Ecb wp2519 0932267132 en
Ecb wp2519 0932267132 en
Disclaimer: This paper should not be reported as representing the views of the European Central Bank
(ECB). The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the ECB.
Abstract
In this paper we examine the effects of limited liability on mortgage dynamics. While
the literature has focused on default rates, renegotiation, or loan rates individually,
we study them together as equilibrium outcomes of the strategic interaction between
lenders and borrowers. We present a simple model of default and renegotiation
where the degree of limited liability plays a key role in agents’ strategies. We
then use Fannie Mae loan performance data to test the predictions of the model.
We focus on Metropolitan Statistical Areas that are crossed by a State border in
order to exploit the discontinuity in regulation around the borders of States. As
predicted by the model, we find that limited liability results in higher default rates
and renegotiation rates. Regarding loan pricing, while the model predicts higher
interest rates for limited liability loans, we find no such evidence in the Fannie Mae
data. We further investigate this by using loan application data, which contains
the interest rates on loans sold to private vs public investors. We find that private
investors do price in the difference in ex-ante predictable default risk for limited
liability loans.
tinuity.
The rise of household debt before the financial crisis combined with high default rates
was a root cause of the Great Recession and highlighted the role of consumer finance for the
macroeconomy. Mortgage debt, in particular, constitutes two-thirds of US household total
debt. Outstanding mortgage amounts declined substantially during the Great Recession,
While there are several factors that determine the rate of mortgage default, such as
adverse economic shocks that leave households unable to honour their debt, default may
implies a fixed limit on the borrower’s obligations, which amounts to the handover of the
mortgaged property. In the absence of limited liability, the borrower is liable for the
repayment of the full loan amount, and the lender is entitled to seize the borrower’s
personal assets.
In contrast to the literature, which has studied several effects of limited liability indi-
vidually, we analyse default decisions, renegotiation and loan pricing together. These are,
in fact, equilibrium outcomes of the strategic interaction between lenders and borrowers.
To this end, we first develop a simple model of default and renegotiation where the degree
of limited liability plays a key role in agents’ strategies. Borrowers who can afford to pay
the loan may choose to default if their mortgage is underwater. Limited liability encour-
under limited liability they would not be able to recover more than the foreclosure value
of the home. Borrowers thus have greater bargaining power over lenders under limited
liability. These interactions also have an effect on loan prices, as the expected value of
each loan will depend on the equilibrium of this game. Thus, the model provides three
main predictions. First, limited liability leads to higher default rates. Second, lenders
renegotiate more under limited liability. Lastly, loan prices are higher for limited liability
loans.
We then use Fannie Mae loan performance data to test the predictions of the model. We
exploit the difference in regulation in different States. In particular, we limit our analysis
to Metropolitan Statistical Areas (MSAs) that are crossed by a State border, where one
side has limited liability laws in place and the other does not. This allows us to isolate the
effect of limited liability on loan outcomes, as other factors such as economic shocks are
expected to be the same within each MSA. As predicted by the model, we find that limited
liability results in higher default and renegotiation rates. Regarding loan pricing, while
the model predicts higher interest rates for limited liability loans, we find no such evidence
in the Fannie Mae data. We further investigate this by using loan application data from
the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act (HMDA) database, which contains the interest rates
on loans sold to private and public purchasers. We find that private investors do price
in the difference in ex-ante predictable default risk for limited liability loans, while their
public counterparts, such as Fannie Mae, do not. This has important policy implications,
as it imposes price distortions in a multi-trillion dollar market.
The rise of household indebtedness before the financial crisis combined with high default
rates was a root cause of the Great Recession and underlined the importance of consumer
finance for the macroeconomy. Mortgage debt, in particular, constitutes two-thirds of
US household total debt, as shown in Figure 1. Outstanding mortgage amounts declined
substantially during the Great Recession, but have since reached new historical highs.
While there are several factors that determine the rate of mortgage default, such as
adverse economic shocks that leave households unable to honour their debt, default may
in place. Under limited liability, the lender is not allowed to seize the household’s assets
Precisely because of the widespread presence of mortgage debt, and in order to prevent
strategic default, some jurisdictions allow for lender recourse. Under recourse, lenders
are allowed to seize borrowers’ assets after default. This aspect of mortgage contracts is
predominant in Europe, as noted by Campbell (2012). In the case of the United States,
the existence of mortgage recourse is heterogeneous across States, a feature which we will
exploit in our analysis.
Strategic default has been widely studied for sovereign debt (e.g. Grossman and
Van Huyck (1988); Atkeson (1991)), and other types of unsecured debt (e.g. Jeske (2006)).
Mortgage debt is a particular case, and it is interesting to evaluate it in isolation. First,
agents making decisions are not sovereign States or investors, but households. Second,
debt contracts are highly structured and backed by a real estate property. Third, this
utility from the asset and can thus heavily influence their choices. Fourth, mortgage con-
tracts typically allow borrowers to reach levels of leverage uncommon in other types of
debt. Lastly, mortgage contracts are typically longer, the most common contract length
being around 30 years. It is worth noting that the decisions made by agents may differ
substantially as the loan is amortised.
events after default, and the payoffs from which agents will derive their decisions. When a
household defaults on a mortgage, the lender recovers the collateral through foreclosure,
short sale, or a deed in lieu. Under limited liability, the borrower is freed from their
debt and the lender only recovers the proceedings from the sale of the property. In
contrast, under recourse or full liability, the lender can pursue a deficiency judgement.
of the collateral. Should the sale of the collateral not be enough to cover the mortgage
balance, the lender is entitled to claim the difference from the borrower.
This paper relates to two bodies of literature. The first one exploits different legislative
discontinuities around State borders to study several aspects of limited liability and its
effect on different market outcomes. Some papers have focused on the effect of limited
liability on loan origination. Pence (2006) studies loan origination volumes through the
difference in the size of loans on recourse and non-recourse States and finds that non-
recourse loans are smaller on average. Curtis (2014) finds that lender-friendly foreclosure
is associated with an increase in subprime originations, but has less effect on the prime
market. Li and Oswald (2017) leverage on the abolition of deficiency judgements in the
State of Nevada in 2009 and find that it led to a decline in equilibrium loan sizes and
approval rates. Some other papers have studied the effect of limited liability on loan rates
and housing prices. Meador (1982) finds that States with judicial foreclosure exhibit lower
interest rates on loans. Pennington-Cross and Ho (2008) inquire whether laws intending
to reduce predatory lending behaviour have an effect on loan rates. Their results suggest
that these laws have only a modest effect on loan prices. Mian et al. (2015) use judicial
requirements for foreclosures across States as an instrument for foreclosures and find
that higher foreclosure rates lead to a decline in house prices, residential investments
and consumer demand. Another set of papers is concerned with forbearance and loan
modifications. Gerardi et al. (2013) find that laws designed to protect borrowers delay
but do not prevent foreclosure. Conditional on a loan being underwater, these laws do not
increase the probability of cure. Collins et al. (2011) test the extent to which distressed
mortgage borrowers benefit from different types of State foreclosure polices. They find
that judicial foreclosure proceedings and foreclosure prevention initiatives are associated
recourse and non-recourse States and find higher mortgage default rates in the latter.
Chan et al. (2016) examine how factors affecting mortgage default spill over to other credit
markets. They find that, while non-recourse mortgage laws increase mortgage default,
they are associated with lower credit card default. Gianinazzi et al. (2019) investigate
default behaviour in Europe, where all mortgages have lender recourse and conclude that
many households default when the value of the house is greater than the outstanding
mortgage balance. They find this result puzzling because it is suboptimal. The authors
rationalise it by arguing that, under recourse, the fear of a decline in house prices pushes
these households to anticipate their default decision, thereby ‘leaving money on the table’.
While these papers focus on individual aspects on limited liability, one contribution of
this paper is to encompass default, renegotiation and loan pricing in an integrated setting.
We consider this an important aspect, as these elements are all equilibrium outcomes of
the strategic interaction between borrowers and lenders, which we show in our model.
The second strand of the literature this paper relates to deals with discrepancies between
Government-Sponsored Enterprises (GSEs) and the private market. Most notably, Hurst
et al. (2016) find that despite large regional variation in predictable default risk, GSE
mortgage rates for otherwise identical loans do not vary spatially. In contrast, they find
that the private market does set interest rates which vary with local risk. In this regard,
Dagher and Sun (2016) find similar results for credit supply by exploiting an exogenous
cutoff in loan eligibility to GSE guarantees. They find that judicial requirements reduce
the supply of credit only for jumbo loans, which are ineligible for GSE guarantees.
In this paper we connect these two strands of the literature by analysing default and
renegotiation choices by borrowers and lenders, as well as loan pricing, and to highlight
the difference in pricing between private and public investors.
Some other papers have studied mortgage contracts and default decisions through the lens
of a dynamic heterogeneous agents model in general equilibrium. Some examples of such
models are Kaplan et al. (2017) and Guren et al. (2018). Guren et al. (2018) investigate the
interaction of adjustable and fixed-rate mortgage contracts with monetary policy. Kaplan
et al. (2017) propose a life-cycle model of housing decisions with both idiosyncratic and
aggregate shocks. Their goal is to replicate the macroeconomic dynamics observed in
the data during the Great Recession. These papers focus exclusively on non-recourse
mortgages.
In what follows, we present a model of debt renegotiation where the strategic choices of
lenders and borrowers depend on the extent to which recourse is enforced. In the model,
both house prices and the income of the borrower are stochastic. In some states of the
world, the household has enough income to pay their mortgage, whereas in other states of
the world it does not. Likewise, in some states of the world, the house value is higher than
the mortgage amount, i.e. the household has positive equity, whereas in other states of
the world the house value is lower, i.e. the mortgage is underwater. Households who can
afford to meet their payments, but whose mortgage is underwater, may find it optimal
to default, in particular on instances where it is unlikely that they will be liable with
their personal assets after default. Lenders who know this may find it optimal to offer
these households a renegotiated mortgage price in order to prevent them from walking
away from their obligations. At the same time, the price of these loans will reflect these
mechanisms.
We test the predictions of this model exploiting the difference in mortgage laws in
However, one result is at odds with our model: there appears to be no significant difference
in the interest rate charged on loans across State borders. Importantly, this finding adds
to the notion that GSEs do not appropriately price regional differences in the likelihood
of default, as pointed out by Hurst et al. (2016). We further investigate this by using
loan application data from loans that were sold to private and public buyers. We find
a statistically and economically significant difference in loan rates in the private market,
as opposed to the findings on GSE pricing. We hence advance to the debate on the
differences in pricing between private and public entities by including its interaction with
limited liability.
These results have non-negligible economic and policy implications. Since observable
differences in local mortgage regulation yield different ex-ante predictable default risk, the
lack of price discrimination implies mispricing by GSEs. This is an important distortion in
a multi-trillion dollar market. The GSE’s single rate policy across jurisdictions generates
demand for homes in limited liability jurisdictions, which could generate divergence in
In sum, this paper contributes to the literature along several dimensions. First, we
law. Other features of the model, such as stochastic income and house prices enhance
its richness and permit a better characterisation of the equilibria in different states of
the world. This is needed to formalise pricing of mortgages theoretically, taking into
empirical literature, which has studied default and renegotiation individually in partial
equilibrium by using this model as a guide for the empirical testing of its implications.
The conclusions of the model are non-trivial. Ex-post, i.e. once a mortgage contract
is sealed, the bargaining power given to borrowers by limited liability intuitively points
to higher default and renegotiation. Yet, ex-ante lenders know the limited liability law
and could be expected to adjust their strategies accordingly, via higher prices or ex-
default. The model suggests that equilibrium pricing should be different but does not
point to less renegotiation offering, as in this setting it would represent a non-credible
threat.
While the data confirms model predictions regarding default and renegotiation, we find
mispricing of ex-ante known strategic default risk in GSEs. This represents an additional
also contribute to the literature that has studied loan pricing by GSEs by highlighting
The rest of the paper is organised as follows. Section 2 proposes a simple model of
the strategic interactions between lenders and borrowers and outlines the optimal rates
of default, renegotiation, and loan prices. Section 3 describes the data and explains
the identification strategy. Section 4 lays out the results for the empirical tests of the
model predictions and elaborates on the loan pricing difference between private and public
investors. Finally, Section 5 concludes.
This model draws from Bester (1994) model of debt renegotiation with collateral, where
we incorporate lender recourse. There are two time periods t = {0, 1}. Consider a house-
hold who wants to buy a house. The house has a purchase price R in period 0. In period
1, the house changes value stochastically to R(s), where s ∈ {sH , sL } denotes the state of
the world. We assume sH realises with probability n, and sL with probability 1 − n. The
household has no initial wealth so it borrows an amount M = R to purchase the property.
In t = 1, the household will have to pay an amount P equal to the principal plus some
income, which can be either high, YH , with probability p, or low, YL with probability 1−p.
There is asymmetric information about the realisation of income, but the market value
information implies that the lender cannot write a contract contingent on income.
In the event of default, the bank can choose to foreclose the property, which yields a
return of ΦR(s) (where Φ < 1 represents the recovery rate considering foreclosure costs),
If the bank chooses to foreclose the property, and in order to model the mortgage
recourse laws outlined in the previous section, we assume that after foreclosure, there is
a judge ruling about the deficiency judgement, which can entitle the bank to seize the
household’s income for the difference between the amount owed, P , and the amount re-
covered in foreclosure, ΦR(s). We assume the judge rules for a deficiency judgement with
probability λ. The limited liability case, or non-recourse, is the nested case where the
It is clear that in the event of a low income realisation, the household is forced to de-
fault. With a high income realisation, however, the household may default strategically.
Then, the right to foreclose, together with the extent of lender recourse play an important
To sum up, a debt contract specifies a payment amount P , and entitles the lender
to seize the borrower’s personal assets (income) with exogenous probability λ. Lender
recourse is a threat that may induce the high income household to pay. At the same time,
the extent of lender recourse will affect the incentives for the lender to renegotiate and
offer a lower payment price. This is because, under limited liability, i.e. non-recourse, by
not renegotiating the bank may be committing to an ex post inefficient outcome. This
happens when the foreclosure value of the property is lower than the potential renegotiated
N ature
1−p p
Household Household
d 1−d
N ature N ature
(YL − P 0 + R(s), (YH − P 0 + R(s),
P0 − M) P0 − M)
1−λ λ 1−λ λ
(YL , (YH ,
ΦR(s) − M ) ΦR(s) − M )
(max{YH − (P − ΦR(s)), 0},
(max{YL − (P − ΦR(s)), 0}, ΦR(s) + min{(P − ΦR), YH } − M )
ΦR(s) + min{(P − ΦR(s)), YL } − M )
where p denotes the probability of high income, d denotes the probability with
which the household chooses to default, r denotes the probability with which the bank
chooses to renegotiate the payment amount, and λ indicates the probability of a deficiency
judgement. The dotted area indicates the information set of the bank in the second stage.
It observes that the household has defaulted, but it doesn’t know whether this default
was strategic, i.e. whether the household has high income. The payoffs of the household
and the bank are reported below the ending nodes, respectively.
In order to simplify the game and to focus on the most interesting parts of the mech-
anism, we make the following assumptions about the relative values of the parameters:
Assumption 1. YH > P > YL . The household can only afford the mortgage payment
amount if it receives a high realisation of income.
Assumption 2. ΦR(s) < YL . The foreclosure value of the house is lower than the
low realisation of income in all states of the world s.
This assumption yields the interesting case where the bank would be able to recover
more by renegotiating than by foreclosing the property.
Assumption 3. P − ΦR(s) > YL . The low income household cannot afford the
deficiency judgement for all s.
From the assumption that YH > P it is clear that YH > P − ΦR(s), i.e. the high in-
come household can always afford the deficiency judgement. If the low income household
could also pay the deficiency judgement, i.e. if YL > P − ΦR(s), then the asymmetry of
information around the realisation of income would be irrelevant to the bank’s decision to
renegotiate because it would get the same expected return whether the household has high
or low income. We impose P − ΦR(s) > YL in order to focus on the more interesting case
where asymmetric information about the borrower’s realisation of income, together with
the fact that the low income household cannot pay the deficiency judgement, introduces
an interesting mechanism for the renegotiation of the price.
It is clear that if P 0 > YL , the low income household cannot afford the renegotiated
price, and will pay at most YL , so the renegotiation price must be equal to the low real-
ization of income.
In order to characterise the equilibria of the game, it is important to note two cases:
Assumption 4. R(sL ) < P < R(sH ). The values of the house in different states of
the world are such that the repayment price of the mortgage falls between them. That is,
the low value of the house is lower than the price of the mortgage, while the high value of
the house is higher, i.e. the mortgage is underwater when sL realises.
In the case of positive equity, i.e. state sH , the equilibria of this game imply no default
and no renegotiation. The borrower would not find it optimal to give up the house when
they can afford the mortgage, given that the house value is higher than the payment
amount unless it gets a renegotiation offer. In turn, the lender would not find it optimal
to renegotiate if they know this is the case. In fact, by choosing r = 0 the lender can
guarantee that the borrower will choose d = 0 since for the high income household
where the inequality comes from the fact that λ ∈ [0, 1] and P < R(sH ).
In state sL , when the mortgage is underwater, one can show that the dominant strategy
is not to default if YH realises, i.e. d = 0 unless
P − R(sL )
λ≤ (1)
P − ΦR(sL )
In this case, the lender will choose r = 1 if
YL ≥ ΦR(sL ) + λ[(1 − p)YL + p(P − ΦR(sL ))], i.e.
YL − ΦR(sL ) (2)
λ≤
p(P − ΦR(sL )) + (1 − p)YL
In the case where (2) holds with equality (and therefore (3) as well), the lender will
first observe the borrower’s strategy, and choose r = 0 if d = 0, or mix r ∈ (0, 1) if d = 1.
and r=0 independently of λ. If P > R(s) the is a pure strategy equilibrium when condition
(1) and (2) are satisfied with strict inequality with d = 1 and r = 0, while if (1) and (3)
are satisfied with strict inequality, the equilibrium is given by d = 1 and r = 1; therefore,
when (1) is satisfied with strict inequality and (3) is satisfied with equality, any r ∈ (0, 1)
and d = 1 is an equilibrium, and when (1) is satisfied with equality and (3) is satisfied
with strict inequality, any d ∈ (0, 1) and r = 1 is an equilibrium.
The equilibria of this game will therefore depend on the value of λ and the relative
position of thresholds (1) and (2) when they hold with equality. Figure 3 provides a
graphical representation of the equilibria as a function of λ when when (1) > (2). As can
because high lender recourse imposes too high a cost for the high income household to
default, as it may risk a deficiency judgement. Knowing this, the lender chooses to not
renegotiate. As lender recourse decreases, the borrower starts facing higher incentives to
default, as the risk of a deficiency judgement is lower. When (1) holds with equality, there
is no renegotiation and the borrower mixes between default and repayment. For values
of lambda between (1) and (2), it is optimal for the household to default, as the risk of
a deficiency judgement is below the threshold, but it is still not optimal for the lender
still high enough such that in expectation they would recover more from the judgement
than from the low renegotiated price YL . For λ below (2), the incentive for renegotiation
kicks in for the lender, as the probability of a deficiency judgement is too low and hence the
renegotiated price is higher than the expected recovery value from a foreclosed property.
Equilibria for the cases where (1) < (2) and (1) = (2) can be found in Appendix A. In
all cases, the equilibria with default and renegotiation appear as λ decreases. Hence, the
testable implication is that default and renegotiation are higher in non-recourse States.
We will test this in the next Section.
We now turn to the pricing decision by the bank. With bank competition, a risk-
neutral bank will set a repayment price P in t = 0 so as to set the expected value of
the game in t = 1 equal to zero. The bank knows the value of λ, and it anticipates the
equilibrium of the game for each state of the world. Hence, there are three cases:
the equilibrium where d = 0 and r = 0. The expected value of the game is then
h i
(1 − p) Φ(nRH + (1 − n)RL ) + λYL − M + p(P − M ) = 0 (4)
so
(1 − p) h i
Pλ>(1) = M − Φ(nRH + (1 − n)RL ) − λYL + M (5)
p
Second, when (1) > λ > (2), the bank anticipates that the household will default if
the low house value realises. Therefore the expected value of the game is
h i
n (1 − p)[ΦRH + λYL − M ] + p(P − M )
h i (6)
+(1 − n) (1 − p)[ΦRL + λYL − M ] + p[ΦRL + λP − M ] = 0
so
(1 − p) [M − λYL − nΦRH − (1 − n)ΦRL ]
P(1)>λ>(2) =
p n + (1 − n)λ
(7)
M − φRL
+
n + (1 − n)λ
Third, when λ < (2), the bank anticipates that under the low realisation of the house
value the household will default, and it also finds it optimal to renegotiate, that is, d = 1
and r = 1. The expected value of the game is then
h i
n (1 − p)[ΦRH + λYL − M ] + p(P − M )
(8)
+(1 − n)[YL − M ] = 0
so
(1 − p) M (1 − n)
Pλ<(2) = [M − ΦRH − λYL ] + + [M − YL ] (9)
p n np
This model outlines the mechanism we want to highlight and provides testable impli-
cations. Namely, that for higher levels of lender recourse, underwater borrowers default
at a higher rate even when they have the means to pay for their mortgage. Lenders are
incentivised to renegotiate the price of the mortgage in cases where lender recourse is
low, as is the case in limited liability States. Loan prices therefore should reflect this.
However, as we will see in the next Section, Government Sponsored Enterprises such as
Fannie Mae, do not set loan prices differently across jurisdictions with different levels of
lender recourse. The fact that in the US most mortgages are bought by GSEs, which
are government-guaranteed, implies that in the end this deadweight loss is borne by the
taxpayer. We now turn to empirically verify the relationship between recourse laws and
This database contains acquisition data from all the mortgage loans acquired by Fannie
Mae, together with monthly performance data of said loans. Acquisition data includes
variables such as the seller name, original unpaid balance, original loan term, origination
date, original loan-to-value (LTV) ratio, original debt-to-income (DTI) ratio, borrower
credit score (FICO score), loan purpose, property type and mortgage insurance percent
and type. Performance data includes variables such as current interest rate, current
unpaid balance, loan age, remaining months to maturity, delinquency status, last paid
instalment date, foreclosure date, foreclosure costs, asset recovery costs and other costs,
taxes, net sale proceeds and other proceeds and principal forgiveness amount. Location
data of the property is also available. In particular, the State, the Metropolitan Statistical
Area (MSA) and the 3-digit Zip code are reported. Data is available on a monthly basis
We focus exclusively on purchase loans for principal home, to abstract from the dif-
ference in default incentives that may be present for mortgage loans used for investment
purposes. We consider a loan to have defaulted once it is over 90 days delinquent, as is
standard in the literature. However, we note that our results are robust to other definitions
of default.1
The Home Mortgage Disclosure Act (HMDA) Database contains the universe of all
mortgage loan applications filed by reporting banks in the United States. Banks are
obliged to report if their balance sheet size is above a certain threshold. The information
on each application includes loan characteristics such as the loan amount and the purpose
of the loan (purchase, refinance or home improvement); borrower and co-borrower char-
acteristics such as income, race and gender; and characteristics of the property such as its
geographical location (Metropolitan Statistical Area, census tract, State, ...), occupancy
and type of dwelling (single-family, multifamily, ...).
In addition, the database includes information about whether the loan was granted or
1
For instance, we consider a loan to have defaulted if it has been delinquent for over 90 days at any
point in time and has not gone back to current status in the 12 months prior to the end of its reporting
life, i.e. no recovery in the 12 months prior to it being sold to a third party, foreclosed or otherwise
finalised. Another definition, used by Ghent and Kudlyak (2011), considers a loan to have defaulted
when it is terminated by short sale, deed in lieu or REO sale.
In order to assert the value of the collateral of each mortgage at each point in time, we
use House Price Indices from the Federal Housing Finance Agency. They are estimates
using all transactions of sold houses in a given period and 3-digit ZIP code. These data
are used to estimate the current value of the property and the current equity value of the
mortgage owner.
Following the literature, we compute the market price of a house at time t as follows:
HP It
Pt = P0 (10)
HP I0
where P0 is the purchase price of the house at the time it was acquired by the borrower,
HP It
and HP I0
is the growth of the Housing Price Index in the period between the home
3.4 Identification
recourse and non-recourse States over their life cycle in order to understand the effect of
In order to exploit the discontinuity around the border of recourse and non-recourse
States, we focus on Metropolitan Statistical Areas that are crossed by a State border.
The United States Office of Management and Budget (OMB) delineates metropoli-
tan and micropolitan statistical areas according to published standards that are
Mortgages in the same MSA are arguably exposed to the same economic shocks since
MSAs are delineated by definition to encompass geographical areas that are ‘economi-
cally and socially integrated’. Households on either side of such borders are expected to
be exposed to the same economic shocks, so a difference in our variables of interest can
We define recourse and non-recourse States following Ghent and Kudlyak (2011). The
resulting dataset, in which we select MSAs that are crossed by a State border where
one side of the border enforces recourse and the other does not, spans 6 Metropolitan
Statistical Areas and 9 States, as shown in Table 1. For the Fannie Mae monthly loan
performance data, this implies over 100,000 individual loans over and 4 million observa-
tions, while for the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act loan application data we have almost
In this section we use the Fannie Mae Single Family Loan Performance database to test
the predictions from the model. Table 2 shows the mean values for some key variables,
separated by recourse and non-recourse, together with the p-values for the two-sided t-test
of whether they are statistically different from each other.
different across jurisdictions. This is puzzling, as one would expect the higher risk of
default to be reflected on prices. We will explore this more formally in the course of
magnitude of the difference is only 5 points in the FICO score. One may worry that
there is self-selection into purchasing a house on either side of the border. Lower quality
borrowers may choose to live on the non-recourse side of the border since they expect
they may need to default with higher probability. This would bias our results. However,
this small difference in the credit score is reassuring that borrower quality is similar on
either side of the border.
In addition, Debt-to-income ratios are also very similar. Debt-to-income ratios are a
good way to measure the likelihood of default of a household, as it measures the strain
that their debt places on their finances. The fact that these ratios are similar across
jurisdictions, together with our use of the discontinuity around the border which ensures
similar exposure to economic shocks, indicates that households can be expected to be
able to meet their financial obligations with similar probability. This relates to the model
along parameter p, that is, the probability that the household will receive a low income
realisation and not be able to meet their payments. Furthermore, Loan-to-value ratios
seem to also be similar across jurisdictions, and very close to the regulatory soft limit of
80%. We call this a soft limit because banks are allowed to issue loans for more than 80%
of the value of the property, but in order to do so, they must meet additional requirements,
which makes 80% the effective limit for a wide majority of loans. Overall, it appears that
most variables are similar in recourse and non-recourse States, which allows us to compare
these loans and draw conclusions on the relevant variables of interest.
Next, we formally test the model predictions using different regressions. First, the
model predicts that default rates should be higher in non-recourse States. We test this
using the following Logit regression:
where LD denotes the log odds of default, DN R is a dummy variable that takes value
1 if the house is located in a non-recourse State and 0 otherwise, and Xi,t is the set of
control variables. Control variables include the credit score of the borrower, the remain-
ing loan term, the debt-to-income ratio of the borrower, the loan’s current outstanding
balance and the market price of the property.
Second, the model shows that, when faced with a delinquent borrower, the bank must
choose whether to renegotiate the loan payment or let the household default. The model
predicts that the bank chooses to renegotiate with lower probability as λ decreases. That
implies that we should expect lower levels of renegotiation, conditional on the borrower
between recourse and non-recourse States, conditional on the loan being more than 3
months delinquent, which is consistent with the standard definition of default used in the
literature. The Logit regression in this case reads:
where LM denotes the log odds of loan modification and the rest of the variables are
Finally, the model prediction is that prices should be higher on non-recourse States,
owing to the higher level of ex-ante predictable risk. We run an OLS regression to test
for the difference in loan prices at origination:
where ratei,t is the interest rate agreed in the initial terms, and Xi,t are a set of con-
Table 3 shows the results from these regressions. Columns 1-4 report Logit coefficient
estimates in odds ratios to facilitate the comparison and interpretation of the relative
probability of default and renegotiation between recourse and non-recourse States. Val-
ues above (below) unity indicate a positive (negative) relation between the independent
variable and the likelihood of default or renegotiation. As shown in Column 2, default
rates are higher in non-recourse States, as predicted by the model. In terms of magni-
tude, borrowers in non-recourse States are around 42% more likely to default on their
mortgage.2 Column 4 shows that the probability of loan renegotiation is 28% higher in
non-recourse States. This result is also in line with the model’s predictions.
Moving on to pricing, Column 8 shows a puzzling result: the difference in the interest
rate between recourse and non-recourse loans is economically negligible at less than 1bp.
In addition, the sign of this difference is the opposite of what is predicted in the model.
In a regression specification with no time or MSA fixed effects, we find that this difference
is not statistically significant. Recalling that these results come from Fannie Mae’s loan
GSEs. In addition to Hurst et al. (2016), who find that GSEs do not correctly price
regional risk, we show that such enterprises do not take into account ex-ante predictable
non-recourse risk. In order to shed light on this issue, in the next section we take a step
2
These results are qualitatively robust if we only use the cross-section of loans rather than the full
panel. In the baseline, we opt to use a period by period approach to account for time spent in delinquency
and possibility of cure. This also allows including running variables as controls, such as house price, in
line with the model.
In this section we focus on loan applications data in order to examine whether there are
differences in loan demand, loan origination, and loan sales that could explain the pricing
puzzle outlined in the previous section.
Table 4 shows the mean values for some key variables in the HMDA Dataset, separated
by recourse and non-recourse, together with the p-values for the two-sided t-test of whether
they are statistically different from each other.
Both origination rates and sales to third parties are higher in recourse States. The
average income of the applicant is higher in non-recourse States, whereas the median
income is equal across jurisdictions, indicating the presence of outliers. Loan amounts
of all received applications, as well as those of accepted loans, are significantly different
in statistical terms, but are very similar in economic terms, differing by roughly $1,500.
burden that the loan repayment poses on the borrowers’ payment capacity, hence higher
loan-to-income is associated with a higher risk of default. The fact that recourse States
display higher loan-to-income ratios of granted loans may indicate that lenders are more
willing to take on risk in recourse States because they have a higher recovery ratio given
that they can seize the borrowers’ personal assets in the event of default.
border. We can therefore conclude that any differences in the probability to originate a
loan are due to differences in limited liability.
Figure 5 illustrates the differences in reasons for denial. The most common reason
for denial is the credit history of the borrower in both types of States. The second most
frequent reason in recourse States is the debt-to-income ratio, followed by the value of
the collateral (the real estate property). Notably, this order is reversed in non-recourse
States, indicating that collateral value is more important to lenders in States with limited
liability. This is intuitive since limited liability implies that the lender may be limited
in how much they can recover from the borrower in case of default, making the value of
Notes: The height of the bars in the histograms indicate the frequency of dif-
ferent reasons for loan denial split by recourse and non-recourse States. Source:
Home Mortgage Disclosure Act Database and authors own calculations, 2004-
2016.
up to the Financial Crisis in 2007, and ever since, it has become increasingly evident that
the business model of many lenders is to originate mortgages and sell them to third parties,
thereby eliminating credit risk from their balance sheets. Figure 6 contains information
about the proportion of loans that were sold to a third party in the year of its origination
It can be seen from the Figure that lenders sell just under 70% of their loans to third
parties. The most common purchasers are State Agencies, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac.
Banks sell slightly more non-recourse loans than recourse loans.
Notes: The height of the bars in the histograms indicate the percentage of
loans kept on the issuer’s balance sheet or sold to a range of public and private
purchasers split by recourse and non-recourse States. Source: Home Mortgage
Disclosure Act Database, 2004-2016.
We would like to examine how recourse affects the willingness of banks to grant a loan
loan-to-income is associated with a higher risk of default since the loan obligation weighs
heavier on the borrower’s ability to pay. We use a Logit model of the following form:
where LO are the log odds of a loan being originated; DN R is a dummy variable that
3
The only further borrower characteristics included in HMDA are self-reported ethnicity, race and
gender. Results are robust to including this set of controls.
interaction term between the non-recourse dummy and the loan-to-income ratio.
We also run a Logit model of the same form to assess the difference in the probability
of selling a loan to a third party:
Table 5 shows the results of these regressions. The interpretation of interaction terms in
Logit regression needs careful consideration. First, it is worth noting that the regression
results are expressed in terms of log odds. While Logit models are linear in log odds,
they are not linear in other metrics such as probabilities. We want to be able to interpret
the results of these regressions in terms of the difference in the probability of originating
a loan between recourse and non-recourse, conditional on the ex-ante risk of the loan as
proxied by the loan-to-income ratio. This probability difference will therefore depend on
the different values of the model variables. Furthermore, the interaction term is composed
4
While we follow Dell’Ariccia et al. (2012) in the use of loan-to-income as a key variable to measure
the riskiness of a mortgage, results are comparable if we use income instead.
We therefore use the margins of responses to retrieve the estimated probabilities of orig-
ination and sale for recourse and non-recourse. We then plot the differences in estimated
probabilities for different values of loan-to-income, together with their 95% confidence
As can be seen, banks are less likely to originate loans in non-recourse States, and this
probability is decreasing in the loan-to-income ratio. This is an intuitive result since non-
recourse loans can be considered ‘riskier’ because of limited liability. For a given level of
LtI risk, banks would rather lend in a State where they can seize the borrower’s assets in
the event of default. At the same time, banks are less likely to sell non-recourse loans to
Notes: The solid line plots the difference in the probability of origination and
sale between recourse and non-recourse States for different levels of loan-to-
income ratios (a proxy of the riskiness of the loan). The dashed lines trace the
95% confidence intervals. Source: Home Mortgage Disclosure Act Database
and authors own calculations, 2004-2016.
One of the striking results from Table 3 is that for loans bought by Fannie Mae, the
interest rate at origination does not differ between recourse and non-recourse loans. Given
that non-recourse loans are expected to have a lower recovery rate in the event of default,
one could expect the interest rate for these loans to be higher. We ask whether the fact
that the interest rate at origination does not differ across jurisdictions for loans that were
sold to Fannie Mae is due to the fact that banks anticipated they would sell this loans to
a third party and therefore did not have an incentive to price in their risk. To this end,
we use the HMDA loan application database to test whether loans that were not sold to
that a loan with similar characteristics would have in the market. Banks must report the
spread (difference) between the annual percentage rate (APR) and the applicable average
prime offer rate if the spread is equal to or greater than 1.5 percentage points for first-lien
loans. Due to this, there is a selection issue on the spread variable: we do not observe the
spread if it is lower than the reporting threshold. In order to overcome this issue, some
papers in the literature, for instance Pennington-Cross and Ho (2008), have applied the
Heckman two-stage procedure for selection correction to this dataset. Hence, we run the
following Probit regression:
Yi = δXi + ui (16)
where Yi takes value 1 if the spread of loan application i is observed (i.e. if the
spread is greater than 1.5 percentage points), and Xi is a set of variables that influence
the probability of the spread being above the reporting threshold. We use all available
borrower information in Xi , which includes income and dummy variables for self-reported
race and gender.
φ(X δ̂)
We then use δ̂ to compute the inverse Mills ratio, λ(X δ̂) = Φ(X δ̂)
, and it to different
second stage regressions in order to answer different questions. First, we examine the
difference in the spread between recourse and non-recourse States using the following
regression:
where DN R takes value 1 for non-recourse loans and 0 otherwise. Then, we ask whether
the spread is higher for loans that are sold to third parties, and whether this differs across
where DSold takes value 1 for loans that were sold to third parties and 0 otherwise and
DN R DSold is an interaction term of both dummy variables.
Hurst et al. (2016) show that public agencies such as Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac
are less efficient at pricing mortgage loan risk than the private market. They argue
that this price difference leads to cross subsidisation from low risk mortgages to high
risk mortgages. We explore whether this issue extends to the difference in risk between
recourse and non-recourse loans in the following way:
where DP rivate takes value 1 for loans that were sold to private buyers (securitisation
agencies, commercial banks, insurance companies, funds...) and 0 for loans that were sold
to public buyers (Fannie Mae, Freddie Mac, Ginnie Mae and Farmer Mac).
The results of these regressions are laid out in Table 6. Regression 17 is shown in
Column 1. The loan spread is significantly lower in non-recourse States which is a sur-
loan pricing for loans that were sold to third parties, and among those, whether there is a
difference between private and public buyers. Column 2 presents the results of Regression
18. The constant term implies that the average spread of a recourse loan that was kept
by the bank is around 6.7%. The coefficient of DN R captures the difference in the interest
rate between non-recourse and recourse for unsold loans. The interest rate on unsold
loans is 24bp lower for non-recourse loans. The coefficient for DSold equals the difference
between sold and kept loans in recourse States. It implies that, among recourse loans, the
spread is around 5bp lower for those that were sold. The coefficient for the interaction
loan sales the spread is higher for non-recourse mortgages. This result is intuitive, since
non-recourse implies a higher rate of default as predicted by the theoretical model, and
shown empirically in the previous section. We note that there may be an endogeneity
issue in interacting DN R and DSold , as we have shown before that non-recourse loans are
less likely to be sold to third parties than their recourse counterparts.
This phenomenon is further investigated in Column 3, where the pool of sold loans
is split between private and public buyers, as outlined in regression 19. The coefficient
for DP rivate indicates the difference between loans sold to private and public agents in
recourse States. The estimate of this difference is almost 200bp, which is an order of
magnitude higher than the DSold coefficient in Column 1. This implies that most of the
variation in the spread of sold loans is driven by pricing behaviour of private investors.
The coefficient for the interaction term DN R DP rivate is also positive and statistically
significant. It means that for non-recourse loans, private purchasers demand a higher
spread than public agencies. This suggests that private markets price in the higher risk
associated with non-recourse loans (or limited liability) to a greater extent than their
public counterparts. We conclude from this analysis that banks do charge significantly
higher interest rates on non-recourse loans when selling the loan to a private third party,
while loans bought by Fannie Mae seem to have the same interest rate at origination, as
was shown in Table 2. These results are in contrast with Hurst et al. (2016), who find
that interest rates do not vary across recourse and non-recourse States for both private
and public loans.
The rise of household indebtedness before the Financial Crisis combined with high
default rates was a root cause of the Great Recession and underlined the role of consumer
finance for the macroeconomy. Mortgage debt in particular, constitutes two-thirds of US
household total debt, and it currently follows an increasing trend.
While there are several factors that determine the rate of mortgage default, such as
adverse economic shocks that leave households unable to honour their debt, default may
also be a voluntary choice, commonly referred to as strategic default. One particular
aspect the household may consider before choosing to default is whether there is limited
liability in place. Under limited liability, the lender is not allowed to seize the household’s
assets after default. On the contrary, under lender recourse, the lender is allowed to claw
While the literature has analysed the consequences of limited liability, such as default
rates, loan renegotiation or forbearance, and interest rates in isolation, we embody all
these features in our analysis as equilibrium outcomes of the strategic interaction between
borrowers and lenders.
We use a model of default and renegotiation to highlight the mechanisms at hand, and
crossed by a State border, where one State enforces lender recourse and the other does
not. Given than MSAs are defined by the US Census Bureau as a core area containing a
substantial population nucleus, together with adjacent communities having a high degree
of economic and social integration with that core’, we argue that borrowers on either
side of the border are exposed to the same economic shocks, and the difference in their
In the model, both house prices and the income of the borrower are stochastic. In some
states of the world, the household has enough income to pay their mortgage, whereas in
other states of the world it does not. Likewise, in some states of the world, the house
value is higher than the mortgage amount, i.e. the household has positive equity, whereas
in other states of the world the house value is lower, i.e. the mortgage is underwater.
Households who can afford to meet their payments, but whose mortgage is underwater,
may find it optimal to default, in particular on instances where it is unlikely that they
will be liable with their personal assets after default. Lenders who know this may find it
optimal to offer these households a renegotiated mortgage price in order to prevent them
from walking away from their obligations. At the same time, the price of these loans will
reflect these mechanisms. Loan rates are expected to be higher under limited liability,
because of the higher ex-ante predictable default and renegotiation risk, and the lower
These predictions are confirmed by the data. In fact, non-recourse loans are around
42% more likely to default, and 28% more likely to receive a renegotiation offer. However,
while the model predicts that loan rates should be higher for non-recourse loans (as they
have a higher expected default rate), loan performance data from Fannie Mae does not
confirm this. This lack of price differentiation has been noted in the literature, for instance
by Hurst et al. (2016). They note that Government-Sponsored Enterprises (GSEs) fail
to appropriately price in regional differences in ex-ante predictable default risk. In this
paper, regional risk is expected to be the same within each MSA, as they are by definition
integrated economic areas. However, we still find a lack of price differentiation on the side
of GSEs, which fail to account for the risk of default and renegotiation brought about
by the difference in legislation. We test this by using additional data from the Home
that the difference in default risk implied by different recourse laws is indeed priced into
loans that are securitised by private investors. Overall, rates on non-recourse loans sold
to private investors are around 22bp higher than their recourse counterparts.
These results overall speak to the distortions imposed by the differences in limited
liability across States, together with the heterogeneity of public and private market par-
ticipants. Given the size of the market and the importance of mortgages in households’
balance sheets, our findings have important macroeconomic implications. Further theoret-
ical research should fill the gap in how these mechanisms interact in general equilibrium.
Figure 8a shows the same graphic representation for the case when (1) < (2). In this
case, for values of λ weakly greater or smaller than the threshold, the above logic still
holds. However, for values between (1) and (2), the household would find it optimal
not to default, so the lender would not renegotiate. For λ = (1), the borrower would
mix between defaulting and repaying. If it defaults, then the lender would mix between
renegotiating or not. The same logic holds when λ = (1) = (2), which is represented in
figure 8b.
Atkeson, A. (1991). International lending with moral hazard and risk of repudiation.
Chan, S., Haughwout, A., Hayashi, A., and Van der Klaauw, W. (2016). Determinants of
mortgage default and consumer credit use: the effects of foreclosure laws and foreclosure
Collins, J. M., Lam, K., and Herbert, C. E. (2011). State mortgage foreclosure policies
and lender interventions: Impacts on borrower behavior in default. Journal of Policy
Curtis, Q. (2014). State foreclosure laws and mortgage origination in the subprime. The
Dagher, J. and Sun, Y. (2016). Borrower protection and the supply of credit: Evidence
Dell’Ariccia, G., Igan, D., and Laeven, L. (2012). Credit Booms and Lending Standards:
Evidence from the Subprime Mortgage Market. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking,
44:367–384.
Gerardi, K., Lambie-Hanson, L., and Willen, P. S. (2013). Do borrower rights improve bor-
rower outcomes? evidence from the foreclosure process. Journal of Urban Economics,
73(1):1–17.
Gianinazzi, V., Pelizzon, L., and Plazzi, A. (2019). Residential mortgage defaults and
Grossman, H. I. and Van Huyck, J. B. (1988). Sovereign debt as a contingent claim: Ex-
cusable default, repudiation, and reputation. American Economic Review, 78(5):1088–
1097.
Hart, O. and Moore, J. (1998). Default and renegotiation: A dynamic model of debt.
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(1):1–41.
Hurst, E., Keys, B. J., Seru, A., and Vavra, J. (2016). Regional redistribution through
Jeske, K. (2006). Private international debt with risk of repudiation. Journal of political
Economy, 114(3):576–593.
Kaplan, G., Mitman, K., and Violante, G. L. (2017). The housing boom and bust: Model
Li, W. and Oswald, F. (2017). Recourse and residential mortgages: The case of nevada.
Journal of Urban Economics, 101:1–13.
Meador, M. (1982). The effects of mortgage laws on home mortgage rates. Journal of
Mian, A., Sufi, A., and Trebbi, F. (2015). Foreclosures, house prices, and the real economy.
The Journal of Finance, 70(6):2587–2634.
Pennington-Cross, A. and Ho, G. (2008). Predatory lending laws and the cost of credit.
Mirco Balatti
European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; ICMA Centre, Henley Business School, Reading, United Kingdom;
email: [email protected]
Carolina López-Quiles
European Central Bank, Frankfurt am Main, Germany; European University Institute, Florence, Italy;
email: [email protected]