Philip R Lane The Banking Channel of Monetary Policy Tightening in The Euro Area
Philip R Lane The Banking Channel of Monetary Policy Tightening in The Euro Area
Introduction
I will focus in this speech on the banking channel of monetary policy.[1] Starting in December 2021 with the
announcement that net purchases under the pandemic emergency purchase programme (PEPP) would
end in March 2022, the ECB has been tightening its monetary policy stance in response to the
extraordinary surge in inflation amid the pandemic shutdowns, supply bottlenecks and, most importantly,
the energy crisis triggered by Russia’s unjustified war against Ukraine.
For a given inflation outlook, the appropriate level and duration of a restrictive monetary policy stance
depends on how powerfully and how quickly the economy responds to the tightening of monetary policy. In
view of the predominant role of the banking system in credit provision in the euro area, how banks
respond to monetary policy is a central issue in assessing the strength of the transmission mechanism.
Accordingly, in our data-dependent approach to calibrating monetary policy, assessing the strength of the
banking channel of monetary policy tightening is a first-order task for the ECB.
I will discuss some of the challenges in forming a quantitative assessment of monetary policy transmission
via the banking channel.[2] First, I will briefly review the various channels through which banks affect the
transmission process. Second, I will assess how the considerable amount of monetary policy tightening
injected over the last year is being transmitted in the euro area.
In addition to the transmission via interest rates, there are amplification mechanisms that work via the
cost, the availability, and the quality of credit and that are able to generate relatively large real effects even
with relatively small monetary policy changes. The main amplification mechanisms operating via banks are
the balance sheet channel, the bank lending channel and the risk-taking channel.
The balance-sheet channel of monetary policy predicts that a policy rate hike tends to compress asset
prices and weaken activity, thus lowering the net worth of borrowers.[3] This translates into a reduced
capacity to raise external funding for firms: the increase in the external finance premium faced by
borrowers due to a decline in net worth and pledged collateral decreases spending and investment by
more than what is predicted by a short-term policy rate change in a framework abstracting from the
balance sheet channel. The same channel also affects households whose net worth is closely linked to
house prices. The lower value of collateral during a policy tightening therefore triggers higher credit risk
and tighter credit conditions for both firms and households.
The bank-lending channel focuses on the impact of policy tightening on the supply of bank loans to the
economy. First, the supply of loans offered by banks is adversely affected by monetary policy tightening
via an increase in bank funding costs.[4] Second, borrower-lender agency costs further reduce the
willingness of banks to lend during periods of higher monetary policy rates or lower economic activity.[5]
Third, bank balance sheet constraints amplify the contraction in credit availability brought about by policy
tightening.[6] Broadly speaking, higher interest rates increase the opportunity cost of holding the most
liquid assets – overnight deposits – compared with less liquid assets such as term deposits or securities.
Moreover, the unwinding of asset purchases and long-term refinancing operations currently lead to a direct
decline in the liquidity available to banks, limiting their capacity to supply credit.[7]
The third amplification mechanism is the risk-taking channel of monetary policy.[8] This is the channel
through which banks are incentivised to make riskier investments in an environment of lower interest
rates, which reduces incentives to engage in costly monitoring.[9] In addition, asset purchases
programmes extract duration risk from the market, increasing the relative attractiveness of riskier
investments and therefore triggering a portfolio rebalancing that ultimately leads to a reallocation towards
real investments.[10] As such, during the period of highly accommodative monetary policy, this may have
led banks to build up a stock of risky investments. The opposite dynamic may not be operating, as
weak macroeconomic conditions may amplify the strength of monetary policy tightening.[12] In particular,
as aggregate demand falls in response to higher interest rates, banks face both lower demand for loans
and a deterioration in borrower credit risk which further weigh on bank balance sheets. These additional
factors may further strengthen the bank lending channel of monetary policy.
This brief review of the role of banks in monetary policy transmission has highlighted that the balance
sheet channel, the bank lending channel, and the risk-taking channel may be relevant in the transmission
of the current hiking cycle. In addition, amongst other mechanisms, the rise in bank funding costs and the
drop in liquidity may lead to a contraction in credit supply, adversely affecting bank-dependent firms and
households. Next, I will review the incoming evidence on the strength of monetary policy transmission via
the banking system during the current tightening cycle.
Against the backdrop of the tightening of monetary policy, the pass-through to bank funding costs has
proceeded rapidly, most notably for yields on bank bonds (Chart 1).[13] Deposit rates contained the rise in
the interest rate expenses of banks during the initial phase of the tightening cycle. This initial sluggishness
was in part driven by an atypical configuration of interest rates during the negative rates period, in which
many banks kept deposit rates higher than the policy rate (Chart 2, right panel). After this initial period,
interest rates on term deposits have followed the policy rate, while the remuneration of overnight deposits
has remained lower. Overall, these patterns were also seen in past periods of positive interest rates
(Chart 2, left panel).
The limited increase in overnight deposit rates has incentivised depositors to rebalance their portfolios
towards time deposits, after the prolonged period of low interest rates and low term premia in which the
opportunity cost of holding overnight deposit had been negligible. Comparing developments in the euro
area and the United States, while the pass-through to overnight deposit rates is limited in both
jurisdictions, the transmission to time deposits has been considerably stronger in the euro area (Chart 2).
[14]
Chart 1
Euro area bank funding costs
(percentages)
Sources: ECB (BSI, MIR), IHS Markit iBoxx and ECB calculations.
Notes: Daily bank bond yields. Monthly deposit rates on new business volumes weighted by outstanding amounts.
Composite funding cost, calculated as a weighted average of the cost of deposits and market debt funding, with the
respective outstanding amounts on bank balance sheets used as weights.
The latest observations are 4 July 2023 for bond yields and May 2023 for BSI and MIR.
Chart 2
Deposit rate pass-through in the euro area and the United States
In addition to the increases in the key policy interest rates, the gradual unwinding of the asset purchase
programme (APP) and the phase-out of targeted longer-term refinancing operations (TLTRO III) have also
played a role in the transmission of monetary policy through banks.[15] In February this year, we moved to
partial reinvestments under the APP before fully ending reinvestments in July. The ensuing decline in
bonds held by the Eurosystem reduces the amount of duration extraction associated with the outstanding
bond portfolio, and thereby increases term premia. The resulting increase in long-term interest rates
pushes up the pricing of bank loans, ultimately increasing lending rates for firms and households. In
addition, the higher yields on bonds increase their attractiveness as an investment for banks, reducing
their incentives to supply loans.
Chart 3
Impact of the ECB’s monetary policy asset portfolio and TLTRO III on bank lending
conditions
(net percentages)
The phase out of TLTRO III has led banks to partially substitute TLTRO loans with more expensive
sources of funding. While a large share of the voluntary early repayments at the end of last year and early
this year was financed out of outstanding excess liquidity, banks have been more recently raising
alternative funding to cover maturing TLTRO loans, in particular in light of the large amount which matured
in June. The need to replace TLTRO funding requires the issuance of more costly bonds and leads to
greater competition in deposit markets to attract funding. Furthermore, the recalibration of TLTRO in
October 2022 increased the cost of TLTRO borrowing, and restored incentives for voluntary early
repayments. The resulting increase in bank funding costs put upward pressure on lending rates and
downward pressure on credit supply.
Moreover, the winding down of both the TLTROs and the asset purchases has contributed to a rapid
reduction in the central bank excess liquidity available to banks. The combined effect of this outright
reduction in liquidity adds downward pressure on the supply of credit by banks, as already evident in
survey data (Chart 3). In contrast to the expansion phase, banks now report that the ECB monetary policy
asset portfolio and the TLTRO III programme are associated with lower expected lending volumes, as well
as tighter expected credit standards and more restrictive terms and conditions.
Turning to the lending rates for firms, the pass-through of tighter monetary policy to overall financing
conditions has been strong. Higher bank funding costs translated into a strong increase in lending rates to
non-financial corporations, although spreads relative to risk-free rates were somewhat compressed.
Lending rates started to increase in June 2022 ahead of the first ECB rate hike. Compared with past hiking
cycles, the current campaign has seen the most prominent lending rate increase in the euro area – in
terms of both speed and magnitude, also reflecting the unprecedented speed and magnitude of policy rate
increases (Chart 4).
At the same time, loan volumes in the euro area have weakened sharply starting from the end of 2022.
Credit flows have remained stagnant on aggregate for loans and bonds, with some substitution between
the two sources of financing (Chart 5, left panel). The weakening in credit has been stronger than in past
hiking cycles and, while this is partly driven by the unprecedented pace of policy tightening, a model-
based simulation confirms that loan volumes turned around faster than what would have been expected
based on historical regularities, given the path of monetary policy hikes since December 2021 (Chart 5,
right panel).
Chart 4
Lending rates to firms across hiking cycles
(left panel: average monthly flows in EUR billions; right panel: x-axis: years, y-axis: growth rate of credit in deviation
from its growth rate at the start of the cycle (t), in percentage points)
The current tightening cycle has been broadly synchronised among major advanced economies but the
downturn in lending dynamics has been starker in the euro area than in the United States, despite the later
start of the hiking cycle and smaller magnitude of rate hikes to date (Chart 6, right panel). In both the euro
area and the United States, the weakening of loan volumes was associated with a strong tightening of
credit standards, as reported by banks in the euro area Bank Lending Survey (BLS), and in the US Senior
Loan Officer Opinion Survey (SLOOS) (Chart 6, left panel). This evidence points to tighter loan supply in
both economies. This tightening combines the reversal of previously highly accommodative conditions and
the further shift into more restrictive territory in recent times.
Chart 6
Change in credit standards and corporate loan dynamics for United States and the euro
area
(left panel: net percentages, right panel: left: three-month annualised growth rates, right: percentages per annum)
Of course, loan volumes and lending rates are the product of both credit demand and credit supply forces.
Establishing the respective contributions is crucial to understand the underlying sources of credit
fluctuations, even if the underlying credit demand and credit supply schedules are unobservable. While the
evidence from surveys and aggregate data is useful in showing in which direction credit conditions are
travelling more broadly, confounding factors might pose difficulties in interpreting aggregate measures.
Indeed, looking at historical regularities, there is a clear positive correlation between lower bank-level loan
demand and the tightening of credit standards. This is due to several factors. For instance, firms may ask
for fewer loans when their expectations on the economy deteriorate. This may lead to an overestimation of
the role of credit supply if credit demand is not properly estimated. At the same time, banks may informally
discourage their clients from applying for loans and therefore not explicitly reject them. In this case,
considering only the part of credit supply that is not related to credit demand would be an overly
conservative approach that captures only part of the actual change in credit supply.
Increased cost of market-based financing and the phase-out of TLTROs has led to a contraction in bank
credit supply (Chart 7, left panel). Empirical analysis that uses granular data to control for broader
demand conditions and thereby extracts a pure supply shock finds that both the reduction in TLTRO funds
and the increase in bank bond yields lead to a significant reduction in loan supply. Specifically, the
empirical estimates suggest that the decline in TLTRO since the recalibration in October 2022 reduced
quarterly loan growth by about 0.5 percentage points, while the average increase in bank bond yields
since the first rate hike in July 2022 led to a 1.1 percentage point lower quarterly loan growth.
Chart 7
Drivers of loan supply restrictions and Loan Supply Indicator
Sources: ECB (AnaCredit, iBSI, MOPDB), IHS Markit iBoxx, and ECB calculations.
Notes: Coefficients from a regression of three-months ahead loan supply shocks (as in Amiti and Weinstein 2018), on
TLTRO over assets, and level of bank bond yields, and bank fixed effects and country-time fixed effects. Sample
December 2019 to November 2022. Standard error clustered at the country-time level. The right panel shows the
Loan Supply Indicator (LSI) as in Altavilla, Darracq-Paries and Nicoletti (2019) and a smoothed version of it.[16]
The latest observations are November 2022 for the left chart and the first quarter of 2023 for the LSI.
The role of credit supply can also be isolated by using soft information from surveys. Individual replies to
the Bank Lending Survey can be used to construct a Loan Supply Indicator (LSI) that purges credit
standards from changes in loan demand and prevailing macroeconomic conditions (Chart 7, right panel).
[17]
This indicator allows us to gauge how much of the observed slowdown in credit conditions is due to
supply effects over and above the impact of monetary policy on credit demand. The indicator shows a
marked contraction in loan supply since the start of the tightening cycle. This shift in loan supply conditions
is even more remarkable in view of the highly accommodative loan supply environment in the years before
the pandemic.
Credit supply restrictions typically lead to a significant drop in real economic activity. Augmenting a macro-
financial empirical model with the LSI indicates that a credit supply shock leading to a 1 percentage point
decline in loan volumes results in a 0.3 percentage point reduction in real GDP (Chart 8). A meta-analysis
shows that this quantification is in line with the results of other empirical studies that use different models
and cover different sample periods and jurisdictions. Overall, the results indicate that a credit supply shock
leads to a contraction in the volume of credit intermediated by banks that in turn generates a substantial
reduction in output, compared to the baseline path.
Chart 8
The impact of credit supply shocks on real GDP
(percentage points)
Sources: Gilchrist, S. and Zakrajšek, E. (2011); Barnett, W. A. and Thomas, R. L. (2014); Mumtaz, H., Pinter, G., and
Theodoridis, K. (2018); Basset, C. et al. (2014); Altavilla, C., Darracq Paries, M., and Nicoletti, G. (2019); Chen, K.,
Higgins, P., and Zha, T. (2021); Gambetti, L. and Musso, A. (2017); Mendicino, C. et al. (2019); Jermann, U. and
Quadrini, V. (2012); Gerali, A. et al. (2010); Darracq Paries, M., Kok Sorensen, C., and Rodriguez-Palenzuela, D.
(2011); World Economic Outlook, IMF (2023); Barauskaitė, I. et al. (2022); Moccero, D. N., Darracq Paries, M., and
Maurin, L. (2014); Ciccarelli, M., Maddaloni, A., and Peydro, J.-L. (2015). [18]
Notes: The chart shows the distribution of the impact on real GDP of a credit supply shock across studies. The vertical
line represents the estimate obtained by using the LSI as an external instrument in a Bayesian vector autoregressive
(BVAR) model to quantify the impact of a credit supply shock on real GDP growth. The solid blue line shows the kernel
density of the distribution of 15 estimates, truncated at the minimum and maximum estimate. The x-axis shows the
percentage ppomt decline in GDP cumulated over a three-year horizon of a credit supply shock that reduces loan
growth by 1 percentage point. The median impact across studies is -0.3 percentage point and coincides with the
results of the LSI augmented BVAR.
First, the current tightening consists of both permanent and temporary components. On the one hand, it
involved the unwinding of the extraordinarily supportive monetary policy measures that were in place since
2014 in order to combat chronic below-target inflation and mitigate the downside risks during the
pandemic. In the absence of new shocks that would drive the economy back towards the lower bound, the
policy rate is expected to settle at around two per cent in the medium term and extraordinary measures
such as large-scale quantitative easing and targeted lending programmes are not expected to be re-
introduced. It follows that this normalisation component is expected to be essentially permanent in nature.
On the other hand, the hike of policy rates into restrictive territory during the first half of this year reflects a
more temporary component of the tightening cycle. While the ECB will set policy rates at sufficiently
restrictive levels for sufficiently long to ensure a timely return of inflation to our medium-term two per cent
target, the restrictive component of monetary policy will ultimately be unwound in order to stabilise inflation
at our target rather than unleashing a subsequent phase of chronically below-target inflation.[19] Before the
surge in inflation, it had been widely expected that the “low for long” policy configuration would have
persisted for several more years. Hence, the permanent component of the current tightening cycle might
amplify the banking channel compared to other tightening episodes which only featured a purely cyclical
tightening. In particular, banks may more extensively re-assess credit supply policies in reaction to the
permanent shift in the underlying monetary policy stance.
Second, the current environment of ample liquidity alters the mechanics of the monetary tightening relative
to previous tightening cycles that took place within policy frameworks in which the banking system
operated with a structural liquidity deficit. While the ECB balance sheet is shrinking, the de facto
operational framework for monetary policy is still underpinned by ample liquidity whereby the deposit
facility rate determines money market conditions.[20] The movement of the DFR into positive territory may
induce a “cold potato” effect, in that banks are incentivised to hold on to funds as the DFR is now positive,
contrasting with the period of negative interest rates.[21] At the same time, the significant decline in excess
liquidity as a result of the contraction in the ECB balance sheet may lead to greater heterogeneity in
money market conditions, especially since the distribution of the excess liquidity is uneven across banks.
In turn, this means that the responses to rate hikes are likely to be increasingly heterogeneous across
euro area banks and across member countries, with associated implications for the overall impact of
Third, the strength of the banking channel of monetary policy plausibly differs across supply-driven and
demand-driven inflationary episodes. The fading of a temporary demand shock is associated with lower
incomes and output, amplifying the transmission of monetary policy through the banking channel. In
contrast, the fading out of temporary supply shocks boosts incomes and supply capacity. Currently, this is
the case for the reversal of the surge in energy prices, the easing of supply chain bottlenecks, as well as
the post-pandemic re-normalisation of sectoral supply and demand conditions. In one direction, the
unwinding of a temporary supply shock puts downward pressure on inflation, reducing the scale of
monetary tightening that is required to return inflation to the medium-term target in a timely manner.[23] In
the other direction, the recovery in incomes attenuates some of the transmission mechanisms via the
banking sector, which should also be taken into account in the calibration of monetary policy.
We can turn to asking which factors can affect the effectiveness of our monetary policy, through these
various channels. In general, all else equal, there has been a substantial reduction in financial tail risks on
account of the improvements in the balance sheets of firms and households that were generated by
pandemic-related fiscal transfers and the excess savings accumulated during pandemic shutdowns. The
curtailment of tail risks means that monetary policy is more likely to transmit in an orderly manner, rather
than be disrupted by the emergence of systemic financial stress. Indeed, the health of the balance sheets
of euro area firms and households is reflected in the only-limited deterioration in borrower defaults
observed so far in this tightening cycle.
For firms, in addition to the aggregate improvement in balance sheets, relatively high profits over the last
year and elevated liquid holdings could act as possible countervailing factors. However, there is
substantial variation across firms. The data show that the firms with higher profit growth and higher
accumulated cash tend to be those with relatively lower leverage. In other words, the aforementioned
possible mitigating factors would not benefit firms that most need them: highly leveraged firms still remain
exposed to credit tightening. Moreover, the expected moderation of firm profits over time could strengthen
transmission.
In addition, granular data suggest that younger and smaller firms have been disproportionately affected by
the decline in bank lending (Chart 9). Historically, such firms have been the first to suffer contractionary
credit supply shocks. The more substantial contraction of lending dynamics for young and small firms can
be interpreted as an indicator of a broader credit supply tightening, where banks start protecting their
balance sheets against a deterioration of the payment capacity of borrowers. Given the risk of adverse
selection, banks opt to reduce credit supply volumes rather than simply raise lending rates.[24]
Furthermore, the finding that smaller firms have seen a larger tightening of credit standards is particularly
relevant in view of the central role that SMEs play in the transmission of monetary policy in the euro area,
particularly through the bank lending channel. Such firms, which account for a large share of employment
in the euro area, tend to be more reliant on banks for lending and thus are more likely to experience
Sources: ECB (CSEC, AnaCredit, RIAD), Orbis and ECB calculations. Notes: The chart compares loan rate and
volume dynamics of small and young firms relative to general market movements around the start of the hiking cycle
in July 2022 based on merged AnaCredit-Orbis data. The series are standardised by overall market developments in
rates and volumes, and subsequently to unity at the start of the hiking cycle.
The latest observation is for March 2023.
In assessing the impact of monetary policy tightening on both broader credit risks and the funding
environment, the growing interconnections between non-bank financial intermediaries and the euro area
banking system require close monitoring.[26] These links account for nine percent of total assets and 14
per cent of total liabilities of significant banks in the euro area on average. It follows that shocks to the
non-bank financial sector could increase the credit risks and/or the funding costs of the euro area banking
system. In particular, since higher interest rates broadly reduce the value of assets held by non-bank
financial intermediaries and increase the funding costs of firms that are dependent on market-based
financing, these interconnections represent an important channel through which monetary policy tightening
affects the euro area banking system. Furthermore, since non-banks have become increasingly significant
credit providers in recent years (especially in some market segments), a contraction in credit supply by
non-banks should be incorporated in an overall assessment of monetary transmission, in addition to credit
On the household side, the changing composition of household balance sheets may affect the strength of
the transmission of monetary tightening via banks. In one direction, gross debt to income ratios, which
measure debt servicing capacity, are now higher than in the 2000 and the 2005 tightening episodes, which
would tend to strengthen transmission (Chart 10). In the other direction, there is a now a higher share of
fixed rate mortgages across the euro area, which could reduce the speed of transmission through the
cash-flow channel. However, looking at how the current rate increases have translated into higher rates on
the stock of mortgages, the difference relative to the past hikes does not seem substantial. In other words,
there is no evidence of a more muted pass-through of higher rates to overall mortgage lending.
In relation to the interconnection between housing markets and the banking channel, residential property
makes up a high portion of household wealth. Data for the first quarter of 2023 show a marked slowdown
in the annual growth rate of nominal house prices for the aggregate euro area and outright nominal price
declines in some countries.[28] Reflecting this, the contribution of changes in real estate asset holdings
towards the growth in household net worth has declined. The adverse impact of declining asset values on
household net worth suggests a more powerful balance sheet channel, with banks more reluctant to offer
mortgages or other credit to home-owning households.
Looking more broadly at household balance sheets, households in the aggregate now hold much higher
stocks of liquid financial assets. However, the real value of money holdings has been eroded through
inflation, while capital losses have been incurred on bond holdings. Despite this, data for the first quarter
saw a rebound in the annual growth rate of the net worth of the household, partially driven by
improvements in equity prices during the quarter. In terms of distribution across households, liquid
financial assets are mostly owned by higher-income households, such that many households cannot draw
down liquid financial assets to counter-balance any pressure through debt channels.
Chart 10
Household balance sheet indicators
(percentages)
Moving to the bank lending channel, bank capital and liquidity positions, as well as the duration of their
asset portfolios, affect the strength of transmission. Ample capital and liquidity buffers, high profitability and
appropriate credit risk management are important to maintain the orderly transmission of monetary policy.
Indeed, these factors enabled the euro area banking system to withstand the market turmoil of March
2023 without a severe dislocation of credit supply. In general, compared to the past, financial stability risks
are now more closely monitored by prudential authorities and are also subject to increasing market
scrutiny.[29] Therefore, the actual realisation of financial stress is now less likely compared to a counter-
factual in which banks had much lower capital and liquidity positions.[30] At the same time, since this is in
part due to a more cautious attitude of banks to emerging risks, it may contribute to a reduction in credit
supply when faced with a sustained weakening of borrower creditworthiness.
Similarly, a longer duration of the bond portfolios of banks could translate into higher unrealised losses
from the fall in bond prices, which may amplify the tightening of monetary policy.[31] As downward pressure
on bank profits from these unrealised losses cumulates and aggregate deposit volumes decrease, banks
become increasingly exposed to a tighter liquidity environment and need to step up efforts to secure their
deposit bases. Alongside this, while increased competition on deposit rates encourages transmission on
one side (in relation to dampening demand by households and firms by making it more attractive to hold
deposits), there may be an acceleration of the pass-through of the interest rate hikes to deposit rates and
broader funding conditions to levels incompatible with the target deposit betas of banks. Such deposit
betas underpin the asset and liability management choices of banks and commitment to investors, and
thus a stronger pass-through may translate into increased perceived banking sector risk and a further
reduction in credit supply.
The strength of the risk-taking channel is underpinned by the higher risk perceptions around the
macroeconomic outlook and the lower risk tolerance of individual banks. Increasing concerns about the
credit worthiness of individual borrowers may test the ability of banks to meet capital targets, inducing a
retrenchment from private sector credit. According to the BLS, risk perceptions continue to be an important
driver of the tightening in credit standards. In part, this can reflect a reversal of the impact of the risk-taking
channel during the accommodative phases of monetary policy, as risk tolerance declines and risk
perceptions remain elevated. Lower liquidity on the back of the contraction in the ECB balance sheet
compounds this tightening pressure by removing the leeway of banks to rely on outstanding liquidity to
meet existing financial obligations and shoulder idiosyncratic shocks. Even the net interest income of
banks, which has expanded substantially since the start of the tightening cycle and has supported the
overall profitability of banks, levelled off in the first quarter of this year, amid a stabilisation in
intermediation margins and the stagnation in credit volumes. Exposure to commercial real estate (CRE)
may also lead to an amplification of monetary policy transmission, particularly if values fall in a sustained
manner. Increasing funding costs put additional pressure on this sector, which was already vulnerable due
to the impact of changing working patterns on the demand for office space.[32] Moreover, falling CRE asset
values would lead to a decline in borrower creditworthiness and collateral values, leaving banks exposed
to losses in the event of default. This could drive further declines in lending supply, potentially leading to a
financial accelerator effect if such firms are particularly financially constrained. It should be noted that
despite increased CRE risks in the euro area, these are less severe than in the United States, with
vacancy rates for euro area CRE lower than those in the United States.
Let me conclude this part with two higher-level considerations on the strength of monetary transmission
via the banking system. First, given the global nature of increased inflation, the ECB is not alone in
increasing policy rates and there are spillovers from the global rate hikes to euro area banks. In particular,
we should see spillovers from hikes by the Federal Reserve and other global central banks to the funding
costs and liquidity of globally active euro area banks, potentially further amplifying the bank lending
channel through global tightening.[33] Second, while the resilience of the euro area economy may have
limited the severity of the credit supply channel by boosting the incomes of firms and households, a
downturn or reversal of these factors would amplify the current slowdown in credit. In particular, as the
cumulative tightening in monetary policy gains further traction, the countervailing impact of these factors
will plausibly decline, with fading profits or a slowdown in household incomes amplifying the impact of the
credit channel.
Conclusions
The banking channel is likely to further strengthen in the coming months. The typical lags in monetary
transmission mean that the full economic impact of the considerable monetary tightening over the last year
will only play out over the next couple of years. In relation to the banking channel, transmission will
continue to strengthen with the ongoing repricing of bank funding, while the repricing of maturing fixed-rate
loans will place further upward pressure on aggregate lending rates. The decline in liquidity due to the
further repayment of TLTRO funds and the shrinking of the APP portfolio will further strengthen
transmission via the banking channel in the coming months. Furthermore, any deterioration in the
macroeconomic environment would also reinforce the banking channel by reducing loan demand and
increasing credit risks. Non-linear amplification effects could materialise in the event that financial stress
emerges either in the euro area or abroad.
Looking ahead, we will continue to monitor the strength of the banking channel through a range of
indicators that draw on both hard and soft information. As part of our broad assessment of the banking
channel, we examine a wide array of indicators on lending conditions, through information on bank
balance sheets, the evolution of lending and deposit rates and survey-based measures. Our assessment
is driven both by incoming data, but also broader modelling of bank lending conditions to create a forward-
looking assessment. We combine macro-level data examining aggregate euro area credit developments
and micro-level data that allows for variation across banks and different sectors of lending. The BLS plays
a key role in our analysis, since it allows us to separate the demand and supply components of credit
developments. The April BLS indicated that the net percentage of banks that further tightened their credit
standards on loans to firms in the first quarter was 27 per cent, while the net percentage of banks
reporting a decline in demand was 38 per cent. These results highlight the role that both credit demand
and credit supply are playing during the current tightening cycle. The imminent July BLS will provide fresh
information on the recent evolution of credit demand and credit supply, while the banks will also report
their expectations for credit demand and credit supply for the coming months. Accordingly, in combination
with the broader banking, financial and economic incoming data, the July BLS will help us to update our
assessment of the banking channel of monetary policy tightening.
Annexes
12 July 2023
Slides
ENGLISH
1.
I am grateful to Franziska Huennekes, Lucía Kazarian, Dorian Henricot, Giulio Nicoletti and Conor Parle
for their contributions in preparing these remarks.
2.
For earlier contributions on monetary policy transmission during the current tightening cycle, see also
Lane, P.R. (2022) “The Transmission of Monetary Policy”, SUERF, CGEG|COLUMBIA|SIPA, EIB,
SOCIÉTÉ GÉNÉRALE conference on “EU and US Perspectives: New Directions for Economic Policy”,
October 11 2022; and Lane, P.R. (2023) “The euro area hiking cycle: an interim assessment”, Dow Lecture
at the National Institute of Economic and Social Research, 16 February.
3.
See Bernanke, B. and Gertler, M. (1989) “Agency Costs, Net Worth and Business Fluctuations”, American
Economic Review, Vol. 79; Bernanke, B. and Gertler, M. (1995) “Inside the Black Box: The Credit Channel
of Monetary Policy Transmission”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 9; Kiyotaki, N. and Moore, J.
(1997) “Credit Cycles”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 105; Bernanke, B., Gertler, M. and Gilchrist, S.
(1999) “The financial accelerator in a quantitative business cycle framework”, Handbook of
Macroeconomics.
4.
See Bernanke, B., and Blinder A. (1992) “The Federal Funds Rate and the Channels of the Monetary
Transmission”, American Economic Review Vol. 82.
5.
See Jiménez, G. Ongena, S., Peydró, J-L and Saurina, J. (2012) “Credit Supply and Monetary Policy:
Identifying the Bank Balance-Sheet Channel with Loan Applications”. The American Economic Review,
Vol. 102; Holmstrom, B. and Tirole, J. (1997) “Financial Intermediation, Loanable Funds and the Real
Sector”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 112; Diamond, D. and Rajan, R. (2011) “Fear of Fire
Sales, Illiquidity Seeking and Credit Freezes”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 126.
6.
Following monetary policy tightening, the transmission of monetary policy is found to be stronger for poorly
capitalised banks (see for example Peek, J. and Rosengren, E. (1995) “Bank regulation and the credit
crunch”, Journal of Banking & Finance, Vol. 19; Kishan, R. and Opiela, T. (2000) “Bank Size, Bank Capital,
and the Bank Lending Channel.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 32; Van den Heuvel, S.
(2002) “Does bank capital matter for monetary transmission?” Economic Policy Review, Vol. 8; Jiménez G.
et al (2012) “Hazardous times for monetary policy: What do twenty-three million bank loans say about the
effects of monetary policy on credit-risk taking?” Econometrica), small banks (Kashyap, A. and Stein, J.
(1995) “The Impact of Monetary Policy on Bank Balance Sheets.” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series
on Public Policy, Vol. 42), and illiquid banks (Stein, J. (1998) “An Adverse-Selection Model of Bank Asset
and Liability Management with Implications for the Transmission of Monetary Policy”, The RAND Journal
of Economics, Vol. 29; Kashyap, A. and Stein, J. (2000) “What Do a Million Observations on Banks Say
about the Transmission of Monetary Policy?”, American Economic Review, Vol. 90; Bernanke, B. and
Gertler, M. (1990) “Financial Fragility and Economic Performance”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics,
Vol. 105, Bernanke, B. and Blinder A. (1988) “Credit, Money and Aggregate Demand”, The American
Economic Review, Vol. 78 and Kashyap, A. and Stein, J. (2000, op. cit)).
7.
Drechsler, I., Savov A. and Schnabl P. (2017) “The Deposits Channel of Monetary Policy,” Quarterly
Journal of Economics, Vol. 132.
8.
See Adrian, T. and Shin H.S. (2009) “Money, liquidity, and monetary policy”, American Economic Review
Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 99; Borio C. and Zhu, H. (2008), “Capital regulation, risk-taking and
monetary policy: A missing link in the transmission mechanism?” BIS Working Paper and Acharya, V., and
Hassan Naqvi, H. (2012) “The Seeds of a Crisis: A Theory of Bank Liquidity and Risk Taking over the
Business Cycle”, Journal of Financial Economics Vol. 136.
9.
Dell’Ariccia, G., Laeven, L., and Suarez, G. (2017) “Bank leverage and monetary policy’s risk-taking
channel: Evidence from the United States”, Journal of Finance, Vol. 72.
10.
Rajan, R. G. (2006) “Has finance made the world riskier?”, European financial management, Vol. 12;
Krishnamurthy, A. and Vissing-Jorgensen, A. (2011) “The effects of quantitative easing on interest rates:
channels and implications for policy”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 42.
11.
For example, in the latest rounds of the euro area Bank Lending Survey, increased risk perceptions and a
lower risk tolerance were cited as factors contributing towards a tightening of monetary policy.
12.
For more details on this, see: Rostagno, M., Altavilla, C., Carboni, G., Lemke, W., Motto, R. and Saint
Guilhem, A. (2021) “Combining negative rates, forward guidance and asset purchases: identification and
impacts of the ECB’s unconventional policies”, Working Paper Series, No. 2564, ECB.
13.
In this speech, I primarily report aggregate data for the euro area. However, there are significant
differences across national banking systems in terms of how banks respond to monetary tightening.
Among other factors, these differences relate to variation in the intensity of competition in the banking
system at the national level and in the design of consumer protection regulations.
14.
While the interest rates on time deposits have increased alongside the policy rate, the widening of the
spread between overnight deposit rates and policy rates is in line with what has been previously observed
during interest rate hiking cycles. Partly this is because overnight deposits offer payment services that are
not explicitly priced. Alongside their short maturity, this has meant that spreads between overnight
deposits and the policy rate have been rather wide. This was not the case during the period of negative
rates, when many banks spared depositors from the below-zero rates. This can also partially explain the
fact that interest rates on overnight deposits have moved much less than policy rates. On this see Altavilla,
C., Burlon, L., Giannetti, M. and Holton, S. (2022) “Is there a zero lower bound? The real effects of
negative interest rates”, Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 144.
15.
While net purchases under the pandemic emergency purchase programme (PEPP) ended in March 2022,
the Governing Council plans to maintain full reinvestment of the PEPP portfolio until the end of 2024.
16.
Altavilla, C., Darracq Paries, M. and Nicoletti, G. (2019) “Loan supply, credit markets and the euro area
financial crisis”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 109.
17.
For the construction of the LSI, see Altavilla, C., Darracq Paries, M. and Nicoletti, G. (2019). The use of
survey data to disentangle demand and supply components of credit dynamics is also available in Bassett,
W., Chosak, M.B., Driscoll, J. and Zakrajšek, E. (2014) “Changes in bank lending standards and the
macroeconomy”, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 62 and Altavilla, C., Boucinha, M., Holton, S. and
Ongena, S. (2021) “Credit supply and demand in unconventional times”, Journey of Money Credit and
Banking, Vol. 53.
18.
In detail, the constituent papers are: Gilchrist, S. and Zakrajšek, E. (2012) “Credit Spreads and Business
Cycle Fluctuations”, American Economic Review, Vol. 102; Barnett, A. and Thomas, R. (2014) “Has Weak
Lending and Activity in the UK been Driven by Credit Supply Shocks?”, The Manchester School, Vol. 82;
Mumtaz, H., Pinter, G. and Theodoridis, K. (2018) “What do VARs Tell Us About the Impact of a Credit
Supply Shock?” International Economic Review, Vol. 59; Bassett, W., Chosak, M. B., Driscoll, J. and
Zakrajšek, E. (2014) “Changes in bank lending standards and the macroeconomy”, Journal of Monetary
Economics, Vol. 62; Gambetti, L. and Musso, A. (2016) “Loan Supply Shocks and the Business Cycle”,
Journal of Applied Economics, Vol. 32; Altavilla, C., Darracq Paries, M. and Nicoletti, G. (2019), “Loan
supply, credit markets and the euro area financial crisis”, Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 109; Chen,
K., Higgins, P. and Zha, T. (2021) “Cyclical lending standards: a structural analysis”, Review of Economic
Dynamics, Vol. 42; Mendicino, C., Nikolov, K., Suarez, J. and Supera, D. (2020) “Bank capital in the short
and in the long run”, Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 115; Jermann, U. and Quadrini, V. (2012),
“Macroeconomic effects of financial shocks”, American Economic Review, Vol. 102; Gerali A., Neri, S.,
Sessa, L. and Signoretti, F. (2010) “Credit and Banking in a DSGE Model of the Euro Area”, Journey of
Money Credit and Banking, Vol. 42; Darracq Paries, M., Kok Sorensen, C. and Rodriguez-Palenzuela, D.
(2011), “Macroeconomic Propagation under Different Regulatory Regimes: Evidence from an Estimated
DSGE Model for the Euro Area”, International Journal of Central Banking, Vol. 7; IMF (2023) “World
Economic Outlook, April 2023”;Barauskaitė, K., Nguyen, A. D. M., Fache Rousovä, L. and Cappiello, L.
(2022) “The impact of credit supply shocks in the euro area: market-based financing versus loans”,
Working Paper Series, No. 2673, ECB; Darracq Paries, M., Moccero, D., Krylova, E. and Marchini, C.
(2014) “The retail bank interest rate pass-through: The case of the euro area during the financial and
sovereign debt crisis”, Occasional Paper Series, No. 155, ECB;Ciccarelli, M., Maddaloni, A. And Peydro,
J-L. (2015) “Trusting the bankers: a new look at the credit channel of monetary policy”, Review of
Economic Dynamics, Vol. 18.
19.
According to the June Survey of Monetary Analysts, the policy rate will settle at two percent by 2026 Q2.
20.
The ECB is undertaking a review of the operational framework, but the current configuration is essentially
a floor system.
21.
See Ryan, E. and Whelan, K. (2021) “Quantitative Easing and the Hot Potato Effect: Evidence from Euro
Area Banks,” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 115.
22.
The decline in the volume of central bank reserves also implies greater heterogeneity in the asset holdings
of banks across the difference member countries. See also Rogers, C. (2023), “Quantitative Easing and
Local Banking Systems in the Euro Area,” mimeo, Stockholm University.
23.
Clearly, there are important differences between temporary and permanent supply shocks.
24.
See Stiglitz, J. E. and Weiss, A. (1981) “Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Information.” The
American Economic Review, Vol. 71. For stickiness in the adjustment of lending rates: see Lowe P. and
Rohling, T., (1992) "Loan Rate Stickiness: Theory and Evidence," RBA Research Discussion Papers,
Reserve Bank of Australia.
25.
For more information on the important role of small enterprises in the transmission of monetary policy, see
Caglio, C., Darst, M. and Kalemli-Özcan, Ṣ. (2021), “Collateral Heterogeneity and Monetary Policy
Transmission: Evidence from Loans to SMEs and Large Firms”, NBER Working Paper, No. 28685; Gertler,
M. and Gilchrist, S. (1994) “Monetary Policy, Business Cycles and the Behavior of Small Manufacturing
Firms”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 109 and Gertler, M. and Gilchrist, S. (1993) “The Role of
Credit Market Imperfections in the Monetary Transmission Mechanism: Arguments and Evidence”,
Scandinavian Journal of Economics, Vol. 95.
26.
See Franceschi, E., Grodzicki, M., Kagerer, B., Kaufmann, C., Lenoci, F., Mingarelli, L., Pancaro, C. and
Senner, R., (2023), “Key linkages between banks and the non-bank financial sector”, Financial Stability
Review, May, ECB.
27.
For instance, in some countries, non-banks had emerged as significant mortgage providers since non-
deposit funding was so cheap during the low-for-long period. Since market funding costs have increased
more quickly than deposit funding costs, these non-banks are no longer as competitive in offering
mortgages.
28.
In inflation-adjusted terms, the real declines in house prices are of course even greater.
29.
Lower credit risks and the improvement in capital and liquidity positions have also been driven by the
rollout of macroprudential policy frameworks and the supervisory policies of the Single Supervisory
Mechanism.
30.
Of course, it is essential for central banks to continuously monitor financial stability risks, especially in the
context of a significant monetary policy tightening cycle.
31.
It should be noted that in the context of the March 2023 market turmoil, the share of bond holdings in the
asset portfolios of euro area banks is much lower than those of US banks, and the differing regulatory
environment makes interest rate risk for banks more moderate on average.
32.
For more details on the role of CRE in the euro area see Ryan, E. Horan, A. and Jarmulska, B. (2022)
“Commercial real estate and financial stability – new insights from the euro area credit register”,
Macroprudential Bulletin, ECB, October.
33.
Of course, global tightening also operates through macroeconomic mechanisms, such as lower global
demand and lower global pricing pressure.