wp04 Nipfp 006
wp04 Nipfp 006
Introduction
∗
The authors are respectively, Director, National Institute of Public Finance and Policy, New
Delhi, 110067; India and Professor of Economics, University of California, Santa Cruz. CA
95064. U.S.A.
The author is grateful to Amaresh Bagchi and Richard Bird for extremely useful discussions
and detailed comments on the earlier draft of the paper. The usual disclaimers apply.
3
viewed in both vertical (between centre1 and states) and horizontal
(among the states) senses. If federations are seen as ‘indestructible
union of indestructible states’, and centre and states are seen to exist on
the basis of equality; neither has the power to make inroads into the
defined authority and functions of the other unilaterally. However, such
‘purists’ view of federalism is rarely, if at all, seen in practice. Even
when the constitution guarantees near equal powers to the states, in the
working on federal systems centre dominates in political, administrative,
as well as fiscal spheres. There is considerable volume of literature on
central domination in Indian federalism in the assignment system in the
constitution and central intrusion into the states’domains in the working
of the federation.2 Unlike the classical federations like the USA, Indian
federation is not an ‘indestructible union of indestructible states’. Only
the union is indestructible and the states are not. Article 3 of the
Constitution vests the Parliament with powers to constitute new states by
separating territories from the existing ones, alter their boundaries, and
change their names. The only requirement for this is that the `Bill’for
the purpose will have to be placed in the Parliament on the
recommendation of the President and after it has been referred to the
relevant state legislature for ascertaining their views (their approval is
not necessary). The federation is not founded on the principle of
equality between the union and states either. The central government in
India has the powers, and it actually does invade the legislative and
executive domains of the states (Chanda, 1965; Rao and Sen, 1996;
Rao and Singh, 2000). However, the nature and basis of relationship
between the centre and states is not the objective of this paper.
1
The words “centre”, “union”, and “federal”are used interchangeably in this paper.
2
For a survey of literature on centripetal bias in Indian constitution and in the functioning of
Indian federalism see, Rao and Chelliah, (1997).
4
the basic fabric of equality and fair treatment of jurisdictions. This would
also require transparency in the arrangements.
5
According to Riker (1975), federalism is an outcome of rational
bargain among various constituents. The bargain may be for political or
economic gains. In the political bargain, the constituents give up
political autonomy for security from external threat. The economic
bargain is to enable a common market and to ensure optimal provision
of public services by reaping economies of scale and catering to diverse
preferences. However while striking the bargain, the constituents try to
preserve their valued identity and seek special status. Motivation for
special status may be purely for expanding economic opportunities and
securing freedom from exploitation by larger and more powerful
members of the federation. The objective may be purely political — of
enhancing freedom and representation to constituents or to maximize
political power and influence. It may also be cultural or religious — of
preserving group identities. It may simply be a means of
accommodating diverse group interests within a unified framework.
6
federation. De facto asymmetry can also be desirable and can
contribute to nation building if it is based on transparent principles. At
the same time special arrangements instituted to meet short term
political expediency or administrative discretion can cause secular
degradation of intergovernmental institutions. Such arrangements can
result in arbitrary conferring of special favours and in the long run can
contribute to greater disharmony and instability in a federation.
7
central government to hold together the diverse economic, linguistic,
and cultural entities and to avoid fissiparous tendencies. Centralisation
was also found desirable to unify the country, comprising regions directly
ruled by the British and 216 princely states and territories.3
3
For a detailed account of the history leading to Indian independence, see, Chanda (1965).
8
federation as a political bargain, with the difference that the successors
of the British in India, the Indian National Congress, were in an
extremely strong bargaining position, even relative to the coalition of the
princes. This was illustrated in the case of the exceptions to voluntary
accession, such as Hyderabad, where military force (the authority over
which was also inherited from the British) ensured integration into the
new union.
4
A good discussion on the asymmetric arrangements in Jammu and Kashmir and north-
eastern states can be found in Arora (1995)
9
union under very special terms, which were subsequently incorporated in
the famous Article 370 of the Constitution. This article provided the
state with a unique position in the Indian union, with its own constitution,
a title interpreted as the equivalent of Prime Minister for its chief
executive, and a special assignment of functional responsibilities.
Specifically, the jurisdiction of the centre was restricted to foreign affairs,
defense and communications, with the state’s legislature having
residuary powers. This was a striking contrast to the situation of other
states, where the centre’s assignment of responsibilities was much more
extensive, and where the centre retained residuary powers.
5
At independence, of course, this entire region except North Eastern Frontier Area (NEFA)
was administratively part of Assam province, and the union territories themselves were created
by separation from Assam. Meghalaya was directly carved out of Assam state, while Sikkim
was formerly an Indian protectorate. See, for example, Brass (1994) for a chronology.
10
and social practices, restrictions on the ownership and transfer of land,
and restrictions on the migration of non-residents to the state. State
legislatures are typically given final control over changes in these
provisions.
6
Union Territories are governed directly by the Central government. However, two Union
Territories namely, Delhi and Pondicherry have their own elected governments and legislatures.
11
The wide differences in the economic characteristics between
the states in Indian federation are highlighted in Table 1. It is seen that
in terms of area the biggest state, Rajasthan is 90 times bigger than the
smallest state, Goa. Similarly, in terms of population size, Uttar
Pradesh, the state with largest population is 308 times bigger than the
smallest state, Sikkim. The density of population varies from 13 in
Arunachal Pradesh to 901 in West Bengal. Maharashtra, the state with
the highest Net State Domestic Product (NSDP) had 284 times that of
the state with the lowest NSDP, i.e., Sikkim. There are significant
variations in per capita incomes as well. In 2000-01, Goa, a small state
in the western coast had the per capita NSDP of Rs. 44613, which was
almost 9 times that of Bihar with Rs. 4813.
7
The states with per capita NSDP more than 15% of the average are classified as High
income states and those with less than 10% of the average are classified as low income states.
12
the most populous state (Uttar Pradesh) had 123 times the population of
Goa, the least populous state and the income differences between the
highest and lowest income state was 36 times.
13
Table 1 : Some Characteristics of States in Indian Federalism
Area Population Density NSDP Per Percent Percent Percent
(Sq. Km) (in ‘000) of Pop 1999-00 capita age of age of age of
Rs. million NSDP total total total
(1999- area populati NSDP
00) on
Rajasthan 342000 56473 165.1 710200 13046 10.40 5.50 5.02
Uttaranchal 53500 8480 158.5 Na Na 1.60 0.83 0.00
Uttar Pradesh 241000 166053 689.0 1493520 9323 7.33 16.17 10.56
General 2736100 955380 349.2 12955990 14605 81.89 93.02 91.59
Category
States
Special 594000 63662 107.2 63930 10695 17.78 6.20 4.52
Category
States
Arunachal 84000 1091 13.0 14270 13352 2.56 0.11 0.10
Pradesh
Assam 78000 26638 341.5 2533300 9720 2.37 2.59 1.79
Himachal 56000 6077 108.5 106570 17786 1.70 0.59 0.75
Pradesh
Jammu & 222000 10070 45.4 121820 12373 6.75 0.98 0.86
Kashmir
Manipur 22000 2389 108.6 28580 12721 0.67 0.23 0.20
Cont’d..
14
significant variations in the unit cost of providing public services varying
expenditure needs and places a heavy burden of equalisation on the
intergovernmental transfer system.
15
Table 2: Revenues and Expenditures of the States – 2000-01 (RE)
States Per Poverty Per Own Per Per capita Per cent
capita ratio capita revenue as capita current of own
SDP (percent) own percentage trans- spending revenue
(rupees) 1999-00 revenue of SDP fers (rupees) to current
(rupees) spending
16
India
2. CSO, Ministry of Planning, Government of India
17
development planning gaining focus, the Planning Commission gained
importance as a dispenser of both grants and loans. Thus, the scope of
the Finance Commissions has been confined to examining the non-plan
requirements of the states and providing transfers to meet these
requirements, and the Planning Commission has been assigned to deal
with the plan requirements. Initially, the volume of central assistance for
state plans as well as its grant-loan composition was determined on the
basis of the approved plan projects in different states. Since 1969,
however, the allocation is determined on the basis of a formula
determined by the National Development Council (NDC).8 However,
over the years, with increased earmarking of central assistance for
specific schemes, formula based component of central assistance for
state plans has been reduced and in 2002-03, it is estimated at just
about 46 percent. In addition, the central ministries exercised discretion
in transfers by increasing them under the central sector and centrally
sponsored schemes. Thus, as shown in Table 3, the Finance
Commissions transfer about two thirds of the transfers and this has
remained broadly constant since the early 1970s. However, transfers
given for both plan schemes and specific purpose transfers for central
sector and centrally sponsored schemes have increased over time.
What is more important, increasing proportion of assistance for state
plan schemes has been kept outside the formula based distribution
scheme and the proportion of normal assistance distributed according to
the formula is just about 46 percent of the total state loan assistance in
2002-03. Thus, on the whole discretionary element in the transfer
system has shown a steady increase over the years. These are
discussed in greater detail below.
8
NDC is an intergovernmental body presided over by the prime minister of the country and has
cabinet ministers, members of the Planning Commission and chief ministers of states as
members.
18
between non-plan expenditures and revenues with grants in aid. This is
called the “gap-filling”approach.
19
central taxes should be transferred to the states. The relative shares are
determined on the basis of general economic variables with weights
assigned, as shown in Table 4. It is in the process of choosing the
variables and assigning weights for them that relative shares of the
states may be influenced. This, however, need not necessarily be a
source of unacceptable asymmetry as the formula used by the
Commission is transparent.9
9
There was, however, considerable controversy on the use of the variable ‘poverty ratio’in tax
devolution formula in the first report of the Ninth Finance Commission. See, Bagchi (1988).
20
state not making enough effort to alleviate poverty. More important
criticism was the discretionary transfer made by the Ninth Finance
Commission for the slum clearance in Bombay (Mumbai) and Calcutta
(Kolkata) (Bagchi, 1988; Guhan, 1989). The Tenth Finance Commission
was similarly criticised for making transfers for one state (Andhra
Pradesh) as a compensation for the loss of revenue by following the
prohibition policy.10
10
Prohibition policy refers to the policy of prohibiting the consumption of sale of alcoholic
products within the state. One state, Gujarat has consistently followed this policy right from
independence and some states like Tamil Nadu and Andhra Pradesh have followed this policy
from time to time for electoral reasons.
11
One of the members of the Commission, however, wrote a note of dissent stating that the
recommended design is inappropriate.
21
A number of shortcomings in the above scheme have been
pointed out. The amount earmarked for giving grants under MTFRP
constitutes less than 2 percent of the transfers recommended by the
Finance Commission. Along with other incentive based transfer
schemes, this has contributed to further segmentation in the transfer
system. More important criticism from the viewpoint of asymmetry is
that in the case of special category states over 80 percent of their
revenues accrue from central transfers. Inability to reduce the deficit
may be due to reduction in central transfers and this will be seen as the
state’s poor performance!
22
states may to some extent be acting as agents of the centre in the
provision of national public good of strategic stability and defence. A
part of the reason for higher transfers to these states may be because,
as they are located in international borders, the centre has not allowed
foreign investments to flow into these regions and therefore has the
responsibility of strengthening the regions to have domestic
investments.
23
Indian union, and keeps them there. This kind of reasoning is
particularly clear for such formal, separate induction into the union as
Sikkim, and for the case of Kashmir, but it also applies to cases such as
Nagaland, where a long insurgency after Indian independence was
finally brought under some control through the granting of statehood with
special provisions, and where an implicit political bargain may require
continuing transfers beyond the average.12
12
One other possible reason also involves strategic motives. For strategic reasons, the central
government may wish to restrict private investment, particularly, but not restricted to foreign
investment into these regions. Thus public spending may be a compensation for this
restriction. To some extent, this is also a consequence of features of the political bargain that
restrict non-residents of the state from certain kinds of ownership of property in the state, thus
acting as a restriction on investment.
24
are eventually routed through the central government. This has enabled
some states to seek substantial loans from multilateral donors whereas
others have not been able to access the assistance. Naturally, the
questions of propriety and partisanship in the selection of states have
come up. The states ruled by regional parties with pivotal support to
coalition government at the centre may find it easier to access the
facility than the states ruled by main opposition parties. In a situation in
which most of the states are ruled by the main opposition party, the
central government seems to have adopted a policy of going slow on
this aspect of liberalisation, though once started, the process is difficult
to fold back.
The way in which both central loans and market borrowings are
allocated to states is not made rule based and transparent and therefore,
has attracted resentment by some states. Generally, after meeting the
repayment liabilities, some additional resources are mobilised through
these instruments for spending on plan schemes. Asymmetry can result
from the volume of loans allocated to each state and the extent of
interest rate repression. Until the early 1990s, the rates of interest
charged on market states’ loans were substantially below the market
rates of interest, but thereafter, interest rates have been better aligned to
market rates. The whole process is not rule based and opaque, there is
significant scope for favouring some states over others in the allocation
of market borrowing. This is particularly true in a government ruled by a
coalition of parties and with some members of coalition wielding power
in the states.
25
There can be tremendous scope for discrimination among the
states arising from the practice of rescheduling and writing off of the
loans on special considerations. In the past, a number of Finance
Commissions were asked delve into states’ indebtedness and
recommend rescheduling and writing off, and it was on the basis of
these recommendations, that rescheduling was done. Referring to the
issue of states’indebtedness was only a convention that was established
and not a constitutional necessity. In recent years, however, the central
government has written off states’loans in Punjab, Jammu and Kashmir
and more recently proposes to write off loans of Nagaland without
referring the issue to anybody, on a discretionary basis. The reasons
advanced for this relief was that these states fought the nation’s battle
on terrorism/insurgency and in the process have had to suffer loss of
economic activity and revenues, and therefore need to be compensated.
They also had to create additional infrastructure to fight terrorism and a
part of the loan spent on this should be written off. Whatever be the
merits of these arguments, such practices have serious moral
implications and the arbitrary manner in which the central government
decides to write off the loans of the states creates asymmetry and scope
for discrimination, which may not be in the long term interest of Indian
federation.
13
Mr. K. K. Venugopal, an eminent constitutional expert has opined that giving grants for these
discretionary schemes is under Article 282 unconstitutional. See, NIPFP (1991).
26
75 percent of the total assistance given for central schemes. The
schemes are introduced by various central ministries and sometimes, on
the basis of announcements made by the Prime Minister from time to
time.14 Once introduced, they are continued. While the central sector
schemes are entirely funded by the centre, the centrally sponsored
schemes are shared cost programmes. But the schemes are designed
by the central ministries, and are mostly uniform across states. There is
scope for discrimination between states in the selection of schemes and
in its design. Often, new schemes can be introduced merely to favour a
particular state or group of states. The transfers given under these
schemes have received the strongest criticism, but that has not deterred
the central government from initiating more schemes. Nor has there
been any attempt to consolidate the schemes to allow greater say and
flexibility to states in their design and implementation. The ways in
which these are introduced and designed continue to be opaque.
14
Independence Day speech is one such occasion to announce new schemes.
27
the commodities at the declared price, the market prices will be
necessarily higher than it would be otherwise. As the support prices are
fixed mostly for agricultural commodities that are relatively price
inelastic, this tends to have significant regional redistribution. This
policy has a discriminatory impact on different states depending on the
product (crop) chosen for fixing support prices and the extent to which
support prices vary from the border prices (international price +
transportation cost). Not surprisingly, determination of support prices on
wheat, rice and other products is a matter of controversy in Indian
federation. It is not uncommon to see some of the regional parties
holding power in the states who are partners in the coalition government
at the centre influencing the determination of procurement prices.
28
institutions have functioned over years. In the initial years of
independence the issue did not come to the fore because, the Indian
National Congress, which was in the forefront of independence
movement had little opposition and had a virtual monopoly in forming
the government at the centre as well as states. Since at both central
and state levels a single party ruled, and as the party itself was
centralised, there was little scope for disharmony between the centre
and individual states and for discrimination between the states.
However, four important developments in Indian federalism have
impacted to create asymmetric treatment of states in Indian federation.
These are discussed in the following.
29
alternating as ruling parties in Tamil Nadu, Telugu Desam reigning
power in Andhra Pradesh, and other parties such as Haryana Vikas
Party in Haryana, Biju Janata Dal with a distinct regional identity in
Orissa are cases in point. This has shifted the perspective of parties on
power at the state level towards strongly safeguarding regional interests
even if that beat the cost of the rest of the country.15
15
For the analysis of regional parties in India’s federal system, see Manor (1995); and Rao and
Singh (2001).
16
The above development has been a subject of consternation and concern. Referring to the
tactics adopted by the Chief Minister of Andhra Pradesh, an editorial in a leading daily stated,
30
VI. Concluding Remarks
“...Armed with several spiral folders listing myriad demands, Mr. Naidu will characteristically
show the folders around, and in all likelihood, have his way too. Like he easily managed to get
10 lakh tons of rice from the food for work program, a new international airport, a drought relief
assistance and Rs. 1300.17 crores for countering extremism. . Already, there are charges that
a “weak” centre is being routinely “blackmailed” by Mr. Naidu. He has very cleverly used his
political leverage to the maximum, and much to the discomfiture of his detractors, he has also
got key Andhra politicians and bureaucrats into decision-making positions in Delhi” (Editorial in
Asian Age, June 11, 2003).
31
may be changes in the arrangement depending on factors such as the
extent to which various units assimilate themselves in the federation and
their relative bargaining strength. In contrast, the asymmetric
arrangements arising from political and administrative expediency are
opaque and discretionary. They can lead to degradation of
intergovernmental institutions and can be inimical to the stability of the
federation in the long term.
32
References
5. Guhan, S 1989. “The Norm and the Tilt: First Report of the Ninth
Finance Commission”, Economic and Political Weekly, January 14.
33