00 04harris BasicPrinciplesSD
00 04harris BasicPrinciplesSD
Jonathan M. Harris
June 2000
Tufts University
Medford MA 02155, USA
http://ase.tufts.edu/gdae
Great ideas are usually simple ideas. While the specific analysis of any important topic
will necessarily involve complexity and subtlety, the fundamental concepts which underlie
powerful paradigms of thought are usually relatively straightforward and easy to grasp. In the
area of social science, ideas which affect millions of people and guide the policies of nations
must be accessible to all, not just to an elite. Only thus can they permeate institutions from the
local to the global level, and become a part of the human landscape, part of the fabric within
which we define our lives.
Such is the concept of development. Prior to the second half of the twentieth century,
the idea of development as we know it today barely existed. The structures of imperial and
colonial power which dominated the world in the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries made
little provision for economic and social advance in what we now call the developing world.
Colonial regions functioned primarily to supply imperial powers with raw materials and cheap
labor – including slave labor as late as the mid-nineteenth century.
Within the richer countries of Europe, North America, and Japan, economic growth
was of course central to the generally accepted goals of “progress” and “modernization”, but
there was relatively little concern for issues of equity and social justice. The desperate poverty
and weak or non-existent social safety nets in Europe and the United States during the Great
Depression showed how even in these countries, policy was not driven by the needs of the
majority of people.
By the end of the Second World War, perceptions and policy had changed drastically.
Economic and social improvement for the majority had become a major preoccupation of
1
This paper will appear in The Encyclopedia of Life Support Systems , sponsored by the United
Nations Educational, Scientific, and Cultural Organization (UNESCO). Portions of the paper will also appear
in Jonathan Harris, Timothy Wise, Kevin Gallagher and Neva Goodwin eds., A Survey of Sustainable
Development: Social and Economic Dimensions, Volume 6 in the series Frontier Issues in Economic
Thought (Washington, D.C.: Island Press, 2001).
1
G-DAE Working Paper No. 00-04: “Basic Principles of Sustainable Development”
governments, and with the crumbling of colonial power relations this goal was extended to the
poorer nations of the world. Economic development, with its social and institutional
correlates, came to occupy an essential place in theory and policy, as well as in the Cold War
competition between capitalism and communism. As the historian of economic thought Roger
Backhouse puts it:
Development economics in its modern form did not exist before the
1940's. The concern of development economics, as the term is now
understood, is with countries or regions which are seen to be under or less
developed relative to others, and which, it is commonly believed, should, if they
are not to become ever poorer relative to the developed countries, be
developed in some way. 2
Within formal neoclassical economic theory, an effort has been made to achieve a
positive rather than a normative perspective – that is, to describe what is rather than positing
what should be. Development economics, in contrast, is explicitly normative, as Backhouse’s
description makes clear. As such, it cannot avoid concern with social and political issues, and
must focus on goals, ideals, and ends, as well as economic means.
When W.W. Rostow published his ambitious overview of economic development, The
Stages of Economic Growth, in 1960, he subtitled it “A Non-Communist Manifesto”.3
Conscious of the claims of Marxism to offer a path to a better future for the majority of the
world’s peoples, Rostow sought to counterpose a superior vision of social and economic goals.
Notable in this perspective was a linear conception of economic development.
According to this view, all successfully developing countries would pass through a
series of stages, from traditional society through economic “take-off” to maturity and high mass-
consumption. The “less-developed” nations therefore might reasonably hope to achieve the
“mature” status of the U.S. and Europe without the need for communist revolution. Rostow’s
concept of take-off, as well as his overall perspective of economic and social progress towards
a goal of mass consumption, was widely accepted by development theorists.
2
Backhouse, Roger (1991). A History of Modern Economic Analysis . Oxford, UK: Basil
Blackwell.
3
Rostow, W.W. (1960). The Stages of Economic Growth: A Non-Communist Manifesto
2
G-DAE Working Paper No. 00-04: “Basic Principles of Sustainable Development”
At the turn of the century, what is the 50-year record of the broad-reaching, and
historically fairly young, effort at global development? The concept has been widely accepted,
by countries of varied political structure. There have been remarkable successes – notably in
East Asia – and worldwide progress both in standard GDP measures and in measures of human
development such as life expectancy and education. There have also been areas of slow or
negative growth, especially in Africa, where GDP increase was slow and food production per
4
Streeten, Paul , with Shahid Burki, Mahbub Ul Haq, Norman Hicks, and Frances Stewart (1981).
First Things First: Meeting Basic Human Needs in the Developing Countries. Published for the World
Bank. New York and Oxford: Oxford University Press.
3
G-DAE Working Paper No. 00-04: “Basic Principles of Sustainable Development”
capita in decline even before the rapid spread of AIDS devastated many countries and
dramatically lowered life expectancies.
Globally, most countries have made significant advances both in GDP and in Human
Development Index measures. But overall, the record of development on a world scale is
open to two major criticisms:
• The benefits of development have been distributed unevenly, with income inequalities
remaining persistent and sometimes increasing over time. The global numbers of
extremely poor and malnourished people have remained high, and in some areas have
increased, even as a global middle class has achieved relative affluence.
• There have been major negative impacts of development on the environment and on
existing social structures. Many traditional societies have been devastated by
development of forests, water systems, and intensive fisheries. Urban areas in
developing countries commonly suffer from extreme pollution and inadequate
transportation, water, and sewer infrastructure. Environmental damage, if
unchecked, may undermine the achievements of development and even lead to collapse
of essential ecosystems.
These problems are not minor blemishes on an overall record of success. Rather, they
appear to be endemic to development as it has taken place over the past half-century, and to
threaten to turn success into failure. World Bank President James Wolfensohn and chief
economist Joseph Stiglitz acknowledged in 1999 that these issues are crucial to address if
global development is to succeed. Harsher critics of the development paradigm, such as
Richard Norgaard, see them as indicative of fundamental error:
5
Norgaard, Richard B. (1994 ). Development Betrayed: The End of Progress and a Coevolutionary
Revisioning of the Future, p. 2. New York and London: Routledge.
4
G-DAE Working Paper No. 00-04: “Basic Principles of Sustainable Development”
The growing awareness of these challenges to traditional development thinking has led
to the increasingly wide acceptance of a new concept – that of sustainable development.
Development which protects the environment, development which advances social justice --
phrases such as these have surrounded the introduction of what has been claimed to be a new
paradigm. The new formulation has been eagerly adopted both by critics of standard
development practice and by leaders of existing development institutions. But what does
sustainable development really mean?
When the World Commission on Environment and Development presented their 1987
report, Our Common Future, they sought to address the problem of conflicts between
environment and development goals by formulating a definition of sustainable development:
In the extensive discussion and use of the concept since then, there has generally been a
recognition of three aspects of sustainable development7:
6
World Commission on Environment and Development (1987). Our Common Future.
7
See e.g. Holmberg ed. (1992), Making Development Sustainable, Chapter 1; Reed ed. (1997),
Structural Adjustment, the Environment and Sustainable Development, Chapter 2.
5
G-DAE Working Paper No. 00-04: “Basic Principles of Sustainable Development”
external debt, and to avoid extreme sectoral imbalances which damage agricultural or
industrial production.
In the real world, we can rarely avoid trade-offs, and as Richard Norgaard points out,
we can “maximize” only one objective at a time. Norgaard concludes that “it is impossible to
define sustainable development in an operational manner in the detail and with the level of
control presumed in the logic of modernity.”8 The strongly normative nature of the sustainable
development concept makes it difficult to pin down analytically.
8
Norgaard, op. cit. p.22.
6
G-DAE Working Paper No. 00-04: “Basic Principles of Sustainable Development”
This implies that we can use different indicators to measure different dimensions of
sustainability. Indicators imply measurement; measurement implies the theoretical definition of
concepts to measure. Let us examine what the three different disciplinary areas have to offer in
this regard.
From the point of view of neoclassical economic theory, sustainability can be defined in
terms of the maximization of welfare over time. (This is assumed to be human welfare – we
will introduce the claims of the non-human world when we consider the ecological perspective.)
Most economists simplify further by identifying the maximization of welfare with the
9
Bossell, Hartmut, ed. (1999). Indicators for Sustainable Development: Theory, Method,
Applications: A Report to the Balaton Group, p.2. Winnipeg, Canada: International Institute for
Sustainable Development (IISD).
7
G-DAE Working Paper No. 00-04: “Basic Principles of Sustainable Development”
A formal economic analysis then raises the question of whether sustainability has any
validity as an economic concept. According to standard economic theory, efficient resource
allocation should have the effect of maximizing utility from consumption. If we accept the use
of time discounting as a method of comparing the economic values of consumption in different
time periods, then sustainability appears to mean nothing more than efficient resource allocation
– a concept already well established in economics.
One line of criticism of this reductionist approach to sustainability centers on the use of
discounting. At a discount rate of 10%, the value of $1 million one hundred years from now is
the same as a mere $72 today. Thus it would apparently be justifiable to impose costs of up to
$1 million on people in the year 2100 in order to enjoy $72 worth of consumption today. By
this logic, much resource depletion and environmental damage could be considered acceptable,
and even optimal, according to a criterion of economic efficiency.
The problem is that in accepting the use of a discount rate, we have implicitly imposed
a specific choice regarding the relative welfare of present and future generations. Howarth and
Norgaard have shown that the choice of a discount rate is equivalent to a choice of allocations
among generations.10 Use of a current market discount rate gives undue weight to the
preferences of current consumers. When we consider issues such as soil erosion or
atmospheric buildup of greenhouse gases, where the most damaging impacts are felt over
decades or generations, this creates a strong bias against sustainability. Thus to achieve
intergenerational equity, we must either impose a low discount rate11 or some kind of
sustainability rule regarding resource use and environmental impacts.
A related issue concerns the concept of natural capital. Soils and atmospheric
functions are aspects of natural capital, which consists of all the natural resources and
environmental services of the planet. Herman Daly has suggested that sustainable development
10
Howarth, Richard B. and Richard B. Norgaard (1993 ). “Intergenerational Transfers and the
Social Discount Rate.” Environmental and Resource Economics 3 (Aug.): 337-58.
11
William Cline has suggested the use of a discount rate of 1.5% for balancing long-term costs and
benefits of global climate change abatement. See The Economics of Global Warming (1992), Chapters 6 and
7. Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics.
8
G-DAE Working Paper No. 00-04: “Basic Principles of Sustainable Development”
can be operationalized in terms of the conservation of natural capital.12 This policy goal
leads to two decision rules, one for renewable and the other for non-renewable resources.
For renewables, the rule is to limit resource consumption to sustainable yield levels; for non-
renewables the rule is to re-invest the proceeds from non-renewable resource exploitation into
investment in renewable natural capital. Following these two rules will maintain a constant
stock of natural capital. To maintain a constant per capita stock of natural capital also
requires a stable level of human population, a factor which Daly has also emphasized.13
This suggestion of a specific sustainability decision rule for natural capital is quite
different from the standard neo-classical approach. In the neo-classical view, there is no
special reason to conserve natural capital. A well-known principle derived from work by
Solow and Hartwick (the “Hartwick rule”) states that consumption may remain constant, or
increase, with declining non-renewable resources provided that the rents from these resources
are reinvested in reproducible capital. 14 Unlike Daly’s reinvestment rule, this does not require
maintenance of any particular stock of natural capital.
12
Daly, Herman E. (1994). “Operationalizing Sustainable Development by Investing in Natural
Capital,” in AnnMari Jansson et al. eds., Investing in Natural Capital: The Ecological Economics Approach
to Sustainability. Washington, D.C.: Island Press.
13
Daly, Herman E. (1991). Steady State Economics (2nd ed.), Chapters 2 and 9. Washington,
D.C.: Island Press.
14
This principle is discussed in Mick Common and Charles Perrings (1992) “Towards an Ecological
Economics of Sustainability,” Ecological Economics 6 (1) pp. 7-34. See also Hartwick, J.M. 1977,
“Intergenerational Equity and the Investing of Rents from Exhaustible Resources,” American Economic
Review 66 pp. 972-974; Solow, R.M. (1986) “On the Intertemporal Allocation of Natural Resources,”
Scandinavian Journal of Economics 88 pp.141-149.
15
Daly, “Operationalizing Sustainable Development,” p. 25.
9
G-DAE Working Paper No. 00-04: “Basic Principles of Sustainable Development”
Michael Toman has suggested that the issue may be resolved by recognizing that some
issues can be appropriately dealt with through neo-classical market efficiency, while others
require the application of a “safe minimum standard” approach to protect essential resources
and environmental functions.16 He suggests that the criteria of possible severity and
irreversibility of ecological damages should be used to decide which theoretical framework is
more appropriate:
The adoption of this reasonable suggestion would have far-reaching implications for
economic theory and policy. Note the essential role of “moral imperatives,” “public decision
making,” and “the formation of social values” in Toman’s suggested decision framework.
None of these appear in the neo-classical economic model, where markets are presumed to be
the best resource allocators, and the occasional correction of a “market imperfection” the only
appropriate role for government. Thus Toman is in effect asserting the importance of
sustainability as a concept independent of standard neo-classical economic analysis, one which
requires an explicitly normative and socially determined process of decision-making.
This represents a fundamental shift in the economic paradigm. Much as the Keynesian
revolution validated the concept of government intervention to achieve macroeconomic stability,
the acceptance of sustainability as a valid social goal places a new complexion on all policy
16
The “safe minimum standard” approach was originally proposed with reference to endangered
species by Ciriancy-Wantrup. See Ciriancy Wantrup, S.V. (1952), Resource Conservation. Berkeley:
University of California Press.
17
Toman, Michael A. “The Difficulty in Defining Sustainability” (1992), Resources 106 pp.3-6,
summarized in Rajaram Krishnan, Jonathan M. Harris, and Neva R. Goodwin eds.(1995), A Survey of
Ecological Economics, p. 88-90. Washington, D.C.: Island Press.
10
G-DAE Working Paper No. 00-04: “Basic Principles of Sustainable Development”
issues concerning the relationship between human economic activity and the environment.
Markets may be valuable and essential means, but they cannot determine the ends, which must
be arrived at by a social decision process informed by different disciplinary viewpoints. This
will require an unaccustomed humility on the part of economists, and a willingness to work
together with other social and natural scientists. As Toman suggests:
In order to explore further the implications of this approach, we need to examine the
ecological and social dimensions of the issue. Then we can return to the question of whether
a new paradigm for development policy has truly emerged from the multidisciplinary discussion
on the nature of sustainability.
Two of the fundamental axioms of ecological and evolutionary biology are that
organisms are exuberantly over-productive, and that limits set by time, space, and
18
Toman, op. cit. p. 90.
11
G-DAE Working Paper No. 00-04: “Basic Principles of Sustainable Development”
energy are inevitably encountered. The foundations for all modern ecology and
evolutionary biology rest in part upon the consequences of these two axioms.19
However, this simple assertion of limits does not fully capture the contribution of
ecologists to the discussion of sustainability. What C.S. Holling identifies as a third axiom of
ecology has even more significant implications. The third axiom “concerns processes that
generate variability and novelty”21 – the generation of genetic diversity and the resultant
processes of evolution and change in species and ecosystems.
19
Holling, C.S. (1994). “An Ecologist View of the Malthusian Conflict,” in Kerstin Lindahl-
Kiessling and Hans Landberg eds., Population, Economic Development, and the Environment, p. 84. New
York and Oxford: Oxford University Press.
20
Ehrlich, Paul R. “Ecological Economics and the Carrying Capacity of the Earth,” in AnnMari
Jansson et al eds., Investing in Natural Capital: The Ecological Economics Approach to Sustainability.
Washington, D.C.: Island Press. Original research in Vitousek, P.M., P.R. Ehrlich , A.H. Ehrlich, and P.A.
Matson, “Human Appropriation of the Products of Photosynthesis” (1986). BioScience 36 (6): 368-73.
21
Holling, ibid.
12
G-DAE Working Paper No. 00-04: “Basic Principles of Sustainable Development”
For the ecologist, then, sustainability should be defined in terms of the maintenance of
ecosystem resilience. This view of sustainability is clearly different from the human-centered
conceptions put forward by the World Commission on Environment and Development and the
consumption-based principles proposed by economic theorists. This contrast has been
explored by Common and Perrings, who distinguish between “Solow-sustainability”, derived
from the economic model of stable or increasing consumption, and “Holling-sustainability”,
based on ecosystem resilience. They find that “the concepts of Solow-sustainability and
Holling-sustainability are largely disjoint. This implies that there may be no close relationship
between economic efficiency and ecological sustainability.”22
The horrifying impact of AIDS, most especially on the African continent, is perhaps the
worst example to date of the feedback effects of human destruction of ecosystem resilience.
AIDS probably originated in rain-forest primates, and spread to humans through human
intrusion into the forest. Rather than remaining isolated in small communities, it then spread
worldwide through global commerce and travel, like many other destructive viruses and pests.
Population checks through such drastic ecological backlash are, of course, familiar to
22
Mick Common and Charles Perrings, “Towards an Ecological Economics of Sustainability”
(1992) Ecological Economics 6 pp. 7-34, summarized in Rajaram Krishnan, Jonathan M. Harris, and Neva R.
Goodwin eds. (1995), A Survey of Ecological Economics, p. 108-112. Washington, D.C.: Island Press.
23
Holling, op. cit. p. 93.
13
G-DAE Working Paper No. 00-04: “Basic Principles of Sustainable Development”
ecologists. But they are generally far from the thoughts of the economists and policymakers
who up until now have shaped our conceptions of development.
Clearly, an integration of economics and ecology is required, and this can only be
achieved with the assistance of the third element of the sustainability triad – the social
perspective. If we cannot rely on unregulated markets to solve our problems, we must turn to
conscious social action. But social action by whom, and at what level? And how do the
environmental issues relate to the other great failure of development to date – the persistence of
inequality? It is in the social area that we must seek the key to the formulation of policies for
sustainable development.
24
Common and Perrings, op. cit. p.112.
25
See Holmberg, op. cit note 6, and Reed op. cit. note 6.
14
G-DAE Working Paper No. 00-04: “Basic Principles of Sustainable Development”
As we have noted, the focus on basic needs and equity in development has been
represented by the United Nations Development Programme’s series of Human Development
Reports. In addition to calculating the Human Development Index which offers a different
measure of development success from per capita GNP or GDP 27, the Human Development
Reports focus each year on a different aspect of social and economic development, such as
democratic governance (1993), gender inequity (1995), and poverty (1997).28
The HDI combines life expectancy, adult literacy, and school enrollment ratios with per
capita GDP in a weighted average to get an index between 0 and 1. The results clearly show
that development is a multidimensional process, and that higher GDP does not necessarily mean
higher overall welfare. Some countries, such as Costa Rica (HDI = 0.883) and Sri Lanka
(HDI= 0.704), stand out in terms of their human development well above others of almost
26
Anand, Sudhir and Amartya K. Sen (1996) Sustainable Human Development: Concepts and
Priorities. United Nations Development Programme, Office of Development Studies Discussion Paper
Series.
27
The statistical difference between GNP and GDP concerns the inclusion of foreign earnings,
which may be significant in an analysis of financial flows but makes little difference to a broad measure of
development.
28
United Nations Development Programme, Human Development Report (1990-1998).
15
G-DAE Working Paper No. 00-04: “Basic Principles of Sustainable Development”
identical GDP per capita (Brazil and Turkey, comparable to Costa Rica in per capita GDP,
have HDI = 0.804 and 0.792 respectively; Congo and Pakistan, almost identical in GDP to Sri
Lanka, have HDI’s of 0.538 and 0.483 respectively) 29.
While the HDI does not explicitly include any environmental measures, the 1994 report
discussed the relationship between sustainability and equity:
In the 1997 report, a section on “Resisting New Forces of Poverty” discusses factors
which cause worsening conditions for the world’s poor. Prominent among these are the
HIV/AIDS pandemic which is “creating a new wave of impoverishment – and reversing earlier
gains.” (We have already noted the relationship of AIDS and resurgent diseases to
ecological degradation.) Another factor is environmental degradation on marginal lands – the
dry, swampy, saline, and steep areas where many of the rural poor struggle to survive.31
Clearly, the issue of environmental sustainability is intertwined with that of poverty and
inequity. It has frequently been noted that the causative relationship runs both ways –
increased poverty and loss of rural livelihoods accelerates environmental degradation as
displaced people put greater pressure on forests, fisheries, and marginal lands.
If the problems of environment and equity are clearly related, then so must be the
solutions. Third World critics of the standard, “Western” development model see that model
itself as a significant cause of the problems. The sweeping optimism implicit in Rostow’s
29
1992 HDI comparison from Richard England and Jonathan Harris (1997), Alternatives to Gross
National Product: A Critical Survey (Tufts University Global Development and Environment Institute
Discussion Paper #5, http://www.tufts.edu/gdae.) Also in Frank Ackerman et al eds. (1997), Human Well-
Being and Economic Goals , Part X (Washington, D.C.: Island Press)
30
UNDP, Human Development Report 1994.
31
UNDP Human Development Report 1997, Chapter 3.
16
G-DAE Working Paper No. 00-04: “Basic Principles of Sustainable Development”
original stages-of-growth paradigm ignores social and cultural differences between nations, as
well as the fundamental power disparity between developed and developing nations. A view
of development as a one-way journey to improved conditions fails to match the experience of
many people whose livelihoods are threatened by globalization.
It is not only radical critics who are aware of the need for significant changes in the
development paradigm. The World Bank has recently produced reports stressing the
importance of social capital, the role of the state, and the importance of local government and
non-governmental organizations in development.33 From the Bank’s more conventional
perspective, participatory democracy, decentralization, and social capital represented by strong
local organization, are compatible with, and beneficial to, standard measures of development
such as GDP per capita. However, simply highlighting the importance of these factors is a new
departure for market-oriented economic theorists.
32
Porter, Philip W. and Eric S. Sheppard (1998). “Views form the Periphery: Encountering
Development,” in Porter and Sheppard, A World of Difference: Society, Nature, Development. New York:
Guilford Press.
33
World Bank, World Development Report 1997: The State in a Changing World. New York:
Oxford University Press.
17
G-DAE Working Paper No. 00-04: “Basic Principles of Sustainable Development”
pollution”.34 This new attention to a combination of social and environmental factors indicates
that lines of thought formerly at the fringes of development policy are making their way into the
mainstream.
What has been referred to as the “Washington consensus” on the virtues of free
markets and globalization has also come under challenge from the World Bank’s own chief
economist, Joseph Stiglitz.35 Stiglitz argues that there are many areas in which the operations
of “free markets” are flawed by asymmetric control of information. This rather abstruse
economic theory can be translated into an awareness of the importance of institutions and social
norms in shaping market outcomes. This in turn justifies social and governmental action at both
the micro and macro levels, and opens the way to a more explicitly normative theory of
development. In this sense, Stiglitz is returning to the more goal-oriented perspective of the of
the original theorists of development – except that the goals which now seem appropriate have
much stronger social and environmental components.
While there are clearly wide differences of perspective and emphasis between the
critics within and without the development establishment, there seems to be a widely felt
discontent with present development theory and practice, and it appears that the elements of a
new paradigm are emerging. Can we combine the economic, ecological, and social
perspectives to provide a new vision of development in the twenty-first century?
6. A Synthesis of Perspectives
Let us briefly review some of the main themes developed thus far:
34
World Bank (1997). Expanding the Measure of Wealth: Indicators of Environmentally
Sustainable Development. Washington, D.C.: The World Bank.
35
Stiglitz, J. (1997), An Agenda for Development for the Twenty-First Century”, presented at the
World Bank Ninth Annual Conference on Development Economics; and Stiglitz, J.(1998), “ More
Instruments and Broader Goals: Moving Toward the Post Washington Consensus.” WIDER Annual
Lectures No. 2, Helsinki.
18
G-DAE Working Paper No. 00-04: “Basic Principles of Sustainable Development”
• The conservation of natural capital is essential for sustainable economic production and
intergenerational equity. Market mechanisms do not operate effectively to conserve
natural capital, but tend to deplete and degrade it.
• From an ecological perspective, both population and total resource demand must be
limited in scale, and the integrity of ecosystems and diversity of species must be
maintained.
• Social equity, the fulfilment of basic health and educational needs, and participatory
democracy are crucial elements of development, and are interrelated with
environmental sustainability.
Taken together, these principles clearly suggest new guidelines for the development
process. They also require a modification of the original goal of economic growth. Economic
growth, especially for those who lack essentials, is clearly needed, but must be subject to global
limits and should not be the prime objective for countries already at high levels of consumption.
As Alan Durning has suggested, a moderate level of consumption, together with strong social
institutions and a healthy environment, represents a better ideal than ever-increasing
consumption.36
36
Durning, Alan (1992). How Much is Enough? The Consumer Society and the Future of Earth.
Worldwatch Environmental Alert Series (Linda Starke ed.). New York and London: W.W.Norton.
37
World Bank, World Development Report 1997, Foreword.
19
G-DAE Working Paper No. 00-04: “Basic Principles of Sustainable Development”
environmental costs and benefits in the market.38 But in a broader perspective, it is the social
and institutional processes of setting social and environmental goals and norms which must
guide sustainable development policy.
38
See, for example, Anil Markandya and Julie Richardson eds. (1993). Environmental Economics:
A Reader, Part III: Instruments for Environmental Control and Applications. New York: St. Martin’s Press.
20
G-DAE Working Paper No. 00-04: “Basic Principles of Sustainable Development”
To bring the argument down to earth, and to get a sense of what the principles
summarized at the beginning of this section mean for development, we can examine some
sectoral specifics. In each major area, it becomes clear that true sustainability means a major
shift from existing techniques and organization of production.
• Energy: Both supply limits and environmental impacts, in particular the accumulation
of greenhouse gases, mean that it will be necessary to accomplish a transition away
from fossil fuels well before 2050.41 A non-fossil energy system would be significantly
more decentralized, adapted to local conditions and taking advantage of opportunities
for wind, biomass, and off-grid solar power systems. This is unlikely to occur without
a major mobilization of capital resources for renewable energy development in
countries now rapidly expanding their energy systems.
39
Harris, Jonathan M. and Scott Kennedy (1999). “Carrying Capacity in Agriculture: Global and
Regional Issues,” Ecological Economics 29 (3) pp.443-461; Pinstrup-Andersen, Per, and Rajul Pandya-
Lorch (1998) “Food Security and Sustainable Use of Natural Resources: A 2020 Vision,” Ecological
Economics 26 (1), pp. 1-10.
40
Pretty, Jules, and Robert Chambers, “Towards a Learning Paradigm: New Professionalism and
Institutions for Agriculture,” in Jonathan M. Harris ed., Rethinking Sustainability: Power, Knowledge, and
Institutions. University of Michigan Press, forthcoming 2000.
41
MacKenzie, James J. (1996) Oil as a Finite Resource: When will Global Production Peak?
Washington, D.C.: World Resources Institute; Ackerman, Frank et al., World Energy Modernization Plan,
discussion paper available at http://www.wemp.org.
21
G-DAE Working Paper No. 00-04: “Basic Principles of Sustainable Development”
• Renewable Resource Systems: World fisheries, forests and water systems are
severely over-stressed43. With even greater demands on all systems expected in the
next century, all levels of institutional management must be urgently reformed.
Multilateral agreements and global funding are needed to conserve transboundary
resources; national resource management systems must be shifted from goals of
exploitation to conservation and sustainable harvesting; and local communities must be
strongly involved in resource conservation.
Each of these areas poses challenges which are social and institutional as well as
economic. It is clear that the social component of sustainability is not just an idealized goal,
but a necessity for achieving the economic and ecological components. Existing institutions of
all kinds, including corporations, local and national government, and transnational organizations,
will have to adapt to the requirements of sustainable development if all the problems which
motivated the development of concept are not to grow worse. Democratic governance,
participation, and the satisfaction of basic needs are thus an essential part of a new development
synthesis.
In 1998 W. W. Rostow, the originator of the stages-of-growth theory which has been
so influential in shaping development policy for nearly half a century, published another
overview of development issues, but this time looking forward to the twenty-first century.
42
Socolow, Robert et al. (1994). Industrial Ecology and Global Change. New York and Cambridge,
England: Cambridge University Press; Powers, Charles W. and Marian R. Chertow, “Industrial Ecology:
Overcoming Policy Fragmentation,” in Marian Chertow and Daniel Esty eds (1997) Thinking Ecologically:
The Next Generation of Environmental Policy. New Haven and London: Yale University Press.
43
Platt-McGinn, A. (1998). Rocking the Boat: Conserving Fisheries and Protecting Jobs.
Washington D.C., Worldwatch Institute; Myers, N. (1996). “The World's Forests: Problems and
Potentials.” Environmental Conservation 23 (2) pp.156-168; Postel, S. (1999). Pillar of Sand, Can the
Irrigation Miracle Last? New York, W.W. Norton & Company.
22
G-DAE Working Paper No. 00-04: “Basic Principles of Sustainable Development”
Here he acknowledges the enormous impact of population and economic growth, and the ways
in which the far greater scale of economic activity changes the requirements of development:
The period from the present to the mid-21st century is likely to be the time of
the maximum strain on resources and the environment and the interval of
maximum readjustment in the locus of population , economic potential, and
political influence in the international community. . .If the earth can carry a
doubling of population in the next half century without a general catastrophe, we
shall have two countries, with populations of about 1.5 billion each, that are
essentially industrialized: India and China. This is, for each country, about five
times the estimated peak population level of the United States. They should
each command by the middle of the next century all the then-available industrial
and agricultural techniques. Much the same can be said of the other major
countries of Asia and Latin America . . . Thus, the period from now until 2050
will be a period not only of maximum strain on resources but also one in which
new industrial powers will enter the world arena. 44
Rostow thus recognizes the way in which the very success of the kind of development
which he envisaged in 1960 has altered the global picture in such a way as to bring very
different problems to the fore. The turn of the century is an appropriate to time to seek a new
model which will address both the original problems of development – limited productive
capacity, inadequate nutrition, and pervasive poverty – and the new problems of resource
limitations, environmental stress, and unresolved or growing inequity.
We have outlined both some of the general principles and some of the specific
requirements of sustainable development. The concept has been broadly accepted, but the
implications of the tripartite theoretical restructuring which we have discussed are more far-
reaching than may be apparent. Development theory, as we have noted, has always been
normative as well as positive in its analytical vision. Today we require a new normative vision
drawing on strong but neglected traditions in economics, political and social theory and
combining traditional wisdom with modern technology.
What has been discussed here, reflecting a dialogue which has expanded rapidly since
the World Commission on Environment and Development Report in 1987, is only an initial
outline and overview. The devil is always in the details; fortunately there is now an extensive
44
Rostow, W. W. (1998). The Great Population Spike and After: Reflections on the 21st Century.
New York and Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.
23
G-DAE Working Paper No. 00-04: “Basic Principles of Sustainable Development”
effort by theorists and practitioners from many disciplines to transform the concept of
sustainable development into reality.
Jonathan Harris is Director of the Theory and Education Program of the Global
Development and Environment Institute. He is also Adjunct Associate Professor of
International Economics at the Fletcher School of Law and Diplomacy, Tufts University.
24
The Global Development And Environment Institute (G-DAE) is a research
institute at Tufts University dedicated to promoting a better understanding
of how societies can pursue their economic goals in an environmentally and
socially sustainable manner. G-DAE pursues its mission through original
research, policy work, publication projects, curriculum development,
conferences, and other activities. The "G-DAE Working Papers" series
presents substantive work-in-progress by G-DAE-affiliated researchers. We
welcome your comments, either by e-mail directly to the author or to G-DAE,
Cabot Center, Fletcher School, Tufts University, Medford, MA 02155 USA;
tel: 617-627-3530; fax: 617-627-2409; e-mail: [email protected]; web:
http://ase.tufts.edu/gdae.
00-01 Still Dead After All These Years: Interpreting the Failure of General Equilibrium
Theory (Frank Ackerman, November 1999)
00-02 Economics in Context: The Need for a New Textbook (Neva R. Goodwin,
Oleg I. Ananyin, Frank Ackerman and Thomas E. Weisskopf, February 1997)
00-05 Getting the Prices Wrong: The Limits of Market-Based Environmental Policy
(Frank Ackerman and Kevin Gallagher, September 2000)
00-06 Telling Other Stories: Heterodox Critiques of Neoclassical Micro Principles Texts
(Steve Cohn, August 2000)