Microsoft Word - Development Economicsi moduleIIfinal
Microsoft Word - Development Economicsi moduleIIfinal
MODULE II
MEKELLE UNIVERSITY
FACULTY OF BUSINESS AND ECONOMICS
DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS
December 5, 2005
Table of Contents Page
4. Determinants of Economic Development 4
Introduction 4
4.1 Traditional Approach (Economic Factors) to Development 4
a) Natural Resource 4
b) Capital Accumulation 5
c) Organization 5
d) Technological Progress 6
e) Division of Labour and Scale of Production 6
4.2 Institutional Approach to Development 7
a) Type of Government 7
b) Institutions 8
c) Social Structure of Population 9
d) Social Capital and Cultural Traits 9
2
INTRODUCTION
This is the second module of Development Economics I. In the first module you have
seen general concepts about Development including its historical background,
different models of growth and development.
3
Chapter IV
DETERMINANTS OF ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT
Introduction
Today, countries of the world are divided into rich (developed) countries and
poor (developing) countries. There is a wide gap between the rich and the poor
countries. The statement that “the rich nations get richer and the poor countries
get poorer” has become popular in the literature in world poverty. But what are
the explanations for the poor performance of the developing countries? There
are two approaches to explain the determinants of economic development the
traditional approach and the institutional approach.
a) Natural Resources.
The principals factor affecting the development of an economy is the natural
resources or land. “Land” as used in economic includes natural resources such
as fertility of land, its situation and composition, forest wealth, minerals,
climate, water resources, sea resources, geographical proximity with rich
countries etc. For growth, the existence of natural resources in abundance is
essential. A country which is deficient in natural resources will not be in a
position to develop rapidly. As pointed out by Lewis, “Other things being
equal, men can make better use of rich resources than they can of poor.”
In LDCs natural resources are either unutilized, underutilized or misutilized.
These is one of the reasons for their backwardness. The presence of natural
resources is not sufficient for economic growth. What is required is their
proper exploitation.
4
It is often said that economic growth is possible even when an economic is
deficient in natural resources. As pointed out by Lewis, “A country which is
considered to be poor in resources today may be considered very rich in
resources at some later time, not merely because unknown resources are
discovered, but equally because new uses are discovered for the known
resources.” Japan is one such country which is deficient in natural resources
but it is one of the advanced countries of the world because it has been able to
discover new uses for limited resources.
b) Capital Accumulation
Capital means the stock of physical reproducible factors of production. When
capital stock increases with the passage of time, it is called capital
accumulation or capital formation. Capital formation is investment in capital
goods that leads to increase in capital stock, national output and income.
Capital formation is the key to economic development. On the one hand it
reflects effective demand and on the other hand, it creates productive efficiency
for production. Capital formation possesses special importance to LDCs. The
process of capital formation leads to the increase in national output in a number
of ways. Capital formation is essential to meet the requirements of an
increasing population in such economies. Investment in capital goods not only
raises production but also employment opportunities. It is capital formation
that leads to technological progress. Technological in turn leads to
specialization and the economies of large scale production. The provision of
social and economic over heads, like transport, power education etc in a
country is possible through capital formation. It is also capital formation that
leads to the exploitation of natural resources, industrialization and expansion of
markets which are essential for economic progress.
c) Organization
Organization is an important part of the growth process. It relates to the
optimum use of factor of production economic activities. Organization is
5
complement to capital and labour and helps in increasing their product
activities. In modern economic growth, the entrepreneur has been performing
the task of an organizer and undertaking risks and uncertainties.
d) Technological Progress
Technological charges are regarded as the most important factor in the process
of economic growth. They are related to changes in the methods of production
which are the result of some new techniques of research or innovation.
Changes in Technology lead to increase in productivity of labour, capital and
other factors of production.
6
Underdeveloped countries are unable to take advantage of the economics of
division of labour and large scale production due to the presence of market
imperfections, which in turn keep the size of the market small.
The institutional factor further argues that most of the economic factors can be
obtained in the globalize market. For example, many MNCs are ready to invest
a significant amount of capital if conditions are favorable. Besides LDCs can
also borrow technologies from DCS.
7
The institutional factors that determine economic performance include.
a) Type of Government
A country with a monarchy system is less likely to develop as compared with a
country with a democratic government. The nature of democracy depends on
the level of education, discipline, culture etc of the people. In maintaining
rules, governments could be soft or strong. To maintain rules and there by
prepare the ground for development, governments need be strong. To provide
for the enforcement of contracts, the prevention of anarchy, and the provision
of other public good, the coercive power of government is necessary.
b) Institutions
Availability of technology like the capital good, complementary factors like
infrastructure, highly skilled labor, innovation etc are required for an economy
to grow. To have such technological changes requires a good institution. For
example, in making innovations, there could be resistance. To calm such
resistance, government effort is required. Thus, institutions that encourage
technological innovation and suitability of institution for successful adoption of
new ideas is an important question. Political and cultural dynamism help in
8
adoption of new technology and the negative forces such as labour union
orthodoxy should be managed properly by good governance. Spread of
education, scientific culture are necessary for adoption of new technology
Reservation/Affirmative Action/. Social justice requires that if some sections
of the society are deprived, they must be given special attention i.e. reservation
is needed. The supporters of reservation justify its use in terms of social justice,
equity and to rectify historical mistakes. However, from the point of view of
efficiency, it is not justified.
9
CHAPTER V
INEQUALITY, POVERTY AND DEVELOPMENT
Introduction
The 1970, witnessed a remarkable change in public and private perceptions
about the ultimate nature of economic activity. In both rich and poor countries,
there was a growing disillusionment with the idea that relentless pursuit of
growth was the principal economic objective of society. In the developed
countries, the major emphasis seemed to shift toward more concern for the
quality of life, a concern manifested mainly in the environmental movement.
In the poor countries, the main concern focused on the question of growth
versus income distribution. That development required a higher GNP and
faster growth rate was obvious. The basic issue, however, was (and is) not
only how to make GNP grow but also who would make it grow, the few or the
many. If it were the rich, it would most likely be appropriated by them, and
poverty and inequality would continue to worsen. But if it were generated by
the many, they would be its principal beneficiaries, and the fruits of economic
growth would be shared more evenly.
In this chapter, we will examine the following five critical questions about the
relationship between economic growth, income distribution and poverty
1. What is the extent of relative inequality in developing countries, and
how is this related to the extent of absolute poverty
2. Who are the poor, and what are their economics characteristics?
3. What determines the nature of economics growth that is, who benefits?
4. Are rapid economic growth and more equitable distributions of income
compatible or conflicting objectives for low income countries? To put it
another way, is rapid growth achievable only at the cost of greater
inequalities in the distribution of income, or can a lessening of income
disparities contribute to higher growth rates?
5. What kinds of policies are required to reduce the magnitude and extent
of absolute poverty?
10
5.1 Inequalities of income: Concepts and Measurement
We can get some idea to question 1 and 2 relating to extent and
character of inequality and poverty in developing countries by pulling
together same recent evidence from a variety of sources. In this section
we define the dimensions of income distribution and poverty problems
and identify some similar elements that characterize the problem in
many developing countries. But first we should be clear about what we
are measuring when we speak about the distribution of income.
a) Size Distributions
The personal or size distribution of income is the measure most commonly
used by economists. It simply deals with individual persons or households and
the total income they receive. The way in which that income was received is
not considered. What matters is how much each earns irrespective of whether
the income was derived solely from employment or came also from other
sources such as interest, profits, rents, gifts or inheritance. Moreover, the
locational (urban or rual) and occupational sources of the income (e.g.
agriculture, manufacturing, commerce, services) are neglected. If Ato Abebe
and W/ro Mulu both receive the same personal income, they are classified
together irrespective of the fact that W/ro Mulu may work 15 hours a day as a
doctor which Ato Abebe does not work at all but simply collects interest on his
inheritance.
11
groups or sizes. A common method is to divide the population in to successive
quintiles (fifths) or deciles (tenths) according to the ascending income levels
and then determine what proportion of the total national income is received by
each income group.
Table 5.1 Size distribution of personal income in a developing country by
Income shares quintiles & Deciles
Personal income Percentage share in total income
Individuals (Money Units) Quintiles Deciles
1 0.8
2 1.0 1.8
3 1.4
4 1.8 5 3.2
5 1.9
6 2.0 3.9
7 2.4
8 2.7 9 5.1
9 2.8
10 3.0 5.8
11 3.4
12 3.8 13 7.2
13 4.2
14 4.8 9.0
15 5.9
16 7.1 22 13.0
17 10.5
18 12.0 22.5
19 13.5
20 15.0 51 28.5
Total 100.0 100 100.0
Measure of inequality = total of bottom 40% to 20% = 14/51 = 0.28
The total or national income of all individuals amounts to 100 units and is the
sum of all entries in column 2. In column 3, the population is grouped in to
quintiles of four individuals each. The first quintile represents the bottom 20%
of the population on the income scale. This group receives only 5% (i.e. a total
of 5 money units) of the national income. The second quintile (individuals 5 -
8) receives 9% of the total income. Alternatively the bottom 40% of the
12
population (quintiles 1 plus 2 ) is receiving only 14% of the income, while the
top 20% ( the fifth quintile) of the population receives 51% of the total
income.
Lorenz Curve
13
Another common way to a personal income statistics is to construct what is
known as a Lorenz curve. The Lorenz curve is shown below.
O’
100
90
80
70
Percentage of income
Line of Equality
60
I.
50 E
40 H.
30 G.
F.
20
E
D.
10
C.
B.
A.
O 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
Percentage of income recipients
Fig. 5.1 Lorenz Curve
Dear students, as usual, we have the vertical axis and horizontal axis in the
above diagram. On the horizontal axis, the number of income recipients is
plotted, not in absolute terms but in cumulative percentages. For example, at
point 20 we have the lowest (poorest) 20% of the population at point 60 we
have the bottom 60%, and at the end of the axis all 100% of the population has
been accounted for. The vertical axis shows the share of total income received
14
by each percentage of the population; it also is cumulative up to 100% meaning
that both axes are equally long.
The entire figure is enclosed in a square; a diagonal line (00’) is drawn from
the lower left corner (the origin) of the square to the upper right corner. At
every point on the diagonal 00’ the percentage of income received is exactly
equal to the percentage of income recipients, for example, at point E, which is
the point half way the length of the diagonal line, represents 50% of the income
being distributed to exactly 50% of the population. Similar, at the three quarter
point on the diagram, 75% of the income would be distributed to 75% of the
population. In other words, the diagonal line 00’ is representative of "perfect
equality" in size distribution of income.
The Lorenz curve shows the actual quantitative relationship between the
percentages of income recipients and the percentage of the actual income they
did in fact receive during, say, a given year. In figure 5.1 we have plotted this
Lorenz curve using the docile data contained to each of the 10 deciles groups.
Point A shows that the bottom 10% population receives only 1.8% of the total
income; point B shows that the bottom 20% is receiving 5% of the total
income, and so on for each of the other eight cumulative deciles groups. Note
that at the halfway point, 50% of the population is in fact receiving only 19.8%
of the total income.
The more the Lorenz line curves is away from the diagonal (perfect equality),
the greater the degree of inequality represented. The extreme case of perfect
inequality ( i.e. a situation in which one person receives all of the national
income while ever body else receives nothing) would be represented by the
congruence of the Lorenz curve with the bottom horizontal and right hand
vertical axes. Because no country exhibits either perfect equality or perfect
inequality in its distribution of income, the Lorenz curves for different
countries will lie somewhere to the right of the diagonal in Figure5.1. The
15
greater the degree of inequality, the greater the bend and the closer to the
bottom horizontal axis the Lorenz curve will be. Two representative
distributions are shown in Figure 5.2, one for a relatively equal distribution
(Figure 5.2a) and the other for a more unequal distribution (Figure 5.2b). (Can
you explain why the Lorenz curve could not lie above or to the left of the
diagonal at any point?)
Exercise 5.1
Using the quintiles data on table 5.1, draw a Lorenz Curve
Gini Coefficient
A final and very convenient short hand summary measure of the relative degree
of income inequality in a country can be obtained by calculating the ratio of the
area between the diagonal and the Lorenz curve divided by the total area of the
half square in which the curve lies. This is shown below.
16
In the above diagram (fig 5.3) the ratio of the shaded area A to the total area of
the triangle BCD is known as the Gini concentration ratio or more simply as
the Gini coefficient, named after the Italian statistician who first formulated it
in 1912.
Gini coefficients are aggregate inequality measures and can vary any where
from 0 (perfect equality) to 1 (perfect inequality). Gini coefficients for
countries with highly unequal income distributions typically lies between 0.50
and 0.70 while for countries with relatively equitable distributions, it is on the
order of 0.20 to 0.35.
b) Functional Distribution
The second common measure of income distribution used by economists, the
functional or factor share distributions of income, attempts to explain the share
of total national income that each of the factors of production (land, labour and
capital) receives. Instead of looking at individuals as separate entities, the
17
theory of functional income distribution inquires into the percentage that labour
receives as a whole and compares this with the percentages of total income
distributed in the form of rent, interest, and profit (i.e. the return to land and
financial and physical capital). Although specific individuals may receive
income from all these sources, that is not a matter of concern for the functional
approach.
18
The figures in the above table (table 5.2) give a first approximation of the
magnitude of income inequality in these developing countries. For example,
we see from the last row that by averaging income shares for different
percentile groups among all 15 countries, on average the poorest 20% of the
population receives only 5.2 of the income the highest 10% and 20% receive
36.0 and 51.8% respectively. By contrast, in a developed country like Japan,
the poorest 20% receives a much higher 8.7% of the income while the richest
10% and 20% get only 22.4% and 37.5% respectively.
Exercise 5.2
What is the relationship between levels of per capita income and degree of inequality? Are
higher incomes associated with greater or lesser inequality or can no definitive statement be
made?
The following table (table 5.3) provides data on income distribution in relation
to per capita GNP for a sample of 10 developing countries.
Table 5.3 Per Capita Income and Inequality in Developing Countries, 1990s
Country GNP per capita Income Share of Ratio of Highest Gini
1996 (US $) Lowest 40% of 20% to Lowest Coefficient
Households 20%
Bangladesh 260 22.9 4.0 0.28
Kenya 320 10.1 18.3 0.58
Sri Lanka 740 22.0 4.4 0.30
Indonesia 1080 20.4 5.1 0.34
Philippines 1160 15.5 8.4 0.43
Jamaica 1600 16.0 8.2 0.41
Paraguay 1850 8.2 27.1 0.59
Costa Rica 2640 12.8 12.9 0.47
Malaysia 4370 12.9 11.7 0.48
Brazil 4400 8.2 25.7 0.60
19
Income distribution in measured in three ways as the total share of income
received by the poorest 40% of the population, as the ratio of the share going to
the richest 20% divided by that of the poorest 20% and as measured by the Gini
coefficient.
What clearly emerges from table 5.3 is that per capita incomes are not highly
correlated with any of our three measures of inequality. For example, we see
that Sri Lanka has only one-sixth the per capita income of Brazil, but its three
inequality measures are much less pronounced than Brazil’s. Its Gini
coefficient is 0.30 compared to Brazil's 0.60. Similarly, Paraguay, with income
seven times higher than that of Bangladesh, shows much greater inequality.
Conversely, Malaysia, with a 1996 per capita income that is 65% higher than
Costa Rica, has inequality measures that are not much different. We can
conclude, therefore, that there is no apparent relationship between levels of per
capita income and the degree of income concentration over relevant range of
LDC incomes.
20
to ensure continued survival extent of obsolete poverty is therefore the
number of people who are unable to command sufficient resources to satisfy
basic needs.
Exercise 5.3
Let's assume that the poverty line is set at $360. If two individuals A and B earn $ 350 and
$300 respectively, the two are below the poverty line Are two equally poor?
21
make this clear, let's consider the following two figures for two countries A and
B, where line PV is the poverty line.
In both country A and country B, 50% the population falls below the same
poverty line PV. However the poverty gap in country A is greater than in
country B which implies that it will take more of an effort to eliminate absolute
poverty in country A.
Exercise 5.4
"Higher per capita incomes per se do not guarantee the absence of significant numbers of
absolute poor. It is possible for a country with a higher per capita income to have a large
percentage line and a larger poverty gap than a country with a lower per capita income "
Argue on this statement by relating your answers to exercise 5.2
22
the relationship between distribution of income & growth, known as the
inverted U hypothesis
0.75
Gini Coefficient
0.5
0.35
0.25
0
GNP Per capital
Fig 5.4 The “Inverted U” Kuznets Curve
23
transfers from the rich to the poor and poverty reducing public expenditures are
more difficult to undertake by governments in very low-income countries.
Having examined the relationship between inequality and levels of per capita
income, let's look now at the relationship, if any, between economic growth
and inequality. In the figure below (Figure 5.5) we have plotted rates of
growth of GNP for 13 developing countries on the horizontal axis and the
growth rate of income of the lowest 40% of their population along the vertical
axis. The data are for the time span shown in parentheses after each country,
and the scatter is intended to reveal any obvious relationships between GNP
growth rates and improvements in relative income levels for the very poor.
Each country's data, therefore, are plotted in the figure at a point reflecting its
combination of GNP growth and the income growth of the lowest 40% of its
population
24
The 45 degree line shows a proportionate growth in percentage growth rate of
gross national product and percentage growth rates of incomes of bottom 40%
of population. Countries above the 45 degree line are those where the
distribution of income has improved that is, the incomes of the bottom 40%
grew faster than the over all GNP growth whereas countries below the 45
degree line have experienced a worsening of their income distributions over the
indicated period.
The scatter of points in the above figure does not reveal any strong or obvious
relationship between GNP growth and the distribution of income. High growth
rates do not necessarily worsen the distribution of income indeed, countries like
Taiwan, Iran, and South Korea experienced relatively high rates of GNP
growth and exhibited improved or at least unchanged distributions of income.
Nevertheless, countries like Mexico and panama grew just as fast but
experienced a deterioration of their income distribution. However there does
not seem to be a necessary relationship between low GNP growth and
improved income distribution. In developing countries like India, Peru and the
Philippines, low rates of GNP growth appear to have been accompanied by a
deterioration of the relative income shares of the bottom 40%. And yet Sri
Lanka, Colombia, Costa Rica, and El Salvador, with similarly low GNP growth
rates, managed to improve the relative well being of their low-income
population. Note that in all cases the poor did share in some of the benefit of
economic growth even though there is no direct, positive relationship between
rate of growth and degree of improvement.
The data from fig. 5.5 suggest that it is the character of economic growth (how
it is achieved, who participates, which sector are given priority, what
institutional arrangements are designed and emphasized etc.) that determines
the degree to which that growth is or is not reflected in improved linking
standards for the very poor. It is not the more fact of rapid growth per se that
determines the nature of distributional benefits
25
5.4 Growth versus Income Distribution.
The debate about the relationship between economics distribution takes many
forms. The key arguments are the traditional argument and the counter
argument.
The basic economic argument to justify large income in equalities was that
high personal and corporate incomes were necessary conditions of saving,
which made possible investment and economic growth through a mechanism
such as the Harrod-Domar model described in chapter 3 of the first module. If
the rich save and invest significant portions of their incomes while the poor
spend all their income on consumption goods, and if GNP growth rates are
directly related to the proportion of national income saved, then apparently an
economy characterized by highly unequal distributions of income would save
more and grow faster than one with a more equitable distribution of income.
Eventually, it was assumed, national and per capita incomes would be high
enough to make sizable redistributions of income possible through tax and
subsidy programs. But until such a time is reached, any attempt to redistribute
incomes significantly would serve only to lower growth rates and delay the
time when a larger income pie could be cut up into bigger slices for all
population groups.
b) Counterargument
There are five general reasons why many development economists believe the
foregoing argument to be incorrect and why greater equality in developing
countries may in fact be a condition for self-sustaining economic growth.
26
First, sizable inequality and widespread poverty create conditions in which the
poor have no access to credit, are unable to finance their children's education,
and, in the absence physical or monetary investment opportunities, have many
children as a source of old-age financial security. Together these factors cause
per capita growth to be less than what it would be if there were greater equality.
Second, common sense, supported by a wealth of recent empirical data, bears
witness to the fact that unlike the historical experience of the now developed
countries, the rich in contemporary poor countries are not noted for their
frugality or for their desire to save and invest substantial proportions of their
incomes in the local economy. Instead, landlords, business leaders, politicians,
and other rich elites are known to spend much of their incomes on imported
luxury goods, gold, jewelry, expensive houses, and foreign travel or to seek
safe havens abroad for their savings in the form of capital flight. Such savings
and investments do not add to the nation's productive resources; in fact, they
represent substantial drains on these resources in that the income so derived is
extracted from the sweat and toil of common, uneducated, and unskilled
laborers. In short, the rich do not necessarily save and invest significantly
larger proportions of their incomes (in the real economic sense of productive
domestic saving and investment) than the poor. Therefore, a growth strategy
based on sizable and growing income inequalities may in reality be nothing
more than an opportunistic myth designed to perpetuate the vested interests and
maintain the status quo of the economic and political elites of Third World
nations, often at the expense of the great majority of the general population.
Such strategies might better be called "antidevelopmental.”
Third, the low incomes and low levels of living for the poor, which are
manifested in poor health, nutrition, and education, can lower their economic
productivity and thereby lead directly and indirectly to a slower-growing
economy. Strategies to raise the incomes and levels of living of, say, the
bottom 40% would therefore contribute not only to their material well-being
but also to the productivity and income of the economy as a whole.
27
Fourth, raising the income levels of the poor will stimulate an overall increase
in the demand for locally produced necessity products like food and clothing,
whereas the rich tend to spend more of their additional incomes on imported
luxury goods. Rising demand for local goods provides a greater stimulus to
local production, local employment, and local investment. Such demand thus
creates the conditions for rapid economic growth and a broader popular
participation in that growth.
Fifth and finally, a more equitable distribution of income achieved through the
reduction of mass poverty can stimulate healthy economic expansion by acting
as a powerful material and psychological incentive to widespread public
participation in the development process. By contrast, wide income disparities
and substantial absolute poverty can act as powerful material and
psychological disincentives to economic progress. They may even create the
conditions for an ultimate rejection of progress by the masses of frustrated and
politically explosive people, especially those with considerable education.
We can conclude, therefore, that promoting rapid economic growth and reduc-
ing poverty and inequality are not mutually conflicting objectives. The World
Bank reached a similar conclusion in its 1990 report on poverty when it
declared:
28
5.5 The Range of Policy Options: Some Basic Considerations
a) Areas of Intervention
We can identify four broad areas of possible government policy intervention,
which correspond to the following four major elements in the determination of
a developing economy's distribution of income:
29
directly (e.g., by outright money transfers) or indirectly (e.g., through public
employment creation or the provision of free or subsidize a primary
education and health care for both men and women. Such public policies
raise the real income levels of the poor above their market-determined
personal income levels.
b) Policy Options
Third World governments have many options and alternative possible policies
to operate in the four broad areas of intervention just outlined. Let us briefly
identify the nature of some of them.
However, it is often also correctly pointed out that the price of capital equip-
ment is "institutionally" set at artificially low levels (below what supply and
demand would dictate) through various public policies such as investment
30
incentives, tax allowances, subsidized interest rates, overvalued exchange rates,
arid low tariffs on capital goods imports such as tractors and automated
equipment. If these special privileges and capital subsidies were removed so
that the price of capital would rise to its true "scarcity" level, producers would
have a further incentive to increase their utilization of the abundant supply of
labor and lower their uses of scarce capital. Moreover, owners of capital (both
physical and financial) would not receive the artificially high economic returns
they now enjoy. Their personal incomes would thereby be reduced.
Because factor prices are assumed to function as the ultimate signals and
incentives in any economy, correcting these prices (Le., lowering the relative
price of labor and raising the relative price of capital) would not only increase
productivity and efficiency but would also reduce inequality by providing more
wagepaying jobs for currently unemployed or underemployed unskilled and
semiskilled workers. It would also lower the artificially high incomes of
owners of capital. Removal of such factor-price distortions would therefore go
a long way toward combining more growth, efficiently generated, with higher
employment, less poverty, and greater equality.
31
Modifying the Size Distribution through Progressive
Redistribution of Asset Ownership
Given correct resource prices and utilization levels for each type of productive
factor (labor, land, and capital), we can arrive at estimates for the total earnings
of each asset. But to translate this functional income into personal income, we
need to know the distribution and ownership concentration of these assets
among and within various segments of the population. Here we come to what is
probably the most important fact about the determination of income
distribution within an economy: The ultimate cause of the unequal distribution
of personal incomes in most Third World countries is the unequal and highly
concentrated patterns of asset ownership (wealth) in these countries. The
principal reasons why less than 20% of their population receives over 50% of
the national income is that this 20% probably owns and controls well over 90%
of the productive and financial resources, especially physical capital and land
but also financial capital (stocks and bonds) and human capital in the form of
better education. Correcting factor prices is certainly not sufficient to reduce
income inequalities substantially or to eliminate widespread poverty where
physical and financial asset ownership and education are highly concentrated.
It follows that the second and perhaps more important line of policy to reduce
poverty and inequality is to focus directly on reducing the concentrated control
of assets, the unequal distribution of power, and the unequal access to
educational and income-earning opportunities that characterize many
developing countries. A classic case of such redistribution policies as they
relate to the rural poor, who comprise 70% to 80% of the target poverty group,
is land reform. The basic purpose of land reform is to transform tenant
cultivators into smallholders who will then have an incentive to raise
production and improve their incomes. But as we shall see in Chapter 10, land
reform may be a weak instrument of income redistribution if other institutional
and price distortions in the economic system prevent small farm holders from
securing access to much needed critical inputs such as credit, fertilizers, seeds,
32
marketing facilities, and agricultural education. Similar reforms in urban areas
could include the provision of commercial credit at market rates (rather than
through exploitive moneylenders) to small entrepreneurs (so called microloans-
see Chapter 17) so that they can expand their 'business and provide more jobs
to local workers.
Human capital in the form of education and skills is another example of the
unequal distribution of productive asset ownership. Public policy should there-
fore promote wider access to educational opportunities (for girls as well as
boys) as a means of increasing income-earning potential for more people. This
investment in human capital as a principal strategy for alleviating poverty has
been widely promoted (along with accelerating economic growth) by the World
Bank in its various poverty reports, especially World Development Report
1998/99: Knowledge for Development. But as in the case of land reform, the
mere pr9vision of greater access to education is no guarantee that the poor will
be any better off, unless complementary policies-for example, the provision of
more productive unemployment opportunities for the educated-are adopted to
capitalize on this increased human capital. The relationship among education,
employment, and development is discussed further in Chapter 9.
33
Reducing the Size Distribution at the Upper Levels through Progressive
Income and Wealth Taxes
Any national policy attempting to improve the living standards oi the bottom
40% must secure sufficient financial resources to transform paper plans into
program realities. The major source of such development finance is the direct
and progressive taxation of both income and wealth. Direct progressive income
taxes focus on personal and corporate incomes, with the rich required to pay a
progressively larger percentage of their total income in taxes than the poor:
Taxation on wealth (the stock of accumulated assets and income) typically
involves personal and corporate property taxes but may also include
progressive inheritance taxes. In either case, the burden of the tax is designed
to fall most heavily on the upper-income groups.
34
Increasing the Size Distribution at the Lower Levels through Direct
Transfer Payments and the Public Provision of Goods and Services
35
CHAPTER VI
INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT
Introduction
International trade has often played a crucial though not necessarily benign role
in the historical development of the third world. In this chapter, we focus on
traditional and more contemporary theories of international trade in the context
of five basic themes or questions of particular importance to developing
nations.
1. How does international trade affect the rate, structure, and character of
LDC economic growth? This is the traditional “trade as an engine of
growth” controversy, set in terms of contemporary development
aspirations.
2. How does trade alter the distribution of income and wealth within a
country and among different countries? Is trade a force for international
and domestic equality or inequality? In other words, how are the gains
and losses distributed, and who benefits at whose expense (for every
winner must there be at least one or, more likely, many losers)?
3. Under what conditions can trade help LDCs achieve their development
objectives?
4. Can LDCs by their own actions determine how much they trade?
5. In the light of past experience and prospective judgment, should LDCs
adopt an outward-looking policy (free trade, expanded flows of capital
and human resources, ideas and technology, etc) or an inward-looking
one (protectionism in the interest of self-reliance), or should they pursue
some combination of both, for example, in the form of regional
economic cooperation? What are the arguments for and against these
alternative trade strategies for development?
36
6.1. Trade Theory and Development: the Traditional Arguments
The neoclassical free trade model, which you will see in another course
“International economics” gives answers to the questions raised above. Here is
a summary of the theoretical answers to the five basic questions about trade
and development derived from the neoclassical free trade model.
1. Trade is an important stimulator of economic growth. It enlarges a
country's consumption capacities, increases world output, and 'provides
access to scarce resources and worldwide markets for products without
which poor countries would be unable to grow
2. Trade tends to promote greater international and domestic equality by
equalizing factor prices, raising real incomes of trading countries, and
making efficient use of each nation's and the world’s resource
endowments (e.g., raising relative wages in labor abundant countries and
lowering them in labor-scarce countries).
3. Trade helps countries achieve development by promoting and rewarding
the sectors of the economy where individual countries possess a
comparative advantage, whether in terms of labor efficiency or factor
endowments.
4. In a world of free trade, h1te~national prices arid costs of production
determine how much a country should trade in order to maximize its
national welfare. Countries should follow the dictates of the principle of
comparative advantage and not try to interfere with the free workings of
the market.
5. Finally, to promote growth and development an outward looking
international policy is required. In all cases self- reliance based on
partial or complete, isolation is asserted to be economically inferior to
participation, in. a world of unlimited free trade
37
6.2. Arguments against free trade within the context of developing
countries.
The conclusions of traditional international trade theory are derived from a
number of explicit and implicit assumptions that in many ways are often
contrary to the reality of contemporary international economic relations. The
theory therefore often leads to conclusions foreign to both the historical and the
contemporary trade experience of many developing nations.
What are the major and crucial assumptions of the traditional factor endow-
ment theory of trade, and how are these assumptions violated in the real world?
What are the implications for the trade and financial prospects of developing
nations when a more realistic assessment of the actual mechanism of interna-
tional economic and political relations is made?
1. All productive resources are fixed in quantity across nations. They are
fully employed, and there is no international mobility of productive
factors.
38
5. Trade is balanced for each country at all point in time, and all economies
are readily able to adjust to changes in the international prices with a
minimum of dislocation
6. The gains from trade that accrue to any country benefit the nationals of
that country.
We can now take a critical look at each of these assumptions in the context of
the contemporary of position of developing countries in the international
economic system. Some of these criticisms form the basis of other, non-
neoclassical theories of trade and development, including vent-for-surplus,
structuralist, and North South models. .. ..
It follows, therefore, that relative factor endowments and comparative costs are
not given but are in a state of constant change. Moreover they are often deter-
mined by, rather than themselves determining, the nature and character of inter-
39
national specialization. In the context of unequal trade between rich and poor
nations, this means that any initial state of unequal resource endowments will
tend to be reinforced and exacerbated by the very trade that these differing
resource endowments were supposed to justify. Specifically, if rich nations (the
North) as a result of historical forces are relatively well endowed with the vital
resources of capital, entrepreneurial ability, and skilled labor, their continued
specialization in products and processes that use these resources intensively
will create the necessary conditions and economic incentives for their further
growth. By contrast, Third World countries (the South), endowed with
abundant supplies of unskilled labor, by specializing in products that
intensively use unskilled labor and for which world demand prospect and terms
of trade may be very unfavorable, often find themselves locked into a stagnant
situation that perpetuates their comparative advantage in unskilled
unproductive activities. This will in turn inhibit the domestic growth of needed
capital, entrepreneurship, and technical skills. Static efficiency become
dynamic inefficiency, and a cumulative process is set in motion in which trade
exacerbates already unequal trading relationships, distributes the benefits
largely to the people who already "have," and perpetuates the physical and
human resource underdeveloped merit that characterizes most poor nations.
In recent years, some economists have therefore challenged the static neoclas-
sical model with alternative dynamic models of trade and growth that
emphasize the process of factor accumulation and uneven development along
the lines suggested in the, preceding paragraphs. These so-called North-South
trade models focus specifically on trade relations between rich and poor
countries, here as the traditional model was assumed to apply to all nations.
The typical North-South model argues, for example, that initial higher
endowments of capital in the industrialized North generate external economies
in manufacturing output and higher profit rates. This in combination with the
rise in monopoly power stimulates higher Northern growth rates (in accordance
with Harrod-Domar model discussed earlier) through further capital
40
accumulation. As a result, the rapidly growing North develops a cumulative
competitive advantage over the slower-growing South.
According to this theory, the opening of world markets to remote agrarian soci-
eties creates opportunities not to reallocate fully employed resources as in the
traditional models but -rather to make use of formerly underemployed land and
41
labor resources to produce greater output for export to foreign markets. The
colonial system of plantation agriculture as well as the commercialization of
small scale subsistence agriculture were made possible, according to this view,
by the availability of unemployed and underemployed human resources. In
terms of our production possibility analyses, the vent-for-surplus argument can
be represented by a shift in production from point V to point B in Figure 6.1
below.
C
Y’ International price ratio, Pa / Pm
Importables Imports
(manufacres)
Y B
V
Exports
O X X’
Exportables (Primary Products)
We see that before trade, the resources of this closed Third World economy
were grossly underutilized. Production was occurring at point V; well within
the confines of the production possibility frontier, and OX primary products
and OY manufactures were being produced and consumed. The opening up of
the nation to foreign markets provides the economic impetus to utilize these
idle resources. (mostly excess land and labor) and expand primary product
exportable production from OX to OX’ at point B on the production frontier.
Given the international price ratio Pa / Pm , X’ – X (equal to VB) primary
product can now be exported in exchange for Y' - Y. (equal to VC) manufac-
tures, with the result that the final consumption point, C, is attained with the
same primary products (X) being consumed as before but with Y'- Y more
imported manufactures now available.
The vent-for-surplus argument does provide a more realistic analytical scenario
42
of the historical trading experience of many LDCs than either the classical or
neoclassical model. However, in the short-run, the beneficiaries of this process
were often colonial and expatriate entrepreneurs rather than LDC nationals.
And in the long run, the heavy structural orientation of the LDC economy
toward primary-product exports in many cases created an export "enclave"
situation and thus inhibited needed structural transformation in the direction of
a more diversified and self-reliant economy.
The second conclusion that we may draw from the recognition of widespread
unemployment in the Third World is that a major .way to create substantial
local job opportunities is to protect domestic-, industries (both manufacturing
and agriculture) against low-cost foreign competition. This protection is
accomplished through the erection of various trade barriers such as tariffs or
quotas. We will discuss the pros and cons of commercial policy in part II of
development economics is that LDCs that place priority on employment
creation may wish to pursue a short - run protectionist policy in order to build
up local rural and urban industries to absorb their surplus labor. This is what
South Korea and Taiwan did in the
43
b) International factor mobility and multinational corporations
44
Technological substitution, together With the low income and price elasticities
of demand for primary products and the rise of agricultural protection in the
markets of developed nations; goes a long way toward explaining why
uncritical, adherence to the theoretical dictates of comparative advantage can
be a risky and often unrewarding venture for many LDCs.
On the other side of the ledger, however, is the argument that the worldwide
availability of "new technologies developed in the West has provided many
newly industrializing countries the-opportunity to capitalize on Western
research and development expenditures. By, first imitating-products
developed abroad but not on the frontiers of technological research, certain
LDCs- With sufficient human capital (e.g., the Asian NICs) can follow the
product cycle of international trade. Using their relatively lower Wages,
they move from low-tech to high-tech production, filling-manufacturing
gaps left, vacant by the more industrialized nations.
45
sovereign about anything, let alone about what and how many major
corporations are going to produce.
46
distribution facilities, and scarcities of managerial and skilled labor, often
inhibit an IDC's ability to respond in the smooth and frictionless way of the
neoclassical-trade model to changing international price signals.
47
Our point, therefore, is quite simple. Traditional trade theories neglect the
crucial role that national governments can and do play in the international
economic arena. Governments often serve to reinforce the unequal distribution
of resources and gains from trade resulting from differences in size and
economic power. Rich-country governments can influence world economic
affairs by their domestic and international policies. They can resist
countervailing economic pressures from weaker nations and can act in
collusion and often in conjunction with their powerful multinational
corporations to manipulate the terms and conditions of international trade to
their own national interests. There is no super agency or world government to
protect and promote the interests of the weaker parties (the LDCs) in such
international affaires. Trade theory makes no mention of these powerful
governmental forces. Its prescriptions are therefore greatly weakened by this
neglect.
48
For the non-oil-producing poor nations in particular, a combination of declin-
ing terms of trade and sluggish international demands for their export products
has meant chronic merchandise trade deficits. The gradual drying up of
bilateral and multilateral foreign assistance and the growing concern of LDCs
with the social costs of private foreign investment have meant that severe
balance of Payments problems necessitate further departures from relatively
free trade.
We know, for example, that in the enclave economies in the Third World, such
as those with substantial foreign-owned mining and plantation operations, for-
eigners pay very low rents for the rights to use land, bring in their own foreign
capital an skilled labor, hire local unskilled workers at subsistence wages, and
have a minimal effect on the rest of the economy even though they may
generate significant export revenue although mining and plantation enclaves
are gradually disappearing, they are often being replaced by "manufacturing
export enclaves personal computer assembly, running shoe and toy
manufacture, etc.) as a result of the economic penetrations of multinational
corporations
49
production in a wide range of countries, aggregate statistics for LDC export
earnings (and, indeed, GDP) may mask the fact that LDC nationals,
especially those in lower income brackets, may not benefit at all from these
exports. The major gains from trade may instead accrue to non-nationals,
who often repatriate large proportions of these earnings. The inter-and
intraindustry trade that is being carried out may do ok like trade between
rich and poor nations. But in reality such trade is being conducted between
rich nations and other nationals of rich nations operating in Third World
countries! Until recently, the activities of most mining and plantation
operations had this characteristic. More important, much of the recent
export enclave manufacturing activities in poor countries may merely be
masking the fact that a large proportion of the benefits are still being
reaped by foreign enterprises. In short, LDC export performances can be
deceptive unless we analyze the character and structure of export earnings
by ascertaining who owns or controls the factors of production that are
rewarded as a result of export expansion.
First, with regard to the rate, structure, and character of economic growth, our
conclusion is that trade can be an important stimulus to rapid economic
growth. This has been amply demonstrated by the successful experiences of
countries like 'Malaysia, Thailand, Brazil, Chile, Taiwan, Singapore, and
50
South Korea. Access to the markets of developed nations (an important factor
for developing nations bent on export promotion) can provide an important
stimulus for the greater utilization of idle human and capital resources.
Expanded foreign exchange earnings through improved export performance
also provide the wherewithal by which LDC can augment their scarce physical
and financial resources. In short where opportunities for profitable exchange
arise, foreign trade can provide an important aggregate economic growth
along the lines suggested by the traditional theory.
Clearly, if the price of a county’s exports is falling relative to the prices of the
products it imports, it will have to sell that much more of its export product and
enlist more of its scarce productive resources merely to secure the same level
of imported goods that it purchased in previous years. In other words, the real
or social opportunity costs of a unit of imports will rise for a country when its
export prices decline relative to its import prices.
Economists have a special name 'for the relationship or ratio between the price
of a typical unit of exports and the price of a typical unit of imports. This
relation ship is called the commodity terms of trade, and it is expressed as
Px/Pm, where Px and Pm represent the export and import price indexes,
respectively, calculated on the same base period (e.g., 1985 = 100). The
commodity terms of trade are said to deteriorate for a country if Px/ Pm falls,
51
that is, if export prices decline relative to 'import prices, even though both may
rise. Historically, the prices of primary commodities have declined relative to
manufactured goods. As a result, the terms of trade have on the average tended
to worsen over time for the non-oil exporting developing countries while
showing a relative improvement for the developed countries. For example,
recent empirical studies suggest that real primary product prices have declined
at 'an average annual rate of 0.6%, since 1900. In the 17 years between 1977
and 1994, the prices of non-oil commodities relative to those of exported
manufactures declined by almost 60% so that 1994 they had reached their
lowest point in 90 years.
After Prebish and Singer have put their analysis, a number of other economists
have worked on the historical trend analysis of the terms of trade. Some have
shown the existence of trend determination in the terms of trade of LDC and
others have shown a trendless movement. A major study of the recent behavior
of non-oil commodity price by the IMF reaches the following conclusions:
• The recent weakness of real commodity prices (the terms of trade) appears
to be primarily of a secular, persistent nature, and not the product of a large
temporary deviation from the trend.
52
• The declining trend is partly the result of a slowing up in the growth of
demand, but much more important has been the growth of commodity
supply.
• The volatility of commodity prices has increased steadily and considerably
since the early 1970s, particularly in the once relatively stable food
grouping.
53