Final Print Dissertation by J.chipunza
Final Print Dissertation by J.chipunza
DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS
BY
CHIPUNZA JOHANNES A. T
R147114A
SUPERVISOR- MR R. MANDISHEKWA
May
©2018
SUPEVISOR’S APPROVAL FORM
The undersigned certify that they have supervised Chipunza Johannes‟ dissertation entitled:
The Relationship Between Public External Debt and Private Investment in Zimbabwe
(1980-2016), submitted in partial fulfilment of the requirements for the Bachelor of
Commerce Economics Honours Degree at the Midlands State University.
Supervisor’s Signature
Chapter ONE
Chapter TWO
Chapter THREE
Chapter FOUR
Chapter FIVE
Date:
i
APPROVAL FORM
The undersigned certify that they have supervised, read and recommend to the Midlands state
University for acceptance, a project entitled, “ The relationship between public external debt
and private investment in Zimbabwe (1980-2016)”, submitted by Chipunza Johannes
(R147114A) in partial fulfilment of the requirements of the Bachelor of Commerce
(Honours) Degree in Economics.
(Signature of Student)
(Signature of Supervisor)
ii
DECLARATION FORM
I, Chipunza Johannes Registration number A.T R147114A do hereby declare that this project
is an original copy of my own work and has not been published before or submitted to any
other institution/university.
iii
DISCLAIMER
This dissertation is submitted in partial fulfilment of the Bachelor of Commerce Honours
Degree in Economics at Midlands State University. The ideas in this dissertation represent
solely those of the author. Therefore, the University, Economics Department and the
Supervisor are not liable for errors and mistakes in this dissertation.
iv
DEDICATION
This dissertation is dedicated to my mother, Lynette Hoyi for her unbound and unconditional
support towards my academic journey. You have turned this dream into a reality. I gratefully
thank you for the financial and emotional support. Utmost dedications also go to my lovely
sisters Johanna, Paidamoyo and Tawonashe. I thank you all for the unconditional love and
care. Special dedications also go to my grandfather Jackson Hoyi who has been a
fundamental source of motivation and guidance.
v
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
The achievement of this academic success borders on a series of very gracious and helping
hands. These hands have been the light upon which this beautiful dream has been achieved. I
am extremely grateful to my supervisor, Mr R Mandishekwa, for his patient guidance and
continued assistance and review of this research project. Regards also belong to the
Economics Department for its assistance assisting in this journey of academic growth.
Special thanks also belong to my beloved friends and colleagues Taonga, Achbald, Tafadzwa
and Tariro for your priceless assistance on this research study and the economics degree as a
whole. Special regards also go to my dear friend Varaidzo for the moral support and belief in
my intellect. I greatly thank you.
vi
ABSTRACT
Progressive public indebtedness in Zimbabwe particularly in the form of foreign financing
has culminated into debt distress in the nation. The country has accumulated stocks of unpaid
public foreign debts over the years and as a consequence debt burden began to develop in the
nation. Apparently such accumulation of external debt stocks is posited to lead to debt
overhang and determent of private investment. As such this research study examined the
relationship between public external debt and private investment in Zimbabwe over the
period 1980-2016. The study regressed private investment (PINV) on current external debt
(EXD), past external debt (LAGEXD), public investment (PUBI), household final
consumption expenditure (HFCE), debt servicing (DEBTSERV), trade openness (TO) and
real interest rate (R). The study aimed at addressing whether external debt accumulation
(debt overhang) deters investment and also addressing the crowding out role of external
indebtedness on private investment. The study found a negative relationship between public
external indebtedness and private investment. Both current and past external debt flows were
seen to deter private investment although current debt flows were seen to have insignificant
influence on private investment. However, debt service was found to promote private
investment. The study therefore concluded that the existence of debt overhang as a
consequence of the accumulation of past external debt stocks is discouraging private
investment into the economy. The study recommend on the formulation of policies aimed at
increasing national savings at the same time reducing public sector access to foreign lending
such that private sector confidence in the economy can be promoted. Also, policies that
maintain desirable servicing of the external debts can mitigate the negative effects of debt
accumulation on private investment.
vii
TABLE OF CONTENTS
SUPEVISOR’S APPROVAL FORM .......................................................................................
APPROVAL FORM ................................................................................................................ii
DECLARATION FORM ...................................................................................................... iii
DISCLAIMER......................................................................................................................... iv
DEDICATION.......................................................................................................................... v
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS ................................................................................................... vi
ABSTRACT ............................................................................................................................vii
TABLE OF CONTENTS .................................................................................................... viii
LIST OF ABBRVIATIONS ................................................................................................... xi
LIST OF APPENDICES .......................................................................................................xii
LIST OF FIGURES ............................................................................................................. xiii
LIST OF TABLES ................................................................................................................ xiv
CHAPTER ONE ...................................................................................................................... 1
INTRODUCTION.................................................................................................................... 1
1.0 Introduction ................................................................................................................. 1
1.1 Background of the Study .................................................................................................. 1
1.2 Problem Statement ........................................................................................................... 4
1.3 Objectives of the Study .................................................................................................... 4
1.4 Research Hypothesis ........................................................................................................ 4
1.5 Significance of the Study ................................................................................................. 4
1.6 Limitations of the Study ................................................................................................... 5
1.7 Study Delimitations .......................................................................................................... 5
1.8 Organization of the Rest of the Study .............................................................................. 5
CHAPTER TWO ..................................................................................................................... 6
LITERATURE REVIEW ....................................................................................................... 6
2.0 Introduction ................................................................................................................. 6
2.1 Theoretical Literature Review .......................................................................................... 6
2.2 Empirical Literature Review .......................................................................................... 11
2.3 Conclusion...................................................................................................................... 15
CHAPTER THREE ............................................................................................................... 16
METHODOLOGY ................................................................................................................ 16
3.0 Introduction .................................................................................................................... 16
viii
3.1 Model Specification ....................................................................................................... 16
3.2 Measurement and Justification of Variables .................................................................. 17
3.2.1 Private Investment (PINV) ...................................................................................... 17
3.2.2 External Debt (EXD) ............................................................................................... 17
3.2.3 External Debt Lagged (LAGEXD) .......................................................................... 17
3.2.4 Debt Service (DEBTSERV) .................................................................................... 18
3.2.5 Public Investment (PUBI) ....................................................................................... 18
3.2.6 Household Fixed Consumption Expenditure (HFCE) ............................................. 18
3.2.7 Real Lending Interest Rate (R) ................................................................................ 19
3.2.8 Trade Openness (TO) .............................................................................................. 19
3.3 Data Types and Sources ................................................................................................. 19
3.4 Diagnostics Tests............................................................................................................ 19
3.3.1 Unit Root Test For Stationarity ............................................................................... 19
3.3.2 Cointegration Test ................................................................................................... 20
3.3.3 Multicollinearity Test .............................................................................................. 20
3.3.4 Heteroscedasticity Test ............................................................................................ 21
3.3.5 Autocorrelation Test ................................................................................................ 21
3.3.6 Model Specification Test ....................................................................................... 21
3.3.7 Normality Test ......................................................................................................... 22
3.5 Conclusion...................................................................................................................... 22
CHAPTER FOUR .................................................................................................................. 23
PRESENTATION AND INTERPRETATION OF RESULTS ......................................... 23
4.0 Introduction .................................................................................................................... 23
4.1 Summary Statistics ......................................................................................................... 23
4.2 Diagnostic Tests ............................................................................................................. 24
4.2.1 Unit Root Testing Results........................................................................................ 24
4.2.2 Cointegration Test Results....................................................................................... 25
4.2.3 Multicollinearity Test Results ................................................................................. 25
4.2.4 Heteroscedasticity Test Results ............................................................................... 26
4.2.5 Autocorrelation Test Results ................................................................................... 27
4.2.6 Model Specification Test Results ............................................................................ 27
4.2.7 Normality Test Results ............................................................................................ 27
4.3 Presentation of Regression Results ................................................................................ 28
ix
4.4 Interpretation of Results ................................................................................................. 29
CHAPTER FIVE ................................................................................................................... 32
SUMMARY, CONCLUSIONS AND POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS ....................... 33
5.0 Introduction .................................................................................................................... 33
5.1 Summary of the Study .................................................................................................... 33
5.2 Conclusions .................................................................................................................... 34
5.3 Policy Recommendations ............................................................................................... 34
5.4 Suggestion for future researches .................................................................................... 35
REFERENCE LIST ............................................................................................................... 35
APPENDICES ........................................................................................................................ 41
x
LIST OF ABBRVIATIONS
ADF Augmented Dickey Fuller
BPG Breusch-Pagan-Godfrey
CLRM Classical Linear Regression Model
DW Durbin-Watson
ESAP Economic Structural Adjustment Programme
EVIEWS Econometric View
GDP Gross Domestic Product
GNP Gross National Product
GFCF Gross Fixed Capital Formation
HIPC Highly Indebted Poor Country
IMF International Monetary Fund
LDC Less Developed Country
OLS Ordinary Least Squares
RBZ Reserve Bank of Zimbabwe
WAMZ West African Monetary Zone
ZIMSTAT Zimbabwe National Statistical Agency
xi
LIST OF APPENDICES
xii
LIST OF FIGURES
Figure 1.1: External debt indicators and Private Investment Trends2
xiii
LIST OF TABLES
xiv
CHAPTER ONE
INTRODUCTION
1.0 Introduction
External debt has progressively become a major source of funding for the majority of
developing nations most of whom do not have sufficient funds for capital formation
(Abdullahi et al, 2016). Developing countries require supplementary foreign capital to bridge
the resource gap and stimulate savings in capital formation. External debt in Zimbabwe has
increased heavily owing to inadequate supply of local and foreign currency, high levels of
consumption and low domestic savings (Bayai and Nyangara, 2013). Private Consumption in
Zimbabwe was 76.42% of GDP in 2016 having had averaged at 73.08% of GDP from 1975-
2016 (Global economy data). Gross domestic savings on the other hand stood at -1.818% of
GDP having improved from -10.276% of GDP in 2015 (World Bank, 2017). This has
emphasised the need for increased foreign financing. External debt as a ratio of GDP in
Zimbabwe stood at 60.04% in 2016 having increased from 59.33% in 2015. This growth in
the access of foreign credits has been aided by the high domestic debt burden in the country
making the International community lender of last resort to Zimbabwe. The IMF (2016) has
posited that the effects of external debt burden on the economy‟s private investment are
emanating from debt distress and liquidity constraints related to servicing of the debt burden.
According to Colgan (2001), debt crisis in Sub Saharan Africa worsened in the 1980s as the
ratio of continent‟s external debt to its GNP rose from 51% in 1982 to 100% in 1992.
Consequently, the region‟s debt grew to four times its export receipts in the early 1990s. In
1
1998, debt stock in the region was estimated at $236 billion, whilst that of the whole African
continent was over $300 billion. By 2001, external debt burden in Africa was estimated to be
twice that of any other region in the world carrying 11% of the developing world's debt. This
reflects a situation of high debt distress in developing nations as theyfail to effectively
manage and service their external debt stocks.
The first approach to address the issue of growing debt burden in low income countries was
the inauguration of the Highly Indebted Poor Country (HIPC) initiative in 1996. The
initiative was introduced to assist developing countries with debt management and servicing.
The HIPC initiative aimed at reducing debt overhang and restore sustainability of the debt of
eligible nations. Debt relief was offered through debt restructuring, rescheduling and debt
forgiveness.
Zimbabwe has over the years accumulated an external debt burden through the restructuring
of its debt and access to new financing. Accumulation of arrears as a result of debt
rescheduling has also contributed massively to the prevailing debt crisis due to increasing
interest payments. Debt rescheduling was administered to the nation as it failed to meet its
debt obligations due to falling export revenues aided by the withdrawal of foreign investment,
IMF (2017). The IMF (2016) has acknowledged that Zimbabwe has failed to receive debt
relief under the HIPC initiative as the country does not qualify as a highly indebted poor
nation thereby contributing to the ever-growing external debt stocks. This has promoted the
development of debt distress in the nation as shown by the external debt indicators in the
Figure 1.1;
300.00
200.00
100.00
0.00
Figure 1.1: Trend of External debt indicators and Private Investment in Zimbabwe
from 1980-2016.
2
Figure 1.1 shows an unattractive situation where external debt occupies high percentages of
GDP and export income. External debt as a percentage of exports of goods, services and
income has increased from 45.8% in 1980 to 207.5% in 2015. This growth in the ratio depicts
debt servicing constraints where majority of export receipts are used to clear the foreign
credits. During the 1980s decade, an average of 30% of Zimbabwe‟s exports where spent on
debt repayment causing a lot of resources and foreign currency to flood out of the country,
(Jones, 2011).
External debt is that part of total public debt in a nation representing arrears to foreign
creditors, (Akomolafe et al, 2015). defined as debt the as a percentage of GDP has increased
overally from 9.33% in 1980 to 60.04 in 2016 signalling the development of debt distress in
the nation. Adegbite et al (2008) posited that the higher the ratio of a nation‟s debt stock to its
output (GDP), the greater the debt burden. The increase in debt burden has been attributed by
Saungweme et al, (2016) to poor debt management and poor budgetary control.
Private investment on the other hand has not shown much positive growth. The trend in
private investment reflects a rather fluctuating and unstable pattern over time. Having
achieved independence in 1980, private investment in Zimbabwe increased from 12.31% of
GDP to 15.18% of GDP in 1981 (World Bank 2017). This increase was due to the
introduction of intervention policies by the State which aimed at shaping the growth path for
private investment, (Makuyana, et al, 2014). However, by 1989, private investment had
reduced to 10.76% of GDP (World Bank data). The decline of private investment during the
1980-1990 decade in developing nations has been attributed to the emergence of the debt
crisis in the mid-1980s facilitated by the growth of public expenditures (Iyoha, 1999).
The growth of private investment in the 1990s era was attributed to the adoption of Economic
Structural Adjustment Programme (ESAP) which promoted the privatization of state
enterprises (Makuyana, et al, 2014). However, the negative growth of private investment up
to 2008 has been accredited by Makuyana et al, (2014) to the impacts of the fast track land
reform policy, high inflation, high interest rates and unstable political environment. This has
led to capital flight during this period. The low and weak growth of private investment after
2000 has been attributed by the IMF (2017) to massive liquidity constraints emanating from
high debt service.
3
1.2 Problem Statement
Public indebtedness has been on the increase over the years due to the accumulation of
unpaid foreign debts. This has ultimately led to the development of debt distress in
Zimbabwe as shown by the external debt indicators in Figure 1.1. The external debt
indicators portray an upward trend implying growth of debt burden in the nation. In contrast,
private investment has declined on declined over the years. This divergence between external
debt and private investment poses serious consequences for economic growth as private
investment is regarded as the major driver of economic growth.This therefore warrants a
research on the nature of the relationship between external debt and private investment in
Zimbabwe.
To analyse how external debt and private investment are related by considering the
role of debt overhang and crowding out effects on private sector capital formation.
4
Ijirshar, et al. (2016), to name a few. Very few studies have however explicitly explored the
impacts of external debt on private investment. Some of the studies include the works of
Apere (2014), Akomolafe et al. (2015) and Abdullahi (2016).
Nonetheless, the most alarming factor is that the bulk of these studies have been performed
outside Zimbabwe in countries like Nigeria and Kenya therefore creating an information gap.
This study therefore seeks to address that information gap and offer more literature on debt
distress in Zimbabwe. The study also seeks to address how external debt can be more
efficiently managed in Zimbabwe therefore reducing its pressures on the fiscus. The study
will also provide advice on how to stimulate private investment in the face of increasing
external debt burden.
5
CHAPTER TWO
LITERATURE REVIEW
2.0 Introduction
In this chapter the study outlines the various theoretical and empirical abstractions on the
relationship between external debt and private investment. The theoretical discuss on the
external debt-private investment problem borders from the Two Gap model, Classical view,
Keynesian theory, Debt overhang hypothesis and the Ricardian equivalence. The chapter
further goes on to summarize some of the empirical works on the relationship between public
external debt and private investment.
The basic idea of foreign financing is derived from the Two Gap model which posits that
external finance supplements domestic resources in capital formation. The Two-Gap model
is an extension of the Harrod-Domar model of investment and growth which states that
investment (I) is a direct function of savings (S), such that: . Harrod (1939) and Domar
(1946) advocated that the amount of money invested today is equal to the amount of money
saved today and that the growth rate is dependent upon the savings rate. That is,
(2.1)
Where g is growth rate, s is the savings rate and k is the capital to output ratio.
In equation 2.1 above, high growth rates are achieved through the availability of high
domestic savings. Chenery and Strout (1966) therefore augmented the Harrod-Domar model
to explain the complimentary role of foreign savings (external debt) on domestic savings. The
Two Gap model posits that developing nations face two gaps namely the savings gap and
trade gap (also referred to as foreign exchange gap). The savings gap is the difference
between available savings and desired level of investment whereas the foreign exchange gap
6
is the difference between imports (outflow of foreign currency) and exports (inflow of
foreign currency).
Foreign capital inflows therefore act as a bridge within which insufficient domestic savings
and foreign currency are complemented to allow for higher levels of investment as shown by
equation 2.2 below:
(2.2)
In equation 2.2, foreign capital inflows eliminate the foreign exchange gap by allowing new
investment projects to be implemented, allowing the importation of capital goods and
technical assistance (Forgha et al.2014). Elimination of the savings gap promotes investment
and growth. In this case the growth rate would be determined by both domestic savings and
foreign capital as shown by the equation below;
(2.3)
Where = foreign savings (foreign debt) and and are as explained before.
Thus, from equation 2.3 it can be observed that an increase in foreign debt inflows adds to the
domestic supply of savings which therefore stimulates investment and growth.This is
supported by Akomolafe et al. (2015) who found external debt to promote investment.
Were (2001) also established the existence of a positive relationship between external debt
and private investment, but in the short run through current debt flows. This study therefore
expects to find a positive relationship between current external debt and private investment.
The theory has however been criticized by Forghaet al.(2014) for not taking into
consideration the distribution of the borrowed funds and their subsequent utilization. The
authors argue that distribution of the foreign credit towards unproductive investments like
political campaigns, purchase of luxurious vehicles, houses and serving of wage bill may not
necessarily stimulate investment and growth. These arguments also align with the arguments
put forward by the classical theory.
Classical theorists like Ricardo and Smith seem to be predominantly unfavourable to public
borrowing as they propose a laisez fare market system where economic activity is run by
7
private individuals. They denounce public expenditures as being unproductive and inefficient
as resources are ultimately wasted by the public sector relative to private investors. The
classical theorists blame state indebtedness for diverting resources from the productive
private sector to the non-productive public expenditures like the traditional roles of national
defence, diplomatic ties and public order. The classical school argued that state indebtedness
distorts private sector capital formation thereby negatively affecting the accumulation of
capital and overall economic development.
Smith (1936) for example denied the state‟s right to incur debt arguing that indebtedness
delayed the natural process of wealth creation and prosperity within the nation by diverting
resources away from the private sector towards the financing of public expenditures that do
not bear any hope of future production (Bilan, 2016). Modighiani (1961) also posited that
public debt is an intergenerational burden that leads to progressive depletion of the capital
outlay for the future generation, that is, debt burden is hereditary. This is supported by the
Loanable funds theory which states that a substantial increase in public access to loanable
funds would decrease the amount of funds available to potential private investors. This
therefore implies that increased access to foreign debt would decrease private access to
foreign credit thereby ultimately crowding out private investment.
Ricardo, together with other classical economists like Adam Smith, expressed fears of capital
flight as a result of excessive taxation for debt service, (Churchman, 2001). Ricardo (1960)
made two standing points that is, under no conditions should public expenditures be financed
by public borrowing and that immediate debt redemption was crucial. The classical theory
therefore attribute a negative relationship between public external debt and private
investment. This is supported by Iyoha (1999) who found external debt to depress capital
formation. This has however been argued against by Keynesian theorists who argue that
external indebtedness assists the economy in gaining momentum after experiencing a
recession. They therefore vote for public indebtedness as a tool for stimulating aggregate
consumption and investment in the economy.
The school attaches an optimistic role to public sector deficit financing through government
borrowing as a means for the regulation of economic activity precisely through aggregate
demand. The school gave high prominence to the derivation of demand side policies as a
means of financing economic recovery from a recession (Bilan, 2016). This lies on parallel
ground to the classical connotations on public indebtedness.
8
Some empirical researches by Bayai and Nyangara (2013), and Abdul Rashid have proved
that public investment crowd‟s in private investment. These results are in conjunction with
the Keynesian view of public debt and investment. As such, public indebtedness is viewed as
an indispensable tool for balanced growth in the economy.
Despite advocating for the positive impact of public indebtedness on economic recovery from
a recession or stagnation, some Keynesians worry that persistent public loans into the long
term may ultimately be problematic. According to Filip (2010), Beveridge, in his systematic
deficit theory, admitted that „„getting out of the crisis is based precisely on public loans to
finance an increase in government spending and therefore a budget deficit‟‟, after which the
state budget must be restored to equilibrium. Keynes (1982), in this regard, posited that it is
possible to pursue favourable levels of aggregate demand and employment using budget
deficits for the budget will correct itself and debt will be reduced. Keynesian theory
attributes a positive relationship between public external debt and private investment.
The Keynesian perspective is however viewed by modern day conventionalists like Krugman
(1988) and Elmendorf and Mankiw (1998) to be a short run phenomenon. They argue that in
the long run, the classical connotations are evident.
Modern day economist have developed a new faith in which they hold fast to both the
principles of both the Classical and Keynesian schools of thought. Coventional theorists, as
portrayed by Bilan (2016), separate their propositions in terms of time horizons, that is short
run and long run. This new faith has been conveniently term the “conventional view” because
it combines both the Keynesian support for public indebtedness and the classical disapproval
for public borrowing to stimulate economic activities in the long term (Bilan, 2016).
The conventionalists believe that in the short run, the Keynesian propositions apply but
however continued and unsustained growth of public indebtedness will lead to the eventual
crowding out of private investment, falling growth rates and weakening economic
performance, (Bilan, 2016).
Bilan (2016) attributes this conventional view to the works of Krugman (1988) and
Elmendorf and Mankiw (1998). Although Krugman does offer respect for the Keynesian
view of public expenditures by accepting that modern day economists have to accept that
Keynesian economics remain the best framework for understanding recessions and
depression, he also holds true to the fact that continued public indebtedness will eventually
lead to debt distress and reduction of private capital and weakened economic performance.
9
The threshold relationship between external debt accumulation, and private investment and
growth stems from the debt overhang theory by Krugman (1988). Krugman defined debt
overhang as being a case where the external debt burden is so inherently large that foreign
lenders cannot expect with full confidence to be fully repaid. Krugman (1988) further asserts
that when the expected present value of potential resource transfers, say export earnings is
less than the debt stock, then current debt service will be insufficient to fully cater for the
actual, total debt stock thus creating disincentives for investment.
The theory was developed from the firm level debt overhang theory by Myers in 1977. Myers
was looking at the debt overhang effect on firm level investment. Myers positioned that an
unsustainable debt will force the firm to make promised payments to the creditors which must
be serviced via the transfer of revenue streams. This transfer of cash flows was posited to
ultimately lead to the decline in the firm‟s investment as the firm derails on intended
investment projects. Ochhino (2010) notes that, „„a debt overhang distortion acts like a tax on
the increase in the firm‟s value generated by new investment projects, and this may lead them
to forego investment projects with positive net present values‟‟.
Krugman therefore likened a debtor nation to something like a debtor firm, although he
recognised that the parallel is not exact. Consequently, Krugman stated that the debtor nation
will allocate some portion of its national income towards debt service allowing it to
effectively manage its debt. The debt overhang theory however postulates that the
accumulation of such debt burden will provide disincentives for investment as the debt acts as
a tax on domestic private investors. The returns from local and foreign investors in the
domestic economy are thus transferred (taxed away) to the creditors as debt repayment. This
therefore makes private investment less lucrative thereby reducing the incentives for
investment (Claessens et al., 1996).
The secondary effects of debt overhang on private investment accrue as a result of poor credit
ratings and reduced access to future borrowings. A debt overhang implies growing inability
of the indebted nation to payback its debts which may discourage further lending which will
then ultimately deter investment. Various scholars have established the existence of a non-
linear, threshold relationship between external debt and private investment. These include:
Apere (2014), Adegbite (2008) and Ayadi and Ayadi (2008). Apere (2014) postulated that the
relationship between external and private investment is non-linear, where debt first promotes
investment but however accumulation of external debt will end up discouraging private
10
investment. Thus the expected relationship between external debt and private investment
entails a positive one in the short run (where current debt inflows crowd in investment) and a
negative relationship in the long run where foreign debt accumulation is seen to crowd out
private investment.
The Ricardian equivalence theory however argues against the aforementioned theorists by
positing that the effect of public indebtedness leads to a neutral effect on private investment.
Challenging the Keynesian ideology of public debt, Barro (1974) augmented Ricardo‟s
(1960) views of the negative effects of public indebtedness on capital formation by
promoting neutrality between tax financed and deficit financed government spending.
Specifically, Barro (1974) posited that an increase in government borrowing (or reduction in
taxation) today, will likely result in the accumulation of public debt which will have to be
serviced at some point in the future. This will therefore force the government to increase
future taxes so as to acquire revenue for future debt service.
The equivalence theory therefore attributes that as rational consumers can accurately predict
future tax increases, an increase in government borrowing will lead to a rise in current private
savings equal to the value of future taxes. This is so because instead of consuming or
investing the extra revenue from the tax cut, rational private individuals will simply save for
future tax payments, (Caron, 2007). Thus the positive effect arising from the Keynesian
perspective is cancelled out thereby emphasising the neutrality of public debt.
A research study by Jarjuet al.(2016) investigated the relationship between external debt and
economic growth in the West African Monetary Zone (WAMZ) using panel data analysis for
the period 2000-2014 and concluded that there exist significant debt overhang and crowding
out effects of external debt on economic growth and investment in the region. The study used
both a fixed effects model and a random effects model. External debt stock was found to
negatively affect economic growth in both models thereby proving the existence of a debt
11
overhang. Debt servicing also negatively affected growth in both models entailing the
existence of a crowding out effect which implied that resources were diverted from
productive investments and channelled towards debt servicing thereby reducing growth. This
aligns with Ricardo‟s (1960) tax incidence connotations.
A research study by Apere (2014) also investigated the effects of total public debt on private
investment in Nigeria using a non-linear model where private investment was regressed on
domestic debt, domestic debt squared, external debt, external debt squared, and private
consumption expenditure as a percentage of GDP. The study used time series data for the
period 1980-2012. The relationship was estimated using the instrumental variables technique
and boot strapping technique for the estimation of standard errors for the turning points.
Domestic debt was found to have a linear but positive relationship with private investment.
External debt was found to have a turning point of 124.69%. Apere concluded that „„unless
external debt as a ratio of GDP reaches some threshold value (124.69%) that is large enough
for meaningful investment, the impact of external debt on private investment in Nigeria will
always be negative‟‟. Apere (2014) therefore highlighted the existence of a debt overhang in
Nigeria.
Applying an endogenous growth model in studying the relationship between public external
debt and growth (Casares, 2015) finds a non-linear but U-shaped relationship between debt
and growth in Mexico. The results are consistent with the findings of Cohen (1983) and
Sachs (1986) which are also in line with the debt overhang theory. Casares states that beyond
a certain level, public external debt becomes unsustainable such that increases in the external
12
public debt will lead to a subjective increase on the country‟s risk premium and interest
payments such that domestic savings decline thereby ultimately leading to a reduction of
capital formation. Therefore, Casares like Apere (2014) also established a debt overhang
relationship between external debt, capital accumulation and growth.
A study by Hunte (2003) found out that debt servicing has contributed to the decline of
domestic savings and investment in Sub-Saharan African countries. This was supported by
Easterly (1999) who postulated that the provision of debt relief without sufficient
improvement in the domestic saving culture may be ineffective in eradicating debt distress in
highly indebted countries.
A study by Adegbiteet al. (2008) examined the impact of Nigeria‟s external debt on
economic development. The study implemented both linear and non-linear simultaneous
models for economic growth and private investment. The study used generalized least
squares to estimate both the non-linear growth and private investment models. The non-linear
growth model was found to suffer from serial autocorrelation rendering parameter estimates
inefficient. The non-linear private investment model was found to be fit for data analysis as
shown by the absence of autocorrelation. In the model private investment was regressed on
the traditional debt burden indicators, that is, external debt ratio of GDP and debt service
ratio of exports. External debt squared was found to have a non-linear effect on private
investment thereby proving the existence of a debt overhang. Debt servicing was also found
to crowd out private investment.
13
0.24% in the Asia-Pacific region. On the other hand, debt was found as having an indirect
effect on GNP by lowering private investment. The indirect impact of crowding-out private
investment was observed to be substantially larger than the direct effects.
An empirical study by Iyoha (1999) which modelled the macroeconomic impacts of external
debt on economic growth in Sub-Saharan Africa concluded that there exist significant debt
overhang and crowding-out effects in the region. The study used simultaneous equation
models for output and investment demand. Huge stocks of external debt and high debt
servicing were found to depress capital formation, features of debt overhang burden and
crowding out effects respectively.
Another study by Mjema (1996) also analysed the impacts of foreign debt on economic
growth in Tanzania using simultaneous equation models. The scholar observed that debt
service had a negative impact on growth. Amoating and Amoaku-Adu (1996) observed that if
a greater proportion of export earnings is used to service external debts, then little foreign
currency will be made available for investment. This therefore subscribes to the classical
disregard for public access to foreign debt.
Some studies have failed to estimate a clear relationship between external debt and domestic
investment levels. With some authors like Forgha et al.(2014) finding unclear results. The
direction of external debt in Cameroon was found to be unclear as most of the funds were
presumably spent on manpower training which was hugely undermined by the existence of
high levels of unemployment and brain drain (Forgha et al., 2014).In their study they
recognise that external debt is channelled towards unproductive expenditures. They also
concur that corruption and embezzlement, and capital flight affective greatly the productivity
of the foreign loans.
14
However, some empirical studies have found evidence of the crowding in of private
investment as a result of increased debt service. Bayai and Nyangara (2013) in their study of
the determinants of private investment in Zimbabwe for the period 2009-2011 found a rather
positive relationship between external debt service and private investment. In their original
model of private investment, the study included independent variables like rate of inflation,
interest rate, savings rate, trade terms, GDP, political risk, public investment and debt service.
After using the forward stepwise model fitting technique, savings and inflation rates were
found to have insignificant influences on private investment. Results from the fitted model
produced a positive relationship between external debt service and private investment
whereby a 1% increase in the level of debt servicing, was found to crowd in private
investment by 4.42%.
A variety of increasing research studies have analysed the effect of foreign debt on private
investment by rather addressing its role on capital flight. A growing proportion of these
studies have confirmed the existence of a „„revolving door‟‟ hypothesis where external debt
comes into the country as some form of capital but simultaneously leave in the form of
private capital flight (Ajilore 2005; Chipalkatti and Rishi 2001)
2.3 Conclusion
Theories of public access to foreign financing have offered diverging views on the
relationship between external debt and private investment. As such empirical literature has
consequently produced diverging conclusions on the nature of the relationship between
external debt and private investment. However, despite lack of such unanimous consensus,
most recent empirical studies have subscribed to the Debt Overhang Theory and confirmed
the existence of both a positive and negative relationship, in the short run and long run
respectively. These include Were 2001; Apere 2014; Casares 2015 andAdegbite et al.,
2008,to name a few. Despite the growing external debt burden in Zimbabwe, little has been
researched on its implications on the economy‟s investment levels. The study therefore seeks
to bridge that information gap provide more evidence on the effects of external debt on
investment in the country. The study therefore adapts an empirical model from the reviewed
literature which will ultimately be specified and clearly justified in the succeeding chapter.
15
CHAPTER THREE
METHODOLOGY
3.0 Introduction
This chapter highlights the methodology used in the study. The chapter starts off with the
specification of the empirical model adopted, then goes to justify the inclusion of selected
variables and finally highlights the diagnostics checks done to ensure that the model is fit for
regression analysis.
₀ ₁ ₂ ₃ ₄ ₅ ₆
₇
Where;
β₀ is the intercept term representing autonomous investment, Uᵢ is the stochastic error term
LAGEXD is external debt as percentage of GDP lagged by one period to measure impact of
past debt flows that is, the accumulation of debt stocks (the variable is used as a proxy for
debt overhang)
16
DEBTSERV is debt service measured by interest payments of external debt as percentage of
exports of goods and services capturing the crowding out effects
β1, β2, β3, β4, β5, β6, β7, and β8 are the coefficients of the explanatory variables in the
model.
17
the effect of external debt on private investment by separating its influences using the time
factor. Were (2001) posited that current debt flows (external debt to GDP ratio) stimulate
investment whereas past debt flows (external debt lagged) deter private investment.
The study therefore expects a negative relationship between external debt lagged and private
investment. Such a negative sign would imply the possibility of debt overhang.
A negative sign signals crowding out of private investment whereas a positive sign implies
that public investment drives private investment.
18
of money spent on private consumption reduces savings thereby ultimately reducing private
investment. The study therefore expects the sign to be negative.
19
The ADF test adopts lagged values of the variables in determining the level and order of
integration, (Gujarati, 2004). If the variables are stationary at level they are regarded as being
I(0), but however if the variables are stationary after first difference are regarded as being
I(1), and so on. The hypothesis for unit root is;
If the ADF test statistic exceeds the test critical values, one therefore rejects the null
hypothesis and concludes that the series is probably stationary.
If the t-statistic is greater than the t-critical value, one does not reject the null hypothesis and
conclude that cointegration does exist within the model.
20
The null hypothesis of the test is rejected if the pairwise correlation is in excess of 0.8.
At the 5% level of significance one does not reject the null hypothesis of no heteroscedastic
error terms if the p value of the BPG test statistic is in excess of 0.05. Otherwise the error
terms would be heteroscedastic.
At the 5% level of significance, one does not reject the null hypothesis of no autocorrelation
if the p value is greater than 0.05. Otherwise one would conclude that the model probably
suffers from the existence of autocorrelation.
21
and etc. The study adopted the Ramsey proposed RESET test in checking for model
specification errors. The RESET test involves the following hypothesis;
Using the significance level of 5% one does not reject the null hypothesis if the probability
value of the RESET test statistic is in excess of 0.05. Otherwise the model would be
incorrectly specified.
We do not reject the null hypothesis of normal distribution if the Probability value of the
Jarque-Bera statistic is greater than 0.05.
3.5 Conclusion
This chapter involved a description of the methodology to be used by the researcher in
identifying the nature of the relationship between public external debt and private investment
in Zimbabwe. This involved first giving an outline of the model to be used in regression
analysis in the following chapters and then giving a justification of the adopted variables. The
chapter also highlighted the diagnostic tests to be carried out during econometric estimation
and finalized by giving a preview of the types of data used and its subsequent sources. This
chapter therefore formed the basis within which estimation, presentation, analysis and
interpretation of data is going to be carried out in the following chapter.
22
CHAPTER FOUR
All variables in the model are continuous. The dependent variable, private investment (PINV)
has a mean of 11.5746 and a median value of 12.9. Its minimum value is 0.21 with a
maximum of 21.88, associated with a standard deviation of 6.19541. External debt on the
other hand has a mean of 36.63 and a median value of 30.91, with a minimum value of 5.37
and maximum value of 70.65. The maximum value of 70.65 implies high external debt
burden on the economy‟s GDP. Past debt (LAGEXD) also has a high mean of 34.9519 and
minimum and maximum values similar to those of current external debt flows (EXD). Public
investment has a slightly lower mean of 10.1568 with a maximum of and a minimum of -2.1.
The mean amount of debt service was 23.3848 with a maximum of 40.56 and a minimum of
4.7. Household consumption is high with a maximum final consumption of 119.41 and
23
minimum consumption of 25.31 with a standard deviation of 20.1423. Interest rate has the
highest standard entailed by a maximum lending rate of 572.94 and a minimum of 4.26.
24
The stationarity tests in Table 4.1 reveal that all given variables except PUBI and
DEBTSERV are stationary after first difference. All the variables were stationary at all levels
of significance with the exception of PUBI which was stationary at 5% and 10% levels of
significance evidenced by the presence of two asterisks. Since the model consists of non-
stationary variables we must check for cointegration to prevent spurious regression.
The Johansen cointegration trace test predicts 3 cointegration equations at the 5% level of
significance since the trace statistic exceeds the test critical values at the none, at most 1 and
at most 2 cointegrated equations. The study therefore that a long run relationship does exist
within the model. Ordinary least Squares regression method can therefore be applied.
25
Table 4.4: Correlation Matrix Results
EXD 1
LAGEXD 0.6328 1
The results from the pairwise correlation matrix signify the existence of moderate to weak
multicollinearity between the exogenous variables. The pairwise correlation between all
variables lies below 0.8 and as such the researcher adopts the do nothing approach as
prescribed by Gujarati (2004).
The Breusch-Pagan-Godfrey test provided satisfactory results as depicted in Table 4.4. Since
the probability that the model is heteroscedastic is greater than 0.05 the study therefore
accepts the null hypothesis and concludes that the model does not suffer from
heteroscedasticity.
26
4.2.5 Autocorrelation Test Results
The Breusch-Godfrey Serial Correlation LM test was adopted in testing for autocorrelation
between disturbance terms. The results of the test are summarized in table 4.5 below
Since the probability value of the test exceeds 0.05, the study does not reject the null
hypothesis and concludes that there‟s no serial autocorrelation within the model.
The probability value (0.0669) of the RESET test is higher than 0.05 implying that the study
must not reject the null hypothesis and conclude that the model is probably correctly
specified. Also, the DW statistic of 1.893 is greater than the R² value of 0.805 therefore
implying that the model is free from spurious regression.
27
Table 4.8: Jarque-Bera Normality Test Results
The Jarque-Bera statistic of 2.464 has a probability value of 0.29 which is higher than 0.05
thereby implying that the disturbance term is normally distributed. The disturbance term has a
maximum kurtosis of 2.727 which is below 3 and is therefore acceptable. Rose et al (2015)
posits that the maximum acceptable range of peakedness is 3. It is therefore safe to conclude
that the disturbance term is normally distributed.
R² 0.778798
Adjusted R² 0.723497
F-statistic 14.08298
Prob (F-statistic) 0.000000
DW 1.848305
28
The estimated equation in table 4.8 above can therefore be summarized by equation 4.1 as;
4.1
In equation 4.1 PINV represents private investment, EXD is external debt, LAGEXD is
external debt lagged by one period (representing the accumulation of external debt), PUBI is
public investment, DEBTSERV is debt servicing, HFCE is household final consumption
expenditure, TO is trade openness and R is real interest rate.
Current debt flows were found to have an insignificant crowding out effect on private
investment as evidenced by a p-value of 0.0589 which is greater than 0.05. This insignificant
impact may imply that it takes time for external debt to significantly affect private
investment.
External debt lagged was found to have the expected negative sign where a 1% increase in
external debt accumulation would decrease private investment in Zimbabwe by 0.125%. This
effect is statistically significant as evidenced by a p-value of 0.0023 which is below 0.05.This
therefore implies that the accumulation of unpaid foreign debts discourages investment by
restricting private access to foreign credit as foreign lenders become reluctant to release
29
further lending to private investors. For example, Zimbabwe cleared off its arrears owed to
the IMF administered Poverty reduction and Growth Trust (PRGT) funds in 2016 after a
decade long of interest accumulation, (IMF, 2017). Zimbabwe was consequently expelled
from the PRGT initiative thus restricted from accessing the poverty and growth funds. Thus,
simply put, accumulation of external debt stocks reduces private sector access to foreign
finance thereby ultimately reducing private investment as shown by the negative coefficient
of -0.125 in table 4.9. This therefore establishes the existence of a debt overhang in
Zimbabwe. This is supported by Were (2001) who also found past external debt to deter
investment in Kenya.
Prior to the estimation of the model, the study expected a negative relationship between debt
servicing and private investment where debt servicing was expected to crowd out private
investment. Regression analysis however produced a rather positive relationship where debt
servicing was found to have a positive coefficient of 0.1769 which was statistically
significant at 5% with a p-value of 0.0447. This therefore implies that when Zimbabwe
manages to service-off old debts it can be able to access new financing cheaply from both old
and new sources. The IMF (2017) does hold true to the fact that the ability of Zimbabwe to
clear-off old arrears to the international community would promote and fast track its re-
engagement process with international lenders. The IMF (2017) does take note that
Zimbabwe is pressing ahead with its reengagement efforts with international finance
institutions like the World Bank Group, IMF and AfDB thereby explaining the positive
relationship between debt servicing and private investment in the economy. These findings
are supported by Bayai and Nyangara (2013) who also found debt service to crowd-in private
investment in Zimbabwe by 4.42%. They conclude that debt servicing provided positive
incentives to foreign investors and lenders who had previously shunned way from investing
in Zimbabwe.
Public investment was seen to crowd out private investment from the regression results in
Table 4.9 although the effect was insignificance as evidenced by the p-value of 0.6941 which
exceeds the 5% level of significance. Also the t-statistic is less than two thereby further
emphasising the insignificance of the variable.
30
4.4.5 Household Final Consumption Expenditure (HFCE)
Household final consumption expenditure had an unexpected positive sign implying that
private consumption would promote private investment in Zimbabwe. From the regression
model a percentage increase in private consumption would stimulate investment by 0.134%.
This positive but unexpected effect was statistically significantwith probability value of
0.0068. This would imply that an increase in household consumption would encourage
investors to engage in more planned and unplanned investments. Although this is supported
by the demand side Keynesian economics which posit that increase in consumption would
have multiplier effect on economic growth by stimulating investment. Nonetheless, such high
consumption has promoted foreign financing to compensate for the inadequate savings as a
result of excessive consumption.
Openness to trade was found to have a positive and expected sign implying that trade
openness encourages private investment into the economy. From the regression model, a
percentage increase in trade openness would drive investment by 0.11. These findings are in
line with the findings of Kamundia et al (2015). Openness to trade promotes the free flow of
imports and exports which encourage private investment especially exports are doing well.
Free flow of raw material imports promote investment.
The findings of real interest rate also referred to as real lending rate does conform to theory
and satisfies the expected negative sign. According to the Keynesian theory of investment,
high interest rates discourage investment. As such the model founds out that a unit increase in
the real interest rate would cause investment to decline by 0.023% approximately. Bayai and
Nyangara (2013) also found increases in the real lending rate to discourage private
investment.
4.5 Conclusion
The estimated model found external debt both in terms of current debt flows and past debt
flows to negatively affect investment in Zimbabwe although current debt inflows had an
insignificant impact evidenced by its p-value of 0.0589. The accumulation of unpaid external
public loans was seen to deter private investment by 0.125% as expected in Chapter 3.
However, debt servicing was found to unexpectedly crowd-in private investment. This was
31
however attributed to the reengagement efforts by the Zimbabwean government where debt
servicing is aimed at restoring the credibility status of Zimbabwe would open old and new
financing alternatives to finance also private investment. The following chapter summarises
the study at the same time offering policy recommendations basing on the findings.
32
CHAPTER FIVE
33
5.2 Conclusions
The concept of public indebtedness has gradually become a major topic of discussion in
heavily indebted and distressed nations with a growing number of researchers trying to
address its effects on domestic investment. This study in trying to estimate the nature of the
relationship between external debt and private investment in Zimbabwe observed that current
debt flows insignificantly affect private investment whilst the accumulation of past debt
stocks leads to debt overhang which ultimately discourages private investment. This
ultimately converges to that public external debt is an evil to private sector capital formation.
The crowding-in role of debt servicing on private leads the researcher to not reject the null
hypothesis that debt servicing does not crowd out private investment.
5.3 Policy Recommendations
The results of this study indicated that external debt does affect private investment
significantly through past debt flows, a feature regarded as debt overhang. Clearly put, the
inability of Zimbabwe to clear off its external debt obligations has consequently led to the
development of a debt overhang which has therefore negatively affected the growth of private
investment in the nation. This has therefore ultimately constrained the achievement of high
growth rates in the country. This converges to the fact that Zimbabwe must develop sound
debt utilization and management frameworks where debt is channelled towards productive
investments where the returns on the foreign debt are enough to pay-off the debt and prevent
further accumulation of unpaid foreign debts.
Zimbabwe has historically borrowed foreign funds for servicing of the high wage bill which
is also argued to be inflated by the presence of ghost workers. This unproductive and
inefficient utilization of these debts has also attributed to the accumulation of external debt
stocks. Thus such debt utilization and management frameworks are essential if private
investment is to be stimulated in the face of high debt distress. This will also reduce further
accumulation of external debt stocks.
Zimbabwe has also suffered poor growth of private investment in the face of the high debt
burden because of the lack of adequate privatization of industries. Privatization of say the
railway industry together with other sectors and government parastatals will definitely
promote private investment at the same time reducing public sector demand for foreign
34
credit. This will reduce the debt overhang effects on private investment and if very successful
the country can even exit the debt overhang.
Considering that debt servicing was actually found to encourage private investment it
therefore implies that if Zimbabwe manages to consistently service its debt, private
investment will be crowded in. This therefore warrants the need for a quarterly debt servicing
management framework where the RBZ undertakes a monthly analysis of debt servicing to
ensure that debt service payments lie in the desirable range of the creditors. The IMF (2017),
for example notes that the clearance of its PRGT loans by Zimbabwe will re-establish the
nation as a benefactor of the scheme. Thus debt servicing will reengage Zimbabwe with
International Financial Institutions. This will open new doors for further access to
international credit. This will also boost both local and foreign investor confidence in the
Zimbabwean economy.
The researcher also feels that the work done has not been too exhaustive in unveiling the
nature and relationship between external debt and private investment mainly due to limited
access to data. Other researches can also analyse the role of external debt on capital flight in
Zimbabwe.
35
REFERENCE LIST
Abdullahi, M.M, Abu Bakar, N, and Hassan, S.B.(2016), „Debt Overhang versus Crowding
Out Effects: Understanding the Impact of External Debts on Capital Formation on Capital
Formation in Theory‟,International Journal of Economics and Financial issues, 6(1), pp.
271-278
Adegbite, S.O, Ayadi, S.F and Ayadi, O.F (2008), „The impact of Nigeria‟s external debt on
economic development‟, International Journal of Emerging Markets, 3(3), pp. 285-301
Ajilore, O.T, (2005) „External Debt and Capital Flight in Nigeria: Is There A Revolving
Door?‟, South Africa Journal of Economics and Management Sciences, 8(2), pp. 211-223
Akomolafe, J.K, Bosede, O, and Achukwu, M.(2015), „Public Debt and Private Investment in
Nigeria‟,American Journal of Economics, 5(5), pp. 501-507
Amoating, K, and Amoaku-Adu, B. (1996), „Economic Growth, Export and External Debt
causality: The Case of African Countries‟Applied Economics, pp. 28, 21-27
Apere, O.T. (2014), „The Impact of Public Debt on Private Investment in Nigeria: Evidence
from a Non-linear Model‟, International Journal of Research in Social Sciences, 4(2), pp.
130-138
Bayai, I. and Nyangara, D. (2013), „An analysis of the determinants of private investment in
Zimbabwe for the period 2009 – 2011‟, International Journal of Economics and Management
Sciences, 2(6), pp. 11-42
Barfour. O. (1995), „Ghana: The Burden of Debt Service Payment Under Structural
Adjustment‟,African Economic Research Consortium Research Papers,8, English press
Limited, Kenya.
36
Barro, R.J, (1974) „Are Government Bonds Net Wealth?‟Journal of political Economy, 82(6),
pp. 1095-1117
Bilan, I. (2016) „Overview of the main theories of the Economic Effects of Public
Indebtedness‟, EIRP Proceedings, 11
Bulow, J. and Rogoff, K. (1990), „Cleaning up Third World Debt Without Getting Taken to
the Cleaners‟,The Journal of Economic Perspective, 4(1), pp. 31-42
Casares, R. E.(2015) „A Relationship between External Public Debt and Economic Growth‟,
Economic Studies, 30(2), pp. 219-243
Chibber, A and Lecchor, C, (1993) „From Adjustment to Growth in Sub-Saharan Africa: the
Lessons of East Asia applied to Ghana‟, Journal of Economics, 4, pp. 54
Chowdhury, K (1994), „A Structural Analysis of External Debt and Economic Growth: Some
Evidence from Selected Countries in Asia and Pacific‟,Applied Economics, 26(12), pp. 1121-
1131
Claessens, S.E, Detragiache, R.K and Wickham, P (1996), „Analytical aspects of the debt
Problems of Heavily Indebted Poor Countries
Claessens, S. E and Diwan, I. (1990), „Investment incentives: New Money, Debt Relief, and
the Critical Role of Conditionality in Debt Crisis‟,The World Bank Economic Review, 4(1).
Cohen, D (1993) „Low Investment and Large LDC Debt in the 1980s‟, American Economic
Review, 83(3), 437-449
37
Cohen, D. and Sachs, J. (1986), „Growth and External Debt under risk of debt repudiation‟,
European Economic Review, 30(3), pp. 529-560
Domar, E.L, (1946) „Capital Expansion, Rate of Growth and Employment‟, Econometrica,
14, pp. 137-147
Easterly, W (1999) „The Ghost of Financing Gap: Testing the Growth Model used in
International Financial Institutions, 60(2), pp. 423-438
Erhiyvowe, E. K, and Onomoakpoma, O.D (2013), „External Debt and its Impacts on
Growth: An Assessment of Major Macroeconomic Variables in Nigeria‟, 2(2), pp. 143-153
Forgha, G.H, Mbella, E.M and Ngangnchi, F.H (2014), “External Debt, Domestic Investment
and Economic Growth in Cameroon; A system Estimation Approach”,Journal of Economics
Bibliography, 1(1)
Hunte. C.K (2003), „Saving Behavior and External Debt-Service: Evidence from Sub-
Saharan Africa‟, Africa Review of Money Finance and Banking, pp. 63-74
Ijirshar, U.V, Joseph, F and Godoo, M (2016), „The relationship between External Debt and
Economic Growth in Nigeria‟,International Journal of Economics and Management
Sciences, 6(1), pp. 1-5
International Monetary Fund (IMF) (2011) „Joint IMF/World Bank Debt Sustainability
Article IV Report: Zimbabwe‟.
IMF (2016), „Staff Report for the 2016 Article 4 Consultation & Third Review of the Staff-
Monitored Program-Debt Sustainability Analysis; Zimbabwe‟.
International Monetary Fund (2017) „Staff Report for the 2017 Article 4 Consultation – Debt
Sustainability: Zimbabwe‟
38
Iyoha, M. A. (1999), „External Debt and Economic Growth in Sub-Saharan African
countries: An Econometric study‟,African Economic Research Consortium Research Papers
No 90, English press Limited, Kenya
Jayaraman T.K and Evan L. (2008) „Does external debt lead to economic growth in Pacific
Island countries‟, Journal of Policy Modeling, 31, pp. 272–288
Jarju, I., Nyarko, E., Kormay, A., Haffner, O and Olukayode, S. O. (2016), “The relationship
between External Debt and Economic Growth in the West African Monetary Zone: A Panel
Data Analysis”, WAMI Occassional Paper Series no 12
Jones, T. (2011), „Uncovering Zimbabwe‟s debt: The case for a democratic solution to the
unjust debt burden‟,Jubilee debt campaign: London
Keynes, J.M (1982), „Activities 1931-1939, World Crises and Policies in Britain and Arenca
in. The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, 21: London: MacMillan
Mjema, G. D. (1996), „The Impact of Foreign Debt Servicing in the Economy of Tanzania: A
Simultaneous equation approach‟,African Journal of Economic Policy, 3(1).
39
Ricardo, D (2005), On the principles of the Political Economy and Taxation, in The work and
correspondence of David Ricardo, (Ed Straffa, P and Dobb M.H) vol 1, Indianapolis: Liberty
Fund
Smith, A. (1936), „An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations‟, 5th
Edition. London: Methuen & Co. Ltd
Ukpe, U.H., Umeh, J. C.,and Asogwa, B.C. (2017), „Effects of Public External Debt and
Private Investment on Agricultural Growth in Nigeria: 1980 - 2016‟,Agricultural Research
and Technology Open Access Journal, 10(2)
Were, M (2001), „The Impact of External Debt on Economic Growth in Kenya‟, Dicussion
Paper No. 2001/2016
40
APPENDICES
Appendix 1: Data Set
41
Appendix 2A: Stationary Tests
t-Statistic Prob.*
t-Statistic Prob.*
42
Sample (adjusted): 1982 2016
Included observations: 35 after adjustments
t-Statistic Prob.*
t-Statistic Prob.*
43
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic -8.826574 0.0000
Test critical values: 1% level -2.634731
5% level -1.951000
10% level -1.610907
t-Statistic Prob.*
44
PUBI UNIT ROOT TEST RESULTS
t-Statistic Prob.*
t-Statistic Prob.*
45
Included observations: 35 after adjustments
t-Statistic Prob.*
46
Appendix 2B: Cointegration Test Results
Test Equation:
Dependent Variable: RESID^2
Method: Least Squares
Date: 04/25/18 Time: 18:14
Sample: 1981 2016
47
Included observations: 36
Test Equation:
Dependent Variable: RESID
Method: Least Squares
Date: 04/18/18 Time: 23:37
Sample: 1981 2016
Included observations: 36
Presample missing value lagged residuals set to zero.
48
Appendix 2F: Model Specification Test
Value df Probability
t-statistic 1.909549 27 0.0669
F-statistic 3.646378 (1, 27) 0.0669
Likelihood ratio 4.560394 1 0.0327
F-test summary:
Mean
Sum of Sq. df Squares
Test SSR 36.26838 1 36.26838
Restricted SSR 304.8215 28 10.88648
Unrestricted SSR 268.5531 27 9.946413
Unrestricted SSR 268.5531 27 9.946413
LR test summary:
Value df
Restricted LogL -89.53352 28
Unrestricted LogL -87.25333 27
49
Appendix 2G: Normality Test Results
50
Appendix 4: Summary Statistics
51