0% found this document useful (0 votes)
116 views31 pages

Bandwagoning and Balancing

This document summarizes a working paper that argues states have response strategies to power preponderance beyond just balancing and bandwagoning. It identifies four alternative strategies based on a state's relative power and integration in the international system: buffering, bonding, binding, and beleaguering. More powerful states may prefer beleaguering and buffering, while weaker states bond and bind. More integrated states may bind and buffer, while less integrated states bond and beleaguer. Considering these alternative strategies can help explain the absence of balancing against the US in the current unipolar world order.
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
116 views31 pages

Bandwagoning and Balancing

This document summarizes a working paper that argues states have response strategies to power preponderance beyond just balancing and bandwagoning. It identifies four alternative strategies based on a state's relative power and integration in the international system: buffering, bonding, binding, and beleaguering. More powerful states may prefer beleaguering and buffering, while weaker states bond and bind. More integrated states may bind and buffer, while less integrated states bond and beleaguer. Considering these alternative strategies can help explain the absence of balancing against the US in the current unipolar world order.
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 31

No.

54

Revisiting Responses To Power Preponderance:


Going Beyond The
Balancing-Bandwagoning
Dichotomy

Chong Ja Ian

Institute of Defence and Strategic Studies


Singapore

NOVEMBER 2003

With Compliments

This Working Paper series presents papers in a preliminary form and serves to stimulate
comment and discussion. The views expressed are entirely the author’s own and not
that of the Institute of Defence and Strategic Studies
The Institute of Defence and Strategic Studies (IDSS) was established in July 1996 as an
autonomous research institute within the Nanyang Technological University. Its objectives are
to:

• Conduct research on security, strategic and international issues.


• Provide general and graduate education in strategic studies, international relations, defence
management and defence technology.
• Promote joint and exchange programmes with similar regional and international institutions;
organise seminars/conferences on topics salient to the strategic and policy communities of the
Asia-Pacific.

Research
Through its Working Paper Series, IDSS Commentaries and other publications, the Institute seeks
to share its research findings with the strategic studies and defence policy communities. The
Institute’s researchers are also encouraged to publish their writings in refereed journals. The
focus of research is on issues relating to the security and stability of the Asia-Pacific region and
their implications for Singapore and other countries in the region. The Institute has also
established the S. Rajaratnam Professorship in Strategic Studies (named after Singapore’s first
Foreign Minister), to bring distinguished scholars to participate in the work of the Institute.
Previous holders of the Chair include Professors Stephen Walt (Harvard University), Jack Snyder
(Columbia University), Wang Jisi (Chinese Academy of Social Sciences) and Alastair Iain
Johnston (Harvard University). A Visiting Research Fellow Programme also enables overseas
scholars to carry out related research in the Institute.

Teaching
The Institute provides educational opportunities at an advanced level to professionals from both
the private and public sectors in Singapore and overseas through the Master of Science in Strategic
Studies and Master of Science in International Relations programmes. These programmes are
conducted full-time and part-time by an international faculty from July each year. The Institute
also has a Doctorate programme in Strategic Studies/International Relations. In 2004, it will
introduce a new Master of Science in International Political Economy programme. In addition to
these graduate programmes, the Institute also teaches various modules in courses conducted by the
SAFTI Military Institute, SAF Warrant Officers’ School, Civil Defence Academy, Singapore
Technologies College and the Defence, Home Affairs and Foreign Ministries. The Institute also
runs a one-semester course on ‘The International Relations of the Asia Pacific’ for undergraduates
in NTU.

Networking
The Institute convenes workshops, seminars and colloquia on aspects of international relations and
security development which are of contemporary and historical significance. Highlights of the
Institute’s activities include a regular Colloquium on Strategic Trends in the 21st Century, the
annual Asia Pacific Programme for Senior Military Officers and the biennial Asia Pacific Security
Conference (held in conjunction with Asian Aerospace). Institute staff participate in Track II
security dialogues and scholarly conferences in the Asia-Pacific. The Institute has contacts and
collaborations with many think-tanks and research institutes in Asia, Europe and the United States.
The Institute has also participated in research projects funded by the Ford Foundation and the
Sasakawa Peace Foundation. The Institute serves as the Secretariat for the Council for Security
Cooperation in the Asia-Pacific (CSCAP), Singapore. Through these activities, the Institute aims
to develop and nurture a network of researchers whose collaborative efforts will yield new insights
into security issues of interest to Singapore and the region.

i
ABSTRACT

Since the 1990s, there has been a growing body of literature in international
relations that looks at the unipolar world order that emerged from the ashes of the Cold
War. Most of these works, however, tend to focus on describing the characteristics of
this unipolar world or predicting its longevity. This working paper contends that such
approaches do not pay adequate attention to how non-leading states in the international
system are attempting to respond to American primacy of power in this age of unipolarity.
The author argues that conventional conceptions of international politics that frame state
reactions to superior power within the bounds of balancing and bandwagoning are
inadequate to understand how state actors are trying to advance and preserve interests in
relation to preponderant American power.

As such, this paper tries to argue that states try to forward and defend interests in
relation to the system leader based on power relative to the pre-eminent state and
integration in the world system. Power, on one hand, defines the capability of
second-tier states to act, while integration, on the other, helps determine the incentives
and costs of different actions. On the basis of relative power and integration, the paper
identifies four possible alternative conceptualisations of alternative strategies to
balancing and bandwagoning—buffering, bonding, binding, and beleaguering. It goes
on to suggest that the tendency of states to pursue these various approaches to advancing
and defending interests may have an impact on the nature and even duration of the
current unipolar order.

Although this paper takes seriously the structural perspective in considering


responses to dealing with the problem created by highly asymmetric power realities that
lie beyond the balancing-bandwagoning dichotomy, it does not rule out the possibility
that other factors may also affect state action. It accepts that a states power and level of
integration are highly dependent on prior decisions within the polity that may rest on
ideational and contingent material realities. The argument of this paper also does not
rule out the effects of path dependence from previous historical events specific to each
state.

********************

Chong Ja Ian was Visiting Sasakawa Fellow at IDSS in 2003 and is a Ph.D. student at the
Department of Politics, Princeton University.

ii
REVISITING RESPONSES TO POWER PREPONDERANCE: GOING BEYOND
THE BALANCING-BANDWAGONING DICHOTOMY

More than a decade into the era of American unipolarity, the question “why no
balancing?” continues to dog the field of international politics. This fixation on
balancing, and its counterpart, bandwagoning, appears to lie in the almost unquestioned
assumption that these two strategies represent the two main, if not exclusive, approaches
to state security in world politics. Central to this line of thinking is that state actors
bandwagon with the powerful and balance against the threatening in order to preserve
security and promote interests.1 Discussions on the balance of power, for example,
argue that states aim to reduce threats to security by attempting to affect the distribution
of power through their alliance and domestic policy choices. When unable or unwilling
to balance, actors tend to side—or bandwagon—with the powerful.

Balancing and bandwagoning, however, may not fully account for the range of
strategies state actors adopt in order to preserve and promote their interests. Nowhere is
this more apparent than in the contemporary unipolar system—hence the seemingly
remarkable absence of balancing behaviour. Given widespread opposition to
increasingly unilateral U.S. behaviour, states also appear to be unwilling to bandwagon.
Instead, I hope to show that depending on the levels of power disparity with the leading
state and integration in the world system, the strategies of second-tier states display four
broad patterns: Buffering, Bonding, Binding, and Beleaguering.

Essentially, I aim to illustrate that more powerful states in the unipolar framework
will likely prefer beleaguering and buffering; while the weaker, bonding and binding.
At the same time, states more integrated within the world system may tend to bind and
buffer, and the less integrated, bond and beleaguer. The fact second-tier states seek
neither to balance nor bandwagon, may help explain the difficulty of using these two
approaches to understand contemporary world politics.2

The author would like to thank the Centre of International Studies, Princeton University, the Institute of
Defence and Strategic Studies, and the Sasakawa Foundation for their generous support.
1
See Stephen M. Walt, The Origin of Alliances (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1987); Kenneth N.
Waltz, Theory of International Politics (New York, NY: McGraw-Hill, 1979); Kenneth N. Waltz, Man, the
State, and War (New York, NY: Columbia University Press, 1959); Hans Morgenthau, Politics among
Nations: The Struggle for Power and Peace, 5th Edition, Revised (New York, NY: Alfred A. Knopf, 1973).
2
Annette Baker Fox, The Power of Small States: Diplomacy in World War II (Chicago, IL: The University
of Chicago Press, 1959), 2-4, 180-188; Charles L. Glaser, “Realists as Optimists: Cooperation as
Self-Help”, International Security, Vol. 19, No. 3 (Winter 1994/1995): 50-90; Robert L. Rothstein,
Alliances and Small Powers (New York, NY: Columbia University Press, 1968), 1-3; and, Joseph S. Nye,
Jr., The Paradox of American Power: Why the World’s Only Superpower Can’t Go It Alone (Oxford,
England: Oxford University Press, 2002). As Karl Mueller argues, even balancing-type strategies such as
deterrence and bandwagoning-type strategies such as accommodation display high degrees of variation.
1
Historically, balancing and bandwagoning do not have as strong a track record for
explaining state behaviour as international relations scholarship sometimes like to claim.
Weaker states, for instance, appear to display much greater diversity in their strategies
vis-à-vis the powerful than either balancing or bandwagoning captures. In considering
European history, Paul Schroeder illustrates that states have a propensity to engage
alternative approaches to self-preservation that he terms “hiding”, “transcendence”, and
“specialisation”. 3 John Ikenberry, Joseph Joffe, Robert Kagan, and others identify
options such as institutional co-binding to blocking, baiting, and legitimating as
alternative security strategies for states.4 Still others like Karl Deutsch and Thomas
Risse look to socialisation and the creation of security communities as possible
alternative paths to security.5 Likewise, Richard Rosecrance’s work on virtual and
trading states implies that functional value-creation may be another strategy available to
states.6

Taking the current unipolar system, I will attempt to argue that states respond to
preponderant power with behaviour that falls between balancing on one end, and
bandwagoning on the other. This balancing is largely the preserve of Great Powers
whose capabilities do not differ too greatly from that of the leading state.7 States that do
not lag far behind the system leader may engage in balancing, since they can affect the
distribution of power and bring about systemic outcomes. Bandwagoning, on the other
hand, is most prevalent among those that fall behind the pre-eminent state to such an
extent that they can do virtually nothing to influence power distributions or bring about

See Karl P. Mueller, Strategy, Asymmetric Deterrence, and Accommodation: Middle Powers and Security
in Modern Europe, Ph.D. Dissertation, Department of Politics, Princeton University, 1991.
3
“Hiding” involves actions taken by a state to ignore difficult issues, essentially drawing into isolation.
“Transcendence”, on the other hand, aims to resolve disputes through the creation of issue-specific
institutional arrangements. See Paul Schroeder, “Historical Reality versus Neo-Realist Theory”,
International Security, Vol. 19 No. 1 (Summer 1994): 108-148. For more on the autonomy action on the
part of second-tier states even during wartime, see Fox, The Power of Small States and Rothstein, Alliances
and Small Powers, 25-28.
4
G. John Ikenberry, After Victory: Institutions, Strategic Restraint and the Rebuilding of Order after
Major Wars (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2001); Joseph Joffe, “Defying History and Theory:
The United States as the ‘Last Remaining Superpower’”, in G. John Ikenberry, America Unrivalled: The
Future of the Balance of Power (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 2002); and Robert Kagan, Of
Paradise and Power: America versus Europe in the New World Order (New York, NY: Alfred A. Knopf,
Inc., 2003).
5
Thomas Risse, “U.S. Power in a Liberal Security Community”, in Ikenberry, America Unrivalled and
Karl W. Deutsch et al, Political Community in the North Atlantic Area (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Press, 1957).
6
Richard Rosecrance, The Rise of the Virtual State: Wealth and Power in the Coming Century (New York,
NY: Basic Books, 1999) and Richard Rosecrance, The Rise of the Trading State: Commerce and Conquest
in the Modern World (New York, NY: Basic Books, 1986).
7
William C. Wohlforth, “Stability of a Unipolar World”, International Security, Vol. 24, No. 1 (Summer
1999): 10-12; Paul W. Schroeder, Transformation of European Politics (Oxford, England: Clarendon Press,
1994); Paul W. Schroeder, Austria, Britain, and the Crimean War: The Destruction of the European
Concert (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1972); and, Adam Watson, The Evolution of International
Society (London, England: Routledge, 1992).
2
significant independent effects, especially on a systemic level.8 It may take a great
number of Lesothos to balance the United States, for example. Hence, it is unlikely that
very weak states can much other than “suffer what they must”.

Contrary to most contemporary arguments about the nature of the unipolar world,
which claim that balancing is on the immediate horizon or power asymmetry under
unipolarity forces all second-tier states to bandwagon, I hope to illustrate that the
empirical record of state behaviour displays neither tendencies. This is largely due to
the fact that power disparities between most second-tier states and the United States fall
between the two extremes necessary for widespread balancing or bandwagoning.9 As
such, depending on power differentials vis-à-vis the preponderant state and the degree of
integration with the world system, strategies that fall between balancing and
bandwagoning may best capture the range of state strategies in this era of unipolarity.10

Attempts to understand how the rest of the world may respond to preponderant
power may provide critical insight into both contemporary world politics as well as the
persistence of American unipolarity. Although individually weak in relation the United
States, Charles Kupchan suggests that smaller actors may, for example, have cumulative
or even collective effects vis-à-vis the hegemon.11 Most of the world’s population and
natural resources also do not reside within the borders of the United States. A
systematic study of the range of possible state responses to preponderant power is
therefore conspicuously absent from the field of world politics.

In looking at the variation in state strategies when dealing with superior power, this
paper aims to develop an initial framework from which to better understand how state
actors respond to, and interact with, those who are much more powerful. In doing so,
this paper hopes to help improve explanations about the variation in state action. Such
an approach to the study of world politics can help fill a gap in the literature; it may also
assist in bringing some perspective on responses to current U.S. unipolar predominance.
As such, the project hopes to provide the foundation for further theoretical research and
empirical elaboration on state strategies in world politics.

8
Walt, Origin of Alliances, 28-32, 173-178 and Waltz, Theory of International Politics, 126.
9
I take “second-tier states” here to simply denote states that are not in the pre-eminent position within a
unipolar system, but are able to behave independently in world politics. This differs from entities such as
“failed” or “failing” states that are unable to behave with effective autonomy. In this definition, I also
differ from the more clearly hierarchical and power-oriented model of the world system developed by
A.F.K. Organski and others. See for example, Jacek Kugler and A.F.K. Organski, “The Power Transition:
A Retrospective and Prospective Evaluation”, in Manus I. Midlarsky [ed.], Handbook of War Studies (Ann
Arbor, MI: The University of Michigan Press, 1996).
10
Robert Rothstein in fact argues that over time, the ability of small states to achieve intended effects over
time is increasing. See Rothstein, Alliances and Small Powers, 3-5 and 12-21.
11
Charles A. Kupchan, End of the American Era: US Foreign Policy and the Geopolitics of the
Twenty-First Century (New York, NY: Alfred A. Knopf, Inc., 2002).
3
Balancing, Bandwagoning, and the Problem of Unipolar Power Preponderance

Most approaches to security issues in world politics that attempt to apply balancing
and bandwagoning as their central analytical frameworks take inadequate account of the
extent of gaps in power. Whether discussing balancing in multipolar or in bipolar
systems, the underlying assumption is that differences in power are small enough such
that states acting independently or in unison, can counter the capabilities and influence of
others.12 On the other hand, smaller states that cannot compete with the great powers
simply have to accept their lot and bandwagon with whom they can. Most states,
however, neither resemble the Concert of Europe Great Powers nor the Cold War
Superpowers that have informed traditional international relations, and they are certainly
not helpless either. As such, the historical record for state behaviour within the world
system is likely to be problematic for bandwagoning- and balancing-based approaches,
especially during this era of unipolarity.

Assuming they can get over the collective action problem, second-tier states under
unipolarity may be lagging so far behind the system leader that balancing is presently not
a viable strategy option. Bandwagoning on the other hand, may not appear as the
necessary strategic alternative either. For many second-tier states today, bandwagoning
may spell the unnecessary compromising of interests. Despite significant disparities in
power, it is unlikely that the United States can readily run roughshod over second-tier
states like China and Russia or even the United Kingdom, France, Germany, and
Australia. As I show later in this section, the historical and contemporary record bear
out these problems for approaches that adopt bandwagoning and balancing as their
overarching analytical frameworks.

Before embarking on a further discussion of balancing and bandwagoning, however,


I wish to make clear what I mean with these two terms. Too often, it seems, the use of
terminology in the field occurs without the realisation that different scholars are using
similar terms to describe overlapping, but ultimately distinct concepts. The term
“normative behaviour” in common usage within the field, for example, can mean
anything from an established regularity in action to the assigning of moral value to an act.
Likewise, the term “hedging” in world politics literature, which originally refers to
pre-emptive acts taken in preparation for possible changes in circumstances, now appears
to include everything from balancing to potential encirclement. 13 The blurring of

12
See E.H. Carr, The Twenty Years’ Crisis: An Introduction to the Study of International Relations
(London, England: Papermac, 1995); Morgenthau, Politics among Nations; Waltz, Man, the State, and War;
and, Waltz, Theory of International Politics.
13
See Colin Elman, “Introduction”, in John A. Vasquez and Colin Elman [eds.], Realism and the
Balancing of Power: A New Debate (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall Publishers, Inc., 2002), 7-17;
4
concepts in recent scholarship is also apparent in the conceptual application of balancing
and bandwagoning. An example is Randall Schweller’s extension of bandwagoning,
which usually means siding with stronger and even more threatening powers for
protection, to “bandwagoning for profit”.14 Such developments suggest the limitations
of balancing and bandwagoning as analytical frameworks, and the loosening of
definitions may blur meanings and cause some confusion. In order to avoid such
problems here, let me first begin by defining balancing, and bandwagoning.

By balancing, I am referring to a strategy taken by a state to actively preserve


security and advance interests by increasing its own power vis-à-vis the most powerful
and threatening actors in order to challenge and offset the dangers that the latter
potentially pose.15 This may be in terms of internal balancing where a state increases its
own power domestically, or external balancing where resources are pooled with other
states for a specific purpose. 16 In short, balancing entails shifting the status quo
distribution of power away from a situation that favours the leading state. All this
presupposes the ability to affect the present or future distribution of power within a
system. It may be possible to observe acts of balancing by looking at the extent to
which states build military alliances as well as increase domestic military and political
capabilities in light of the emergence of a threat or potential threat. Increasing tensions
between the different camps usually accompany balancing; this is when one side
increasingly challenges the position of the other, and when the other responds in kind.

Bandwagoning, on the other hand, is a strategy to preserve basic security concerns


by seeking protection from a stronger and even threatening, power.17 It often entails
acquiescing to the will or ambitions of the more powerful state, such as Latin America’s
acceptance of American hegemony over the Western Hemisphere under the Monroe
Doctrine. Such actions may be observable by the creation of alliances with stronger
powers by weaker powers, especially in the absence of other threats. Another possible

Patricia Weitsman, “Intimate Enemies: The Politics of Peacetime Allies”, Security Studies, Vol. 7 No. 1
(autumn 1997): 156-192; and, Deborah Welch Larson, “Bandwagon Images in American Foreign Policy:
Myth or Reality?”, in Robert Jervis and Jack L. Snyder [eds.], Dominoes and Bandwagons: Strategic
Beliefs and Great Power Competition in the Eurasian Rimland (Oxford, England: Oxford University Press,
1991), 85.
14
Randall Schweller, “Bandwagoning for Profit: Bringing the Revisionist State Back In”, International
Security, Vol. 19, No. 1 (summer 1994): 72-107.
15
See Waltz, Theory of International Politics, 126; Waltz, Man, the State, and War, 198-210; Morgenthau,
Politics among Nations; Carr, The Twenty Years’ Crisis; Walt, The Origin of Alliances, 21-22; and, John J.
Mearshiemer, The Tragedy of Great Power Politics (New York: NY: W.W. Norton and Company, 2001),
139 and 156-157.
16
Waltz, Theory of International Politics, 168 and Mearshiemer, The Tragedy of Great Power Politics,
156-157.
17
See Waltz, Theory of International Politics, 126; Morgenthau, Politics among Nations; Carr, The Twenty
Years’ Crisis; Walt, The Origin of Alliances, 21-22; Mearshiemer, The Tragedy of Great Power Politics,
139, 162-163; and Larson, “Bandwagon Images in American Foreign Policy”, in Jervis and Snyder,
Dominoes and Bandwagons, 85.
5
measure of bandwagoning is to look at support for, or lack of opposition to, the policies
of the predominant state by weaker states despite the potential of these actions to threaten
the interests of the latter. Ultimately in bandwagoning, the lesser actors give up a
substantial degree of autonomy for action internationally in exchange for protection by
the powerful.

Despite their popularity as paradigms in international relations scholarship, the


historical occurrence of balancing and bandwagoning are not as dominant as their
academic reputations may suggest. Paul Schroeder points out that the three centuries
from the creation of the Westphalian state system until the end of World War Two was a
period which many scholars use as historical evidence for balancing and bandwagoning.
He adds that:

I cannot construct a history of the European states system from 1648 to 1945 based on the
generalisation that most unit actors within that system responded to crucial threats to their
security and independence by resorting to self-help, as defined [in terms of different means
of balancing] above. In each major period in these centuries, most unit actors tried if they
possibly could to protect their vital interests in other ways. (This includes great powers as
well as smaller ones, undermining the neo-realist argument that weaker states are more
inclined to bandwagon than stronger ones…)18

Schroeder identifies “hiding”, “transcendence”, and “specialisation” as regular


alternatives to balancing and bandwagoning. Here, “hiding” refers to ignoring a threat,
declaring neutrality, or simply drawing into isolation, while “transcendence” refers to
solving a problem and preventing its recurrence by seeking international agreement on
norms and rules to regulate specific matters.19 “Specialisation”, on the other hand,
represents the provision of some indispensable function to give others a stake in a
particular state’s security, survival, and perhaps even development.20

Furthermore, in studying the relationship between second-tier powers in the


American sphere of influence and the United States, Annette Baker Fox finds empirical
evidence to conclude that on “the great issues of world politics that transcend specific
problems in their bilateral relations with the United States, the four middle powers have
consistently put autonomy above a united front”. 21 Yet, for the period from the
Inter-War Years through most of the Cold War, the four states in Baker’s study, Canada,
Australia, Mexico, and Brazil have been firmly within the American sphere of influence.
Hence, according to balancing and bandwagoning thinking, these countries should be

18
Paul Schroeder, “Historical Reality vs. Neo-Realist Theory”, International Security, Vol. 19, No. 1
(Summer 1994): 116. See pages 129-147 for Schroeder’s empirical study.
19
Schroeder, “Historical Reality vs. Neo-Realist Theory”, International Security, Vol. 19, No. 1 (Summer
1994): 117-124.
20
Schroeder, “Historical Realist vs. Neo-Realist Theory”, International Security, Vol. 19, No. 1 (Summer
1994): 124-129.
21
Fox, The Politics of Attraction, 191.
6
unreservedly bandwagoning with Washington.22

Unipolarity presents circumstances that make the inadequacies of the balancing and
bandwagoning approach particularly apparent. This is in contrast to the common view
that the vast power asymmetries under unipolarity will necessarily lead to balancing and
bandwagoning. In fact, the continuing unipolar political environment in the past
decade-and-a-half is likely to account for the seemingly surprising absence of balancing
since the end of the Cold War. Nonetheless, persistent affronts to U.S. aims and
interests on the world stage by states ranging from France and Germany to Russia, China,
and India during this time indicates that bandwagoning may not capture responses to
unipolarity either.

In fact, even the staunchest supporters of seeing the world purely through balancing
appear to be at a loss as to how to understand state behaviour under unipolarity. Even
one of the great proselytisers of the balancing paradigm, Kenneth Waltz, concedes that, at
least in the case of balancing:

[Realism p]redicts that balances disrupted will one day be restored. A limitation of the
theory, a limitation common to social science theories, it that it cannot say when. William
Wohlforth argues that though restoration will take place, it will be a long time coming. Of
necessity, [Waltz’s version of the] realist theory is better at saying what will happen than in
saying when it will happen. Theory cannot say when “tomorrow” will come because
international political theory deals with the pressures of structure on states and not how
states will respond to the pressures.23

This claim seems like merely a leap of faith. For all the claims about the limitations of
social science theories in general, and political science theories in particular, such
theories can at least specify conditions that allow an event to occur. It appears from
Waltz’s argument, that limiting state strategies to balancing and perhaps bandwagoning
does not even allow a proper appreciation for the factors that can give rise to such
behaviour. Balancing and perhaps bandwagoning thus appear almost as ontological
givens.

Buck-passing, a variant of the balancing argument that considers the collective


action problem may be similarly problematic under unipolarity. According to Thomas
Christensen and Jack Snyder, buck-passing is a situation where states avoid balancing by
“counting on third parties to bear the costs of stopping a rising hegemon”.24 Stephen
Walt similarly defines buck-passing as the situation where the great powers believe that
readily available allies promote buck-passing; since “states that are threatened strive to

22
Fox, The Politics of Attraction. See in particular Chapters Eight and Ten.
23
Kenneth N. Waltz, “Structural Realism after the Cold War”, International Security, Vol. 25 No. 1
(Summer 2000): 27.
24
Thomas J. Christensen and Jack L. Snyder, “Chain Gangs and Passed Bucks: Predicting Alliance
Patterns in Multipolarity”, International Organisation, Vol. 44, No. 2 (Spring 1990): 138
7
pass to others the burdens of standing up to the aggressor”.25

Here, the very title of Christensen and Snyder’s article “Chain Gangs and Passed Bucks”
reveals the problem with buck-passing in a system with a clearly predominant state,
namely that buck-passing is a strategy that works best under multipolarity.
Buck-passing occurs when states can identify actors other than themselves who may
successfully challenge the influence of the pre-eminent or potentially most threatening
state. Under unipolarity, however, states may not be able to find others who are willing
or able to bear the brunt of balancing against the system leader and are aware that
individual actions are unlikely to make any major impact. Even if a large number of
states find it in their interest to work against the system leader, there are the usual
problems of collective action and free riding to overcome.

Approaches to understanding international bandwagoning behaviour are similarly


limiting. One of the reasons William Wohlforth claims to be behind the stability of the
current unipolar world is the fact that:

Because the current leading state is by far the world’s most formidable military power, the
chances of leadership conflict are more remote than at any time over the last two centuries.
Unlike past international systems, efforts by any second-tier state to enhance its relative
position can be managed in a unipolar system without raising the spectre of a power
transition and a struggle for primacy. And because the major powers face incentives to
shape their policies with a view toward the power and preferences of the system leader, the
likelihood of security competition among them is lower than in previous systems.26

Although the quasi-bandwagoning behaviour Wohlforth describes may accurately capture


the general conditions behind the current unipolar persistence, it ignores the possible
range of responses non-leading states may take to address questions of preserving
security and promoting interests, especially if they conflict with the desires of the system
leader.

In recent years, there have been some attempts to look beyond the balancing and
bandwagoning paradigm in world politics scholarship, especially in response to the
absence of balancing under unipolarity. Like Wohlforth’s work, however, much of this
recent scholarship on the current unipolar system provides less than complete pictures of
state responses to preponderant power. For instance, John Ikenberry’s study on
institutions and strategic restraint under American unipolarity focuses almost exclusively
on advanced industrial nations already entrenched within the U.S.-dominated Western
orbit.27

25
Walt, The Origins of Alliances, 30-31.
26
Wohlforth, “Stability of a Unipolar World”, International Security, Vol. 45, No. 1 (Summer 1999): 13.
27
Ikenberry, After Victory.
8
Other arguments like those put forward by Robert Kagan, Richard Rosecrance in
Rise of the Virtual State, and Charles Kupchan in The End of the American Era, are
equally guilty of this shortcoming.28 Still others working on the issue of world politics
under unipolarity, for example Joseph Joffe, Michael Mastanduno, John Owen, Thomas
Risse, and Christopher Layne largely concentrate on the maintenance of the unipolar
order on the part of the United States, rather than on responses to American dominance
by the rest of the world.29

Another shortcoming of current work on power preponderance in world politics is


the shortage of explanations for alternative strategies. In his examination of the
accuracy of realist explanations against the empirical historical record, Paul Schroeder
does excellent work in identifying the presence of non-balancing, non-bandwagoning
behaviour which he terms “hiding”, “transcending”, and “specialisation”.30 However,
he does not provide much in-depth explanation about the conditions that may lead states
to adopt the various different approaches in their external relations with others. There is
also little on how these strategies may apply under unipolarity and how they may perhaps
help answer the question, “why no balancing?”

The limitations of the balancing-bandwagoning paradigm leave the question on


responses to preponderant power under unipolarity wide open. The rest of this paper
will try to narrow this gap by proposing buffering, binding, bonding, and beleaguering as
possible alternatives that may provide a more accurate picture of state strategies under
unipolarity. These understandings of state strategy may additionally provide a better
general understanding of responses to power preponderance.

Buffering, Bonding, Binding, and Beleaguering as Alternative Strategies

I argue that second-tier states that are unable to change the distribution of power
within a unipolar system, but are strong enough to assert some degree of independence
from leading state are likely to adopt strategies that go beyond balancing and
bandwagoning. This should account for a large number of states in the contemporary

28
Kagan, Of Paradise and Power; Rosecrance, The Rise of the Virtual State; and, Kupchan, The End of the
American Era.
29
Joseph Joffe, “Defying History and Theory: The United States as the “Last Remaining Superpower”, in
Ikenberry, America Unrivalled, 155-180; Michael Mastanduno, “Incomplete Hegemony and Security Order
in the Asia-Pacific”, in Ikenberry, America Unrivalled, 181-212; John M. Owen IV, “Transnational
Liberalism and American Primacy; or, Benignity is in the Eye of the Beholder”, in Ikenberry, America
Unrivalled, 239-259; and, Thomas Risse, “U.S. Power in a Liberal Security Community”, in Ikenberry,
America Unrivalled, 260-283.
30
Schroeder, “Historical Reality versus Neo-Realist Theory”, International Security, Vol. 19 No. 1
(Summer 1994): 108-148.
9
world system. The pattern of their strategic choices, however, may depend on the level
of power disparity with the leading state and level of integration in the world system.
However, I also suspect that the effects of historical path dependence particular to each
individual situation may influence the effects of power and integration on state strategy.

I want to make the argument that states with less of a power disparity with the
system leader tend toward buffering and beleaguering. Those who experience a larger
power gap may prefer bonding or binding. Simultaneously, states that enjoy more
integration in the world system may lean toward buffering and binding, while those that
have less linkage may adopt bonding or beleaguering. This, of course, assumes an ideal
world where unique historical path dependence does not have an effect. Diagram One
illustrates this argument:
Relative Power under Unipolarity
Lesser Greater
Level of Integration in the

Lesser Bonding Beleaguering


World System

Greater Binding Buffering

Diagram 1: State responses to preponderant power where differences in power between the leading
and other states are moderately large

To avoid confusion, I want to make clear that in this paper, strategy refers to
purposive actions undertaken by states to achieve specific types of objectives, such as
state survival or economic development. The success of strategies depends on their
ability to help states achieve these aims. This paper, however, will choose to focus
mainly on security goals. The success or failure of particular security strategies may be
assessable by looking at the degree to which they preserve autonomy of action, restrain
the actions of the powerful, avert conflict, reduce tensions, or otherwise allow states to
satisfactorily address concerns about security, survival, and other interests. Possible
ways to delineate strategies include exploring the behaviour and means through which
states preserve or promote interests such as security and autonomy. Now, let me turn to
discussing each alternative strategy in more detail.

Bonding
Bonding is a strategy where states promote autonomy by providing a function or
service others may find indispensable—i.e. states “bond” the interests of others with their
own. As such, other states as well as the preponderant power may have a stake in
maintaining the security and autonomy of the state providing the service or function.
10
This may even encourage others to support the interests of the bonding state against the
system leader under certain circumstances. Bonding, in effect, establishes and increases
linkages with the world system and may not focus exclusively on the relationship with
the pre-eminent state.

Second-tier states with lesser influence tend to prefer bonding, because these states
realise that they can preserve their interests only by ingratiating themselves with the
world, as well as with the leading state. These states, which fall in the upper left
quadrant of Diagram 1, understand that there is not much that they can do on their own to
change the distribution of power or level of integration in their favour, especially in the
short- to medium-term. As such, the only way for them to protect their most
fundamental interests is to give others a stake in their security and other such national
priorities. To do so, such states may seek to provide some indispensable function to the
preponderant state and the rest of the world in order to generate influence and give others
cause to support them.

It may be possible to observe bonding by looking at the extent to which the world or
a region depends on a state to provide particular services or functions. A further
measure is the extent to which other states or the international system remains impartial
to the actions of a state actor, in exchange for a particular service it provides. The
trading and virtual state models put forward by Richard Rosecrance, as well as acts of
“specialisation” proposed by Paul Schroeder may fall within this category of strategy.31
Examples may include Switzerland providing a politically neutral space for political
exchanges and financial services, the Scandinavian states supplying humanitarian and
developmental assistance, or even Belgium’s provision of a buffering function in the past.

Binding
Binding occurs when weaker states are able to restrain the actions of the powerful
through the creation of institutional agreements and frameworks between states with
different degrees of power, in exchange for support of the status quo under the leadership
of the leading state. In other words, binding can occur between weaker states and the
pre-eminent state in efforts to establish formal, institutionalised restraints on the exercise
of power by the leading state in exchange for accepting its leadership. Binding,
therefore, permits a degree of formal autonomy as well as influence over the powerful by
weaker states that goes beyond what balancing and bandwagoning allow.

31
Rosecrance, The Rise of the Virtual State; Rosecrance, The Rise of the Trading State; and, Schroeder,
“Historical Realist vs. Neo-Realist Theory”, International Security, Vol. 19, No. 1 (Summer 1994):
124-129. Also, see Michael I. Handel, Weak States in the International System (London, England: Frank
Cass and Company Limited, 1990), 148-152 and Fox, The Power of Small States, 144-146.
11
For states that fall within the lower left quadrant of Diagram 1, binding is preferable
as it makes use of the institutional and network linkages already available to exert their
influence. Since these states are also unable to do much about their power shortfalls,
they may use existing institutional and network relationships with the preponderant state
and the rest of the world to preserve and perhaps even forward their interests. This may
be particularly true of states already in institutions and networks with accepted
mechanisms of operation that allow at least some formal channels of influence on the
leading state by even the weakest members. At the same time, the importance of
worldwide linkages to these second-tier states makes it highly costly to disrupt the world
system.

Binding may be measured by the ways that allow for formal restraints on the
powerful in multiple issue areas. A tendency by the powerful to adhere to institutional
restraints in its relations with weaker states may provide a further indication of binding.
An example of binding may be the post-World War II US-led Western alliance system
that enabled war-devastated European states to influence American decision-making in
exchange for accepting Washington’s leadership, as John Ikenberry argues in After
Victory.32 The strategy that Paul Schroeder calls transcendence and the concept of a
North Atlantic “political community” between the United States and Western Europe
developed by Karl Deutsch and his colleagues may fall within this category as well.33

Beleaguering
Beleaguering is a strategy where states aim to undermine the influence and authority
of the more powerful as well as their ability to exercise power through disruption for the
purposes of gaining specific concessions. This may include the sowing of discord

32
Ikenberry, After Victory. See especially the definition of binding from page 40 to 43. Also see
Handel, Weak States in the International System, 120-148; Emanuel Adler, “Seeds of Peaceful Change: The
OSCE’s Security Community-Building Model”, in Emanuel Adler and Michael Barnett [eds.], Security
Communities (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press, 1998) 120-123; Annette Baker Fox, The
Politics of Attraction: Four Middle Powers and the United States (New York, NY: Columbia University
Press, 1977), 193-202; Joseph M. Greico, “Understanding the Problem of International Cooperation: The
Limits of Neoliberal Institutionalism and the Future of Realist Theory”, in David A. Baldwin [ed.],
Neoliberalism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New York, NY: Columbia University Press,
1993); Joseph M. Greico, “The Maastricht Treaty, Economic and Monetary Union and the Neo-Realist
Research Programme”, Review of International Studies, No. 21 (1995): 21-40; Joseph M. Greico, “State
Interests and Institutional Rule Trajectories”, Security Studies, Vol. 5 No. 3 (Spring 1996): 261-306; Daniel
H. Duedney, “The Philadephian System”, International Organisation, Vol. 49 No. 2 (Spring 1995):
191-228; Daniel H. Duedney, “Binding Sovereigns”, in Thomas J. Biersteker and Cynthia Weber [eds.],
State Sovereignty as Social Construct (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press, 1996).
33
Paul Schroeder, “Historical Reality versus Neo-Realist Theory”, International Security, Vol. 19 No. 1
(Summer 1994): 108-148 and Karl W. Deutsch et al, Political Community in the North Atlantic Area:
International Organisation in the Light of Historical Experience (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press,
1957). Also, see Rothstein, Alliances and Small States, 47-48; Etel Solingen, Regional Orders at
Century’s Dawn: Global and Domestic Influences on Grand Strategy (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Press, 1998), Chapters Two and Three; and, George Liska, Nations in Alliance: The Limits of
Interdependence (Baltimore, MD: The Johns Hopkins Press, 1962), especially Chapters Two and Three.
12
between the greater power and her allies, the instigation of domestic unrest within the
territory of the greater power, or disturbing the smooth implementation of the policies by
the powerful.34 An example is the constant tensions existing between the United States,
Japan, and South Korea by North Korea in order to receive concessions or security
guarantees.35 Some forms of state-sponsored terrorism or socio-economic disruption
may also fall within the category of beleaguering, although not all such behaviour may be
classifiable as beleaguering.

Second-tier states with low levels of integration and relatively more power may opt
for beleaguering since they not only possess the ability to cause disruption, but also that
the cost of such action may be low. As states that fall within the upper right quadrant of
Diagram 1 have limited linkages with the rest of the system. Disrupting the policies of
the leading state or others in the system may allow the beleaguering state get others to
acquiesce to some of its demands. At the same time, the relative power position of
states in the upper right quadrant also means that their attempts to beleaguer others can
have substantial impact on other actors. In exchange for ending or not repeating
destabilising actions, other states, including perhaps the leading state may pay the
beleaguerer off by conceding to some of its demands. Beleaguering, however, is a risky
strategy; it may bring about retaliation from the leading state or a coalition of other
second-tier states.

Evaluating beleaguering strategies can be carried out by observing the presence of


conscious attempts to divide the opinions of the greater power and her allies through
diplomatic, social, and economic activity. Measurement of beleaguering may also be
possible by assessing the existence of state-sponsored terrorism, proliferation of weapons
of mass destruction, attempts to create domestic social unrest within the greater power, or
potential regionally destabilising moves.

Buffering
Buffering is the lessening of exposure to, and influence by, the more powerful by
creating alternative spheres of influence or carving out neutral areas in terms of
geography or function that can remove or at least significantly limit the immediate and
active impact of the dominant power. This can allow states to pursue their own interests
more freely. Unlike balancing, however, buffering is more passive. It does not aim to
alter the existing status quo or present an affront to the position of the pre-eminent state,
but rather to maintain or exploit elements of prevailing circumstances that limit the

34
See Solingen, Regional Orders at Century’s Dawn, 238-245.
35
Susan L. Shirk, “Asia-Pacific Regional Security: Balance of Power of Concert of Powers”, in Lake and
Morgan, Regional Orders, 263-264.
13
exercise of power by the pre-eminent state.

States in the system that are both moderately powerful relative to the unipolar leader
and highly integrated into the world system are likely to adopt buffering as they can make
the best use of available capabilities to advance their interests. Buffering utilises
institutional and other network linkages with like-minded states and the system leader to
establish exclusive regional or functional areas, which in turn can reduce the active
influence of the leading state on related matters. These moderately powerful states also
have the capability to ensure some level of effective control over these issue areas to
make buffering successful. This may allow for more autonomy from the preponderant
state when pursing their interests. Beleaguering may not be a viable option for
beleaguerers with high levels of and need for integration with the rest of the world.

Buffering behaviour may be measured by the presence of security communities, a


series of overlapping institutions, or geographical areas that limit or even exclude the
active participation of the powerful. It creates a political space where second-tier states
can handle issues before the leading state intervenes. It also builds legitimacy for action
independent of the pre-eminent actor. However, buffering de-emphasises the
importance of formal military alliances that aim to directly challenge the position of the
most powerful state. An example is the argument that the creation of a political and
economic system in a region limits or reduces American influence, such as today’s
European Union. Certain aspects of Robert Kagan’s claims about the relationship
between the present day European Union and the United States Of Paradise and Power
fall within this category of buffering.36

Hiding
Apart from the four main categories of strategy, I also note the existence of a fifth
possible approach to power preponderance, which scholars sometimes refer to as
“hiding”. This is essentially avoidance of tension or disputes by states through
withdrawal into isolation. It may appear when states voluntarily withdraw from
disputes and potential disputes by reducing or cutting contact with potential or existing
adversaries. Paul Schroeder discusses this approach at some length in the International
Security article “Historical Reality versus Neo-Realist Theory”.37

36
Robert Kagan, Of Paradise and Power: America and Europe in the New World Order (New York, NY:
Alfred A. Knopf, 2003). Also see David A. Lake and Patrick M. Morgan [eds.], Regional Orders:
Building Security in a New World (University Park, PA: The Pennsylvania State University Press, 1997)
and Solingen, Regional Orders at Century’s Dawn, see especially Chapters One and Three.
37
Schroeder, “Historical Reality vs. Neo-Realist Theory”, International Security, Vol. 19, No. 1 (Summer
1994): 117-124. Also, see Fox, The Power of Small States, 177-179; Rothstein, Alliances and Small
Powers, 28; and, Subrata Roy Chowdhury, Military Alliances and Neutrality in War and Peace (Bombay,
Maharashtra: Orient Longmans, 1966), especially Chapters Three and Four.
14
Hiding, however, may not be a feasible strategy in a contemporary world system
where a large number of institutional and other connections and networks linking states
in areas such as security to economics and society affect even those seeking to avoid
entanglement in world affairs. The pervasiveness of U.S. power and influence in the
contemporary world may make hiding even more unfeasible as a strategy. In the event
that states do try to hide in the current international context, they may end up
relinquishing their ability to influence world politics, especially in the realm of security.
Myanmar is perhaps one of the few remaining actors in the contemporary world that
behaves in a way that may broadly resemble hiding. Given the increasing rarity of such
behaviour, this paper will not delve into this last approach.

Collective and Cumulative Effects

Apart from being possible reactions to preponderant power, the adoption of


strategies such as buffering, binding, bonding, and beleaguering by second-tier states may
have broader implications for the future of a unipolar order. Although individual state
strategies may have little individual impact on a unipolar system, the dominance of
particular approaches toward power preponderance may work together and over time to
reinforce, erode, or modify the status quo. After all, an international system, even a
unipolar one, necessarily consists of a variety of actors that include both leading and
second-tier states. Over time, changes to any part of this system can potentially alter the
nature of the world order, even if disproportionately.

Of the four alternative strategies, binding and bonding may prove the most
conducive to the persistence of unipolarity. By signing institutional agreements that
acknowledge and legitimate the position of the leading power in exchange for some
degree of influence, the binding of second-tier states is likely to strengthen the
established unipolar order. Hence, if large numbers of states choose to bind with the
unipolar power, this will in fact entrench the position of the current system leader even if
there is some decline in its relative power.

Likewise, if many states adopt bonding, this is likely to enhance the longevity of a
unipolar order. The choice by states to enhance their intrinsic value to the world by
providing some essential function or service does not challenge the position of the
leading state. Such a decision is also unlikely to erode the position of the system leader
as the second-tier states often specialise in specific spheres. As states discover their
unique areas of expertise and become more integrated with the world, they may move
towards binding by establishing institutional arrangements with the leading state to “lock
in” their positions and the advantages that come with such bargains.

15
In the case where a great number of states opt to bind or bond, a unipolar system
may be highly stable and long-lived. This is as states are unlikely to challenge a
prevailing order that provides them with substantial benefits. As Robert Gilpin argues
in War and Change in World Politics, states are only likely to desire a change or
overthrow of the system if it is no longer useful or even detrimental to their interests.38
Systems where most states bind with the unipolar leader or bond with the world, however,
tend to be more susceptible to disruption caused by beleaguering states.

If, on the other hand, the majority of states select strategies akin to buffering or
beleaguering, a unipolar order is likely to be more short-lived. With buffering, there is
an erosion of the relative influence of the leading state over time as second-tier states
begin to reduce the ability of the system leader to act in certain areas. Left unchecked,
buffer areas may evolve to the extent that a system leader may find significant constraints
on its ability to wield its influence and impose its will. As such, buffering may create
the political space for the development of potential rivals to the unipolar power.

A system where buffering is common can, however, be stable for a long time until
challengers to the status quo power emerge. In fact, even power transitions in systems
where there are well-established areas of influence can be stable, such as during the shift
from British hegemony to American dominance during the mid-twentieth century.
However, there remains the potential for instability at a non-systemic level as buffering
states compete against each other as they become increasingly more powerful. 39
Nonetheless, by being conducive to the rise of potential challengers to the system leader,
widespread buffering may have an adverse overall long-term impact on unipolar
longevity.

The most potentially unstable scenario for unipolarity is when a large number of
states choose to beleaguer. In this situation, there are likely to be constant attempts to
disrupt the prevailing system. Not only will successful beleaguering create problems for
other states in the system, the leading state may have to expend significant resources to
address disruption. Writing about the British Empire in The Weary Titan, Aaron
Friedberg points that this may wear down a unipolar power more quickly by placing
greater strain on its limited, though substantial, resources.40 By cracking down on
beleaguerers and potential beleaguerers, the unipolar power may also become
increasingly oppressive and hence encourage further beleaguering, as well as a growing

38
Robert Gilpin, War and Change in World Politics (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press,
1981).
39
Wohlforth, “The Stability of a Unipolar World”, International Security, Vol. 24 No. 1 (Summer 1999):
30-32.
40
Aaron L. Friedberg, The Weary Titan: Britain the Experience of Relative Decline, 1895-1905 (Princeton,
NJ: Princeton University Press, 1988).
16
desire to alter the prevailing system.

From the collective and cumulative effects of state strategies beyond balancing and
bandwagoning, it seems then that a unipolar order is likely to be most stable when most
secondary states enjoy high levels of integration within the system. This is because
more integrated states tend to prefer binding, bonding, and buffering strategies, which do
not immediately disrupt or challenge the prevailing system. Buffering, however, can
make a system with a preponderant power less persistent over time as it may limit
hegemonic influence and allow for the rise of future challengers. In contrast, binding
and bonding may tend to support unipolar persistence as they entrench and reinforce the
existing world order and the position of the leading state.

When a large number of secondary states are both powerful and lack substantial
linkages with the world system, unipolarity is likely to be relatively unstable and
short-lived. Since second-tier states that fall within this category are liable to select
beleaguering as a course of action, the propensity for wide-spread disruption make a
unipolar system relatively unstable and even war prone. This is likely to place
significant strain on the resources, influence, and position of the leading state, possibly
reducing the longevity of the existing system.

It seems that unipolar stability and persistence depends on much more than simply
the power and actions of the leading state. The strategy choices, as well as the relative
power and level of integration among second-tier states may have an important impact on
the nature and persistence of preponderant power in a world system. As such, those
seeking to understand the permanence of the current status quo from both the academic
and policy standpoints may do well to comprehend the behaviour of second-tier states, as
well as that of the system leader.

In the Asia-Pacific example, the pattern of binding, bonding, buffering, and


beleaguering suggests that the current unipolar order is likely to be relatively stable, at
least in that region. Most states in the area seem to be buying into the prevailing system,
albeit to different degrees. Even China, the most likely serious challenger to U.S.
pre-eminence appears to be opting to preserve the stability offered by the current system.
By seeking to buffer, Beijing prefers to maintain the status quo and not challenge the U.S.
position. With the exception of an increasingly isolated North Korea and perhaps
Myanmar, other second-tier states seem to choose to bind or bond, strategies that support
if not reinforce the prevailing system.

However, as the United States increasingly disregards the interests and opinions of
others and with other states gradually becoming more integrated and powerful, buffering
17
may gain greater currency in the world. Such a development may lead to rising attempts
to limit the exercise of U.S. influence. This may spell a steady erosion of U.S. unipolar
dominance in time. Nonetheless, the actual cumulative and collective effects of state
strategies beyond balancing and bandwagoning on regions and the world system are
likely to present themselves as topics that demand further study. Such a development
may be particularly interesting as more data on the era of U.S. unipolarity becomes
available.

Thoughts on Further Testing

To operationalise the study of alternative forms of state behaviour other than


balancing and bandwagoning, it may be necessary to test the following hypotheses:

H1: Balancing and bandwagoning cannot explain significant variation in state


responses to preponderant power.

H2: Relative differences in power and the level of integration help influence the type
of strategy that states will adopt toward preponderant power such that:
a. States that are weaker tend to bond or bind; states that are relatively stronger
tend beleaguer or buffer.
b. States more integrated in the world system tend to buffer or bind; less
integrated states tend to bond or beleaguer.

Additionally, the project will attempt to disprove the following null hypothesis:

H0: Balancing and bandwagoning explain systematic variation in state strategy when
reacting to preponderant power.

The argument that states act in ways that go beyond balancing and bandwagoning in
their security behaviour should appear particularly plausible if the project is able bring
evidence to support the two main hypotheses and reject the null hypothesis. Note that I
am trying to present a probable theory and that the different strategies are not necessarily
mutually exclusive over time, especially as states shift along power and integration lines.
As such, testing the above hypotheses will involve looking at the incidence of particular
types of behaviour, rather than to assert that other strategies will not appear at all.
Additionally, as states may adopt different strategies in different relationships, this paper
will limit its scope to relations with the pre-eminent power.

To prove Hypothesis One, I will need to show that balancing and bandwagoning
cannot account for much of the behaviour of second-tier states toward preponderant
power. In order to prove Hypothesis Two, this paper will also need to show that state
responses to preponderant power vary in accordance with expectations about the
relationships between power and integration in the international system that I lay out
earlier in this section. The inability to reject the first three hypotheses should help
permit the rejection of the Null Hypothesis.
18
To further elucidate the case for state responses to power preponderance that fall
outside of balancing and bandwagoning, I hope to make clear what I mean by the degree
of disparities in power and level of integration. Since this paper aims to look at
responses to preponderant power, it will assume that other states lags behind the
pre-eminent state in terms of the capability to achieve state objectives as well as the
ability to influence the behaviour of others in a clear and significant manner. This may
take material form such as the capability of military forces and economic capacity or
“softer” forms such as social strength, cultural effects, or ideational influences. The
degree of difference in power looks at the extent to which the power capabilities of
individual states vary in relation to the system leader.

The level of integration refers to the participation in international organisations or


institutions, in addition to economic and social networks by a state. This includes both
the number of institutions and networks that a state participates in, plus the extent to
which institutions and networks can constrain or promote state behaviour and resist
shocks over time. The extent of communication between those within a state and those
outside may also help determine the extent of integration in the world system. The level
of integration in this discussion includes the breadth of participation in institutions and
networks that both involve and do not include the predominant state.

International organisations (IOs) and institutions here are formal establishments with
some defined function and include some form of state membership. Examples range
from political organisations such as the United Nations and European Union, economic
institutions like the World Trade Organisation and International Monetary Fund, as well
as functional establishments such as the World Health Organisation and International
Labour Organisation.

International networks, on the other hand, are mutually dependent social and
economic linkages between states that are not necessarily formalised through
organisational structures or official state participation. They may involve economic ties
in trade and finance as well as systems of relationships and exchange between societies in
different states. The networks of concern here include linkages among the weaker states,
as well as between them and the predominant power.

The measurement of economic networks can be assessed by looking at the volume of


trade and financial transactions, including the level of foreign investment in a state. An
indication of the breadth and depth of social networks is indicated by the extent of
cross-border population exchanges, communication, and the degree of non-governmental
cooperation on issues. It may be possible to gauge the level of non-governmental
19
exchanges by looking at the number of international Non-Governmental Organisations
(NGOs) and other transnational entities functioning within a state. Here, international
NGOs include non-governmental civic organisations whose work may range from
development assistance to human rights and health.

Conclusion

As this paper indicates, looking at responses to power preponderance through the


lenses of bandwagoning and balancing can prove highly problematic. To stop an
analysis at such a critique, however, presents an incomplete research project. A better
understanding of alternative responses to power preponderance requires the testing of
these approaches against empirical evidence. The almost decade-and-a-half of
American unipolarity should offer the historical data necessary to engage in precisely this
sort of examination. If the reactions of second-tier states to American power
preponderance play out according to the theoretical expectations that I lay out in this
paper, then it may be possible to reject that null hypothesis that states largely resort to
balancing and bandwagoning to deal with overwhelming might. This may allow me to
claim at least some support for argument of this project.

Rigorous testing of the model for state reactions to power preponderance needs to
consider several key issues. Firstly, there must be variation along my two key
independent variables, power and integration in the world system, as well an
understanding of the effects of historical path dependence. Secondly, there ought to be
a serious attempt to control for several important factors that may bias the results of
testing. These elements include the impact of geography, culture, regional influences,
as well as the historical baggage that often feeds into concepts of identity. Such an
approach may enable me to better consider whether I can reject the null hypothesis and
make a strong case for the two main alternative hypotheses that this paper tries to argue
for.

If the empirical record supports to the theory that second-tier states do indeed
respond to power preponderance along the lines of bonding, binding, buffering, and
beleaguering, depending on their power, integration, and perhaps path dependence to a
lesser extent, then the model here may actually offer an alternative way of understanding
contemporary world politics. Even if the empirics do not support the model that this
paper lays out, the question of responses to preponderant power would still require
further study, given the problems with the current study about conventional
bandwagoning-balancing dichotomy. Work in this area may help bring about a better
appreciation of the dynamics of a unipolar world.

20
Bibliography

Adler, Emanuel and Michael Barnett [eds.], Security Communities (Cambridge, England:
Cambridge University Press, 1998)

Baldwin, David A. [ed.], Liberalism and Neoliberalism: The Contemporary Debate (New
York, NY: Columbia University Press, 1993)

Biersteker, Thomas J., and Cynthia Weber [eds.], State Sovereignty as Social Construct
(Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press, 1996)

Bull, Hedley, The Anarchical Society: A Study of Order in World Politics (New York,
NY: Columbia University Press, 1977)

Carr, E.H., The Twenty Years’ Crisis, 1919-1939: An Introduction to the Study of
International Relations (London, England: Papermac, 1995)

Chowdury, Subrata Roy, Military Alliances and Neutrality in War and Peace (Bombay,
Mahasrashtra: Orient Longmans, 1966)

Christensen, Thomas J. and Jack Snyder, “Chain Gangs and Passed Bucks: Predicting
Alliance Patterns in Multipolarity”, International Organisation, Vol. 44, No. 2 (Spring
1990): 137-168

Duedney, Daniel H., “The Philadelphian System”, International Organisation, Vol. 49,
No. 2 (Spring 1995): 191-228

Deutsch, Karl W., et al, Political Community in the North Atlantic Area: International
Organisation in the Light of Historical Experience (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University
Press, 1957)

Fox, Annette Baker, The Politics of Attraction: Four Middle Powers and the United
States (New York, NY: Columbia University Press, 1977)

Fox, Annette Baker, The Power of Small States: Diplomacy in World War II (Chicago, IL:
The University of Chicago Press, 1959)

Friedberg, Aaron L., The Weary Titan: Britain and the Experience of Relative Decline,
1895-1905 (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1988)

21
Glaser, Charles L., “Realists as Optimists: Cooperation as Self-Help”, International
Security, Vol. 19, No. 3 (Winter 1994/1995): 50-90

Greico, Joseph M., “The Maastricht Treaty, Economic and Monetary Union and the
Neo-Realist Research Programme”, Review of International studies, No. 21 (1995):
21-40

Greico, Joseph M., “State Interests and Institutional Rule Trajectories”, Security Studies,
vol. 5 No. 3 (Spring 1996): 261-306

Gilpin, Robert, War and Change in World Politics (Cambridge, England: Cambridge
University Press, 1981)

Handel, Michael I., Weak States in the International System (London, England: Frank
Cass and Company Limited, 1990)

Ikenberry, G. John, After Victory: Institutions, Strategic Restraint, and the Rebuilding of
Order after Major Wars (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 2001)

Ikenberry, G. John, America Unrivalled: The Future of the Balance of Power (Ithaca, NY:
Cornell University Press, 2002)

Jervis, Robert and Jack Snyder [eds.], Dominoes and Bandwagons: Strategic Beliefs and
Great Power Competition in the Eurasian Rimland (Oxfod, England: Oxford University
Press, 1991)

Kagan, Robert, Of Paradise and Power: America versus Europe in the New World Order
(New York, NY: Alfred A. Knopf, Inc., 2003)

Kupchan, Charles A., End of the American Era: U.S. Foreign Policy and the Geopolitics
of the Twenty-First Century (New York, NY: Alfred A. Knopf, 2002)

Lake, David A., and Patrick Morgan, Regional Orders: Building Security in a New World
(University Park, PA: The Pennsylvania State University Press, 1997)

Liska, George, Nations in Alliance: The Liimts of Interdependence (Baltimore, MD: The
Johns Hopkins Press, 1962)

Mearsheimer, John J., The Tragedy of Great Power Politics (New York, NY: W.W.
Norton and Company, 2001)
22
Midlarsky, Manus A. [ed.]. Handbook of War Studies (Ann Arbor, MI: The University of
Michigan Press, 1996)

Morganthau, Hans, Politics among Nations: The Struggle for Power and Peace, Fifth
Edition Revised (New York, NY: Alfred A. Knopf, 1973)

Mueller, Karl P., Strategy, Asymmetric Deterrence, and Accommodation: Middle Powers
and Security in Modern Europe, Ph.D. Dissertation, Department of Politics, Princeton
University, 1991

Nye, Joseph S., Jr., The Paradox of Power: Why the World’s Only Superpower Can’t Go
It Alone (Oxford, England: Oxford University Press, 2002)

Rosecrance, Richard, The Rise of the Trading State: Commerce and Conquest in the
Modern World (New York, NY: Basic Books, 1986)

Rosecrance, Richard, The Rise of the Virtual State: Wealth and Power in the Coming
Century (New York: NY: Basic Books, 1999)

Rothstein, Robert L., Alliances and Small Powers (New York, NY: Columbia University
Press, 1968)

Schroeder, Paul W., Austria, Britain, and the Crimean War: The Destruction of the
European Concert (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1972)

Schroeder, Paul W., “Historical Reality versus Neo-Realist Theory”, International


Security, Vol. 10, No. 1 (Summer 1994): 108-148

Schroeder, Paul W., Transformation of European Politics (Oxford, England: Clarendon


Press, 1994)

Schweller, Randall, “Bandwagoning for Profit: Bringing the Revisionist State Back In”,
International Security, Vol. 19, No. 1 (Summer 1994): 72-107

Solingen, Etel, Regional Orders at Century’s Dawn: Global and Domestic Influences on
Grand Strategy (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1998)

Vasquez, John A., and Colin Elman [eds.], Realism and the Balance of Power: A New
Debate (Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall Publishers, 2002)
23
Walt, Stephen M., The Origin of Alliances (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1987)

Waltz, Kenneth N., “Structural Realism after the Cold War”, International Security, Vol.
25, No. 1 (Summer 2000): 5-41

Waltz, Kenneth N., Theory of International Politics (New York, NY: McGraw-Hill,
1979)

Watson, Adam, The Evolution of International Society (London, England: Routledge,


1992)

Wohlforth, William C., “Stability of a Unipolar World”, International Security, Vol. 24,
No. 1 (Summer 1999): 5-41

24
IDSS Working Paper Series

1. Vietnam-China Relations Since The End of The Cold War (1998)


Ang Cheng Guan

2. Multilateral Security Cooperation in the Asia-Pacific Region: Prospects and (1999)


Possibilities
Desmond Ball

3. Reordering Asia: “Cooperative Security” or Concert of Powers? (1999)


Amitav Acharya

4. The South China Sea Dispute re-visited (1999)


Ang Cheng Guan

5. Continuity and Change In Malaysian Politics: Assessing the Buildup to the (1999)
1999-2000 General Elections
Joseph Liow Chin Yong

6. ‘Humanitarian Intervention in Kosovo’ as Justified, Executed and Mediated (2000)


by NATO: Strategic Lessons for Singapore
Kumar Ramakrishna

7. Taiwan’s Future: Mongolia or Tibet? (2001)


Chien-peng (C.P.) Chung

8. Asia-Pacific Diplomacies: Reading Discontinuity in Late-Modern (2001)


Diplomatic Practice
Tan See Seng

9. Framing “South Asia”: Whose Imagined Region? (2001)


Sinderpal Singh

10. Explaining Indonesia's Relations with Singapore During the New Order (2001)
Period: The Case of Regime Maintenance and Foreign Policy
Terence Lee Chek Liang

11. Human Security: Discourse, Statecraft, Emancipation (2001)


Tan See Seng

12. Globalization and its Implications for Southeast Asian Security: A (2001)
Vietnamese Perspective
Nguyen Phuong Binh

13. Framework for Autonomy in Southeast Asia’s Plural Societies (2001)


Miriam Coronel Ferrer

14. Burma: Protracted Conflict, Governance and Non-Traditional Security Issues (2001)
Ananda Rajah
15. Natural Resources Management and Environmental Security in Southeast (2001)
Asia: Case Study of Clean Water Supplies in Singapore
Kog Yue Choong

16. Crisis and Transformation: ASEAN in the New Era (2001)


Etel Solingen

17. Human Security: East Versus West? (2001)


Amitav Acharya

18. Asian Developing Countries and the Next Round of WTO Negotiations (2001)
Barry Desker

19. Multilateralism, Neo-liberalism and Security in Asia: The Role of the Asia (2001)
Pacific Economic Co-operation Forum
Ian Taylor

20. Humanitarian Intervention and Peacekeeping as Issues for Asia-Pacific (2001)


Security
Derek McDougall

21. Comprehensive Security: The South Asian Case (2002)


S.D. Muni

22. The Evolution of China’s Maritime Combat Doctrines and Models: (2002)
1949-2001
You Ji

23. The Concept of Security Before and After September 11 (2002)


a. The Contested Concept of Security
Steve Smith
b. Security and Security Studies After September 11: Some Preliminary
Reflections
Amitav Acharya

24. Democratisation In South Korea And Taiwan: The Effect Of Social Division (2002)
On Inter-Korean and Cross-Strait Relations
Chien-peng (C.P.) Chung

25. Understanding Financial Globalisation (2002)


Andrew Walter

26. 911, American Praetorian Unilateralism and the Impact on State-Society (2002)
Relations in Southeast Asia
Kumar Ramakrishna

27. Great Power Politics in Contemporary East Asia: Negotiating Multipolarity (2002)
or Hegemony?
Tan See Seng
28. What Fear Hath Wrought: Missile Hysteria and The Writing of “America” (2002)
Tan See Seng

29. International Responses to Terrorism: The Limits and Possibilities of Legal (2002)
Control of Terrorism by Regional Arrangement with Particular Reference to
Asean
Ong Yen Nee

30. Reconceptualizing the PLA Navy in Post – Mao China: Functions, Warfare, (2002)
Arms, and Organization
Nan Li

31. Attempting Developmental Regionalism Through AFTA: The Domestics (2002)


Politics – Domestic Capital Nexus
Helen E S Nesadurai

32. 11 September and China: Opportunities, Challenges, and Warfighting (2002)


Nan Li

33. Islam and Society in Southeast Asia after September 11 (2002)


Barry Desker

34. Hegemonic Constraints: The Implications of September 11 For American (2002)


Power
Evelyn Goh

35. Not Yet All Aboard…But Already All At Sea Over Container Security (2002)
Initiative
Irvin Lim

36. Financial Liberalization and Prudential Regulation in East Asia: Still (2002)
Perverse?
Andrew Walter

37. Indonesia and The Washington Consensus (2002)


Premjith Sadasivan

38. The Political Economy of FDI Location: Why Don’t Political Checks and (2002)
Balances and Treaty Constraints Matter?
Andrew Walter

39. The Securitization of Transnational Crime in ASEAN (2002)


Ralf Emmers

40. Liquidity Support and The Financial Crisis: The Indonesian Experience (2002)
J Soedradjad Djiwandono

41. A UK Perspective on Defence Equipment Acquisition (2003)


David Kirkpatrick
42. Regionalisation of Peace in Asia: Experiences and Prospects of ASEAN, (2003)
ARF and UN Partnership
Mely C. Anthony

43. The WTO In 2003: Structural Shifts, State-Of-Play And Prospects For The (2003)
Doha Round
Razeen Sally

44. Seeking Security In The Dragon’s Shadow : China and Southeast Asia In (2003)
The Emerging Asian Order
Amitav Acharya

45. Deconstructing Political Islam In Malaysia: UMNO’S Response To PAS’ (2003)


Religio-Political Dialectic
Joseph Liow

46. The War On Terror And The Future of Indonesian Democracy (2003)
Tatik S. Hafidz

47. Examining The Role of Foreign Assistance in Security Sector Reforms: The (2003)
Indonesian Case
Eduardo Lachica

48. Sovereignty and The Politics of Identity in International Relations (2003)


Adrian Kuah

49. Deconstructing Jihad; Southeast Asian Contexts (2003)


Patricia Martinez

50. The Correlates of Nationalism in Beijing Public Opinion (2003)


Alastair Iain Johnston

51. In Search of Suitable Positions’in the Asia Pacific: Negotiating the (2003)
US-China Relationship and Regional Security
Evelyn Goh

52. American Unilaterism, Foreign Economic Policy and the ‘Securitisation’ of (2003)
Globalisation
Richard Higgott

53. Fireball on the Water: Naval Force Protection-Projection, Coast Guarding, (2003)
Customs Border Security & Multilateral Cooperation in Rolling Back the
Global Waves of Terror from the Sea
Irvin Lim

54. Revisiting Responses To Power Preponderance: Going Beyond The (2003)


Balancing-Bandwagoning Dichotomy
Chong Ja Ian

You might also like