0% found this document useful (0 votes)
145 views7 pages

Small Is Beautiful and Efficient: The Case For Secession: Hans-Hermann Hoppe

This document argues that political centralization and the formation of larger states is driven by states seeking to expand their power and tax base. While decentralizing forces have existed, the overall trend in history has been toward greater centralization and fewer independent states. The document claims that political and economic integration are different, and that centralization does not necessarily lead to greater prosperity, as some argue. Smaller states are actually better for the economy as they are constrained by competition from other states to tax and regulate less heavily.

Uploaded by

Archilolo
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
145 views7 pages

Small Is Beautiful and Efficient: The Case For Secession: Hans-Hermann Hoppe

This document argues that political centralization and the formation of larger states is driven by states seeking to expand their power and tax base. While decentralizing forces have existed, the overall trend in history has been toward greater centralization and fewer independent states. The document claims that political and economic integration are different, and that centralization does not necessarily lead to greater prosperity, as some argue. Smaller states are actually better for the economy as they are constrained by competition from other states to tax and regulate less heavily.

Uploaded by

Archilolo
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 7

THE CASE FOR SECESSION 95

Small is Beautiful and Efficient:


The Case For Secession

Hans-Hermann Hoppe

A state is a territorial monopoly of compulsion — an agency which may


engage in continual, institutionalized expropriation of property and the exploita-
tion — in the form of taxation and regulation — of private property owners.'
Assuming no more than self-interest on the part of government agents, all states
can be expected to exhibit a tendency toward increased exploitation. On the one
hand, this means increased domestic exploitation (and internal taxation); on the
other, it means territorial expansion. States will always try to enlarge their
exploitation and tax base. In doing so, however, they will come into conflict with
other, competing states. The competition between states qua territorial monopo-
lies of compulsion is by its very nature an eliminative competition (i.e., there can
be only one monopolist of exploitation and taxation in any given area). Thus, the
competition between different states can be expected to promote a tendency
toward increased political centralization and ultimately one single world state.
A glance at Western history suffices to illustrate the validity of this conclusion.
Thus, at the beginning of this millennium, Europe consisted of numerous indepen-
dent political units. Now, only a few such units remain. To be sure, decentralizing
forces also existed. There was the progressive disintegration of the Ottoman
Empire from the 16th century until after WWI and the establishment of modern
Turkey. The Habsburg Empire was gradually dismembered from the time of its
greatest expansion under Charles V until it disappeared and modern Austria was
founded in 1918. And only recently has the former Soviet Empire disintegrated.
There are now more than a dozen independent states on the territory of the former
Soviet Union. The former Yugoslavia consists now of Slovenia, Croatia, Serbia,
Macedonia, and Bosnia. And the Czechs and the Slovaks have split and formed
independent countries. However, the overriding tendency was in the opposite
1. On the theory of the state, see Murray N. Rothbard, For A New Liberty (New
York: Macmillan, 1978); The Ethics of Liberty (Atlantic Highlands: Humanities Press,
1982); Power and Market (Kansas City: Sheed, Andrews & McMeel, 1977); Hans-Her-
mann Hoppe, Eigentum, Anarchie und Staat (Opladen: Westdeutscher Verlag, 1987); A
Theory of Socialism and Capitalism (Boston: Kluwer, 1989); The Economics and Ethics of
Private Property (Boston: Kluwer, 1993); also Albert J. Nock, Our Enemy the State (Del-
evan: Hallberg Publishing, 1983); Franz Oppenheimer The State (New York: Vanguard
Press, 1914); System der Soziologie, Vol. 2, "Der Staat" (Stuttgart: G . Fischer, 1964).
96 HANS-HERMANN HOPPE

direction. For instance, during the second half of the 17th century, Germany con-
sisted of some 234 countries, 51 free cities, and 1500 independent knightly man-
ors. By the early 19th century, the total number of the three had fallen to below
50, and by 1871 unification had been achieved. The ssame happened in Italy.
Even small states have a history of expansion and centralization. Switzerland
began in 1291 as a confederation of three independent cantonal states. By 1848 it
was a single federal state with some two dozen cantonal provinces.
Moreover, from a global perspective, mankind has come closer than ever
before to the establishment of a world government. Even before the dissolution
of the Soviet Empire, the US had attained hegemony over Western Europe (most
notably over West Germany) and the Pacific rim countries (most notably over
Japan) — as indicated by the presence of American troops and military bases, by
the NATO and SEATO pacts, by the role of the American dollar as the ultimate
international reserve currency and of the US Federal Reserve System as the
"lender" or "liquidity provider" of last resort for the entire Western banking sys-
tem, and by institutions such as the International Monetary Fund (IMF), the
World Bank, and the recently established World Trade Organization (WTO). In
addition, under American hegemony the political integration of Western Europe
has steadily advanced. With the establishment of a European Central Bank and a
European Currency Unit (ECU), the European Community will likely be com-
plete before the turn of the century. At the same time, with the North American
Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) a significant step toward the political integra-
tion of the American continent has been taken. In the absence of the Soviet
Empire and its military threat, the US has emerged as the world's sole and undis-
puted military superpower and its "top cop."
According to the orthodox view, centralization is generally desirable and
progressive movement, whereas disintegration and secession, even if sometimes
unavoidable, represent an anachronism. It is assumed that larger political units —
and ultimately a single world government — imply wider markets and hence
increased wealth. As evidence of this, it is pointed out that economic prosperity
has increased dramatically with increased centralization. However, rather than
reflecting any truth, this orthodox view illustrates the fact that history is typically
written by its winners. Correlation or temporal coincidence do not prove causa-
tion. In fact, the relation between economic prosperity and centralization is very
different from and indeed almost the opposite of what the orthodoxy alleges.
Political integration (centralization) and economic (market) integration are
two completely different phenomena. Political integration involves the territorial
expansion of a state's power of taxation and property regulation (expropriation).

2. On the political economy of centralization and decentralization, see Jean


Baechler, The Origins of Capitalism (New York: St. Martin's Press, 1976), esp. ch. 7; and
Hans-Hermann Hoppe, "Migrazione, Centralismo e Secessione nell' Europa Contempora-
nea," inBibliotecaDeliaLiberta, no.l 18 (1992).
THE CASE FOR SECESSION 97

Economic integration is the extension of the interpersonal and interregional divi-


sion of labor and market participation. In principle, in taxing and regulating pri-
vate property owners and market income earners, all governments are
counterproductive. They reduce market participation and the formation of eco-
nomic wealth. Once the existence of a government has been assumed, however,
there is no direct relation between territorial size and economic integration. Swit-
zerland and Albania are both small countries, but Switzerland exhibits a high
degree of economic integration, whereas Albania does not. Both the US and the
former Soviet Union are large. Yet while there is much division of labor and mar-
ket participation in the US, in the Soviet Union, where there was virtually no pri-
vate capital ownership, there was hardly any economic integration. Centraliza-
tion, then, can go hand in hand with either economic progress or retrogression.
There are improvements whenever a less taxing and regulating government
expands its territory at the expense of a more exploitative one. If the reverse
occurs, centralization implies economic disintegration and retrogression.
Yet there is a very important indirect relation between size and economic inte-
gration. A central government ruling over a large territories — much less a single
world government — cannot come into being ab ovo. Instead, all institutions with
the power to tax and regulate private owners must start out small. Smallness, how-
ever, contributes to moderation. A small government has many competitors,3 and
if it taxes and regulates its own subjects more than its competitors, it is bound to
suffer from the emigration of labor and capital and a corresponding loss of future
tax revenue. Consider a single household, or a village, as an independent terri-
tory. Could a father do to his son, or a mayor to his village, what the government
of the Soviet Union did to its subjects (i.e., deny them private capital ownership)
or what governments all across Western Europe and the US do to their citizens
(i.e., expropriate up to 50% of their productive output)? Obviously not. There

3. Political competition is a far more effective way of limiting a government's natu-


ral desire for expansion than internal constitutional limitations. Indeed, the attempts of
some public choice theorists and of "constitutional economics" to design liberal model con-
stitutions must strike one as hopelessly naive. For constitutional courts, and supreme court
judges, are part and parcel of the government apparatus whose powers they are supposed to
limit.Why in the world should they want to constrain the power of the very organization
that provides them with jobs, money, and prestige? To assume so is not only theoretically
inconsistent (i.e., incompatible with the assumption of self-interest), it is also without any
historical foundation. Despite the explicit limitation of the power of the central government
contained in the 10th amendment of the US constitution, for instance, it has been the inter-
pretation by the US Supreme Court which has rendered the amendment essentially null and
void. Similarly, despite the constitutional guarantee of private property by the (West) Ger-
man constitution, for instance, the German supreme court, after German reunification in
1990, declared all communist expropriations prior to the founding of the East German state
in 1949 "valid." Thus, more than 50% of former East Germany's land used for agriculture
was appropriated by the (West) German state (rather than being returned to the original pri-
vate owners, as required by a literal interpretation of the constitution).
98 HANS-HERMANN HOPPE

would either be an immediate revolt and the government would be overthrown,


or emigration to another nearby household or village would ensue.
Contrary to orthodoxy, then, it is precisely the fact that Europe possessed a
highly decentralized power structure composed of countless independent politi-
cal units which explains the origin of capitalism — the expansion of market par-
ticipation and of economic growth — in the Western world. It is not by accident
that capitalism first flourished under conditions of extreme political decentraliza-
tion: in the northern Italian city states, in southern Germany, and in the seces-
sionist Low Countries (Netherlands).
The competition among small states for taxable subjects brings them into
conflict with each other. As a result of interstate conflicts, historically drawn out
over the course of centuries, a few states succeed in expanding their territories,
while others are eliminated or incorporated. Which states win in this process of
eliminative competition depends on many factors, of course, but in the long run,
the decisive factor is the relative amount of economic resources at a government's
disposal. In taxing and regulating, governments do not contribute to the creation
of economic wealth. Instead, they parasitically draw on existing wealth. However,
they can influence the amount of existing wealth negatively. Other things being
equal, the lower the tax and regulation burden imposed by a government on its
domestic economy, the larger its population tends to grow (due to internal reasons
as well as immigration factors), and the larger the amount of domestically pro-
duced wealth on which it can draw in its conflicts with neighboring competitors.
For this reason, centralization is frequently progressive. States which tax and reg-
ulate their domestic economies little — liberal states — tend to defeat and expand
their territories at the expense of non-liberal ones. This accounts for the outbreak
of the "Industrial Revolution" in centralized England and France. It explains why,
in the course of the 19th century, Western Europe came to dominate the rest of the
world (rather than the other way around). Furthermore, it explains the rise of the
US to the rank of superpower in the course of the 20th century.
However, the further the process of more liberal governments defeating less
liberal ones proceeds (i.e., the larger the territories, the fewer and more distant the
remaining competitors, and thus the more costly international migration), the
lower a government's incentive to continue in its domestic liberalism will be. As
one approaches the limit of a One World state, all possibilities of voting with
one's feet against a government disappear. Wherever one goes, the same tax and
regulation structure applies. Thus relieved of the problem of emigration, a funda-
mental rein on the expansion of governmental power is gone. This explains devel-
opments in the 20th century: with WWI, and even more so with WWII, the US
attained hegemony over Western Europe and became heir to its vast colonial
empires. A decisive step in the direction of global unification was taken with the
establishment of a pax Americana. Indeed, throughout the entire period the US,
Western Europe, and most of the rest of the world have suffered from a steady and
THE CASE FOR SECESSION 99

dramatic growth of government power, taxation, and regulatory expropriation.


In light of social and economic theory and history, then, a case for secession
can be made. Initially, secession is nothing more than a shifting of control over
the nationalized wealth from a larger, central government to a smaller, regional
one. Whether this will lead to more or less economic integration and prosperity
depends largely on the new regional government's policies. However, the sole
fact of secession has a positive impact on production, for one of the most impor-
tant reasons for secession is typically the belief on the part of the secessionists
that they and their territory are being exploited by others. The Slovenes felt they
were being robbed systematically by the Serbs and the Serbian-dominated central
Yugoslavian government; and the Baltic people resented the fact that they had to
pay tribute to the Russians and the Russian-dominated government of the Soviet
Union. By virtue of secession, hegemonic domestic relations are replaced by con-
tractual, mutually beneficial foreign relations. Instead of forced integration, there
is voluntary separation. Forced integration, as also illustrated by measures such
as busing, rent controls, affirmative action, anti-discrimination laws and, as will
be explained shortly, "free immigration," invariably creates tension, hatred, and
conflict. In contrast, voluntary separation leads to harmony and peace. Under
forced integration, any mistake can be blamed on a "foreign" group or culture
and all success claimed as one's own; hence, there is little reason for any culture
to learn from another. Under a regime of "separate but equal," one must face up
to the reality not only of cultural diversity but in particular of visibly different
ranks of cultural advancement. If a secessionist people wishes to improve or
maintain its position vis-a-vis a competing one, nothing but discriminative learn-
ing will help. It must imitate, assimilate, and, if possible, improve upon the skills,
traits, practices and rules characteristic of more advanced societies, and it must
avoid those characteristic of less advanced societies. Rather than promoting a
downward leveling of cultures as under forced integration, secession stimulates a
cooperative process of cultural selection and advancement.
Moreover, while everything else depends on the new regional government's
domestic policies and there is no direct relation between size and economic integra-
tion, there is an important indirect connection. Just as political centralization ulti-
mately tends to promote economic disintegration, so secession tends to advance
integration and economic development. First, secession always involves the break-
ing away of a smaller from a larger population and is thus a vote against the princi-
ple of democracy and majoritarian rule in favor of private, decentralized ownership.
More importantly, secession always involves increased opportunities for interre-
gional migration, and a secessionist government is immediately confronted with the
specter of emigration. To avoid the loss of its most productive subjects, it comes
under increased pressure to adopt comparatively liberal domestic policies by
4. On this theme, see also Paul Johnson, Modern Times (New York: Harper &
Row, 1983); and Robert Nisbet, The Present Age (New York: Harper & Row, 1988).
/ 00 HANS-HERMANN HOPPE

allowing more private property and imposing a lower tax and regulation burden
than its neighbors. Ultimately, with as many territories as separate households,
villages or towns, the opportunities for economically motivated emigration is
maximized, and government power over a domestic economy minimized.
Specifically, the smaller the country, the greater the pressure to opt for free
trade rather than protectionism. All government interference with foreign trade
forcibly limits the range of mutually beneficial interterritorial exchanges and thus
leads to relative impoverishment, at home as well as abroad. But the smaller a ter-
ritory and its internal markets, the more dramatic this effect will be. A country the
size of the US, for instance, might attain comparatively high standards of living
even if it renounced all foreign trade, provided it possessed an unrestricted internal
capital and consumer goods market. In contrast, if predominantly Serbian cities or
counties seceded from surrounding Croatia, and if they pursued the same protec-
tionism, this would likely spell disaster. Consider a single household as the con-
ceivably smallest secessionist unit. By engaging in unrestricted free trade, even the
smallest territory can be fully integrated into the world market and partake of every
advantage of the division of labor, and its owners may become the wealthiest peo-
ple on earth. On the other hand, if the same household owners decided to forego all
interterritorial trade, abject poverty or death would result. Accordingly, the smaller
a territory and its internal markets, the more likely it is that it will opt for free trade.
Moreover, secession also promotes monetary integration. The process of
centralization has also resulted in monetary disintegration; the destruction of the
former international commodity (gold) money standard and its replacement with
a dollar-dominated system of freely fluctuating government paper monies (i.e., a
global, US-led government counterfeiting cartel). However, a system of freely
fluctuating paper currencies — the Friedmanite-monetarist ideal — is strictly
speaking no monetary system at all.5 It is a system of partial barter — dysfunc-
tional of the very purpose of money of facilitating rather than complicating
exchange. This becomes obvious once it is recognized that, from the viewpoint of
economic theory, there is no special significance attached to the way national
borders are drawn. Yet, if one then imagines a proliferation of ever smaller
national territories, ultimately to the point where each household forms its own
country, Friedman's proposal is revealed for what it is — an outright absurdity. If
every household were to issue its own paper currency, the world would be right
back at barter. No one would accept anyone else's paper, economic calculation
would be impossible, and trade would come to a virtual standstill. It is only due to
centuries of political centralization and the fact that only a relatively small num-
ber of countries and national currencies remains, and hence that the disintegrative

5. See also Murray N. Rothbard, The Case for a 100 Percent Gold Dollar (Auburn,
Al.: Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1991); The Case Against the FED (Auburn, Al.: Ludwig
von Mises Institute, 1995); and Hans-Hermann Hoppe, "How is Fiat Money Possible? — or
The Devolution of Money and Credit," in Review ofAustrian Economics, Vol.7, no.2 (1994).
THE CASE FOR SECESSION 101

consequences and calculational difficulties are far less severe, that this could
have been overlooked. From this insight it follows that secession, provided it
proceeds far enough, will actually promote monetary integration. In a world of
hundreds of thousands of independent political units, each country would have to
abandon the current fiat money system, which has been responsible for the great-
est, world-wide inflation in all of human history, and once again adopt an inter-
national commodity money system such as the gold standard.
Secessionism, and the growth of separatists and regionalist movements in
Eastern and Western Europe, in North America as well as elsewhere, represent
not an anachronism but potentially the most progressive historical forces. Seces-
sion increases ethnic, linguistic, religious and cultural diversity, while in the
course of centuries of centralization hundreds of distinct cultures were stamped
out. It will end the forced integration brought about as the result of centralization,
and rather than stimulating social strife and cultural nivellation, it will promote
the peaceful, cooperative competition of different, territorially separate cultures.
In particular, it will eliminate the immigration problem increasingly plaguing
Western Europe as well as the US. Presently, whenever the central government
permits immigration, it allows foreigners to proceed — literally on govern-
ment-owned roads — to any of its residents' doorsteps, regardless of whether or
not these residents desire such proximity to foreigners. "Free immigration" is
thus to a large extent forced integration. Secession solves this problem by letting
smaller territories each have their own admission standards and determine inde-
pendently with whom they will associate on their own territory and with whom
they prefer to cooperate from a distance.6
Lastly, secession promotes economic integration and development. The
process of centralization has resulted in the formation of an international,
US-dominated government cartel of managed migration, trade, and fiat money,
ever more invasive and burdensome governments, globalized welfare-warfare
statism and economic stagnation or even declining standards of living. Seces-
sion, if it is only extensive enough, could change all this. A world consisting of
tens of thousands of distinct countries, regions and cantons, and of hundreds of
thousands of independent free cities such as the present-day "oddities" of
Monaco, Andorra, San Marino, Liechtenstein, Hong Kong, and Singapore, with
the resulting greatly increased opportunities for economically motivated migra-
tion, would be one of small liberal governments economically integrated through
free trade and an international commodity money such as gold. It would be a
world of unprecedented economic growth and unheard of prosperity.

6. On immigration see also Murray N. Rothbard, "Nations by Consent: Decompos-


ing the Nation State," in Journal of Libertarian Studies, Vol.11, no.l (1994); and Hans-
Hermann Hoppe, "Free Immigration or Forced Integration?" in Chronicles (June 1995).

You might also like