
interest is at the heart of the moral hazard problem. What is good for the agent
is not (necessarily) good for the principal, and the principal cannot always be
on hand to monitor what the agent does.
The only way in which the firm can solve this problem is by choosing
an appropriate compensation scheme. Pay for performance, or compensation
packages that link the worker’s salary to the number of computers sold, are
likely to be the solution to the problem. In this chapter we will find that there
exists an extreme incentive scheme that is likely to be the solution to our
problem. In the extreme scheme the worker ends up making a fixed up-front
payment to the firm at the beginning of the month, and thereafter acts as a
sort of entrepreneur. In other words, the worker ‘buys’ the job from the firm,
and then acts as a residual claimant on the revenues obtained. This scheme
corresponds to a labour contract with a 100 per cent commission rate. The
salesman keeps all the revenues from the sales, and pays the firm a fixed fee.
Yet further problems exist. The first problem is whether such a scheme is
technically feasible. It is often impossible for the firm to obtain a payment from
the worker. Negative payments are simply not allowed. We will see that in this
case the firm will have to change its optimal compensation scheme.
Second, the discussion so far has not dealt with an important factor: risk.
The worker is likely to be risk averse, and she is likely to prefer income streams
that are time invariant to income streams that change dramatically from month
to month. We will see that also in this case, the optimal compensation scheme
will have to be changed slightly.
We can summarize the problem of the compensation package with the
following key questions.
The principal/firm has two problems:
Agent/worker problem Number 1: If the agent accepts the contract and goes
to work for this principal, how hard should she work on that job?
Agent/worker problem Number 2: Once she knows how hard it is optimal
to work, should she accept such a contract?
84 OPTIMAL COMPENSATION SCHEMES
x = (e + η),
x̄ = E(x) = e
É A more formal way to describe what was said in the text it is to assume that
A compensation package offered to the worker is a wage contract that specifies a fixed wage
component, independent of revenues, and a variable wage component.2
= β2v
The variance will play an important role when we introduce risk-averse workers.
86 OPTIMAL COMPENSATION SCHEMES
We
W e = a +pe;
W e = a + be; b < p
W e= a
2. Bonus Scheme (0 < β < p), so that the compensation scheme is made
up of a fixed component plus a variable bonus, which is proportional
to output. The larger the coefficient β, the larger the sensitivity of the
compensation scheme to the revenues obtained.
3. Franchising Schemes (β = p; α < 0). In this scheme all the extra output
is given to the worker, so that he becomes a residual claimant in the
project. Under this pay scheme, the agent is an entrepreneur who rents a
job, and the firm makes money by choosing the fixed payment α.
where δ is simply a parameter that reflects how much the worker dislikes
effort. In the utility function, 1 additional euro of income yields one addi-
tional utils, while an additional unit of effort yields a disutility equal to
δe. This implies that the marginal utility of income is constant, while the
marginal disutility of effort is increasing. At the margin, increasing effort
becomes more and more costly to the individual, while additional income
yields the same utility level.Í
Outside option. The agent has always the possibility of turning down the
principal’s job offer and working at another job (maybe as self-employed)
that yields utility level u ≥ 0.
Firm profits. The principal is a firm that maximizes expected profits. We
assume that the principal has only one worker and that there are no other
costs beyond labour costs. The expected profits can be written as expected
revenues minus expected costs, or
E[] = pE[x] − w e
= (p − β)e − α
where we make use of the definition w e = α + βe and E[x] = e. In the
previous expression p−β is the profit per unit of output sold, E[x] = e is the
expected revenues and α represents the fixed cost of the firms, independent
of output. Two remarks are in order. First, since p − β is the profit per unit
of output, the term (p − β)e can be thought of as the variable profits of the
firm. Second, the fixed cost α can obviously become a fixed revenue, since
we argued above that α can be negative.
Indifference Curves
Let’s call the indifference curve of the worker the combination of expected
income (w e ) and effort (e) that delivers to the individual the same level of
utility.Î (Figure 6.2 reports a family of indifference curves.) There are various
properties of these utility functions:
• Indifference curves are upward sloping. Higher effort, which the worker
dislikes, must be compensated by higher income in order to remain on
the same indifference curve.
• Indifference curves do not intersect. This is true with any indiffer-
ence curve. If they did intersect, then a unique combination of effort
and income would yield two different utility levels, which is obviously
not possible.
Í The indifference curves describe the behaviour of the utility function.
Î The equation of the indifference at utility level Ū for an individual that is risk neutral is
e2
E(w) = δ + Ū
2
88 OPTIMAL COMPENSATION SCHEMES
U2
E (w) U1
Rearranging the terms of the previous expression, the slope of the utility
function is
w MUe
=− = δe
e MUw
In other words, when wages are fixed and independent of output, the agent
optimally chooses zero effort.
Effort under the Bonus Contract: In the bonus contract w = α +βx so that
w e = α + βe. The optimal level of effort can be easily analysed graphically, as
90 OPTIMAL COMPENSATION SCHEMES
We
U1
W e = a + be; b < p
U2
B
A W e= a
e* = b/d e
the choice of an optimal level of effort on the part of the worker. The worker
wants to enjoy the maximum level of utility subject to the budget constraint.
The maximum point requires a tangency condition between the indifference
curve and the budget constraint. If the budget constraint is horizontal, then
clearly the worker maximizes his utility by choosing an optimal level of effort
at point A, to which corresponds a zero amount of effort. Conversely, if the
budget constraint is the one typical of a bonus scheme, then the optimal
position cannot be at zero effort, since the worker can obtain a larger level
of utility by choosing a larger amount of effort. The optimal solution of the
worker is now at point B, where the level of effort is the one corresponding to
the level of effort e ∗ = βδ . Let’s understand why.
The optimal choice of effort is simply given by the tangency between the
budget constraint and the indifference curve, so that
The optimal effort choice is typically called the incentive compatibility con-
straint. As we will see later on, such a condition acts as a constraint on the firm’s
choice of the optimal compensation package, and should be always taken into
account by the firm.
The formal problem of the worker is to maximize utility with respect to e,
using the compensation scheme as a constraint
e2
Maxe : U (w e , e) = w e − δ
2
such that w e = α + βe
OPTIMAL COMPENSATION SCHEMES 91
Substituting the constraint into the utility function, the problem is simply to
maximize with respect to effort the following function:
e2
Maxe : U (w e , e) = α + βe − δ
2
which implies that the first-order condition is
β − δe = 0
This result is just a corollary of the previous condition. The maximum level
of effort requires the maximum possible level of the bonus scheme, which we
know to be β = p.
e ∗2
U (w e , e) = α + βe ∗ − δ
2
where we already know that effort will be chosen optimally at a point in which
e ∗ = βδ . Participation is convenient if and only if the utility obtained by the
contract is larger than the outside option. In formula, this is equivalent to
U (w e (e ∗ ), e ∗ ) ≥ u (6.1)
where the notation w(e ∗ ) shows that the expected income will depend crucially
on the optimal effort e ∗ . With a general compensation package, the expected
92 OPTIMAL COMPENSATION SCHEMES
β2 β2
α+ −δ 2 ≥u
δ 2δ
so that
β2
α+ ≥u ((P) Participation Constraint)
2δ
The participation constraint has also a graphical interpretation. The
participation constraint requires that at the optimal level of effort the worker
enjoys a level of utility which is at least as large as the worker’s outside option,
which we labelled u. In terms of Fig. 6.3, if we say that the worker can enjoy
an outside level of utility equal to u = U2 , than at a point such as B, the agent
would be better off working for the principal (since the utility level U1 is larger
than the alternative utility level u = U2 ).
The problem of the agent is now solved and it is fully described by the two
constraints IC and P. Having solved the worker’s problem, we now turn to the
firm’s behaviour, taking into account the worker’s choices.
The P constraint simply says that the agent will work for this principal as long
as his utility is as high as the outside option. Thus, the smallest base pay α that
the principal can offer, given that she offers β to the worker, and still get the
agent to work for her, is the one that makes the agent just indifferent between
accepting and rejecting this offer. In other words, the principal will want to
choose an α so that the participation constraint (P) is binding:
β2
α=u− (6.2)
2δ
This condition gives us an important insight. There is a negative relationship
between the fixed payment and the bonus scheme: the fixed payment decreases
as the bonus scheme increases. There is a lot of intuition here. The principal
must provide the worker with a fixed level of utility u. Such a level can be
guaranteed with different combinations of fixed pay and bonus component,
taking into account that effort will be in any case chosen optimally. The pre-
vious expression shows that for very much larger values of the bonus scheme
(a larger β), the choice of α can even become negative. In other words, as
the bonus scheme increases, the fixed payment can becomes a payment from
the worker to the firm.
Choice of β. Let’s analyse the profits of the principals as a function of β,
given that the agent is offered a level of α indicated above. We know already
that the expected profits of the agents are expected revenues minus expected
costs or
E[] = px e − w e
= pe − α − βe,
= (p − β)e − α
Since the agent chooses effort level e ∗ to maximize his utility and since we
know that e ∗ = βδ , total profits become
β
E[] = (p − β) −α
δ
Profits depend on three terms, and all three terms depend on β. Let’s analyse
those terms:
1. Firm profit per unit of sale. This is given by the term p − β. Since β is
the bonus component, the firm gets only p − β per output sold. A larger
β obviously reduces the firm profit per unit of sale.
2. Total quantity sold depends entirely on worker effort, which we know to
be equal to βδ . Larger bonus component β implies larger effort and larger
quantity.
94 OPTIMAL COMPENSATION SCHEMES
The first two elements make the variable part of profits (p − β) βδ , while the
last term is the fixed part of profits.
where the term in parentheses reflects the fact that the fixed payment
may turn into a positive revenue. The problem of the firm at this point
is simply to select the value of β that maximizes profits. We begin the
exposition with a numerical example, and we then move to the formal
derivation.
The firm must choose the level of β that maximizes total profits. The fixed
payment of the worker decreases with β, so that a larger β means that the
fixed payments from the worker increase profits. At the same time, a lar-
ger β has two effects on the variable profits. On the one hand, a larger β
increases the quantity produced. On the other hand a larger β reduces the
margin of each quantity since the firm gets only a share equal to p − β.
Indeed, a β equal to p makes the variable profits equal to 0. Table 6.1 cal-
culates all possible values of profits for different values of β. The value of
variable profits is maximum when β = 1 in the figure. But the table shows
p
that β = 1 = 2 is not the optimal profits. The firm can do better by further
increasing β (and reducing the variable profits) so as to increase the fixed pay-
ment. The maximum is clearly reached when β = p. Figure 6.4 confirms this
finding.
OPTIMAL COMPENSATION SCHEMES 95
Firm Worker
Beta Var. rev. Fixed paym. Profits Worker’s ut. Fixed paym. Bonus Effort cost
E[] = (p − β)e ∗ − α
β β2
= (p − β) − u −
δ 2δ
pβ β2 β2
= −u+ −
δ 2δ δ
pβ β2
= −u−
δ 2δ
96 OPTIMAL COMPENSATION SCHEMES
2.500
Total profits
2.000
1.500
Profits from variable
payment
0.500
0.000
0. 0
0. 7
0. 3
0. 0
0. 7
0. 3
0. 0
0. 7
0. 3
0. 0
0. 7
0. 3
0. 0
0. 7
1. 3
1. 0
1. 7
1. 3
1. 0
1. 7
1. 3
1. 0
1. 7
1. 3
1. 0
1. 7
1. 3
1. 0
1. 7
2. 3
0
00
06
13
20
26
33
40
46
53
60
66
73
80
86
93
00
06
13
20
26
33
40
46
53
60
66
73
80
86
93
00
0.
Bonus b
Figure 6.4. Firm profits for different values of the bonus scheme
The principal will maximize profits with respect to β so that the first-order
condition solves
MaxE[]β
p β
− =0 (6.3)
δ δ
β=p (6.4)
which implies that the optimal β is equal to the price. In other words, all the
revenues from the sale should go to the worker, and the profits are simply given
by the value of α.
With a risk-neutral agent, the optimal commission rate to offer is the franchising
commission.
from which it follows that the base wage is negative as long as u = 0 (the
worker is paying for the job). Finally, the net profits of the principal are
pβ β2
E[] = −u−
δ 2δ
p2 p2
= −u−
δ 2δ
p2
= −u
2δ
which are obviously positive as long as
p2
u≤ .
2δ
If the latter condition is not satisfied, the principal does not offer the contract
to the agent. In other words, the principal has a participation constraint which
requires positive expected profits, or E[] > 0.
Summing up
For a risk-neutral agent the optimal compensation scheme of the type w =
α + βx is such that
β=p
p2
α=u−
2δ
and the agent will accept at the utility u. Further, effort is such that
p
e∗ =
δ
The optimal contract is described at point C in Fig. 6.5. The level of utility in
equilibrium is exactly equal to that of the outside option, while the incentive
E (y) = a + pe;
U=u
E (y) U2
C
scheme has the slope equal to the price. The optimal effort is chosen at level
e ∗ = δ and the α is negative in the figure, so that the worker buys the job.
p
When negative payments are not allowed, the optimal compensation is never
at the maximum effort, and the firm chooses a level of β < p.
Let’s call β̂ the level of bonus chosen by the firm when there is a non-negative
constraint on α. What will be the optimal level of β̂ in this case? Let’s first look
at the numerical example. Figure 6.4 immediately suggests that the optimal β̂
corresponds to β = 1 = p/2. Note also that the firm could set a larger β̂ and
still make positive profits, but such profits would be lower.
Let’s now formally obtain the optimal β̂.
β̂
Max (p − β̂) when α = 0
δ
so that the firm chooses β̂
β̂ p − β̂
− + =0
δ δ
p
β̂ =
2
When non-negative payments are ruled out, the optimal commission scheme is
the 50 per cent commission rate.
Let’s see now what the worker utility is in the case of a full variable payment
δ
U (w e (β̂), e ∗ (β̂)) = w e (β̂) − e ∗ (β̂)2
2
2
β̂ β̂
= β̂ −
δ 2δ
p2
= >0
8δ
where we recall that u = 0 in this case. The utility level is strictly positive, and
larger than the outside option. In other words, the worker gets a rent, or a value
of the utility above the reservation level, as the following remark shows:
When non-negative payments are impossible, the worker gets an extra rent and
enjoys a level of utility larger than the reservation value.
It is also clear that the firm reduces its expected profits. In the example in
the table the profits of the firms when β = 1 are much lower than the profits
under the first best scheme.
Summing up
For a risk-neutral agent with reservation utility u = 0 the optimal com-
pensation scheme with non-negative payments is of the type w = βx
100 OPTIMAL COMPENSATION SCHEMES
such that
p
β̂ =
2
α̂ = 0
The difference between risk aversion and risk neutrality on the agent’s
preferences is analysed next.
e2
U (w, e) = w e − δ
2
e2
= α + βe − δ
2
Risk-averse guy with mean variance preferences: A risk-averse guy with
mean variance preferences is somebody who does care about income
variability, so that his utility function is
e2
U (w, e) = w e − λVar(w) − δ
2
The larger λ is, the more the worker is averse to income variability.
e2
U (w, e) = α + βe − λβ 2 v − δ
2
e2
Maxe : U (w, e) = α + βe − λβ 2 v − δ
2
which implies that the optimal choice of effort is the condition (IC) above, or
that
β
e∗ = (IC: Incentive Compatibility Constraint)
δ
102 OPTIMAL COMPENSATION SCHEMES
The choice of the optimal effort does not depend on the presence of risk
aversion.
The second problem of the worker is whether participating in the contract is
convenient, since the worker can enjoy an outside option which yields expected
utility equal to u.
The utility of the agent is
e ∗2
U (w, e) = α + βe ∗ − λβ 2 v − δ
2
β
since e ∗ = δ it follows that participation is convenient if and only if
U (w(e ∗ ), e ∗ )) ≥ u
β2 β2
α+ − − λβ 2 v ≥ u
δ 2δ
β2
α+ − λβ 2 v ≥ u
2δ
so that
1 − λv2δ
α + β 2[ ]≥u ((P) Participation Constraint-Risk Aversion)
2δ
Choice of α̃. Let’s first consider the optimal choice of α̃ given β̃. For given
choice of β̃ the principal will want to pay a salary so that the agent will choose
to work. The agent chooses to work for this principal as long as he is just as
well off as at his next-base opportunity. Thus, the smallest base pay α̃ that the
principal can offer, if she offers β̃, and still get the agent to work for her is
β̃ 2
α̃ + − λβ̃ 2 v = u
2δ
1 − λv2δ
α̃ = u − β̃ 2
2δ
Choice of β̃. Let’s study the profits of the principal when she offers β̃ and
the agent is going to work by offering a level of α̃ as indicated above. The
expected profits of the agents are
E[] = pE[x] − w e
= pe ∗ − α̃ − β̃e ∗
β̃ β̃ 2
s.t. e ∗ = and α̃ = u − + λβ̃ 2 v
δ 2δ
p β̃ β̃ 2
E[] = −u− − λβ̃ 2 v
δ 2δ
The principal will maximize profit with respect to β̃ so that the first-order
condition solves
p β̃
− − 2λβ̃v = 0
δ δ
p
β̃ =
1 + 2λδv
which implies that the optimal β̃ is less than the price (as long as λ > 0, υ > 0
and δ > 0).
For a risk averse guy, the optimal commission rate is never the franchising
compensation scheme, i.e. 0 < β̃ < p
104 OPTIMAL COMPENSATION SCHEMES
Summing up
With a risk-averse agent the scheme works as follows
p
β̃ =
1 + 2λδv
2 1 − λv2δ
α̃ = u − β̃
2δ
p 2 1 − λv2δ
α=u−
(1 + 2λδv)2 2δ
Let’s start by defining the surplus from the deal as the sum of the utility of each party,
net of the respective outside option. This is identical to the difference between the
revenues from the deal and the workers’ cost of eliciting effort. The surplus is then
S = ( − 0) + (U − u)
δe 2
= pe − w + w − −u
2
δe 2
= pe − −u
2
and let us assume that the two parties could contract directly on effort, rather than
relying on the output x. Let’s see what the effort choice is that maximizes the surplus
from the job. In other words, the optimal effort is the one that makes the marginal
surplus zero (i.e. ∂S
∂e = 0). We call the optimal level of effort e and it is easy to see that
0
p − δe o = 0
from which it follows that
p
eo =
δ
The level of effort that maximizes the surplus is e 0 = p/δ.
So that the maximum value of the surplus is (evaluating S at e o )
p2 δp 2 p2
S(e o ) = − 2 =
δ δ 2 2δ
and the job is efficient as long as
S(e o ) > 0
p2
>u
2δ
OPTIMAL COMPENSATION SCHEMES 105
The analysis above shows clearly that the efficient contract is identical to the contract
between the principal and a risk-neutral agent. In other words, with a risk-neutral agent,
the franchising payment implements the first best contract.
Thus, in the case of risk neutrality on the part of the agent, there is no cost linked
to the impossibility of contracting directly on effort.
The previous expression gives the joint value of the surplus, which still needs to be
allocated to the worker and to the firm. The payment w is chosen so that the worker’s
utility is identical to the outside option U = u so that
δe o2
w =u+
2
The worker will receive exactly the utility level u, while the firm will get all the
uncertainty and will have a payment equal to the residual value, in other words
p2
(e o ) = −u
2δ
p2
>u
2δ
∗ = pe ∗ − (α̃ + β̃e ∗ )
where
p2 1 − λv2δ
α̃ = u −
(1 + 2λδv)2 2δ
p
β̃ =
1 + 2λδv
β̃
e∗ =
δ
106 OPTIMAL COMPENSATION SCHEMES
p β̃ β̃ 2
∗ = −α−
δ δ
p 2 1 p2 1 − λv2δ p2 1
= −u+ −
1 + 2λδv δ (1 + 2λδv)2 2δ (1 + 2λδv)2 δ
p2 1 p2 −1 − 2λδv
= −u+
1 + 2λδv δ (1 + 2λδv)2 2δ
2
p 1
= −u
2δ 1 + 2λδv
So that the cost of dealing with a risk-averse guy is
p2 p2 1
o − ∗ = −
2δ 2δ 1 + 2λδv
2
p 1
= 1−
2δ 1 + 2λδv
p 2 λv
=
δ 1 + 2λδv
The cost of being unable to contract on effort is equal to zero if λ = 0 and if υ = 0.
7 Pay for Performance with
Wage Constraints
7.1 Introduction
The baseline theory of optimal compensations suggests that properly designed
incentive contracts can be very effective in extracting workers’ effort. A fixed
wage scheme, where compensation is independent of output, does not provide
incentives to the worker. As we have seen in the previous chapter, in response to
a fixed wage, a utility maximizer worker would choose the minimum amount
of effort. Conversely, bonus schemes, where a fixed wage is mixed with a bonus
component proportional to output, are a much more effective compensation
scheme. We have also seen that as a benchmark limit case, when the worker is
risk neutral and no other constraints are binding, the optimal compensation
scheme is an extreme bonus scheme, with a negative fixed payment up front
and a bonus component identical to the price (we called such a scheme the
franchising scheme). In such a setting, production efficiency is maximized and
the worker becomes the residual claimant. Yet, we know that such a scheme is
hardly attainable in real life labour markets, since it requires the worker to pay
for the job.
In real life labour markets and real life organizations, it is very difficult to
implement the franchising scheme. Even if agents are risk neutral, payments
from the workers to the firms are barely conceivable. The previous chapter
has shown that the optimal franchising contract turns into a 50 per cent com-
mission rate as soon as negative payments are not allowed. In such a setting
the firms set a base pay equal to zero, and share with the worker the variable
outcome.
This chapter looks into compensation behaviour under more realistic wage
constraints. For example, firms often have to offer a simple fixed wage inde-
pendent of performance. Sometimes such a wage can be chosen by the firm
and sometimes it is negotiated outside the firm’s control, either by a minimum
wage constraint or by industry-wide collective agreements. What should the
firm do when it is forced to pay a fixed wage, independent of output? How
should such a wage be chosen? Is it possible for the firm to obtain the max-
imum profits when the wage contract must simply be a fixed (positive) wage.
The answer is yes, if three conditions hold: (i) the wage level can be optim-
ally chosen by the firm; (ii) a minimum amount of output can be observed
108 PAY FOR PERFORMANCE WITH WAGE CONSTRAINTS
and imposed on the employment contract; and (iii) workers are homogeneous
vis-à-vis their ability. When one of these conditions breaks, some profits must
be given away. This chapter focuses on heterogeneity.
In this chapter we explore in detail the impact on firm performance of
worker heterogeneity. We will assume that firms face a variety of workers, and
different workers have different attitudes toward efforts. Ability is like a DNA
component known to the worker but not known to the firm. We will see that a
firm that offers a single wage with a minimum output requirement surrenders
some rent to workers, and the most efficient production cannot be realized.
Some workers in the firm enjoy a pure economic rent, and are strictly better off
than their best outside options. This is a situation that probably gets closer to
most real life firms. In most firms, workers take it easy and enjoy a specific rent.
The core of the chapter studies how the firm can improve its situation
when some of its workers are enjoying a pure economic rent. We basically
study the effect of a bonus scheme with a minimum guarantee, or a scheme
in which a minimum wage is guaranteed, but if workers do well, they can
obtain additional income. We will see that such a scheme is likely to improve
productivity vis-à-vis the simple fixed payment with minimum output. We will
show that two different effects emerge from such a move: efficiency effects and
sorting effects. The efficiency effects refer to the improvements in performance
and productivity of workers that are already in the firm. The sorting effects
refer to a change in the composition of the workforce in the firm.
The second part of the chapter shows how a minimum guarantee with
bonus scheme worked in a real life case study. We will review the Safelite case,
a window installer in the United States that introduced a pay for performance
scheme with minimum wage guarantee. The case study will clearly show that
sizeable sorting and efficiency effects are linked to the changes of remuneration
schemes.
outside option = au
so that workers with larger ability have better outside options. This makes
sense, since better workers have better outside chances.
Let’s see how the preferences and the indifference curve change with ability.
The utility function is the same as the one we used in the previous chapter, so
that utility depends positively on wage income and negatively on effort.É Since
output and ability are linked by the relationship x = a + e, the utility function
reads for an individual with ability a
w if x < a
U =
w − δ(x−a)
2
2 if x ≥ a
To properly understand the utility function introduced above let us study the
indifference curve in a space [x, w]. An indifference curve in such a setting will
refer to all the combinations of x and w that give the same utility to the agent.
For this purpose, we need to define the maximum output at zero effort.
• Each individual has a maximum output level x̄ = a that he or she can
produce without exercising any effort.
• Beyond the zero effort output level x̄ = a , individuals need to exercise
effort to produce more output.
• Individuals that are more able, have larger output x̄ = a .
With respect to the indifference curves in the [w, x] space, the following
properties apply
• Indifference curves are flat up to the maximum output at zero effort.
• Indifference curves are upward sloping beyond x̄ = a .
• The slope of the indifference curve depends on ability, and less able
individuals have steeper indifference curves.
The formal definition of the indifference curve at utility level k for an
individual with ability a is given by the following relationship
k if x < a
w=
k + δ(x−a)
2
2 if x ≥ a
2
É The utility function in the previous chapter was written as U = w − δe2 .
110 PAY FOR PERFORMANCE WITH WAGE CONSTRAINTS
W Low ability
High ability
K1
K2
x = al x = ah x
If x is lower than the zero effort output the slope is zero (since ∂U∂x ), while if x is beyond the zero
output level the
dw 0 if x < a
=
dx δ(x − a) if x ≥ a
Ë The indifference curves for the same individual never cross. Yet, the indifference curves of two
different individuals can and do cross each other.
PAY FOR PERFORMANCE WITH WAGE CONSTRAINTS 111
High ability
W
Low ability
W*
K
K2
Xmin X
Figure 7.2. Optimal solution with fixed wage and minimum output when ability is
heterogeneous
known to the individual but it is not known to the firm. The problem can first
be described graphically.
Let us first consider the constraint faced by each worker. The constraint is
similar to the linear constraint with the fixed wage that we have analysed in
Fig. 6.1, with the only difference that the wage w is obtained only for quantity
produced larger than the selected minimum xmin . The constraint is thus a step
function, with the step that corresponds to the point at the minimum output
xmin .
Given this constraint, it is clear that no employees will ever want to produce
more than the minimum required by the firm xmin . At the same time, producing
less than xmin is not allowed. Figure 7.1 presents the indifference curve while
Fig. 7.2 describes the equilibrium with minimum output for two individuals
with different ability levels. As is clear from the picture, the individual with high
ability reaches a utility level k1 while the individual with low ability reaches
a level of utility equal to k2 . Clearly we have k1 > k2 . This makes a lot of
sense: an individual with larger ability must exercise less effort to produce an
output equal to xmin so that he will have a larger level of utility for working at
the firm. Yet, there is another key dimension to consider, namely the fact that
individuals with larger ability have also larger outside options, and may not
find it interesting working in the firm. We need to solve the problem of which
worker will self-select for the firm that we are analysing.
The utility for an individual that works for this firm with ability a is
w if a > xmin
U = δ(x−a)2
w− 2 if a ≤ xmin
PAY FOR PERFORMANCE WITH WAGE CONSTRAINTS 113
The condition for working at a firm that pays according to the contract
[w, xmin ] is
δ(xmin −a)2
au ≤ w − 2 if a ≤ xmin
w if a > xmin
More able individuals find it easier and easier to produce the minimum amount
of output, and thus need to exercise lower and lower effort at the margin.
Beyond a level of utility a = xmin , individuals do not even need to exercise
effort to obtain xmin and their utility no longer increases. The outside option
increases linearly with a. This suggests that the condition above is satisfied for
al ≤ a ≤ ah
The solution is clearly described in Fig. 7.3. Individuals with utility level below
al are characterized by an outside option (the straight line in the figure) that
is larger than the utility for working at the firm. Such characteristics hold also
for individuals with ability larger than ah . While individuals in the positions al
and ah , the two extremes, are just indifferent and their participation constraint
is binding, individuals in between are enjoying a pure economic rent. The rent
emerges since the firm must obey an egalitarian wage policy.
When a firm pays a job [w, xmin ] and there is heterogeneity in the population,
a subset of workers in the population enjoys a pure surplus by working at
the firm.
The result can be summarized by saying that there are three types of worker
in the population.
1. Individual workers that are not good enough to work at the firm. Those
are the workers for which a < al ;
Outside option
Utility for working at a firm
that pays fixed wage W with
minimum output x0
u
a1 a = x0 ah
Figure 7.3. Individual self-selection for working at the firm that pays w, xmin
114 PAY FOR PERFORMANCE WITH WAGE CONSTRAINTS
2. Individual workers that work at the firm that pays [w, xmin ] and are those
workers for whom a ∈ [al , ah ]; Such workers (with the exception of those
at the boundaries) enjoy a surplus inside the firm.
3. Individuals workers that are too good to work at the firm, so that a > ah .
xo = ā + eo
1
xo = ā +
δ
xo = 2
since ā = δ = 1. What is the wage that the firm should fix? To find the wage
recall that the wage must satisfy
δ(xo − ā)2
w ∗ = āu +
2
1 1
= + =1
2 2
This suggests that when ability is constant and equal to ā = 1 a firm that
pays [w = 1, xo = 2] behaves efficiently. The profits of the firm are =
2δ + ā(1 − u) = 1.
1
Assume now that workers are heterogeneous and that a is uniformly dis-
tributed between amin = 0 and amax = 4. Let’s see which workers will choose
to work at this firm that pays [w ∗ = 1, xo = 2]. The condition is
δ(xo − a)2
w∗ − ≥ au
2
(2 − a)2 a
1− ≥
2 2
PAY FOR PERFORMANCE WITH WAGE CONSTRAINTS 115
a 2 − 3a + 2 = 0
al = 1
ah = 2
Individuals with a < 1 are not good enough to work in the firm; individuals
with a > 2 are too good to work in the firm and will choose their outside
option. Individuals in between the two values (al , ah ) are enjoying a rent, since
they get a utility which is larger than their outside option. In other words,
heterogeneity implies that the firm that pays a fixed wage is no longer able to
induce all workers to be just to their outside option. Take an individual with
ability a = 3/2. The utility for working at the firm w = 1, xo = 2 is 7/8 while
the outside option is 3/4, so that he is enjoying a rent equal to 1/8. The firm’s
profits are still 1.
Hourly wage, w
Minimum Output, x
output
Figure 7.4. Bonus scheme with minimum wage guarantee (and minimum output required)
to all workers that produce at least x̄. The firm is offering a performance pay
w pr that can be described by our general bonus scheme as
w pr = α + βx
where β is the incentive factor (β ≤ 1) and α is the fixed payment for zero
output (which we know can be negative). All the individuals that produce
more than x̄ can be eligible for the performance plan. Figure 7.4 describes the
constraints that each worker faces with this scheme. The fixed wage works as a
step function exactly like the one we analysed in Fig. 7.2. Yet the figure reports
also the constraint of a general bonus scheme, described by an upward-sloping
line with intercept equal to α (negative in the figure). The bold lines report the
actual compensation. As long as the individual produces the minimum output
required, a wage equal to w̄ is guaranteed, and only if the pay with the bonus
scheme is larger than such value is the bonus scheme effective. In formula, the
compensation that we are analysing is described by the following:
0 for x < x̄
Compensation =
Max[βx + α, w̄] for x > x̄
where output x̄ is required.
Let’s see which individuals would choose to produce under the bonus
scheme. We now solve the problem for the quantity x, but we know that
there is a one-to-one relationship between effort and output, as described by
x = a + e. Let’s call x pr the quantity of output that maximizes the utility. This
means that x pr is the solution to
Maxx U (w pr , x)
δ(x − a)2
U (w pr , x) = α + βx −
2
PAY FOR PERFORMANCE WITH WAGE CONSTRAINTS 117
High ability
w
Low ability D
β
x pr = +a
δ
scheme if
U pr w pr , x pr , a > U (w̄, x̄, a)
where we explicitly recognized that utility depends also on the ability level.
Since we know that x pr = βδ + a the utility associated with the performance
plan is
2
β
U pr (w pr , x pr , a) = + α + βa
2δ
which clearly shows that individuals with larger utility level a get larger util-
ity from the bonus scheme. The utility associated with operating under the
minimum guarantee (which corresponds to point C in Fig. 7.5) is
w for a > x̄
U (w̄, x̄, a) = δ(x̄−a)2
w− 2 for a < x̄
The previous condition simply says that the utility level associated with the
minimum guarantee is at most w. This is not surprising. Very able individuals
can obtain the minimum output x without any effort and therefore get a utility
equal to w. Conversely, individuals with lower ability need to exercise effort
and reach a lower utility. Since the utility with the minimum guarantee has an
upper bound level, it is clear that there exists a threshold level ã + such that for
all utility levels above the individuals are better off in the bonus scheme. In
formula, we can write that
U pr (w pr , x pr , a) > U (w̄, x̄, a) for a > ã +
The situation is clearly described in Fig. 7.6. The horizontal axis reports
different utility levels, while the vertical axis reports the utility levels. Let’s now
focus on the straight line labelled PPP and the curved lane labelled Fixed Wage.
As one can see, the curved line reaches an upper bound for ability level beyond
a = x̄ while the line labelled PPP is upward sloping. Clearly, individuals
beyond ã + are better off in the bonus scheme.
Let’s now consider the entire population of individuals with ability that
can vary from amin to amax . In the previous section we established that the
population potentially employed by the firm that was paying according to
[w̄, x̄] was described by all the individuals that belong to an interval [al , ah ]
and that with the exception of the individuals on the boundaries, there was
a pure economic rent inside the firm. The possibility of producing under the
bonus scheme, and the emergence of the threshold ã + , modifies the scheme.
In particular, the most natural assumption (consistent with Fig. 7.5 and with
the case study that will be analysed in the next section) is to have
al < ã + < ah
PAY FOR PERFORMANCE WITH WAGE CONSTRAINTS 119
PPP Outside
Utility option
Fixed wage
al ã a = x0 ah
Figure 7.6. Utility levels for different individuals when a bonus scheme is introduced in a
firm that was offering a fixed wage with minimum output
From the analysis of these intervals, we can also clearly distinguish between
two types of effects associated with the introduction of a bonus scheme: the
incentive effect and the sorting effect.
Note not all individuals are present in the nineteen months. Some individuals
have joined Safelite later than the first month. For example, if individual j has
joined Safelite at month 10, he or she will have observation xj1 = ., . . . xj10 = .
where the dot refers to a missing value (the individual was hired) for that
month. Similarly, if individual k leaves Safelite at month 15, he or she will
have missing values for the rest of the period. For each individual, it is
also possible to know whether he or she was working in the PPP regime or
not. Remember that the plan was phased in gradually in different branches,
so that for each individual the moment in which the PPP was operating
varies.
1. Incentive effect : Output (or effort) of the workers should increase (or
not fall) as the company moves to a PPP system. Further, if there are
able individuals in the workforce, the effort increases (this is an incentive
effect).
2. Sorting effect : The average quality of the workforce increases (less able
individuals stay with the firm, but in addition it is possible to attract
better individuals into the firm) (this is a sorting effect).
1a 0.368 0.04
s.d 0.013
2b 0.197 0.73
s.d 0.09
3c 0.202 0.224 0.273 0.76
s.d 0.009 0.058 0.018
4d 0.309 0.424 0.13 0.243 0.06
s.d 0.014 0.019 0.024 0.025
only for those individuals that were operating under both regimes. When
one performs such an exercise one finds that the increase in productivity is
equal to 22 per cent (which corresponds to 50 per cent of the total increase in
productivity).
Hawthorne Effect
The Hawthorne effect is described as the rewards you reap when you pay atten-
tion to people. Elton Mayo argued that the mere act of showing people that
you are concerned about them usually spurs them to better job performance.
Individuals’ behaviours may be altered because they know they are being stud-
ied; this was first argued in a research project (1927–32) at the Hawthorne
Plant of the Western Electric Company in Cicero, Illinois. The research, led by
the Harvard professor Elton Mayo, found that regardless of the experimental
manipulation implemented, the production of the workers under investigation
seemed to improve.
To control for the Hawthorne effect one has to control for the experience of
the worker in the firm as well as time since the individual has operated under
126 PAY FOR PERFORMANCE WITH WAGE CONSTRAINTS
the PPP regime. Data suggest that the effect actually increases one year after
the introduction of the PPP (and if the change was only due to a Hawthorne
effect, we should have observed a decline).
Sorting or Learning?
The residual effect could be imputed to a pure sorting effect (better people
were employed by the firm), but we have also to consider that experience
is very important to the average productivity. One way to go about it is to
calculate the effect of the increase in productivity for the individuals hired
when the PPP was already introduced. Data suggest that the productivity of
the new hires (controlling for tenure or seniority) is much larger. In other
words, new hires are more productive.
7.7 Econometrics
The econometric model used to estimate the effect of the swap is the following
individual-based longitudinal equation
where t = 1 . . . T are the nineteen months in which the firm is observed while
i = 1 . . . I are the 3,707 individuals who are observed. The representative
individual is the person month.
The dependent variable is ln xit , the log of output per day per person
(number of autoglass installed).
αi are individual fixed effects aimed at capturing a measure of individual
ability.
δt are time dummies aimed at capturing seasonal effects.
PPPit is an individual dummy that takes a value of 1 if the individual has
been in the PPP regime in that particular month. It’s the key variable for the
analysis of the incentive effects (row 2 in the regression table).
tenureit is the control for tenure. It is very important since productivity
increases with tenure.
timePPPit is a variable that takes the value of 1 if an individual has been in
PPP for 1 year, and 0.5 if for 6 months. It is crucial for the Hawthorne effect.
new_Hirei is an individual dummy that takes the value of 1 if the individual
has been hired after the introduction.
PAY FOR PERFORMANCE WITH WAGE CONSTRAINTS 127
The various regressions in Table 7.3 report the various specifications. The
first regression includes only the PPPit dummy and it represents the estimates
of the pure PPP effect. The coefficient is positive and significant, and evaluated
at the mean of the log of units-per-worker-per-day; this coefficient implies that
there is a 44 per cent gain in productivity with a move to a PPP. Month and
year dummies are included in the regression, to account for factors, other than
the move to PPP, that can have a significant impact on productivity. In the
second regression worker-specific dummies are added. When worker dummies
are included in the regression, the coefficient drops to .197 from .368. The .197
coefficient is the pure incentive effect that results from switching from hourly
wages to piece rates. Evaluated at the means, it implies that a given worker
installs 22 per cent more units after the switch to PPP than he did before the
switch to PPP. This estimate controls for month and year effects. Regression 3
controls also for the worker tenure and the time since PPP, or the time spent
by each individual in the new regime. It shows that there should not be a
Hawthorne effect. The regression includes a variable for tenure and also one
for time that the worker has been on the PPP programme. The coefficient of
.273 on time since tenure coupled with a PPP dummy coefficient of .202 means
that the initial effect of switching from hourly wage to piece rate is to increase
log productivity by .202. After one year on the programme, the increase in log
productivity has grown to .475. The Hawthorne effect would imply a negative
coefficient on time since PPP. If the Hawthorne effect held, then the longer the
worker were on the programme, the smaller would be the effect of piece rates
on productivity. The reverse happens here. After workers are switched to piece
rates, they seem to learn ways to work faster or harder in time. The last row
of Table 7.3 provides evidence on the sorting effect, by measuring the output
of new workers hired. The variable labelled ‘New hire’ is a dummy set equal to
1 if the individual was hired after 1 January 1995, by which point almost the
entire firm had switched to piecework. The theory predicts that workers hired
under the new regime should produce more output than the previously hired
employees. Indeed, workers hired under the new regime have log productivity
that is .24 greater than those hired under the old regime, given tenure.
Before entering the analysis of this chapter, we review the optimal franchising scheme
when ability is present in the analysis. This is easily done, once we recall from the
previous chapter the optimal linear contract w = α + βe is described by (replacing u
with au)
β
e∗ =
δ
β2
α = au −
2δ
β=p
where α is the fixed payment, β is the bonus scheme, and p is the price of output that
in this chapter we fixed at p = 1.Ì In light of the optimal scheme, the level of output
produced by an individual with ability a is indicated with x ∗ and reads
x∗ = a + e∗
1
x∗ = a + .
δ
The previous expression shows clearly that a firm that hires a more able individual will
produce more output under a franchising scheme which is done for all individuals by a
fixed payment plus an extreme bonus scheme. The profits of the firm for an individual
with ability a areÍ
E[] = px − w
1
= + ā(1 − u) (7.2)
2δ
Ì In the previous chapter we saw that with a compensation equal to w = a +βx, the optimal amount
of effort is βδ . The chapter has also shown that the optimal choice of β from the firm’s standpoint is
β = p. Since we set p = 1, we have that β = 1 is the maximum.
Í The profits are obtained through the following steps
E[] = px − w
= p(e ∗ + ā) − α − βe,
= (p − β)e ∗ + p ā − α
β β2
= (p − β) + ā − au −
δ 2δ
1
= + ā(1 − u).
2δ
PAY FOR PERFORMANCE WITH WAGE CONSTRAINTS 129
Suppose now that the only scheme that the firm can implement is a fixed wage scheme,
so that the compensation must be equal to a fixed α that cannot vary with output.
In other words, the compensation that the firm may offer to its workers is just of the
type w = α without any bonus scheme. The firm cannot implement the franchising
scheme, since such compensation would require a wage that is negative if no output
is produced. Assume that the firm can easily observe output produced, but it cannot
observe the ability of the worker. As it will turn out, the heterogeneous ability is very
important. To show this we start asking the following question. What will be the level of
efficiency (and of profits) when a firm has to offer a fixed wage? The answer will depend
on two key conditions. What we want to show, as a benchmark case, is that the firm
that offers a fixed wage can obtain an efficient level of output if two conditions hold.
Such conditions are
Note that when we talk about an efficient level of profits, we mean a level of profits
that is as high as the one that would be obtained by a firm that implements the
franchising scheme, as indicated by equation 7.2.
Let’s assume for a moment that both conditions are satisfied. Homogeneous work-
force in this chapter means that the parameter a is fixed in the population, so that
a = ā, and for technical reasons we also assume that ā < 1/δ. In other words, all the
individuals have the same ability ā. Let’s see how the firm can choose a minimum level
of output xmin . The idea of a minimum level of output is simply to impose a minimum
standard of quantity, so that if a worker does not reach such a minimum standard, the
firm is not going to hire the worker, or the employment relationship can be interrupted
without cost. In this section we label a job [w, xmin ] as a job that pays a fixed wage
α = w and requires an output xmin . Let’s see how the firm operates. The problem is
solved in two steps. The first problem involves the choice of the minimum output xmin .
The second step involves the choice of the optimal wage w.
It is immediately clear that the first problem, the choice of a minimum quantity
xmin , has been already solved. With a fixed ability, all the firm should do is to select the
minimum output equal to optimal output x ∗ so that
xmin = x ∗
1
xmin = ā +
δ
δ(xmin − ā)2
U (w, xmin ) = w −
2
In order for the worker to participate in the market we need the level of utility (described
by the previous condition) to be larger than the worker outside option:
δ(xmin − ā)2
w− ≥ āu
2
The previous condition provides a participation constraint to the firm. Given xmin ,
the firm should choose a level of wage that makes the worker just indifferent between
working for the firm and his or her outside option (in other words the participation
constraint binds). If we call the optimal wage w ∗ the problem is solved by
1
xmin = ā +
δ
δ(xmin − a)2
w ∗ = āu +
2
The level of profits in this case isÎ
= xmin − w ∗
1
= + ā(1 − u)
2δ
One can compare this level of profit with that obtained under a flexible system and
one immediately finds that they are the same.
If individuals are homogeneous (ā is fixed) the efficient level of profits can still be
obtained with a fixed wage plus a minimum output guaranteed.
= xmin − w ∗
1 δ(ā + 1δ − ā)2
= ā + − āu −
δ 2
1 δ 1
= − − āu + ā
δ 2 δ2
1
= + ā(1 − u)
2δ
PAY FOR PERFORMANCE WITH WAGE CONSTRAINTS 131
the firm in such a way that the worker participation constraint is binding:
Maxxmin pxmin − w̄
δ(xmin − ā)2
s.t . w̄ − ≥ au
2
For maximization simply choose an x such that
δ(xmin − ā)2
w̄ − = āu
2
And the solution to the quadratic solution gives the minimum output. If profits are
positive the firm operates.
If the wage is completely fixed at w̄, all the firm can do is select a quantity so that
the worker participation constraint is binding, and operate if profits are positive.
A sufficient condition for the minimum level of ability al to be found is
δ(xmin − al )2
w− <0
2
To find the two levels of ability we need to distinguish two cases, which depend on
whether ah < xmin or ah > xmin . In the first case we need to solve for the following
quadratic equation:
δ(xmin − a)2
w− = au
2
δa 2 + 2a[u − δxmin ] + δxmin
2
− 2w = 0
8.1 Introduction
Piece rates and bonus schemes provide incentives that operate independently of
the relationship among co-workers. Specifically, workers need not be working
with anyone else to be motivated by a piece rate scheme. Piece rate com-
pensation is based on an individual’s absolute performance rather than his
performance relative to some standard or some other individual. Yet, in real-
ity, most individual motivation is produced not by absolute reward but by
a compensation that is based on relative comparison. Managerial employees
who move up the corporate ladder do so by being better than their peers, not
necessarily by being good.
Comparisons are key in determining promotions in private firms. Since
promotions carry with them higher salaries, higher status, and perhaps more
interesting assignments, workers seek to get promotions. In this process, they
exert effort in an attempt to outperform their neighbours. Thus relative com-
pensation can provide an incentive that is as effective as a piece rate or
output-based compensation scheme based on individual performance.
There are good reasons why firms may prefer to use relative compensation
schemes. The first is that it may be easier to observe relative position than it
is to observe absolute position. Second, relative compensation differences out
common noise that risk-averse people may not like.
The most extreme form of relative compensation is a pure tournament, a
setting in which two workers compete for a promotion, an outcome that can be
described in terms of higher salaries. Workers are promoted if they do better
than their co-workers. In such a setting, the effort exercised by the workers is
proportional to the spread in prize, or to the increase in salary associated with
the promotion.
Pure tournaments are just one possible relative compensation scheme.
Indeed, the chapter introduces also the concept of a Linear Performance Eval-
uation (LPE), a situation in which workers receive a salary structure that is
the sum of two components: a fixed part plus a bonus (penalty) term, with
the bonus term linked to the average performance of the workers. There are
differences between LPE and pure tournament, particularly important when
players are heterogeneous. In LPE winning by a lot is important, since the
RELATIVE COMPENSATION AND EFFICIENCY WAGE 133
larger the victory the larger the increase in salary. In pure tournaments, con-
versely, all that is important is winning. The implications of the two relative
compensation schemes are analysed in the context of a case study of broiler
production.
The chapter introduces also the concept of efficiency wage, a compensation
scheme whereby firms use salaries to increase workers’ effort in the context of
imperfect information. In a dynamic context, the efficiency wage mechanism
ensures that workers’ wages increase with tenure, even when productivity is
constant. Upward-sloping wage profiles appear particular relevant in real life
labour markets. Further, they form the basis of implicit contract between
workers and firms, whereby workers continuously exercise effort in view of
future wage increases.
The chapter proceeds as follows. Section 8.2 presents the basis tourna-
ment model. Section 8.3 introduces the relative compensation scheme, while
sections 8.4 and 8.5 are devoted to the case study of broiler production. Sec-
tion 8.6 deals with efficiency wages and section 8.7 with the upward-sloping
wage profiles.
W1 , and the loser receives wage W2 . No wages are paid until after the contest
is completed. The probability of winning the contest depends on the amount
of effort that each individual exerts. Let the two individuals be denoted by j
and k.
Output of worker j is denoted by qj and depends on effort ej and on luck z
so that
1
qj = ej − z,
2
where z is a random variable with 0 mean. Similarly, output of worker k is
1
qk = ek + z
2
where z can simply be interpreted as relative luck with 0 mean. This implies
that expected output for worker j is E(qj ) = ej while expected output of worker
k is equal to E(qk ) = ek . Effort is chosen by the worker and it is not observed
by the firm, which observes only output.
We assume that z is uniformly distributed with zero mean over the interval
[−b, b]. Recall that if a variable is uniformly distributed over the interval
[−b, b] the following features hold:
E(z) = 0
b2
Var(z) =
3
x +b
G(x) = P(z ≤ x) =
2b
1
g (x) =
2b
where G is the cumulative distribution function and g is its density function.
Let’s define with P the probability of winning the context. For worker j, the
probability of winning the context depends on whether his output j is larger
than output k, so that
1 1
P(qj > qk ) = Pr ob ej − z > ek + z
2 2
= Pr ob(z < ej − ek )
= G(ej − ek )
ej − ek + b
=
2b
We are now in a position to solve the problem. We do this in two steps.
First, we model worker behaviour. Second, we solve for the firm maximization
RELATIVE COMPENSATION AND EFFICIENCY WAGE 135
problem, taking worker behaviour into account. The second problem is thus
choosing an optimal compensation scheme to maximize profits.
δej2
Maxej W1 G(ej − ek ) + (1 − G(ej − ek ))W2 −
2
The FOC reads
∂G
(W1 − W2 ) = δej
∂ej
(W1 − W2 )g (ej − ek ) = δej
W1 − W 2
= δej
2b
∂G(e −e )
where we used the fact that j
∂ej
k
= g (ej − ek ) and that g (ej − ek ) = 2b
1
the participation constraint satisfied with equality. In other words, the firm
problem is
W1 + W2
MaxW1 ,W2 e∗ −
2
W1 + W2 δe ∗2
s.t. =
2 2
which becomes simply
∗
δe 2
W1 ,W2 = e ∗ −
2
So that the first-order condition is
∂ ∂e ∗ ∂e ∗
= − δe ∗ =0
∂W1 ∂W1 ∂W1
1 e∗
= 1−
2bδ δ
∂e ∗
where we used the fact that ∂W 1
= 1
2bδ from the ICC, which suggests that when
wages are chosen optimally
1
e∗ = (efficient effort)
δ
A conclusion immediately follows:
There are two ways to see this conclusion. First, firms force workers to
induce effort up to the point in which the marginal cost of effort (namely δe ∗ )
is equal to the marginal benefit (which is 1). Second, note that this condition
is the same condition that appeared in Chapter 6 on optimal wage contracts
when p = 1. Indeed, with a risk-neutral worker, you recall that the optimal
contract requires β = 1 so that optimal effort is equal to e ∗ = 1δ . This is the
same result that we have now obtained. In other words, a tournament is an
optimal compensation package, and satisfies all the conditions of the optimal
bonus scheme analysed in Chapter 6 for a risk-neutral worker.
system to solve is
∗
W1 + W 2 δe 2
=
2 2
(W1 − W2 )
= δe ∗
2b
where the optimal level of effort is e ∗ = 1δ . Using this result we get
W 1 + W2 δ1
= 2
2 δ 2
(W1 − W2 )
=1
2b
so that
1
(W1 + W2 ) =
δ
W1 − W2 = 2b
anyway and winning by little or by a lot makes little difference, this option
offers little gain. As a result, more able players will play it safe and choose
a low-variance action. The reverse is true for less able players. Since losing
by a little or a lot is still losing and this is the likely outcome, expanding the
negative tail of the performance distribution has little cost. Less able players
should take a chance. Consequently, where tournaments encompass players of
unequal ability, there should be a negative relation between ability and variance
of performance.
implies that, unlike tournaments, LPE provides no incentives for better players
to choose conservative strategies and poorer players to choose risky ones, nor
does it provide an incentive for organizers to handicap better players. The
reason is that under LPE the incremental reward for improved performance is
the same whether a player is more able or less able. As a consequence, under LPE
there should be no relation between player ability and performance variability
nor should there be evidence of handicapping.
those whose flocks are harvested in the same geographical area at nearly the
same time.
An important reason for using relative performance schemes to compensate
broiler growers is that these schemes automatically difference out the effects of
common shocks to grower productivity. Since variations in temperature and
the breed of chick delivered by the integrator affect all growers, none must bear
the risk of such variation, and contracts are very simple.
Another important test is the one that looks whether performance is at all
affected by different payment periods. Indeed, mean performance varies across
periods, as suggested by the rejection of the test that γ1 = γ2 = γ3 = γ4 . In
other words growers do respond to different payment structures with different
levels of effort. Overall, this suggests that incremental rewards, and not absolute
levels, determine performance.
1.4
1.2
d (std. dev. of performance)
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
–2 –1.5 –1 –0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5
d (grower quality decreases left to right)
2
1.8
d (std. dev. of performance)
1.6
1.4
1.2
1
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0
–2 –1.8 –1.6 –1.4 –1.2 –1 –0.8 –0.6 –0.4 –0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2
d (grower quality decreases left to right)
Figure 8.3. Variability of grower performance and grower quality: LPE contracts
estimate of δi , the dummy variable coefficient for grower i from the settlement
cost regression. Remember that the best growers are those with the lowest
settlement cost and the worst are those with the largest. Despite the noise
present in Fig. 8.2, it obviously slopes upward. Better growers choose less
risky strategies. During the LPE period, growers were paid based on their
performance relative to the average of all growers. The reward for improved
performance was the same for high-quality and low-quality growers. As a
consequence no differential incentive existed for low-quality growers to take
risks or for high-quality growers to play safe. In principle, there should be no
relation between σi and δi in the LPE regimes. Nevertheless, in the LPE regime
there was a minimum payment provision, so that the per pound payment
was truncated from below. The effect of this is to restore the incentive for low-
quality growers to take risks. Therefore, low-quality growers did have incentives
to adopt high-variance strategies during the LPE regimes, and this seems to be
borne out in Fig. 8.3. However, most of the positive relationship seems to be
due to the worse growers. To the left of δ = −0.4 the relationship is quite flat
while in Fig. 8.2 it is more uniform. This suggests that there was an effect of
the minimum payment provision on risk taking by low-quality growers during
the LPE period. Nevertheless, there is some qualitative difference in the two
regimes.
Handicapping
When players with different qualities interact in tournaments, organizers
should try to handicap better players, so that all players have the right incentive
146 RELATIVE COMPENSATION AND EFFICIENCY WAGE
where δi is the quality variable of grower i and the variable δi TRN looks
at the relationship between chicksit and performance under the tournament
period. If there is some handicapping we would expect a negative coefficient
on δi (negative θ1 ), with better growers (lower δi ) being given larger seasonally
adjusted flocks. This is because flock size is indeed negatively related to δi .
Indeed the coefficient θ1 is negative, and suggests that better growers are given
larger flocks. While this is consistent with handicapping it could also simply
mean that better growers have more houses. But the key test is on the interac-
tion effect between quality and the tournament periods. Since the incentive to
handicap is greater under the TRN regime, one might expect this coefficient
to be negative, suggesting that handicapping is stronger under tournaments
than under the LPE regime. If a grower is good, it should have more chicks
under tournament, so that low delta should be associated with high chicks in
the tournament dummy. The coefficient γ1 is indeed positive.
The worker will choose to exercise effort only if the utility with effort is
larger than the utility under shirk. This is equivalent to:
c
w− ≥ (1 − p)w + pu
2
where the left-hand side is the worker utility if the worker chooses e = 1 while
the right-hand side is the utility if e = 0. Rearranging, the worker will exercise
effort if and only if
c
w ≥u+ (no shirking)
2p
The previous condition is the fundamental equation of the efficiency wage,
since it says that the worker will exercise effort only if the wage is large enough.
In this setting, the only instrument that can induce the worker to exercise effort
is a high wage. The logic goes as follows. Worker’s dislike effort but if they are
caught shirking they suffer a penalty equal to the wage loss. As a result, the
larger the wage the lower the chance that the worker shirks.
Looking at the firm’s profits, it appears that the firm would like to set the
lowest possible wage, conditional on the worker choosing e = 1. It implies that
the optimal wage is the minimum wage that satisfies the no shirking condition,
and reads
c
w =u+
2p
The efficiency wage increases the more difficult it is monitoring the worker
To establish this conclusion simply note that the lower p is, the larger is
the wage. The intuition is that the worker needs to be compensated more the
lower the probability of finding out whether he or she is shirking. This suggests
that the asymmetric information over effort leads to an increase in wage. To
investigate this further we can define the worker surplus as the difference
between the utility of the worker and his outside option. The worker surplus
is indicated with Sw and its expression reads
Sw = U − u.
RELATIVE COMPENSATION AND EFFICIENCY WAGE 149
Period 1 Period 2
The problem should be solved backwards, starting from period 2 and going
backwards to period 1.
In the second period the problem is like a static problem, since there is only
one period to go and thereafter the game ends. This suggests that in the second
period the problem is identical to the efficiency wage model discussed in the
previous paragraph. In formula the wage for the old worker is
c
wo = u +
2p
The key problem is for the firm to choose the young wage and for the worker
to decide whether effort should be chosen or whether shirking is optimal. The
firm can take into account the second period wage and knows that in the
second period the worker will not shirk and will be paid a wage equal to wo .
Let’s focus on the worker. Suppose that the firm pays a wage wy (which is still
to be determined). The worker will choose to exercise effort if his lifetime utility
with effort is larger than the lifetime utility without effort. This is equivalent to
c c c
wy − + wo − ≥ (1 − p) wy + wo − + p2u
2 2 2
The left-hand side of the previous condition is the utility when the worker
chooses effort and receives wy when young and wo when old. The right-hand
side is the utility if the worker shirks in the first period, while he or she will not
shirk in the second period, since we have already established this. Rearranging
the previous expression one gets
c (1 − p)c
(wy + wo ) ≥ − + 2u
p 2p
and using the solution for the old wage the solution is
c (1 − p)c
wy ≥ u + − (8.1)
2p 2p
The firm’s problem is now easy to determine, since the firm will choose the
minimum young wage so that the worker does not shirk. This is identical to
RELATIVE COMPENSATION AND EFFICIENCY WAGE 151
9.1 Introduction
Lifetime education, as a form of a lifelong process of learning, is a key concept
in modern organizations. It is often argued that in a competitive and changing
world the only successful firms are those that employ workers that continuously
upgrade and adapt their skills. While such a view may look extreme, it is obvious
that lifelong learning is a key dimension in all organizations. Just think about
how difficult it is for older workers to adapt to a digital economy without the
appropriate skills. This means that education, the process of acquiring skills,
does not finish with graduation, but it continues throughout the working
careers of most workers. And most of such education takes place during the
employment relationship, in the form of training. In other words, training is a
key decision in personnel economics.
The current and the following chapter deal with on-the-job training. In this
chapter, the basic models of training are set up.These models are known in the
literature as Becker models of training. A common feature of the models of this
chapter is the assumption of a perfect labour market. In the following chapter,
we will analyse how the training decision changes when the underlying labour
market is imperfect.
To understand how economists think about training, it is first necessary
to understand how economists think about education in general. The most
important view of education is the theory of human capital. Loosely speak-
ing, human capital corresponds to any stock of knowledge or characteristics
the worker has (either innate or acquired) that contributes to his or her ‘pro-
ductivity’. This definition is very broad, but it enables us to think not only
about the years of schooling, but also about a variety of other characteristics
as part of human capital investments. Training done during the employment
relationship is one of such characteristics, and it is the core analysis of this
chapter.
Before entering into the theory of training, the chapter starts from a simple
model of human capital that enables us to understand the individual’s decision
to acquire education. The human capital approach to education (which is
common to this and the following chapter) assumes that acquiring knowledge
TRAINING AND HUMAN CAPITAL INVESTMENT 153
x(1 + r) = 1
educate himself if
Ê Assume that θ can take any value between θmin and θ max and there is a continuum of individuals
distributed according to the cumulative density function F (θ ) defined over the support θmin , θ max .
156 TRAINING AND HUMAN CAPITAL INVESTMENT
Worker stays or
Production takes quits at no costs
place, net of the
Firm decides training y –ct.
training level t Wage paid Wage offer w Production
takes place, y + t
Period 1 Period 2
wage
Wage profile
with training
y+f
y Wage profile
without training
y–c
in the second period, either from the current or from another employer. The
firm makes zero profits, and has no incentive to deviate from such a situation.
To sum up, the equilibrium is described as follows. At time t = 1 the firm
chooses τ = 1 and offers a wage equal to w = y − cτ . At time t = 2 the
firm offers a wage w1 = y + τ f and the worker accepts. Figure 9.2 plots the
solution, with wage on the vertical axis against time on the horizontal axis.
With perfect competition in the labour market, the efficient level of general
training will be achieved with firms bearing none of the costs and workers
financing training by taking a wage cut in the first period of employment.
Two very important implications follow:
• Human capital investors forgo wages early on in their career in exchange
for future wage gains.
• The wage profile becomes positively sloped: workers earn less when they
are young but experience makes wages grow.
In section 9.6 we discuss some of the empirical evidence on training.
General training
y = 100, c = 15, f = 25
Marginal prod. Outside option Wage Firm surplus Worker surplus Total surplus
τ =0 τ =1 τ =0 τ =1 τ =0 τ =1 τ =0 τ =1 τ =0 τ =1
t = 1 100 85 100 100 100 85 0 0
t = 2 100 125 100 125 100 125 0 0
At time t = 1, there is a specific training opportunity s that can take two values s = {0, 1}
s = 1 corresponds to a situation in which specific training is undertaken and s = 0 when
training does not take place. The worker decides on s. Undertaking training costs c in terms of
forgone production. The marginal product is thus y without training and y − c when training
is undertaken.
The wage w1 in the first period is equal to y − cs, so that undertaking training implies
obtaining a wage equal to y − c.
At time t = 2, there are three stages:
Since s refers to specific skills, the outside option of the worker at time t = 2 is still
equal to y.
We also assume that f > s; this means that the increase in production is strictly positive
and the training opportunity is efficient.
Can the firm have the incentive to pay all the training costs at time t = 2
and still offer a wage w1 = y? Such an option would not even work since the
firm will make a certain loss at time t = 1 and it would not have any guarantee
that the worker will stay with the firm in the second period.
The worker surplus is the present discounted value of the difference between the wages and
the outside option. The firm surplus is the present discounted value of profits (since the firm
outside option is normalized to zero).
Sw,2 = w2 − y
Sf ,2 = y + fs − w2
The worker surplus is just the difference between the wage paid at time t = 2
and his or her outside option, which is equal to y. The firm surplus is equal to
the marginal product at time t = 2, which is now the sum of y + fs net of the
wage to be paid to the worker. Without specifying what is the wage that is paid
to the worker, it is impossible to argue whether the surplus of each party is
positive or not. Nevertheless, no matter how such a wage is determined, once
training has taken place, the sum of the two surpluses is a positive amount as
long as s = 1. Formally
S2 = Sw,2 + Sf ,2 = fs
Once again, it is not possible to establish the value of the surplus without
specifying the wages, but we know that the total surplus at time t = 1 is
S1 = Sw,2 + Sf ,2 = s(f − c)
which is strictly positive as long as s = 1. We thus have a positive total surplus
as long as there is specific training.
Firm-Specific Rent (or Surplus): A specific rent is a positive surplus that can be exploited only
by the current relationship.
f = c /b
Increase in B . f=c
productivity
A .
C .
Investment cost
wage
Productivity
y+f
Specific
surplus y + βf Wage profile
with training
y
Outside option
y – βc
y–c
will invest in training with full sharing, so that the worker pays a fraction β of
the costs and gets a fraction β of the revenues. With full sharing, the worker
chooses to invest if
y + βf − y − βc > 0
which will lead to the worker choosing the investment as long as
f >c
which is the condition that ensures that the investment is efficient.
One can look at the problem from the firm’s standpoint. The firm at time
t = 1 would like to sponsor training if
(1 − β)(y + f ) − (1 − β)(y + c) > 0
from which it follows that the firm would choose an amount of training that
satisfies f > c. An important conclusion follows.
With full sharing of costs and benefits, all profitable specific training opportun-
ities are obtained.
Further note that the wage tenure profile becomes steeper once the specific
investment is undertaken.
Note that by splitting costs and benefits, the worker and the firm have
an incentive to stay together, so that firm-specific human capital is a good
condition for establishing long-run relationships. This suggests that each time
parties engage in firm-specific investments, the relationship is going to last
longer. Note that these concepts can be applied also outside personnel eco-
nomics, such as in the economics of family. For two partners, the best example
166 TRAINING AND HUMAN CAPITAL INVESTMENT
more skilled workers and/or that their marginal costs are lower. Most stud-
ies find also that women receive less training than their male counterparts.
The most common argument points to the lower labour force attachment of
women, which may cause employers to invest less. Gender differences might
also come about because women hold jobs that require less training, for which
there is some evidence. Training rates are also found to increase with firm size.
Perhaps the main explanation is economies of scale in training provision from
which larger firms benefit.
Human capital theory predicts upward-sloping productivity profiles. Wage
profiles are assumed to proxy these productivity profiles. The problem, how-
ever, is that there are many other theories, besides human capital, that predict
upward-sloping wage profiles and as such it is hard to argue that this is a defin-
itive test. One would like to know to what extent wage growth correlates with
productivity growth, but the literature has not found an obvious test for such
a prediction.
It is practically very difficult to distinguish between firm-specific and general
training, since in real life most training opportunities contain a combination
of the two. In this respect, the results reviewed in this section apply to both
types of investment. Yet, one can find a range of examples for which the
baseline theory of general training appears to provide a good description.
These include some of the historical apprenticeship programmes where young
individuals worked for very low wages and then graduated to become master
craftsmen; pilots who work for the Navy or the Air Force for low wages, and
then obtain much higher wages working for private sector airlines; securities
brokers, often highly qualified individuals with MBA degrees, working at a
pay level close to the minimum wage until they receive their professional
certification; or even academics taking an assistant professor job at Harvard
despite the higher salaries in other departments.
1. The firm decides the level of training τ incurring the cost c(τ ), where c(τ ) reads
cτ 2
c(τ ) =
2
and c is a positive constant. We are assuming that training can be simply measured
through the variable τ .
168 TRAINING AND HUMAN CAPITAL INVESTMENT
sponsor the training. The firm would certainly make a loss on the training, since it would
incur a certain cost at time t = 1 without incurring the benefits. Since the worker is
the full residual claimant of the increase in his or her own productivity, he or she will
have the right incentive to invest. The firm will then offer to the worker the following
package at t = 0, level of training τ ∗ = a/(b + c) and wage equal to w0 = y− c(τ ∗ ).
In this situation, the worker accepts the deal, since he will get the full wage
w1 = y + f (τ ∗ )
in the second period, either from the current or from another employer.Ë
To solve this problem we need to proceed by backwards induction. The worker will
accept any wage w1 ≥ y since y represents the worker’s outside option. Knowing this,
the firm simply offers w1 = y. Then, given this wage w1 = y, in the previous period
the worker makes no investment in specific skills, even though there is an efficient level
of investment that satisfies c (s) = f (s) so that
a − bs ∗ = cs ∗
a
s∗ =
b+c
The problem is the sharing of the specific investment and the fact that the worker is
held up by the firm. The partial solution to the underinvestment in firm-specific skills
is rent sharing. Let’s modify the game above by assuming that in the final period, rather
than the firm making a take it leave it offer, the worker and the firm bargain over the
firm-specific surplus so that the worker’s wage in the first period is
w1 (s) = y + βf (s)
Ë To understand why offering exactly τ ∗ is the equilibrium one would need to consider the alternative
policy of offering any τ = τ ∗ . For being in equilibrium, we have to be in a situation in which
no unilateral deviation increases profits. Let’s see whether there are possible deviations when the
training investment is τ = τ ∗ . In that case the worker’s income would be lower, since by definition
y − c(τ ∗ ) + y + f (τ ∗ ) > y − c(τ ) + y + f (τ ). In this case a firm offering to the worker yo − c(τ ∗ ) − in
the first period would attract the worker and make positive profits. This implies that there is a profitable
deviation from the policy of offering τ = τ ∗ , so that we cannot be in equilibrium.
170 TRAINING AND HUMAN CAPITAL INVESTMENT
where β is the worker’s bargaining power. Given this wage, at time t = 0 the worker
will choose s so as to maximize with respect to s
y + βf (s) − c(s)
which gives the investment
βf (ŝ) = c (s)
βa − βbŝ = c ŝ
which yields the investment level
βa
ŝ =
βb + c
which is a positive amount.
Rent sharing induces a positive amount of investment in firm-specific skills, and
partly solves the underinvestment problem.
Yet, it is easy to show that as long as β < 1, the amount of investment is less than
the efficient level.
With ex post rent sharing firm-specific investment is less than the first best.
Is there a way in which the optimal level of specific human capital can be achieved?
The only way is a full sharing of cost and benefits, so that the worker and the firm
change the organizational system in such a way that not only the benefits are shared,
but also the costs. Let’s see what is the amount of training that the worker will choose
with full sharing, so that the worker pays a fraction β of the costs and gets a fraction
β of the revenues. With full sharing, the worker chooses an amount s w such that he or
she maximizes with respect to s w
y1 + βf (s w ) − βγ (s w )
which will lead the worker to choose the investment such that
βf (s w ) − βγ (s w ) = 0
from which it immediately follows that s w = s ∗ . Let’s see now what level of training is
going to be chosen by the firm. The firm at time 0 would like to sponsor an amount of
training that maximizes with respect to s f
(1 − β)f (s f ) − (1 − β)γ (s w )
from which it follows that the firm would choose an amount of training that satisfies
(1 − β)f (s w ) = (1 − β)γ (s w )
10.1 Introduction
The general conclusion of the baseline model of training (or the Becker model
as it is known in the literature) developed in the previous chapter is that there
will be no firm-sponsored investment in general training. This conclusion
follows from the assumption that the labour market is competitive, so the firm
will never be able to recoup its training expenditures in general skills later
during the employment relationship.
In real life labour markets, and particularly in imperfect labour markets,
there are many instances in which firms bear a significant fraction (sometimes
all) of the costs of general training investments.
The chapter explores the key dimensions of firm-sponsored general train-
ing. We will see that in imperfect labour markets, where specific rents are
pervasive, it may well be the case that firms undertake some investment
in general training. Such a result crucially depends on the existence of an
imperfect labour market, in the sense that wages paid to workers are higher
than the corresponding outside option. Yet, such a condition is not suf-
ficient to guarantee firm-sponsored training. Beyond market imperfection,
firm-sponsored training requires skill wage compression. The intuition of this
key result is that with wage compressions firms make greater profits from
better-trained workers, and have an incentive to increase the skills of their
workforce.
A first piece of evidence comes from the German apprenticeship system.
Apprenticeship training in Germany is largely general. Firms training appren-
tices have to follow a prescribed curriculum, and apprentices take a rigorous
outside exam in their area of expertise at the end of the apprenticeship. The
industry or crafts chambers certify whether firms fulfil the requirements to
train apprentices adequately, while works councils in the firms monitor the
training and resolve grievances. At least in certain technical and business occu-
pations, the training curricula limit the firms’ choices over the training content
fairly severely. Estimates of the net cost of apprenticeship programmes to
employers in Germany indicate that firms bear a significant financial burden
172 TRAINING INVESTMENT IN IMPERFECT MARKETS
Worker stays or
quits and gets v (t)
Firm pays
Firm decides training costs Production takes
training level t –c (t) Wage offer place, wage is
w (t) paid y + f (t)
Period 1 Period 2
The previous condition ensures that the worker has some costs of chan-
ging jobs, even when there is no training. As we describe below, the wage
is obtained through a simple rent sharing.
3. If the worker stays with the firm production takes place and the wage is
paid. The value of the marginal productivity is y + f τ .
Assume that all training is technologically general in the sense that the
marginal product is y + f τ in all firms.
f is greater than c, which ensures that undertaking training is potentially an
efficient opportunity.
As we argued above, the labour market is imperfect, and the value of the
outside option is less than the wage. Assume now that wages are obtained by
rent splitting, and the worker gets his outside option plus a fraction β of the
total surplus. This is equivalent to assuming that the wage w(τ ) reads
where v(t ) is the outside option of the worker and S(τ ) is the total firm-specific
surplus.
174 TRAINING INVESTMENT IN IMPERFECT MARKETS
To obtain a formal expression for the wage we need to specify the outside
option and the total surplus.
The outside option of the worker is specified as follows:
v(τ ) = a[y + f τ ] − b 0 < a < 1; b > 0
The parameters a and b play a key role in the analysis of training in imper-
fect labour markets. While both parameters refer to the existence of labour
market rents and specific surplus, they have very different implications. As we
show next, the parameter b generates a specific rent that is independent of pro-
ductivity, while the parameter a generates a specific rent that is proportional
to the marginal productivity on the job.
Let’s now consider the surplus.
If we indicate with Sf (τ ) and Sw (τ ) the firm and the worker surplus at time
t = 2, and with w(τ ) the wage, the expression of the total surplus S(τ ) is
Sf (τ ) = y + f τ − w(τ )
Sw (τ ) = w(τ ) − v(τ )
S(τ ) = y + f τ − v(τ )
S(τ ) = (1 − a)(y + f τ ) + b
The surplus is positive as long as a < 1 and/or b > 0. We will see below that
the two types of imperfections generate very different implications. What is
crucial to our analysis is that the parameter b generates a specific rent that is
independent of productivity y + f τ , while the parameter a generates a specific
rent that is proportional to the marginal productivity on the job.
imperfect labour markets. It says that the firm will finance training if the
increase in the marginal product (hence in revenue) associated with training
is larger than the cost of training augmented by the increase in wage. This
condition implies that if the wage increase associated with training is equal to
the increase in the marginal product (hence w = f ) there is no way in which
firm-sponsored training can arise in equilibrium. This is exactly what happens
in the case of a perfect labour market. Conversely, if there is no increase in
wage (hence w = 0) then firm sponsoring of general training may arise. To
obtain a solution we need to calculate the increase in wage.
Using the definition of the surplus, the wage with and without training is
w(τ = 1) = a(y + f ) − b + β[(1 − a)(y + f ) + b]
w(τ = 0) = ay − b + β[(1 − a)y + b]
so that the increase in wage associated with training is
w = f [β + a(1 − β)]
The previous condition shows that the increase in wage is proportional to f ,
but it is less than f as long as a < 1. The parameter a shows that the key
condition for general training is wage compression. The smaller a is, the more
compressed are the wages, since the wage difference across different skill levels
is larger the smaller a is. Condition (10.1) is thus identical to
f > c + f [β + a(1 − β)]
so that the final key condition is
f [1 − a](1 − β) > c (10.2)
Several important conclusions follow:
If labour markets are perfect, firms never finance general training.
This is easily established. Markets are perfect if a = 1 and b = 0. It is clear
that if a = 1 firm-sponsored training never takes place. Note that the para-
meter b does not enter in the condition (10.2). Another important conclusion
immediately follows:
If labour markets are imperfect but wages are not compressed firms do not
finance general training.
This implies that if b > 0, a condition that ensures that labour markets are
imperfect, firm-sponsored training does not arise. In other words, the key
condition for firm-sponsored training is wage compression, as the next and
last conclusion shows:
If labour markets are imperfect and wages are compressed, financing of general
training is possible.
176 TRAINING INVESTMENT IN IMPERFECT MARKETS
marginal product in the current firm. As in the model above, the expression
for the outside option is written as
v(τ ) = af (τ ) − b a ≤ 1 and 0 ≤ b ≤ 1
The fact that v(τ ) < f (τ ) or that b > 0 implies that there is a surplus that
the firm and the worker can share when they are together. The total surplus is
S(τ ) = f (τ ) − v(τ ). Let us suppose that this surplus will be divided by Nash
bargaining, which gives the wage of the worker as:
where β ∈ [0, 1] is the bargaining power of the worker. Note that the equi-
librium wage rate w(τ ) is independent of c(τ ): the level of training is chosen
first, and then the worker and the firm bargain over the wage rate. At this
point the training costs are already sunk, and do not feature in the bargaining
calculations. As is typically the case with sunk costs, bygones are bygones.
Assume that τ is determined by the investments of the firm and the worker,
who independently choose their contribution, cw and cf , and the total amount
of training τ is given by c(τ ) = cw + cf . Assume that $1 investment by the
worker costs $p where p ≥ 1. When p = 1, the worker has access to perfect
credit markets and when p → ∞, the worker is severely constrained and
cannot invest at all.
More explicitly, the timing of events is:
1. In the first period the worker and the firm simultaneously decide their
contributions to training expenses, cw and cf . The worker receives an
amount of training τ such that c(τ ) = cw + cf .
2. At the beginning of the second period the firm and the worker bargain
over the wage for the second period, w(τ ), where the threat point of the
worker is the outside wage, v(τ ), and the threat point of the firm is not
to produce.
3. Production takes place.
Wage compression
MB, MC
ct
0<a<1
(1 – b)(1– a) d No wage
compression
a=1
t*f t
Figure 10.2. Marginal benefit and marginal cost of training to the firm with and without
wage compression
there is no wage compression and the marginal benefit is along the horizontal
axis. In this case there is no incentive from the firm to sponsor training and
τ ∗ = 0 will be chosen. A competitive labour market obviously implies this
outcome. Conversely, when 0 < a < 1 the marginal benefits cross the marginal
costs at a positive amount and the firm is willing to sponsor general training.
The intuition is that when there is wage compression and a < 1 the firm makes
more profits from more skilled workers, and is willing to invest in the general
skills of its employees.
Consider now a situation in which p is finite so that there is a solution to
both τw and τf . Let τw be the level of training that satisfies (10.4), and τf be the
solution to (10.3). It is then clear that if τw > τf , the worker will bear all the
cost of training. And if τf > τw , then the firm will bear all the cost of training
(despite the fact that the worker may have access to perfect capital markets,
i.e. p = 1).
A decrease in a is equivalent to a decrease in the price of skill in the outside
market, and would also tilt the wage function inside the firm, w(τ ), decreasing
the relative wages of more skilled workers because of bargaining between the
firm and the worker, with the outside wage v(τ ) as the threat point of the
worker. Starting from a = 1 and p < ∞, a point at which the worker makes
all investments, a decrease in a leads to less investment in training, as is clear
from equation (10.4) and Fig. 10.3. This is simply an application of the Becker
reasoning; without any wage compression, the worker is the one receiving all
the benefits and bearing all the costs, and a decline in the returns to training will
reduce his investments. As the parameter a declines further, we will eventually
reach the point where τw = τf . Now the firm starts paying for training, and
a further decrease in a increases investment in general training (from (10.3)).
180 TRAINING INVESTMENT IN IMPERFECT MARKETS
pc t
No wage
compression
MB, MC
ct
a=1 Wage
[a + b(1– a)]d compression
a=0
bd
t *w t
Figure 10.3. Worker financing of general training with imperfect labor markets
Therefore, there is a U -shaped relation between the skill premium and training,
so starting from a compressed wage structure, a further decrease in the skill
premium may increase training.
Changes in labour market institutions, such as the minimum wage, will
also affect the amount of training in this economy. To see the impact of a
minimum wage, consider the case with a = 1 and b > 0. The wage is then
w(τ ) = −b(1 − β) + δτ . We have already established that in such a case there
should not be firm-sponsored training. Yet, for very low values of τ such a
wage can even be negative. Suppose that there is a minimum wage w̄ that is
binding for values of τ lower than τ̄ . In other words, the wage is
w̄ if τ ≤ τ̄
w(τ ) =
−b(1 − β) + δτ if τ > τ̄
No wage compression
with minimum wage
MB, MC ct
t* t
w
more important. Empirical evidence suggests that higher minimum wages are
typically associated with more training for low-skill workers.
Table 10.1. Skills training: prevalence and policies at US temporary help agencies
(82 per cent), while 52 per cent of establishments provide workbook exercises
and 45 per cent provide classroom-based training.)
Almost without exception, training is given prior to or between assignments
during unpaid hours with all fixed and marginal costs paid by the THS firm.
It is reported that 44 per cent of all skills training is given ‘up front’ to allow
workers to qualify for their first assignments. Trainees are not contractually
bound to take or retain a job assignment afterwards, nor would such a contract
be enforceable. While THS firms are prone to overstate the efficacy and depth
of their training, evidence of its value is found in the fact that several leading
firms sell the same training software and courses to corporate customers that
they provide for free to their workers.
These basic facts run counter to the baseline human capital model of train-
ing outlined in the previous chapter. In the competitive case analysed by Becker,
workers pay for general skills training by accepting a wage below their mar-
ginal product during training. The threat of poaching or hold-up ensures that
workers earn their full post-training marginal product, and hence up-front
general skills training should never be provided by the employer. By contrast,
the case study under scrutiny reveals that THS firms routinely provide train-
ing up front during unpaid hours, and hence the opportunity for workers to
TRAINING INVESTMENT IN IMPERFECT MARKETS 183
Table 10.2. Comparison of log hourly wages of worker at training and non-training
establishments
White collar
All 2.66 2.79 −0.13 10,497 13,034
(0.04) (0.05) (0.06) 360 270
Professional specialty 3.05 3.17 −0.13 2,918 5,016
(0.02) (0.03) (0.04) 200 170
Technical 2.41 2.45 −0.05 5,805 6,554
(0.04) (0.05) (0.06) 274 213
Accountants and 2.72 2.77 −0.06 1,774 1,464
auditors (0.04) (0.06) (0.07) 187 134
Clerical/sales
All 2.01 2.09 −0.09 156,419 17,925
(0.01) (0.03) (0.03) 693 166
Clerical and 2.02 2.10 −0.08 145,997 16,957
administrative (0.01) (0.02) (0.03) 690 164
support
Marketing and sales 1.84 1.97 −0.13 10,422 1,328
(0.03) (0.08) (0.09) 435 42
Blue collar
All 1.76 1.78 −0.02 85,756 50,257
(0.01) (0.01) (0.02) 461 294
Precision production, 1.89 1.97 −0.08 8,193 6,142
craft, and repair (0.04) (0.04) (0.06) 216 162
Operators, assemblers, 1.79 1.82 −0.03 19,867 12,851
and inspectors (0.02) (0.02) (0.03) 310 187
Transport, material 1.89 1.92 −0.03 1,884 1,809
movement (0.06) (0.05) (0.08) 186 126
Handlers, equipment 1.72 1.71 0.01 55,812 29,445
cleaners, and labourers (0.01) (0.01) (0.02) 445 252
Rj is a vector of 103 MSA indicators, and eij is a random error term assumed
to be composed of a person-specific and establishment-specific component.
The parameter of interest is δ, the wage differential at training estab-
lishments. Due to the inclusion of narrow MSA and occupation indicators,
δ effectively measures wage differentials among local THS establishments
potentially competing for the same workers and supplying labour to the same
customers.
The first three columns of Table 10.3 presents wage models for the full
sample. The initial specification estimates the training wage differential with
an indicator variable that is equal to one if the establishment provides computer
skills training. The coefficient on this variable indicates that wages at training
establishments are on average 2.0 log points lower, which is significant at the
5 per cent level. To probe alternative explanations for this wage differential,
the second column introduces two additional controls. The first is the log of
TRAINING INVESTMENT IN IMPERFECT MARKETS 185
Table 10.3. Estimates of the relationship between establishment training policies and
worker wages
and there is no discounting between periods. In the first period, workers may
select to work at either a training or non-training firm. Training firms provide
general skills training to the workers whom they hire during the first period.
Non-training firms do not. At the end of the first period, a fraction of the
workers at each THS firm quits for exogenous reasons to enter the second-hand
market. In addition, workers may quit their first period THS firms voluntarily
to enter the second-hand market. Workers in the second-hand market are hired
by other THS firms. At the beginning of the third period, all workers are hired
by clients into the permanent sector.
The model can generate several equilibria. The equilibrium of empirical rel-
evance, and consistent with the facts above, is a separating equilibrium in which
workers with high-ability beliefs self-select to receive training while those with
low beliefs do not. The separating equilibrium works as follows. In period 1
wages are identically zero for trainees and non-trainees and expected period 3
wages are higher for trainees. Although all workers would forgo some earnings
to receive training, workers with high beliefs will forgo more because their
expected period 3 gains are larger. At a separating equilibrium, the expected
period 3 wage gain for high-belief workers offsets their training wage penalty
in period 2, while for low-ability belief workers it does not. Consequently, at a
separating equilibrium, wages at training firms are lower than at non-training
firms.
The separating equilibrium depends critically upon two features of the
model. The first is the complementarity between training and ability. Because
training and ability are complements, high-belief workers apply to training
firms, and low-belief workers apply to non-training firms. Training therefore
serves as a self-selection device. If training and ability were not complements,
either all workers or no workers would choose training. A separating equi-
librium would be infeasible. The second critical feature of the model is that
training elicits private information about worker ability. If training firms did
not acquire private information about worker ability, competitive markets
would ensure that each trainee received his marginal product after train-
ing. Hence, the dual roles played by training in the model, self-selection
and information acquisition, are complementary. By inducing self-selection
of high-ability workers, training improves the firm’s worker pool. By revealing
private information about worker ability, training then allows the firm to profit
from this pool.
While the model is of course stylized, these private-information-based
results appear consistent with the personnel policies of THS firms. After
initial training and testing, THS workers are normally first placed at lower-
wage, lower-skill assignments and subsequently given better placements as
they demonstrate success. Workers who test and train successfully and per-
form well at assignments advance more rapidly while workers who perform
poorly are rarely offered placements. Consequently, poor workers turn over
disproportionately while good workers frequently remain.
11 Job Destruction
11.1 Introduction
Sooner or later, every firm experiences bad times. And in bad times,
management often needs to reduce the size of the workforce. The choice of
downsizing is obviously a key concern for personnel managers and for person-
nel economics. The firm needs not only to choose which workers should be
targeted for lay-off, but also to realize that reducing the workforce will have an
impact on the remaining workers.
Job destruction is a subtle business, even in labour markets in which employ-
ment protection legislation is not particularly stringent, and employer-initiated
legislation is largely admissible. The first key concept that the chapter high-
lights is the difference between consensual and non-consensual separation,
where the former refers to those separations that, at a given wage, are agreed
by both parties, while the latter refers to those separation decisions that are
not shared by both parties. Over the job destruction decision, each party (i.e.
the firm and the worker) looks at his or her surplus from the job, and wants to
preserve a job as long as the difference between the value of the job net of his
or her outside option is positive. When the surplus of each party is negative
there is obviously no point in continuing the job, and job destruction should
take place without particular difficulties.
Whenever a non-consensual separation emerges, the firm has to consider
whether it is possible to preserve jobs through wage cuts. Wage cuts, or an
agreed reduction in future wages, are a job-preserving possibility that should
always be contemplated. The chapter shows that as long as the joint surplus
from the job is positive, there is always a profitable wage cut that can preserve
the job. The issue is whether such wage cuts will be implemented in reality.
There are, indeed, a number of reasons that explain why job-preserving wage
cuts are barely observed in practice. A first issue to consider is whether reducing
wages is allowed by the existing legislation. But there are other more subtle
issues to consider, such as the effects of wage cuts on the remaining workers. In
practice, firms often opt for job destruction rather than job cuts, even though
there are important exceptions.
In simple and static views of labour demand, job destruction should take
place each and every time the wage falls short of the value of the marginal
productivity. In dynamic settings, and especially when employment protection
legislation is stringent and firm-initiated separation is costly, things are more
188 JOB DESTRUCTION
We have not formally specified what is the time horizon of the job. This
was not an omission, since the concepts we are highlighting hold for both
static jobs (i.e. 1 period) and multi-period jobs. In the former case, the wage
Wt is simply the period wage. In the latter case, the variable Wt refers to the
present discounted value of wages. Similar distinction can be made for Jt and
for Ut and Appendix 11.1 reports the present discount interpretation of our
discussion.
In any event, the total surplus from a single job can be written as
S = Sf + Sw
= (Jt − Wt ) + (Wt − Ut ) (11.1)
= Jt − Ut
This works as follows. A worker wants to stop working for a firm as soon as
Sw < 0 while a firm wants to fire the worker as soon as Sf < 0. If Wt < Ut and
simultaneously Jt < Wt , then necessarily Ut > Jt . In this case there is no point
in continuing with this job, and it does not matter whether it is the firm that
fires the worker or whether it is the worker himself that quits. In either case
the job is going to be terminated.
Things are more complicated when the firm surplus is negative for the firm
while positive for the worker. In this case the firm has an interest in terminat-
ing the job and proceeding to a firm-initiated separation. Nevertheless, such
separation may not be consensual.
When the worker surplus is positive (i.e. Sw > 0), there are no individual
incentives to quit the job, and the worker will hold on to the job as long as the
firm-initiated separation is not completed. If the firm has full authority over
the continuation of the job, and there are no separation costs to be paid, the
firm will initiate a separation procedure. The key question we address in the rest
of this section is the following. Is it possible for the worker to accept a sufficiently
large wage cut so that the firm-initiated separation is avoided? The remark shows
that such a worker–firm transfer exists only when the total surplus is positive. A
job-preserving wage cut exists when firm-initiated separation is not consensual
but the surplus is positive.
190 JOB DESTRUCTION
Consensual separation
Sw < 0 and Sf < 0
Firm-initiated
separation Efficient
Sf < 0 S = Sf + Sw < 0
Non consensual
separation
Sw > 0 and Sf < 0
Inefficient
S = Sf + Sw > 0
1 70 60 70 0 10 10
2 75 65 80 5 10 15
3 40 35 32 −8 5 Firm initiated −3 Separation
4 85 74 80 −5 11 Firm initiated 6 Wage cut
5 90 85 100 10 5 15
6 25 30 25 0 −5 Quit −5 Separation
7 65 70 71 6 −5 Quit 1 Wage raise
8 55 45 65 10 10 20
9 90 75 70 −20 15 Firm initiated −5 Separation
10 60 55 70 10 5 15
a surplus of 15. On worker 4, the situation is more complicated, since the firm
is losing 5 but the worker enjoys a surplus of 11. Here a job-preserving wage
cut is possible, since the total surplus is positive. Indeed, a wage cut equal to 6
would make the job viable.
The situation of workers 6 and 7 is also interesting. On worker 6, the firm
is indifferent while the worker has a negative surplus. This separation is not
firm initiated but worker initiated, and we typically called it a quit. There is
no surplus and the job is going to be destroyed. On worker 7, conversely, a
profitable wage rise is possible.
Ê As we discuss in the next chapter the firing costs involve a monetary transfer to the worker as well
as a tax to be paid outside the firm–worker pair.
194 JOB DESTRUCTION
where S refers to the fact that we are now explicitly considering the firing cost.
The surplus of the worker is unchanged and it is equal to Sw = W − U .
To understand the effect of firing costs let us assume that there are many
jobs in the firm and that different jobs can have different values of J . In other
words, we now assume that J can take any value from a minimum of zero up
to a maximum of J max . Let’s try to understand which jobs will be kept open by
the firm.
Let’s first analyse the case in which there are no firing costs, so that F = 0,
and let’s ask what is the minimum value of J for the firm to keep a job open.
The answer is simple, since the firm will want to continue to operate any job
that yields at least the wage rate. Let’s call this value the reservation productivity
J ∗ or a value of J that makes the firm indifferent between keeping the job open
and closing it down. The reservation productivity when there are no firing
costs is the value of J that makes the surplus equal to zero
Sf ( J ∗ ) = 0
J∗ = W
When there are no firing costs the firm’s firing decision is as follows: keep open
any job that yields a marginal value that is at least as high as the wage rate. This
is also the simple condition of labour demand in a static setting.
Let’s now consider what happens when the firm has to pay a firing cost for
implementing a job destruction. The firm will want to keep a job open as long
as the continuation value is larger than the firing cost. Let’s indicate with J ∗∗
the value of the marginal productivity to the firm when there are firing costs
so that
Sf (J ∗∗ ) = 0
J ∗∗ − W + F = 0
J ∗∗ = W − F
where it immediately follows that J ∗∗ < J ∗ . The implication of this finding is
obvious. When there are firing costs to be paid, the firm holds on to jobs that
yield a value that is lower than the wage rate. This is called the labour hoarding
effect of firing costs. In order to avoid the firing costs, the firm is willing to accept
a loss on the marginal job and keeps open a job that yields less than the wage
rate. This effect is clearly visible from Fig. 11.2.
Firing costs reduce the number of jobs that are destroyed.
This conclusion can be easily verified, since the larger the firing cost, the
lower the reservation productivity. Firing costs induce firms to hold on to
jobs that have lower marginal value. This is not surprising, since we have
imposed a cost on the job destruction decision. Yet, in a general view of the
JOB DESTRUCTION 195
S=J–W+F
S = J–W
J **
F
J
–(W–F )
J*
–W
firm’s personnel policies, firing costs may certainly reduce job destruction, but
they are also likely to have an impact on job creation. The rest of the chapter
describes a two-period model of job creation and job destruction.
Production Production
Firm observes ε takes place Firm observes ε takes place
Period 1 Period 2
There are two key decisions that the firm should make. At period 1 the firm
should decide which realizations of ε should lead to a job formation. In period
2, the firm should decide which jobs should be destroyed. The problem is
solved backwards. We first solve the job destruction decision at the beginning
of the second problem, and then, given this decision, we move to the first
problem and solve for the job creation decision.
We begin with the job destruction condition. At the beginning of the second
period the firm observes a value of ε, so that if the firm operates it enjoys a
marginal profit equal to ε − w. If the firm destroys the job it has to pay the
fixed cost equal to −F . It is clear that the job destruction decision is given by
the solution to the following problem
Destroy if ε − w < −F
Continue if ε − w > −F
This is the same problem as the one that we discuss in the previous para-
graph, and it is clear that the firm decision will be described by a reservation
productivity ε d such that
εd = w − F
εc
JD
Jobs
created JC
εc
Jobs not
created A
εd = w – F εd
independent from what happens in the first period. Bygones are bygones, and
the firm decision is completely forward looking.
Two results are immediate:
1. Job destruction increases if the wage goes up. To see this one can notice
that an increase in the wage increases the reservation productivity εd .
2. Job destruction is reduced if firing costs go up. To see this one can
notice that an increase in the firing cost −F increases the reservation
productivity ε d .
The job creation decision is more difficult to write down, but it delivers
very important insights on hiring decisions in the context of firing costs. Let
us indicate with 1 (ε) the present discounted value, evaluated at time 1 of
profits at the beginning of the first period, once the firm has observed the
realization of the productivity. Its expression reads
1
1 (ε) = (ε − w) + Expected Profits in Period 2
1+r
1
1 (ε) = (ε − w) + Max[z − w, −F ]dG(z)
1+r
The previous expression should be read in the following manner. The left-hand
side is the presented discounted profits for a job with realization in the first
period equal to ε. The term in brackets ε − w is simply the operational profits
of the first period. The term 1/1+r is the discount factor, while the term inside
198 JOB DESTRUCTION
the integral is the expected profits from the second period, taking into con-
sideration the job destruction decision. This expression, whose formal value is
given by the term inside the brackets, should be read as follows. In the second
period the productivity will be equal to z, where z can take any value from the
support of the distribution G. But we know that, conditional on observing z,
the firm will operate as long as the expected profits are larger than the firing
costs. This is reflected by the max operator. The integral symbol simply sums
up all possible values of z, with weights given by the distribution G(z).
At time 1 there are no firing costs to be paid, since the job has not yet been
established. If the job is not going to be created, the firm does not face any cost,
so that the outside option at the moment of creation is simply zero. The job
creation decision is then described by the following simple condition:
Create if 1 (ε) > 0
Not Create if 1 (ε) < 0
This suggests that the decision to create will be regulated by a reservation
productivity ε c such that
1 (ε c ) = 0
εc is the creation margin, and needs to be solved with a few steps of algebra.
dεc g (ε d ) d
= [ε − w + F ]
dε d 1+r
In other words, the job creation margin is akin to a quadratic function that
features a minimum in correspondence to a point of the job destruction curve.
To understand this property recall that along the job creation curve (ε c ) = 0.
Consider a point on the job creation curve to the left of the job destruction
curve. In such a point, an increase in the job destruction margin (which is
lower than w − F ) increases profits in the second period, and such an increase
must be compensated by a decrease in ε c for the expected profits to be zero.
The opposite happens to the right of the maximum.
An increase in firing costs reduces job destruction in the second period but it
also reduces job creation in the first period.
This conclusion is the fundamental effect of firing costs on job creation and
destruction.
200 JOB DESTRUCTION
εc
JD
εc
JC
εd = w–F εd
Figure 11.5. The effects of an increase in firing costs on job creation and job destruction
T
uk+t
Ut =
(1 + r)k
k=1
When the firm problem is dynamic and multi-period, the surplus of the firm
is the difference between the present discounted value of productivity and the
presented discounted value of wages. If we label t the present discounted
value of profits (or Sft ) we have
yt +2 − wt +2 y T − wT
t = yt − wt + ... +
1+r (1 + r)T
which can be written as
T
yt +k − wt +k
t =
(1 + r)k
k=1
T
yt +k wt +k
T
t = − ≥0
(1 + r)k (1 + r)k
k=1 k=1
t = Jt − Wt ≥ 0.
12 Further Issues in
Employment Protection
Legislation
12.1 Introduction
The previous chapters in the book studied the role of employment protection in
the context of temporary contract and in the case of job destruction. We learnt
two key messages. First, employment protection biases the firm choice toward
temporary contract. Second, employment protection reduces job destruction
and increases labour hoarding. Yet, when job creation is also explicitly con-
sidered, employment protection also depresses job creation. While these are
indeed the key messages in the literature of employment protection legislation,
other important issues need to be considered.
In real life labour markets, employment protection legislation is a multi-
dimensional institution. Its provisions are often very complex, and the
legislation not only forces the firm to pay specific sums of money to the dis-
missed worker, but it also forces the firm to follow specific procedures, which
inevitably involve deadweight losses to both parties. In other words, employ-
ment protection legislation involves both transfer inside the firm–worker pair
as well as taxes paid outside the match. Section 12.2 documents that the largest
part of the legislation refers to transfer. But the difference between taxes and
transfer is economically very important when wage determination is explicitly
considered. In previous chapters, the role of employment protection legisla-
tion was always analysed at a given wage. In reality, wages are likely to respond
to the existence of EPL. Indeed, the model of section 12.3 shows that when
wages are endogenously determined by rent sharing, the transfer component
of EPL is likely to be allocative neutral. This means that employment protec-
tion legislation may have a large impact on wage profiles, but little impact on
job destruction. Such a conclusion is not true in the case of the tax component
of EPL, whose effects cannot be fully absorbed the wages.
Another dimension of EPL in real life labour markets is the different degree
of stringency across firms of different sizes. Large firms have typically a degree
of EPL that is tighter than the degree of EPL imposed on small firms. This
differences is also economically important, since it may affect the scale of
EMPLOYMENT PROTECTION LEGISLATION 203
operation of each firm. In other words, firms may have an incentive to operate
below a given EPL threshold just as a way to save on EPL provisions beyond
the threshold. These issues are analysed in section 12.4, in a simple model of
EPL with threshold effects.
É This requirement goes well beyond the information published by the OECD (1999). Possibly, for
this reason we are not aware of any other study trying to make this comparison.
Ê The union to which the worker is affiliated usually bears all the legal costs in this case.
Ë Concerning the definition of a legitimate separation, the Italian EPL does not make any difference
in terms of firm size. Yet, the maximum compensation to which unlawfully fired workers are entitled
varies with firm size in two important dimensions. For small firms (with less than fifteen employees),
the choice between a full reinstatement and a severance payment rests with the firm. Further, for
workers employed in firms with less than fifteen employees the maximum severance payment that can
be obtained in court is limited to six months’ wages.
EMPLOYMENT PROTECTION LEGISLATION 205
the firm will pay the forgone social insurance contributions augmented by a
penalty for delayed payment. In addition, the worker may choose between a
severance payment of fifteen months or the right of being reinstated by the
firm that unlawfully fired him.Ì In over 95 per cent of the cases, the worker opts
for the former option. Finally, all the legal costs will be paid by the firm. Thus,
if we let n be the number of months that it takes to reach a court decision,
w the gross monthly wage, τ s the social security contributions, τ h the health
insurance contribution, φ the penalty rate on forgone contributions, sp the
mandatory severance payments for unfair dismissal, and lc the total legal cost,
the total ex post firing cost FC is
FC = nw + (τ s + τ h + φ)nw + sp + lc.
The pure transfer component paid by the firm to the worker is
S = nw + ατ s nw + sp,
where α is the share of the social security contributions that is rebated to
the worker in the form of increased future pensions, in which case such a
payroll contribution should be counted as transfer inside the match. The tax
component is
T = (1 − α)τ s nw + (τ h + φ)nw + lc.
Table 12.1 provides an estimate of the size of FC as well as of the components T
and S in the total firing costs when α = 0, the share that minimizes the transfer
Forgone wages nw 12 0 12
Health insurance τ h w 1 1 0
Social security contributions τ s w 4 4 0
Sanctions for delayed payments φ w 3 3 0
Legal costs lc 6 6 0
Severance payments sp 15 0 15
Ex post firing costs FC 41 14 27
Share 100 34 66
Ì See Ichino (1996) for the legal sources of this binding rule. Note that the number reported by the
OECD (1999: table 2.A.2, p. 95) on the statutory severance payment in Italy is erroneous, since it refers
instead to the mandatory deferred wage scheme (TFR), a very different institution.
206 EMPLOYMENT PROTECTION LEGISLATION
component, i.e. the case that makes the tax component as large as possible. The
estimate suggests that the total ex post cost is over forty months’ wages, and
the transfer component of the total firing costs amounts to 66 per cent.
Ex ante firing cost. The above computation results in an impressively high
firing cost, but we should keep in mind that it is based on the worst possible
scenario for the firm: once the case has been taken to court and the judge has
reached a verdict favourable to the worker. Obviously, ex ante the firm–worker
pair does not know with certainty whether the separation will be ruled unfair
by the tribunal: let pu denote the probability of such event. Many employer-
initiated separations are not settled in court. Firms and workers often find
a satisfactory settlement out of court and strike a deal before the full trial is
over. In the case of an out of court agreement, the parties can save any court
penalties that may eventually be imposed by a judge, and all the legal costs
linked to the trial. In particular, if the two parties bargain in a symmetrical
Nash fashion on the settlement, the joint maximization problem will solve
1 1
max S − pu S 2 −S + pu (S + T ) 2 ,
S
where we denote by Ŝ the point of agreement between firm and worker. Notice
that we have assumed—as common practice in Italy—that the labour union
will pay the legal costs in cases where the lay-off is ruled fair. The solution gives
Ŝ = pu (S + (T /2)) which is an amount larger than the expected transfer the
worker would receive, but smaller than the total cost (transfer plus tax) the
firm would pay in case the firing is ruled unfair. The intuition is that half of
the tax becomes part of the settlement. For the purpose of our analysis, it is
important to remark that in this case the entire firing cost for the firm is a
transfer to the dismissed worker.
Let pa be the probability of agreement out of court. If we ignore discounting,
the ex ante (with respect to the court’s verdict) expected firing cost FC is
T
FC = pa pu S + + 1 − pa pu FC + (1 − pu )CL , (12.1)
2
where CL is the firing cost incurred by the firm when the judge rules the firing
legitimate. Since, as we explained above, in the Italian legislation CL = 0, the
expected transfer component is
T
S = pa pu S + + 1 − pa pu S (12.2)
2
Galdon-Sanchez and Guell (2000), using data based on actual court sen-
tences, compute
that in Italy the probability of reaching an out of court
agreement pa is roughly
0.50, and the probability of the individual lay-off
being ruled unfair pu is also approximately 0.50. With these probabilities,
falls to eighteen months’ wages. However,
using the estimates of Table 12.1, FC
for the sake of our analysis, what matters is the fact that the share of the transfer
rises to over 80 per cent of the total.
the party must agree on a salary that we label wi . At that point production
takes place.
• We assume that there is no discount rate. This means that 1 euro at time
2 yields a value at time 1 equal to 1 euro.
Sf ,2 = εh − wi − (−T )
Let’s now consider the worker position at time t = 2. The worker surplus from
a wage agreement is
Sw,2 = wi − (T + u)
where u is the value of the outside option for 1 period and T is the severance
payment. The total surplus is simply
S2 = εh − u
wi : wi − (T + u) = βS2
wi = (1 − β)u + βεh + T
EMPLOYMENT PROTECTION LEGISLATION 209
The wage of the insider is a simple weighted average between the worker outside
option and the productivity of the match. In addition, the severance payment
increases the wage of the insiders. This means that insiders’ wages go up with
respect to a situation without severance payment.
Let’s now move to the first period. The cumulative expected profits from
employment at time 1 for the firm are equal to
1 = εh − wo + p(εh − wi ) − (1 − p)T
where εh − wo are the operational profits in the first period. Note that the
second period expected profits are random. In the second period two things
can happen: with probability p the job continues and the firm gets εh − wi (wi
is the insider wage), while with probability (1 − p) the job is destroyed and the
firm pays the severance payment to the worker.
Let’s now turn to the workers’ value of employment at time 1, which can be
written as
W1 = wo + pwi + (1 − p)(u + T ).
The total value of the outside option, which we indicate with U , is simply equal
to the total sum of the per period outside option u, so that U = 2u.
As we mentioned above, at time t = 1 the worker is an outsider and he or
she is not entitled to severance payment. This means that the total surplus to
the worker is
Sw,1 = W1 − U1 .
As for the firm, if agreement is not reached, there is no severance payment
involved so that Sf ,1 = 1 . This means that the total surplus at time t = 1 is
S1 = W1 − U1 + 1
which, after a simple substitution of the functions, leads to
S1 = εh − u + p(εh − u)
The previous expression simply says that the total surplus from the match
is the difference between the value of the labour product and the worker’s
outside option in period 1, plus the same difference in period 2 multiplied
by the probability that the job continues (which is equal to p). Note that the
severance payment does not enter in the determination of the surplus also in
the first period. To obtain the insider wage consider that
W − U = βSi
which is an expression that says that the worker gets a fraction β of the total
surplus. The total outsider wage is then
wo + pwi + (1 − p)T − u − u = βεh − βu + βp(εh − u)
wo = u(1 − β) + βεh − T
210 EMPLOYMENT PROTECTION LEGISLATION
The wage of the outsider worker is reduced by the full amount of the severance
payment. While it is true that the insider workers get an increase in their wage
equal to T , the analysis has also shown that such a wage increase is fully prepaid
by the outsider worker. This has also a further important consequence.
When wages are flexible, the severance payment has no impact on firm profits.
In other words, the severance payment with wage flexibility is neutral.
This can be seen by showing that the severance payment has no impact on
the firm’s expected profits. One simply substitutes the outsider wage and the
insider wage into the firm’s profits to obtain
1 = εh − wo + p(εh − wi ) − (1 − p)T
= εh − u(1 − β) − βεh + T + pεh − p(1 − β)u − pβεh − pT − (1 − p)T
= (εh − u)(1 − β) + p(1 − β)(εh − u)
From the previous conclusion it follows immediately that the firm’s hiring
decision is not affected by the presence of severance payments. If the cumu-
lative profits are unchanged, the firm clearly does not change its hiring policy,
even though the hiring decision is not explicitly modelled in this section.
Having derived the surplus, the wage of the insider is obtained so that the
worker gets a fraction β of the total surplus. This means that
wi : wi − u = βS2
from which it follows, after a simple substitution, that
wi = (1 − β)u + βεh + βF
The wage of the insider is then a simple weighted average between the worker’s
outside option and the productivity of the match. In addition, the firing tax
increases the wage of the insiders by a factor that is proportional to the workers’
bargaining power. This means that insiders’ wages go up with respect to a
situation without firing tax.
Let’s now move to the first period. The expected profits from employment
at time 1 for the firm are equal to
1 = εh − wo + p(εh − wi ) − (1 − p)F
where εh − wo are the operational profits in the first period. The second period
expected profits are random. In the second period two things can happen:
with probability p the job continues and the firm gets εh − wi (wi is the insider
wage), while with probability (1 − p) the job is destroyed and the firm pays
the firing tax. Let’s now turn on the workers’ value of employment at time 1,
which can be written as
W1 = wo + pwi + (1 − p)u.
The total value of the outside option, which we indicate with U , is simply equal
to the total sum of the per period outside option u, so that U = 2u.
As we mentioned above, at time t = 1 the worker is an outsider and he or
she is not entitled to the firing tax. This means that the total surplus to the
worker is
Sw,1 = W1 − U1 .
As for the firm, if agreement is not reached, there is no severance payment
involved so that Sf ,1 = 1 . This means that the total surplus at time t = 1 is
simply
S1 = W1 − U1 + 1
which, after a simple substitution of the functions, leads to
S1 = εh − u + p(εh − u) − (1 − p)F
The previous expression simply says that the total surplus from the match is
the difference between the value of the labour product and the outside option
212 EMPLOYMENT PROTECTION LEGISLATION
W − U = βSi
so that
The wage of the outsider worker is reduced by a fraction β of the firing tax.
While the insider worker gets an increase in his wage equal to βF , the analysis
has also shown that such a wage increase is fully prepaid by the outsider worker.
This has also a further important consequence.
Even when wages are flexible, the firing tax has impact on firm profits, and
it is not neutral.
This can be seen by showing that the firing tax reduces expected profits.
One simply substitutes the outsider wage and the insider wage into the firm’s
profits to obtain
1 = εh − wo + p(εh − wi ) − (1 − p)F
= (εh − u)(1 − β) + p(1 − β)(εh − u) − F (1 − β)(1 − p)
The previous expression clearly shows that the firing tax F negatively affects
the present discounted profits.
labour demand. This section proceeds as follows. First, we solve for the efficient
allocation, next we show the properties of the model with an extreme form
of EPL. Finally, we introduce threshold effects, and derive the main empirical
predictions on firm level dynamics.
Constrained Firm: A type-ε firm with efficient employment allocation in good business con-
ditions larger than the threshold (lg (ε) > l thr ) is constrained when it employs l = lb in bad
business conditions and l = l thr in good business conditions.
the latter case, they permanently fluctuate inside the flexible fringe of the size
distribution.
To complete our description, we need to characterize the conditions that
ensure that constrained firms exist in equilibrium. In general, a type-ε firm
will be constrained and will follow a stay-small policy as long as its average
profits are higher than the average profits from the rigid system, or when
ESC (ε) > ER (ε). Among other things, this condition clearly depends on
the specific value of the idiosyncratic parameter ε, as we show in our next
result.
Firms in the interval ε ∈ [ε∗ , ε∗∗ ] are constrained, where ε∗ = l thr + w
and ε ∗∗ is a positive number larger than ε∗ . In light of this result, the firm
size distribution is partitioned in three intervals. Firms with idiosyncratic
component ε lower than ε ∗ are totally efficient and do not interact in any
way with the threshold (their employment level in good times is lower than
the threshold). Firms with idiosyncratic component in the interval [ε ∗ , ε∗∗ ]
are constrained, and in good times bunch with employment l thr = ε∗ − w.
Finally for idiosyncratic values of ε larger than ε ∗∗ , firms are rigid and hire
l R (ε).
To prove this result one needs simply to introduce the function
z(ε) = E SC (ε) − E R (ε)
whose expression reads
p 2 thr 1 thr 2
z(ε) = (ab − w) + (1 − p) εl − l − wl
2 2
1
− [pab + (1 − p)ε − w]2
2
First note that the threshold is irrelevant for those firms for which lg (ε) <
l thr , which is a condition that is satisfied as long as ε < ε∗ , with ε ∗ = l thr + w.
Type-ε firms with idiosyncratic component below ε ∗ are totally efficient and
do not interact in any way with the threshold.
Second, note that z(ε∗) = p(1 − p)[ab − w − l thr ]2 > 0 and that z(ε∗ ) > 0
so that firms with ε > ε∗ are certainly constrained. To find the upper support
of the interval [ε∗ , ε∗∗ ] one needs to solve the quadratic equation z(ε) = 0
whose largest root reads
ε∗ − (pab )1/2
ε∗∗ =
1 − p 1/2
It is immediately clear that ε∗∗ > ε ∗ strictly, so that all firms in the interval
[ε∗ , ε∗∗ ] are constrained. Conversely, for ε > ε∗∗ z(ε) < 0 and firms choose
the rigid system.
EMPLOYMENT PROTECTION LEGISLATION 217
MPL, w
ab
A B
D
C
w
Figure 12.1. Labor demand in good and bad times and threshold effects
13.1 Introduction
Team-organized production is a key feature of many organizations. Most job
advertisements explicitly look for workers that possess team-specific skills, and
are motivated to work in teams. Indeed, team production and group-based
incentives pose a great challenge to personnel economics. As it turns out, a
simple approach to the problem would argue that organized team production
is likely to lead to a reduction in productivity. This is the so-called 1/N th
problem, whereby effort put forward by workers under team production is
likely to be less than what would be exerted under individual-based incentives.
If this is indeed the case, all we can do under team production is to find ways to
preserve the right incentives, even though it appears that overall productivity
will hardly be larger than what it would have been if individual-based incentives
were in place.
Yet, to fully understand team production, and all the emphasis that real
life organizations do place on teams, we have to move forward and expli-
citly recognize that there exist benefits and costs linked to team production.
After all, if so many firms are interested in workers able to work in teams,
it has to be the case that team-specific skills (such as communication skills)
and the possibility of mutual learning among team members may increase
the total surplus generated by the workforce. The personnel economics lit-
erature is still growing in this dimension. Many good questions exist, but
answers are often limited. In this context, we prefer to offer a case study
approach.
Does the adoption of a team increase or decrease productivity? How does
team composition affect productivity? Are teams more productive if members
are homogeneous or heterogeneous? As we argued above, personnel economics
has no full answer to this problem. What we can do is to bring empirical
research to the topic, and analyse in close detail a case study on the adoption
of team production in the garment industry. Surprisingly, and contrary to
what the 1/N th problem would predict, we will see that in the specific study
analysed, individual productivity under group incentives has increased, rather
than decreased. This suggests that there is still a lot to be learnt in the area of
team production.
TEAMS AND GROUP INCENTIVES 219
Worker’s problem. Beside the efficient level, we know that each individual
solves their own maximization problem by maximizing their utility. The utility
of the individual depends, as always, on the compensation scheme and on the
cost of effort, so that
ei2
Ui = compensationi −
2
The most obvious compensation scheme is one in which the total output from
the team is shared proportionally among its team members. In other words,
each worker maximizes his or her individual utility, given a compensation
schedule, or ‘output sharing rule’. Further suppose this sharing rule implies the
e
following compensation, compensationi = N i ∀i. In other words the team
members agree to share the total revenues of the team equally. In this situation,
how hard will people actually work?
Individual i’s pay-off: Yi = e1 +eiN+...eN ; Individual i’s disutility of effort:
e12
C(ei ) = 2. So the individual’s problem is:
e 1 + e i + . . . eN e2
max − i
e1 N 2
with the following first-order condition:
1
− ei = 0
N
An Individual’s (privately) optimal effort is therefore given by e1∗ = 1/N .
How can the previous conclusion be explained, and why is the individual
optimal effort so different from the efficient level? The intuition is as follows.
While the worker is still bearing the full cost of his or her additional effort,
the compensation scheme implies that the marginal benefit of one additional
unit of effort is only 1/N . This is called the ‘free rider problem’ or the ‘1/N
problem’. The total effort of all agents is N × N1 = 1 instead of N , which is the
efficient level.
Note that this result has nothing to do with the assumption that the group’s
output is shared equally among its members. It is true for any fixed sharing
rule, where worker i receives a share γi of the total, as long as γi = 1 (all the
workers’ shares must add up to 100 per cent).
Under the above rule in our example each worker’s effort will equal γi , and
the sum of all the workers’ efforts will equal γi = 1, rather than N which is
needed for efficiency. Summarizing our result:
Any group compensation rule that shares group output according to a fixed
rate induces sub-optimal effort due to free riding. The problem increases in
severity as the group size, N , increases.
TEAMS AND GROUP INCENTIVES 221
The free rider problem associated with team production is quite common
in reality, even outside strict personnel economics examples. Among students,
when group projects are associated with a common grade, it is very difficult to
induce efforts by all members, and there is always a tendency to rely on other
people’s effort and ability. A somewhat similar problem takes place when a
group of friends decide to share restaurant bills. Each individual has a tendency
to consume expensive meals, so as to rely on other friends’ contributions.
One way to obtain this scheme is that the ‘firm’ or some agreed-on team
member sets a target output M , which we can call team norm M .
• Everyone is paid zero if the output M is not reached, and the firm keeps
the difference.
• The output is split evenly among team members if the output norm is
reached, while the pay is zero otherwise.
• If the team norm M is the output when all individuals produce at the
efficient level e ∗ = 1, then each worker gets paid $1 and the firm breaks
even.
As you can see, establishing a team norm is the way to keep the incentive
right for workers, since that marginal increase of producing at the efficient
level is exactly $1. But the very difficult task is to establish the proper norm,
and to enforce it.
cost–benefit analysis over the decision to enter team production. Obviously, the
highest-ability worker will join a team only if he or she obtains an additional
source of surplus from team production. In terms of output performance,
high-ability workers are bound to suffer, since they are going to share pro-
duction with less productive co-workers. This suggests that for a high-ability
worker to join the team, there must be additional reasons, which can be concep-
tualized in two ways: (i) productivity gains may derive from multi-skill abilities;
(ii) socialization within the team may compensate high-ability workers in
terms of income. As we see in the case study below, these phenomena do exist in
reality.
Productivity
25% 80.12 71.55 87.58
50% 99.33 86.8 105.45
75% 118.3 108.5 120.38
Weekly earnings
25% $197.52 $159.64 $226.66
50% $274.02 221.77 $301.03
75% $350.26 291.51 $369.06
Hours/week
25% 28.52 24 30.01
50% 34.4 32 35.72
75% 38.8 38.33 38.86
Age
25% 30 30.9 30.1
50% 37 39.7 35.9
75% 45.4 48 44.3
Observations 20,626 6,688 13,938
É In technical terms the presence of cyclical variation implies that a proper multivariate analysis
should include also time dummies.
TEAMS AND GROUP INCENTIVES 225
100 120
90
110
80
Percent of workers in team
100
Worker productivity
70
60
90
50 Median weekly
worker productivity 80
40
30 70
20
Fraction of workers in team 60
10
0 50
0 26 52 78 104 130 156
Number of weeks since 1/1/1995
would be predicted if free riding were dominant. Table 13.2 reports average
weekly worker productivity for individuals prior to joining the team and team
productivity after joining the team. Productivity increased in fourteen of the
twenty-three teams for which data are available. Teams formed in 1995 are the
most likely to show an increase in productivity, suggesting that workers with
greater collaborative skills joined the early teams.
The case study analysed three questions in detail:
1. Did the use of teams lead to higher productivity, contrary to what might
be predicted by simple models of free riding?
2. Which type of workers (in terms of ability) joined the teams? Is there
an adverse selection into teams (with less able workers joining teams) as
the free riding problem would suggest? Or maybe there are collaborative
skills that were not used in PBS?
3. How does team composition affect team productivity?
a Entries in col. (2) are calculated by averaging the individual person week productivity values of
workers who subsequently join the particular team (individuals are weighted by the length of time
they spent on the team).
b Team averages in col. (3) are calculated after excluding the first 20 weeks.
c Team 21 consisted of almost all new hires, and so the pre-team productivity data are not available.
more productive workers, rather than less productive, were the first to join
teams. The 1/N problem would suggest that most able workers have the most
to lose from team membership. One can examine the issue in more detail. To
investigate the self-selection into teams, one can estimate a ‘pre-team’ regres-
sion for the 151 non-team workers employed in week 0, when teams were not
yet formed. This simple regression takes the form
where yi0 is the ln(productivity) of worker i in the first week of January 1995
(week 0) and the indicator variable FTEAMio equals one if worker i joins a team
by mid-1996 and zero if she does not. Basically the coefficient γ captures the
productivity under PBS of the individuals that later decided to enter team pro-
duction. Because future team membership cannot affect current productivity,
γ measures the selection into teams. Panel A of Table 13.4 indicates that work-
ers who joined teams in future are approximately 15 per cent more productive
in non-team work in January 1995. This result goes against the free rider prob-
lem. It is not that low-productivity workers are sorted into teams because of
the adverse selection problem. Just the opposite occurs. Either technical ability
is somewhat positively correlated with collaborative skills or teams offer non-
pecuniary benefits that are larger for high-ability workers. In addition, it may
be that the disutility imposed by a team norm on low-productivity workers was
so large as to discourage many of them from joining teams at the beginning.
The big puzzle is what happens to earnings. Regressions of the log of hourly
pay on team membership (controlling for demographics and cyclical factors)
in Table 13.5 show that while average pay increased after the introduction of
teams, workers at the top end of the pay distribution experienced an 8 per cent
reduction in hourly pay under teams. The overall increase in average pay is
not surprising, especially since we saw that overall productivity increased. The
surprise is the fall in wage at the top of the distribution. This suggests that
non-pecuniary benefits of team membership, such as more control over the
work environment and less repetition, are important factors for many workers.
Further analysis shows also that the pay results are not caused by the fact
that high-ability workers participated in teams only for a few periods and then
quit the firm when they learned that their pay was unlikely to rise.
230 TEAMS AND GROUP INCENTIVES
Variable −1 −2 −3 −4 −5 −6
Note:The number of observations is 20,193. Standard errors are in parentheses (robust standard errors
for OLS regressions). Each regression also includes a constant, age of the worker and its square, dummies
for each month.
PRODUCTION FUNCTION
The production function is the technology that the firm uses in the production process.
For simplicity, in Appendix A we assume that there are only two factors of production
(two inputs): the number of employee-hours hired by the firm (L) and capital (K ).
We write the production function as
q = f (L, K )
where q is the firm output, and f is the technological relationship that transforms
inputs into output. The production function specifies how much output is produced
by any combination of labour and capital. With respect to the labour input, there are
two key assumptions to be discussed in detail. First, the number of employee-hours
L is given by the product of the number of workers hired times the average number
of hours worked per person. Chapter 3 considers the distinction between the number
of workers hired and the number of hours worked. In this appendix we simply refer
to labour input L as the number of workers hired. Second, the production function
assumes that different types of workers can be aggregated into a single input that we call
labour. In fact workers are heterogeneous, and Chapter 2 discusses issues of workers’
heterogeneity.
MARGINAL PRODUCT
The marginal product of labour, which we denote as MPL , is defined as the change in
output resulting from hiring an additional worker, holding constant the quantities of
all other inputs. The MPL is formally given by
q
MPL =
L K
q
MPk =
K L
LABOUR DEMAND AT THE FIRM LEVEL 233
The marginal product of labour is the slope of the total curve, which can be thought
as the relationship between output and labour holding capital constant. There are two
important properties of the marginal product
70.00
60.00
50.00
40.00
Output
30.00
20.00
10.00
0.00
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
–10.00 Employment
PROFIT MAXIMIZATION
We assume that the firm’s employment decision maximizes profits. The firm’s profits
are given by:
π = pq − wL − rK
where p is the price at which the firm can sell its output; w is the wage rate (that is,
the cost of hiring an additional worker) and r is the price of capital. In this appendix
we assume that the firm is perfectly competitive, both in the output market and in
the input market. This simply means that the firm takes as given the price p, the wage
w, and the cost of capital r. Further, such quantities are independent of how much
the firm produces and hires. If we substitute the production function into the profit
equation we obtain
π = pf (L, K ) − wL − rK
Since p, w, and r are constant, the previous equation makes clear that the only actions
the firm can take to influence profits involve the decisions of how much labour and
capital to hire. The firm maximizes profits by hiring the right amounts of these inputs.
12.00
Marginal product High wage
11.00
10.00 Low wage
Wage, marginal product
9.00
8.00
7.00
6.00
5.00
4.00
3.00
2.00
1.00
0.00
1.00 2.00 3.00 4.00 5.00 6.00 7.00 8.00 9.00 10.00
Employment
LABOUR DEMAND
The demand for labour tells us what happens to the firms’ employment as the wage
changes, holding capital constant. From Fig. A.1, it is clear that the optimal quantity of
labour hired depends on the wage rate. If the wage rate increases to 8, the amount of
labour hired falls, while if the wage rate falls, the amount of labour hired increases. All
this happens as long as the marginal product of labour is downward sloping. It follows
that the firm’s demand for labour in the short run is equivalent to the downward-sloping
segment of its value marginal product of labour schedule.
worker yields MPL and costs w so that the ratio gives the output of the last dollar
spent on labour. Similarly, the right-hand side gives the output yield of the last dollar
spent on capital. The condition can be used to obtain the capital–labour ratio. Once
the capital–labour ratio is obtained we can obtain the actual level of labour from the
second condition, which is identical to the short-run maximization.
b APPENDIX B CONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION
x2
x*
h(x1, x2) = C
x1
The fact that the level curve f is tangential to the constraint set C at the constrained
maximizer (x1∗ , x2∗ ) means that the slope of the level set of f equals the slope of the
constraint curve C at (x1∗ , x2∗ ). The slope of the level set f at (x1∗ , x2∗ ) is
∂f
∂x1
− ∂f
(x1∗ , x2∗ )
∂x2
The fact that these two slopes are equal at (x1∗ , x2∗ ) means
∂f ∂h
∂x1 ∂x1
∂f
(x1∗ , x2∗ ) = ∂h
(x1∗ , x2∗ )
∂x2 ∂x2
To avoid working with (possibly) zero denominators in the previous expression, let
us indicate with µ the common value of the two quotients in the previous expression
so that
∂f ∂f
∂x1 ∂x2
∂h
(x1∗ , x2∗ ) = ∂h
(x1∗ , x2∗ ) = µ
∂x1 ∂x2
There is a convenient way of writing the system. Form the Lagrangian function as
maximize f (x1 , x2 )
subject to h(x1 , x2 ) = c
whose solution is x1∗ , x2∗ is solved (as long as x1∗ , x2∗ is not a critical point of h) by setting
up a Lagrange function
and the solution x1∗ , x2∗ is obtained by finding a critical point x1,∗ x2∗ , µ∗ of the Lagrangian
so that
∂L ∂L ∂L
= 0, = 0, =0
∂x1 ∂x2 ∂µ
É The process would not have worked if both ∂h/∂x1 and ∂h/∂x2 were zero at the point x1∗ x2∗ . This
implies that we need to make the assumption that these partial derivatives are not zero at the constrained
maximizer. In a case where the constraint is linear this additional condition is automatically satisfied.
CONSTRAINED OPTIMIZATION 241
at x1,∗ x2∗ , µ∗
If the problem is one of minimizing a function, the second-order condition involves
finding a determinant that is negative, so that in the previous condition the determinant
of the 3 by 3 matrix should be negative.
Second-order condition for a minimization. Suppose that . x1,∗ x2∗ , µ∗ are a critical
point of the Lagrangian so that
∂L ∂L ∂L
= 0, = 0, =0
∂x1 ∂x2 ∂µ
To check whether x1,∗ x2∗ is a local min of f (x1 , x2 ) on h(x1 , x2 ) one needs to check that
⎧ ∂h ∂h
⎫
⎪
⎪ 0 ∂x1 ∂x2 ⎪
⎪
⎨ ∂h ∂2L ∂2L
⎬
det ∂x1 ∂x12 ∂x ∂x <0
⎪
⎪
1 2
⎪
⎪
⎩ ∂h ∂2L ∂2L ⎭
∂x2 ∂x1 ∂x2 ∂x2 2
at x1,∗ x2∗ , µ∗
b R E F E R E N C ES
Abowd, J. M., Kramarz, F., Margolis, D. N., and Philippon, T. (2000), The Tale of Two Countries:
Minimum Wage and Employment in France and the United States, IZA working paper.
Acemoglu, D. (1997), ‘Training and Innovation in an Imperfect Labour Market’, Review of
Economic Studies, 64: 445–64.
Acemoglu, Daron, and Pischke, Jorn-Steffen (1998), ‘Why Do Firms Train: Theory and Evidence’,
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113: 79–199.
—— (1999), ‘The Structure of Wages and Investment in General Training’, Journal of Political
Economy, 107: 539–72.
Adam, Paula, and Canziani, Patrizia (1998), Partial De-regulation: Fixed Term Contracts in Italy
and Spain, Centre for Economic Performance Discussion Paper 306.
Akerlof, G. A., and Katz, L. (1989),‘Workers’ Trust Funds and the Logic of Wage Profiles’, Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 104/3: 525–36.
Alvarez, F., and Veracierto, M. (2001),‘Severance Payments in an Economy with Frictions’, Journal
of Monetary Economics, 47: 477–98.
Autor, David (2001), ‘Why Do Temporary Help Firms Provide Free General Skills Training?’,
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116/4 (Nov.): 1409–48.
Autor, D., Katz, L., and Krueger, A. (1988), ‘Computing Inequalities: Have Computers Changed
the Labor Market’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113: 1169–213.
Baker, George (1992), ‘Incentives Contracts and Performance Measurement’, Journal of Political
Economy, 100: 598–614.
—— (1994),‘The Internal Economics of a Firm: Evidence from Personnel Data’, Quarterly Journal
of Economics, 109/4: 891–919.
—— and Holmstrom, Bengt (1995),‘Internal Labor Markets: Too Many Theories, Too Few Facts’,
AER, 85/2: 255–9.
—— Gibbons, Robert, and Murphy, Kevin (1984), ‘Subjective Performance Measures in Optimal
Incentive Contracts’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109/4: 921–55.
—— Jensen, Michael, and Murphy, Kevin (1988), ‘Compensation and Incentive: Practice vs.
Theory’, Journal of Finance, 43: 593–616.
Barron, J. M., Black, D. A., and Loewenstein, M. A. (1987), ‘Employer Size: The Implications
for Search, Training, Capital Investment, Starting Wages, and Wage Growth’, Journal of Labor
Economics, 5/1: 76–89.
—— (1993), ‘Gender Differences in Training, Capital, and Wages’, Journal of Human Resources,
28/2: 343–64.
Barron, J. M., Berger, M. C., and Black, D. A. (1997), ‘How Well do we Measure Training?’ Journal
of Labor Economics, 15/3: 507–28.
Barron, J., Berger, M., and Black, D. (1999), ‘Do Workers Pay for On-the-Job Training?’ Journal
of Human Resources, 34/2: 235–52.
Bartel, A. (1995), ‘Training, Wage Growth, and Job Performance: Evidence from a Company
Database’, Journal of Labor Economics, 13: 401.
REFERENCES 243
Barton, H. Hamilton, Nickerson, Jack A., and Owan, Hideo (2003), ‘Team Incentives and
Worker Heterogeneity: An Empirical Analysis of the Impact of Teams on Productivity and
Participation’, Journal of Political Economy, 111/3: 465–97.
Becker, G. S. (1962), ‘Investment in Human Capital: A Theoretical Analysis’, Journal of Political
Economy, 70: 9–49.
Becker, Gary (1964), Human Capital, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Becker, G. (1993), Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis with Special Reference to
Education, 3rd edn. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Bentolila, Samuel, and Bertola, Giuseppe (1990), ‘Firing Costs and Labor Demand: How Bad is
Eurosclerosis?’, Review of Economic Studies, 57: 381–402.
Bertola, Giuseppe (1990), ‘Job Security Employment and Wages’, European Economic Review,
851–66.
—— (2004), ‘A Pure Theory of Job Security Provisions’, Review of Economic Studies.
—— and Rogerson, R. (1997), ‘Institutions and Labor Reallocation’, European Economic Review,
1147–71.
Blanchard, O. (1998), Employment Protection and Unemployment, mimeo, MIT, http://econ.www.
mit.edu/faculty/blanchar/index.htm.
Blanchard, Olivier, and Landier, Augustin (2000), ‘The Perverse Effects of Partial Labor Market
Reform: Fixed Duration Contracts in France’, Economic Journal, 112: F214–F244.
Boeri, T. (1999), ‘Enforcement of Employment Security Regulations, on the Job Search and
Unemployment Duration’, European Economic Review, 43: 65–89.
Boeri, Tito (1999), ‘Enforcement of Employment Security Regulations, On-the-Job Search and
Unemployment Duration’, European Economic Review, 43: 65–89.
Booth, A. (1993), ‘Private Sector Training and Graduate Earnings’, Review of Economics and
Statistics, 75/1: 164–70.
Booth, Alison, Francesconi, Marco, and Frank, Jeff (2002), ‘Temporary Jobs: Stepping Stones or
Dead Ends?’, Economic Journal, 112: F189–F213.
Borjas, G. (2004), Labor Economics, 3rd edn. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Brown, J. N. (1989), ‘Why do Wages Increase with Tenure? On-the-Job Training and Life-Cycle
Wage Growth Observed within Firms’, American Economic Review, 79: 971–91.
Brown, C. (1990), ‘Firms’ Choice of Method of Pay’, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 43/3:
165–82.
Burda, M. (1992), ‘A Note on Firing Costs and Severance Payments in Equilibrium Unemploy-
ment’, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 94/3: 479–89.
Calmfors, L., and Hoel, M. (1988), ‘Work Sharing and Overtime’, Scandinavian Journal of
Economics, 90: 45–62.
Cobb, C., and Douglas, P. (1928), ‘A Theory of Production’, American Economic Review, Papers
and Proceedings, 18: 139–65.
Crépon, Bruno, and Kramarz, Francis (2002), ‘Employed 40 Hours or Not-Employed 39: Lessons
from the 1982 Mandatory Reduction of the Workweek’, Journal of Political Economy, 110/6:
1355–89.
Davis, Steven, Haltiwanger, John, and Schuh, Scott (1996), Job Creation and Destruction,
Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Ehrenberg, R. G. (1971), ‘Heterogeneous Labor, the Internal Labor Market, and the Dynamics of
the Employment–Hours Decision’, Journal of Economic Theory, 3: 85–104.
244 REFERENCES
Ehrenberg, Ron, and Bonanno, Michaeal (1990),‘The Incentive Effects of Tournaments Revisited:
Evidence from PGA Tour’, Industrial Labor Relation Review, 43: 74–89.
Ehrenberg, R., and Smith, R. (2003), Modern Labor Economics: Theory and Public Policy, 8th edn.
New York: Addison Wesley Longman Inc.
Elliot, R. F. (1999), Labor Economics: A Comparative Text, New York: McGraw-Hill.
Galdon-Sanchez, J., and Guell, M. (2000),‘Let’s Go to Court! Firing Costs and Dismissal Conflicts’,
Industrial Relations Sections, Princeton University, working paper no. 444.
Garibaldi, Pietro (1998),‘Job Flow Dynamics and Firing Restrictions’, European Economic Review,
42: 245–75.
—— (2004), ‘Search Unemployment with On the Job Search’, Macroeconomic Dynamics.
—— and Pacelli, Lia (2004), ‘Employment Protection and the Size of Firms’, Giornale degli
economisti.
Garibaldi, P., and Violante, G. (2005),‘The Employment Effects of Severance Payments with Wage
Rigidities’, Economic Journal, November.
Gibbons, Robert (1987), ‘Piece Rate Incentives Scheme’, Journal of Labor Economics, 5: 413–29.
—— (1996), ‘Incentives and Careers in Organization’, in David Kreps and Ken Wallis (eds.),
Advances in Economics and Econometrics: Theory and Applications. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press, vol. ii, ch. 1.
Gibbons, R. A. (1998), ‘Incentives in Organizations’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 12: 115–32.
Gibbons, R., and Murphy, K. J. (1992), ‘Optimal Incentive Contracts in the Presence of Career
Concerns’, Journal of Political Economics, 100: 468–506.
Goux, D., Maurin, E., and Pauchet, M. (2001), ‘Fixed Term Contract and the Dynamics of Labor
Demand’, European Economic Review, 45: 533–52.
Grubb, D., and Wells, W. (1993), ‘Employment and Regulations and Patterns of Work in OECD
Countries’, OECD Economic Studies, 7–58.
Guell, M. (2000), Fixed-Term Contracts and Unemployment: An Efficiency Wage Analysis, Industrial
Relations Sections, Princeton University, Working Paper 433.
Hamermesh, D. (1993), Labor Demand, Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Hart, R. (1987), Working Time and Employment, Boston: Allen and Unwin.
Holmstrom, Bengt (1979),‘Moral Hazard and Observability’, Bell Journal of Economics, 10: 75–91.
—— (1982), ‘Moral Hazard in Teams’, Bell Journal of Economics, 13: 324–40.
Hunt, J. (1999), ‘Has Work-Sharing Worked in Germany?’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Feb.:
117–48.
Hunt, Jennifer (2000), ‘Firing Costs, Employment Fluctuations and Average Employment: An
Examination of Germany’, Economica, 67: 177–202.
Ichino, P. (1996), Il lavoro e il mercato, Milan: Mondadori.
Ichino, Pietro (1996), Lo stato e il mercato. Milan: Mondadori.
Kandel, Eugene, and Lazear, Edward P. (1982),‘Peer Pressure and Partnerships’, Journal of Political
Economy, 100: 801–17.
Knoeber, Charles, and Thruman, Walter (1994), ‘Testing the Theory of Tournaments: An
Empirical Analysis of Broiler Production’, Journal of Labour Economics, 12/2: 155–79.
Kuhn, P. (1986), ‘Wages, Effort, and Incentive Compatability in Life-Cycle Employment
Contracts’, Journal of Labor Economics, 4/1: 28–49.
REFERENCES 245
Rosen, S. (1969), ‘Short-Run Employment Variation on Class-I Railroads in the U.S., 1947–1963’,
Econometrica, 36: 511–29.
Schivardi, Fabiano (2000), ‘Labor Market Rigidities, Unemployment and Growth’, Giornale degli
economisti e annali di economia, 115–41.
Shapiro, Carl, and Stiglitz, Joseph (1984), ‘Equilibrium Unemployment as a Discipline Device’,
American Economic Review, 74: 434–44.
Spence, Michael (1973), ‘Job Market Signaling’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87: 355–74.
Spence, A. M. (1974), Market Signaling: Informational Transfer in Hiring and Related Screening
Processes, Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Trejo, S. J. (1991), ‘The Effects of Overtime Pay Regulation on Worker Compensation’, American
Economic Review, 81/4: 719–40.
Wassmer, Etienne (1999), ‘Competition for Jobs in a Growing Economy and the Emergence of
Dualism in Employment’, Economic Journal, 109/457: 349–71.
Yashiv, Eran (2000), ‘The Determinants of Equilibrium Unemployment’, American Economic
Review, 90/5: 1297–322.
b INDEX
ability 68, 72, 74, 128, 131, 141, 225 negative relationship between fixed
average 80, 119, 231 payment and 93
complementarity between training and optimal 95–6, 102–4, 137
186 option for particularly productive
education useful for signalling 78 individuals 115
heterogeneous 108–10, 111–15, 129 preference for 120
high/low 63, 75–81, 110, 112, 117–20, reduction in 100
186, 223, 226, 227, 229, 230, 231 two types of effects associated with 119
private information about 186 bordered Hessian matrix 241
screening of 185 borrowing 98, 156
technical 229, 230 bottlenecks 224
tendency to rely on other people’s 221 broiler production 140–6
unequal 139 budget allocation 31, 34
workers know their own 62, 67 budget constraint 43, 90
accountancy 121 buffer stock model 45, 46, 47
advance notice 8, 203 formal derivation of 49–51, 60–1
adverse selection 62–81, 225, 229 interim costs 53–5
agencies 46, 53 temporary contracts 52
interim 52, 60–1 business conditions:
apprenticeship programmes 167, 171–2 fluctuations 2, 45, 46, 50, 51
asymmetric information 62, 67, 148, 149 good/bad 45, 46, 47, 48, 49, 52, 53, 54,
job-preserving wage with 192–3 55, 187, 213, 214, 215, 217
Autor, David 181, 183
California 223
backward induction 161 capital 232
bad candidates/workers 63, 64, 67, 70, 72, constant 236
186 costly, independent labour interacting
bad times, see business conditions with 22–4
bank credit 98 stock of 12, 13, 18, 233, 234
bargaining power 163, 177, 211 see also human capital
baseline (Becker) model 100, 153, 167, capital markets 179
171, 172–80 cheating 147
facts that run counter to 182 chief executives 140
Belgium 6 classroom-based training 172, 182
Bentolila, S. 212 clerical and secretarial jobs 172, 181
Bertola, G. 212 Cobb-Douglas Production
BLS (US Bureau of Labor Statistics) 181 Function 18
blue collars 15, 204 coefficients 40–1, 124, 127, 145, 146,
Bonanno, M. 140 184, 230
bonus schemes 6, 85, 86, 99, 101, 105, 108, collaborative skills 225, 227, 229, 231
116, 117, 132, 139, 221 collective agreements 1, 2, 8, 34, 37, 190,
effort under 89–91 192, 203
extreme 107, 128 wage set by 188
individuals better off in 118 collective bargaining 7
248 INDEX
severance payments 8, 9, 203, 207, 211 negative 187, 189, 190, 191, 192
choice between full reinstatement and positive 189, 190, 191, 192, 201
204 n., 205 specific 174
deriving wages with 208–10 worker gets fraction of total 207, 208,
mandatory 205 209, 211
shifter parameter 213 zero 194
shirking 138, 147, 148, 149, 150, 151 synthetic indicators 9
shocks:
idiosyncratic 212, 213 tangency condition 17, 31, 90
productivity 52, 56, 142 taxes and transfers 203–12
sickness pay 29 see also firing taxes
signals 63 team production problem 218, 219–20
educational 74–8 team norms as remedies to 221–2
imperfect 84 team productivity 218, 222, 223, 224,
skill acquisition 75, 153 225–7, 229
skill composition 11, 12 ‘stars’ influential in raising 231
skill premium 156, 180 team composition and 230
productivity 20 technological considerations 11
see also skilled wage premium temporary contracts 45, 46, 49, 53, 60
skilled labour 12–13, 64, 65, 70 as buffer stock 52
amount hired must be consistent with costly turnover and 55–8
output 30 identifying unskilled workers at the end
attracting 67, 68, 70, 73 of 70
independent 19–20, 22–4 probation period/wage and 62, 67–72
interdependence of unskilled and 15–19 women more likely to hold 59
outside options 68, 69 temporary help industry, see THS
wage compression 22 tenure 63, 67–8, 126, 127, 160
skilled wage premium 14, 17, 18, 19, 22, 25 average 204
larger than productivity skill premium wages increase with 133
20 termination of contracts 45, 46, 52, 56
smaller firms 37, 202, 204 n. early 203
social security 6, 205 tertiary education 21
socialization 223 threat point 177
sorting effect 108, 115, 119, 120, 123, 124, threshold effects 212–17
127, 141 Thruman, W. 140
pure 126 THS (temporary help service) industry
Spain 6, 9 172
specialization gains 222, 233 firm-sponsored training 181–6
specific training 153 tournaments 132–46
standard deviation 124, 144 trade unions 192, 223
statutory payments 203 density 6–7
stay-small policy 215, 216 desire to have egalitarian wage policy 21
students 69 training 152–86
subsidiary decisions 12 training costs 158, 161, 167, 174, 175
substitution 208, 209, 210, 211 already sunk 177
sunk costs 177 difference between training benefits and
surplus 2–3, 4–5, 113, 114, 148–9, 162, 175, 168
188, 194, 210, 218, 223 financing by taking a wage cut 159, 180
divided by Nash bargaining 177 firm pays all 162, 171, 172, 179
firm-specific 163, 173 marginal 178
joint 166 opportunity to offset 182–3
joint value of 105 sharing 165, 166, 170
marginal 104 total 157
INDEX 257