Small Is Beautiful and Efficient: The Case For Secession: Hans-Hermann Hoppe
Small Is Beautiful and Efficient: The Case For Secession: Hans-Hermann Hoppe
Hans-Hermann Hoppe
direction. For instance, during the second half of the 17th century, Germany con-
sisted of some 234 countries, 51 free cities, and 1500 independent knightly man-
ors. By the early 19th century, the total number of the three had fallen to below
50, and by 1871 unification had been achieved. The ssame happened in Italy.
Even small states have a history of expansion and centralization. Switzerland
began in 1291 as a confederation of three independent cantonal states. By 1848 it
was a single federal state with some two dozen cantonal provinces.
Moreover, from a global perspective, mankind has come closer than ever
before to the establishment of a world government. Even before the dissolution
of the Soviet Empire, the US had attained hegemony over Western Europe (most
notably over West Germany) and the Pacific rim countries (most notably over
Japan) — as indicated by the presence of American troops and military bases, by
the NATO and SEATO pacts, by the role of the American dollar as the ultimate
international reserve currency and of the US Federal Reserve System as the
"lender" or "liquidity provider" of last resort for the entire Western banking sys-
tem, and by institutions such as the International Monetary Fund (IMF), the
World Bank, and the recently established World Trade Organization (WTO). In
addition, under American hegemony the political integration of Western Europe
has steadily advanced. With the establishment of a European Central Bank and a
European Currency Unit (ECU), the European Community will likely be com-
plete before the turn of the century. At the same time, with the North American
Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) a significant step toward the political integra-
tion of the American continent has been taken. In the absence of the Soviet
Empire and its military threat, the US has emerged as the world's sole and undis-
puted military superpower and its "top cop."
According to the orthodox view, centralization is generally desirable and
progressive movement, whereas disintegration and secession, even if sometimes
unavoidable, represent an anachronism. It is assumed that larger political units —
and ultimately a single world government — imply wider markets and hence
increased wealth. As evidence of this, it is pointed out that economic prosperity
has increased dramatically with increased centralization. However, rather than
reflecting any truth, this orthodox view illustrates the fact that history is typically
written by its winners. Correlation or temporal coincidence do not prove causa-
tion. In fact, the relation between economic prosperity and centralization is very
different from and indeed almost the opposite of what the orthodoxy alleges.
Political integration (centralization) and economic (market) integration are
two completely different phenomena. Political integration involves the territorial
expansion of a state's power of taxation and property regulation (expropriation).
allowing more private property and imposing a lower tax and regulation burden
than its neighbors. Ultimately, with as many territories as separate households,
villages or towns, the opportunities for economically motivated emigration is
maximized, and government power over a domestic economy minimized.
Specifically, the smaller the country, the greater the pressure to opt for free
trade rather than protectionism. All government interference with foreign trade
forcibly limits the range of mutually beneficial interterritorial exchanges and thus
leads to relative impoverishment, at home as well as abroad. But the smaller a ter-
ritory and its internal markets, the more dramatic this effect will be. A country the
size of the US, for instance, might attain comparatively high standards of living
even if it renounced all foreign trade, provided it possessed an unrestricted internal
capital and consumer goods market. In contrast, if predominantly Serbian cities or
counties seceded from surrounding Croatia, and if they pursued the same protec-
tionism, this would likely spell disaster. Consider a single household as the con-
ceivably smallest secessionist unit. By engaging in unrestricted free trade, even the
smallest territory can be fully integrated into the world market and partake of every
advantage of the division of labor, and its owners may become the wealthiest peo-
ple on earth. On the other hand, if the same household owners decided to forego all
interterritorial trade, abject poverty or death would result. Accordingly, the smaller
a territory and its internal markets, the more likely it is that it will opt for free trade.
Moreover, secession also promotes monetary integration. The process of
centralization has also resulted in monetary disintegration; the destruction of the
former international commodity (gold) money standard and its replacement with
a dollar-dominated system of freely fluctuating government paper monies (i.e., a
global, US-led government counterfeiting cartel). However, a system of freely
fluctuating paper currencies — the Friedmanite-monetarist ideal — is strictly
speaking no monetary system at all.5 It is a system of partial barter — dysfunc-
tional of the very purpose of money of facilitating rather than complicating
exchange. This becomes obvious once it is recognized that, from the viewpoint of
economic theory, there is no special significance attached to the way national
borders are drawn. Yet, if one then imagines a proliferation of ever smaller
national territories, ultimately to the point where each household forms its own
country, Friedman's proposal is revealed for what it is — an outright absurdity. If
every household were to issue its own paper currency, the world would be right
back at barter. No one would accept anyone else's paper, economic calculation
would be impossible, and trade would come to a virtual standstill. It is only due to
centuries of political centralization and the fact that only a relatively small num-
ber of countries and national currencies remains, and hence that the disintegrative
5. See also Murray N. Rothbard, The Case for a 100 Percent Gold Dollar (Auburn,
Al.: Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1991); The Case Against the FED (Auburn, Al.: Ludwig
von Mises Institute, 1995); and Hans-Hermann Hoppe, "How is Fiat Money Possible? — or
The Devolution of Money and Credit," in Review ofAustrian Economics, Vol.7, no.2 (1994).
THE CASE FOR SECESSION 101
consequences and calculational difficulties are far less severe, that this could
have been overlooked. From this insight it follows that secession, provided it
proceeds far enough, will actually promote monetary integration. In a world of
hundreds of thousands of independent political units, each country would have to
abandon the current fiat money system, which has been responsible for the great-
est, world-wide inflation in all of human history, and once again adopt an inter-
national commodity money system such as the gold standard.
Secessionism, and the growth of separatists and regionalist movements in
Eastern and Western Europe, in North America as well as elsewhere, represent
not an anachronism but potentially the most progressive historical forces. Seces-
sion increases ethnic, linguistic, religious and cultural diversity, while in the
course of centuries of centralization hundreds of distinct cultures were stamped
out. It will end the forced integration brought about as the result of centralization,
and rather than stimulating social strife and cultural nivellation, it will promote
the peaceful, cooperative competition of different, territorially separate cultures.
In particular, it will eliminate the immigration problem increasingly plaguing
Western Europe as well as the US. Presently, whenever the central government
permits immigration, it allows foreigners to proceed — literally on govern-
ment-owned roads — to any of its residents' doorsteps, regardless of whether or
not these residents desire such proximity to foreigners. "Free immigration" is
thus to a large extent forced integration. Secession solves this problem by letting
smaller territories each have their own admission standards and determine inde-
pendently with whom they will associate on their own territory and with whom
they prefer to cooperate from a distance.6
Lastly, secession promotes economic integration and development. The
process of centralization has resulted in the formation of an international,
US-dominated government cartel of managed migration, trade, and fiat money,
ever more invasive and burdensome governments, globalized welfare-warfare
statism and economic stagnation or even declining standards of living. Seces-
sion, if it is only extensive enough, could change all this. A world consisting of
tens of thousands of distinct countries, regions and cantons, and of hundreds of
thousands of independent free cities such as the present-day "oddities" of
Monaco, Andorra, San Marino, Liechtenstein, Hong Kong, and Singapore, with
the resulting greatly increased opportunities for economically motivated migra-
tion, would be one of small liberal governments economically integrated through
free trade and an international commodity money such as gold. It would be a
world of unprecedented economic growth and unheard of prosperity.