20.09.investment Valuation and Asset Pricing - Models and Methods
20.09.investment Valuation and Asset Pricing - Models and Methods
Seppo Pynnönen
Departent of Mathematics and Statistics, University of Vaasa, Vaasa,
Finland
© The Editor(s) (if applicable) and The Author(s), under exclusive license
to Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2023
This work is subject to copyright. All rights are solely and exclusively
licensed by the Publisher, whether the whole or part of the material is
concerned, specifically the rights of translation, reprinting, reuse of
illustrations, recitation, broadcasting, reproduction on microfilms or in any
other physical way, and transmission or information storage and retrieval,
electronic adaptation, computer software, or by similar or dissimilar
methodology now known or hereafter developed.
The publisher, the authors, and the editors are safe to assume that the advice
and information in this book are believed to be true and accurate at the date
of publication. Neither the publisher nor the authors or the editors give a
warranty, expressed or implied, with respect to the material contained
herein or for any errors or omissions that may have been made. The
publisher remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published
maps and institutional affiliations.
This Palgrave Macmillan imprint is published by the registered company
Springer Nature Switzerland AG
The registered company address is: Gewerbestrasse 11, 6330 Cham,
Switzerland
For my wife Karie and family Wes and Mary.
—James W. Kolari
For my wife Marja Leena and family Lauri, Erno,
and Laura and Nicklas and grandchildren
Sebastian, Benjamin, and Vanessa.
—Seppo Pynnönen
with admiration and love.
Preface
A major change in the field of finance was marked by the advent of the
Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM). Numerous authors are credited with
this famous model of how asset prices are determined, including Treynor
(1961, 1962), Sharpe (1964), Lintner (1965), Mossin (1966), and Black
(1972). According to Black (1981) and recounted by French (2003), Jack
Treynor is now recognized to have developed the first version of the CAPM
as early as 1958 during a summer vacation to Colorado. As a former
graduate of Harvard University, he shared his writings with John Lintner at
Harvard in 1960. Never formally publishing his work, in the early 1960s he
presented the CAPM as a graduate student at the Massachusetts Institute of
Technology (MIT) to finance faculty, including Robert Merton.1 A close
friend and colleague was Fischer Black, with whom numerous discussions
of the model likely led to Black's later work on the related zero-beta
CAPM. Additionally, Jan Mossin was from Norway but attended Ph.D.
studies at Carnegie Mellon University in the United States. Together, these
students and professors worked contemporaeously on the fundamental
relation between risk and return (or prices) of assets.
An important foundation underlying the CAPM is the mean-variance
analyses of Markowitz (1952, 1959) and Tobin (1958). Harry Markowitz
received his Ph.D. in Economics from the University of Chicago on
portfolio theory. His work led to the fundamental concept of diversification
in portfolio investments. By combining assets in a portfolio with returns
that are less than perfectly correlated, investors can reduce risk as measured
by the variance of returns. In theory, by varying expected returns, an infinite
number of portfolios comprised of assets can be constructed that have
minumum risk at different return levels. These portfolios trace out an
efficient frontier in expected return/variance space. Relevant to the CAPM,
total risk (or variance of returns) can be divided into diversifiable and
nondiversifiable risks. It is the nondiversifiable portion of risk, known as
systematic risk, that is the focus of the CAPM. Markowitz worked for some
time at the Cowles Foundation of Yale University, where he met James
Tobin, a Harvard trained economist and Yale professor. Tobin’s insightful
separation principle posited that risk-averse investors seek: (1) efficient
portfolios and (2) some optimum fraction of an efficient portfolio and a
riskless asset as determined by their risk aversion. Importantly, these two
investment decisions are separate from one another.
It is interesting that the lives of these early pioneers in asset pricing
crossed paths with one another during the development of the CAPM. Their
interaction was instrumental in the evolution of breakthroughs that
transformed our thinking about risk and return in finance. Of course, it
helps to be smart too! In this regard, Nobel Prizes in Economics were
awarded to Tobin (1981), Markowitz (1990), and Sharpe (1990). Other
contributors did not receive this honor due to death or nonpublication but
are no less appreciated for their intellectual achievements. Certainly all of
these notable scholars played important roles in shaping our understanding
of modern finance. This book pays tribute to their accomplishments by
retracing their steps in financial history.
Investments Valuation and Asset Pricing: Models and Methods is
intended to fill a gap in undergraduate finance curriculums by providing an
asset pricing text that is accessible to undergraduate students. The course is
most suitable for senior finance students in the last year of their
undergraduate studies. Also, it can be used in a graduate finance class,
including Executive M.B.A. and Executive Business Education. The book
has three unique features that set it apart from other finance textbooks.
1.
Original published studies by researchers on the foundations of asset
pricing are reviewed in chronological order over time. Retracing their
steps in financial history, each chapter stays close to their authentic
works, including quotations, examples, graphical exhibits, and
empirical results. We want undergraduate students to gain a firm grasp
of their achievements in the theory and practice of finance.
2.
Important statistical concepts and methods relevant to the field of
finance are covered. These statistical materials are crucial to learning
asset pricing, which often employs statistical tests to evaluate different
asset pricing models. Also, statistical skills are important tools for any
finance professional.
3.
Practical examples, questions, and problems are included in the text to
help students check their learning and better understand the
fundamentals of asset pricing.
The roadmap for our journey through the emergence and development
of asset pricing is as follows.
Chapter 1 reviews the diversification principles of Markowitz (1952,
1959).
Chapter 2 introduces the basic assumptions of investor behavior and
financial markets that are foundational to asset pricing models.
Chapter 3 builds upon these principles by following Sharpe’s (1964)
derivation of the CAPM under equilibrium market conditions.
Chapter 4 covers the CAPM market model that is used for empirical
estimation using real world return data.
Chapter 5 reviews the first extension of the CAPM known as the zero-
beta CAPM by Black (1972).
Chapter 6 overviews a number of other forms of the CAPM developed by
researchers, including the intertemporal CAPM, international asset
pricing model (IAPM), consumption CAPM (CCAPM), production
CAPM (PCAPM), and conditional CAPM.
Chapter 7 reviews the famous arbitrage pricing model (APT) by Ross
(1976).
Chapter 8 introduces the innovative Fama and French (1993) three-factor
model.
Chapter 9 expands the discussion to other multifactor models that have
become increasingly popular over the past few decades.
Chapter 10 reviews theory and evidence with respect to a recently
proposed special case of the zero-beta CAPM dubbed the ZCAPM by
Kolari, Liu, and Huang (2021).
Chapter 11 applies asset pricing models to event studies that investigate
the effects of market news announcements on stock returns.
Fig. 1.3 The minimum variance boundary of portfolios based on data for
securities 1 and 2 in Table 1.3
Fig. 1.4 The minimum variance boundary of portfolios and opportunity set
of all assets
Fig. 2.2 Expected returns and utility for multiple risky investment choices
Fig. 2.4 Empirical return distributions for Microsoft, U.S. S &P 500 index,
and German Dax index using daily, weekly, and monthly returns
Fig. 3.1 Equilibrium relationship between expected rates of return and risk
Fig. 4.1 The estimated market model for Microsoft (MSFT) stock returns
with fitted regression line
Fig. 5.2 Industry portfolios and S &P 500 index returns with ex post
efficient frontier and the market line
Fig. 6.3 Currency risk in world currency markets affects the stock returns in
different countries through their exchange rate risk exposure or sensitivity
to national currency movements
Fig. 6.4 Consumers buy and sell financial assets over time to smooth
consumption in the consumption CAPM (CCAPM)
Fig. 6.5 Close relation between stock return and capital investment
forecasts in the production CAPM (PCAPM)
Fig. 6.6 Beta estimates for the market factor tend to vary randomly over
time consistent with the unconditional CAPM but contrary to the
conditional CAPM
Fig. 7.1 Arbitraging riskless profits by buying and selling mispriced assets
(Source Adapted from Wikipedia
[https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Arbitrage_pricing_theory])
Fig. 8.1 Stocks are sorted into a 2 3 matrix by size and value (BM). The
size factor is the average returns of the three small (blue) portfolios minus
the three (red) big portfolios, and the value factor is average returns of the
two value (green) portfolios minus the two growth (brown) portfolios
Fig. 8.2 The Fama and French three-factor model with excess returns a
function of market, size, and value factors takes into account four
dimensions in return/risk space
Fig. 9.2 Multifactor models extensions of the original Fama and French
three-factor model using discretionary methods
Fig. 9.3 Machine learning methods based on artificial intelligence (AI)
models rather than human judgment
Fig. 10.2 The ZCAPM with beta risk related to average excess market
returns and zeta risk associated with positive and negative sensitivity to
return dispersion (Source Kolari et al. 2021, p. 72)
Fig. 10.4 This graph shows the average beta risk, zeta risk, and one-month-
ahead equal-weighted returns for 25 beta-zeta sorted portfolios. These long-
only portfolios approximate the shape on an investment parabola. In each
one-year estimation window, the empirical ZCAPM is estimated using daily
returns to obtain the beta and zeta risk parameters. The analysis period is
January 1965–December 2018 (Source Kolari et al. 2021, p. 272)
Table 1.2 Actual or realized (ex post) return and risk over time (in percent
terms)
Table 1.3 Portfolio return and risk effects (in percent terms)
Table 2.1 Sample statistics for S &P 500 index, DAX index, and Microsoft
Corporation: daily, weekly, and monthly returns (in percent)
Table 4.1 Monthly returns for Microsoft (MSFT), S &P 500 index, and
Treasury bills from January 2018 to December 2020
Table 8.1 Average monthly returns for U.S. stock portfolios sorted by size
and book-to-market equity (BM) from July 1963 to December 1990 in the
Fama and French (1992) study
Table 9.3 Mispricing error of different models in the Lettau and Pelger
(2020) study
Table 11.1 Short-run event study results for 50 SEO events of U.S. firms
from 1985 to 2015
Table 11.2 Abnormal returns for four industries using the Fama and French
five-factor model: Selected news announcement dates during the 2008
financial crisis and 2020 COVID-19 crisis
Table 11.3 Long-run event study results for 200 SEO events of U.S. firms
from 1985 to 2015
Footnotes
1 See Chapter 2 of Korajczyk (1999) for a reproduction of Treynor (1962).
© The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2023
J. W. Kolari, S. Pynnönen, Investment Valuation and Asset Pricing
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-16784-3_1
Seppo Pynnönen
Email: [email protected]
Supplementary Information
The online version contains supplementary material available at https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-16784-3_1
This chapter overviews the portfolio selection process developed by Nobel Laureate Harry Markowitz (1952,
1959). Basic concepts are introduced that are important in the field of asset pricing. These concepts are
fundamental to understanding the relation between return and risk, which is the central theme of finance.
Markowitz showed how to reduce risk by diversification in assets with less than perfect correlation. Many experts
agree that diversification is the only “free lunch” available to investors in the market for real and financial assets.
Diversification leads to the mean-variance parabola that describes the lowest risk portfolios for any given return.
These major advances in modern portfolio theory have laid the foundation for general equilibrium asset pricing
models in forthcoming chapters. Moreover, they have revolutionized investment management practices around the
world.
Should investors seek securities that maximize expected returns? On its surface, the answer to this simple
question would seem to be “yes.” However, Markowitz (1952, p. 77) argued that, “The hypothesis (or maxim) that
the investor does (or should) maximize discounted return must be rejected.” In his words, any rule of investment
behavior that ignored “... the superiority of diversification must be rejected.” A better rule is to maximize expected
returns per unit of risk. Risk can be conveniently measured as the variance of returns.
Returning to Table 1.1, the variance of returns across states for security j is equal to 12.50. Variance is a
measure of the dispersion, volatility, or variability of returns across the states. The formula for the variance of
returns is:
$$\begin{aligned} \sigma ^2(R_j) = \sum _{s=1}^S p_s [R_{sj}-E(R_j)]^2. \end{aligned}$$ (1.5)
The variance of returns is not in percentage terms like expected returns. However, the standard deviation of
returns is an equivalent measure of total risk that has units of measurement in percentage terms like expected
returns. We can easily compute the standard deviation of returns as:
$$\begin{aligned} \sigma (R_j)= \sqrt{\sigma ^2(R_j)}. \end{aligned}$$ (1.6)
Using the data in Table 1.1, we get approximately $$\sigma (R_j)=\sqrt{12.50}\approx 3.54\%$$. Given
a one standard deviation change in returns due to volatility, returns can vary around the expected return from a low
of $$6.46\%\ (= 10\% - 3.54\%)$$ to a high of $$13.54\%\ (= 10\% + 3.54\%)$$. A two-standard
deviation change implies a range from 2.92% to 17.08%. From statistics, it is known that two-standard deviations
encompass all possible future return outcomes with a 95% probability. This wide range of values suggests that
security j is fairly risky, which explains the relatively high expected return of 10%.
Based on these return and risk concepts, Markowitz established straightforward methods for evaluating
portfolio effects. The expected return of a portfolio is defined as:
$$\begin{aligned} E(R_P)= w_1 E(R_1) + w_2 E(R_2), \end{aligned}$$ (1.7)
where $$w_1$$ is the proportion invested in security 1, and $$w_2$$ is the proportion invested in
security 2. Note that the sum $$w_1 + w_2 =1$$, i.e., $$w_2 = (1-w_1)$$. What is the variance of
portfolio returns? Here is where Markowitz made an important contribution to our thinking about risk. The
variance formula from basic statistical methods is:
$$\begin{aligned} \sigma ^2(R_P) = w^2_1 \sigma ^2(R_1) + 2 w_1 w_2 Cov (R_1,R_2) + w^2_2 \sigma
(1.8)
^2(R_2), \end{aligned}$$
where $$Cov (R_1,R_2)$$ = the covariance of returns between security 1 and security 2 over time.
Covariance can be expressed in terms of deviations from expected returns for each security:
$$\begin{aligned} Cov (R_1,R_2) = E\{[R_1 - E(R_1)] [R_2 - E(R_2)]\}. \end{aligned}$$ (1.9)
A useful statistical definition of return covariance is:
$$\begin{aligned} Cov (R_1,R_2) = \rho _{12} \sigma (R_1) \sigma (R_2), \end{aligned}$$ (1.10)
where $$\rho _{12}$$ = the correlation of returns between security 1 and security 2 over time. For two
securities, denoting the covariance term $$Cov (R_j,R_k)$$ in the simpler notation $$\sigma _{jk}$$,
we can re-write Eq. (1.8) in matrix form as:
$$\begin{aligned} \sigma _P^2 =(w_1, w_2) \begin{pmatrix} \sigma _{11} &{} \sigma _{12}\\
\sigma _{21} &{} \sigma _{22} \end{pmatrix} \begin{pmatrix} w_1\\ w_2 \end{pmatrix} = w^2_1 (1.11)
\sigma ^2_1 + w_1 w_2 (\sigma _{12} + \sigma _{21}) + w^2_2 \sigma ^2_2, \end{aligned}$$
where $$w_1 + w_2 = 1$$, $$\sigma ^2(R_1) = \sigma _{11} = \sigma ^2_1$$, and
$$\sigma ^2(R_2)= \sigma _{22} = \sigma ^2_2$$. Notice that the covariance terms $$\sigma _{12}$$
and $$\sigma _{21}$$ are equal to one another and, therefore, their sum equals $$2 \sigma _{12}$$
such that:
$$\begin{aligned} \sigma _P^2 = w^2_1 \sigma ^2_1 + 2 w_1 w_2 \sigma _{12} + w^2_2 \sigma ^2_2,
(1.12)
\end{aligned}$$
which is the same as Eq. (1.8).
Instead of assessing future expected returns, which requires dealing with uncertainty about the future, let’s
consider how to measure expected returns and risk from ex post or historical data. We can measure past returns and
risk over time. Suppose securities 1 and 2 have actual or realized returns in previous years 1 to 5 after investment
as shown in Table 1.2. To compute the sample mean or average return for security j over $$t = 1, \ldots , T$$
periods, we can use the following formula:
$$\begin{aligned} \bar{R}_j= \frac{\sum _{t=1}^T R_{jt}}{T}. \end{aligned}$$ (1.13)
The sample variance of returns over time t related to risk is:
$$\begin{aligned} \sigma ^2(R_j)= \frac{\sum _{t=1}^T (R_{jt} - \bar{R}_j)^2}{T-1}. \end{aligned}$$ (1.14)
As shown in Table 1.2, the returns for securities 1 and 2 over the past five years are known. From this data we
can compute their average returns over the five years—namely, $$\bar{R}_1 = 12.2$$% and
$$\bar{R}_2= 6.6$$%, respectively. The variance of their returns can be computed, which yields
$$\sigma ^2(R_1) = 20.70$$ with $$\sigma (R_1) = 4.55$$% and $$\sigma ^2(R_2) = 7.30$$
with $$\sigma (R_2) = 2.70$$%.
This information can be utilized to see how the average portfolio return $$\bar{R}_P$$ and variance of
portfolio returns $$\sigma ^2(R_P)$$ changes as the proportion investment weights $$w_1$$ and
$$w_2$$ are changed. Table 1.3 shows the portfolio results. A naive investor that sought to maximize
average portfolio returns would choose weights $$w_1 = 1$$ and $$w_1 = 0$$ to earn an average
return ( $$\bar{R}_P$$) equal to 12.20%; hence, such investor would put all their funds in security 1.
However, according to Markowitz, we need to evaluate how the security weights affect both
$$\bar{R}_P$$ and $$\sigma (R_P)$$. Table 1.3 shows that, as $$w_1$$ increases from 0.1 to
0.9 and $$w_2$$ decreases from 0.9 to 0.1, the portfolio variance increases. If we take the ratio of average
returns/standard deviation of returns, we see that this ratio reaches a maximum at 8.28/2.25 = 3.68 using weights
$$w_1 = 0.3$$ and $$w_2 = 0.7$$. Investing only in security 1, such that $$w_1 = 1.0$$ and
$$w_2 = 0.0$$, this ratio equals 12.20/4.55 = 2.68, which is not as high as 3.68 for the two-security portfolio
with $$w_1 = 0.30$$ and $$w_2 = 0.70$$. It is clear that, per unit standard deviation of returns (or
risk), the investor is better off holding a portfolio containing both securities 1 and 2 with weights 0.30 and 0.70,
respectively. This example demonstrates that investment returns should only be evaluated in the context of
portfolio returns per unit risk. Investors should seek to maximize portfolio returns per unit risk as measured by the
standard deviation or variance of returns.
Table 1.3 Portfolio return and risk effects (in percent terms)
$$w_ $$w_ $$\bar{R}_ $$\bar{R}_ $$\bar{R}_ $$\sig $$\sig $$\r $$Cov $$\sigm $$\sig $$\bar
1$$ 2$$ 1$$ 2$$ P$$ ma ma ho (R_1,R_2)$$ a ma ma (R_P
(R_1)$$ (R_2)$$ _{12}$$ ^2(R_P)$$ (R_P)$$
0.0 1.0 12.2 6.6 6.60 4.55 2.70 0.1708 0.0000 7.29 2.70 2.44
0.1 0.9 12.2 6.6 7.16 4.55 2.70 0.1708 2.0983 4.40 2.10 3.41
0.3 0.7 12.2 6.6 8.28 4.55 2.70 0.1708 2.0983 5.05 2.25 3.68
0.5 0.5 12.2 6.6 9.40 4.55 2.70 0.1708 2.0983 7.40 2.72 3.46
0.7 0.3 12.2 6.6 10.52 4.55 2.70 0.1708 2.0983 11.45 3.38 3.11
0.9 0.1 12.2 6.6 11.64 4.55 2.70 0.1708 2.0983 17.19 4.15 2.80
1.0 0.0 12.2 6.6 12.20 4.55 2.70 0.4549 0.0000 20.70 4.55 2.68
In the above portfolio analyses, portfolio risk can be dramatically affected by the correlation between security
1 returns and security 2 returns, which can be measured by the correlation coefficient $$\rho _{12}$$. If
$$\rho _{12} < 1$$ , Markowitz argued that the total risk of the portfolio as measured by
$$\sigma ^2(R_P)$$ can be reduced. This reduction in risk is due to a diversification benefit arising from
less than perfect positive correlation at $$\rho _{12} = 1$$. The old adage that to diversify you should not
“... put all your eggs in one basket” needed amendment. According to Markowitz’s insight, to successfully
diversify, you need to “... put your money in multiple securities that are not perfectly correlated with one another.”
Using the simpler notation in Eq. (1.12), if securities 1 and 2 are perfectly positively correlated such that
$$\sigma _P^2 = w^2_1 \sigma ^2_1 +2w_1 w_2 \sigma _1 \sigma _2 (i.e.,
$$\rho _{12} = 1$$, then
+ w^2_2 \sigma ^2_2$$
$$\sigma _{12} = 1 \sigma _1 \sigma _2$$). If they are uncorrelated with $$\rho _{12} = 0$$ so that
$$\sigma _{12} = 0$$, then $$\sigma _P^2 = w^2_1 \sigma ^2_1 + w^2_2 \sigma ^2_2$$, as the term
$$2w_1 w_2 \sigma _{12}$$ = 0. Clearly, dropping this covariance term reduces the variance of portfolio
returns. Surprisingly, if securities 1 and 2 have perfectly negatively correlated returns with
$$\sigma _P^2 = w^2_1 \sigma ^2_1 - 2w_1 w_2 \sigma _1 \sigma _2
$$\rho _{12} = -1$$, such that
+ w^2_2 \sigma ^2_2$$
(i.e., $$\sigma _{12} = -1 \sigma _1 \sigma _2$$), portfolio variance can be substantially reduced.
Remarkably, assuming that the investment proportions $$w_1$$ and $$w_2$$ are chosen optimally,
perfect negative correlation of two securities can drive total risk down to zero! Appendix A shows how to compute
the optimal weights for two securities.
Figure 1.1 provides graphical depictions of how the correlation between the returns of securities 1 and 2 over
time affects portfolio returns. The top panel shows that, if the securities’ returns are perfectly positively correlated
with $$\rho _{12} = 1$$, the combined portfolio exhibits an identical pattern of returns over time. If
$$\rho _{12} = -1$$, portfolio returns could be flat line indicating zero total risk or volatility. In the more
likely case that $$0< \rho _{12} < 1$$, the portfolio return is less volatile than either security due to
diversification that results in risk reduction.
In the real world, it is most likely that $$0< \rho _{12} < 1$$. Indeed, it can be difficult to find
securities that have negative correlations with other securities over time. Given $$\rho _{12}$$, the investor
should seek to minimize the variance of portfolio returns by optimally choosing the investment proportions or
weights $$w_1$$ and $$w_2$$ to achieve this goal. These optimal weights can be solved to generate
the average return and variance of a minimum variance portfolio, or $$\bar{R}_P$$ and
$$\sigma ^2_P$$. In this regard, at each level of $$\bar{R}_P$$, a different minimum variance
portfolio is possible.
Figure 1.2 illustrates the basic principles of Markowitz diversification. We assume that only two securities are
considered. Securities 1 and 2 have correlation somewhere in the reasonable range
$$0< \rho _{12} < 1$$. Average returns are on the Y-axis, and standard deviations of returns are on the
X-axis. The locations of securities 1 and 2 are shown in return/standard deviation space. The set of portfolios that
would exist if these securities were perfectly positively correlated ( $$\rho _{12} = 1$$) is shown by the
dashed line. Two other dashed lines coincide with different combinations of these securities if they were perfectly
negatively correlated. Portfolio X is the zero variance combination of these portfolios at some optimal weights.
Here we interchangeably use the words variance and standard deviation of returns, which measure total risk.
The curved bold line in Fig. 1.2 shows the infinite number of optimal combinations of securities 1 and 2 with
minimum variance based on varying the average return of the portfolio. Markowitz referred to this curve as the
mean-variance parabola. The range of average portfolio returns runs from all security 1 (i.e., $$w_1 = 1$$
so the $$\bar{R}_P= R_1$$) to all security 2 (i.e., $$w_2 = 1$$ so the $$\bar{R}_P = R_2$$).
Portfolio G is the global minimum variance portfolio that has the smallest variance of returns for all possible
combinations of these two securities. Portfolio G has average return $$R_G$$. Importantly, Markowitz
named the set of minimum variance portfolios on the upward sloping boundary of the bold curve the efficient
frontier. These portfolios are efficient in the sense that they have: (1) the lowest variance for any given average
portfolio return, and (2) the highest average portfolio return for any given variance of returns. He argued that
rational, risk-averse investors would only be interested in these efficient portfolios. Other portfolios on the
downward sloping boundary of the bold curve are inefficient minimum variance portfolios.
Fig. 1.3 The minimum variance boundary of portfolios based on data for securities 1 and 2 in Table 1.3
Figure 1.3 shows the efficient frontier based on security 1 and security 2 data for average portfolio returns and
standard deviations of portfolio returns in Table 1.3. Recalling this table, we varied the security weights
$$w_1$$ and $$w_2$$ from 0 to 1 for each security. The returns of securities 1 and 2 equal to 8.40%
and 9.60%, respectively, are represented by the endpoints of the bold frontier. Since their correlation coefficient
$$\rho _{12} = 0.3544 < 1$$, different combinations of securities 1 and 2 generate a Markowitzian
efficient frontier. Referring to the data in Table 1.3, the global minimum variance portfolio G has weights of
approximately $$w_1 \approx 0.1$$ and $$w_2 \approx 0.90$$. Portfolios on the minimum variance
boundary from G to security 1 comprise the efficient frontier. Investors would choose different minimum variance
portfolios based on their risk preferences. The most risk averse investors would logically choose G. As risk
aversion decreases, investors would choose portfolios with higher average returns on the efficient frontier.
Fig. 1.4 The minimum variance boundary of portfolios and opportunity set of all assets
Lastly, consider the more realistic and general case of many assets, not just securities but all assets. The
population of assets includes both financial and nonfinancial (real) assets such as stocks, bonds, real estate,
commodities, etc. As the number of assets under consideration increases, the efficient frontier will gradually move
left due to increasing diversification benefits. Figure 1.4 illustrates the efficient frontier for all assets in the
opportunity set at a single point in time.
It is interesting to consider what happens to the shape of the parabola over time. Some assets may experience
higher returns and others lower returns than in previous periods (e.g., days). Over time the vertical width of the
parabola could increase or decrease on a daily basis in response to changes in the cross-sectional return dispersion
among assets (i.e., the variability of returns across all assets at any given time).
Assuming a large number N of assets that is not infinite in number, in theory a return/standard deviation
hyperbola exists (or a return/variance parabola).1 A dashed line is shown at $$E(R_G)$$ that divides the
hyperbola into equal and symmetric halves. This line is known as the axis of symmetry.
For a large number of N securities, the average portfolio return can be written more generally as follows:
$$\begin{aligned} \mu _P = \sum _{j=1}^N w_j E(R_j), \end{aligned}$$ (1.15)
where $$\mu$$ denotes the population mean return, $$w_j$$ is the weight for the jth security,
$$\sum _{j=1}^N w_j =1$$ , and other notation is as before. The variance of portfolio returns for N securities
is:
$$\begin{aligned} \sigma _P^2 = \sum _{j=1}^N w_j^2 \sigma ^2_j + \sum _{j=1}^N \sum _{k \ne j}^N
(1.16)
w_j w_k \rho _{jk}\sigma _j \sigma _k, \end{aligned}$$
where $$Cov (R_j,R_k) = \sigma _{jk} = \rho _{jk}\sigma _j \sigma _k$$. In terms of the covariances of
security returns, the same formula can be alternatively written as:
$$\begin{aligned} \sigma _P^2 = \sum _{j=1}^N \sum _{k = 1}^N w_j w_k Cov (R_j,R_k) = \sum
(1.17)
_{j=1}^N \sum _{k = 1}^N w_j w_k \sigma _{jk}. \end{aligned}$$
In this realistic case of many securities or assets, the computation of the optimal weights to minimize variance
at different feasible expected return levels is considerably more complicated than the two-asset case discussed
above. Appendix B reviews Markowitz’s solution to this optimization problem. In the real world, some problems
can arise in this solution. For example, some assets will get very low weights that do not allow their inclusion in
the portfolio (e.g., the cost of the investment is less than determined by the weight). Another challenge is that the
portfolio weights need to be adjusted over time to maintain efficient portfolios. To do this, rebalancing transactions
costs must be incurred by buying and selling assets. These costs can offset potential diversification benefits. Yet
another issue is that some researchers have documented that the out-of-sample performance of Markowitz
portfolios is not very good. In this regard, Michaud (1989) found that even simple equal-weighted portfolio
returns have outperformed optimally weighted mean-variance efficient portfolios.
What could explain this poor performance? It is well known that estimation errors can be serious in terms of
accurately measuring input values such as expected returns that are proxied by average historical sample returns.
Also, portfolio performance can be diminished due to other issues, including liquidity requirements, management
policy guidelines, and benchmarks to use for performance evaluation.
1.3 Summary
According to Markowitz (1952, 1959), investors follow a two-step portfolio section process. First, they assess the
potential future (ex ante) performance of securities. Second, they choose a portfolio of securities based on
maximizing the discounted values of future returns by using the present value formula. In this formula, expected
cash flows are in the numerator, and the expected rate of return or discount rate is in the denominator. The discount
rate contains the riskless rate plus a risk premium related to the risk of the security and the risk aversion of
investors. The expected return and variance of returns (or risk) can be computed from the probabilities of returns in
different states of the world.
In a portfolio, the expected return and variance of returns (risk) are affected by the proportionate weights used
for the securities, their individual expected returns and variances of returns, and the correlation of their returns.
The latter correlation results in a covariance term. If two assets have less than perfect correlation, the covariance
term will be reduced, which decreases the variance of returns. Hence, diversification reduces the risk of the
portfolio but not its expected return.
Investors can use ex post return information to compute average returns and the variance of returns over time
for any security. By weighting security holdings, an investor can evaluate the optimal weights that maximize
average returns per unit standard deviation of returns (or variance of returns). Mathematical methods exist to
compute the optimal weights of different securities in a portfolio. Minimum variance portfolios define the mean-
variance investment parabola of Markowitz. The smallest variance portfolio is the minimum variance global
portfolio G. The efficient frontier is the upper boundary of the parabola to the right of G. Minimum variance
portfolios on the lower boundary of the parabola are inefficient. In the real world, some challenges exist in
implementing minimum variance portfolios on the efficient frontier. Extremely small weights for assets, trading
costs, and estimation of expected returns from average historical returns have led to poor out-of-sample portfolio
performance of optimally weighted portfolios. Further work is needed to realize the dream of highly diversified,
efficient portfolios in professional investment management.
Questions
1.
What is the two-step investment process proposed by Markowitz?
2.
Write the general present value formula used to maximize the discounted value of future investment returns.
What are the two components of the discount rate?
3.
Assume that there are s states of nature. Write the formulas for the expected return of security j and the
variance of security j returns. Next assume that there are two securities 1 and 2 in a portfolio. Write the
formulas for the expected return and variance of portfolio returns.
4.
What is the difference between ex ante and ex post returns?
5.
Write the formulas for ex post computation of mean or average returns for security j for time
$$t = 1, \ldots , T$$ periods and the sample variance of returns.
6.
According to Markowitz, what is wrong with maximizing returns of a portfolio as an investment goal? How
can investors use ex post data to evaluate an investment?
7.
How does the correlation between different assets in a portfolio affect the risk of the portfolio?
8.
Figure 1.2 in the text plots the mean-variance parabola of Markowitz. Why is the parabola curved in shape?
What is the minimum variance portfolio? What is the efficient frontier? Are some portfolios on the parabola
inefficient?
9.
In the real world, there are millions of assets. Why have investors had difficulty implementing Markowitz’s
optimization methods to find the optimal weights of assets to hold and therefore hold portfolios on the mean-
variance parabola?
Problems
1.
Table 1.1 contains some computations of the expected rate of return and variance of returns for an asset.
Assume that the probability $$p_s$$ are changed to 0.30, 0.40, and 0.30 in states 1, 2, and 3, respectively.
Recompute the results to create a new Table 1.1.
2.
Table 1.2 computes the average return and variance of returns for two securities. For security 1, change the
returns for years 1 through 5 to the return series 5, 10, 6, 12, and 15. For security 2, change the return series to
8, 9, 8, 5, and 12. Recompute the results to create a new Table 1.2.
3. Table 1.3 computes the portfolio return and risk (in percent) using the data in Table 1.2. Use the data in your
new Table 1.2 from problem 2 to create a new Table 1.3.
References
Kolari, J.W., W. Liu, and J. Huang. 2021. A New Capital Asset Pricing Model: Theory and Evidence. New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan.
[Crossref]
Markowitz, H.M. 1959. Portfolio Selection: Efficient Diversification of Investments. New York, NY: Wiley.
Michaud, R.O. 1989. The Markowitz optimization enigma: Is “optimized’’ optimal? Financial Analysts Journal 45: 31–42.
[Crossref]
Footnotes
1 Kolari et al. (2021) observed that the efficient frontier could collapse to the Y-axis in the unrealistic case of infinite number of assets. In the real world,
the total number of assets is large but far from this infinite limit condition.
© The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland
AG 2023
J. W. Kolari, S. PynnönenInvestment Valuation and Asset
Pricinghttps://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-16784-3_2
Seppo Pynnönen
Email: [email protected]
Supplementary Information
This chapter covers different aspects of capital markets that are essential to
understanding asset pricing. In the previous chapter, we learned that market
participants make investment choices based on the expected returns and
risks of assets. Total risk is measured by the variance or standard deviation
of returns. According to Markowitz, investors should diversify to minimize
risk and, in turn, seek to maximize their returns per unit risk. We begin this
chapter by considering the following market conditions that facilitate asset
pricing by investors: perfect capital markets, efficient markets, risk aversion,
and normally distributed returns. While these market conditions do not
always hold in the real world, they may be sufficiently justified by
regulatory and legal practices in countries that promote the development of
modern capital markets.
rational behavior;
perfect certainty.
In the real world, however, investors may not always act rationally. For
example, suppose that you have a choice between increasing your
wealth and compromising a friendship or family relation. It is possible that
you would not seek to maximize your personal wealth in this situation. For
personal reasons, you may choose to sacrifice potential wealth gains in favor
of your ethical values. From a broader perspective, financial markets can
behave in irrational ways at times. History is replete with price crashes in
financial markets. Asset prices begin to fall in the market due to some bad
news. As prices fall, panic can break out among investors, which causes
large numbers of investors to sell en masse with severe downward pressure
on prices. Conversely, at times market optimism or irrational exuberance1
can push asset prices up to excessively high levels known as a bubble.
Normally, bubbles are precursors of crashes as they later burst with
devastating consequences to asset prices.
All Investors Are Price Takers. No investor should be able to move prices
by buying and selling assets, thereby becoming a price maker. Instead, all
investors should be price takers. Investors have equal and costless access to
information needed to price assets. If an investor did have an ability to set
prices, they could unfairly achieve arbitrage profits. Again, arbitrage profits
do not exist in a perfect capital market.
Perfect Certainty. Lastly, all investors agree about the future expected
returns and risks of assets. This certainty implies homogeneous
beliefs among investors concerning the mean-variance investment parabola
proposed by Markowitz. Without this assumption, no equilibrium prices are
available to construct the investment parabola. In this regard, it should be
noted that, even in uncertain markets, homogeneous expectations are
essential to equilibrium asset prices.
Are capital markets perfect in the real world? Of course, this possibility is
far from reality. Nonetheless, this assumption is a useful simplification in
theoretical derivations of asset pricing models, which we cover in
forthcoming chapters. No model is completely valid due to the violation of
perfect markets. Instead, the validity of models is determined by their
empirical success in helping to explain realized returns and risks in the
financial marketplace. If they do a good job based on actual price data, we
can infer that violations of the perfect capital markets assumption are not so
large as to prevent us from measuring returns and risks with a fair degree of
accuracy.
Many tests of publicly available news about companies have shown that
semi-strong efficiency holds in financial markets. Fama showed that prices
react rapidly to news of a stock split by a company. Many event studies of
news announcements about new products, patent approvals, changes in
profits, etc., have confirmed that prices are fairly efficient in response to
most public information. However, there are numerous studies that find
persistent abnormal price movements lasting over a year or more in response
to major corporate actions, including mergers and acquisitions, new issues
of stocks, stock repurchases, dividend initiations, etc. Again,
behavioralists attribute these long-run abnormal prices (and returns) to
psychological factors. Others believe that changing risk explains these long-
run anomalies. If an asset pricing model correctly adjusts for risk, no long-
run abnormal returns or profits are possible. In Chapter 11, we provide
further discussion of event studies, which employ asset pricing models in
their analyses.
Fig. 2.1
Based on graphs in Friedman and Savage (1948), Fig. 2.1 depicts the above
utility analysis of alternative investments under risk. The actuarial value of
investment A in assets $$I_1$$ and $$I_2$$ is shown along the straight
line at $$\bar{I}(A)$$. Investment A has utility equal to the certainty
equivalent return $$I^*$$, or $$\bar{U}(A) = U(I^*)$$. Recall also that
investment B has certain return $$I_0$$. The left (right) graph illustrates
risk averse (risk preference) behavior by an investor. To simplify matters,
we adopt the reasonable assumption that certain return $$I_0$$ from
investment B is less than risky return $$\bar{I}(A)$$ from investment A.5
In the risk averse graph on the left, with diminishing marginal utility, if
$$I_0$$ is greater than certainty equivalent return $$I^*$$, the investor
will prefer certain investment B with higher utility. Furthermore, in the
likely case that $$I_0 < \bar{I}(A)$$, the investor would be willing to
pay $$\bar{I}(A) - I_0$$ for this certainty, which is the same as “buying
insurance” to obtain the certain outcome. This payment for risky investment
A is referred to as the risk premium, which is required by the investor for
taking risk. However, if $$I_0 < \bar{I}(A)$$ and also
$$I_0 < I^*$$, investment A is preferred with higher utility. This
framework describes risk-averse behavior among investors.
The graph on the right shows how investors who prefer risk behave. As
discussed above, risk loving behavior is reflected in the utility curve
increasing at an increasing rate and $$I^* > \bar{I}(A)$$. In the likely
case that $$I_0 < \bar{I}(A)$$, higher utility is gained from risky
investment A compared to certain investment B. But unlike risk-
averse behavior, the investor would be willing to pay $$\bar{I}(A) - I_0$$
for risky investment A, i.e., this situation can also be interpreted as “selling
insurance.”
Fig. 2.2
Fig. 2.3
Asset returns are based on price changes between adjacent time periods
$$t-1$$ to t. Using stocks as the asset, simple returns are defined as
$$\begin{aligned} R_t = (P_t + D_t - P_{t-1}) / P_{t-1}, \end{aligned}$$
(2.4)
where $$P_t$$ is the stock price at time t, $$D_t$$ is the dividend paid
on the stock during the period from $$t - 1$$ to t, and $$P_{t-1}$$ is
the stock price at previous time $$t-1$$. Assuming an infinite number of
subperiods within period t, continuously compounded returns can be
computed using log returns as
$$\begin{aligned} r_t = \log (P_t + D_t) - \log (P_{t-1}), \end{aligned}$$
(2.5)
where $$\log$$ is the natural logarithm. Simple and log returns are related
to one another as follows:
$$\begin{aligned} r_t = \log (1 + R_t), \end{aligned}$$
(2.6)
where $$1 + R_t$$ is the gross return, and $$1 + r_t$$ is the gross log
return.
It is important to note that returns are scale free but not unitless, which
means that they are always defined with respect to some time interval, e.g.,
one month. The typical jargon is (for example) “5 percent per month” for
$$R_t = 0.05$$ measured over a one-month period of time.
Assuming no dividends, and using the definition of the gross return
$$1 + R_t = P_t / P_{t-1}$$, we can compute the k-period gross return as
a product of the single-period returns from $$t - k + 1$$ to t as follows:
$$\begin{aligned} 1 + R_{t} (k) & = (1 + R_{{t - k + 1}} ) \times (1
+ R_{{t - k + 2}} ) \times \cdots \times (1 + R_{t} ) \\ & =
\frac{{P_{{t - k + 1}} }}{{P_{{t - k}} }} \times \frac{{P_{{t - k + 2}} }}
{{P_{{t - k + 1}} }} \times \cdots \times \frac{{P_{t} }}{{P_{{t - 1}} }} =
\frac{{P_{t} }}{{P_{{t - k}} }}. \\ \end{aligned}$$
(2.7)
This relation only holds if dividends are ignored. If dividends are paid at
some point within the period, then the single-period returns in the equation
can be adjusted to compute the k-period return. In this case, the equation
implicitly assumes that dividends are reinvested in the stock over time. In
the same fashion, other adjustments such as stock splits or new issues can be
taken into account at the time they occur.
Computing a mean return over some time period k is more complicated. The
arithmetic mean over the whole sample period of $$t = 1, \ldots , T$$ is
defined as
$$\begin{aligned} \bar{R} = \frac{1}{T} \sum _{t = 1}^T R_{t}.
\end{aligned}$$
(2.8)
The arithmetic mean of k period returns from $$t - k + 1$$ to t is
mathematically defined as:
$$\begin{aligned} \bar{R}_t(k) = \frac{1}{k} \sum _{j = 1}^k R_{t - j +
1}. \end{aligned}$$
(2.9)
However, this mean return is always biased upward and therefore is too
high. The main problem is that returns on investment develop in a
compounded manner, not additive. A simple example illustrates the bias. If
you start with $200 and lose 20% in the first period, you have
$$(1 - 0.20)\times \$200 = \$160$$ to invest in the second period. If the
gain in this second period is 30%, the end value becomes
$$(1 + 0.30)\times \$160 = \$208$$, such that the 2-period return of your
investment is $$(208-200) / 200 = 4\%$$, i.e.,
$$(1 - 0.20) \times (1 + 0.30) - 1$$. The additive return of 10% (
$$= -0.20 + 0.30$$) in the arithmetic mean formula is clearly too high and
therefore yields an upward-biased mean return equal to 5% ( $$=10\%/2$$
).
The correct mean return in a multiperiod context is the geometric mean
computed as:
$$\begin{aligned} \bar{R}_g = \left[ \prod _{t = 1}^T(1 + R_t)\right]
^{1/T} - 1 \end{aligned}$$
(2.10)
for the whole sample period, and for a subperiod of k returns from
$$t - j + 1, \ldots , t$$ the geometric mean becomes:
$$\begin{aligned} \bar{R}_{g,t}(k) = \left[ \prod _{j = 1}^k (1 + R_{t - j
+ 1})\right] ^{1/k} - 1. \end{aligned}$$
(2.11)
Note that the whole sample notations are simplifications of the subperiod
notations. That is, for the whole sample $$k = T$$ and therefore for
example $$\bar{R}_{g,t}(k) = \bar{R}_{g,T}(T) = \bar{R}_g$$.
As noted earlier, while returns are scale free, they are not unit free. That is,
they depend on the time unit. Therefore, when discussing returns, it is
important to indicate the unit, whether it is daily, weekly, monthly, yearly,
etc. In particular, when making comparisons, it is important to transform
returns to the same time unit. It is not useful to annualize single daily
returns. A simple example demonstrates the problem. Assume a 1% return
on some day. If annualized by assuming 365 days, one gets
$$(1 + 0.01)^{365} - 1 \approx 36.78$$ or 3,678%, implying that the
transformation explodes the numbers. However, average daily returns can be
annualized as averaging smooths single day variation. The k-period
geometric mean in Eq. (2.11) can be used for the annualization. Also, even
though it is biased, sometimes the k-period arithmetic mean in Eq. (2.9) is
used.
Regarding simple versus log returns, in high frequency data based on daily
or weekly returns, the numerical value differences between simple
returns and log returns are usually negligible as demonstrated shortly.
However, there are fundamental differences between these return concepts.
One difference is that the simple return is bounded below by $$-1$$ when
the stock price falls to zero. In this case, log returns approach minus infinity.
Therefore, while simple returns can take values from minus one upward, log
returns can be all real values.
The excess kurtosis, or $$\text {ku} - 3$$, tends to be positive for both
individual stocks and stock indices, which indicates fatter tails with a more
peaked mean than the normal distribution. Therefore, various alternatives,
such as stable distributions, have been proposed. However, the popularity of
these alternatives has diminished today due to some counterintuitive
properties (e.g., increasing variance with the sample size). On the other
hand, some fatter tailed distributions, like the t-distribution and generalized
error distributions of which the normal distribution is a special case, have
gained popularity over time. In spite of these issues, normal and lognormal
distributions continue to play a central role in theoretical financial
economics. Hence, the empirical challenge is to assess how critical the
normality assumption is for the predictions of theory.
Sample statistics for S &P 500 index, DAX index, and Microsoft
Corporation: daily, weekly, and monthly returns (in percent)
Mean 0.09 0.05 0.04 0.44 0.22 0.19 1.89 1.01 0.77
Median 0.07 0.07 0.08 0.52 0.31 0.42 2.23 1.50 0.71
Volatility 25.39 17.50 20.55 22.69 13.90 20.84 21.33 14.07 17.76
Skewness 0.04 −0.58 −0.38 −0.25 −0.49 −0.82 0.03 −0.31 −0.50
Kurtosis 9.91 15.13 7.21 2.89 1.84 5.69 0.34 0.93 1.65
Daily Weekly Monthly
Min −14.74 −11.98 −12.24 −14.37 −7.19 −20.01 −15.52 −12.51 −19.19
Max 14.22 9.38 10.98 15.02 7.39 10.91 19.63 12.68 15.01
Notes Mean and median are percentage returns per indicated period, and
volatility is annualized. Kurtosis is the excess kurtosis, or
$$\text {ku} - 3$$, with $$\text {ku}$$ defined in Eq. (2.22).
Fig. 2.4
Figure 2.4 shows the return frequency distributions (in blue) for Microsoft
as well as U.S. S &P 500 and German DAX stock price indexes.
Distributions are shown using daily, weekly, and monthly return
frequencies. These empirical distributions are compared to the imposed
normal curves (in red) calibrated by respective sample means and sample
variances. The peakedness of the empirical distributions illustrates
graphically the kurtosis feature, which is characteristic of both individual
stocks and indexes (portfolios). Fat tails, even though not that obvious from
the graphs, are well-recognized features associated with stock returns due to
high kurtosis. The mild skewness of the return distributions is not obvious
from the graphs. Scanning down the rows of graphs reveals that, as return
frequency decreases from daily to monthly returns, the normal
approximation improves.
Finally, we should note that the above sample statistics and graphs are
produced using simple returns (in percentages). We have left as an exercise
for the student to reproduce these results using log returns and compare if
there are material differences.
2.5 Summary
A number of capital market conditions are foundational to asset pricing.
Perfect capital markets assume rational investor behavior, all information is
freely available, no taxes and transactions costs, all investors are price
takers, and perfect certainty. The efficient market hypothesis (EMH) by
Nobel Laureate Eugene Fama (1970) posits that prices reflect all available
information. Weak-form, semi-strong form, and strong-form
efficiency describe different types of market efficiency. In an efficient
market, the random walk hypothesis (RWH) of Malkiel (2003) argues that
prices move randomly over time and therefore are independent of past
prices. Behavioralists counter that price trends can occur due to investor
psychology which can cause over- or underreactions to information in the
market.
Stock returns can be defined in a variety of ways. Simple returns take into
account dividends and capital gains on a stock for a discrete time period.
Log returns provide a continuously compounded return. The log of one plus
the simple return (or gross simple return) equals the log return. An
arithmetic mean takes the average of simple returns over a number of time
periods. Because the arithmetic mean return has an upward bias, the
geometric mean is used to compute an average multiperiod return.
Alternatively, the simple arithmetic mean of log returns over a number of
time periods can be used to measure the average multiperiod return. For
high frequency data, such as daily or weekly returns, simple returns, and log
returns are similar to one another, at least up to about a 10% return. When
aggregating returns in a portfolio, simple returns should be used in cross-
sectional analyses of assets at a point in time, and log returns should be used
in time-series analyses of returns over multiple periods. Using log
returns defined as the sum of many subperiod log returns, the Central Limit
Theorem (CLT) says that returns are normally distributed. However, in the
real world, stock returns are not normally distributed; instead, they tend to
have some degree of asymmetry (i.e., skewness) and fatter tails (i.e.,
kurtosis). Mean, variance, skewness, and kurtosis measures are used to
characterize return distributions. Individual stocks normally have higher
variances of returns than portfolios due to the diversification benefit in
portfolios. As the return frequency decreases from daily to monthly returns,
the distribution of stock returns becomes closer to a normal curve.
Questions
1. 1.
2. 2.
3. 3.
Under the efficient markets hypothesis (EMH), what are the three types
of market efficiency? Briefly describe them.
4. 4.
5. 5.
What is a certainty equivalent return of a risky investment?
6. 6.
7. 7.
8. 8.
9. 9.
Write the simple return for a stock. Also, write the continuously
compounded rate of return. How are these two returns related to one
another?
10. 10.
How can the Central Limit Theorem (CLT) be applied to explain why
log returns approach a normal distribution?
12. 12.
Problems
1. 1.
2. 2.
Suppose that there is some certain return $$I^*$$ with the same
utility as A, i.e., $$\bar{U}(A) = U(I^*)$$. Also, assume that this
certainty equivalent return $$I^*$$ is less than the actuarial value of
A. What does this tell you about the investor? How much is the investor
willing to pay as insurance against the risk of A?
3. 3.
Draw a graph of the utility curve showing risk-averse investor behavior
with respect to the risky investment opportunity in problem 1 above.
How would this graph change for risk loving investors?
4. 4.
. Also,
5. 5.
How can we compute the mean return for an investment over some
time period k? Show the formulas for the arithmetic mean and
geometric mean. Utilizing the gross returns in problem 4, i.e,
$$(1 + R_1) = 1.1111$$, $$(1+R_2) = 1.0500$$, and
$$(1+R_3) = 1.0476$$, compute the arithmetic and geometric mean
returns. Which mean return should you use and why?
6. 6.
How would we compute the gross return $$1 + R_t(k)$$ over some
time period k using log returns? In this case, what is the simple
arithmetic mean of these gross returns? Is the average of this
multiperiod correct (unbiased)? Assuming that $$(1+R_1)= 1.1111$$
, $$(1+R_2)=1.0500$$, and $$(1+R_3)=1.0476$$, compute these
returns. What is the formula for the geometric mean return?
7. 7.
Consider the monthly returns of a stock. Assume that the returns are
normally distributed with mean $$\mu = 1\%$$ and standard
deviation $$\sigma = 9\%$$ (per month). How often would you
expect to see a monthly return that exceeds $$10\%$$? How about
$$20\%$$.
8. 8.
References
Footnotes
1
See Shiller (2000), who titled his book “Irrational Exuberance” after a
warning by Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan of a possible market
bubble in 1996.
2
It is possible that limits to arbitrage can occur due to constraints on traders
arising from institutional or structural restrictions in the financial market.
For example, an investor that borrowed money to buy an asset could face a
margin call to cover losses on the asset that are short run in nature due to a
temporary market panic. These sudden losses could prevent arbitrage gains
from being realized such that equilibrium prices cannot be achieved.
According to Fama and Miller (1972, p. 339, footnote 19), further RWH
assumptions are that prices are identically distributed and that expected
price changes can be nonzero due to drift.
See Friedman and Savage for the case in which $$I_0 > \bar{I}(A)$$.
8
As shown by Tobin (1958, p. 76), this assumption limits the range of mean
returns R.
See Wikipedia on the internet for an excellent review of the Taylor series.
This mathematical method enables the evaluation of a general function with
incremental accuracy by a polynomial of finite order. Often even the first-
order approximation provides a sufficiently accurate approximation for
practical purposes.
10
https://finance.yahoo.com.
© The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2023
J. W. Kolari, S. Pynnönen, Investment Valuation and Asset Pricing
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-16784-3_3
Seppo Pynnönen
Email: [email protected]
Supplementary Information
The online version contains supplementary material available at https://doi.
org/10.1007/978-3-031-16784-3_3
This chapter covers the now famous Capital Asset Pricing Model
(CAPM) as proposed by William Sharpe (1964), for which he was awarded
the Nobel Prize in Economics in 1990. Other authors credited with
contributions to the CAPM are Jack Treynor (1961, 1962), John
Lintner (1965), and Jan Mossin (1966). The CAPM builds upon the mean-
variance paradigm of Harry Markowitz (1952, 1959) and risk-aversion
concepts of Tobin (1958). Interestingly, Sharpe was a Ph.D. student
working closely with Markowitz at University of California at Los Angeles
(UCLA), who shared the Nobel Prize with him along with Merton Miller.
The CAPM represents a landmark that established the study of asset
pricing. Up until that time, finance as an academic and professional
discipline was grounded primarily in accounting principles, present value of
cash flow mathematics, and descriptive risk measures. The CAPM changed
everything. Combining portfolio theory in Chapter 1 with capital market
conditions in Chapter 2, including perfect capital markets, efficient markets,
risk aversion, and mathematical return concepts, the CAPM provided the
first equilibrium asset pricing model. It marked the beginning of a
revolution that elevated the academic and professional field of finance
around the world.
Fig. 3.1 Equilibrium relationship between expected rates of return and risk
Fig. 3.3 Locating market portfolio as a tangent point on the ray from riskless rate
The formulas for Eqs. (3.5) and (3.6) imply that combinations of the
riskless rate and any efficient portfolio’s risky return lie on a straight line.
Figure 3.3 shows a variety of possible combinations of the riskless rate with
different risky portfolios. It is obvious that the ray from riskless rate
$$R_f$$ to the tangent point on the efficient frontier provides the
highest expected return E(R) per unit risk as measured by the standard
deviation of returns $$\sigma (R)$$. Other combinations are less
efficient than this optimal combination.
Sharpe referred to the optimal tangent point as the market
portfolio denoted M. All points on the Capital Market Line (CML) from
$$R_f$$ to M represent different proportionate investments in the
riskless asset f and market portfolio M. All risk-averse investors buy market
portfolio M, which is comprised of the value-weighted returns of all assets
in the market with weights equal to the ratio of the market value of each
asset to the aggregate market value of all assets. This theoretical result is
remarkable! What about investors that buy other risky asset portfolios?
According to Fig. 3.3, they would earn lower risk-adjusted returns than if
they invested in M.
How do investors achieve expected return and total risk combinations
along the CML? Points on the line from $$R_f$$ to M require that the
investor lend some proportion a of their funds to earn the riskless rate
$$R_f$$ (e.g., depositing funds in an insured bank deposit account or
buying a riskless government bond) and invest the remainder in proportion
$$(1 - a)$$ in market portfolio M. Where the investor lies on this
section of the CML depends on their risk aversion as determined by the
tangency point of their indifference curve with the CML. If the investor
prefers points above M on the CML, these points could be achieved by
borrowing funds at the riskless rate $$R_f$$ and adding to their
purchases of market portfolio M.
There is a long controversy about Sharpe’s market portfolio results.
Many professional investors argue that they can “beat the market” in the
sense of actively managing investments to pick assets earning a higher rate
of return per unit risk greater than market portfolio M. Opposing this claim,
academics point to Sharpe’s mean-variance theory. Historical evidence
proves that over 90% of professional managers do not outperform common
stock market indexes over reasonable investment horizons (e.g., the S &P
500 index over five years). This empirical fact led to the widespread
adoption of index investing in well-diversified portfolios that contain all
assets in the stock market. So-called passive index funds have very low
transactions costs which help to further explain their relatively higher
performance compared to actively managed funds. Professional managers in
the latter funds seek to apply investment skills to choose portfolio assets
and incur higher operating costs from this aggressive activity (e.g.,
transactions costs, management salaries, etc.).
8.
Investors are able to purchase a portfolio in the marketplace that is a
close substitute or proxy for market portfolio M.
9.
There are no other systematic risk factors than the market factor equal
to the market risk premium. No mispricing exists after taking into
account sensitivity to the market factor as measured by beta risk. Tests
of other potential risk factors are needed to support this implication.
As we will see in forthcoming chapters, these implications motivated a
tremendous amount of research in the years to come. Can such a simple
model really be valid? Will it work in the real world? Does the CAPM lead
to other theoretical discoveries? Are there competing models of asset
pricing? As we will see, confirming the final remarks of Lintner at the end
of his paper, the CAPM opened the doors to a flood of new theories and
applied for empirical work.
3.6 Summary
The traditional approach to valuation employs the present value formula.
This formula specifies asset prices as a function of expected future cash
flows divided by expected discount rates. Fundamental accounting, finance,
and operating information about the firm are used to estimate expected cash
flows. A wide variety of risks are incorporated into the expected discount
rate. Alternatively, historical rates of return on an asset can be used to
approximate expected discount rates. However, historical rates have the
drawback of being backward looking and, therefore, are not helpful in
determining whether an asset is over- or undervalued relative to future
returns.
The CAPM represents a breakthrough in terms of measuring the
relevant risk to diversified investors. Based on idealistic assumptions of
perfect competition, homogeneous expectations, utility maximization, risk
aversion, and riskless borrowing and lending rates, Treynor, Sharpe,
Lintner, and Mossin independently derived the price of risky assets in
equilibrium. To do this, they assumed that Markowitz portfolio theory and
the Tobin Separation Principle hold. Investors that practice Markowitz
diversification will hold a single optimal portfolio on the efficient frontier.
This efficient portfolio is obtained as the tangent point on a ray extending
from the riskless rate to the efficient frontier. The resultant ray is the Capital
Market Line (CML) relating expected rates of return to total risk as
measured by the standard deviation of returns. All investors will purchase
the tangent point known as the market portfolio M, which is a separate
decision from their risk preferences. Depending on their risk preferences,
investors will hold different combinations of the riskless rate and the market
portfolio. Investors who want to take more risk than the market portfolio
can borrow funds and increase their holdings of the market portfolio. These
results are logical outcomes of Markowitz diversification and Tobin risk
preference concepts.
The next step is to derive the price of an individual asset. By setting the
slopes of the linear CML to the efficient frontier of risky assets, Sharpe
showed that asset prices are determined by the riskless rate, expected rate of
return on the market portfolio, and beta risk. Beta risk (denoted
$$\beta$$) is a parameter relating the expected rate of return of asset i
to the market risk premium defined as the expected rate of return on the
market portfolio return minus the riskless rate. The linear relationship
between expected rates of return for assets and their beta risks is the
Security Market Line (SML). The SML represents the equilibrium pricing
relationship in which only beta measuring systematic risk is priced by
investors. Hence, total risk as measured by the standard deviation of
returns can be broken down into undiversifiable systematic risk (beta) and
diversifiable unsystematic (idiosyncratic) risk. Assets that are underpriced
(overpriced) lie above (below) the SML; arbiteurs will buy (sell) these
assets until they lie on the SML. Thus, the SML is an equilibrium
return/risk relation. Two alternative but equivalent forms of the CAPM are
the risk-adjusted rate of return valuation formula and certainty equivalent
valuation formula. Both of these formulas, like the CAPM itself, value
assets without regard to the risk preferences of individuals that have
homogeneous expectations. If investors have heterogeneous expectations, a
single efficient market portfolio may not be identified by investors, which is
critical to the CAPM. For this reason, empirical tests of the CAPM
discussed in the next chapter jointly test the CAPM and the efficiency of the
market portfolio.
The CAPM has many important implications. All investors buy the
same market portfolio. All systematic risk is captured in beta risk related to
the market portfolio. Besides identifying over- and underpriced assets, it
can be used in portfolio management, capital budgeting, and other financial
decisions. Its assumptions are idealistic but may well be relaxed in many
cases, such as the allowance of risky borrowing rates and short sales. The
simple elegance of the CAPM is both an advantage and disadvantage. If
true, it allows investors to spend less time evaluating a myriad of different
risks affecting assets (e.g., credit risk, liquidity risk, legal risks, regulation,
etc.) and instead focus on beta risk. Contrary to the CAPM, many
professional investment managers believe that they can outperform the
market portfolio (e.g., a general market index) by means of skill in
evaluating market information. As will see in forthcoming chapters, the
CAPM opened the door to a large body of theoretical and applied research.
Even today, researchers grapple with what we might call the CAPM
paradox—are asset prices determined by the equilibrium mechanics of
Treynor–Sharpe–Lintner–Mossin, or are they entangled in a more complex
pricing mechanism?
Questions
1.
Write the present value formula for future cash flows. Re-write this
present value formula using m-talk. Redefine the m-talk equation in
terms of expected returns.
2.
Draw the Capital Market Line (CML) of Sharpe (1964). What does
this line show?
3.
Assuming Markowitz’s efficient frontier and Tobin’s mean-variance
indifference curves, what portfolio should the investor select?
Illustrate this portfolio with a graph with mean returns on the Y-axis
and standard deviation of returns on the X-axis.
4. Write the expected return of the portfolio combination of the riskless
asset in proportion a and risky efficient portfolio P in proportion (
$$1-a$$). What is the standard deviation of returns for this
combination? Since the riskless rate $$R_f$$ is a constant over
time, to what does this standard deviation reduce? What do these
results imply to investors?
5.
Given the results for question 4 above, which portfolio will an
investor optimally select to maximize their expected returns per unit
risk as measured by the standard deviation of returns
$$\sigma (R)$$? Draw a picture of your Capital Market
Line (CML) solution. How can investors locate themselves at
different points along this CML?
6.
Do you think that professional investors can buy a risky portfolio that
“beats the market” in the sense of outperforming portfolio M?
7.
Draw the Security Market Line (SML). Is this line an equilibrium
relation between risk and return? Is systematic risk part of total risk?
8.
A certainty equivalent form of the CAPM is as follows:
$$\begin{aligned} P_0=\frac{E(P_1) - [ Cov (P_1, R_M)/\sigma
^2(R_M)][E(R_M)-R_f]}{1 + R_f}.\nonumber \end{aligned}$$
Why does the equation use the riskless rate to discount the cash flows
in the numerator?
9.
Give a definition of the market portfolio M. Are some assets in the
market not contained in M?
10.
The CAPM has a number of implications for the theory and practice
of finance. Discuss five implications.
Problems
1. Assume that investors hold a portfolio of an individual risky asset and
riskless asset f. Starting with the expected return of this combination
and its standard deviation, derive the slope of the efficient frontier and
then set this slope equal to the slope of the efficient frontier at market
portfolio M. Rearranging terms, write the equation for the CAPM in
more general form as well its more common simplified form.
2.
Using data in the following table, compute the expected returns for
different assets using the CAPM.
References
Black, F. 1981. An open letter to Jack Treynor. Financial Analysts Journal 37: 14.
Cochrane, J. H. 2005. Asset Pricing: Revised Edition. NJ: Princeton University Press, Princeton.
Fama, E.F. 1968. Risk, return, and equilibrium: Some clarifying comments. Journal of Finance 23:
29–40.
[Crossref]
Ferson, W. E. 2019. Empirical Asset Pricing: Models and Methods. MA: The MIT Press, Cambridge.
French, C.W. 2003. The Treynor Capital Asset Pricing Model. Journal of Investment Management 1:
60–72.
Lintner, J. 1965. The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock portfolios
and capital budgets. Review of Economics and Statistics 47: 13–37.
[Crossref]
Markowitz, H.M. 1959. Portfolio Selection: Efficient Diversification of Investments. New York, NY:
John Wiley & Sons.
Sharpe, W.F. 1964. Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk.
Journal of Finance 19: 425–442.
Tobin, J. 1958. Liquidity preference as behavior toward risk. Review of Economic Studies 4: 65–86.
[Crossref]
Treynor, J.L. 1961. Market value, time, and risk. Unpublished manuscript.
Treynor, J.L. 1962. Toward a theory of market value of risky assets. Unpublished manuscript.
Weston, T.E., and J.F. Weston. 1980. Financial Theory and Corporate Policy. Reading, MA:
Addison-Wesley Publishing Company.
Footnotes
1 In different contexts, the variable m is sometimes referred to as the asset pricing kernel or
marginal rate of substitution.
2 See advanced textbooks by Cochrane (2005) and Ferson (2019) for excellent in-depth discussions
and applications of m-talk in asset pricing models.
3 For example, assuming no risk, if you indifferent between $$\$100$$ today or $$\$101$$ at
the end of a year, your rate of time preference is 1%. This rate can be attributed to your
utility preference of present consumption over future consumption.
10 Note that, to find Markowitz efficient portfolios, it is not necessary to use optimization methods
such as quadratic programs. Conceptually at least, beta could be used to construct efficient
portfolios with different levels of market risk.
© The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2023
J. W. Kolari, S. Pynnönen, Investment Valuation and Asset Pricing
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-16784-3_4
Seppo Pynnönen
Email: [email protected]
Supplementary Information
The online version contains supplementary material available at https://doi.
org/10.1007/978-3-031-16784-3_4
The famed capital asset pricing model (CAPM) of Treynor (1961; 1962),
Sharpe (1964), Lintner (1965), and Mossin (1966) is surprisingly elegant in
design. It hypothesizes that only a single market factor is sufficient to
measure systematic risk and price assets in financial markets. All investors
will price assets using the market factor regardless of their individual risk
preferences. To test this hypothesis, the market model was invented in the
form of a simple regression equation. Using a proxy for the market portfolio
and a riskless rate, this regression model enables the estimation of beta
risk for assets.
The earliest applications of the market model focused on the U.S. stock
market. As we will see, this early evidence did not entirely support the
CAPM. High (low) beta stocks had lower (higher) returns than predicted by
the CAPM. In effect, the slope of the Security Market Line (SML) was
flatter than predicted by the theory. This flatter SML resulted in a higher
than expected intercept term, which implies that other risks may well exist
that are embedded in the intercept or $$\alpha$$ parameter in the
market model. Given that $$\alpha$$ is fairly large in magnitude, as
discussed in forthcoming chapters, researchers subsequently proposed
various remedies that led to new forms of the CAPM as well as alternative
models extending the CAPM to multiple factors.
In this chapter, we take a look at the market model and early CAPM
evidence. Because the market model is a statistical model, we supplement
the discussion with a primer on simple regression analysis, including the
interpretation of regression coefficients, justification for ordinary least
squares (OLS) estimation of regression coefficients, relation of the market
model to the theoretical CAPM, and goodness-of-fit of regression models.
Year/Month MSFT Tbill S &P 500 Excess MSFT Excess S &P 500
18/1 −1.31 0.11 -3.89 -1.41 -4.00
18/2 −2.67 0.12 −2.69 −2.78 −2.80
18/3 2.47 0.14 0.27 2.33 0.14
18/4 5.69 0.14 2.16 5.55 2.02
18/5 −0.23 0.14 0.48 −0.37 0.34
18/6 7.58 0.15 3.60 7.42 3.45
18/7 5.89 0.16 3.03 5.73 2.87
18/8 1.82 0.16 0.43 1.65 0.27
18/9 −6.61 0.17 −6.94 −6.78 −7.11
18/10 3.82 0.18 1.79 3.64 1.60
18/11 −8.40 0.19 −9.18 −8.59 −9.36
18/12 2.82 0.20 7.87 2.62 7.67
19/1 7.28 0.20 2.97 7.08 2.77
19/2 5.28 0.20 1.79 5.07 1.59
19/3 10.73 0.20 3.93 10.53 3.73
19/4 −5.30 0.20 −6.58 −5.50 −6.78
19/5 8.31 0.20 6.89 8.11 6.69
19/6 1.72 0.19 1.31 1.54 1.13
19/7 1.17 0.18 −1.81 0.99 −1.99
Year/Month MSFT Tbill S &P 500 Excess MSFT Excess S &P 500
19/8 0.85 0.17 1.72 0.68 1.55
19/9 3.12 0.17 2.04 2.96 1.88
19/10 5.59 0.14 3.40 5.44 3.26
19/11 4.17 0.13 2.86 4.04 2.73
19/12 7.95 0.13 −0.16 7.82 −0.29
20/1 −4.83 0.13 −8.41 −4.96 −8.54
20/2 −2.65 0.13 −12.51 −2.79 −12.64
20/3 13.63 0.03 12.68 13.60 12.65
20/4 2.25 0.01 4.53 2.25 4.52
20/5 11.06 0.01 1.84 11.05 1.83
20/6 0.74 0.01 5.51 0.73 5.50
20/7 10.01 0.01 7.01 10.00 7.00
20/8 −6.74 0.01 −3.92 −6.75 −3.93
20/9 −3.74 0.01 −2.77 −3.74 −2.77
20/10 5.73 0.01 10.75 5.72 10.75
20/11 3.90 0.01 3.71 3.89 3.70
20/12 −2.22 0.01 1.43 −2.22 1.43
This table reports the monthly returns (in percent) for Microsoft (MSFT),
the S &P 500 index, and Treasury bills from January 2018 to December
2020. Stock prices are downloaded from Yahoo Finance. Adjusted stock
prices are used that take into account dividends and splits. Treasury bill
rates are downloaded from the FRED database provided online by the
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (see https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/
DGS1MO)
Fig. 4.1 The estimated market model for Microsoft (MSFT) stock returns with fitted regression line
Figure 4.1 plots the excess returns of MSFT (or Y variable) and the S
&P 500 index (or X-variable) as well as the fitted regression line. The fitted
line is comprised of the predicted values of the market model. The predicted
MSFT return for each monthly S &P 500 return is computed as:
$$\begin{aligned} R_{ MSFT t}-R_{ft}=\hat{\alpha }_{ MSFT
}+\hat{\beta }_{ MSFT }(R_{ S \& P500 t}-R_{ft}), (4.7)
\end{aligned}$$
where $$\hat{\alpha }_{ MSFT }$$ is the estimated intercept
parameter, and $$\hat{\beta }_{ MSFT }$$ is the estimated slope
measuring the beta risk of MSFT. We provide a screenshot of the Excel
output below the diagram. The fitted line plots the predicted values of
excess MSFT returns (see faded points on the straight line). The monthly
returns for MSFT are represented by the scatter plot of points around the
fitted line. The difference between each scatter plot point and the fitted line
equals the residual $$e_{ MSFT ,t}$$ in Eq. (4.6). The larger the
residuals, the lower the goodness-of-fit of the market model. In this regard,
the Excel output reports the commonly used goodness-of-fit measure
known as the adjusted R-squared . In the present case, MSFT had an
estimated R-squared value of 61.4%, which means that the fit is fairly good.
The $$\alpha$$ estimate is greater than zero at
$$\hat{\alpha }_{ MSFT } = 1.67$$, and the $$\beta$$ estimate
is less than one at $$\hat{\beta }_{ MSFT } =0.79$$. The t-statistics
for these estimated parameters are 2.88 and 7.35, respectively, which have
very low p-values below 0.01 suggesting at least a 1% level of significance.
These results indicate that $$\hat{\alpha }_{ MSFT }$$ and
$$\hat{\beta }_{ MSFT }$$ are highly significant in terms of their
difference from zero. The positive and highly significant
$$\hat{\alpha }$$ implies that other factors are needed to fully price
MSFT. Also, the positive and even more highly significant
$$\hat{\beta }_{ MSFT }$$ can be interpreted to mean that the excess
market factor proxied by S &P 500 index returns minus Tbill rates helps to
explain movements in MSFT excess returns in our sample period. Because
this estimate is less than one, we can infer that MSFT has less systematic
risk than the market as a whole (or at least the largest 500 stocks).
The market model results for MSFT are consistent with the CAPM for
the most part but not entirely. There appears to be a linear relation between
its excess stock returns and excess market returns in line with the CAPM.
However, according to the CAPM, the intercept or $$\alpha$$
parameter should be zero. Clearly, the large $$\alpha$$ term at 1.67%
per month suggests that a large part of MSFT’s excess returns are not
explained by excess market returns. For comparison purposes, the average
excess MSFT return and average excess market return in the sample period
were 2.35% and 0.86% per month, respectively. Hence, 1.67% is quite large
in terms of mispricing error captured by the $$\alpha$$ term. It
appears that some additional factors are needed to more fully price MSFT
and thereby reduce the magnitude of $$\alpha$$ mispricing.
4.5.1 Goodness-of-Fit
The most popular goodness-of-fit measure in regression analysis is R-
squared (also known as the coefficient of determination) and its adjusted
variant often denoted as $$\bar{R}$$-squared. These measures tell us
how well the regression equation fits the data observations. The basic idea
is that, if the regression equation yields predicted values that are close to the
actual values of observations, it has strong goodness-of-fit, and vice versa if
predicted and actual values are very different from one another. To compute
goodness-of-fit, we need to decompose the total variation measure
$$\text {SST} = \sum _{i = 1}^n(y_i - \bar{y})^2$$ of the dependent
variable. Letting
$$\hat{y}_i = \hat{\alpha }+ \hat{\beta }_1x_{i1} + \cdots + \hat{\beta
}_kx_{ik}$$
denote the fitted value, the decomposition becomes
$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{i = 1}^n(y_i - \bar{y})^2 = \sum _{i =
1}^n(\hat{y}_i - \bar{y})^2 + \sum _{i = 1}^n(y_i - \hat{y}_i)^2, (4.17)
\end{aligned}$$
or
$$\begin{aligned} \text {SST} = \text {SSE} + \text {SSR}
(4.18)
\end{aligned}$$
where $$\text {SST} = \sum _{i = 1}^n(y_i - \bar{y})^2$$ is the total
sum of squares,
$$\text {SSE} = \sum _{i = 1}^n(\hat{y}_i - \bar{y})^2$$ is the sum of
squares explained by the regression which measures the share of variability
around the mean $$\bar{y}$$ that is due to the independent variables in
the regression model, and
$$\text {SSR} = \sum _{i = 1}^n(y_i - \hat{y}_i)^2$$ is the sum of
squares due to residuals which is the variation not captured by the estimated
regression model. The R-squared is the ratio of the total variation explained
by the regression model,
$$R^{2} = \frac{{{\text{SSE}}}}{{{\text{SST}}}} = 1 -
(4.19)
\frac{{{\text{SSR}}}}{{{\text{SST}}}}.$$
The adjusted R-squared is based on the rightmost representation by
adjusting the sums of squares using the respective degrees of freedom with
k independent variables such that
$$\begin{aligned} \bar{R}^2 = 1 - \frac{s_e^2}{s_y^2},
(4.20)
\end{aligned}$$
where
$$\begin{aligned} s_e^2 = \frac{1}{n - k - 1}\sum _{i = 1}^n(y_i -
(4.21)
\hat{y}_i)^2 \end{aligned}$$
is the unbiased OLS variance estimator of the error variance
$$\sigma _e^2$$, and $$s_y^2$$ is the usual unbiased estimator of the
variance of y.
The major difference between $$R^2$$ and $$\bar{R}^2$$
is that the latter measure is penalized by the degrees of freedom. While
adding a new variable can reduce $$\bar{R}^2$$ if the variable does
not improve the explanatory power enough, the non-adjusted
$$R^2$$ tends to increase or at least never decrease. By definition
$$0 \le R^2 \le 1$$. Note that the adjusted R-squared can be negative
if none of the explanatory variables helps to predict y. For these reasons, the
adjusted R-squared is more popular to report, as a positive value indicates
that the fitted model has some explanatory power.
4.6 Summary
The empirical form of the CAPM named the market model was proposed by
Markowitz (1959) and developed by Sharpe (1963) and Fama (1968).
Excess asset returns (dependent y variable) are regressed on excess market
portfolio proxy returns (independent x variable) to yield an $$\alpha$$
intercept parameter and beta $$\beta$$ slope parameter. Jensen (1968)
recognized that the $$\alpha$$ terms, so-called Jensen’s alpha, can be
used to jointly test whether the proxy for the market portfolio is efficient or
mispricing exists due to missing factors. According to the CAPM, the
$$\alpha$$ estimate should equal zero in the market model. In the real
world, stocks and other assets do not lie exactly on the Security Market
Line (SML), which results in a random error term in the market model.
Early tests of the CAPM employed the market model. Black, Jensen,
and Scholes (BJS) (1972) found that the SML was flatter than predicted by
the CAPM. They formed 10 portfolios of U.S. stocks sorted by beta.
Contrary to the CAPM, 3-out-of-10 portfolios had significant
$$\alpha$$ intercept terms. Also, stock portfolios with betas greater
(less) than one tended to have negative (positive) intercepts. These results
suggested that low (high) beta stocks had higher (lower) returns than
predicted by the CAPM. Additionally, average $$\alpha$$s for their
stock portfolios were significantly different from zero. This finding means
that either the market portfolio proxy is inefficient or missing factors exist,
which rejects the CAPM.
Another study by Fama and MacBeth (FM) (1973) conducted further
market model tests using U.S. stock portfolio returns. They proposed a two-
step estimation procedure: (1) a time-series regression model is used to
estimate model parameters; and (2) a cross-sectional regression is used to
estimate the market price of risk (or $$\lambda$$ coefficient)
associated with the step (1) estimated model parameters (called loadings).
Some key findings in their study were: (1) time-series regressions showed
that non-linear beta and non-beta risks were not significant, only beta
risk was significant; and (2) cross-sectional regression showed that
$$\lambda _m$$ associated with beta risk was significant meaning
that beta risk is priced in the cross-section of stock returns. Because the
market price of beta risk tended to be less than the actual excess return of
the market portfolio proxy, they inferred that the borrowing rate is greater
than the riskless government bond rate.
Understanding the fundamentals of regression analyses is crucial to
asset pricing. Simple regression with one independent variable and multiple
regression with multiple independent variables are important tools in
finance. Both regression models can be adapted to different transformations
of the variables, including logarithms of variables, non-linear variables, etc.
Regression $$\beta$$ coefficients measure the average change in y
when x changes by one unit, given other independent variables are held
constant in the model. The intercept $$\alpha$$ coefficient is used in
regression models to improve the goodness-of-fit and ensure that the
expected value of the error terms (denoted e) equals zero.
Under the Gauss–Markov Theorem, ordinary least squares (OLS)
provide the best linear unbiased estimator (BLUE) of the regression
coefficient. This theorem requires a number of statistical properties—(i)
zero mean error terms: $$E(e_i) = 0$$ for all i; (ii)
homoskedasticity (constant variance of error terms):
$$Var \,(e_i) = \sigma _e^2$$ for all i; (iii) errors are uncorrelated:
$$Cov \,(e_i, e_j) = 0$$ for all $$i \ne j$$; (iv) no perfect
multicollinearity: x-variables are not linearly dependent; and (v)
$$Cov \,(x_i, e_i) = 0$$. Assumption (i) is achieved by using an
intercept term. If assumption (ii) is violated due to heteroskedaisticity (or
nonconstant error variance), a White (1980) estimator (HC) can be used to
adjust for this potential bias. If assumption (iii) is violated due to correlation
of errors in a time-series regression, a Newey and West (1987) estimator
(HAC) can be used. For cross-sectional regression, an adjustment by
Cameron, Gelbach, and Miller (2011) can be implemented. The no
multicollinearity assumption (iv) concerns the correlation between multiple
independent variables, which normally is not a major problem in financial
economics. Lastly, assumption (v) requires zero correlation between the
error terms and independent variables. If nonzero, an endogeneity
problem exists. This problem can be treated by introducing instrumental
variables into the regression model but is not easily accomplished.
Interestingly, under the OLS assumptions, it can be proven that the
market model represents an empirical counterpart of the theoretical CAPM.
That is, due to satisfying these assumptions, the market model can
efficiently estimate the beta parameter. To test whether beta is significantly
different from zero, a t-ratio can be computed using the beta estimate and
the standard error of this estimate. In the case that the CAPM does not hold,
an intercept term is needed in the market model. This form of the market
model is typically used in empirical studies. Finally, the goodness-of-fit of
regression models is measured by R-squared measures. An adjusted
$$\bar{R}$$-squared is normally used to adjust for the number of
degrees of freedom that is affected by the number of regression parameters
in the model. In words, this goodness-of-fit statistic measures the amount of
variation around the mean value of the dependent variable explained by the
independent variables in the regression model.
Questions
1.
Write the equation for the market model form of the CAPM. What is
the intercept term in this model? Can the intercept be used to test the
CAPM?
2.
Why put a random error term in the market model? How would you
estimate the market model with regression analysis?
3.
Black, Jensen, and Scholes (BJS) (1972) tested the CAPM using the
market model. Why did they use portfolios rather than individual
stocks in their tests? How were the portfolios formed for their tests?
Write the t-test that they performed to test whether the
$$\alpha _p$$ for a portfolio was not equal to zero. What were the
three main findings of their study? What did they conclude about the
CAPM?
4.
Fama and MacBeth (FM) (1973) tested the CAPM using cross-
sectional regression analysis. What is the cross-sectional regression
model that they tested?
5. What did Fama and MacBeth (1973) find in their cross-sectional tests
of the CAPM?
6.
Write a simple regression model with one explanatory variable. Also,
write a multiple regression model with k explanatory variables
$$x_1, \ldots , x_k$$. How would you test for a non-linear
relationship between an independent variable and the dependent
variable?
7.
What are the statistical properties of the error term, or e, in a
regression model? How should the regression coefficient $$\beta$$
be interpreted? How should the intercept $$\alpha$$ be interpreted
from both a statistical perspective and an asset pricing perspective?
8.
List the underlying classical assumptions in OLS regression analysis.
Why are these assumptions important to OLS estimation of regression
coefficients?
9.
What does homoskedasticity of error terms mean in regression
analysis? Are error terms correlated with one another? What is
multicollinearity and can it cause problems in a multiple regression
model? Lastly, what is the problem if error terms in the regression
model are correlated with an independent variable?
10.
If the CAPM does not hold, how does this affect the market model?
11.
You want to test whether an estimated $$\beta _j$$ coefficient in an
OLS regression model is significant. What is the null hypothesis?
What is the statistical test of this hypothesis? What values of the t-
statistic are needed to reach 5% and 1% significance levels? (Hint:
this question is based on Appendix A.)
12.
What is goodness-of-fit mean in regression analysis? How would you
estimate it? Show a formula and explain its terms. Can it be adjusted
for the degrees of freedom in the estimation of the regression
equation? Which measure of goodness-of-fit should be used?
13.
You want to test whether the market risk of a stock is the same as the
market portfolio in CAPM. What is the null hypothesis? What is the
alternative hypothesis?
x y
4.6 10.6
11.1 22.6
19.5 29.7
3.2 2.6
9.5 23.4
10.8 9.0
14.2 26.8
8.6 15.0
21.9 38.9
9.2 17.5
Compute the OLS estimates for the intercept and the slope coefficient for
the simple regression $$y = \alpha + \beta x + e$$ using Eqns. (4.11) and
(4.12).
Problems
1.
Update the data in Table 4.1 for Microsoft. Download monthly stock
returns for MSFT and the S &P 500 index from Yahoo Finance.
Download monthly Treasury bill rates from the Federal Reserve Bank
of St. Louis (https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/DGS1MO). Gather data
for 36 months. What did you get for the intercept? Beta? Are these
model parameters significant as determined by t-statistics? Also, draw
a plot of the fitted regression line with excess MSFT returns on the Y-
axis and excess S &P 500 index returns on the X-axis. Do the results
support the CAPM?
2.
In the text, it is proved that OLS estimation of the market model is the
empirical counterpart of the CAPM under classical Gauss–Markov
assumptions. Show that: (i) $$E(u_{it}) = 0$$, (ii)
$$Var \,(u_{it}) = \sigma _i^2(1 - \rho _{iM}^2) \equiv \sigma
_{u_i}^2$$
is constant, and (iii) $$Cov \,(u_{it}, u_{is}) = 0$$ for all .
3. Consider the following observations for variables x and y:
Appendix A: Statistical Inference
Statistical inference gives us guidelines concerning what we can say about
the population slope coefficients on the basis of the sample estimates.
Confidence intervals and hypothesis testing are the major tools in this
process. Statistical properties of the error term $$e_{it}$$ are critical.
While the Gauss–Markov BLUE result needs only assumptions about the
expected values, variances, and covariances, statistical inference needs
more precise information about the whole distribution of the error terms.
The textbook assumption is that the error term is normally distributed,
or $$e_{i} \sim N(0, \sigma _{e}^2)$$. While this assumption
strengthens OLS estimator properties, as discussed in this chapter, it also
determines the distribution (called the sampling distribution) of the
estimator. An important property of the normal distribution is that any
linear combinations of normal random variables are again normally
distributed. Therefore, as an example considering $$\hat{\beta }$$ in
Eq. (4.10), using fairly straightforward calculations, we can write
$$\begin{aligned} \hat{\beta }= \beta + \sum _{i = 1}^n w_i e_i,
\end{aligned}$$
in which
$$w_{i} = (x_i - \bar{x}) / \sum _{i = 1}^n(x_i - \bar{x})^2$$, such
that $$\hat{\beta }_i$$ indeed is a linear combination of
$$e_i$$. Thus, given $$x_i$$, $$\hat{\beta }$$ is
normally distributed with expected value $$\beta$$ and variance
$$\begin{aligned} \sigma _{\hat{\beta }}^2 = \frac{\sigma _e^2}{\sum
_{i = 1}^n(x_i - \bar{x})^2}. \end{aligned}$$
In the same fashion, $$\hat{\alpha }$$ is normal with expected value
$$\alpha$$ and variance
$$\begin{aligned} \sigma _{\hat{\alpha }}^2 = \sigma _e^2\left( \frac{1}
{n} + \frac{\bar{x}^2}{\sum _{i = 1}^n(x_i - \bar{x})^2}\right) .
\end{aligned}$$
In the general case of Eq. (4.15), the variances of respective OLS
coefficients are obtained from the diagonal of the matrix
$$\begin{aligned} Var \,(\hat{\boldsymbol{\beta }}) = \sigma
(A4.1)
_e^2(\mathbf{X'X})^{-1}. \end{aligned}$$
If the error variance $$\sigma _e^2$$ were known, we could base our
inferences directly on the normal distribution. In practice, however,
variance $$\sigma _e^2$$ must be replaced by its regression estimate
$$s_e^2$$ in Eq. (4.21) with the implication that inferences are based
on the Student t-distribution. Thus, in a regression with k independent
variables, the t-ratio for testing the null hypothesis
$$\begin{aligned} H_0 : \beta _j = \beta _j^* \end{aligned}$$ (A4.2)
becomes
$$\begin{aligned} t = \frac{\hat{\beta }_j - \beta _j^*}
(A4.3)
{s_{\hat{\beta }_j}}, \end{aligned}$$
where $$\beta _j^*$$ is the hypothesized value of the population
coefficient (i.e., a fixed value defined by the researcher),
$$s_{\hat{\beta }_j}$$ is the estimated standard error of
$$\hat{\beta }_j$$, equaling the square root of the jth diagonal
element of Eq. (A4.1) with $$s_e^2$$ substituted for
$$\sigma _e^2$$, $$j = 0, 1, 2, \ldots , k$$, and
$$\beta _0$$ the intercept term (equaling $$\alpha$$ in the
text). Under the null hypothesis, the t-ratio in Eq. (A4.3) is t-distributed
with $$n - k - 1$$ degrees of freedom. Regarding the null hypothesis
in Eq. (A4.2), the most common case is that we are interested in whether
variable $$x_j$$ has any impact on y. In this case,
$$\beta _j^* = 0$$ in (A4.2) so that the null hypothesis becomes
$$\begin{aligned} H_0: \beta _j = 0 \end{aligned}$$
and the t-statistic in (A4.3) reduces to
$$\begin{aligned} t = \frac{\hat{\beta }_j}{s_{\hat{\beta }_j}},
\end{aligned}$$
which is the t-ratio shown in standard computer outputs.
Confidence intervals are of the form
$$\hat{\beta }\pm t_ps_{\hat{\beta }}$$ in which $$t_p$$ is an
appropriate percentile from the t-distribution to match the desired
confidence interval. Typical values are $$p = .025$$ for 95% and
$$p = .005$$ for 99% interval. The $$t_p$$ value itself depends
on the degrees of freedom. Typically in financial applications the number of
observations is large. Therefore, as the t-distribution approaches the normal
distribution when the degrees of freedom increases,
$$t_p \approx z_p$$ such that for the 95% interval
$$t_{.025} = 1.96 \approx 2$$ and for the 99% interval
$$t_{.005} = 2.58$$. These t-statistics are interpreted as 5% and 1%
significance levels, respectively. If t-statistics reach these levels or higher,
they indicate that the estimated beta coefficient is statistically significant.
Notably, even if the coefficient is statistically significant, it may not be
economically significant. The magnitude of the beta coefficient needs to be
large enough to suggest that a change in the independent variable will result
in a economically meaningful change in the dependent variable.
If the normality of the error term does not hold, the Central Limit
Theorem (CLT) provides us with so-called large sample results under fairly
mild assumptions. The CLT implies that the above normal
distribution results can be reliably used when the sample size is reasonably
large. There is no exact definition of how large the sample should be. In
general, with as small as 50 observations, the approximation is fairly close
for practical purposes.
As discussed earlier in the chapter, if the error terms are heteroskedastic
and/or autocorrelated, the major implication is bias in the standard
errors leading in most cases to overconfidence about the precision of the
estimates. For cross-sectional data, the White (1980) heteroskedastic robust
variance estimators (HC) are routinely used to correct the bias. In time-
series regression, the Newey and West (1987) heteroskedastic
autocorrelation robust measure (HAC) is used to correct standard errors.
And, if data are clustered, Cameron, Gelbach, and Miller (2011) clustering
robust standard errors can be used to take into account the correlation of
error terms.
As an example, we apply HAC standard errors to our earlier example of
Microsoft CAPM estimates in Sect. 4.3. For this purpose, we need more
sophisticated regression software than provided by Excel. R (https://r-
project.org) is a powerful open source software for general statistical
analyses as well as a wide variety of regression estimation methods.
Below is R-code for the estimation in which we assume that the data is
in an Excel file named msft.xlsx with the above headings on the first
line.
We observe that the HAC standard is just slightly larger than those of
OLS, which indicates that there is no material heteroskedasticity and/or
autocorrelation in the OLS residuals. Therefore, the OLS results are equally
reliable as those produced by the HAC approach, and the conclusions of
Sect. 4.3 pass this robustness check.
References
Black, F. 1972. Capital market equilibrium with restricted borrowing. Journal of Business 45: 444–
454.
[Crossref]
Black, F., M.C. Jensen, and M. Scholes. 1972. The capital asset pricing model: Some empirical tests.
In Studies in the Theory of Capital Markets, ed. M.C. Jensen. New York, NY: Praeger.
Blume, M. 1970. Portfolio theory: A step towards its practical application. Journal of Business 43:
152–174.
[Crossref]
Cameron, A.C., J.B. Gelbach, and D.L. Miller. 2011. Robust inference with multiway clustering.
Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 29: 238–249.
[Crossref]
Cochrane, J.H. 2005. Asset Pricing. Revised. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Douglas, G.W. 1969. Risk in the equity markets: An empirical appraisal of market efficiency. Yale
Economic Essays 9: 3–45.
Fama, E.F. 1968. Risk, return, and equilibrium: Some clarifying comments. Journal of Finance 23:
29–40.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and J.D. MacBeth. 1973. Risk, return, and equilibrium: Empirical tests. Journal of
Political Economy 81: 607–636.
[Crossref]
Friend, I., and M. Blume. 1970. Measurement of portfolio performance under uncertainty. American
Economic Review 60: 607–636.
Gibbons, M.R., and J. Shanken. 1983. A test of the Sharpe-Lintner CAPM. Working Paper,
University of California, Berkeley, CA.
Jensen, M.C. 1968. The performance of mutual funds in the period 1945–1964. Journal of Finance
23: 389–416.
[Crossref]
Lintner, J. 1965. The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock portfolios
and capital budgets, Review of Economics and Statistics 47: 13–37.
[Crossref]
Markowitz, H.M. 1959. Portfolio Selection: Efficient Diversification of Investments. New York, NY:
Wiley.
Merton, R.C. 1972. An analytical derivation of the efficient portfolio frontier. Journal of Financial
and Quantitative Finance 7: 1851–1872.
[Crossref]
Miller, M., and M. Scholes. 1972. Rates of return in relation to risk: A re-examination of some recent
findings. In Studies in the Theory of Capital Markets, ed. M.C. Jensen, 47–78. New York, NY:
Praeger.
Newey, W., and K. West. 1987. A simple, positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and
autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix. Econometrica 55: 703–708.
[Crossref]
Roll, R. 1977. A critique of the asset pricing theory’s tests, part I: On past and potential future
testability of the theory. Journal of Financial Economics 4: 129–176.
[Crossref]
Roll, R. 1980. Orthogonal portfolios. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 15: 1005–1012.
[Crossref]
Shanken, J. 1992. On the estimation of beta pricing models. Review of Financial Studies 5: 1–34.
[Crossref]
Sharpe, W.F. 1963. A simplified model for portfolio analysis. Management Science 9: 277–293.
[Crossref]
Sharpe, W.F. 1964. Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk.
Journal of Finance 19: 425–442.
Stambaugh, R. F. 1982. On the exclusion of assets from tests of the the two-parameter model.
Journal of Financial Economics 10: 237–268.
[Crossref]
Treynor, J.L. 1961. Market value, time, and risk. Unpublished manuscript.
Treynor, J.L. 1962. Toward a theory of market value of risky assets. Unpublished manuscript.
White, H. 1980. A heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test for
heteroskedasticity. Econometrica 22: 193–218.
Footnotes
1 See also Black et al. (1972).
2 Treasury rates were only available from 1948 to 1966. From 1925 to 1947 they used the dealer
commercial paper rate for the riskless rate proxy.
4 In forthcoming Sect. 4.4, we discuss the error term and other OLS assumptions in more detail.
5 The exact details of their data are somewhat complicated and beyond the scope of the present
general discussion. See Fama and MacBeth (1973, pp. 616–617).
6 It is well known that this rolling FM procedure eliminates correlation between residuals, or , in
cross-sectional regressions that can bias average risk premium t-tests. Some researchers conduct the
cross-sectional regressions within the sample by regressing portfolio returns in each month in the
sample period on average estimates for the entire period. In this case, it is necessary to make a
correction to adjust the standard errors in the t-statistic. Excellent discussions of this correction can
be found in Shanken (1992) and Cochrane (2005, Chapter 12).
7 See https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/DGS1MO.
8 In the estimation of the market model and other asset pricing models with multiple factors, the
authors have found that the beta coefficients are changed little if any. Nonetheless, inclusion of an
intercept is more appropriate to ensure that the regression coefficients are BLUE.
9 The term , where , , and
. In the CAPM, , and using
in above, we get after adding up and rearranging terms
..
© The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2023
J. W. Kolari, S. Pynnönen, Investment Valuation and Asset Pricing
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-16784-3_5
Seppo Pynnönen
Email: [email protected]
Supplementary Information
The online version contains supplementary material available at https://doi.
org/10.1007/978-3-031-16784-3_5
In its early years, as discussed in the last chapter, the CAPM came under
question. Empirical tests of the market model found that the relationship
between CAPM beta and U.S. stock returns was weaker than expected. The
estimated Security Market Line (SML) relating the excess returns of stock
portfolios on the Y-axis and their estimated betas on the X-axis was flatter
than predicted by the CAPM with a higher intercept (or $$\alpha$$
parameter). Black, Jensen, and Scholes (1972) found that low (high) beta
stocks had higher (lower) returns than theorized by the CAPM.
Consequently, they proposed that the borrowing rate in the real world is
greater than the riskless rate used in the theoretical CAPM.
With this empirical evidence in hand, Black (1972) created the zero-
beta CAPM by relaxing key assumptions in the CAPM: (1) investors can
invest in both long and short positions in risky assets; and (2) investors can
borrow in financial markets at interest rates greater than the riskless rate.
Applying these assumptions, Black derived an alternative form of the
CAPM. We next review of the zero-beta CAPM in addition to empirical
tests of this model.
Fig. 5.2 Industry portfolios and S &P 500 index returns with ex post efficient frontier and the
market line
5.5 Summary
Early stock return evidence using the market model to estimate the CAPM
found that the slope of the Security Market Line (SML) was flatter than
expected and the intercept term was higher than the predicted riskless
rate of interest (proxied by the government bond rate). Given this evidence,
Black (1972) proposed the zero-beta CAPM in which both long and short
positions in risky assets were allowed and investor borrowing could occur
at rates higher than the riskless rate. His asset pricing model led to a two-
factor model comprised of an efficient portfolio factor and zero-beta
portfolio factor. The efficient portfolio and zero-beta portfolio are assumed
to be uncorrelated (or orthogonal) to one another. Efficient portfolios are
changed from those located along a single line in the CAPM (extending
from the riskless rate to the tangent market portfolio on the
Markowitz efficient frontier of risky assets) to two possible cases: (1)
portfolios along the ray from the riskless rate to the tangent point of the
efficient frontier; and (2) a segment of the efficient frontier extending from
this tangent point to the end of the efficient frontier. The latter result is due
to the fact that investors are not allowed to borrow at the riskless rate. The
resultant zero-beta CAPM is more general than the CAPM because it holds
for any two portfolios located on the efficient frontier of the mean-variance
parabola and its zero-beta counterpart on the lower, inefficient boundary of
the parabola.
Empirical tests of the zero-beta CAPM are based on both time-series
regressions and cross-sectional regressions. The Fama and MacBeth (1973)
two-step procedure combines both of these regressions in an effort to
estimate the relation between betas and future returns of asset portfolios.
The time-series regression of the market model for the CAPM yields an
intercept known as Jensen’s $$\alpha$$ which should be zero for all
assets. If they are nonzero, the implication is that the zero-beta CAPM is
valid; however, other missing factors could explain nonzero
$$\alpha$$s also. The cross-sectional regression yields an intercept
denoted $$\lambda _0$$ that measures the risk premium on the zero-
beta portfolio. If $$\lambda _0>0$$, then the zero-beta CAPM’s
assumption that investors borrow at a rate greater than the riskless rate is
supported. Also, if other risk factors than the market factor are significant in
cross-sectional tests, then the zero-beta CAPM does not hold.
Research by Fama and French (1992, 1993, 1995) showed that size and
value are significant firm-level characteristics that help to explain average
stock returns. Thus, they rejected the zero-beta CAPM in addition to its
precursor the CAPM. Because any test of the CAPM or zero-beta CAPM is
a joint test that the model is valid and the portfolio proxy is an efficient
portfolio, their findings suggested that efficient portfolios must be
multifactor efficient in terms of multiple risk factors. By way of
explanation, they cited the ICAPM of Merton (1973) and APT of
Ross (1976) as theoretical models that are consistent with their three-factor
model containing market, size, and value factors.
While the efficient market hypothesis (EMH) suggests that prices reflect
all available information to evaluate risks in financial markets,
behavioralists argue that mispricing can happen due to irrational actions of
investors affected by human psychology. If behavioralists are right, then
asset pricing faces serious challenges. It is likely that short-run market
anomalies can occur due to irrational investor behavior as well as short run,
transitory market risk factors, but long-run anomalies are attributable to
unknown risk factors. Regarding the latter, if investors are rational (for the
most part), asset pricing models should continue to evolve and increasingly
explain the average returns of stocks (and other asset classes such as bonds,
commodities, real estate, etc.) in the long run. As we will see in upcoming
chapters, researchers are making progress!
In his assessment of the zero-beta CAPM, Sharpe (1973) critically
commented that, given any efficient portfolio, its zero-beta portfolio is not
directly identifiable. In asset pricing models, researchers typically employ
proxies for the market portfolio and the riskless rate—namely, the value-
weighted index of all stocks in the market and the government bond rate.
However, it is not clear how to proxy the zero-beta portfolio. With no such
ready proxy at hand, researchers typically do not include a zero-beta
portfolio rate of return in their specifications of different models. Instead, a
riskless rate proxy is almost always employed as the borrowing rate in
empirical models. Circumventing the zero-beta portfolio identification
problem, Chapter 10 reviews a new form the zero-beta CAPM dubbed the
ZCAPM. The ZCAPM enables estimation of the zero-beta CAPM with
readily available stock return data that does not require a proxy for the zero-
beta portfolio rate.
Questions
1.
Black (1972) developed the zero-beta CAPM due to some unrealistic
assumptions of the CAPM. What assumptions did he relax?
2.
Black et al. (1972) found that the market model needed to be modified
to better fit U.S. stock returns. What did they propose as a better fitting
model?
3.
Black (1972) proposed a zero-beta CAPM without and with a riskless
rate. Write the equations for these two models. Can investors borrow at
the riskless rate in the second model?
4. In the CAPM, the Security Market Line (SML) defines combinations of
the riskless asset and market portfolio M that investors can hold. By
contrast, under Black’s zero-beta CAPM, what are two ways for
investors to hold efficient portfolios? Draw a diagram to illustrate your
answer. Where is the market portfolio M in this diagram? How can the
investor hold M. Assuming the investor holds an efficient portfolio,
using your diagram, how can the uncorrelated zero-beta portfolio
counterpart be located?
5.
Assume that the investor holds risky efficient portfolio I that is a
combination of market portfolio M and its uncorrelated zero-beta
portfolio counterpart ZI. How can we write the zero-beta CAPM using
these two risky portfolios?
6.
Assume that you run a time-series regression of the market model.
Next, you run a cross-sectional regression using one-month-ahead
returns. In the cross-sectional regression, how should you interpret the
estimated market prices of beta risk, or $$\lambda _m$$, and the
intercept term, or $$\lambda _0$$? How is $$\lambda _m$$
related to the expected market risk premium in the CAPM?
7.
Fama and French published a series of studies in the 1990s that are
important to the validity of the CAPM and zero-beta CAPM. What did
they find in these studies? What did they propose as an alternative asset
pricing model?
8.
What is a market anomaly? What might explain market anomalies?
Give two explanations. What does the efficient market hypothesis
(EMH) have to say about market anomalies?
9.
Can financial markets be irrational? Give an example from stock
market history.
Problems
1.
How can the zero-beta CAPM be empirically tested with real-world
data? Discuss two tests using equations based on the market model.
Which test is more reliable and why?
2. Show that the GRS statistic
$$F = \frac{T - N - 1}{N} \frac{\hat{\theta }^{*2} - \hat{\theta
}_p^2}{1 + \hat{\theta }_p^2}$$
can be equivalently written as
$$F = \frac{T-N-1}{N}\left(\left[ \frac{\sqrt{1 + \hat{\theta
}^{*2}}}{\sqrt{1 + \hat{\theta }_p^2}}\right] ^2 - 1\right).$$
3.
Using 12 industry portfolios from Kenneth French’s data library,
replicate the GRS testing for mean-variance efficiency of the market
portfolio, available in
FF_Research_Data_Factors_CSV. Use monthly data for the time
period January 2000 to September 2021. Verify that the test statistics in
Eqs. (5.10) and (5.11) produce the same results.
$$\begin{aligned} B-AE({R}_{ZI})+CE({R}_I)E({R}_{ZI})-
(A5.13)
AE({R}_I)=0\end{aligned}$$
$$\begin{aligned} E({R}_{ZI})=\frac{AE({R}_I)-B}
{CE({R}_{I})-A}=\frac{A}{C}-\frac{BC-A^2}{C^2[E({R}_I)- (A5.14)
\frac{A}{C}]}. \end{aligned}$$
Finally, upon re-writing Eq. (A5.11), Black’s zero-beta CAPM is obtained:
$$\begin{aligned} E({R}_{P})=E({R}_{ZI})+\beta
(A5.15)
_P[E({R}_I)-E({R}_{ZI})]. \end{aligned}$$
Appendix B: R Snippet for the GRS Testing
Example in Section 5.4
References
Barberis, M., A. Shleifer, and R. Vishny. 1998. A model of investor sentiment. Journal of Financial
Economics 49: 307–343.
[Crossref]
Black, F. 1972. Capital market equilibrium with restricted borrowing. Journal of Business 45: 444–
454.
[Crossref]
Black, F., M.C. Jensen, and M. Scholes. 1972. The capital asset pricing model: Some empirical tests.
In Studies in the Theory of Capital Markets, ed. M.C. Jensen. New York, NY: Praeger.
Blume, M. 1970. Portfolio theory: A step towards its practical application. Journal of Business 43:
152–174.
[Crossref]
Blume, M., and I. Friend. 1973. A new look at the capital asset pricing model. Journal of Finance
28: 19–33.
[Crossref]
Cochrane, J.H. 2005. Asset Pricing. Revised. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Daniel, K., D. Hirshleifer, and A. Subrahmanyam. 1998. Investor psychology and security market
under- and overreactions. Journal of Finance 53: 1839–1885.
[Crossref]
De Bondt, W.F.M., and R. Thaler. 1985. Does the stock market overreact? Journal of Finance 40:
793–805.
[Crossref]
De Bondt, W.F.M., and R. Thaler. 1987. Further evidence of stock market overreaction and
seasonality. Journal of Finance 42: 557–581.
[Crossref]
Douglas, G.W. 1969. Risk in the equity markets: An empirical appraisal of market efficiency. Yale
Economic Essays 9: 3–45.
Fama, E.F. 1968. Risk, return, and equilibrium: Some clarifying comments. Journal of Finance 23:
29–40.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F. 1970. Efficient capital markets: A review of theory and empirical work. Journal of
Finance 25: 383–417.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 1992. The cross-section of expected stock returns. Journal of Finance
47: 427–465.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 1993. The cross-section of expected returns. Journal of Financial
Economics 33: 3–56.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 1995. Size and book-to-market factors in earnings and returns. Journal
of Finance 50: 131–156.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 2004. The capital asset pricing model: Theory and evidence. Journal of
Economic Perspectives 18: 25–46.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and J.D. MacBeth. 1973. Risk, return, and equilibrium: Empirical tests. Journal of
Political Economy 81: 607–636.
[Crossref]
Ferson, W.E. 2019. Empirical Asset Pricing: Models and Methods. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.
Ferson, W., A.F. Siegel, and J.L. Wang. 2019. Asymptotic distributions of tests of portfolio efficiency
and factor model comparisons with conditioning information. Working paper, University of Southern
California and University of Washington.
Friend, I., and M. Blume. 1970. Measurement of portfolio performance under uncertainty. American
Economic Review 60: 607–636.
Gibbons, M.R., S.A. Ross, and J. Shanken. 1989. A test of the efficiency of a given portfolio.
Econometrica 57: 1121–1152.
[Crossref]
Green, R.C., and B. Hollifield. 1992. When will mean-variance efficient portfolios be well
diversified? Journal of Finance 47: 1785–1809.
[Crossref]
Jagannathan, R., and T. Ma. 2003. Risk reduction in large portfolios: A role for portfolio weight
constraints. Journal of Finance 58: 1651–1684.
[Crossref]
Jensen, M.C. 1968. The performance of mutual funds in the period 1945–1964. Journal of Finance
23: 389–416.
[Crossref]
Kallberg, J.G., and W.T. Ziemba. 1983. Comparison of alternative utility functions in portfolio
selection problems. Management Science 29: 1257–1276.
[Crossref]
Kroll, Y., H. Levy, and H. Markowitz. 1984. Mean-variance versus direct utility maximization.
Journal of Finance 39: 47–61.
[Crossref]
Lakonishok, J., A. Shleifer, and R.W. Vishny. 1994. Contrarian investment, extrapolation, and risk.
Journal of Finance 49: 1541–1578.
[Crossref]
Levy, H. 1983. The capital asset pricing model: Theory and empiricism. Economic Journal 93: 145–
165.
[Crossref]
Levy, M. 2007. Conditions for a CAPM equilibrium with positive prices. Journal of Economic
Theory 137: 404–415.
[Crossref]
Levy, M., and Y. Ritov. 2010. Mean-variance efficient portfolios with many assets: 50% short.
Quantitative Finance 10: 1–11.
Markowitz, H.M. 1959. Portfolio Selection: Efficient Diversification of Investments. New York, NY:
John Wiley & Sons.
Merton, R.C. 1972. An analytical derivation of the efficient portfolio frontier. Journal of Financial
and Quantitative Finance 7: 1851–1872.
[Crossref]
Merton, R.C. 1973. An intertemporal capital asset pricing model. Econometrica 41: 867–887.
[Crossref]
Miller, M., and M. Scholes. 1972. Rates of return in relation to risk: A re-examination of some recent
findings. In Studies in the Theory of Capital Markets, ed. M.C. Jensen, 47–78. New York, NY:
Praeger.
Pulley, L.B. 1981. General mean-variance approximation to expected utility for short holding
periods. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 16: 361–373.
[Crossref]
Roll, R. 1977. A critique of the asset pricing theory’s tests, part I: On past and potential future
testability of the theory. Journal of Financial Economics 4: 129–176.
[Crossref]
Roll, R. 1980. Orthogonal portfolios. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 15: 1005–1012.
[Crossref]
Ross, S.A. 1976. The arbitrage theory of capital asset pricing. Journal of Economic Theory 13: 341–
360.
[Crossref]
Sharpe, W.F. 1966. Mutual fund performance, Journal of Business 39: 119–138.
[Crossref]
Sharpe, W.F. 1973. The capital asset pricing model: Traditional and “zero-beta” versions.
Presentation at the 1973 annual meetings of the Midwest Finance Association, 1–15.
Thaler, R.H. 1999. The end of behavioral finance. Financial Analysts Journal 55: 12–17.
[Crossref]
Thaler, R.H. 2016. Behavioral economics: Past, present, and future. American Economic Review 106:
1577–1600.
[Crossref]
Footnotes
1 This graph is based on Figure 4 in Sharpe’s (1973) conference presentation to the Midwest Finance
Association.
4 For example, see Pulley (1981), Kallberg and Ziemba (1983), Levy (1983), Kroll et al. (1984),
Green and Hollifield (1992), Jagannathan and Ma (2003), Levy and Ritov (2010), and others.
5 For example, assuming all betas for assets are positive, long and short positions would be needed
to get a portfolio beta equal to zero. Since it is a zero-investment portfolio like other factors, we use
the notation $$\lambda$$ to acknowledge this fact.
6 For example, see Blume (1970), Friend and Blume (1970), and Black et al. (1972).
7 See recent work by Ferson et al. (2019) for further discussion and citations of other studies that
have progressively refined these statistical tests.
8 In other words, when the riskless rate is available, $$\hat{\theta }^{*2}$$ is the square of the
slope of the tangent line from the origin to the (ex post) efficient frontier, whereas $$\theta _p^2$$
is the slope of the line from the origin to portfolio p in standard deviation and excess return space.
9 The intuition of representation (5.12) is as follows. Since a line in the standard deviation (
$$\sigma$$) mean excess return ( $$\mu$$) space through the origin is of the form
$$\mu = \theta \sigma$$, the square of the length of the line (by Pythagoras) is
$$\sigma ^2 + \theta ^2\sigma ^2 = (1 + \theta ^2)\sigma ^2$$. As a result, the ratio
$$\sqrt{1 + \hat{\theta }^{*2}} / \sqrt{1 + \hat{\theta }_p^2}$$ in Eq. (5.12) is the ratio of the
lengths at any $$\sigma > 0$$ of the tangent line with slope $$\hat{\theta }^{*2}$$ and the
line of portfolio p with slope $$\hat{\theta }_p$$. Therefore the ratio
$$[(1 + \hat{\theta }^{*2})\sigma ^2] / [(1 + \hat{\theta }_p^2)\sigma ^2] = (1 + \hat{\theta
}^{*2}) / (1 + \hat{\theta }_p^2)$$
is the ratio of the squared lengths of the lines. The closer this ratio is to the lower bound of one, the
closer the portfolio p is to the efficient frontier.
10 https://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/data_library.html.
© The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2023
J. W. Kolari, S. Pynnönen, Investment Valuation and Asset Pricing
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-16784-3_6
Seppo Pynnönen
Email: [email protected]
Supplementary Information
The online version contains supplementary material available at https://doi.
org/10.1007/978-3-031-16784-3_6
Weak early empirical evidence with respect to the CAPM inspired a variety
of alternative forms proposed by researchers to take into account realistic
aspects of capital markets not considered in its original form. In the last
chapter we covered Black’s (1972) zero-beta CAPM allowing short sales
and borrowing at rates greater than the riskless rate. Here we review further
extensions of the CAPM, including the foundational and more general
intertemporal CAPM (ICAPM) which spawned a number of new models
such as the international asset pricing model (IAPM), consumption CAPM
(CCAPM), production CAPM (PCAPM), and conditional CAPM. The latter
conditional CAPM allows for time-varying risk parameters in any asset
pricing model to take into account the business cycle with economic
expansions and recessions. Over the years, different forms of the
aforementioned models have been developed by researchers. In general,
they attest to the widespread interest in the CAPM by academics and
professionals in finance.
Unfortunately, the aforementioned extensions of the ICAPM did not
consistently cure the weak empirical evidence problem. While they
continue to draw the interest of many researchers, most asset pricing
researchers nowadays emphasize multifactor models. The latter models
augment the market factor by adding many new factors proposed by
researchers. Multifactor models are considered to be related to the
intertemporal CAPM (ICAPM) by Merton (1973) covered in this chapter in
addition to the Arbitrage Pricing Model (APT) by Ross (1976) discussed in
forthcoming Chapter 7. In Chapters 8 and 9 we will see that multifactor
models do a better job of explaining stock returns than the CAPM and its
companion models presented in this chapter. However, in Chapter 10 we
return to the CAPM with an alternative form of the zero-beta CAPM
dubbed the ZCAPM by Kolari et al. (2021). Recent empirical evidence
discussed there shows that the ZCAPM outperforms popular multifactor
models in cross-sectional tests. Hence, the development of alternative
CAPMs continues to hold promise in asset pricing.
Fig. 6.1 A three-dimensional depiction of an empirical ICAPM with two systematic beta risk
factors: (1) market factor beta $$\beta _{i,M}$$ , and (2) state variable beta $$\beta _{i,s1}$$
At the end of his paper, reflecting on the ICAPM, Merton (1973, pp.
885–886) suggested future directions for research:
Fig. 6.2 Alternative CAPM specifications based on the intertemporal CAPM (ICAPM)
Fig. 6.3 Currency risk in world currency markets affects the stock returns in different countries
through their exchange rate risk exposure or sensitivity to national currency movements
Fig. 6.4 Consumers buy and sell financial assets over time to smooth consumption in the
consumption CAPM (CCAPM)
Fig. 6.5 Close relation between stock return and capital investment forecasts in the production
CAPM (PCAPM)
The PCAPM draws an important link between investment in the real sector
of the economy and asset returns in the financial sector. The fact that the
conditional model improved its performance suggests that risk parameters
are time-varying over the business cycle. Good and bad economic times are
relevant to asset pricing. We next take a closer look at conditional
models and their empirical setup.
Fig. 6.6 Beta estimates for the market factor tend to vary randomly over time consistent with the
unconditional CAPM but contrary to the conditional CAPM
Questions
1.
Merton (1973) developed the intertemporal CAPM (ICAPM). What is
different about the ICAPM compared to the CAPM? What new
assumption does it make?
2.
In the ICAPM, how do investors respond to unfavorable shifts in
future investment opportunities? What are state variables?
3.
In the ICAPM, what is the three-fund theorem? In view of this
theorem, write the equation for the ICAPM.
4.
In the ICAPM, if correlations $$\rho _{iN} = 0$$ for all securities i,
which also implies that $$\rho _{NM} = 0$$ (where M is the
market portfolio), but $$r_N$$ is perfectly negatively correlated
with $$R_f$$ (which is true by definition), the correlations of
stocks with the future riskless rate would be zero. What happens to the
ICAPM is this special case? What is the beta of security N in this
case? Is N related to the zero-beta portfolio of Black in this case? If
the market beta $$\beta _{i,M} = 0$$ but $$\beta _{i,N}>0$$,
is the expected return on the i asset equal to the riskless rate?
5. Solnik (1974) proposed an international asset pricing model (IAPM)
based on an international three-fund theorem. What is this theorem
based on an international three fund theorem. What is this theorem
and how does it change the CAPM? Write the equation for the IAPM
and discuss Solnik’s model.
6.
How did Adler and Dumas (1984) define currency risk? How is
currency risk different than exchange rate risk? How did they propose
to measure the exchange risk exposure of a security? Write an
equation that can be used to measure this exposure.
7.
Jorion (1990) investigated the exchange risk exposure of U.S. stocks.
He modified the total exchange risk exposure equation of Adler and
Dumas (1984) in what way? What did he find?
8.
Lucas (1978) and Breeden (1979) proposed the consumption CAPM
(CCAPM) using the ICAPM framework of Merton (1973). In this
model, consumers buy and sell financial assets over time to smooth
consumption and maximize lifetime expected utility. What assets will
consumers seek? Why? How does it affect the risk premiums on these
assets? What happens to other assets?
9.
Breeden (1979) specified a CCAPM that collapses the multi-beta
Merton (1973) ICAPM into a single-beta equation. Write this model
and define its variables and parameters. Why did he believe that the
CCAPM was a better model than the CAPM from a theoretical
perspective as well as in terms of empirical testing? Later work by
Breeden et al. (1989) conducted empirical tests of the CCAPM. What
did they find?
10.
Cochrane (1991, 1996) created a production CAPM (PCAPM). How
is the PCAPM different from the consumption CAPM (CCAPM)? He
tested it using a single factor model. Write the equation for this model
and discuss his results. What did he conclude?
11. Assume that we scale the market factor with an instrumental lagged
variable denoted as $$I_{t-1}$$. Write a conditional (time-varying)
linear function for beta and define its terms. Assuming that the alpha
term is conditional also, incorporate this instrument into the market
model and discuss the parameters in this conditional form of the
market model.
12.
Does time-variation in beta explain the weak evidence for the CAPM?
Discuss empirical results of studies testing conditional CAPMs.
Problems
1.
Write the ICAPM as a multifactor model with state variables. What
could be used to proxy for the state variables?
2.
Write the market model form of Solnik’s IAPM. Solnik ran this model
on 10 major industrialized countries from 1966 to 1971. What did he
find? What did cross-sectional regression tests find? What did later
authors find in testing the IAPM?
3.
Assume that you are a U.S. investor buying a European stock:
1.
You exchange 100 dollars for 90 euros at the exchange rate 1 USD
= 0.90 EUR or 1 EUR = 1.11 USD.
2.
You buy 10 shares of a European stock for 90 euros.
3.
One year later you sell the European stock for 100 euros. You
exchange the 100 euros for 120 dollars at the exchange rate 1 USD
= 0.83 EUR or 1 EUR = 1.20 USD.
What is your stock rate of return? What is your euro rate of return?
What is your total return?
References
Adler, M., and D. Bernard. 1984. Exposure to currency risk: Definition and measurement. Financial
Management 13: 41–50.
Black, F. 1972. Capital market equilibrium with restricted borrowing. Journal of Business 45: 444–
454.
[Crossref]
Black, F., M.C. Jensen, and M. Scholes. 1972. The capital asset pricing model: Some empirical tests.
In Studies in the Theory of Capital Markets, ed. M.C. Jensen. New York, NY: Praeger.
Breeden, N.D. 1979. An intertemporal asset pricing model with stochastic consumption and
investment opportunities. Journal of Financial Economics 7: 265–296.
[Crossref]
Breeden, N.D., M.R. Gibbons, and R.H. Litzenberger. 1989. Empirical tests of the consumption-
oriented CAPM. Journal of Finance 44: 231–262.
Chen, N., R. Roll, and S.A. Ross. 1986. Economic forces and the stock market. Journal of Business
59: 383–404.
[Crossref]
Cochrane, J.H. 1991. Production-based asset pricing and the link between stock returns and
economic fluctuations. Journal of Finance 46: 209–237.
[Crossref]
Cochrane, J.H. 1996. A cross-sectional test of an investment-based asset pricing model. Journal of
Political Economy 104: 572–621.
[Crossref]
Cochrane, J.H. 2005. Asset Pricing. Revised. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 1992. The cross-section of expected stock returns. Journal of Finance
47: 427–465.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 1993. The cross-section of expected returns. Journal of Financial
Economics 33: 3–56.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 1995. Size and book-to-market factors in earnings and returns. Journal
of Finance 50: 131–156.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 1998. Value versus growth: The international evidence. Journal of
Finance 53: 1975–1999.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and J.D. MacBeth. 1973. Risk, return, and equilibrium: Empirical tests. Journal of
Political Economy 81: 607–636.
[Crossref]
Jorion, P. 1990. The exchange-rate exposure of U.S. multinationals. Journal of Business 63: 331–
345.
[Crossref]
Ferson, W.E., S. Kandel, and R.F. Stambaugh. 1987. Tests of asset pricing with time-varying
expected risk premiums and market betas. Journal of Finance 42: 201–220.
[Crossref]
Gibbons, M.R., and W.E. Ferson. 1985. Testing asset pricing models with changing expectations and
an unobservable market portfolio. Journal of Financial Economics 14: 217–236.
[Crossref]
Griffin, J.M. 2002. Are the Fama French factors global or country specific? Review of Financial
Studies 15: 783–803.
[Crossref]
Hansen, L.P., and R.J. Hodrick. 1983. Risk averse speculation in the forward foreign exchange
market: An econometric analysis of linear models. In Exchange Rates and Iinternational
Macroeconomics, ed. J.A. Frenkel. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
Harvey, C.R. 1989. Time-varying conditional covariances in tests of asset pricing models. Journal of
Financial Economics 24: 289–317.
[Crossref]
Karolyi, G.A., and R.M. Stulz. 2002. Are financial assets priced locally or globally?’’. In The
Handbook of the Economics of Finance, ed. G. Constantinides, M. Harris, and R. Stulz. Amsterdam,
Netherlands: North Holland Publishing Co.
Kolari, J.W., W. Liu, and J.Z. Huang. 2021. A New Model of Capital Asset Prices: Theory and
Evidence. Cham, Switzerland: Palgrave Macmillan.
[Crossref]
Lettau, M., and S. Ludvigson. 2001. Resurrecting the (C)CAPM: A cross-sectional test when risk
premia are time-varying. Journal of Political Economy 109: 1238–1287.
[Crossref]
Lewellen, J., and S. Nagel. 2006. The conditional CAPM does not explain asset pricing anomalies.
Journal of Financial Economics 82: 289–413.
[Crossref]
Lucas, R.E. 1978. Asset prices in an exchange economy. Econometrica 46: 1429–1445.
[Crossref]
Merton, R.C. 1973. An intertemporal capital asset pricing model. Econometrica 41: 867–887.
[Crossref]
Petkova, R., and L. Zhang. 2005. Is value riskier than growth? Journal of Financial Economics 78:
187–202.
[Crossref]
Roll, R. 1977. A critique of the asset pricing theory’s tests, part I: On past and potential future
testability of the theory. Journal of Financial Economics 4: 129–176.
[Crossref]
Ross, S.A. 1976. The arbitrage theory of capital asset pricing. Journal of Economic Theory 13: 341–
360.
[Crossref]
Simin, T. 2008. The poor performance of asset pricing models. Journal of Financial and Quantitative
Analysis 43: 335–380.
[Crossref]
Solnik, B.H. 1974a. The international pricing of risk: An empirical investigation of the world capital
market structure. Journal of Finance 29: 365–378.
[Crossref]
Solnik, B.H. 1974b. An international market model of security price behavior. Journal of Financial
and Quantitative Analysis 9: 537–554.
[Crossref]
Footnotes
1 Merton cited Fama (1970), who had observed that intertemporal portfolio maximization can be
treated as if the investor had a single-period utility function.
3 See equation (34) in Merton (1973, p. 882). The derivation of this model is quite complicated and
beyond the scope of the present text. He utilized stochastic differential calculus, complex continuous
functions, instantaneous returns (as opposed to discrete one-period returns), and optimality
conditions to solve the asset pricing problem.
4 For an excellent survey of the issue of domestic (local) versus global asset pricing, see Karolyi and
Stulz (2002).
5 If $$R_{xt}>0$$, we can infer a depreciation of the dollar against the euro, as each euro can
buy more dollars at time t than before at time $$t-1$$. If $$R_{xt}<0$$, then the dollar
appreciated against the euro.
6 A more widely used currency basket by the IMF is the Special Drawing Right (SDR) consisting of
currencies in the United States, Europe, Japan, and the United Kingdom. The Federal Reserve in the
United States constructs a number of other currency baskets. In general, currency baskets are formed
using trade weights of the different exchange rates.
7 Also, he tested a five-factor model by Chen et al. (1986) that contains the growth in industrial
production and some inflation and interest rate variables. Like the CAPM, the performance of this
multifactor model was similar to the PCAPM.
9 Beyond the scope of the present discussion, a first-order Taylor series can be used to approximate
the potentially complex effects of an instrument on factor loadings. Taylor series are well known in
the sciences and represent an infinite sum of derivatives of a mathematical function at a single point.
10 Simin (2008) also found that conditional versions of the CAPM and Fama and French three-
factor model did not outperform their unconditional versions in terms of one-month-ahead cross-
sectional tests of their predictive ability.
© The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2023
J. W. Kolari, S. Pynnönen, Investment Valuation and Asset Pricing
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-16784-3_7
Seppo Pynnönen
Email: [email protected]
Supplementary Information
The online version contains supplementary material available at https://doi.
org/10.1007/978-3-031-16784-3_7
One of the most controversial assumptions of the CAPM is that returns are
normally distributed, which implies that agents have quadratic utility
functions. This assumption guarantees the mean-variance efficiency of the
market portfolio. Also, it leads to a linear equilibrium relation between the
expected return on an asset and its sensitivity to the expected market
premium (i.e., beta risk). This implied linear relation is widely accepted due
to its sound intuition and easy empirical specification.
Taking linearity as a starting premise, Ross (1971, 1974, 1976)
developed the arbitrage pricing theory (APT).1 The APT depends on no-
arbitrage conditions in the financial market. The underlying intuition is that
the total variation of the return on a single asset stems from a (small)
number of common factors and a random idiosyncratic residual term.
Although the APT is based on the similar intuition of linearity in the
CAPM, it is much more general. This chapter discusses briefly the concept
of no arbitrage, introduces the basic idea of Ross’s APT model, and reviews
empirical tests of the model. Huberman and Wang (2017) give an excellent
overview of the APT and its practical applications.
Fig. 7.1 Arbitraging riskless profits by buying and selling mispriced assets
(Source Adapted from Wikipedia [https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Arbitrage_pricing_theory])
The no-arbitrage condition has two main features: (1) no wealth; and (2)
no risk must earn zero return on average. These features are easy to
understand in terms of riskless returns. If $$R_f$$ and
$$R_f^*$$ are two riskless rates that differ, then borrowing at the
lower rate and investing in the higher rate would generate a possibility to
earn unlimited riskless returns generated by the interest rate difference. As
another example, Fig. 7.1 shows how to arbitrage riskless profits by buying
underpriced assets and selling overpriced assets.
Arbitrage portfolios are portfolios that involve no wealth, which is
known as zero-investment portfolios. In this respect, buying assets in a long
portfolio is financed by selling short other assets (i.e., selling borrowed
assets). Mathematically, such a zero-investment portfolio satisfies the
following condition:
$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{i = 1}^n w_i = 0, \end{aligned}$$ (7.2)
where $$w_i$$ are the amounts invested in asset i.
In developing the APT it is assumed that the portfolio weights
$$w_i$$ are of order 1/n to guarantee a well-diversified zero-
investment portfolio. This assumption allows us to utilize the law of large
numbers in probability theory to eliminate idiosyncratic risks from the
portfolio. Given that returns to satisfy the representation in Eq. (7.1), the
arbitrage portfolio becomes
$$\begin{aligned} R_p= & {} \sum _{i = 1}^n w_iR_i \\
\nonumber= & {} \sum _{i = 1}^n w_i E(R_i) + \sum _{i = 1}^n (7.3)
w_i \beta _i F + \sum _{i = 1}^n w_i \epsilon _i. \end{aligned}$$
In order to make this a zero risk arbitrage portfolio, we should be able to
eliminate the last two terms in the second line of the equation. That is, the
systematic risk component $$\sum _i w_i\beta _i F$$ and the residual
idiosyncratic risk $$\sum _iw_i\epsilon _i$$ drop out. The latter is
eliminated by the independence assumptions of random error terms
$$\epsilon _i$$ from common factor F and the error terms of different
assets. These assumptions combined with the assumption that
$$w_i \approx \pm 1/n$$ imply that the last term is zero, or
$$\sum _i w_i \epsilon _i \approx 0$$ for large n as idiosyncratic
risks are diversified away. Subsequently, for large n we can discard the error
from (7.3) and approximate the portfolio by
$$\begin{aligned} R_p = \sum _{i = 1}^n w_iE(R_i) + \sum _{i =
(7.4)
1}^n w_i \beta _i F. \end{aligned}$$
Note that $$\sum _i w_i\beta _i F = F \sum _i w_i \beta _i$$. Under
the zero-investment restriction in Eq. (7.2), we can always select weights
$$w_i$$ such that
$$\begin{aligned} \sum _i w_i\beta _i = 0. \end{aligned}$$ (7.5)
With these weights, all the risks from the arbitrage portfolio become
eliminated so that
$$\begin{aligned} R_p = \sum _{i = 1}^n w_i E(R_i),
(7.6)
\end{aligned}$$
which is a riskless, zero-investment portfolio. Therefore, because the zero-
investment portfolio is riskless, the no-arbitrage condition implies that we
must have $$R_p = 0$$, or
$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{i = 1}^nw_i E(R_i) = 0. \end{aligned}$$ (7.7)
Given that this must hold for all zero-investment portfolios with
$$\sum _i w_i = 0$$ and $$\sum _i w_i\beta _i = 0$$, pure
linear algebra implies that the expected return, or $$E(R_i)$$, is a
linear combination of a constant and the asset’s beta. This insight yields the
APT model for the expected return on each asset of the form:
$$\begin{aligned} E(R_i) = \gamma _0 + \gamma _1 \beta _i,
(7.8)
\end{aligned}$$
where $$\gamma _0$$ and $$\gamma _1$$ are common to all
stocks, and $$\beta _i$$ is the stock’s sensitivity to the risk factor.
It should be noted that, because all arbitrage portfolios are not
necessarily well diversified, Eq. (7.8) may hold only approximately. Taking
the approximation as a starting point, Huberman (1982) provided an
interesting approach to derive the APT model. Using purely the no-
arbitrage argument and without explicit reference to the meaning of well
diversified, we can utilize linear algebra to write:
$$\begin{aligned} E(R_i) = \gamma _0 + \gamma _1 \beta _i +
(7.9)
\alpha _i \end{aligned}$$
wherein alpha ( $$\alpha _i$$) is orthogonal to both the vector of ones
and betas. Huberman and Wang (2017) refer to Eq. (7.9) as an approximate
APT model and Eq. (7.8) as an exact APT model. Even though the
representation in Eq. (7.9) is purely a mathematical identity, the way it is
constructed makes $$\alpha _i$$ satisfy the zero-investment arbitrage
portfolio restrictions in Eqs. (7.2) and (7.5), which can be utilized as a basis
for defining a zero-investment portfolio. With this convention, Huberman
derived the main result of the APT theory that, if there is no arbitrage, the
deviations, or
$$\alpha _i = E(R_i) - (\gamma _0 + \gamma _i \beta _i)$$, must be
negligible as the number of stocks n grows, i.e., the representation of the
expected return $$E(R_i)$$ in Eq. (7.8) is essentially accurate.2 Of
course, from a financial economics perspective, the $$\alpha _i$$
parameter in equation (7.9) can be interpreted as a pricing error.
These results must hold for all assets. In particular, if there exists a
riskless asset with return $$R_f$$ whose sensitivity to the common
risk factor F is zero by definition, Eq. (7.8) yields for the riskless asset
$$R_f = \gamma _0$$. Therefore, if a riskless rate exists, the APT
model becomes
$$\begin{aligned} E(R_i) - R_f = \gamma _1 \beta _i.
(7.10)
\end{aligned}$$
Alternatively, setting $$\lambda = \gamma _1 + R_f$$, we can re-
write Eq. (7.10) in the commonly expressed form
$$\begin{aligned} E(R_i) - R_f = (\lambda - R_f)\beta _i,
(7.11)
\end{aligned}$$
which is known as the APT model for asset returns. The difference
$$\lambda - R_f$$ is common to all stocks as the factor risk
premium, and $$\lambda$$ is the expected value of the common risk
factor. Finally, if F is the market portfolio, the APT model reduces to the
CAPM.
Example: Assume that the common factor in the APT model is the
market portfolio with expected return $$\lambda = E(R_m)$$. Let
$$R_p$$ be the return of a well-diversified portfolio such that
$$R_p^e = \alpha _p + \beta _p R_m^e,$$
where $$R_p^e = R_p - R_f$$ is the excess return of the portfolio,
and $$R_m^e = R_m - R_f$$ is the market excess return. If
$$\alpha _p \ne 0$$, there is an arbitrage opportunity. The general
recipe is that, if $$\alpha _p$$ is positive, short the market, and if
$$\alpha _p$$ is negative, short the portfolio.
More precisely, as
$$\alpha _p = R_p - \beta _p R_m - (1 - \beta _p)R_f$$, then if
$$\alpha _p > 0$$, the sign in front of each return gives the long (
$$+$$) versus short (−) position. That is, for a desired riskless
arbitrage income of $$\alpha _p\times x$$ dollars, multiply both sides
by x. This would result in buying portfolio p with x dollars, selling short the
market portfolio with $$\beta _px$$ dollars, and borrowing/lending
$$(1 - \beta _p)\times x$$ dollars (borrowing if
$$\beta _p < 1$$, lending if $$\beta _p > 1$$, and neither
if $$\beta _p = 1$$). If $$\alpha _p < 0$$, the strategy is
simply reversed.
The single factor model can be easily extended to multiple factors,
wherein the single factor F in Eq. (7.1) is replaced by K common
factors denoted $$F_1, F_2, \ldots , F_K$$ with slope coefficients
$$\beta _{i1}, \beta _{i2}, \ldots , \beta _{iK}$$, respectively. Each
factor is orthogonal to (or uncorrelated with) all other factors. Then the
multifactor model becomes:
$$\begin{aligned} R_i = E(R_i) + \beta _{i,1} F_1 + \cdots + \beta
(7.12)
_{i,K} F_K + \epsilon _i. \end{aligned}$$
In this case the equilibrium relation in Eq. (7.10) generalizes to the
following form:
(7.13)
$$\begin{aligned} E(R_i) - R_f = \beta _{i,1}\gamma _1 + \cdots +
\beta _{i,K}\gamma _K, \end{aligned}$$
where $$\gamma _1, \ldots , \gamma _K$$ are risk premiums
associated with the K common factors.
The arbitrage portfolio is again selected to diversify away asset-specific
idiosyncratic risk. Similarly, the weights $$w_i$$ can be selected
similar to the single factor case such that
$$\sum _{i = 1}^nw_i\beta _{i,k} = 0$$ for all
$$k = 1, \ldots , K$$. Finally, it is notable that the APT applies even if
some of the error terms are correlated within some clusters of assets, like
industries, provided that the error terms are independent between the
clusters and the number of clusters is large. In this case the number of
clusters takes care of the diversification effect.
Unlike the CAPM mean-variance theory, which implies a linear
relation with the market portfolio, the APT neither identifies the number of
factors nor what the factors are. This generality is one of the main
weaknesses of the APT model. In the next section we discuss attempts by
researchers to empirically identify the number of factors in the APT.
7.3 Summary
Ross (1971, 1974, 1976) developed the arbitrage pricing theory (APT) as a
new general equilibrium framework grounded in a linear relation between
expected returns on assets and their risks. A no-arbitrage condition is
assumed in which no wealth is required due to long/short portfolios held by
investors. Investors earn zero returns for zero risk in well-diversified
portfolios with no asset-specific idiosyncratic risk. Ross showed that the
CAPM is a special case of the APT with a single market factor. More
generally, the APT can have multiple orthogonal factors that investors use
to arbitrage away any excess risk-adjusted return in the market. However,
Ross did not specify the number of factors or their identity in the APT.
To empirically test the APT, Roll and Ross (1980) used the statistical
method of factor analysis in combination with cross-sectional
regression analyses to show that at least three factors exist in U.S. stock
returns. Further tests of own variance as a factor were insignificant in line
with the APT. Another factor analysis study by Chen (1983) found five
significant factors in cross-sectional tests. The empirical findings of these
studies supported the APT.
In sum, the APT provides a general framework for linear factor pricing
models. Researchers building multifactor models in forthcoming chapters
often cite the APT as a theoretical justification for their specifications. Due
to their widespread acceptance among both academic researchers and
investment professionals, multifactor models have become popular over the
past 30 years.
Questions
1. In the CAPM, one of the assumptions is that investors have common
(homogeneous) beliefs about the return distribution of assets. What is
the common assumption about the asset return generating process in
the APT theory?
2.
What are the major strengths and weaknesses of the APT in relation to
the CAPM?
3.
In the single factor case, given that
$$R_i = E(R_i) + \beta _i F + \epsilon _i$$, the APT model specified
as $$E(R_i) = \gamma _0 + \gamma _i\beta$$ is called the exact
APT model by Huberman and Wang (2017). Huberman (1982)
considers the representation
$$E(R_i) = \gamma _0 + \gamma _1\beta _i + \alpha _i$$, which
Huberman and Wang refer to as an approximate APT model. Here it is
assumed that $$\sum _{i = 1}^n\alpha _i = 0$$ and
$$\sum _{i = 1}^n\alpha _i\beta _i = 0$$. How can $$\alpha _i$$s
be interpreted in economic terms?
Problems
1. Consider the following APT model:
$$\begin{aligned} E(R_i) - R_f = \gamma _1\beta _{i,1} +
(7.15)
\gamma _2\beta _{i,2}. \end{aligned}$$
Suppose that the riskless rate $$R_f = 5\%$$, and we have the
following data for three stocks.
(a)
What are the risk premiums of the factors, i.e., $$\gamma _1$$
and $$\gamma _2$$?
(b)
What are the expected values of the factors?
(c)
What is the stock risk premium for each stock?
(d) What is $$\beta _{3,2}$$?
2.
Form the equal-weighted portfolio of the stocks in problem 1.
(a)
Compute $$\beta _{i,1}$$ and $$\beta _{i,2}$$ for the
portfolio.
(b)
Compute the expected return of the portfolio.
(c)
Compute the portfolio’s risk premium.
3.
Suppose the expected market return $$E(R_M)$$ equals $$8\%$$.
(a)
Compute CAPM betas for the stocks in problem 1.
(b)
Are the data in problem 1 consistent with both the CAPM and the
APT?
References
Chen, N.-F. 1983. Empirical tests of the theory of arbitrage pricing. Journal of Finance 38: 1393–
1414.
[Crossref]
Connor, G., and R. Korajzyck. 1985. Risk and return in equilibrium APT: Theory and tests. Banking
Research Center Working paper 129, Northwestern University.
Connor, G., and R. Korjzyck. 1986. Performance measurement with the arbitrage pricing theory.
Journal of Financial Economics 15: 373–394.
[Crossref]
Dhrymes, P., I. Friend, and N.B. Gultekin. 1984. A critical reexamination of the empirical evidence
on the arbitrage pricing theory. Journal of Finance 39: 703–738.
[Crossref]
Dybvig, P., and S.A. Ross. 1985. Yes, the APT is testable. Journal of Finance 40: 1173–1188.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and J.D. MacBeth. 1973. Risk, return, and equilibrium: Empirical tests. Journal of
Political Economy 38: 607–636.
[Crossref]
Huberman, G. 1982. A simple approach to arbitrage pricing theory. Journal of Economic Theory 28:
183–191.
[Crossref]
Huberman, G., and Z. Wang. 2017. Arbitrage pricing theory. In The New Palgrave Dictionary of
Economics, ed. M. Vernengo, E.P. Caldentey, and B.J. Rosser Jr. London, UK: Palgrave Macmillan.
Ingersoll, J.E. 1984. Some results in the theory of arbitrage pricing. Journal of Finance 39: 1021–
1039.
[Crossref]
Miller, M.H., and M. Scholes. 1972. Rates of return in relation to risk: A re-examination of recent
findings. In Studies in the Theory of Capital Markets, ed. M.C. Jensen. New York, NY: Praeger.
Roll, R., and S.A. Ross. 1980. An empirical investigation of the arbitrage pricing theory. Journal of
Finance 35: 1073–1103.
[Crossref]
Ross, S.A. 1971. The general validity of the mean variance approach in large markets. Discussion
paper no. 12–72. Rodney L, White Center for Financial Research, University of Pennsylvania.
Ross, S.A. 1974. Return, risk, and arbitrage. In Risk and Return in Finance, ed. I. Friend and J.
Bicksler. New York, NY: Heath Lexington.
Ross, S.A. 1976. The arbitrage theory of capital asset pricing. Journal of Economic Theory 13: 341–
360.
[Crossref]
Shanken, J. 1982. The arbitrage pricing theory: Is it testable? Journal of Finance 37: 1129–1140.
[Crossref]
Footnotes
1 See also Huberman (1982).
8. Multifactor Models
James W. Kolari1 and Seppo Pynnönen2
(1) Mays Business School, Texas A&M University, College Station, TX,
USA
(2) Departent of Mathematics and Statistics, University of Vaasa, Vaasa,
Finland
Seppo Pynnönen
Email: [email protected]
Supplementary Information
The online version contains supplementary material available at https://doi.
org/10.1007/978-3-031-16784-3_8
In 1990 William Sharpe was awarded the Nobel Prize in Economics for the
CAPM along with Harry Markowitz for portfolio diversification and
Merton Miller for corporate valuation.1 The Swedish industrialist Alfred
Nobel (inventor of dynamite) dedicated a foundation to recognize
discoveries that benefit humankind. The gold standard for intellectual
achievement, the Nobel Prize is conferred on a person after the true
significance of their discoveries, research, and writings are known. The
CAPM and mean-variance portfolio diversification had become the
centerpieces of modern finance.
Unfortunately, the leading role of the CAPM in asset pricing was cut
short by soon-to-be-published studies. In 1992 Fama and French published
the first in a series of papers that showed the CAPM did not work in the real
world. They documented extensive evidence that there was no relationship
between beta risk and average U.S. stock returns over long periods of time.
Upon reviewing their accumulating evidence in a number of papers, they
concluded that the CAPM was dead. In its place, they proposed a three-
factor model comprised of the market factor plus two factors based on the
firm characteristics of size (i.e., small and large firms) and book
equity/market equity ratios (i.e., value and growth firms). Their empirical
tests showed that this new multifactor model substantially improved the
goodness-of-fit of the CAPM to stock returns. Not surprisingly, some
degree of controversy was sparked by the three-factor model. In this chapter
we review the three-factor model and resultant controversy in the asset
pricing literature.
This table reports the average monthly returns (in percent) for U.S. stock
portfolios sorted into deciles by size and book-to-market equity (BM). Size
is measured by the market capitalization of stocks (i.e., stock price times
shares outstanding). The sample period is July 1963 to December 1990. The
selected results shown below are based on Fama and French (1992, Table V,
p. 446)
Next, the authors ran formal statistical tests using Fama and
MacBeth (1973) cross-sectional regressions using different models. The
time-series models contained a number of variables, including the market
factor, size, BM, leverage, and the earnings/price ratio. The market price of
risk for CAPM beta ( $$\lambda _m$$) was insignificant. However,
the market prices of beta coefficients associated with size and BM (or
loadings) were very significant. Their market prices were −0.15% and
0.50% per month with significant t-statistics equal to −2.58 and 5.71,
respectively. These results confirmed that bigger stocks have lower returns
than smaller stocks (i.e., the negative price of risk), and that high BM
(value) stocks have higher returns than lower BM (growth) stocks (i.e.,
positive price of risk). Also, loadings for leverage and the earnings/price
ratio were not significant when size and BM beta loadings were included in
the model. Therefore, they inferred that these firm characteristics were
absorbed (or accounted for) by the size and BM variables. From these
findings, the authors concluded that size and BM beta risk loadings help to
explain stock returns but not CAPM beta. In their final remarks, concerning
the CAPM, they commented:
Black et al. (1972) and Fama and MacBeth (1973) find that, as
predicted by the model, there is a positive simple relation between
average return and market $$\beta$$ during the years (1926-1968)
... we find that this simple relation between $$\beta$$ and average
return disappears during the more recent 1963-1990 period. (Fama
and French 1992, p. 449)
Fig. 8.1 Stocks are sorted into a 2 $$\times$$ 3 matrix by size and value (BM). The size factor is
the average returns of the three small (blue) portfolios minus the three (red) big portfolios, and the
value factor is average returns of the two value (green) portfolios minus the two growth (brown)
portfolios
Fig. 8.2 The Fama and French three-factor model with excess returns a function of market, size, and
value factors takes into account four dimensions in return/risk space
This table reports the $$R^2$$ estimates for the CAPM and Fama and
French three-factor model using U.S. stock portfolios sorted into quintiles
by size and book-to-market equity (BM). Size is measured by the market
capitalization of stocks (i.e., stock price times shares outstanding). The
sample period is July 1963 to December 1991. The selected results shown
below are based on Fama and French (1993, Tables 4 and 6, pp. 20 and 24)
This table reports the monthly $$\alpha$$ estimates (in percent) for the
CAPM and Fama and French three-factor model using U.S. stock portfolios
sorted into quintiles by size and book-to-market equity (BM). Size is
measured by the market capitalization of stocks (i.e., stock price times
shares outstanding). The sample period is July 1963 to December 1991. The
selected results shown below are based on Fama and French (1993, Table
9a, pp. 36–37)
Note Asterisks indicate that the $$\alpha$$ estimate is statistically
different from zero at the *−10%, **−5%, and ***−1% levels
In Panel A of Table 8.3, we see the results for the CAPM. The
$$\alpha$$ estimates for the portfolios using the market factor alone
produced positive and significant intercepts. For example, the small size
quintile and high BM quintile portfolio has a monthly $$\alpha$$
equal to 0.92%, which is highly significant at the 1% level and therefore
different from zero. This $$\alpha$$ corresponds to a very large
mispricing error of about 11% per year. Except for low BM (growth) stocks,
the $$\alpha$$ estimates for most portfolios are significantly greater
than zero. When they repeated these tests using only the SMB and HML
factors in a two-factor model, the $$\alpha$$ estimates were again
very positive and significant with a high of 0.79% per month, or about 9.5%
per year.
In stark contrast to the CAPM and two-factor model with size and value
factors, as shown in Panel B of Table 8.3, upon combining the market factor
with SMB and HML factors in the three-factor model, the intercepts became
close to zero. With the exception of only 3-out-of-25 portfolios, the
intercepts were not significantly different from zero. These results strongly
support the three-factor model.
The bond factors TERM and DEF did not further reduce the intercepts
for stock portfolios but did so for bond portfolios. Based on these and other
tests, Fama and French (1993, p. 41) inferred that “... the three-factor
model does a good job on the cross-section of average stock returns.” They
interpreted the size and value factors as proxies for risk factors associated
with these firm-level characteristics (akin to the CRSP excess return serving
as a proxy for the true market factor in the CAPM).
In their paper Fama and French conjectured that Merton’s (1973)
ICAPM and Ross’ (1976) APT provided some theoretical support for their
three-factor model. Recall that these theoretical models proposed multiple
risk factors to price assets in equilibrium. In this regard, the three-factor
model is mainly justified on empirical grounds—that is, it noticeably
improves the goodness-of-fit to stock return data compared to the CAPM.
In their paper entitled “The CAPM is Wanted, Dead or Alive,” Fama and
French (1996) argued that the failures of the CAPM to explain expected
returns motivate the investigation of return anomalies which can be taken
into account by multifactor ICAPM and APT models. In their view, the
CAPM was dead.
Summarizing their new long/short zero-investment portfolio,
multifactor model approach to asset pricing, Fama and French were mindful
of the questions left unanswered. In their words,
... our work leaves many open questions. Most glaring, we have not
shown how the size and book-to-market factors in returns are driven
by the stochastic behavior of earnings ... Can specific fundamentals
be identified as variables that lead to common variation in returns
that is independent of the market and carries a different premium
than general market risk? These and other interesting questions are
left for future work. (Fama and French 1993, p. 55)
Returning to the above question of the role of earnings, Fama and French
(1996) published another paper in which they considered the following dual
hypotheses: (1) size and value factors are related to some common factor;
and (2) size and value patterns are related to the behavior of earnings which
affects stock prices. They contended that high BM (value) ratios with low
relative stock prices signal low earnings and possible financial distress, and
vice versa for low BM (growth) ratios with high relative stock prices.
Moreover, holding BM constant, small companies tend to have lower
earnings than big companies. While it is possible that small companies’
earnings fluctuate with the business cycle and exceed those of big
companies at times, in the long run small companies underperform big
companies in terms of profits over time.
To investigate these dual research hypotheses, Fama and French
collected data on size, BM, earnings, and stock returns for U.S. companies
in the period 1963 to 1992. Using simple descriptive analyses, they
documented that size and BM factors based on companies’ earnings were
similar to those computed using stock returns. In other words, common
factors in earnings and returns were found. However, while market and size
factors in earnings were linked to the market and size factors in returns, the
BM factor in returns did not appear to be closely associated with the BM
factors in earnings. Contrary to their hypothesis, equity returns were not
related to the BM factor in earnings.
In sum, there is some evidence to support the notion that common
variations in returns are related to common factors in earnings. As such,
they concluded by posing the following questions for future research:
(i) What are the underlying state variables that produce variation in
earnings and returns related to size and BE/ME?
(ii) Do these unnamed state variables produce variation in
consumption and wealth that is not captured by the overall market
factor and so can explain the risk premiums associated with size and
BE/ME? (Fama and French 1996, p. 154)
8.4 Summary
After extensive tests using U.S. stock returns over many years, Fama and
French (1996) declared the CAPM dead. Little or no relation between U.S.
stock returns and beta risk led them to propose a new multifactor model. In
their papers, Fama and French (1992, 1993, 1995, 1996) introduced a three-
factor model, which proved to boost the empirical fit to stock returns of the
CAPM’s market factor by using the firm characteristics of size and value
(i.e., book-to-market equity ratios denoted BM). A major innovation
consistent with Ross’ (1976) APT was the construction of long/short zero-
investment factors—for example, long small stocks and short big stocks as
well as long high BM stocks and short low BM stocks. These so-called size
and value factors in combination with the market factor substantially
lowered intercept ( $$\alpha$$) estimates that reflect mispricing in the
time-series regression estimation of asset pricing models. Related loosely to
the theoretical ICAPM and APT models of Merton (1973) and Ross (1976),
respectively, the three-factor model is foundational in the evolution of asset
pricing. In an effort to link their three-factor model to economic
fundamentals, they showed that the size and value factors in stock returns
have some relationship to size and value factors in firm earnings. However,
the identification of ICAPM and APT state variables that drive the linkage
between size plus BM firm characteristics and returns/earnings was left an
unanswered question for future research.
Controversy surrounding the three-factor model started with
Black’s (1993) criticism that it was a product of data mining rather than
theory. While it improved the empirical fit of the CAPM to stock return
data, the state variables underlying the size and value factors were
unknown. Also, Black (1995) reasoned that, given positive expected excess
returns in the market over time, if the return/beta relation is flat, then the
zero-beta factor from his zero-beta CAPM must be large to explain market
returns. The size and value factors were not always present in different
sample periods and, more importantly, lacked theory. A well-known study
by Kothari et al. (1995) found evidence that annual stock returns over long
periods of time were consistent with a linear relation between market beta
and the cross-section of average stock returns. Fama and French (1996)
countered that the CAPM failed in some periods but worked in others; in
both cases, the size and value factors boosted the explanatory power of the
CAPM. Kothari et al. also argued that the value factor did not work well
with industry portfolios and that survivor bias exists among high book-to-
market equity ratio firms that are distressed and can drop out of data
samples in some time periods. Relatedly, some researchers have cited an
endogeneity problem wherein the test asset portfolios’ returns (i.e., the
dependent variable in an asset pricing model) are closely related by
construction to the factors (i.e, the independent variables in a model).
Naturally the model would fit this data quite well. Hence, Lewellen et al.
(2010), Daniel and Titman (2012), and others have recommended that other
test assets portfolios exogenous to the factors should be used to investigate
the validity of an asset pricing model. Industry portfolios were believed to
be good exogenous portfolios.
Fama and French (1996, 2004) defended the three-factor model due to
the failure of the CAPM. According to their logic, the market portfolio is
not efficient which means the CAPM is dead. Two possibilities help to
explain this failure: (1) other factors exist as theorized by the ICAPM and
APT; and (2) investors can be irrational at times that causes anomalies in
asset returns unrelated to risk as proposed by the behavioral school. The
ensuing search for multifactors and anomalies in stock returns triggered a
revolution in asset pricing that continues today. As we will see in
forthcoming Chapter 9, many new long/short factors have been proposed by
researchers that go well beyond the prototypical three-factor model.
Questions
1. If CAPM beta does not explain stock returns, what does? In this
regard, Fama and French (1992) found that stock returns were related
to two firm characteristics. What are these characteristics and briefly
discuss what they found.
2.
Fama and French (1993) used the size and BM variables to construct
zero-investment factors. Define these factors and write the equation
for their resultant three-factor model. What are the multifactors in this
model?
3.
Fama and French (1993) conducted tests of their proposed three-factor
model. What were the test asset portfolios? What did they find?
Discuss the results for estimated beta coefficients and goodness-of-fit
of their model.
4.
How did Fama and French (1993) cross-sectionally test the three-
factor model? What did they find in test results?
5.
Fama and French (1993) specified and tested a bond model. What did
their results show?
6.
If the CAPM is dead, and asset prices are better explained by multiple
factors, what theoretical support for multifactor models exists?
7.
Fama and French (1996) argued that size and value factors are linked
to economic fundamentals such as earnings within the firm. What
were their arguments in this regard?
8.
Did Fama and French (1996) find evidence to support a link between
earnings and the size and value factors? Review their findings. What
are the underlying state variables that produce variation in earnings
and stock returns related to size and BM ratios?
9.
Controversy surrounded the three-factor model due to skepticism by
researchers. Black (1993, 1995) said that the model had two problems.
Discuss these two potential problems.
10.
Kothari, Shanken, and Sloan (1995) found evidence to support the
CAPM. Also, they criticized the Fama and French studies. Review
these issues in their study.
11. What is a possible endogeneity problem in the Fama and French asset
pricing tests of the three-factor model? How can we reduce this
bl i t i i t t?
problem in asset pricing tests?
12.
How did Fama and French (1996) counter criticisms of their three-
factor model? Do you think that multifactor models are needed to
more fully price assets or are investors irrational leading to anomalous
returns in the market not explained by the CAPM market factor?
Problems
1.
Assume that stocks are sorted into a 2 $$\times$$3 matrix of size and
value (BM). How did Fama and French (1993) use this matrix to create
their size and value factors?
2.
Draw a diagram that depicts Fama and French’s three-factor model.
How many dimensions are there in your drawing?
References
Banz, R.W. 1981. The relationship between return and market value of common stocks. Journal of
Financial Economics 9: 3–18.
[Crossref]
Basu, S. 1977. Investment performance of common stocks in relation to their price-earnings ratios: A
test of the efficient market hypothesis. Journal of Finance 12: 129–156.
Bhandari, L.C. 1988. Debt/equity ratio and expected common stock returns: Empirical evidence.
Journal of Finance 43: 507–528.
[Crossref]
Black, F. 1972. Capital market equilibrium with restricted borrowing. Journal of Business 45: 444–
454.
[Crossref]
Black, F. 1993. Beta and return. Journal of Portfolio Management 20: 8–18.
[Crossref]
Black, F. 1995. Estimating expected return. Financial Analysts Journal 49: 36–38.
[Crossref]
Black, F., M.C. Jensen, and M. Scholes. 1972. The capital asset pricing model: Some empirical tests.
In Studies in the Theory of Capital Markets, ed. M.C. Jensen. New York, NY: Praeger.
Clare, A.D., R. Priestley, and S.H. Thomas. 1998. Reports of beta’s death are premature: Evidence
from the UK. Journal of Banking and Finance 22: 1207–1229.
[Crossref]
Daniel, K., and S. Titman. 2012. Testing factor-model explanations of market anomalies. Critical
Finance Review 1: 103–139.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 1992. The cross-section of expected stock returns. Journal of Finance
47: 427–465.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 1993. The cross-section of expected returns. Journal of Financial
Economics 33: 3–56.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 1995. Size and book-to-market factors in earnings and returns. Journal
of Finance 50: 131–156.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 1996. The CAPM is wanted, dead or alive. Journal of Finance 51:
1947–1958.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 1998. Value versus growth: The international evidence. Journal of
Finance 53: 1975–1999.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 2004. The capital asset pricing model: Theory and evidence. Journal of
Economic Perspectives 18: 25–46.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and J.D. MacBeth. 1973. Risk, return, and equilibrium: Empirical tests. Journal of
Political Economy 81: 607–636.
[Crossref]
Gibbons, M.R., S.A. Ross, and J. Shanken. 1989. A test of the efficiency of a given portfolio.
Econometrica 57: 1121–1152.
[Crossref]
Gordon, M.J. 1962. The Investment, Financing, and Valuation of the Corporation. Homewood, IL:
R.D Irwin.
Hsia, C.-C., B.R. Fuller, and B.Y.J. Chen. 2000. Is beta dead or alive? Journal of Business Finance
and Accounting 27: 283–311.
[Crossref]
Jagannathan, R., and E.R. McGrattan. 1995. The CAPM debate. Quarterly Review 19 (4, Fall): 2–17.
Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.
Kolari, J.W., W. Liu, and J. Huang. 2021. A New Capital Asset Pricing Model: Theory and Evidence.
New York, NY: Palgrave Macmillan.
[Crossref]
Kothari, S.P., J. Shanken, and R.G. Sloan. 1995. Another look at the cross-section of expected stock
returns. Journal of Finance 50: 185–224.
[Crossref]
Lakonishok, J., and A.C. Shapiro. 1986. Systematic risk, total risk, and size as determinants of stock
market returns. Journal of Banking and Finance 10: 115–132.
[Crossref]
Lakonishok, J., and A. Shleifer. 1984. Stock returns, beta, variance and size: An empirical analysis.
Financial Analysts Journal 40: 36–41.
[Crossref]
Lewellen, J., S. Nagel, and J.A. Shanken. 2010. A skeptical appraisal of asset pricing tests. Journal
of Financial Economics 96: 175–194.
[Crossref]
Lintner, J. 1965. The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock portfolios
and capital budgets. Review of Economics and Statistics 47: 13–37.
[Crossref]
Markowitz, H.M. 1959. Portfolio selection: Efficient diversification of investments. New York, NY:
Wiley.
Merton, R.C. 1973. An intertemporal capital asset pricing model. Econometrica 41: 867–887.
[Crossref]
Modigliani, F., and M.H. Miller. 1958. The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of
investment. American Economic Review 48: 261–297.
Modigliani, F., and M.H. Miller. 1963. Corporation income taxes and the cost of capital: A
correction. American Economic Review 53: 433–443.
Roll, R. 1977. A critique of the asset pricing theory’s tests, part I: On past and potential future
testability of the theory. Journal of Financial Economics 4: 129–176.
[Crossref]
Rosenberg, B., K. Reid, and R. Lanstein. 1985. Persuasive evidence of market inefficiency. Journal
of Portfolio Management 11: 9–17.
[Crossref]
Ross, S.A. 1976. The arbitrage theory of capital asset pricing. Journal of Economic Theory 13: 341–
360.
[Crossref]
Sharpe, W.F. 1964. Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk.
Journal of Finance 19: 425–442.
Statman, D. 1980. Book values and stock returns. The Chicago MBA: A Journal of Selected Papers
4: 25–45.
Treynor, J. L. 1961. Market value, time, and risk. Unpublished manuscript.
Treynor, J. L. 1962. Toward a theory of market value of risky assets. Unpublished manuscript.
Footnotes
1 See their original works, especially Sharpe (1964), Markowitz (1959), and Modigliani and Miller
(1958, 1963). With respect to the CAPM, both Lintner (1965) and Mossin (1966) had died by 1990
and Treynor (1961, 1962) had not never published his CAPM papers, such that these authors were
not eligible for the prize.
2 See Basu (1977), Lakonishok and Shapiro (1986), and Bhandari (1988). Fama and French (2004)
have provided an excellent survey of the CAPM and these contradictory studies.
4 In Chapter 10 we cover the ZCAPM of Kolari et al. (2021), which is based on Black’s (1972) zero-
beta CAPM. Consistent with Black’s (1995) comments about a large second factor, empirical tests of
the ZCAPM have revealed a highly significant, large second factor (viz.,cross-sectional returncross-
sectional return dispersion in the market).
5 See also Hsia et al. (2000), who used annual returns to compute moving-average betas and better
take into market anomalies. Their results supported a positive relation between average returns and
beta risk also. Additionally, a study of U.K. stock market returns by Clare et al. (1998) found that the
beta was not dead. Using a somewhat different method of estimating the cross-sectional relation
between expected returns and factor loadings, market beta risk was significantly priced in their tests.
However, their study only employed 100 U.K. stocks with data available from 1980 to 1993. Thus,
their results were somewhat limited in scope.
6 In time-series regressions of the three-factor model, information in the size and value test asset
portfolios (and even residual errors for these portfolios) will naturally have information related to the
size and value factors. In this respect, recall from Chapter 4’s discussion of the market model and
underlying statistical assumptions, the error terms should be uncorrelated with the independent
variables.
© The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2023
J. W. Kolari, S. Pynnönen, Investment Valuation and Asset Pricing
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-16784-3_9
Seppo Pynnönen
Email: [email protected]
Supplementary Information
The online version contains supplementary material available at https://doi.
org/10.1007/978-3-031-16784-3_9
Fama and French (1992, 1993, 1995, 1996) published a series of papers in
the 1990s that replaced the CAPM with a three-factor model containing size
and value factors. Their innovative long/short zero-investment factors based
on firm characteristics of size and book-to-market equity ratios sparked a
revolution in asset pricing. Loosely grounded in Merton’s (1972) ICAPM
and Ross’ APT (1976) theoretical multifactor asset pricing models, the
three-factor model became the foundation for many new factors and models
that continue to be proposed by researchers.
In this chapter we highlight some of the most popular multifactor
models in the field of asset pricing. Carhart (1997) added a momentum
factor to create a four-factor model for studying mutual fund performance.
Fama and French (2015, 2018) extended their three-factor to five- and six-
factor models. Other researchers, such as Hou et al. (2015) as well
as Stambaugh and Yuan (2017) proposed alternative four-factor models. In
a major departure from previous multifactor models, Fama and French
(2020), Lettau and Pelger (2020), and others began using machine learning
and artificial intelligence (AI) to create multifactors driven by stock return
data instead of researcher judgment. In general, asset pricing models can be
classified into those based on theoretical, discretionary, and machine
learning methods. Due to the increasing diversity of asset pricing models, a
new problem has arisen. Cochrane (2011), a factor zoo exists with hundreds
of different factors. Which factors should be used? Which combinations of
factors yield the best model? These questions are new challenges facing the
field of asset pricing.
Fig. 9.1 Momentum factor returns are long/short zero-investment portfolio returns
(1)
Avoid funds with persistently poor performance;
(2)
funds with high returns last year have higher-than-average
expected returns next year, but not in years thereafter; and
(3)
the investment costs of expense ratios, transactions costs, and
load fees all have a direct, negative impact on mutual fund
performance.
This table reports selected results from Carhart (1997). Based on the
returns of U.S. equity mutual funds, mispricing error is regressed on
different operating characteristics of mutual funds. The dependent
variable in these time-series regressions is monthly mispricing error or
$$\alpha$$ on an out-of-sample basis. More specifically, the four-factor
model is estimated for a mutual fund using three previous years of monthly
returns. Alpha is estimated in the next month using the factor loadings of
the model from the previous three years multiplied by the four factors in the
next month. This out-of-sample monthly alpha is regressed on mutual fund
characteristics. The average results for over 1,800 mutual funds are shown
in the table by mutual fund returns sorted into deciles from high to low
returns. The results shown below are based on Carhart (1997, Table IV, p.
66)
The portfolios of small and big stocks in the lowest B/M quartile
and highest Inv (growth stocks that invest a lot) produce intercepts
more than 3.5 standard errors from zero but of opposite sign –
(-0.20% per month, $$t = -4.18$$) for small stocks and positive
(0.37%, $$t = 5.39$$) for big stocks.
Hence, these portfolios are not priced by their four-factor model, which
suggests that a missing factor is needed to price these test assets.
This table reports selected results from Stambaugh and Yuan (2017). Based
on U.S. stock returns, monthly $$\alpha$$ estimates (in percent) are
shown. These mispricing errors are estimated for the following models:
Fama and French three- and five-factor models, Hou, Xue, and Zhang four-
factor q model, and Stambaug and Yuan four-factor model. The sample
period is January 1967–December 2013. Anomaly returns are long-short
portfolio returns using high and low decile returns. The results shown
below are based on Stambaugh and Yuan (2017, Table 4, p. 1287)
Note Asterisks indicate that the $$\alpha$$ estimate is statistically
different from zero at the
* = 10%, ** = 5%, and *** = 1% levels
Using the sample period 1967–2013 and U.S. stock returns, they tested
alternative models using the anomalies in Hou et al. (2015). Table 9.2
shows some selected results from their study. In the left-hand column of
numbers, the table gives the average anomaly return computed as long
minus short portfolio returns using high and low decile returns for each
anomaly. They compared the multifactor model in Eq. (9.6) with the Fama
and French three- and four-factor models and Hou, Xue, and Zhang four-
factor q-factor model. Notice that estimated alphas ( $$\alpha _i$$s)
tend to be lower in magnitude and significance (indicated by asterisks) for
the Hou, Xue, and Zhang q-factor model as well as Stambaugh and
Yuan four-factor models compared to the Fama and French three- and four-
factor models. Also, comparing the four-factor models in the last two
columns, their performance is somewhat similar, but the Stambaugh and
Yuan model outperforms the q-factor model in terms of smaller and less
significant mispricing error.
The authors reported further evidence that their four-factor model did a
better job of pricing factors in the other models. That is, they used the
factors in other models as anomaly portfolios or test assets. In view of these
and other tests, they concluded that, instead of constructing each factor
from a single anomaly, multifactor models can be improved by developing
factors from multiple anomalies. In this way each factor has a broader
ability to price a wider array of stocks manifesting different anomalies. This
innovative multifactor approach has the advantage of reducing the number
of factors in asset pricing models. With so many factors being proposed by
researchers that are associated with different anomalies, Stambaugh and
Yuan (2017, p. 1307) observed:
In other words, the cross-section factors did not improve their original time-
series models enough to warrant their use. However, using cross-section
factors in combination with firm characteristics (or accounting variables) in
the conditional mathematical model improved upon time-series models
using researcher definitions of factors based on firm characteristics as in
their original models.
A drawback of the conditional mathematical model is that no out-of-
sample Fama and MacBeth tests are possible. The intercept tests performed
in their study are entirely in-sample tests. Simin (2008) has argued that step
ahead (e.g., one-month-ahead that are out-of-sample) Fama and MacBeth
tests avoid a number of model evaluation problems, such as data snooping.
Also, Ferson et al. (2013) have recommended that the practical value of
asset pricing models should be evaluated based on out-of-sample tests.
An important point here is that model tests should be investable. For
example, an investor picks stocks based on the estimation of their risk and
then subsequently tracks their return performance in the future. Fama–
MacBeth tests first estimate model parameters from available historical
data. In the second step, returns in the next (out-of-sample) month are
regressed on previously estimated parameters (beta loadings). There is no
possibility of cheating in this setup. The model that performs best in the
second step dominates the other models. Note that some researchers use an
in-sample Fama–MacBeth approach. Model parameters are estimated with
monthly returns over many years in a sample period. Then returns in each
month within the sample period are regressed on the model parameters in
the second step. But this method is not investable. Investors could not rely
on this kind of analysis to guide them concerning the relation between past
risk and future returns. They want models that give estimates of risk
parameters that are related to returns in the future rather than the past. The
Fama and French conditional mathematical model (using time-varying firm
characteristics as risk loadings and cross-section factors) proved itself to be
a dominant model using in-sample tests. However, out-of-sample tests are
needed to assess its practical use as an investable strategy.
9.7 Lettau and Pelger Latent Five-Factor Model
In light of the growing number of possible factors in asset pricing models,
Lettau and Pelger (2020) proposed a method for finding the most important
factors. Their method identifies latent asset pricing factors using Principal
Component Analysis (PCA). PCA is a statistical method that can reduce the
information contained in sample observations (e.g., stock portfolios’
returns) into a select few components that summarize all of the sample
information.
Each factor in an asset pricing model can be considered a risk
dimension. The CAPM is a single risk dimension (market factor) model.
The three-factor Fama and French model has three-dimensional risk. If say
50 different stocks are input into a PCA (i.e., we start with 50 dimensions),
the PCA seeks to reduce the dimensions down to a smaller set that explains
the data. In this way PCA is very similar to factor analysis covered in
Chapter 7’s discussion of empirical tests of Ross’ (1976) APT. It is
reasonable to believe that some of the stocks’ returns are correlated with
one another. For example, 10 stocks’ returns could be highly correlated and
therefore are combined into one dimension. The first dimension in PCA has
higher explanatory power in terms of stock returns than other dimensions.
In their study, they found that stock returns could be explained by a five-
dimensional space. The sixth dimension and higher dimensions were
dropped because they did not significantly help to explain the data
observations (or stock returns).
Since the dimensions are not readily observable, they are referred to as
latent or hidden. Each component is constructed by PCA to be orthogonal
(or uncorrelated) with other components. For this reason, PCA has some
connection to the intertemporal CAPM (ICAPM) of Merton (1972) and
arbitrage pricing theory (APT) of Ross (1976) which assume orthogonal
asset pricing factors.
PCA is a machine learning technique that has been applied in many
fields of study, including finance and economics. Rather than use researcher
judgment to form factors, computer algorithms within the PCA software let
the data select the factors based on correlation patterns in stock returns. In
Fama and French’s (2020) study of cross-section factors, they let the data
compute these factors from cross-sectional regressions. PCA is another
example of machine learning in factor construction. According to Lettau
and Pelger, PCA analyses yielded five systematic factors.
In the sample period 1963–2017, the authors gathered U.S. stock returns
for 370 portfolios sorted on size, BM, accruals, investment, profitability,
momentum, volatility measures, and other characteristics of firms. In-
sample intercept ( $$\alpha _i$$) tests of mispricing errors were
performed on different models. Some out-of-sample intercept tests were
conducted also (i.e., factor loadings were estimated and then average
pricing errors were computed in the step ahead period).
Table 9.3 Mispricing error of different models in the Lettau and Pelger (2020) study
This table reports selected results of mispricing error tests in Lettau and
Pelger (2020). Average mispricing error is measured by the root mean
square of alpha pricing error computed as follows:
$$RMS _\alpha =(\hat{\alpha }^{T}\hat{\alpha }/N)^{1/2}$$, where
$$\alpha$$ is mispricing error for T months, and N is the number of
portfolios or stocks. There are four models: the Lettau-Pelgar five-factor
PCA model, five-factor PCA model based on previous methods, and Fama
and French three- and five-factor models. In-sample and out-of-sample
$$RMA_\alpha$$ estimates are shown for 370 stock portfolios and 270
individual stocks. The sample period is from November 1963 to December
2017 ( $$T=650$$). The results shown below are based on Lettau and
Pelger (2020, Table 2, p. 2297)
Fig. 9.2 Multifactor models extensions of the original Fama and French three-factor model using
discretionary methods
Fig. 9.3 Machine learning methods based on artificial intelligence (AI) models rather than human
judgment
9.9 Summary
After extensive tests using U.S. stock returns over many years, Fama and
French (1996) declared the CAPM dead. Little or no relation between U.S.
stock returns and beta risk led them to propose new multifactor models. In
their papers, Fama and French (1992, 1993, 1995, 1996) introduced a three-
factor model, which proved to boost the empirical fit to stock returns of the
CAPM’s market factor by using the firm characteristics of size and value
(i.e., book-to-market equity ratios denoted BM). A major innovation was
the construction of long/short zero-investment factors—for example, long
small stocks and short big stocks as well as long high BM stocks and short
low BM stocks. These so-called multifactors triggered a revolution in asset
pricing.
The multifactor movement resulted in many new long/short factors
proposed by researchers. Carhart (1997) added a momentum factor to the
three-factor model to make a four-factor model. The momentum factor is
long stocks with high past returns in the last year and short stocks with low
past returns. This new factor was helpful in explaining the returns on
mutual funds, which are portfolios of securities. Practical implications for
investment were gained, such as to buy funds with higher-than-average
performance in the recent past. Also, buy passively managed index funds
rather than actively managed funds with higher operating expenses. Fama
and French (2015) augmented their three-factor model with two more
factors—namely, profit and capital investment factors—to make a five-
factor model. These additional long/short factors further boosted the
empirical fit and suggested that the value factor could be dropped.
Other researchers began to enter the multifactor competition. Hou et al.
(2015) advanced a four-factor model with the market factor plus new size,
profit, and capital investment factors. They linked their model to production
CAPM models by means of the q-theory of investment. According to this
theory, firms with high investments and profits should tend to earn higher
stock returns, and vice versa for those with low investments and profits.
They found that their model helped to explain 80 anomalies, most of which
were based on different firm characteristics. In this respect, their model
outperformed the Fama and French three-factor and Carhart four-factor
models. They inferred that many of these anomalies in stock returns were
effectively explained by investment and profit factors. Another study by
Stambaugh and Yuan (2017) proposed an alternative four-factor
model containing market and size factors plus management and
performance mispricing factors. To construct their two mispricing factors,
they formed two clusters of a number of anomalies and then computed
long/short factors from them. Their model was able to do a good job of
explaining 80 different anomalies and exceeded the performance of the
Fama and French five-factor model and Hou, Xue, and Zhang four-factor
model. Hence, an effective way to construct a parsimonious set of factors is
from the anomalies themselves.
Extending their previous work, Fama and French (2018) put forward a
six-factor model that added momentum to their five-factor model. In this
model they defined long/short factors in different ways to test a variety of
size, value, profit, capital investment, and momentum factors. The winner
model contained market and size factors plus small stock factors for size,
value, capital investment, and momentum. In a related paper, Fama and
French (2020) proposed the use of cross-section factors that are estimated
from cross-sectional market prices of risk. That is, in the second step of
the Fama and MacBeth (1973) procedure to test a model, the cross-
sectional regression produces $$\lambda _k$$ estimates associated
with the factor loadings for k factors. These $$\lambda _k$$s are
mimicking portfolio returns dubbed cross-section factors that were
substituted into their five- or six-factor models in place of the original
factors. Another innovation was to specify a conditional mathematical
model with time-varying firm characteristics as the loadings on the cross-
section factors in a mathematical conditional model. This mathematical
model outperformed the regression models tested in their study. In effect,
cross-section factors use machine learning instead of researcher judgment to
design factors.
In another recent study using machine learning, Lettau and Pelger
(2020) applied Principal Components Analysis (PCA) to search for
correlation patterns in stock returns that represent so-called latent factors.
They found that five latent factors were suggested by five-dimensional risk
patterns in stock returns. The first factor was highly correlated with the
CRSP market index, and other factors were related to value and momentum
factors. Tests with stock portfolios associated with well-known asset pricing
anomalies, including size, BM, investments, profitability, momentum, and
others, showed that their five-factor model had small mispricing errors (or
$$\alpha _i$$s) and therefore explained stock returns.
In sum, theoretical methods led to the creation of the CAPM, its
companion models, and the APT. Over time, these models were supplanted
by better fitting models based on discretionary methods that emphasized
researcher judgment, including the three-, four-, five-, and six-factor
models. Researchers constructed various long/short zero-investment
portfolios as multifactors that were added to the CAPM market factor. More
recently, machine learning methods have been proposed that produce
factors based on artificial intelligence (AI). Cross-section and latent
factors employ statistical and computer algorithms to form factors. In this
man versus machine battle, who will win? Will some hybrid approach
emerge in the future? As we will see in the next chapter, an unlikely
outcome may be a return to theoretical methods with a new model dubbed
the ZCAPM.
Questions
1.
What is momentum in asset returns? Can it be used to construct a
long/short factor? How did Carhart (1997) modify the three-factor
model to take into account momentum?
2.
In Carhart’s (1997) empirical tests, did momentum affect stock returns
of mutual funds? What practical advice to investors in mutual funds
did his research reveal?
3.
Fama and French (2015) built upon their three-factor model to
develop a five-factor model. What motivated them to add two more
factors to their model? Write their five-factor model.
4.
Fama and French (2015) tested their five-factor model in the sample
period 1963–2013. What test asset portfolios did they use? Was the
five-factor model supported?
5.
Hou et al. (2015) developed a model that is very close to the Fama
and French four-factor model. Write the equation for their model.
What is the theoretical foundation for their model? What did they use
as the test assets to empirically test their model? What did they find?
6.
Stambaugh and Yuan (2017) developed a four-factor model. They
added two new factors to the market and size factors. How did they
construct these new factors? In empirical tests of over 80 anomalies,
what did they find? They also created a three-factor model. How did
this model perform?
7. Write the Fama and French (2018) six-factor model. They expanded
this model to include different variations of these factors for a total of
this model to include different variations of these factors for a total of
48 factors. Which model worked the best?
8.
More recently, Fama and French (2020) proposed a modified version
of their five-factor model in which the multifactors are replaced by
long/short mimicking portfolios estimated from a cross-sectional
regression. What is the two-step process they implemented to do this?
9.
Fama and French (2020) proposed two additional models that allow
for time-varying risk parameters. Write the equations for these two
conditional models. In empirical tests, which model was the best one?
In these tests, how did they test one of the models that had no
intercept (mispricing $$\alpha$$) term?
10.
Normally, joint tests that the intercepts ( $$\alpha _i$$s) equal zero
are in-sample tests. What is a criticism of this testing approach?
11.
Lettau and Pelger (2020) proposed the use of Principal Component
Analysis (PCA) to identify latent asset pricing factors. How does PCA
find factors in stock returns? How many latent factors did they find in
empirical tests? Are PCA latent factors related to traditional factors
used in asset pricing models?
12.
Distinguish between theoretical methods, discretionary methods, and
machine learning methods of developing asset pricing models. What
are examples of each of these methods?
Problems
1.
Draw a diagram of returns on the Y-axis and time in months over the
past year on the X-axis. Using this diagram, illustrate how momentum
portfolios are formed.
2.
Draw a diagram comparing the machine learning methods of Fama and
French’s (2020) cross-section factors and Lettau and Pilger’s (2020)
latent factors.
References
Back, K., N. Kapadia, and B. Ostdiek. 2013. Slopes as factors: Characteristic pure plays. Working
paper, Rice University.
Back, K., N. Kapadia, and B. Ostdiek. 2015. Testing factor models on characteristic and covariance
pure plays. Working paper, Rice University.
Barillas, F., and J. Shanken. 2018. Comparing asset pricing models. Journal of Finance 73: 715–754.
Barroso, P., and P. Santa-Clara. 2015. Momentum has its moments. Journal of Financial Economics
116: 111–120.
[Crossref]
Carhart, M.M. 1997. On persistence in mutual fund performance. Journal of Finance 52: 57–82.
[Crossref]
Cochrane, J.H. 1991. Production-based asset pricing and the link between stock returns and
economic fluctuations. Journal of Finance 46: 209–237.
[Crossref]
Cochrane, J.H. 2011. Presidential address: Discount rates. Journal of Finance 56: 1047–1108.
[Crossref]
Daniel, K., and T. Moskowitz. 2016. Momentum crashes. Journal of Financial Economics 122: 221–
247.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and J.D. MacBeth. 1973. Risk, return, and equilibrium: Empirical tests. Journal of
Political Economy 81: 607–636.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 1992. The cross-section of expected stock returns. Journal of Finance
47: 427–465.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 1993. The cross-section of expected returns. Journal of Financial
Economics 33: 3–56.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 1995. Size and book-to-market factors in earnings and returns. Journal
of Finance 50: 131–156.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 1996. The CAPM is wanted, dead or alive. Journal of Finance 51:
1947–1958.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 2015. A five-factor asset pricing model. Journal of Financial
Economics 116: 1–22.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 2018. Choosing factors. Journal of Financial Economics 128: 234–252.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 2020. Comparing cross-section and time-series factor models. Review
of Financial Studies 33: 1892–1926.
[Crossref]
Ferson, W.E. 2019. Empirical Asset Pricing: Models and Methods. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.
Ferson, W.E., S.K. Nallareddy, and B. Xie. 2013. The “out-of-sample” performance of long-run risk
models. Journal of Financial Economics 107: 537–556.
[Crossref]
Gibbons, M.R., S.A. Ross, and J. Shanken. 1989. A test of the efficiency of a given portfolio.
Econometrica 57: 1121–1152.
[Crossref]
Gordon, M.J. 1962. The Investment, Financing, and Valuation of the Corporation. Homewood, IL:
R.D. Irwin.
Hou, K., C. Xue, and L. Zhang. 2015. Digesting anomalies: An investment approach. Review of
Financial Studies 28: 650–705.
[Crossref]
Jegadeesh, N., and S. Titman. 1993. Returns to buying winners and selling losers: Implications for
stock market efficiency. Journal of Finance 48: 65–91.
[Crossref]
Kozak, S., S. Nagel, and S. Santosh. 2020. Shrinking the cross section. Journal of Financial
Economics 135: 271–292.
[Crossref]
Lettau, M., and M. Pelger. 2020. Factors that fit the time series and cross-section of stock returns.
Review of Financial Studies 33: 2274–2325.
[Crossref]
Merton, R.C. 1972. An analytical derivation of the efficient portfolio frontier. Journal of Financial
and Quantitative Finance 7: 1851–1872.
[Crossref]
Novy-Marx, R. 2013. The other side of value: The gross profitability premium. Journal of Financial
Economics 108: 1–28.
[Crossref]
Ross, S.A. 1976. The arbitrage theory of capital asset pricing. Journal of Economic Theory 13: 341–
360.
[Crossref]
Simin, T. 2008. The poor performance of asset pricing models. Journal of Financial and Quantitative
Analysis 43: 335–380.
[Crossref]
Stambaugh, R.F., and Y. Yuan. 2017. Mispricing factors. Review of Financial Studies 30: 1270–1315.
[Crossref]
Footnotes
1 Novy-Marx (2013) also found that stock returns are related to expected profits.
3 In a later study by Barillas and Shanken (2018), various factors and models in previous studies
were tested. Using novel tests of the relative performance of different models, in both in-sample and
out-of-sample tests, they found that a six-factor model containing market, size, value, profit,
investment, and momentum factors outperformed other possible models.
4 The 11 anomalies were: net stock issues, equity issuance, accruals, net operating assets, asset
growth, investment to assets, financial distress, O-score of distress, momentum, gross profitability,
and return on assets.
5 As cited in footnote 3, Barillas and Shanken (2018) tested this model also.
6 Beyond the scope of the present introductory text, this squared Sharpe ratio test of intercepts was
based on work by Barillas and Shanken (2018), who developed the performance metric for
comparing competing asset pricing models.
7 Barillas and Shanken (2018) tested different factors and models and found that a six-factor model
with market, size, value, profit, investment, and momentum factors outperformed other models in
both in-sample and out-of-sample tests.
8 Fama and French (2018) conducted a different kind of out-of-sample test for models by using a
subsample of returns in the sample period for in-sample test statistics and then using the remaining
returns in the same sample period for out-of-sample test statistics.
9 In regression models with an intercept term, OLS fits the model such that the average of the
residuals, or $$E(e_{it})$$, approximately equals zero. Without an error term in model (9.10) the
average of the residual terms will not be zero and, therefore, is a good proxy for the mispricing alpha.
10 As in their 2015 study of the six-factor model, they applied maximum squared Sharpe ratio tests
of the intercepts also (see footnote 6).
© The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2023
J. W. Kolari, S. Pynnönen, Investment Valuation and Asset Pricing
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-16784-3_10
Seppo Pynnönen
Email: [email protected]
Supplementary Information
The online version contains supplementary material available at https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-16784-3_10
A new CAPM dubbed the ZCAPM was recently proposed by Kolari, Liu, and Huang (KLH) (2021). In their book,
the authors derived the ZCAPM as a special case of the more general zero-beta CAPM of Black (1972).1 The
theoretical ZCAPM is comprised of only two factors: mean excess market returns and the cross-sectional standard
deviation of returns for all assets in the market more simply referred to as return dispersion. Sensitivity of asset
returns to these two factors is measured by beta risk and so-called zeta risk, respectively. Their derivation of the
ZCAPM relied heavily on the mean-variance investment parabola of Markowitz (1959), the CAPM equilibrium
framework of Treynor (1961, 1962), Sharpe (1964), Lintner (1965), and Mossin (1966), and Black’s zero-beta
CAPM with two factors.
Relative to multifactor models, empirical tests using U.S. stock returns strongly supported the special case of
the ZCAPM and, therefore, the more general zero-beta CAPM. Out-of-sample, cross-sectional Fama and MacBeth
(1973) regression tests of the factor loadings (or beta risk and zeta risk coefficients) showed that zeta risk
associated with return dispersion is more significantly priced than other factors in popular multifactor models.
Based on the sample period 1965–2018, the authors compared the ZCAPM to the CAPM, Carhart (1997) four-
factor model, Fama and French (1992, 1993, 1995, 1996, 2015, 2018), three-, five-, and six-factor models, Hou
et al. (2014) four-factor model, and Stambaugh and Yuan (2017) four-factor model. Many different test asset
portfolios (including individual stocks) were used as well as split sample tests with subperiods.
Surprisingly, the ZCAPM consistently outperformed multifactor models in terms of both higher $$R^2$$
values of goodness-of-fit and significance of the return dispersion factor. While multifactors are statistically
significant in many cases, which confirms many published studies, they are not as significant as return
dispersion in virtually all tests. Moreover, when using industry portfolios, which are exogenous to the factors in
models, the ZCAPM dominated other models by large margins in many instances. Recall that discretionary
methods incorporating multifactors in asset pricing models were initiated by Fama and French (1992, 1993) to
boost the goodness-of-fit of the market model form of the CAPM and other companion CAPM specifications. The
finding that goodness-of-fit can be improved by a CAPM-based asset pricing model is a remarkable turn of events.
In this chapter we review ZCAPM evidence in KLH’s book in addition to findings related to many of the
multifactor models covered in Chapters 8 and 9. Interestingly, KLH argue that the ZCAPM has some relation to
discretionary methods relying on long/short multifactors. Each long/short portfolio in these models (e.g., the Fama
and French three-factor model) is a rough measure of cross-sectional returncross-sectional return dispersion. For
example, the size factor is small stocks’ returns minus big stocks’ returns. This factor comes from the cross-
sectional distribution of all stock returns in the market. It represents one slice of the total return dispersion that
describes the distribution of stock returns at a point in time. Other factors, such as value, profit, capital investment,
momentum, etc., capture other slices within the total return dispersion. Together, multifactors incorporate most of
the total return dispersion. However, each multifactor factor can change over time in terms of their location within
the total return dispersion. Another interesting aspect of multifactors is that they sometimes can become negative
(e.g., big stock returns are greater than small stock returns). The ZCAPM takes into account this kind of outcome
as the empirical form of the ZCAPM allows for both positive and negative zeta risk associated with return
dispersion.
Thus, as discussed by the authors, multifactor models are related to the ZCAPM and thereby the CAPM.
Multifactor models are other forms of the ZCAPM that are more appropriately modeled using total return
dispersion rather than different slices of return dispersion. Even new models using machine learning methods that
utilize long/short portfolios as multifactors are related to the ZCAPM. It appears that the CAPM is not dead after
all but is alive and well!
Fig. 10.1 Locating orthogonal portfolios $$I^*$$ and $$ZI^*$$ on the mean-variance parabola (Source Kolari et al. 2021, p. 59)
Before proceeding further, let’s review Black’s (1972) zero-beta CAPM. Dropping the time subscript t due to a
one-period model, the expected return for the ith asset is specified as follows:
$$\begin{aligned} E(R_i)=E(R_{ZI}) +\beta _{i,I}[E(R_I)-E(R_{ZI})], \end{aligned}$$ (10.1)
where $$E(R_I)$$ is the expected return on an efficient portfolio on the upper boundary of the parabola,
$$E(R_{ZI})$$ is the expected return on an orthogonal zero-beta portfolio on the lower boundary of the
parabola, and $$\beta _{i,I}$$ is beta risk associated with excess return of efficient portfolio I. The expected
return of the zero-beta portfolio replaces the riskless rate $$R_f$$ in the CAPM as the borrowing rate.
Unlike the CAPM, that requires the use of the market portfolio M on the efficient frontier, Black’s zero-beta
CAPM allows the use of any pair of efficient/inefficient minimum variance portfolios on the parabola that are
orthogonal to one another. If M could somehow be located, then ZM would be the zero-beta portfolio.
Returning to Fig. 10.1, suppose that the parabola is a picture based on asset returns for one day in the market.
In their book, KLH mathematically proved that the width or span of the parabola is largely determined by the
cross-sectional standard deviation (or variance) of returns for all assets denoted $$\sigma ^2_{at}$$ in a
given period of time t (e.g., one day).2 This previously unknown result makes sense. The opportunity set of all the
assets in the market is plotted within the parabola. The Y-axis shows the distribution of asset returns in the market.
This distribution has a mean and variance of returns. The variance is obviously the width of the parabola, such that
the mean market return must logically be approximately in the middle of the distribution. They denoted the mean
market return at time t as $$E(R_{at})$$. In another result not previously recognized, the mean market
return is proposed to be approximately equal to the expected return on the minimum variance portfolio
$$E(R_{Gt})$$, which splits the parabola into two halves on the axis of symmetry shown as the dashed line
in Fig. 10.1. The simple logic is that the mean market return $$E(R_{at})$$ lies approximately in the middle
of the distribution of returns on the Y-axis.
Most researchers prior to these findings believed that the mean market return (e.g., the value-weighted
CRSP index or S &P 500 index) was located somewhere in the vicinity of the efficient frontier. However,
according to KLH, the mean market return is far below the efficient frontier. As you will recall in previous
chapters, researchers have tested the CAPM with U.S. stock returns using the value-weighted CRSP index as a
proxy for the efficient market portfolio M. If this index lies somewhere along the axis of symmetry, it obviously is
far below the true market portfolio M. This mean market return location helps to explain empirical tests of the
CAPM that find a flatter relation between expected returns and beta risk estimates than predicted by the CAPM.
This flatter relation would result in a higher intercept or $$\alpha$$ term than otherwise. Consistent with the
Roll (1977) critique, an inefficient estimate of the market portfolio cannot be used to test the CAPM. If one accepts
these new insights about the mean-variance parabola, then researchers have erroneously rejected the CAPM by
using an inefficient market index m as a proxy for M.
Using the geometry shown in Fig. 10.1, the authors located two orthogonal portfolios denoted $$I^*$$
and $$ZI^*$$ on the parabola. Symmetric rays extending from $$E(R_G) \approx E(R_a)$$ yield two
tangent points to the minimum variance boundary of the parabola. Portfolio $$I^*$$ lies on the efficient
frontier, and portfolio $$ZI^*$$ is on the inefficient, minimum variance boundary of the parabola. This
orthogonal pair of portfolios is unique due to having the same time-series variance of returns and therefore are
marked with $$*$$ superscripts as $$\sigma ^2_{I^*}=\sigma ^2_{ZI^*}$$. Since the ZCAPM is a
one-period model, as in Black’s zero-beta CAPM, the time subscript t is dropped. These two portfolios are
important because their expected returns can be defined as follows:
$$\begin{aligned} E(R_{I^*})\approx & {} E(R_{a})+\sigma _{a}\end{aligned}$$ (10.2)
This two-sided, opposite market volatility risk is a distinctive feature of the ZCAPM that arises by virtue of
the mean-variance investment parabola with span determined by return dispersion.
Fig. 10.2 The ZCAPM with beta risk related to average excess market returns and zeta risk associated with positive and negative sensitivity to return
dispersion (Source Kolari et al. 2021, p. 72)
Figure 10.2 provides an illustration of the ZCAPM. The beta risk of the ith asset is based on the relation
between the ith asset’s excess returns, or $$R_{i}-R_{f}$$ on the Y-axis, and average excess market returns,
or $$R_{a}-R_{f}$$ on the X-axis. Zeta risk is determined by the relation between the asset’s excess
returns, or $$R_{i}-R_{f}$$, and market return dispersion, or $$\sigma _a$$. Here we see the two-
sided, opposite effects of zeta risk on asset returns.
Fig. 10.3 Two-sided, opposite effects of return dispersion on the expected returns of two assets (Source Kolari et al. 2021, p. 94)
Figure 10.3 gives another more simplified view of two-sided return dispersion effects. Assume there are two
time periods t = 1 and 2 in addition to two assets B and C. Return dispersion in the market increases from
$$\sigma _{a1}=1$$% at time 1 to 2% at time 2. Due to this increase in cross-sectional market volatility
from time 1 to 2, asset C experiences increasing returns but the returns of asset B decrease at time 2. Of course, if
return dispersion decreased over time, asset C would experience decreasing returns and asset B increasing returns.
Thus, return dispersion has opposite effects on the returns of assets depending on where they are located in the
distribution of returns.
In combination with beta risk, the dual systematic risk effects of return dispersion in the market give the mean-
variance parabola its upper and lower boundaries. We can think of the upper (lower) boundary as having some
amount of positive (negative) zeta risk—for example, $$Z_{i,a}^* = 0.8\ (-0.8)$$. Along the upper (lower)
boundary, assets will have increasing levels of beta risk. Hence, beta and zeta risk are important in defining the
architecture of the mean-variance parabola.
As a visual example, Fig. 10.4 shows some results for 25 U.S. stock portfolios based on the ZCAPM in Kolari
et al. (2021).6 The top horizontal boundary (or frontier) contains the five stock portfolios with the highest average
zeta risk. The frontier has an upward slope due to increasing levels of beta risk among these five portfolios. The
bottom boundary contains five stock portfolios with the lowest zeta risk in addition to varying levels of beta risk
from low to high. At each beta risk level, there is a vertical beta risk curve (i.e., represented by a dashed line) that
intersects different zeta risk curves. Taken together, the intersecting latticework of beta-zeta risk portfolios in the
graph takes on the general form of a mean-variance parabola. In effect, stock portfolios within the parabola have
beta and zeta risk characteristics that jointly determine their expected returns. Rather than being randomly
distributed within the parabola, portfolios are ordered by their systematic risks related to average market
returns and market return dispersion. Hence, equilibrium asset prices are established within the parabola due to
these two market forces.
Fig. 10.4 This graph shows the average beta risk, zeta risk, and one-month-ahead equal-weighted returns for 25 beta-zeta sorted portfolios. These long-
only portfolios approximate the shape on an investment parabola. In each one-year estimation window, the empirical ZCAPM is estimated using daily
returns to obtain the beta and zeta risk parameters. The analysis period is January 1965–December 2018 (Source Kolari et al. 2021, p. 272)
10.2 Empirical ZCAPM
How can we model the positive and negative effects of return dispersion on real-world asset returns? Kolari, Liu,
and Zhang proposed the following novel empirical ZCAPM:
$$\begin{aligned} {R}_{it}-R_{ft}=\alpha _i+\beta _{i}({R}_{at}-R_{ft})+Z_{i}D_{it}{\sigma }_{at}+
(10.9)
{u}_{it}, ~~t = 1,\ldots , T \end{aligned}$$
where $$Z_{i}$$ measures sensitivity to return dispersion $$\sigma _{at}$$, $$D_{it}$$ is a signal variable
with values $$+1$$ and $$-1$$ representing positive and negative return dispersion effects on stock returns at
time t, respectively, $$u_{it} \thicksim \text {iid N}(0,\sigma _i^2)$$, and other notation is as before. The
dummy signal variable $$D_{it}$$ is not observable and therefore is considered to be an unknown or latent
(hidden) variable. Unfortunately, due to the hidden variable $$D_{it}$$, commonly used ordinary least squares
(OLS) regression cannot be used to estimate the empirical ZCAPM.
To take into account signal variable $$D_{it}$$, the well-known statistical method of expectation-
maximization (EM) regression can be employed.7 In EM, hidden variable $$D_{it}$$ is defined as an
independent random variable with the following two-point distribution:
$$\begin{aligned} D_{it}={\left\{ \begin{array}{ll} +1 &{} \text {with probability}~ p_i\\ -1
(10.10)
&{} \text {with probability}~ 1-p_i, \end{array}\right. } \end{aligned}$$
where $$p_i$$ (or $$1-p_i$$) is the probability of a positive (or negative) return dispersion effect, and
$$D_{it}$$ is independent of $$u_{it}$$. No previous studies utilize EM regression in an asset pricing
model.
Notice that, in the empirical ZCAPM relation (10.9), the interaction term $$Z_{i,a}D_{i,t}$$ has two
possible values equal to $$+Z_{i,a}$$ or $$-Z_{i,a}$$ based on the sign of signal variable
$$D_{i,t}$$ . Since the mean of binary signal variable $$D_{i,t}$$ equals $$2 p_i -1$$, we can
define $$Z_{i,a}^* = Z_{i,a} (2p_i-1)$$, which results in the final form of the empirical ZCAPM:
$$\begin{aligned} R_{it}-R_{ft}=\beta _{i,a}(R_{at}-R_{ft}) + Z_{i,a}^* \sigma _{at}+u_{it}, ~~t =
(10.11)
1,\ldots , T. \end{aligned}$$
EM regression provides estimates of beta risk coefficient $$\beta _{i,a}$$ as well as zeta risk coefficient
$$Z_{i,a}^*$$ that coincides with theoretical ZCAPM relation (10.8). The positive or negative sign of
$$Z_{i,a}^*$$ is determined by the probability $$p_i$$ of signal variable $$D_{it}$$ in sample
period $$t = 1,\ldots , T$$ . If $$p_i > 1/2 \text { (or } <1/2)$$ , $$Z_{i,a}^*$$ will have a
positive (or negative) sign. In words, $$Z_{i,a}^*$$ gives the average increase or decrease of asset returns in
response to a one-unit change in return dispersion $$\sigma _{at}$$.
Unlike other empirical asset pricing models, the empirical ZCAPM does not have an intercept (
$$\alpha$$) term. The EM algorithm does not utilize an intercept to minimize squared error terms as in OLS
regression. For this reason, KLH repeated cross-sectional tests discussed in the next section with and without
intercepts in time-series multifactor models. They found that the cross-sectional tests of factor prices were
unaffected for the most part by time-series regressions that set the intercept to zero. However, no Gibbons et al.
(1989) (GRS) tests of the joint equality of $$\alpha$$s are possible for the empirical ZCAPM to compare to
other models.
For interested readers, KLH have placed Matlab, R, and Python programs for EM estimation of the empirical
ZCAPM on GitHub (https://github.com/zcapm). Their R programs estimate the ZCAPM faster than the Matlab and
Python programs. Programs for running Fama–MacBeth cross-sectional regression tests are provided on the
GitHub website also.
Fig. 10.5 Out-of-sample cross-sectional ZCAPM relationship between average one-month-ahead realized excess returns in percent (Y-axis) and average
beta risk $$\beta _{i,a}$$ in the previous 12-month estimation period (X-axis). Results are shown for 25 size-BM portfolios used in the Fama and
French studies. Portfolios are sorted into zeta risk $$Z^*_{i,a}$$ quintiles and then beta risk $$\beta _{i,a}$$ quintiles within each
$$Z^*_{i,a}$$ quintile. The analysis period is January 1965–December 2018 (Source Kolari et al. 2021, p. 141)
For test asset portfolios, they used 25 size and BM sorted portfolios from Kenneth French’s data website.8
These portfolios are often used by Fama and French as well as other researchers in asset pricing model tests.
Figures 10.5 and 10.6 graphically show the relation between average one-month-ahead excess returns (Y-axis) and
average beta and zeta risk coefficients (X-axis), respectively. It is apparent from Fig. 10.5 that returns are not
related to beta risk. Most of the portfolios have betas near one, which is the beta of the CRSP market risk.
Moreover, a slightly inverse relation can be seen, which is opposite of CAPM theory. Concerning these results, as
discussed earlier, beta risk is different in the ZCAPM than CAPM.
Fig. 10.6 Out-of-sample cross-sectional ZCAPM relationship between average one-month-ahead realized excess returns in percent (Y-axis) and average
zeta risk $$Z^*_{i,a}$$ in the previous 12-month estimation period (X-axis). Results are shown for 25 size-BM portfolios used in the Fama and
French studies. Portfolios are sorted into beta risk $$\beta _{i,a}$$ quintiles and then zeta risk $$Z^*_{i,a}$$ quintiles within each
$$\beta _{i,a}$$ quintile. The analysis period is January 1965–December 2018 (Source Kolari et al. 2021, p. 140)
In stark contrast, Fig. 10.6 reveals a very strong relation between returns and zeta risk. Given zeta risks for the
25 portfolios, their future returns in the next month line up almost perfectly with the order of their previously
estimated risks. This finding is extraordinary. Additionally, KLH sorted the 25 portfolios into beta risk quintiles
and then zeta risk quintiles within each beta risk quintile. This sorting reveals that small stocks tended to have
larger betas than big stocks. This pattern occurs in Fig. 10.5 also.
10.3.2 Predicted and Actual Return Relations
Are predicted returns using the ZCAPM related to future actual returns? Recall from Chap. 4 that Fama and
MacBeth (1973) argued that normative models, which are intended to help investors make better decisions, are
only valid to the extent that past information is related to future returns. To evaluate predicted versus actual
returns, we estimated beta and zeta risk parameters using the empirical ZCAPM with one year of daily returns. In
the next month on an out-of-sample basis, estimated beta and zeta coefficients were multiplied by average excess
market returns $$R_{at}-R_{ft}$$ and market return dispersion $$\sigma _{at}$$ on each day t to compute
predicted (or fitted) excess returns for each portfolio. These daily predicted excess returns are used to compute a
one-month predicted excess return in the next month. The realized (or actual) excess return in the next out-of-
sample month is recorded also. This process is rolled forward month-by-month until December 2018 to get out-of-
sample monthly series of predicted and realized excess returns for each portfolio. Lastly, averages of these excess
returns from January 1965 to December 2018 are computed. In forthcoming Table 10.1, we utilize these average
excess returns to assess the goodness-of-fit of different models. To do this, we regress average realized excess
returns on average predicted excess returns for each model to estimate their $$R^2$$ value.
Fig. 10.7 Out-of-sample cross-sectional relationship between average one-month-ahead realized excess returns in percent (Y-axis) and average one-
month-ahead predicted (fitted) excess returns in percent (X-axis) for 25 size-BM sorted portfolios: Fama and French three-factor model in Panel A and
empirical ZCAPM in Panel B. The analysis period is January 1965 to December 2018 (Source Kolari et al. 2021, p. 146)
Using the 25 size and BM sorted portfolios, Fig. 10.7 shows the results for the Fama and French three-factor
model versus the empirical ZCAPM. The three-factor model performs well in these tests. The (out-of-sample)
predicted and realized excess returns in these out-of-sample analyses line up closely to the 45-degree line. By
comparison, the ZCAPM performs even better. Notice that the three-factor model has one stray portfolio, which is
the small-size portfolio with low BM (growth).9 However, this stray portfolio is priced by the ZCAPM as it lies
exactly on the 45-degree line.
Fig. 10.8 Out-of-sample cross-sectional relationship between average one-month-ahead realized excess returns in percent (Y-axis) and average one-
month-ahead predicted (fitted) excess returns in percent (X-axis) for 25 size-BM sorted plus 47 industry portfolios: Fama and French Fama and French
three-factor model in Panel A and empirical ZCAPM in Panel B. The analysis period is January 1965–December 2018 (Source Kolari et al. 2021, p. 147)
Figure 10.8 repeats these experiments with the 25 size and BM portfolios plus 47 industry portfolios. Here we
see that the three-factor model is not useful, but the ZCAPM does a fairly good job. Industries are exogenous to
the three-factor model, unlike the endogenous size and BM portfolios (i.e., as discussed in Chapter 8, the size and
value factors are related to the size and BM portfolios). In this regard, referring back to Fig. 10.6, the size and BM
portfolios are exogenous to the ZCAPM. Even so, the ZCAPM outperforms the three-factor model. Together, these
results suggest that the ZCAPM has better goodness-of-fit than the three-factor model. The tables have turned!
Goodness-of-fit is higher in the CAPM model than the multifactor model.
Fig. 10.9 Out-of-sample cross-sectional relationship between average one-month-ahead realized excess returns in percent (Y-axis) and average one-
month-ahead predicted (fitted) excess returns in percent (X-axis) for 25 profit-investment sorted portfolios: Fama and French six-factor model in Panel A
and empirical ZCAPM in Panel B. The analysis period is January 1965 to December 2018 (Source Kolari et al. 2021, p. 150)
Fig. 10.10 Out-of-sample cross-sectional relationship between average one-month-ahead realized excess returns in percent (Y-axis) and average one-
month-ahead predicted (fitted) excess returns in percent (X-axis) for 25 profit-investment sorted plus 47 industry portfolios: Fama and French Fama and
French six-factor model in Panel A and empirical ZCAPM in Panel B. The analysis period is January 1965–December 2018 (Source Kolari et al. 2021, p.
151)
Figures 10.9 and 10.10 repeat these analyses using the Fama and French six-factor model. Here the 25 size and
BM portfolios are replaced with 25 profit-investment sorted portfolios from Kenneth French’s data website.
Clearly, the six-factor model performs quite well and does better than the three-factor model, but the ZCAPM still
outperforms it. Also, the six-factor model has difficulty in fitting returns for industry portfolios. When test asset
portfolios are used that are not related to long/short factors, the multifactor models are more likely to fall down.
This table reports selected results from Kolari et al. (2021). Out-of-sample (one-month-ahead) estimated prices of
risk were estimated using the standard two-step Fama-MacBeth cross-sectional tests. Estimated prices of risk are
denoted $$\hat{\lambda }_k$$ for the kth factor in monthly percent return terms (t-statistics in parentheses).
Factors are denoted as m (CRSP index, see footnote), RD (return dispersion), $$\textit{SMB}$$ (size),
$$\textit{HML}$$ (value), $$\textit{MOM}$$ (momentum), $$\textit{RMW}$$ (profit), and
$$\textit{CMA}$$ (capital investment). Value-weighted returns were used in the period January 1965–
December 2018. Different sets of test asset portfolios were employed as shown in Panels A–D. The results
shown below are based on Kolari et al. (2021, Table 7.1, p. 166)
aIn the ZCAPM, the price of beta risk associated with CRSP index excess returns is denoted
The first notable finding in Table 10.1 is the relatively high $$R^2$$ values of the ZCAPM compared to
the other models. In Panels A and C, the ZCAPM achieves $$R^2$$ estimates of 94% and 96%,
respectively. This goodness-of-fit is near perfect! Almost all variation in cross-sectional stock returns in these
portfolios is explained by the ZCAPM. The near perfect fit of the ZCAPM is remarkable in light of fact that these
tests utilize one-month-ahead (out-of-sample) returns. The CAPM has fairly good fit at 48% for the 25 size and
BM sorted portfolios (Panel A) but is zero for 47 industry portfolios (Panel B). The highest multifactor model
$$R^2$$ value of 80% is achieved by the six-factor model in the 25 size and BM portfolios (Panel A) but
falls to 50% for 47 industry portfolios (Panel B) and only 35% for 97 combined portfolios (Panel D). In the latter
two portfolio tests, the ZCAPM posted respectable 70% and 83% $$R^2$$ values. These results suggest that
the ZCAPM outperforms the CAPM and multifactor models in general and by large margins with industry
portfolios in particular.
Looking at the market prices of risk, or $$\lambda _k$$s, in Table 10.1, the market price of return
dispersion ( $$\lambda _{RD}$$ ) has the highest t-values of statistical significance ranging from 4.03 to 5.42
in the different panels. Size factor loadings ( $$\lambda _{SMB}$$) never reach statistical significance at the
5% level. Loadings for other factors, including value ( $$\lambda _{HML}$$), momentum (
$$\lambda _{MOM}$$), profit ( $$\lambda _{RMW}$$), and capital investment (
$$\lambda _{CMA}$$), are intermittently significant in different models and test asset portfolios. And,
market factor loadings are normally insignificant but are significant with a negative sign for the 25 size and BM
portfolios in some models (opposite of CAPM theory).
Notice that none of the multifactor loadings achieves a t-statistic greater than 3. In extensive tests of over 300
multifactors, Harvey et al. (2016) and Chordia et al. (2020) documented evidence that most multifactors are false
discoveries.10 For this reason, these authors recommended that asset pricing factors should surpass a t-statistic
threshold of 3 to be considered significant in cross-sectional tests. This hurdle is relatively high. Rarely are widely
used factors able to exceed this threshold, especially in out-of-sample cross-sectional tests. Using this criterion,
only zeta risk loadings in the ZCAPM pass recent standards for the validity of factors. Other models are subject to
question in view of these findings.
Overall, the results in Table 10.1 show that the empirical ZCAPM outperforms the CAPM and popular
multifactor models in standard Fama and MacBeth cross-sectional tests. KLH also conducted cross-sectional tests
of the Hou et al. (2015) q-factor model with four factors (viz., market, equity capitalization, investment to assets
ratio, and return on equity) as well as the Stambaugh and Yuan (2017) mispricing model with four factors (market,
size, management, and performance). None of the t-statistics for estimated $$\lambda _k$$s exceeded three.
Moreover, the goodness-of-fit was less than the ZCAPM, especially for industry portfolios as in the tests of other
models in Table 10.1. Hence, using similar test assets and sample periods, the ZCAPM outperformed these four-
factor models in cross-sectional tests.
More recent work by Kolari et al. (2022b) extended the U.S. stock return analyses in KLH to a longer sample
period of 1927 to 2020. The results corroborated those in KLH. Also, Kolari et al. (2022a) extended the analyses to
Canada, Japan, Germany, and Japan. Again the results confirmed findings in KLH—namely, the ZCAPM
outperformed multifactor models especially when using exogenous industry portfolios.
A natural question is: Why does the ZCAPM consistently outperform multifactor asset pricing models? As
discussed in KLH and mentioned earlier, the long/short multifactors are themselves rough measures of return
dispersion. They capture different slices of the total return dispersion as measured by $$\sigma _{at}$$. At
times the market prices of multifactor loadings can turn negative (e.g., see the 25 beta-zeta portfolios in Panel C).
These negative prices are difficult to explain in the context of the multifactor models. However, in line with the
ZCAPM, they are picking up negative zeta risk. As more factors are added to multifactor models, they come closer
to capturing total return dispersion. Of course, the multifactors can change over time and shift their position within
the distribution of total returns. In general, all multifactors are subsumed or contained within total return
dispersion.
Fama and French and others loosely link multifactor models to the hedge portfolio theories of Merton’s (1973)
intertemporal CAPM and Ross’ (1976) arbitrage pricing theory (APT). Further linking theory to empirical models,
KLH assert that multifactor models are closely linked to total return dispersion in the ZCAPM. Viewed as return
dispersion measures, multifactors are therefore related to both KLH’s ZCAPM and Black’s (1972) zero-beta
CAPM in addition to the CAPM of Treynor (1961, 1962), Sharpe (1964), Lintner (1965), and Mossin (1966). In
a very real sense, all of these models are cousins of the CAPM! As already discussed, the main complaint against
the CAPM by Fama and French and others was its poor empirical fit to stock returns. The ZCAPM overcomes this
objection by dramatically improving the empirical fit of a CAPM-based model.
10.4 Summary
Kolari, Liu, and Huang (KLH) (2021) recently proposed a new CAPM dubbed the ZCAPM. The ZCAPM has two
factors: mean excess market returns and the cross-sectional standard deviation of returns for all assets in the
market or simply return dispersion. Return sensitivity to these two factors is measured by beta risk and zeta risk,
respectively. The ZCAPM is grounded in the Markowitz (1959) mean-variance investment parabola, equilibrium
conditions of the famous CAPM by Treynor (1961, 1962), Sharpe (1964), Lintner (1965), and Mossin (1966), and
the zero-beta CAPM of Black (1972).
KLH mathematically derived the ZCAPM as a special case of Black’s (1972) zero-beta CAPM. Two key
insights proposed by KLH are: (1) the width or span of the mean-variance parabola at time t is largely determined
by market return dispersion; and (2) the mean market return is approximately in the middle of the parabola
somewhere along its axis of symmetry. Using these insights, they identified two unique orthogonal portfolios on
the parabola denoted $$I^*I^*$$ and $$ZI^*$$ that have the same time-series variance of returns.
Upon substituting the formulas for the expected returns of these two portfolios into Black’s equation for the zero-
beta CAPM, they obtained a special case that represents the theoretical ZCAPM. Adding a riskless rate, they
derived the final form of the theoretical ZCAPM.
KLH specified a novel empirical ZCAPM with a dummy signal variable (equal to $$+1$$ or
$$-1$$) to capture either positive or negative return dispersion effects on asset returns. Since this signal
variable is unobservable, they used expectation-maximization (EM) regression methods to estimate the
probability that the signal variable is $$+1$$ or $$-1$$. Multiplying this probability times the zeta
risk regression coefficient, they obtained an estimate of zeta risk (denoted $$Z^*$$) for a stock. Beta
risk (denoted $$\beta$$) is the regression coefficient associated with mean excess market returns. The
empirical ZCAPM is a parsimonious two-factor model that employs factors that can be readily estimated from
available market data. There is no need to obtain a proxy for an efficient market portfolio M as in the CAPM or a
zero-beta portfolio ZM as in the zero-beta CAPM.
Empirical tests of the ZCAPM yielded impressive results. Using cross-sectional analyses, KLH showed that a
close relation exists between stock returns in the next month and previously estimated zeta risk coefficients. Also,
using step-ahead or out-of-sample returns in the next month, predicted (fitted) excess returns from the ZCAPM
were closer to realized (actual) excess returns in comparisons to the CAPM and Fama and French (1993, 2015,
2018) multifactor models.
More formal Fama and MacBeth (1973) cross-sectional tests using out-of-sample stock returns strongly
supported the ZCAPM over the CAPM and multifactor models. Comparative tests of the Carhart (1997) four-
factor model, Fama and French three-, five-, and six-factor models, Hou et al. (2015) four-factor q model, and
Stambaugh and Yuan (2017) four-factor model showed that:
(1)
estimated $$R^2$$ values from the empirical ZCAPM were noticeably higher on a consistent basis in tests
of different portfolios than those for the CAPM and multifactor models; and
(2)
zeta risk loadings estimated from the ZCAPM normally had t-statistics greater than 3, but multifactors in
other models did not exceed this recommended threshold.
A major difficulty of the CAPM as well as multifactor models is their poor pricing performance with respect to
exogenous industry portfolios. By contrast, the ZCAPM did a good job of pricing industry portfolios.
Why does the ZCAPM outperform popular multifactor models? The main reason is that multifactor models
depend on long/short portfolios as factors that are rough measures of return dispersion. A more complete and
accurate measure of return dispersion is the cross-sectional standard deviation of returns in the market. From this
perspective, all multifactor models are related to the ZCAPM and therefore the CAPM also. The main complaint of
poor empirical fit among CAPM models is overcome by the ZCAPM. Indeed, the ZCAPM consistently
outperforms the multifactor models in out-of-sample cross-sectional tests. Rather than the CAPM being
empirically dead, it is reborn in the form of the empirical ZCAPM. The history of asset pricing has come full
circle. The early theoretical models of the CAPM led to discretionary models with empirically justified
multifactors. However, the ZCAPM subsumes multifactors within its total return dispersion factor. Can machine
learning methods be developed to further enhance the empirical ZCAPM? Are there better proxies for mean
market returns and the cross-sectional return dispersion? By improving these proxies, the empirical ZCAPM could
be enhanced. It will be interesting to see what the future of asset pricing holds!
Questions
1.
Draw a picture of Markowitz’s mean-variance investment parabola. Label the Y-axis as $$E(R_P)$$ for
expected returns and X-axis as $$\sigma ^2_P$$ for the variance of returns. Where is the minimum
variance portfolio G? In your figure, show how Kolari, Liu, and Huang (KLH) (2021) located two orthogonal
portfolios with equal time-series variance of returns: $$I^*$$ on the efficient frontier, and $$ZI^*$$ on
the inefficient boundary of the parabola. According to KLH, what defines the width or span of the parabola?
Show this in your diagram along with the mean market return.
2.
In their picture of the mean-variance investment parabola, Kolari, Liu, and Huang (KLH) (2021) argued that
commonly used general stock market indexes (e.g., the value-weighted CRSP index or S &P 500 index) are
inefficient. Where do they locate these general indexes within the parabola? If this is true, what is the
implication to tests of the CAPM using the market model?
3.
Assuming a riskless asset exists, write the equation for the theoretical ZCAPM. What do beta risk and zeta
risk measure in this model? Does the ZCAPM have an empirical advantage in terms of testing over other
forms of the CAPM?
4. According to Kolari, Liu, and Huang (KLH) (2021), zeta risk (denoted by $$Z_{i,a}^*$$) in the ZCAPM
can be positive or negative in sign. Illustrate this two-sided zeta risk in a diagram with the ith asset’s excess
returns denoted $$R_{i}-R_{f}$$ on the Y-axis and average excess market returns denoted
$$R_{a}-R_{f}$$ on the X-axis. In your diagram, what is beta risk? Show how positive and negative zeta
risk affect the excess returns of assets.
5.
Show how two-sided return dispersion effects impact expected stock returns. Assume there are two time
periods t = 1 and 2 in addition to two assets B and C. Return dispersion in the market increases from
$$\sigma _{a1}=1$$% at time 1 to 2% at time 2. Due to this increase in cross-sectional market volatility
from time 1 to 2, show how expected asset returns of assets B and C are affected. What if return dispersion
decreased over time?
6.
Kolari, Liu, and Huang (KLH) (2021) argued that the mean-variance parabola is shaped by the dual
systematic risk effects of beta risk and zeta risk. How is the architecture of the parabola affected by these
systematic risks?
7.
Kolari, Liu, and Zhang (KLH) (2021) conducted out-of-sample (or one-month-ahead), cross-sectional Fama
and MacBeth (1973) tests of a number of different test asset portfolios. The final form of the empirical
ZCAPM was estimated using one year of daily returns. The U.S. Treasury bill rate proxied the riskless rate.
To begin their analyses, KLH reported evidence on the relation between beta risk and zeta risk with respect
to one-month-ahead stock returns. Using 97 stock portfolios, the empirical ZCAPM was run using daily
returns for one year to obtain $$\beta _{i,a}$$ and $$Z_{i,a}^*$$ estimates for each portfolio. The
actual returns $$R_{it+1}$$ in the next one month were retained. The process was repeated by rolling
forward one month to get new estimates of $$\beta _{i,a}$$ and $$Z_{i,a}^*$$ as well as the next one-
month returns $$R_{it+1}$$ for portfolios. Repeating this process from 1964 to the end of 2018, they
generated a series of 648 monthly values for $$\beta _{i,a}$$, $$Z_{i,a}^*$$, and $$R_{it+1}$$.
Next, the average values of these values were computed for each portfolio. What did they find?
8.
Following standard practices, Kolari, Liu, and Zhang (KLH) (2021) implemented Fama–MacBeth cross-
sectional regression tests. The analyses were rolled forward one month at a time to generate a series of
estimated market prices of beta and zeta risk loadings (denoted $$\lambda _a$$ and $$\lambda _{RD}$$
, respectively). To comparatively evaluate the performance of the ZCAPM, they ran tests for the
CAPM, Carhart (1997) four-factor model, and Fama and French (1992, 1993, 2015, 2018) three-, five-, and
six-factor models. For the often used 25 size and BM sorted portfolios from Kenneth French’s data website,
they produced graphs comparing realized excess returns to fitted excess returns for the three-factor model of
Fama and French (1992, 1993) versus the empirical ZCAPM. What did these graphs show? What about the
results for 47 industry portfolios? What do these results mean?
9.
Kolari, Liu, and Zhang (KLH) (2021) repeated the question above by comparing other multifactor models to
the empirical ZCAPM. For the six-factor model of Fama and French (2018) compared to the empirical
ZCAPM, using 25 profit-investment sorted portfolios, what did they find? For industry portfolios?
10.
In empirical tests of the ZCAPM, is there an explanation for why multifactor models were dominated by the
ZCAPM? Fama and French (1993, 1995, 2015, 2018) link that multifactor models to Merton’s (1973)
intertemporal CAPM and Ross’ (1976) arbitrage pricing theory (APT). Can the ZCAPM be linked to these
theoretical models?
Problems
1.
Given their new geometry of the parabola, how did Kolari, Liu, and Huang (KLH) (2021) define the expected
returns for the special case of orthogonal portfolios $$I^*$$ and $$ZI^*$$ on the parabola? Describe this
new geometry for locating these portfolios. How does this geometry differ from the CAPM and market
portfolio M.
2.
If we substitute the definitions of $$E(R_{I^*})$$ and $$E(R_{ZI^*})$$ into the zero-beta CAPM
Eq. 10.1, we can derive a theoretical ZCAPM without a riskless rate. Show how to get the theoretical ZCAPM
in this case.
3. Kolari, Liu, and Zhang (KLH) (2021) proposed a novel empirical ZCAPM to capture positive and negative
sensitivity to return dispersion (i.e., zeta risk). Write their empirical model. What is $$D_{it}$$ in this
model? Using the definition of $$D_{it}$$, write the final form of the empirical ZCAPM. Why must the
expectation-maximization (EM) regression method must be used to estimate this final form?
4.
How did Kolari, Liu, and Zhang (KLH) (2021) compute mean market returns as well as the return dispersion
for U.S. stocks? Are equal-weighted or value-weighted return used in their computations of these factors?
5.
Kolari, Liu, and Zhang (KLH) (2021) conducted out-of-sample Fama and MacBeth (1973) cross-sectional
regression tests for the empirical ZCAPM and a number of other models, including the market model and
multifactor models. What did these tests reveal about the goodness-of-fit? About the significance of estimated
market prices of risk for different factors?
References
Black, F. 1972. Capital market equilibrium with restricted borrowing. Journal of Business 45: 444–454.
[Crossref]
Carhart, M.M. 1997. On persistence in mutual fund performance. Journal of Finance 52: 57–82.
[Crossref]
Chordia, T., A. Goyal, and A. Saretto. 2020. Anomalies and false rejections. Review of Financial Studies 33: 2134–2179.
[Crossref]
Dempster, A.P., N.M. Laird, and D.B. Rubin. 1977. Maximum likelihood from incomplete data via the EM algorithm. Journal of the Royal Statistical
Society 39: 1–38.
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 1992. The cross-section of expected stock returns. Journal of Finance 47: 427–465.
[Crossref]
Fama, F.F. and K.R. French 1995. Size and book-to-market factors in earnings and returns. Journal of Finance 50: 131–155.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 1993. The cross-section of expected returns. Journal of Financial Economics 33: 3–56.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 1996. The CAPM is wanted, dead or alive. Journal of Finance 51: 1947–1958.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 2015. A five-factor asset pricing model. Journal of Financial Economics 116: 1–22.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 2018. Choosing factors. Journal of Financial Economics 128: 234–252.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and J.D. MacBeth. 1973. Risk, return, and equilibrium: Empirical tests. Journal of Political Economy 81: 607–636.
[Crossref]
Gibbons, M.R., S.A. Ross, and J. Shanken. 1989. A test of the efficiency of a given portfolio. Econometrica 57: 1121–1152.
[Crossref]
Harvey, C.R., Y. Liu, and H. Zhu. 2016. and the cross-section of expected returns. Review of Financial Studies 29: 5–68.
[Crossref]
Hou, K., C. Xue, and L. Zhang. 2015. Digesting anomalies: An investment approach. Review of Financial Studies 28: 650–705.
[Crossref]
Jones, P.N., and G.J. McLachlan. 1990. Algorithm AS 254: Maximum likelihood estimation from grouped and truncated data with finite normal mixture
models. Applied Statistics 39: 273–282.
[Crossref]
Liu, W. 2013. A New Asset Pricing Model Based on the Zero-Beta CAPM: Theory and Evidence. Doctoral dissertation, Texas A &M University.
Liu, W., J.W. Kolari, and J.Z. Huang. 2012. A new asset pricing model based on the zero-beta CAPM. Best paper award in investments at the annual
meetings of the Financial Management Association, Atlanta, GA, October.
Liu, W., J.W. Kolari, and J.Z. Huang. 2019. Creating superior investment portfolios. Working paper, Texas A &M University.
Kolari, J.W., W. Liu, and J.Z. Huang. 2021. A New Model of Capital Asset Prices: Theory and Evidence. Cham: Palgrave Macmillan.
[Crossref]
Kolari, J.W., J.Z. Huang, H.A. Butt, and H. Liao. 2022a. International tests of the ZCAPM asset pricing model. Journal of International Financial
Markets, Institutions &Money 79: 101607.
Kolari, J.W., W. Liu, J.Z. Huang, and H. Liao. 2022b. Further tests of the ZCAPM asset pricing model. Journal of Risk and Financial Management 15:
1–23.
[Crossref]
Linnainmaa, J., and M. Roberts. 2018. The history of the cross-section of stock returns. Review of Financial Studies 31: 2606–2649.
[Crossref]
Lintner, J. 1965. The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock portfolios and capital budgets. Review of Economics and
Statistics 47: 13–37.
[Crossref]
Markowitz, H.M. 1959. Portfolio selection: Efficient Diversification of Investments. New York, NY: Wiley.
McLachlan, G.J., and T. Krishnan. 2008. The EM Algorithm and Extensions, 2nd ed. New York, NY: Wiley.
[Crossref]
McLachlan, G. J., and D. Peel. 2000. Finite Mixture Models. New York, NY: Wiley Interscience.
[Crossref]
McLean, R.D., and J. Pontiff. 2016. Does academic publication destroy predictability? Journal of Finance 71: 5–32.
[Crossref]
Merton, R.C. 1973. An intertemporal capital asset pricing model. Econometrica 41: 867–887.
[Crossref]
Roll, R. 1977. A critique of the asset pricing theory’s tests, part I: On past and potential future testability of the theory. Journal of Financial Economics
4: 129–176.
[Crossref]
Ross, S.A. 1976. The arbitrage theory of capital asset pricing. Journal of Economic Theory 13: 341–360.
[Crossref]
Sharpe, W.F. 1964. Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. Journal of Finance 19: 425–442.
Stambaugh, R.F., and Y. Yuan. 2017. Mispricing factors. Review of Financial Studies 30: 1270–1315.
[Crossref]
Treynor, J.L. 1961. Market value, time, and risk. Unpublished manuscript.
Treynor, J.L. 1962. Toward a theory of market value of risky assets. Unpublished manuscript.
Footnotes
1 The material in the book is based on earlier academic studies of U.S. stock market returns by the authors in Liu et al. (2012, 2019) and Liu (2013) as
well as real-world investment services in collaboration with the Teachers Retirement System of Texas (TRS). Additionally, recent papers by Kolari et al.
(2022a, b) extend their previous work to a number of major industrialized countries as well as a longer U.S. sample period.
2 Interested readers can refer to the random matrix theory and Markowitz’s mean-variance portfolio proofs in their book.
3 We have simplified the notation somewhat here. The authors use $$f(\theta ) \sigma ^2_a$$ instead of simply $$\sigma ^2_a$$ in Eq. (10.2),
where $$f(\theta ) > 0$$ is a complex function of other terms.
6 The authors estimated the ZCAPM to compute beta and zeta risk coefficients for thousands of U.S stocks (see Sect. 10.2 for an overview of the
empirical ZCAPM). In 1964 the ZCAPM was estimated for stocks which were then sorted into quintiles by their beta and zeta coefficients to form the 25
portfolios. Next, portfolios’ returns were computed in the out-of-sample month of January 1965. This process was rolled forward one month at a time to
generate monthly series of beta, zeta, and one-month-ahead returns for each portfolio from January 1965 to December 2018. For each portfolio, average
returns and the standard deviations of these monthly returns were computed. All portfolios were long-only with no short positions.
7 Originally invented by Dempster et al. (1977), EM regression is widely used in the sciences. See also studies by Jones and McLachlan
(1990), McLachlan and Peel (2000), and McLachlan and Krishnan (2008), among others. Wikipedia gives an excellent discussion of the EM algorithm
with literature citations.
8 See https://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/data_library.
9 This portfolio is the smallest-size/lowest-BM (growth) stock portfolio with the lowest average realized excess return. It is well known that the three-
factor model has difficulty explaining this small, growth portfolio (e.g., see Fama and French (1996)).
10 We should mention that some researchers have found that many anomalous factors tend to disappear after their publication in finance journals (e.g.,
see McLean and Pontiff (2016), Linnainmaa and Roberts (2018), and others). Nonetheless, numerous anomalous factors persist over time.
© The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2023
J. W. Kolari, S. Pynnönen, Investment Valuation and Asset Pricing
https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-16784-3_11
Seppo Pynnönen
Email: [email protected]
Supplementary Information
The online version contains supplementary material available at https://doi.
org/10.1007/978-3-031-16784-3_11
(11.2)
There are several ways to specify and estimate the mean model. The
simplest approach is to specify equal to the unconditional
expected return , which can be estimated by the sample mean
over the estimation window. A more common way to measure abnormal
returns is to use an asset pricing model. Following Fama et al. (1969), let’s
take the simplest case of the market model written as
, where is the proxy market return.5
Extending the market model approach, event studies have utilized a
multifactor model written as ,
where the information set is based on multifactor values (e.g., the
Fama and French [1993, 2015] three- and five-factor models with
). Interestingly, Brown and Warner (1985) have found that
statistical results in event studies are not critically dependent on the chosen
asset pricing model. Hence, short-run event study results are not very
sensitive to the asset pricing model employed.
Given the factor model, the regression parameters and ,
are estimated by ordinary least squares (OLS) using the
estimation window returns for each sample stock . Estimates
for the abnormal returns in the event window are prediction errors:
(11.3)
where t is the event time within the event window for
different assets.
In short-run event studies, statistical tests of event effects can be broadly
divided into two categories: parametric and nonparametric. Parametric
tests rely on the assumption that returns follow some parametric probability
distribution like the Gaussian normal distribution. Nonparametric tests relax
this assumption and therefore tend to be more robust. Even so, this
robustness does not come without some cost. For instance, if the underlying
assumptions of the parametric return generating process hold, parametric
tests tend to be more powerful, which means that they will detect the event
effect with higher probability than nonparametric test if indeed there is a
significant event (i.e., Type II error is reduced). Conversely, if the
underlying assumptions are violated, parametric tests can be prone to false
alarms in the sense that they detect significant event effects when there are
none (i.e., Type I error is increased).6 Because the vast majority of event
studies utilize parametric testing, we focus on this approach here. For
interested readers, Appendix A provides a short introduction to
nonparametric approaches.
(11.6)
where is the sample mean of ARs (or CARs) of sample event firms, and
is the standard error of the sample mean.
Assuming that the event windows of different firms are not overlapping
in calendar time, the t-statistic in Eq. (11.6) for testing the null hypothesis
(11.4) for ARs becomes:
(11.7)
where
(11.8)
where
(11.10)
(11.13)
where
(11.14)
is the sample standard deviation of in which is the OLS residual
standard deviation of the estimation window residuals and is the
prediction error correction to account for sampling errors in the OLS
regression coefficient estimates. Standardized cumulative abnormal returns
(SCARs) over event days are defined in the same manner:
(11.15)
where
(11.16)
in which is the same as in Eq. (11.14).9
For SARs computed using the market model, Patell (1976) proposed the
following test statistic:
(11.17)
where is the length of the estimation window of the ith stock. By the
CLT in large samples, we know that .
The Patell statistic does not account for possible event-induced
variance. To fix this problem, Boehmer et al. (1991) proposed to utilize the
event time t estimated standard error in the test statistic. As such, their test
statistic is analogous to the t-ratios in Eqs. (11.7) and (11.9) with s and
s replaced by their standardized counterparts. Hence, for s, we
now have:
(11.18)
(11.19)
(11.20)
11.1.4 Examples
Example 1: To demonstrate event study testing of abnormal returns, we
employ daily stock returns for a sample of 50 seasoned equity offerings
(SEOs) by U.S companies. We collect this sample of events in the period
1985– 2015. SEOs raise equity capital for firms to deploy in various capital
expenditures (e.g., merger and acquisition bids, fixed plant expenses, etc.).
They are highly visible events as new information about the future activities
of a firm is revealed to investors. The event period (or event window) is
days around the event day 0. The estimation period is 250 days prior
to the event period, i.e., days from to .
Table 11.1 reports results using the test statistics for event day 0 as well
as the cumulative abnormal return windows , , ,
and . In this sample the event days are not clustered (i.e., SEOs
for different firms happen on different days), so no cross-sectional
correlation adjustments are needed. The event day return is %, which
is economically large and statistically significant in terms of the non-
standardized test as well as standardized tests of the Patell and BMP.
None of the other event windows shows significant abnormal returns. We
infer that these results support market efficiency wherein market
information is rapidly absorbed in stock prices and returns without delays or
pre-event leakages. In general, investors viewed SEOs negatively as stock
returns materially decreased on the event day.
Table 11.1 Short-run event study results for 50 SEO events of U.S. firms from 1985 to 2015
Event window
Event day
AR/CAR(%) −2.54 −2.31 −1.21 0.27 −3.84
$$t_{ CAR }$$ −1.95 −1.65 −0.98 0.20 −1.52
p-value 0.056 0.105 0.331 0.840 0.134
$$z_{\textrm{patell}}$$ −4.50 −2.31 −1.54 1.83 −1.09
p-value 0.000 0.021 0.125 0.067 0.274
$$t_{\textrm{bmp}}$$ −2.20 −1.40 −1.41 1.33 −1.12
p-value 0.033 0.196 0.165 0.190 0.269
Abnormal returns are computed using the Fama and French five-factor
model:
$$R_p^e = \alpha _p + \beta _pR_m^e + s_p SMB + h_p HML + r_p
RMW + c_p CMA + \epsilon _p,$$
where $$R_p^e = R_p - R_f$$ is the excess return over the riskless
Treasury bill rate for an industry portfolio, $$R_m^e = R_m - R_f$$ is
the excess return for the market proxy, and $$SMB$$, $$HML$$,
$$RMW$$, and $$CMA$$ are the zero-investment portfolio factors.
The estimation window is 255 trading days before the beginning of the
event window containing $$\pm 10$$ trading days around event day 0
Note p-values for the level of significance are shown in parentheses: * =
10*, ** = 5%, and *** = 1%
Data source https://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/data_
library.html
Fig. 11.1 Cumulative abnormal returns for selected industries in response to 2008 financial
crisis news events
Fig. 11.2 Cumulative abnormal returns for selected industries in response to 2020 COVID-19 crisis
news events
Figures 11.1 and 11.2 graph the industry CARs in the 21-day event
windows for the news events. Notice in particular the larger negative effects
of the financial crisis announcement on October 3, 2008 (Fig. 11.1, Panel
D) and COVID-19 announcement on March 11, 2020 (Fig. 11.2, Panel A)
with respect to the manufacturing sector compared to the other sectors.
Interestingly, this industry seems to anticipate these events by a few days.
Thus, investors were expecting these events to some extent, which is
consistent with an efficient market.
11.2.3 Example
Here we compare the BHAR and CTAR approaches to long-run event
studies based on a sample of 200 seasoned equity offerings (SEOs) among
U.S. firms from 1985 to 2015. Using a 5-year post-event period, the total
sample period extends to the end of 2020. Comprehensive analyses of this
event and other major corporate events are reported by Kolari et al. (2021).
For BHAR, control firms are selected by matching size (market
capitalization) and book-to-market (BM) ratio characteristics to event firms
using CRSP and Compustat databases. Firm size is calculated at the end of
December prior to the SEO announcement. The BM ratio is calculated at
the end of the year prior to the event.
Table 11.3 reports the results for the event month as well as post-event
months (i.e., 6-month as well as 1-, 2-, 3-, and 5-year periods). BHAR
abnormal returns are the excess returns over respective holding periods, and
CTAR abnormal returns are average returns per month. The signs of
abnormal returns computed using these two methods are the same for the
most part. One exception is 6 months, in which BHARs are approximately
4% but CTARs equal −0.31% monthly return or about −1.8% over six
months. However, both of these abnormal returns are not statistically
significant. A major difference in results occurs in the 1-year post-event
period, wherein BHARs equal an insignificant −4.77% but CTARs equal a
significant −0.81% per month or about −9.7% per year. Looking at other
results, both approaches lead to the same inferences of significant 2-year
abnormal returns and insignificant 3- and 5-year abnormal returns. In the
post-event 5-year period, BHARs and CTARs suggest that SEO firms
underperform their matches by an economically meaningful −22.1
percentage points and −0.28 percentage points per month or about −16.8%
over 5 years, respectively. While economically large in magnitude, as
observed by Kothari and Warner (2006), both approaches suffer from weak
power that causes problems in detecting statistically significant events. In
general, our results suggest that long-run abnormal returns occurred in
response to SEOs by firms. Is the cause behavioral or is there a risk
explanation for these negative abnormal returns? Alternatively, do
managers sacrifice shareholder wealth to achieve their goals for the firm?
Table 11.3 Long-run event study results for 200 SEO events of U.S. firms from 1985 to 2015
Questions
1.
Explain the concepts of event date, event time, event window, and
estimation window.
2.
Explain normal return, abnormal return, and cumulative abnormal
return.
3.
Discuss pros and cons of standardized event study tests with relation to
non-standardized tests.
4.
Suppose that you want to test the null hypothesis of no mean effect
when event days are completely clustered. The sample size is
$$n = 100$$ firms and the test statistic applied is BMP due to its
good sample properties. You estimate the value of
$$t_{\textrm{bmp}} = 2.7$$ with $$p = 0.007$$ in two-sided
testing. As a result, you infer that the event effect is highly statistically
significant. Since the average cross-sectional correlation of the
abnormal returns is $$\bar{r} = 0.02$$, you argue that the small
average cross-sectional correlation will not materially change the test
results. Is this right?
5.
In the text it was noted that the BHAR approach in long-run event
studies is vulnerable to cross-sectional correlation. Is it vulnerable to
autcorrelation or heteroskedasticity of the returns too?
6.
Consider a long-run event study of SEO events with abnormal returns
defined as the difference between the returns of the event firm and its
matched control firm. What would you consider to be a major problem
with this definition of the abnormal return?
7. Discuss some of the major pros and cons of nonparametric rank tests in
event studies (see Appendix A).
Problems
1.
A key requirement for efficient capital markets is that prices fully and
instantaneously reflect all available relevant information. Consider the
event of an earnings announcement. Suppose that the current price of a
stock is 100. Sketch a stock price process for $$\pm 5$$ days around
the event (using end of day prices) to reflect:
a.
an efficient capital market when the announcement is
b.
leakage of information before the event day when the surprise is
i. positive (+5%)
ii. negative (−5%)
c.
a price process as in (a) when the full price adjustment takes place
over a few days after the event.
2. The table below reports event day abnormal returns, standard
deviations of the estimation window abnormal returns (i.e., OLS
residuals of the market model), and rank number of the event day
abnormal return for each stock relative to its estimation window
abnormal returns in a sample of $$n = 30$$ stocks. The estimation
window is $$T_e = 200$$ days so that $$T = T_e + 1$$ (i.e.,
estimation window returns $$+$$ event return) is the total number of
returns for each stock. The smallest return for each stock assumes rank
number 1 and the largest 201. Using this ranking approach, the rank
number 164 for the first stock indicates that the event day abnormal
return of 1.21% is the 164th largest among the 201 returns from the
combined estimation period and the event day. Test the null hypothesis
of zero abnormal return using each of the following statistics:
a. $$t_{ AR }$$
b. $$z_{\textrm{patell}}$$
c. $$t_{\textrm{bmp}}$$
d. $${}^*$$ $$z_{\textrm{sgn}}$$
e. $${}^*$$ $$t_{\textrm{grank}}$$.
References
Aharony, J., and I. Swary. 1980. Quarterly dividend and earnings announcements and stockholders’
returns: An empirical analysis. Journal of Finance 35: 1–12.
[Crossref]
Ashley, J.W. 1962. Stock prices and changes in earnings and dividends. Journal of Political Economy
70: 82–85.
[Crossref]
Baker, C.A. 1956. Effective stock splits. Harvard Business Review 34: 101–106.
Baker, C.A. 1957. Stock splits in a bull market. Harvard Business Review 35: 72–79.
Baker, C.A. 1958. Evaluation of stock dividends. Harvard Business Review 36: 99–114.
Ball, R., and P. Brown. 1968. An empirical analysis of accounting income numbers. Journal of
Accounting Research 6: 159–178.
[Crossref]
Barber, B.M., and J.D. Lyon. 1997. Detecting long-run abnormal stock returns: The empirical power
and specification of test statistics. Journal of Financial Economics 43: 341–372.
[Crossref]
Binder, J.J. 1985. On the use of the multivariate regression model in the event studies. Journal of
Accounting Research 23: 370–383.
[Crossref]
Binder, J.J. 1998. The event study methodology since 1969. Review of Quantitative Finance and
Accounting 11: 111–137.
[Crossref]
Boehme, R.D., and S.M. Sorescu. 2002. The long-run performance following dividend initiations and
resumption: Underreaction or product chance? Journal of Finance 57: 871–900.
[Crossref]
Boehmer, E., J. Musumeci, and A.B. Poulsen. 1991. Event study methodology under conditions of
event induced variance. Journal of Financial Economics 30: 253–272.
[Crossref]
Brockett, P.L., H.-M. Chen, and J.R. Graven. 1999. A new stochastically flexible event methodology
with application to Proposition 103. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics 25: 197–217.
Brown, S.J., and J.B. Warner. 1980. Measuring security price performance. Journal of Financial
Economics 8: 205–258.
Brown, S.J., and J.B. Warner. 1985. Using daily stock returns: The case of event studies. Journal of
Financial Economics 14: 3–31.
[Crossref]
Cameron, A.C., J.B. Gelbach, and D.L. Miller. 2011. Robust inference with multiway clustering.
Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 29: 238–249.
[Crossref]
Campbell, J.Y., A.W. Lo, and A.C. MacKinlay. 1997. The Econometrics of Financial Markets.
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
[Crossref]
Corrado, C. J. 1989. A Nonparametric test for abnormal security-price performance in event studies.
Journal of Financial Economics 23: 385–395.
[Crossref]
Dolley, J.C. 1933. Characteristics and procedure of common stock split-ups. Harvard Business
Review 11: 316–326.
Dutta, A., J. Knif, J.W. Kolari, and S. Pynnonen. 2018. A robust and powerful test of abnormal stock
returns in long-horizon event studies. Journal of Empirical Finance 47: 1–24.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F. 1998. Market efficiency, long-term returns, and behavioral finance. Journal of Financial
Economics 49: 283–306.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 1993. Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds. Journal
of Financial Economics 33: 3–56.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., and K.R. French. 2015. A five-factor asset pricing model. Journal of Financial
Economics 116: 1–22.
[Crossref]
Fama, E.F., L. Fisher, M.C. Jensen, and R. Roll. 1969. The adjustment of stock prices to new
information. International Economic Review 10: 1–21.
[Crossref]
Harrington, S.E., and D.G. Shrider. 2007. All events induce variance: Analyzing abnormal returns
when effect vary across firms. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 42: 229–256.
[Crossref]
Ikenberry, D., J. Lakonishok, and T. Vermaelen. 1995. Market underreaction to open market share
repurchases. Journal of Financial Economics 39: 181–208.
[Crossref]
Jaffe, J.F. 1974. The effect of regulatory changes on insider trading. Bell Journal of Economics and
Management Science 5: 93–121.
Knif, J., J.W. Kolari, and S. Pynnonen. 2008. Stock market reaction to good and bad inflation news.
Journal of Financial Research 31: 141–166.
[Crossref]
Kolari, J.W., and S. Pynnönen. 2010. Event study testing with cross-sectional correlation of abnormal
returns. Review of Financial Studies 23: 3996–4025.
[Crossref]
Kolari, J.W., and S. Pynnönen. 2011. Nonparametric rank tests for event studies. Journal of
Empirical Finance 18: 953–971.
[Crossref]
Kolari, J.W., B. Pape, and S. Pynnonen. 2018. Event study testing with cross-sectional correlation
due to partially overlapping event windows. Mays Business School Research Paper No. 3167271.
Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3167271 or https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3167271.
Kolari, J.W., S. Pynnonen, and A.M. Tuncez. 2021. Further evidence on long-run abnormal returns
after corporate events. Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 81: 421–439.
[Crossref]
Kothari, S.P., and J.B. Warner. 2006. Econometrics of event studies. In Handbook of corporate
finance: Empirical corporate finance, Vol. 1, ed. B.E. Eckbo, Chapter 1, 1–36. Amsterdam: North
Holland.
Lyon, J.D., B.M. Barber, and C.-L. Tsai. 1999. Improved methods for tests of long-horizon abnormal
stock returns. Journal of Finance 54: 165–201.
[Crossref]
MacKinlay, C.A. 1997. Event studies in economics and finance. Journal of Economic Literature 35:
13–39.
Myers, J.H., and A.J. Bakay. 1948. Influence of stock split-ups on market price. Harvard Business
Review 26: 251–265.
Patell, J. 1976. Corporate forecasts of earnings per share and stock price behavior: Empirical tests.
Journal of Accounting Research 14: 246–276.
[Crossref]
Pynnonen, S. 2022. Non-parametric statistic for testing cumulative abnormal stock returns. Journal
of Risk and Financial Management 15: 149. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm15040149.
Schwert, G.W. 1981a. Using financial data to measure the effect of regulation. Journal of Law and
Economics 24: 121–157.
[Crossref]
Schwert, G.W. 1981b. The adjustment of stock prices to information about inflation. Journal of
Finance 36: 15–29.
[Crossref]
Schipper, K., and R. Thompson. 1983. The impact of merger-related regulations on the shareholders
of the acquiring firms. Journal of Accounting Research 21: 184–121.
[Crossref]
Sharpe, S.A. 2001. Reexamining stock valuation and inflation: The impact of analysts’ earnings
forecast. Review of Economics and Statistics 84: 632–648.
[Crossref]
Sunder, S. 1973. Relationship between accounting changes and stock prices: Problem of
measurement and some empirical evidence. Journal of Accounting and Research 11: 1–45.
[Crossref]
Sunder, S. 1975. Stock prices and related accounting changes in inventory valuation. Accounting
Review 50: 305–315.
Footnotes
1 See, for example, Dolley (1933), Myers and Baker (1948), Baker (1956, 1957, 1958), Ashley
(1962), Ball and Brown (1968), and many others.
2 For example, see studies by Sunder (1973, 1975), Aharony and Swary (1980), Binder (1985),
and others.
3 For example, see studies by Schwert (1981a, b), Schipper and Thompson (1983), Brockett et al.
(1999), Sharpe (2001), Knif et al. (2008), and others.
6 In statistical testing, Type I error means falsely rejecting the null hypothesis when it is true (false
alarm), and Type II error means accepting the null hypothesis when it is not true (missed alarm). The
probability of Type I errors is set by the researcher. Typical values are 5% or 1%. The Type II error
probability depends on the Type I error probability, sample size, distribution of the sample statistic,
and the extent to which the true parameter value deviates from the null hypothesis value. Statistical
power is measured by $$1 - \text {Type-II-probability}$$, or the probability of detecting a false
null hypothesis (correct alarm). It is important to use statistical tests that have maximum power in
event studies.
7 The respective standard errors in Eqs. (11.7) and (11.9) are defined as:
$$\begin{aligned} \mathrm {s.e}({\overline{ AR }_0}) = \sqrt{\frac{1}{n(n - 1)} \sum _{i =
1}^n\left( AR _{i0} - \overline{ AR }_0\right) ^2} \qquad {(11.11)} \end{aligned}$$
and
$$\begin{aligned} \mathrm {s.e}({\overline{ CAR }_{\tau _1, \tau _2}}) = \sqrt{\frac{1}{n(n-1)}
\sum _{i = 1}^n\left( CAR _i(\tau _1, \tau _2) - \overline{ CAR }_{\tau _1, \tau _2}\right) ^2}.
\qquad {(11.12)} \end{aligned}$$
8 The standard error used in the CAR t-statistic (11.9) is an example of clustering robust standard
errors (with respect to serial correlation), where the event windows over which individual CARs are
aggregated from the clusters. See Cameron et al. (2011), Dutta et al. (2018), and Kolari et al. (2018)
for further information.
9 With the market model $$R_{it} = \alpha _i + \beta R_{mt} + e_{it}$$, $$d_{it}$$ in
Eq. (11.14) becomes:
$$\begin{aligned} d_{it} = \frac{1}{T} + \frac{(R_{mt} - \bar{R}_m)^2}{\sum _{s = 1}^{T}
(R_{ms} - \bar{R}_m)^2} \end{aligned}$$
and $$d_{i\tau }$$ in Eq. (11.16)
$$\begin{aligned} d_{i\tau } = \tau ^2\left( \frac{1}{T} + \frac{(\bar{R}_{m\tau } -
\bar{R}_m)^2}{\sum _{s = 1}^{T}(R_{ms} - \bar{R}_m)^2}\right) , \end{aligned}$$
where T is the estimation window length, $$\bar{R}_m$$ is the average market return in the
estimation window, and $$\bar{R}_{m\tau }$$ is the average market return in the window over
which CAR is computed. Because calendar times of the event are assumed not overlapping,
estimation and event windows are unique for each stock i, such that we use the subscript i in
$$d_{it}$$ and $$d_{i\tau }$$.
In general, for a factor model with p factors, the correction terms are
$$d_{it} = x_t' (X'X)^{-1}x_t$$ and
$$d_{i\tau } = \tau ^2\bar{x}_\tau ' (X'X)^{-1}\bar{x}_{\tau }$$, where
$$x_t = (1, F_{1t}, \ldots , F_{pt})'$$ includes event time t returns,
$$\bar{x}_{\tau } = (1, \bar{F}_{1\tau }, \ldots , \bar{F}_{p\tau })'$$ includes factor averages
over the CAR-window of length $$\tau$$, and $$(X'X)^{-1}$$ is the inverse of the
$$(p+1)\times (p+1)$$ matrix of estimation window cross-products of the constant term and
factor returns.
10 See Campbell et al. (1997, Chapter 4) for an excellent discussion and further details.
11 Approaches for taking into account cross-sectional correlation with clustering robust estimation
methods as well as estimating the average cross-sectional correlation explicitly in the partial
clustering case are discussed in Kolari et al. (2018).
13 https://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/data_library.html.
15 We should note that, because the number of stocks in each month can vary from 1 to n (the total
number of stocks), weighted least squares are recommended in the regression estimation.
Index
A
Abnormal return (AR) 19, 22, 157, 201–209, 211, 214–219
Accounting variables 165–167
Achilles’ heel 134, 215
Actively managed mutual funds 45, 157
Actual return 187, 188, 198, 203, 205
Actuarial value 23, 34, 36
Adjusted BMP test 208
Adjusted R-squared 67, 74
Adler, Michael 113, 114, 123, 125
Aggregate consumption 116, 117, 119, 121, 124
Aggregate consumption beta 121
Aggregate weights 121
Aharony, J. 202
Alpha term 121, 125
Anomaly 21, 92, 147, 156, 158, 162, 163
Arbitrage 19, 20, 40, 92, 129, 130, 136, 157, 168, 195
Arbitrage portfolio 130–134
Arithmetic mean return 18, 35
Artificial intelligence (AI) 155, 169, 172
Ashley, J.W. 201
Asset pricing anomalies 150, 160, 161, 172
Asset pricing theory (APT model) 130, 132–134, 146, 150
Average market return 61, 182, 184
Average portfolio return 5, 8, 10
Average return 5, 7–9, 11, 62, 91, 97, 140, 141, 161, 166, 182, 184, 186,
217
Axis of symmetry of the parabola 180, 196
B
Back, K. 165
Bad model problem 92
Bakay, A.J. 201
Baker, C.A. 201
Ball, R. 201
Banz, R.W. 140
Barber, B.M. 215, 218
Barberis, M. 92
Barillas, F. 161, 163, 164
Barroso, P. 158
Behavioralists 19, 21, 22, 34, 92, 97, 216
Benchmark asset pricing model 214
Best linear unbiased estimator (BLUE) 69–71, 73, 75
Beta 47
Beta coefficients 71, 91, 92, 108, 124, 141, 143, 152, 165
Beta loading 119, 136, 141, 167
Beta risk 47, 50–54, 57–59, 61–63, 67, 75, 86–88, 91, 92, 98, 108, 111,
120, 129, 139, 148–150, 166, 171, 177, 179, 180, 182–184, 186, 187, 194–
196
Beta risk loadings 141, 148
Bhandari, L.C. 140
Binder, J.J. 202
Black, F. 51, 58, 59, 61, 64, 75, 85–87, 90, 96, 107, 111, 141, 147, 148,
151, 177, 179, 195, 196
Blume, M. 60, 62, 90
BMP test 207
Boehme, R.D. 216
Boehmer, E. 207, 208, 218
Bond market model 144
Book equity to market equity ratio (BM) 91, 140
Breeden, N.D. 115–117, 123–125
Brockett, P.L. 202
Brownian motion 106
Brown, P. 201
Brown, S. 202, 204
Butt, H.A. 177, 195
Buy-and-hold abnormal return (BHAR) 214, 215, 218
C
Calendar time abnormal return (CTAR) 214–216, 219
Cameron, A.C. 71, 76, 80, 206
Campbell, J.Y. 202, 208
Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM) 26, 39, 42, 57
Capital investment factor 159, 163, 171
Capital Market Line (CML) 42, 44, 53, 54, 100
Carhart, M.M. 155–158, 161, 163, 171, 177, 187, 192, 196, 198
Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP) 58, 93, 117, 142, 146, 172,
180, 186, 187, 217
Central Limit Theorem (CLT) 29, 35, 36, 80, 206, 221
Certain return 23, 34
Certainty equivalent 23, 50
Certainty equivalent valuation formula 50, 53
Chen, H.-M. 202
Chen, N.-F. 136, 137
Chordia, T. 193
Clustered event days 209, 223
Clustering robust standard errors 71, 80
CMA factor 159
Cochrane, J.H. 41, 63
Coefficient of determination 73
Common factor 129–131, 133, 134, 146, 147
Computer algorithms 15, 168, 169, 172
Conditional CAPM 105, 109, 120–122, 124
Conditional mathematical model 166, 167, 172
Conditional model 119, 165, 166, 172
Conditional state variables 124
Consumption CAPM (CCAPM) 105, 115, 122, 123
Consumption pattern 115
Continuously compounded return 27, 28, 35
Continuous-time process of asset pricing 106
Control firm 215–217
Copeland, Thomas 49
Corrado, Charles 222
Correlation of returns 4, 46
Covariance of returns 4
2020 COVID-19 pandemic 210, 218
Cross-sectional correlation 208, 209, 223
Cross-sectional regression 61–63, 75, 89, 90, 96, 119, 135, 136, 141, 148,
164, 165, 168, 172, 186, 199
Cross-sectional return 9
Cross-sectional standard deviation of returns 177, 195, 197
Cross-section factor model 166, 169
Cross-section factors 164–168, 172
Cumulative abnormal return (CAR) 203, 209, 211, 218, 222, 223
Currency risk 113, 123
D
Daniel, K. 92, 149, 151, 158
Data dredging exercise 164
Data mining 147, 151
De bondt, W.F.M. 92
Decile portfolios 140
Default risk (DEF) 145
Demand side theory 118
Dempster, A.P. 184
Dependent variable 67–69, 71, 73, 76, 80, 143, 148, 151, 158
Dhrymes, P. 134
Discount rate 2, 11, 40, 41, 50, 52, 159
Discretionary methods 169, 170, 172, 178
Diversifiable unsystematic risk 53
Diversification 1, 6, 7, 9–11, 33, 35, 53, 134, 139, 169
Diversified portfolio 45, 133, 136
Dividend discount model 159, 164
Dolley, J.C. 201
Domestic factors 111
Domestic model 112
Douglas, G.W. 62, 90
Dumas, Bernard 113, 114, 123, 125
Dummy signal variable 184, 196
Dutta, A. 206
Dybvig, P. 134
E
Economic significance 203, 218
Economy-wide events 202
Efficient frontier 8, 9, 11, 42–44, 46, 50, 53, 55, 87, 88, 93–96, 179–181
Efficient market hypothesis (EMH) 20, 34, 92, 97
Efficient portfolio 8, 10, 11, 44, 50, 52, 53, 87, 88, 91, 96, 97, 99, 100, 179
Efficient portfolio I 14, 88
Empirical model 58, 97, 108, 147, 195, 199
Empirical ZCAPM 184–191, 194, 196–198
Endogeneity problem 72, 76, 149, 151
Endogenous portfolio 190
Equilibrium prices 19, 20, 26
Equilibrium relationship between risk and return 51
Error-in-variables 62
Estimation window 63, 185, 203, 204, 207, 208, 211, 212, 218, 222, 223
Euler, Leonard 28
Event 202
Event day 203, 205, 207–209, 211, 212
Event-induce variance 206, 208, 222, 223
Event study 201, 202, 209, 211, 214
Event window 203–207, 209, 211–213, 215, 218, 222, 223
Ex ante return 11, 42, 49
Exchange rate movements 112, 113, 123
Exchange rate puzzle 123
Exchange rate risk 110, 112, 113, 123
Exchange risk exposure coefficient 115
Exogenous portfolio 151
Expectation-maximization (EM) regression 184, 196, 199
Expected lifetime utility 115, 123
Expected rate of return 2, 11, 41, 42, 46, 47, 53, 58, 64
Expected return 2–4, 10, 11, 13, 17, 20, 22, 24, 44, 45, 47, 63, 86, 87, 91,
92, 99, 100, 106, 108, 116–118, 129, 130, 132, 133, 136, 140, 146–150,
179, 180, 184, 203
Expected return of a portfolio 3, 44
Expected utility of wealth 42, 86
Explanatory variable 67–69, 71, 72, 74, 135
Ex post return 4, 11, 41, 49
F
Factor loading 89, 90, 135, 136, 158, 164, 168, 172, 177, 192
Fama, E.F. 21, 34, 50, 58, 61, 62, 75, 88, 90, 92, 96, 117, 135, 141, 148,
164, 167, 172, 177, 188, 192, 194, 196, 201, 202, 204
Ferson, W.E. 89, 91, 120, 167
2008 financial crisis 210, 213, 218
Firm-specific events 202
Fisher, L. 201, 202, 204
Five-factor model 119, 159–163, 165, 168, 171, 172, 204, 211
Four-factor model 155, 156, 158–162, 171, 172, 177, 187, 192
Friedman, M. 22, 23, 34
Friend, I. 60, 62, 90, 134
F-statistic 91, 94, 96
Fundamental economic forces 52
G
Gauss-Markov Theorem 69, 75
Gelbach, J.B. 71, 76, 80, 206
General equilibrium conditions 195
Generalized standardized abnormal return (GSAR) 222
Geometric mean return 18, 36
Gibbons, M.R. 62, 117, 120, 124, 125
Gibbons, Ross, and Shanken (GRS) test 159, 186
Global factors 111
Global minimum variance portfolio G 8, 9, 87
Global model 112
Goodness-of-fit 57, 67, 69, 73
Gordon, M.J. 159
Goyal, A. 193
Graven, J.R. 202
Green, R.C. 88
Griffin, J.M. 111, 123
Gross log return 27
Gross return 18, 27, 28, 157
Gultekin, N.B. 134
H
Hansen, L.P. 120
Harrington, S.E. 206
Harvey, C.R. 120, 192
Hedge portfolio 108, 111, 123, 195
Heteroskedasticity 71, 82
Hidden variable 184
Hirshleifer, D. 92
HML factor 142, 144, 146, 162
Hodrick, R.J. 120
Hollifield, B. 88
Homogeneous beliefs 20, 130
Homoskedasticity 69, 71, 75
Hou, K. 155, 160–162, 171, 172, 178, 187, 194, 196
Huang, J. 9, 99, 148, 177, 182, 184, 192, 194, 195
Huang, J.Z. 177, 195
Huberman, G. 129, 132, 133
I
Idiosyncratic risk 47, 52, 130, 131, 134, 136
Ikenberry, D. 215, 218
Independent variable 62, 68, 69, 71, 74–76, 80, 94, 143, 147–149, 151
Index funds 45, 171
Indifference curve 17, 24, 26, 34, 42, 43, 45
Inefficient portfolio ZI 9
Industry portfolios 95, 148, 149, 151, 159, 178, 190, 192, 195, 196, 210
Inflation rate 113
Ingersoll, J.E. 133
Instrumental variable 72, 76, 124
Integrated world market 109, 123
Interaction terms 166
Intercept term 57, 58, 62, 64, 68, 69, 71, 75, 76, 79, 89, 96, 111, 117, 123,
165
International asset pricing model (IAPM) 109, 123
International Monetary Fund (IMF) 114
Intertemporal CAPM 91, 105–107, 123, 168
Investment-based model 119
Investment/capital ratio 119, 124
Investment expenses 157
Investment opportunity set 46, 106, 107, 109, 111, 120, 123
Investments to assets ratio 160, 194
I* portfolio 181, 199
Irrational investor behavior 92, 97
J
Jaffe, J.F. 216, 219
Jagannathan, R. 88, 141
Jegadeesh, N. 21, 156
Jensen’s alpha 59, 69, 74, 90, 96
Jensen, M.C. 58, 59, 75, 86, 90, 111, 141, 201, 202, 204
Jones, P.N. 184
Jorion 114, 123, 125
K
Kallberg, J.G. 88
Kandel, S. 120
Kapadia, N. 165
Knif, J. 202, 206
Kolari, J.W. 9, 99, 106, 148, 177, 182, 184, 192, 194, 195, 202, 206, 208,
209, 218, 222, 223
Kothari, S.P. 148, 149, 151, 152
Kozak, S. 169
Krishnan, T. 185
Kroll, Y. 88
Kurtosis 18, 31, 32, 34, 35
L
Lagged variable 121
Laird, N.M. 184
Lakonishok, J. 92, 140, 215, 218
Lanstein, R. 140
Latent factor 169, 172
Latent factor model 169
Lettau, M. 121, 122, 124, 155, 167–169, 172
Levy, H. 88
Levy, M. 88
Lewellen, J. 121, 122, 124, 149, 151
Liao, H. 177, 195
Lifetime consumption 106, 109
Linear relation 67, 92, 129, 134, 136, 151
Linnainmaa, J. 193
Lintner, J. 26, 39, 42, 50–53, 57, 139, 177, 195
Litzenberger, R.H. 117, 124, 125
Liu, W. 9, 99, 148, 177, 182, 184, 192, 194, 195
Liu, Y. 192
Load fees 157
Loadings 62, 63, 75, 135, 141, 165
Lo, A.W. 202, 208
Log return 18, 27–30, 34, 35
Long position 86, 88
Long-run event studies 213, 214, 217, 218
Long/short portfolio 89, 136, 142, 164, 178, 196
Lucas, R.E. 115–117, 123
Ludvigson, S. 121, 122, 124
Lyon, J.D. 215, 218
M
MacBeth, J.D. 61, 62, 75, 88, 90, 96, 117, 135, 141, 148, 164, 167, 172,
177, 188, 192, 194, 196
Machine learning methods 155, 169, 171, 172, 178, 197
Machine learning technique 168
MacKinlay, A.C. 202, 208
MacKinlay, C.A. 202
Malkiel, B.G. 21, 34
Management expenses 157
Management factor 161
Man versus machine 172
Marginal rate of substitution 40, 115
Market anomaly 98
Market capitalization 58, 64, 91, 140, 141, 144, 145, 160, 186, 217
Market factor 52, 57, 61, 67, 73, 90–92, 96, 105–108, 111, 118, 120, 121,
123, 136, 139, 141, 142, 144–146, 149, 150, 163, 167, 171
Market imperfections 20, 52
Market model 57–60, 62, 64, 66, 67, 71–76, 86, 88, 90, 96, 109–111, 121,
140, 201
Market portfolio 44–47, 50, 52, 53, 55, 58, 86, 109, 117, 129, 133, 134,
149
Market portfolio proxy 60, 62–64, 74, 75
Market price of risk 62, 63, 75, 123, 141, 164
Markowitz, H.M. 1, 3–8, 10, 11, 13, 17, 18, 20, 22, 24, 26, 39, 42, 50, 53,
58, 62, 74, 88. 90, 96, 150, 177, 195
Ma, T. 88
Matched control firm 216
Mathematical model 165, 172
Matlab program 186
McGrattan, E.R. 141
McLachlan, G.J. 184, 185
McLean, R.D. 193
Mean model 203, 204, 208, 211
Mean-variance parabola 1, 8, 96, 178, 180, 183, 184, 196
Merton, R.C. 91, 97, 100, 105–110, 115, 120, 123, 146, 150, 168, 195
MGMT factor 161
Michaud, R.O. 10
Miller, D.L. 71, 76, 80, 206
Miller, M. 62, 90, 135
Mimicking portfolio 142, 164, 165, 172
Minimum variance portfolios 8, 9, 11, 179
Minimum variance unbiased estimator (MVUE) 71
Mispricing alpha 69, 165
Mispricing error 67, 145, 157, 158, 162, 168, 169, 216
Missing factors 59, 71, 73–75, 89, 90, 96, 111
Model parameters 75, 78, 167
Momentum factor 122, 155–158, 160, 164, 169, 171, 172
Momentum profits 21, 156, 157
MOM factor 163
Morgenstern, O. 22, 34
Moskowitz, T. 158
Mossin, J. 26, 42, 50, 51, 53, 57, 139, 177, 195
M-talk 41
Multicollinearity 71, 144
Multifactor APT model 146, 150
Multifactors 108, 123, 142, 148, 151, 155, 159, 160, 164, 165, 169, 171,
172, 178, 195, 197
Multilateral Exchange Rate Model (MERM) 114
Multinational firms 114, 115, 123
Multiple regression 68–71, 75, 108
Musumeci, J. 207, 208, 218
Mutual funds 156, 157, 171
Myers, J.H. 201
N
Nagel, S. 121, 122, 124, 149, 151, 169
Nallareddy, S.K. 167
Napier, John 28
Negative return dispersion 184, 196
Newey, W. 71, 75, 80
No-arbitrage condition 130, 132, 136
Nobel, Alfred 139
No load mutual fund 157
Nonlinear relation 62
Nonparametric test 204, 221, 223
Nonresidential investments 119
Normal distribution 29–32, 78–80, 85, 204, 221
Normality of returns 130, 221
Normative models 62, 188
Novy-Marx, R. 159
Null hypothesis 71, 79, 80, 93, 94, 205, 206, 215, 216
O
Optimal portfolio weights 15
Ordinary least squares (OLS) regression 57, 58, 184
Orthogonal portfolios 180, 181, 196
Ostdiek, B. 165
Out-of-sample return 196
Overlapping calendar days 209
Overpriced asset 130
P
Pape, B. 206, 209, 223
Parameter 30, 53, 57, 63, 67–69, 73, 76, 105, 124, 192
Parametric test 204, 205, 223
Parsimonious factor model 163
Partial clustering 209
Passively managed mutual funds 157
Patell, J. 207, 208, 218
Patell test 209
Peel, D. 184
Pelger, M. 155, 167–169, 172
Perfect capital market 17–20, 39, 52
Perfect certainty 20, 34
Performance factor 161
Pontiff, J. 193
Population mean 10, 205
Portfolio return 4–6, 10–12, 18, 62, 64, 75, 89, 90, 110, 143, 158, 162, 178,
216
Positive return dispersion 178, 185, 196
Poulsen, A.B. 207, 208, 218
Power 74, 113, 151, 161, 168, 207, 217
Predicted return 188, 203, 205, 214, 218
Present value formula 1, 11, 40, 41, 52
Present value of future cash flows 40
Price taker 20, 34
Principal Component Analysis (PCA) 167
Probability 22, 23, 41, 42, 131, 196
Probability of positive (or negative) return dispersion effect 185
Production CAPM (PCAPM) 105, 118, 124, 171
Profit factor 159, 171
Pulley, L.B. 88
Pynnonen, S. 202, 206, 208, 209, 218, 222, 223
Python program 58, 186
Q
Quadratic utility function 26, 42, 129, 130
q-theory 160
R
Random Walk Hypothesis (RWH) 17, 21, 34, 201
Rank test 223
Realized return 4, 20
Regression analysis 57, 58, 64, 73
Regression coefficient 57, 68–71, 75, 114, 165, 166, 196, 207
Reid, K. 140
Residential gross investments 119
Residual error 62, 149, 201
Return dispersion 148, 177, 178, 182, 183, 186, 194, 195
Return on equity 160, 194
Rise of the machines 169
Risk-adjusted rate of return valuation formula 49, 50, 53
Risk-adjustment 92, 214, 215
Risk averse 2, 9, 23, 24, 34
Risk dimension 41, 108, 135, 167
Riskless asset 42, 44, 46, 50, 86, 87, 107, 110, 133
Riskless rate 2, 11, 41, 42, 44, 47, 50, 52, 53, 57, 72, 85–87, 90, 96, 97,
105–108, 110, 116, 117, 123, 130, 133, 187, 196, 216
Risk loving 22, 24, 34
Risk neutral 22
Risk preference 9, 23, 50, 53, 57, 110
Risk premium 2, 11, 17, 23, 34, 41, 42, 50, 52, 63, 64, 89, 96, 110, 111,
115, 116, 124, 135, 143, 159
Ritov, Y. 88
RMW factor 159, 165
Roberts, M. 193
Robustness 82, 164, 204, 208, 223
Roll critique 59
Roll, R. 134–136, 201, 202, 204
Rosenberg, B. 140
Ross, S.A. 92, 97, 134–136
Rough measures of return dispersion 195, 197
R program 58, 186, 211
R squared 67, 73, 74, 76
Rubin, D.B. 184
S
Sample mean return 135
Sample variance of returns 5
Santa-Clara, P. 158
Santosh, S. 169
Saretto, A. 193
SAS regression software 211
Savage, L. 22, 23, 34
Scaling abnormal returns 201
Schipper, K. 202
Scholes, M. 58, 59, 62, 75, 86, 90, 111, 135, 141
Schwert, G.W. 202
Seasoned equity offering (SEO) 209, 217–219
Security Market Line (SML) 47, 53, 57, 59, 75, 85, 96
Semi-strong form efficiency 21
Shanken, J. 62, 63, 148, 149, 151, 152, 161, 163, 164
Shapiro, A.C. 140
Sharpe, W.F. 26, 39, 42, 46, 57, 74, 97, 139, 177, 195
Shleifer, A. 92
Short-run event studies 202, 204, 209, 214, 218
Short sell 42
Shrider, D.G. 206
Signal variable 184, 185
Simin, T. 122, 167
Simple return 18, 26, 29, 34, 35, 223
Six-factor model 155, 161, 164, 166, 172, 178, 187, 191, 192, 196
Size factor 142, 143, 147, 162–164, 172, 178
Skewness 18, 31, 32, 34, 35, 222
Sloan, R.G. 148, 149, 151, 152
SMB factor 142, 143, 146
Smooth consumption 116
Solnik, B.H. 109–111, 123, 125
Sorescu, S.M. 216
Sorting 60, 163, 187
Span of the parabola 179, 197
Special Drawing Right (SDR) 114
Stable distributions 32
Stambaugh, R.F. 120, 155, 161–163, 171, 178, 187, 194, 196
Standard deviation of returns 3, 5, 7, 11, 17, 42, 44–46, 53, 54, 135
Standard deviation of returns in a portfolio 46
Standard error 60, 63, 71, 76, 79, 80, 205, 206, 215, 222
Standardized abnormal returns 218, 222
Standardized cumulative abnormal return (SCAR) 222
Stata regression software 211
State variable 91, 92, 106–108, 111, 120, 122, 123, 147, 151, 159
Statistical significance 192, 207
Statman, D. 140
Stochastic discount factor 40
Stock splits 27, 64, 201, 202
Strong-form efficiency 21, 34
Subrahmanyam, A. 92
Sunder, S. 202
Supply side theory 118
Survivor bias 148, 151
Swary, I. 202
Systematic risk 47, 52–54, 57, 67, 89, 108, 116, 122, 124, 131, 136, 183,
184, 201
T
Tangent portfolio 50
Taxes 19, 52, 106
Taylor series 30, 121
Technical analysis 21
Term-to-maturity (TERM) 144
Test asset portfolios 88, 144, 148, 149, 160, 161, 178, 186, 187, 192, 194
Test assets 90, 119, 143, 148, 149, 151, 156, 159, 160, 162, 195
Thaler, R.H. 92
Theoretical methods 171, 172
Theoretical (ZCAPM) 171
Thompson, R. 202
Three-factor model 91, 92, 97, 121, 122, 139, 140, 142–147, 149–151, 155,
156, 158, 160, 161, 163, 171, 190, 216
Three-fund theorem 107, 109, 123
Time-series regression 63, 64, 75, 89, 91–93, 96, 111, 118, 123, 135, 147,
150, 158, 186
Time-varying loadings 165
Titman, S. 21, 149, 151, 156
Tobin, J. 24, 26, 34, 39, 42, 44, 50
Total risk 3, 6, 7, 42, 44, 46, 47, 53
Transactions costs 10, 19, 20, 34, 45, 52
Treynor, J.L. 26, 39, 42, 50, 51, 53, 57, 139, 177, 195
Tsai, C.-L. 215, 218
t-statistic 61, 63, 67, 78, 80, 111, 141, 143, 148, 193–196, 205–207
t-test 60, 61, 63, 93, 218
Turnover 157
Two-factor model 96, 108, 111, 146, 196
Two-sided, opposite effects of return dispersion 182
U
Unconditional CAPM 120–122, 124
Uncorrelated 6, 30, 61, 64, 69, 96, 144, 149, 168
Underpriced asset 54, 130
Undiversifiable systematic risk 53
Unsystematic risk 47
Utility 17, 22–24, 26, 34, 42, 50, 115, 117
V
Value factor 91, 92, 97, 111, 121, 122, 142–144, 146, 148, 149, 151, 155,
162, 171, 190, 216
Value-weighted market return dispersion 186
Variance of portfolio returns 4–6, 10–12
Variance of returns 3, 6, 8, 11, 12, 17, 24, 26, 30, 34, 87, 178–181, 196
Vermaelen, T. 215, 218
Vishny, R. 92
Von Neumann, J. 22, 34
W
Warner, J.B. 202, 204
Weak-form efficiency 21
Wealth 18, 43, 51, 91, 117, 123, 147
West, K. 71, 75, 80
Weston, J. Fred 49
White, H. 71, 75, 80
Width of the parabola 9, 180
X
Xie, B. 167
Xue, C. 155, 160–162, 171, 172, 178, 187, 194, 196
Y
Yuan, Y. 155, 161–163, 171, 178, 187, 194, 196
Z
ZCAPM 97, 105, 148, 171, 172, 177, 178, 181, 182, 184, 185, 187, 190–
192, 194–196
Zero-beta CAPM 85, 86, 88–92, 96, 97, 99, 105, 106, 177, 179–182, 195,
196
Zero-beta portfolio 64, 86, 87, 89, 90, 96, 97, 100, 107, 117, 148, 179, 182,
196
Zero-investment portfolio 86, 89, 130, 133, 142, 146, 150, 162, 172, 212
Zeta coefficient 184, 188
Zeta risk 177, 178, 182–184, 186, 187, 195, 196
Zeta risk loadings 187, 194, 196, 198
Zhang, L. 155, 160–162, 171, 172, 178, 187, 194, 196
Zhu, H. 192
Ziemba, W.T. 88
ZI* portfolio 181, 199