0% found this document useful (0 votes)
7 views

GradMicro Pure Exchange Slides

This document provides an example of a general equilibrium model with two consumers and two goods. It defines the structure of the economy including consumer endowments and preferences. It also defines equilibrium concepts such as Walrasian equilibrium, Pareto optimality, and supportability with transfers. Key results shown are the existence of equilibrium, uniqueness under some conditions, and the two fundamental theorems of welfare economics.

Uploaded by

Paulina
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
7 views

GradMicro Pure Exchange Slides

This document provides an example of a general equilibrium model with two consumers and two goods. It defines the structure of the economy including consumer endowments and preferences. It also defines equilibrium concepts such as Walrasian equilibrium, Pareto optimality, and supportability with transfers. Key results shown are the existence of equilibrium, uniqueness under some conditions, and the two fundamental theorems of welfare economics.

Uploaded by

Paulina
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 20

1.

Examples of General Equilibrium Analysis


1.1. Pure Exchange Economy

Main aim:
provide example that contains basic ideas of general equilibrium theory

Literature:
Mas-Colell, A., Whinston, M.D. and J.R. Green (1995), Microeconomic
Theory, Oxford University Press, Chapter 15.B

# 1/20
Basic Structure and Notation
structure of the economy:
I no production, only trade
I two consumers i = 1, 2, two commodities ` = 1, 2
endowment:
I consumer i’s endowment of commodity `: ω`i ∈ R+
I consumer i’s endowment vector: ωi = (ω1i , ω2i ) ∈ R2+
I total endowment of commodity `: ω̄` = ω`1 + ω`2
consumption:
I consumer i’s consumption of commodity `: x`i ∈ R+
I consumer i’s consumption vector: xi = (x1i , x2i ) ∈ R2+
allocation:
I allocation: x = (x1 , x2 ) = ((x11 , x21 ), (x12 , x22 )) ∈ R4
+
I feasible allocation: x is feasible if x`1 + x`2 ≤ ω̄` for ` = 1, 2

I note: free disposal x`1 + x`2 < ω̄` is possible


# 2/20
Edgeworth-Box
I depicts all allocations x with x`1 + x`2 = ω̄` for ` = 1, 2

I examples: ω = endowment, x 6= ω
I note: all allocations in the Edgeworth-box are nonwasteful

# 3/20
Budget
I price of commodity `: p` ∈ R+ ; price vector: p = (p1 , p2 ) ∈ R2+
I consumer i’s wealth: p · ωi = p1 ω1i + p2 ω2i
I consumer i’s budget set: Bi (p ) = {xi ∈ R2+ : p · xi ≤ p · ωi }
I budget sets and budget lines:

# 4/20
Preferences
I consumer i has preference relation %i over consumption vectors xi
I strictly convex, continuous, strongly monotone
I indifference curves:

# 5/20
Demand
I consumer i chooses most preferred consumption vector in Bi (p )
I consumer i’s demand: xi (p, p · ωi ) = (x1i (p, p · ωi ), x2i (p, p · ωi ))
I homogenous of degree 0 in p (→ Why?)
I illustration for consumer 1 (consumer 2 analogous):

# 6/20
Offer Curve
I variation of price vector p → rotation of budget line arround ω
I offer curve of consumer i = set of all xi (p, p · ωi ) for alternative p
I illustration for consumer 1 (consumer 2 analogous):

I tangent to indifference curve through ω, since xi (p, p · ωi ) %i ωi


# 7/20
Excess Demand
I consumer i’s excess demand for commodity `: x`i (p, p · ωi ) − ω`i
I illustration for given price vector p:

I commodity 2 in excess demand: x21 + x22 > ω̄2


commodity 1 in excess supply: x11 + x12 < ω̄1
# 8/20
Walrasian Equilibrium
I Definition 1: A Walrasian (or competitive) equilibrium is a price
vector p ∗ and an allocation x ∗ = (x1∗ , x2∗ ) such that
(1) for i = 1, 2: xi∗ %i xi0 for all xi0 ∈ Bi (p ∗ )
(2) for ` = 1, 2: x`∗1 + x`∗2 = ω̄`
I illustration:

I How to come from disequilibrium on p. 8 to equilibrium above?


# 9/20
Some Properties of Equilibrium
I tangent point of indifference curves (exceptions on edge of the box)
I any intersection of offer curves (except at ω) is an equilibrium:

I equilibrium determines only relative price p1∗ /p2∗


reason: xi (θp ∗ , θp ∗ · ωi ) = xi (p ∗ , p ∗ · ωi ) for any θ > 0
→ if p ∗ = (p1∗ , p2∗ ) is an equilibrium, then θp ∗ = (θp1∗ , θp2∗ ), too
# 10/20
Example I
I consumer i’s preferences: u (x1i , x2i ) = x1αi x21i−α with α ∈]0, 1[
endowment: ω1 = (1, 2) and ω2 = (2, 1)
I consumer 1’s offer curve (check!): wealth is p1 + 2p2
α(p1 + 2p2 ) (1 − α)(p1 + 2p2 )
 
OC1 (p ) = ,
p1 p2
I consumer 2’s offer curve (check!): wealth is 2p1 + p2
α(2p1 + p2 ) (1 − α)(2p1 + p2 )
 
OC2 (p ) = ,
p1 p2
I equilibrium price vector p ∗ = (p1∗ , p2∗ ) clears market for good 1:
α(p1∗ + 2p2∗ ) α(2p1∗ + p2∗ )
+ =3
p1∗ p1∗
p∗ α
I solving: 1∗ =
p2 1−α
I note: p ∗ also clears market for good 2 (check) → Walras’ Law
thus: one equilibrium condition can be ignored
# 11/20
Uniqueness

I above: unique equilibrium


I but: there may be multiple equilibria

# 12/20
Example II
−8
I consumer 1’s preferences: u1 (x11 , x21 ) = x11 − x21 /8
−8
consumer 2’s preferences: u2 (x12 , x22 ) = x22 − x12 /8
endowment: ω1 = (2, r ), ω2 = (r , 2) with r = 28/9 − 21/9
I consumer 1’s offer curve (check!): wealth is 2p1 + rp2
    8/9   −1/9 !
p2 p2 p2
OC1 (p ) = 2 + r − ,
p1 p1 p1
I consumer 2’s offer curve (check!): wealth is rp1 + 2p2
  −1/9     8/9 !
p1 p1 p1
OC2 (p ) = ,2+r −
p2 p2 p2
I equilibrium price vector p ∗ = (p1∗ , p2∗ ) clears market for good 1:
    8/9   −1/9
p2 p2 p1
2+r − + = 2+r
p1 p1 p2
p∗ p∗ p∗
I solving: 1∗ = 0.5 or 1∗ = 1 or 1∗ = 2
p2 p2 p2
# 13/20
Existence
I so far: equilibrium exists
I but: there may be cases where an equilibrium does not exist
I example: non-convex preferences (consumer 1)

I note: no intersection of the offer curves


# 14/20
Pareto Efficiency
I Definition 2: An allocation x is Pareto optimal (or Pareto efficient)
if there is no other allocation x 0 with
(1) xi0 %i xi for all i = 1, 2 and
(2) xi0 i xi for some i = 1, 2.
I illustration:

I if optimum is an interior point: indifference curves are tangent

# 15/20
Pareto Set and Contract Curve
I Pareto set: set of all Pareto optimal allocations
I contract curve: part of the Pareto set where both consumers do at
least as well as at the initial endowment
I illustration:

# 16/20
First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics
I Theorem: Any Walrasian Equilibrium is Pareto efficient!
I repeat illustration of the equilibrium:

I efficiency because no lense between indifference curves


I microeconomic foundation of Adam Smith’s ’invisible hand’
only justification of policy intervention: distributional objectives
# 17/20
Second Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics
I Definition: An allocation x ∗ is supportable as an equilibrium with
transfers if there is a price vector p ∗ and welfare transfers T1 and
T2 satisfying T1 + T2 = 0, such that for all i = 1, 2 we have:
xi∗ %i xi0 for all xi0 ∈ R2+ satisfying p ∗ · xi0 ≤ p ∗ · ωi + Ti .
I Theorem: Any Pareto optimal allocation is supportable as an
equilibrium with transfers (fulfills distributional objectives!).
I illustration for wealth transfers and transfers of endowments:

# 18/20
Non-Convexities
I second welfare theorem does not hold if preferences are non-convex
I illustration: consumer 1 has non-convex preferences

I x ∗ is Pareto efficient, but not supportable as an equilibrium with


transfers (consumer 2 chooses x2∗ , but 1 prefers e.g. x10 )

# 19/20
Exercises

Mas-Colell/Whinston/Green (1995, pp. 540):


I Exercise 15.B.1

I Exercise 15.B.2

I Exercise 15.B.6

# 20/20

You might also like