ECON3122 Intermicch14out
ECON3122 Intermicch14out
1. Nodes –places where the branches of the game tree extend from
gains no additional information from Firm A’s decision (such as a change in the market price),
then the game is essentially one where Firm A and Firm B choose simultaneously.
1
label for information set is pointing to the open circle that encircles the term
“Firm B”. Thus, Firm B can see how much Firm A has decided to produce. If
Firm B could not determine if Firm A decided to produce 48 or 64 units, then
Firm B would have one information set, and there would be one open circle
encircling both of Firm B’s decision nodes.
To solve sequential games we start from the end of the game and work our
way back towards the beginning. This is called backward induction. To …nd
the Nash Equilibrium (NE), we …rst determine what Firm B would do given a
quantity choice by Firm A. In this example, Firm B would choose QB = 64 as
its strategy if Firm A chose QA = 48 because $5:1 > $4:6. Also, Firm B would
choose QB = 64 if Firm A chose QA = 64 because $4:1 > $3:8. Thus, Firm B’s
strategy is: {Choose QB = 64 if Firm A chooses QA = 48; choose QB = 64 if
Firm A chooses QA = 48}. We now know what Firm B will do for any given
choice by Firm A, which means that we have an entire strategy for Firm B.
Firm A, knowing that Firm B will choose QB = 64 regardless of its quantity
choice, can now “lop o¤ the branches”that correspond to QB = 48. The reason
that Firm A can lop o¤ these branches is that it knows that it will never see
the payo¤s associated with following those branches because Firm B will never
follow them. Thus, to Firm A, the game tree looks like:
2
I have left the payo¤s there but removed the branches. Firm A has one
decision to make, produce a quantity of 48 or a quantity of 64. If it produces
a quantity of 48, Firm B will produce 64, and Firm A will receive a payo¤ of
$3.8. If it produces a quantity of 64, Firm B will produce 64, and Firm A will
receive a payo¤ of $4.1. Since $4:1 > $3:8, Firm A will choose QA = 64. Thus,
the complete NE for this game is:
Firm A: Choose QA = 64
Firm B: Choose QB = 64 if Firm A chooses QA = 48; choose QB = 64 if
Firm A chooses QA = 48
Now, when the game is played only one payo¤ is received. To …nd this payo¤
just follow the path outlined by the NE strategy. Firm A chooses QA = 64,
and if Firm A chooses QA = 64 then Firm B chooses QB = 64, which leads to
a payo¤ of $4.1 for Firm A and $4.1 for Firm B. Notice that we didn’t use the
fact that Firm B chooses QB = 64 if Firm A chooses QA = 48 because Firm
A did not choose QA = 48. We still need to include that piece as part of our
NE strategy even though we don’t use it when we …nd the path that the game
actually follows.
3
…rm sells 12 the market quantity at that price. Assume that the …rm’s are iden-
tical, and that each …rm has constant M C equal to c. To make this a sequential
Bertrand game, assume that Firm A chooses its price …rst, and then Firm B
observes Firm A’s choice and sets its own price. The game tree is depicted be-
low, with a slight modi…cation. Since …rms can choose any price greater than 0
they have an in…nite amount of strategies (PA = 0; PA = 1; PA = 1:5; :::). Since
it is impossible to write down an in…nite amount of branches that correspond
to the in…nite amount of strategies we simplify the game tree by drawing two
branches corresponding to the lowest possible price (PA = 0) and the highest
possible price (PA = 1) and then connect those two branches with a dotted line
to represent the fact that there are an in…nite amount of possibilities there.2
Also note that the payo¤s have been removed as listing an in…nite amount of
payo¤s to correspond to the in…nite amount of strategies is unrealistic.
Again, to …nd the solution of this game use backward induction. We want
to …nd out what Firm B would do in response to any price choice that Firm A
could make. Suppose that Firm A sets a really high price, above the M C of c.
Firm B’s best response would be to charge a slightly lower price and capture
the entire market. Suppose that Firm A sets a really low price, less than the
M C of c. Firm B’s best response in this case is NOT to undercut Firm A. If it
undercuts Firm A then it captures the entire market, but it captures the entire
market at a price below cost which means it is making a loss, which it could
2 Technically no …rm would choose a price above a (the intercept of the inverse demand
function) as any price above this level implies that the …rm sells 0 units and thus earns 0
pro…ts.
4
avoid by not producing at all, which means that if Firm A chooses a price less
than c that Firm B should choose a price greater than Firm A. We can assume
that if Firm A chooses a price less than c that Firm B will choose to set its price
equal to c to ensure that it does not make any losses. Suppose that Firm A
chooses a price equal to the M C of c. If Firm B chooses a price below c then it
captures the entire market, but at a price less than cost, which means that it is
making a loss. Clearly, Firm B could do better if it decided to stay out of the
market. If Firm B charges a price above c then it will not earn any pro…ts as it
allows Firm A to capture the entire market. If Firm B charges a price exactly
equal to c, then it will still earn zero economic pro…t but at least it will then
produce half of the market quantity. Formalizing this thought process into a
strategy we can write down:
8
< PA " if PA > c
PB = c if PA = c
:
c if PA < c
The term " means the smallest possible amount by which Firm B can un-
dercut Firm A’s price (perhaps a penny). Firm A now knows that Firm B will
use this strategy.3 Firm A then has to decide what it will do. If it prices
below M C it will capture the entire market but will make a loss. If it prices
above M C then Firm B will undercut its price and Firm A will sell nothing. If
Firm A chooses to price at M C then it splits the market quantity with Firm B.
Thus, Firm A chooses to set PA = c, which means that Firm B will set PB = c,
which means that in the sequential Bertrand game the result is the same as in
the simultaneous Bertrand game.4
at the lowest possible increment above M C. If c = 12, and …rms must price in increments
of pennies, then the NE result is that both …rms charge $12.01 and make very, very small
economic pro…ts. This is true of the simultaneous game as well.
5
Notice that this is the same picture as the sequential Bertrand game, only
now the …rms are making quantity choices. Again, begin with …nding Firm B’s
strategy. When we worked the simultaneous Cournot game we found the best
response functions for each …rm. Firm B’s best response function, for a given
choice of qA , was:
a c bqA
qB =
2b
Since this problem has the same basic structure, Firm B’s best response
function is the same as it was in the Cournot game. Thus, for any choice of qA
we know the exact quantity amount that Firm B would choose. There is one
a c
slight caveat to this. If Firm A were to choose an amount of qA b , then
Firm B would choose to produce 0. The reason why is that if Firm A chooses
qA = a b c , then it is choosing to produce the competitive quantity, where the
price in the market equals marginal cost. If Firm A for some reason decides to
produce a quantity qA > a b c , then Firm A is producing a quantity such that
the price in the market is LESS than M C. In this case, Firm B would opt
out of the market and produce 0, as producing 0 ensures Firm B of receiving
0 pro…ts, while producing any positive quantity will only force the price lower
and ensure that Firm B earns a loss. To summarize, Firm B’s strategy is:
a c bqA a c
2b
if 0 qA b
qB = a c
0 if qA > b
Firm A then takes Firm B’s strategy as given. Firm A is like any other
pro…t maximizing …rm, and will set M R = M C. We know what Firm A’s M C
6
is as it is given. We need to …nd Firm A’s M R. Let’s look at the inverse
demand function, P (Q) = a bQ. We know that:
a c bqA
P (qA ) = a b bqA
2b
Simplifying:
a c bqA
P (qA ) = a bqA
2
Simplifying:
a c bqA
P (qA ) = a + + bqA
2 2 2
Combining terms:
a c bqA
P (qA ) = +
2 2 2
Now, we know that this is almost in the form of P (Q) = a bQ, which we
bqA
know has M R = a 2bQ. If we let a+c 2 = A, then P (qA ) = A 2 , which
bqA
means that M R = A 2 2 =A bqA . Thus,
a+c
MR = bqA
2
Now, setting M R = M C we have:
a+c
bqA = c
2
Or:
a+c
c = bqA
2
Or:
a c
= bqA
2
Or:
a c
= qA
2b
Thus, if Firm B uses the strategy that we found, Firm A will produce qA =
a c
2b . So the NE to the Stackelberg game is:
7
a c
qA =
2b
a c bqA a c
2b
if 0 qA b
qB = a c
0 if qA > b
We can …nd the payo¤s to the …rms of using these strategies by plugging
qA = a2bc into Firm B’s best response function to determine how much Firm B
will produce.
a c
a c b 2b
qB =
2b
Or:
a c
a c 2
qB =
2b
Or:
a c
a c 2 + 2
qB =
2b
Or:
a c
2 2
qB =
2b
Or:
a
c
qB =
4b
Thus, if Firm A produces qA = a2bc , Firm B will produce qB = a4bc . Note
that this is NOT the NE strategy for Firm B, just what the result is of Firm B
using its NE strategy. Total market quantity is then qA + qB = a2bc + a4bc =
3 a c 3
4 b , or 4 of the perfectly competitive quantity.
8
As should be clear from the total, consumer’s are made better o¤ at the
expense of the …rms as we move down the table. It is interesting to note that
the Cournot case, with two identical …rms, is slightly less e¢ cient than the
Stackelberg case, with one large …rm and one small …rm (in terms of relative
quantities produced). This raises the question of why antitrust policy may
focus on the industry with one large …rm and one small …rm, rather than the
one with two equal-sized …rms. The reason has to do with the dynamic aspects
of the markets, which we will now discuss in the form of entry prevention by a
monopolist.
9
We can actually solve for the amount of the fee that the government could
charge the …rm. The …rm will pay the fee if the pro…t from paying the fee and
receiving monopoly power is greater than the pro…t from not paying the fee and
receiving the 2-…rm Cournot payo¤, or:
m C
F
Using some earlier results, we know that, for a linear inverse demand function
and constant marginal costs:
2
m (a c)
=
4b
2
C (a c)
=
9b
We can plug those in to …nd:
2 2
(a c) (a c)
F
4b 9b
Or:
2 2
(a
c) (a c)
F
4b 9b
Getting a common denominator:
10
2 2
9 (a c) 4 (a c)
F
36b 36b
Combining terms:
2
5 (a c)
F
36b
m (a c)2
Now, one little trick. We know that = 4b . The term on the
5 (a c)2
left-hand side of the equation is just 9 4b . This means that:
2
5 (a c)
F
9 4b
As long as the fee is less than 95 of the monopoly pro…t the …rm would be
willing to pay the fee. Think about that – the government can essentially re-
ceive 55% of the monopoly pro…t if it grants a …rm the right to be a monopoly
producer. This could be a decent method of generating revenue for the govern-
ment.
1. Monopolist could make a large …xed cost (or sunk cost) investment to
appear to credibly commit to producing a large amount if a potential
competitor decides to enter.
2. Over time, the monopolist could develop a reputation as a …erce competi-
tor when someone threatens his market. This reputation could act as a
credible commitment.
3. In multi-product markets, monopolists may attempt to “…ll in all the
niches”. Consider the market for breakfast cereals. There are healthy
cereals, frosted cereals, fruit-‡avored cereals, chocolate cereals etc. If the
monopolist can …ll in all the niches before his competitors get there, then
he can capture the market.
4. The monopolist, if it has a cost advantage over the potential entrant, can
set a price below the true pro…t-maximizing price in order to keep the
potential entrant out. This will work if the monopolist can charge a price
lower than the entrant’s cost but still above his own cost.
11
In this picture the true pro…t-maximizing price for the monopolist is above
the potential entrant’s MC. Thus, the potential entrant may decide to enter the
industry. However, if the monopolist wishes to deter entry then it could charge
a price slightly below the entrant’s MC. The monopolist will still receive positive
pro…ts since the price is above cost, but the entrant will not enter because the
price is below its cost, preserving the monopoly for the monopolist.
12