R. Solow - Technical Change and The Aggregate Production Function
R. Solow - Technical Change and The Aggregate Production Function
this case the price consists of one new required time series, the Q = A(t)f(K,L), 1a
share of labor or property in total income, and one new assump-
tion, that factors are paid their marginal products. Since the
11 and the multiplicative factor A(t) measures the cumulated eRect
of shifts over time. Differentiate l a totally with respect to time
former is probably more respectable than the other data I shall
use, and since the latter is an assumption often made, the price I and divide by Q and one obtains
1. 1 owe a debt of gratitude to Dr Louis Lefeber for statistical and other wk = (aQlaK>KlQ
assistance and to Professors Fellner, Leontief and Schultz for stimulating I
suggestions. Eco~zornicStudies, vol. 23, no. 2). Were the data available, it would be better
2. Mrs Robinson (1954) in particular has explored many of the profound to apply the analysis to some precisely defined production function with
difficulties that stand in the way of giving any precise meaning to the many precisely defined inputs. One can at least hope that the aggregate
quantity of capital, and I have thrown up still further obstacles (Review of analysis gives some notion of the way a detailed analysis would lead.
544 Technical Change and the Aggregate Production Function i R. Solow 345
and easily handled graphically. The production function is com-
pletely represented by a graph of q against k (analogously to the
WL = (2QIaL)LIQ
fact that if we know the unit-output isoquant, we know the
the relative shares of capital and labor, and substitute in the whole map). The trouble is that this function is shifting in time,
above equation (note that i;'Q/bK = A 8f/2~,'etc.) and there so that if we observe points in the (q, k) plane, their movements
results : are compounded out of movements along the curve and shifts of
the curve. In Figure 1, for instance, every ordinate on the curve
i
Of these, 4d is the Cobb-Douglas case; 4c and 4e have upper
asymptotes; the semi-logarithmic 4b and the hyperbolic 4c must that kind of smooth departure from linearity that one would like
to catch. A test can be constructed using published tables of
f Table 2 critical values for runs of two kinds of elements.
Ij:
This has been done for the linear, semi-logarithmic and Cobb-
Curve a B i' Douglas functions. The results strongly confirm the visual in-ipres-
4a 0-438 0-091 0.9982 sion of diminishing returns in Figure 4, by showing the linear
b 0.448 0.239 0.9996 9. It would be foolhardy for an outsider (or maybe even an insider) to
c 0-917 0.618 0.9964 hazard a guess about the statistical properties of the basic time series. A few
1 d -0.729 0.353 0.9996 general statements can be made, however. (a) The natural way to introduce
e -0.038 0-913 0.9980
Q -
an error term into the aggregate production function is multiplicatively:
(1 +I~)F(K,L;I).In the neutral case it is apparent that the error factor
will be absorbed into the estimated A(r). Then approximately the error in
cross the horizontal axis at a positive value of k and continue AAIA will be Au/l +it. If rc has zero mean, the variance of the estimated
ever more steeply but irrelevantly downward (which means only AAIA will be approximately 2(1 -p) var rc, where p is the first autocorrela-
that some positive k must be achieved before any output is tion of the ii series. (b) Suppose that marginal productivity distribution does
not hold exactly, so that KlQ6Ql2K = )tlk -Lo, where now o is a random
forthcoming, but this is far outside the range of observation); deviation and )v, is the share of property income. Then the error in the
4e begins at the origin with a phase of increasing returns and ends estimated AAIA will be c Alilk, with variance (Aklk)' var 21. Since K1.L
with a phase of diminishing returns - the point of inflection changes slowly, the multiplying factor will be very small. The effect is to
occurs at k = 812 and needless to say all our observed points bias the estimate of AAIA in such a way as to lead to an overestimate when
property receives less than its nlarginal product (and k is increasing).
come well to the right of this. (c) Errors in estimating A(t) enter in a relatively harmless way so far as the
8. .4 discussion of the same problem in a diflerent context is to be found regression analysis is concerned. Errors of observation in k will be more
in Prais and Houthakker (1955, pp. 82-8). See also Prais (1952-3, pp. serious and are likely to be large. The effect will of course be to bias the
87-104). estimates of B downward.