Eco 431
Eco 431
138
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
COURSE
GUIDE
ECO 431
ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Abuja Office
5 Dar es Salaam Street
Off Aminu Kano Crescent
Wuse II, Abuja
e-mail: [email protected]
URL: www.nou.edu.ng
Published by
National Open University of Nigeria
Printed 2014
ISBN: 978-058-855-9
140
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
CONTENTS PAGE
Introduction………………………………………………. iv
Course Content…………………………………………… iv
Course Aims……………………………………………… iv
Course Objectives………………………………………… v
Working through this Course……………………………... v
Course Materials………………………………………….. v
Study Units……………………………………………….. v
Textbooks and References……………………………….. vi
Assignment File…………………………………………... vi
Presentation Schedule……………………………………. vi
Assessment……………………………………………….. vi
Tutor-Marked Assignments (TMAs)……………………... vii
Final Examination and Grading…………………………... vii
Course Marking Scheme…………………………………. vii
Course Overview………………………………………… viii
How to Get the Most from this Course…………………... viii
Tutors and Tutorials……………………………………… x
Summary………………………………………………… xi
141
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
INTRODUCTION
COURSE CONTENT
COURSE AIMS
There are 16 study units in this course and each unit has its objectives.
You should read the objectives of each unit and bear them in mind as
you go through the unit. In addition to the objectives of each unit, the
overall aims of this course include, to:
142
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
COURSE OBJECTIVES
define both functions of the economy and the power and breadth
of economics
explain consumer utility and consumer surplus
describe the concept of linear programming and welfare
economics.
To successfully complete this course, you are required to read the study
units, referenced books and other materials on the course. Each unit
contains Self-Assessment Exercise (SAE). At some points in the course,
you may be required to submit assignments for assessment purposes. At
the end of the course, there is a final examination.
COURSE MATERIALS
The major components of the course, what you have to do and how you
should allocate your time to each unit in order to complete the course
successfully on time are listed as follows:
1. Course Guide
2. Study Unit
3. Textbook and References
4. Assignment File
5. Presentation Schedule
STUDY UNITS
There are five modules in this course broken into16 study units as
follows:
143
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Each unit contains a list of materials for further reading. Try to get as
many as possible of those textbooks. They are meant to deepen your
knowledge of the course.
ASSIGNMENT FILE
In this file, you will find all the details of the work you must submit to
your tutor for marking. The marks you obtain from these assignments
will count towards the final mark you obtain for this course. Further
information on assignments will be found in the Assignment File itself
and later in this Course Guidein the section on assessment.
PRESENTATION SCHEDULE
144
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
ASSESSMENT
You will be able to complete your assignments from the information and
materials contained in your text books and study units. However, it is
desirable that you demonstrate that you have read and researched more
widely than the required minimum. You should use other references to
have a broad viewpoint of the subject and also to give you a deeper
understanding of the subject.
When you have completed each assignment, send it, together with a
TMA form, to your tutor. Make sure that each assignment reaches your
tutor on or before the deadline given in the Presentation File. If for any
reason, you cannot complete your work on time, contact your tutor
before the assignment is due to discuss the possibility of an extension.
Extensions will not be granted after the due date unless there are
exceptional circumstances.
The final examination for ECO 431 will be of three hours' duration and
have a value of 70% of the total course grade. The examination will
consist of questions which reflect the types of Self-Assessment
Exercises and Tutor-Marked Assignments you have previously
encountered. All areas of the course will be assessed.
Use the time; between finishing the last unit and sitting for the
examination to revise the entire course material. You might find it useful
to review your Self-Assessment Exercises, TMAs and comment on them
before the examination. The final examination covers information from
all parts of the course.
Assessment Marks
145
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Assignment 30%
Final Examination 70%
Total 100%
In distance learning, the study units replace the university lecturer. This
is one of the great advantages of distance learning; you can read and
work through specially designed study materials at your own pace and at
a time and place that suit you best. Think of it as reading the lecture
instead of listening to a lecturer. In the same way that a lecturer might
set you some reading to do, the study units tell you when to read your
books or other materials, and when to embark on discussion with your
colleagues. Just as a lecturer might give you an in-class exercise, your
study units provide exercises for you to do at appropriate points.
Each of the study units follows a common format. The first item is an
introduction to the subject matter of the unit and how a particular unit is
integrated with the other units and the course as a whole. Next is a set of
learning objectives. These objectives let you know what you should be
able to do by the time you have completed the unit.
You should use these objectives to guide your study. When you have
finished the unit, you should go back and check whether you have
achieved the objectives. If you make a habit of doing this you will
significantly improve your chances of passing the course and getting the
best grade.
The main body of the unit guides you through the required reading from
other sources. This will usually be either from your text books or from a
reading section. Some units require you to undertake practical overview
of historical events. You will be directed when you need to embark on
discussion and guided through the tasks you must do.
146
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Once you have created your own study schedule, do everything you can
to stick to it. The major reason that students fail is that they get behind
in their course work. If you get into difficulties with your schedule,
please let your tutor know before it is too late for help.
Turn to Unit 1 and read the introduction and the objectives for the unit.
Assemble the study materials. Information about what you need for a
unit is given in the `introduction' at the beginning of each unit. You will
also need both the study unit you are working on and one of your set
books on your desk at the same time.
Work through the unit. The content of the unit itself has been arranged
to provide a sequence for you to follow. As you work through the unit,
you will be instructed to read sections from your set books or other
articles. Use the unit to guide your reading.
Work before the relevant due date (about 4 weeks before due dates), get
the Assignment File for the next required assignment. Keep in mind that
147
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
you will learn a lot by doing the assignments carefully. They have been
designed to help you meet the objectives of the course and, therefore,
will help you pass the examination. Submit all assignments no later than
the due date.
Review the objectives for each study unit to confirm that you have
achieved them. If you feel unsure about any of the objectives, review the
study material or consult your tutor.
When you are confident that you have achieved a unit's objectives, you
can then start on the next unit. Proceed unit by unit through the course
and try to pace your study so that you keep yourself on schedule.
After completing the last unit, review the course and prepare yourself
for the final examination. Check that you have achieved the unit
objectives (listed at the beginning of each unit) and the course objectives
(listed in this Course Guide).
Your tutor will mark and comment on your assignments, keep a close
watch on your progress and on any difficulties you might encounter, and
provide assistance to you during the course. You should mail your
Tutor-Marked Assignments to your tutor well before the due date (at
least two working days are required). They will be marked by your tutor
and returned to you as soon as possible.
148
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
You should try your best to attend the tutorials. This is the only chance
to have face to face contact with your tutor and to ask questions which
are answered instantly. You can raise any problem encountered in the
course of your study. To gain the maximum benefit from course
tutorials, prepare a question list before attending them. You will learn a
lot from participating in discussions actively.
SUMMARY
149
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
MAIN
COURSE
CONTENTS PAGE
150
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
CONTENTS
1.0 Introduction
2.0 Objectives
3.0 Main Content
3.1 Positive versus Normative Economics
3.2 What is a Market?
3.3 Competitive versus Noncompetitive Markets
3.4 Real versus Nominal Prices
4.0 Conclusion
5.0 Summary
6.0 Tutor-Marked Assignment
7.0 References/Further Reading
1.0 INTRODUCTION
151
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
2.0 OBJECTIVES
152
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
to be whether the tax is in the public interest. The same policy objectives
(say, an increase in tax revenues and a decrease in dependence on
imported oil) might be met more cheaply with a different kind of tax,
such as tariff on imported oil.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
The combination of buyers and sellers forms the market. A market is the
collection of buyers and sellers that, through their actual or potential
interactions, determine the price of a product or set of products. Also,
the term market refers to economic institutions for the
commercialisation of goods and services. It does not basically imply a
location where goods and services are physically exchanged. It implies
the summation of all transactions involving a specific good or service.
In the market for personal computers, for example, the buyers and
business firms, households and students; the sellers are Hawlett-Packard
(HP), Lenovo, Dell, Apple, and a number of other firms. Note that a
market includes more than an industry. An industry is a collection of
firms that sell the same or closely related products. In effect, an industry
is the supply side of the market.
The motivating force that makes the market mechanism to work is the
conflicting interests of selfish buyers and sellers and competition.
Conflicts stems from the fact that the two basic sides of the market have
conflicting interests. Suppliers want to sell at the highest possible prices.
Buyers on the other hand, want to purchase at the lowest possible price.
In a market, all participants want to buy cheap and sell dear. As the
sellers push for the highest possible price and buyers lobby for the
lowest; the resulting conflict between the basic sides of the market is
resolved by competition. In general, prices tends to rise when goods
become scarce, and when they are in abundance, prices tends to fall
because competition will beat the price down. The twin forces of
competition and self-interest make the market to operate effectively.
153
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Sellers will always strive to obtain the highest possible prices for their
products, bearing in mind that if the price is too high, competitors will
make all the sales. Buyers lobby for the lowest possible price while
noting that goods will in the end go to the highest bidder. The prices in
most markets are determined in this manner by these market forces.
Qs = Q d
If the market price is not at equilibrium, market forces drive the market
toward equilibrium. If the market price is at equilibrium, there exists no
market pressure to move to some other level. To better understand this
concept, consider the Figure 1.1.
S1
Qs > Qd1 Surplus
P2
P1 E
P3
Q2 Q1 Q3
154
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
price, sellers are willing to provide more to the market than consumers
are willing to buy. This situation is defined as a surplus. To combat their
rising inventories, sellers begin to lower their prices, attempting to
entice consumers to buy more. In addition, because of the lower price,
sellers decrease the amount they offer for sale. As this process unfolds,
there is an increase in Qd and a decrease in Qs as the market moves to
the equilibrium at point E.
Now consider a market price below the equilibrium value. At the price
P3, the quantity demanded, Q3, exceeds the quantity supplied, Q2,
resulting in a shortage in the market. In response to the shortage,
consumers begin to beat up the price. To understand this process,
consider the process of an auction. An auction usually begins with the
number of willing and able buyers exceeding the amount of product
available. The role of the auctioneer is to bid the price up until Qs = Qd.
As the price increases, consumers begin to drop out of the bidding
process. In the market represented above, consumers begin bidding the
price up and, as a result, some consumers begin to drop out of the
market and Qd begins to fall. As the price begins to increase, sellers who
are willing and able respond by increasing the amount they provide to
the market, and Qs begins to increase. These changes in Qs and Qd
continue until the market reaches equilibrium at a price of P1 and a
quantity of Q1.
155
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
At equilibrium, Qs = Qd =>Qe= Qd – Qs
Equating (1) and (2),
At equilibrium,
46 + px – 2py = -3 + 16py
-px + 18py = 49 (8)
Px = 5 and py = 3
156
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Qex = 35
Qey = 45
Px = 5, Qex = 35
Py = 3, Qey = 45.
There are three main arguments proffered in support of the price system
as a means of resource allocation. They are:
157
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
What if the industry has only one firm? How does the firm behave when it
is a monopolist that differs from its behaviour in a competitive industry?
Because the industry has only one firm, that firm must consider the effect
of its production decisions on the price of its output. The problem is that
when the monopolist produces an additional unit of output it cannot sell
that output at the prevailing price because the prevailing price corresponds
to some point on the demand curve for the product. At that price, the most
consumers are willing to buy some amount, say q0. To sell an addition unit
158
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
of output, the monopolist must cut its price by an amount P for all q0units
of output. This behaviour implies that the marginal revenue associated
with selling an additional unit of output is less than the price that this unit
of output is sold for in the market:
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
We often want to compare the price of goods today with what it was in
the past or is likely to be in the future. To make such a comparison
meaningful, we need to measure prices relative to an overall price level.
In absolute terms, the price of a dozen of oranges is many times higher
today than it was 50 years ago. We need to correct for inflation when
comparing prices across time. This means measuring prices in real rather
than nominal terms. For example, the nominal value of a pen is its
money values in different years. Real values adjust for differences in the
price level in those years i.e. Gross Domestic Product (GDP) and
income. For a series of nominal values in successive years, different
values could be because of differences in general price level. Nominal
value does not specify how much of the differences are from changes in
price level. Real values remove this ambiguity.
Real values convert the nominal values as if prices were held constant in
each year of the series. Any differences in real values are then attributed
to differences in quantities of the good that the money income could buy
in each year. For example, suppose the inflation rate in Nigeria is 3% in
2020. We can buy a basket of onion today (2020) and it will cost 100
naira, or we can buy that basket next year (2021) and it will cost 103
naira. If we buy a bond with a 6% nominal interest rate for 100 naira in
2020, sell it after a year (2021) and get 106 naira, buy a basket of onion
for 103 naira in 2021 from the proceed of the bond, we will have 3 naira
left over. So after factoring in inflation, our 100 naira bond will earn us
3 naira in income in 2021.
159
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Given only the nominal value and price, derivation of a real value is
immediate.
Real prices are defined as prices that have been adjusted for inflation.
The real price in a given month is calculated by dividing the nominal
price (the price observed in the market) by the CPI of that month, where
the CPI is expressed as a ratio and not a percentage. In other words, a
CPI of 150 is expressed as 1.5. Usually, we are most interested in the
changes in real prices over time rather than the level of real prices at one
time. For example, it is not very useful to know that the real price of
maize in June 2008 was say #40 per unit. It is more interesting to know
that, although nominal prices of maize in 2008 increased by 80%, the
real prices of maize increased by only 45%. This implies that, relative to
other prices in the economy, the price of maize rose by 45% over the
year.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
4.0 CONCLUSION
5.0 SUMMARY
161
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
162
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
CONTENTS
1.0 Introduction
2.0 Objectives
3.0 Main Content
3.1 Economic Systems
3.2 Evaluating Economic Performance
3.3 Capitalism and Economic Freedom
4.0 Conclusion
5.0 Summary
6.0 Tutor-Marked Assignment
7.0 References/Further Reading
1.0 INTRODUCTION
2.0 OBJECTIVES
163
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Advantages
The main strength of a traditional economy is that everyone knows
which role to play. Little uncertainty exists over what to produce. If you
are born into a family of hunters, you hunt. If you are born into a family
of farmers, you farm. Likewise, little uncertainty exists over how to
produce, because you do everything the same way your parents did.
Finally, for whom question is determined by the customs and traditions
of the society. Life is generally stable, predictable, and continuous.
Disadvantages
On the other hand, the main drawback of the traditional economy is that
it tends to discourage new ideas and new ways of doing things. The
164
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
How are the questions of what, how and for whom answered in the
traditional economic system?
Advantages
People do not have to worry about what they will study, or where they
will work, or if they might lose their job because these decisions are
made for them. Most command economies tend to provide minimum
levels of education, health, and other public services at little or no cost
to its people.
165
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Disadvantages
Finally, people with new or unique ideas find it difficult to get ahead in
a command economy. Rewards for individual initiative are rare. Each
person is expected to perform a job in a factory, in the bureaucracy, or
on a farm, according to the economic decisions made by central
planners.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
In a market economy, people and firms act in their own best interests to
answer the what, how, and for whom questions. In economic terms, a
market is an arrangement that allows buyers and sellers to come together
in order to exchange goods and services. A market might be in a specific
location, or not. As long as a mechanism exists for buyers and sellers to
get together, a market can exist. In a market economy, people’s
decisions act as votes. When consumers buy a particular product, they
166
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
are casting their naira “votes” for that product. After the “votes” are
counted, producers know what people want. Because producers are
always looking for goods and services that consumers will buy, the
consumer plays a key role in determining what to produce. For example,
many of the largest and most prosperous economies in the world, such
as the United States, Canada, Japan, South Korea, Singapore, Germany,
France, Great Britain, and other parts of Western Europe, are based on
the concept of a market economy. While there are also many significant
differences among these countries, the common thread of the market
binds them together.
Advantages
167
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Disadvantages
Finally, market economies can fail if three conditions are not met.
First, markets must be reasonably competitive, allowing producers to
compete with one another to offer the best value for the price. Second,
resources must be reasonably free to move from one activity to another.
Workers, for example, need the freedom to change jobs if they have a
better opportunity elsewhere. Producers need the freedom to produce
goods and services in the best way they know how. Third, consumers
need access to adequate information so that they can weigh the
alternatives and make wise choices. When markets fail, some businesses
become too powerful and some individuals receive incomes much larger
than that justified by their productivity. Because of this, we often have
to rely on government to ensure that sufficient competition, freedom of
resource movement, and adequate information exist.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
168
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Every economic system has goals such as financial security and freedom
to carry out economic choices. Goals are important because they serve
as benchmarks that help us to determine if the system meets most if not
all of our needs. If the system falls short, then we may demand laws to
change the system until the needs are met.
People share many broad social and economic goals. While it might be
difficult to find them listed in any one place, they are repeated many
times in the statements that friends, relatives, community leaders, and
elected officials make. We can categorise those statements into seven
major economic and social goals.
Economic Freedom
In Nigeria and mostly the United States, people place a high value on
the freedom to make their own economic decisions. People like to
choose their own occupations, employers, and uses for their money.
Business owners like the freedom to choose where and how they
produce. The belief in economic freedom, like political freedom, is one
of the cornerstones of American society.
Economic Efficiency
Most people recognise that resources are scarce and that factors of
production must be used wisely. If resources are wasted, fewer goods
and services will be produced and fewer wants and needs can be
satisfied. Economic decision making must be efficient so that benefits
gained are greater than costs incurred.
Economic Equity
Many people, for example, believe in equal pay for equal work. As a
result, it is illegal to discriminate on the basis of age, sex, race, religion,
or disability in employment. When it comes to selling products, most
people feel that advertisers should not be allowed to make false claims
about their products.
Economic Security
169
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Full Employment
When people work, they earn income for themselves while they produce
goods and services for others. If people do not have jobs, however, they
cannot support themselves or their families, nor can they produce output
for others. As a result, people want their economic system to provide as
many jobs as possible.
Price Stability
Economic Growth
The last major goal of most Nigerians is economic growth. Most people
hope to have a better job, a newer car, better clothes, their own home,
and a number of other things in the future. Growth is needed so that
people can have more goods and services. Because the nation’s
population is likely to grow, economic growth is necessary to meet
everyone’s needs.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
170
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
1. Economic Freedom
2. Voluntary Exchange
171
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
incentives to work, save, and invest. When people are free to do as they
wish with their property, they are not afraid to use, accumulate, or lend
it. Private property gives people the incentive to be successful; they
know that if they succeed they will be able to keep any rewards they
might earn.
4. Profit Motive
Under free enterprise and capitalism, people are free to risk their savings
or any part of their wealth in a business venture. If the venture goes well
for them, they will earn rewards for their efforts. If things go poorly,
they could lose part or all of their investment. The very possibility of
financial gain, however, encourages many people to become
entrepreneurs, or those who risk entering business in hopes of earning a
profit.
5. Competition
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
172
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
4.0 CONCLUSION
5.0 SUMMARY
The unit focused on decision making and the economic system. The
topic captures the different economic systems with emphasis on
traditional, command and the market economic system. The traditional
economy is based on customs and ethics, command system is a centrally
planned economy, while the market system is characterised by minimal
government interventions. The strength and weaknesses of those
economic systems were also discussed.
173
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
174
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
CONTENTS
1.0 Introduction
2.0 Objectives
3.0 Main Content
3.1 Comparative Static
3.2 The Dynamic Analysis
4.0 Conclusion
5.0 Summary
6.0 Tutor-Marked Assignment
7.0 References/Further Reading
1.0 INTRODUCTION
2.0 OBJECTIVES
175
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
P
S
D2
D1 e2
P2
e1
P1
Q1 Q2 Q
Using Figure 1.2 for example, the initial equilibrium position, price and
quantity for the market is e1, P1 and Q1 respectively. Assuming there is
an expansion in demand over time, this will lead to a new equilibrium at
e2, which is higher than the initial equilibrium. Under comparative
statics, the focus is on comparing these two equilibriums without regard
to the process of adjustment from one equilibrium to another.
176
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
Explain the comparative statics model and its application for profit
maximisation.
177
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
D
Q
Q1 Q3 Q2
178
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
S
P3
P2
D
Q
Q3 Q1 Q2
The Model
The cobweb model is based on a time lag between supply and demand
decisions. Agricultural markets are a context where the cobweb model
might apply, since there is a lag between planting and harvesting.
Suppose that as a result of unexpectedly bad weather, farmers go to
market with an unusually small crop of produce. This shortage,
equivalent to a leftward shift in the market's supply curve, results in high
prices. If farmers expect these high price conditions to continue, then in
the following year, they will raise their production relative to other
crops. Therefore when they go to market the supply will be high,
resulting in low prices. If they then expect low prices to continue, they
will decrease their production for the next year, resulting in high prices
again. This process is illustrated in the first diagram. The equilibrium
price is at the intersection of the supply and demand curves. A poor
harvest in Period 1 means supply falls to Q1, so that prices rise to P1. If
producers plan their Period 2.
Productions under the expectation that this high price will continue, and
then the Period 2 supply will be higher, at Q2. Prices therefore fall to P2
when they try to sell all their output. As this process repeats itself,
oscillating between periods of low supply with high prices and then high
supply with low prices, the price and quantity trace out a spiral. They
may spiral inwards, as in the first figure, in which case the economy
converges to the equilibrium where supply and demand cross; or they
may spiral outwards, with the fluctuations increasing in magnitude.
Simplifying, the cobweb model can have two main types of outcomes:
179
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
(i) If the supply curve is steeper than the demand curve, then the
fluctuations decrease in magnitude with each cycle, so a plot of
the prices and quantities over time would look like an inward
spiral, as shown in the first diagram. This is called the stable or
convergent case.
(ii) If the slope of the supply curve is less than the absolute value of
the slope of the demand curve, then the fluctuations increase in
magnitude with each cycle, so that prices and quantities spiral
outwards. This is called the unstable or divergent case.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
4.0 CONCLUSION
5.0 SUMMARY
180
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
181
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
CONTENTS
1.0 Introduction
2.0 Objectives
3.0 Main Content
3.1 Individual and Market Demand
3.2 Normal versus Inferior Goods
3.3 Substitution and Complements
3.4 Consumer Surplus
4.0 Conclusion
5.0 Summary
6.0 Tutor-Marked Assignment
7.0 References/Further Reading
1.0 INTRODUCTION
2.0 OBJECTIVES
182
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
10
D
Q
2
Fig. 2.1: The Demand4 Curve
183
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
b1 b2 B
P1
a2
a1
A
P2
d2 D*
d1
Q
Fig. 2.2: Derivation of Market Demand Curve
There are several factors that influence individual and market demand.
Individual demand is influenced by an individual’s age, sex, income,
habits, expectations and the prices of competing goods in the
marketplace. Market demand is influenced by the same factors, but on a
184
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
When the income consumption curve has a positive slope, the quantity
demanded increases with incomes. As a result, the income elasticity of
demand is positive. The greater the shift to the right of the demand
curve, the larger the income elasticity. In this case, the goods are
described as normal (consumers want to buy more of them as their
income increases).
CF
15
Income Consumption Curve
10 C
U3
B
5
U2
A U1
G
5 10 20 30
CF = Corn-Flakes G = Garri
Fig. 2.3: Income vs. Consumption
185
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Good X
IC1 IC2
X1
X2
BC1
Good Y
Y1 Y2 BC2
Fig. 2.4: Indifference Curve (IC = Indifference
Curve BC = Budget Constraint)
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
Describe the inferior and normal goods using indifference curve and
income consumption curve
The demand curve shows the relationship between the price of a good
and the quantity demanded, with preferences, income, and prices of
other goods held constant. Examples of complementary goods are
football boot and football, bread and tea, computer hardware and
186
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
software, etc. other goods such as Milo and Bournvita, flour and wheat,
movie ticket and DVD disk, tend to substitute for one another. Two
goods are substitutes if an increase in the price of one leads to an
increase in the quantity demanded of the other. If the price of a movie
ticket rises, we would expect individuals to rent or buy more DVD discs,
because movie ticket and DVD disc are substitutes. Similarly, two goods
are complements if an increase in the price of one good leads to a
decrease in the quantity demanded of another good. For example, if the
price of petrol goes up, causing petrol consumption to fall, we would
expect the consumption of motor oil to fall as well, because petrol and
motor oil are used together. Two goods are however independent if a
change in the price of one good has no effect in the quantity demanded
of the other.
187
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
where consumer surplus is the sum, over all units, of the excess of the
maximum willingness to pay over the equilibrium (market) price. The
consumer's surplus is highest at the largest number of units for which,
even for the last unit, the maximum willingness to pay is not below the
market price. Figure 2.5 depicts the consumer surplus.
Consumer Surplus
Q
8
Figure 2.5: Consumer Surplus
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
4.0 CONCLUSION
From our discussion so far on the theory of demand, we can infer the
following:
income, taste, price and other prices are the major determinants
of demand according to the traditional theory of demand
individual demand is different from market demand, and for
market demand to hold, individual demand must be summed
together
as income increases, proportion of income spent on inferior good
tends to reduce and vice versa
when two goods are used together, and the use of one does not
reduce the use of another, those goods are tagged complimentary
goods otherwise substitutes.
consumer surplus occurs whenever a consumer pay below the
price he is willing to pay for a good.
5.0 SUMMARY
Submit an essay of two pages (A4, 1.5 spacing, 12pts, Times New
Roman Font) on the theory of demand, analysis of consumer surplus
using demand curve diagram, inferior and normal good using Income-
Consumption curve and the Indifference Curve.
189
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
CONTENTS
1.0 Introduction
2.0 Objectives
3.0 Main Content
3.1 Elastic Demand
3.2 Inelastic Demand
3.3 Price Elasticity of Demand
3.4 Arc Elasticity of Demand
3.5 Income Elasticity of Demand
3.6 Cross Elasticity of Demand
4.0 Conclusion
5.0 Summary
6.0 Tutor-Marked Assignment
7.0 References/Further Reading
1.0 INTRODUCTION
190
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
2.0 OBJECTIVES
P1
P2
DD
Q
Q1 Q2
Fig. 2.6: Elastic Demand
P2 = N8
Q1 = 30
191
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Q2 = 50
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
Price
P1
P2
Demand
Q1 Q2 Quantity
Fig. 2.7: Inelastic Demand
P1 = N12
P2 = N6
Q1 = 40
Q2 = 50
= 10÷90 / 6÷18
This does not mean that the demand for an individual producer is
inelastic. For example, a rise in the price of petroleum at all stations may
192
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
P0 = 9
P1 = 10
Q0 = 150
Q1 = 110
Where P0 and Q0 represent the old price and quantity and P1 and Q1
represent the new price and quantity. To calculate the price elasticity, we
need to know what the percentage change in quantity demand is and
what the percentage change in price is. It's best to calculate this one at a
time.
Applying the (1) and (2) to the PED formula gives the PED figure.
PED = (-0.2667) / (0.1111) = -2.4005.
193
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
The arc elasticity is the elasticity of one variable with respect to another
between two given points. It is the ratio of the percentage change of one
of the variables between the two points to the percentage change of the
other variable. It contrasts with the point or price elasticity, which is the
limit of the arc elasticity, as the distance between the two point
approaches zero and which hence, is defined at a single point rather for a
pair of points.
Ex,y=
% change in x =
% change in y =
194
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
For example, suppose that the two points on a demand curve, (Q1, P1)
and (Q2, P2) are known, the arc elasticity is obtained using the formula:
Ep =
Suppose that the change in the price of meat-pie, which led to this
change in quantity demanded from 80 to 120, was from N3 to N1. The
percent change in price measured against the midpoint would be (1-3)/2
= -100%, so the price elasticity of demand is 40%/(-100%) or -40%. It is
common to refer to the absolute value of the price elasticity as simply
price elasticity, since for a normal (decreasing) demand curve the
elasticity is always negative and so the "minus" part can be made
implicit. Thus the demand of the football fans for meat-pie has 40%
elasticity.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
195
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
196
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
Or
Where:
197
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
4.0 CONCLUSION
From our discussion so far on the elasticity of demand, we can infer the
following:
5.0 SUMMARY
198
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
2. P1 = 5, P2 = 7
Q1 = 4, Q2 = 2
Using the above information, calculate:
199
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
CONTENTS
1.0 Introduction
2.0 Objectives
3.0 Main Content
3.1 The Concept of Budget
3.2 The Concept of Budget Constraint
3.3 Properties of the Budget Set
3.4 How the Budget Line Changes
3.5 Implication of Taxes and Subsidies on Budget
4.0 Conclusion
5.0 Summary
6.0 Tutor-Marked Assignment
7.0 References/Further Reading
1.0 INTRODUCTION
2.0 OBJECTIVES
200
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
microeconomic concept that shows the tradeoff made when one good is
exchanged for another. In other words, a budget is an important concept
in microeconomics, which uses a budget line to illustrate the trade-offs
between two or more goods.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
We suppose that we can observe the prices of the two goods, (pl and p2),
and the amount of money the consumer has to spend, m. Then the
budget constraint of the consumer can be written as:
(1)
201
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
(2)
This expression simply says that the amount of money spent on Good 1,
p1x1, plus the amount of money spent on all other Goods, x2, must be no
more than the total amount of money the consumer has to spend, m.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
202
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Budget set consist of all bundles that are affordable at the given prices
and income. The budget line is the set of bundles that cost exactly m:
(3)
These are the bundles of goods that just exhaust the consumer's income.
The budget set is depicted in diagram below. The downward sloping line
is the budget line which also represents the bundles that cost exactly m,
and the bundles below this line are those that cost strictly less than m.
x2
Vertical
intercept Budget line slope = -p1/p2
= m/p2
x1
Horizontal intercept = m/pt
Fig. 2.7a: Budget Line Analysis
(4)
The above formula tells us how many units of Good 2 the consumer
needs to consume in order to just satisfy the budget constraint if she is
consuming xl units of Good 1.
Here is an easy way to draw a budget line given prices (pl , p2) and
income m. The question of how much of Good 2 the consumer could
buy if she spent all of her money on Good 2 is then asked. The answer
is, of course, m/p2. Then ask how much of Good 1 the consumer could
buy if she spent all of her money on Good 1. The answer is m/pl. Thus,
the horizontal and vertical intercepts measure how much the consumer
could get if she spent all of her money on Goods 1 and 2, respectively.
203
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
And
This says that the total value of the change in her consumption must be
zero. Solving for ∆x2/∆xl, the rate at which Good 2 can be substituted
for Good 1 while still satisfying the budget constraint, gives:
This is just the slope of the budget line. The negative sign is there since
∆xl and ∆x2 must always have opposite signs. If you consume more of
Good 1, you have to consume less of Good 2 and vice versa if you
continue to satisfy the budget constraint.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
When prices and incomes change, the set of goods that a consumer can
afford changes as well. To determine how these changes affect the
budget set, we will have to consider changes in income. It is easy to see
from equation (4) that an increase in income will increase the vertical
intercept and not affect the slope of the line. Thus, an increase in income
will result in a parallel shift outward of the budget line as in Figure 2.7b.
Similarly, a decrease in income will cause a parallel shift inward.
204
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
x2
m1/p2
Budget lines
m/p2
Slope = -p1/p2
x1
m/p1 m1/p1
Fig. 2.7b: Budget Line Analysis
Another way to see how the budget line changes is to use the trick
described earlier for drawing the budget line. If you are spending all of
your money on Good 2, then increasing the price of Good 1 does not
change the maximum amount of Good 2 you could buy, thus the vertical
intercept of the budget line does not change. But if you are spending all
of your money on Good 1, and Good 1 becomes more expensive, then
your consumption of Good 1 must decrease. Thus the horizontal
intercept of the budget line must shift inward, resulting in the Figure
2.7c.
X2
m/p2
Budget Line
Slope=-p1/p2
Slope=-p11/p2
X1
m/p11 m/p1
205
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
What happens to the budget line when the prices of Good 1 and Good 2
change at the same time? Suppose for example that we double the prices
of both Goods 1 and 2. In this case, both the horizontal and vertical
intercepts shift inward by a factor of one-half, and therefore the budget
line shifts inward by one-half as well. Multiplying both prices by two is
just like dividing income by 2. We can also see this algebraically.
Suppose our original budget line is:
Now suppose that both prices become t times as large. Multiplying both
prices by t yields:
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
Highlight and explain the factors that cause changes in budget line.
206
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
naira per unit of Good 1 simply changes the price of Good 1 from pl to
pl+ t. This implies that the budget line must get steeper.
Another kind of tax is a value tax. As the name implies, this is a tax on
the value-the price-of a good, rather than the quantity purchased of a
good. A value tax is usually expressed in percentage terms. Consider for
example if the sales tax is 6 per cent, then a good that is priced at #1
naira will actually sell for #1.06. (Value taxes are also known as ad-
valorem taxes).If Good 1 has a price of pl but is subject to a sales tax at
rate 7, then the actual price facing the consumer is (1 + t)pl. The
consumer has to pay pl to the supplier and tpl to the government for each
unit of the good. Therefore, the total cost of the good to the consumer is
(1 + t)pl.
We can see that taxes and subsidies affect prices in exactly the same
way except for the algebraic sign: a tax increases the price to the
consumer, and a subsidy decreases it. Another kind of tax or subsidy
that the government might use is a lump sum tax or subsidy. In the case
of a tax, this means that the government takes away some fixed amount
of money, regardless of the individual's behaviour. Thus, a lump-sum
tax means that the budget line of a consumer will shift inward because
his money income has been reduced. Similarly, a lump-sum subsidy
means that the budget line will shift outward. Quantity taxes and value
taxes tilt the budget line one way or the other depending on which good
is being taxed, but a lump-sum tax shifts the budget line inward.
207
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
budget set of the consumer would look like that depicted in the diagram
below: it would be the old budget set with a piece lopped off. The
lopped-off piece consists of all the consumption bundles that are
affordable but have xl> x1*.
x2
Budget line
Budget
set
x1
X1*
Fig. 2.7d: Budget Line Analysis
x2
Budget line
Slope = -p1/p2
Budget
set Slope = -(p1 + t)/p2
x1
X1*
Fig. 2.7e: Budget Line Analysis
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
What are the effects of subsidy and taxes on the budget line?
208
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
4.0 CONCLUSION
5.0 SUMMARY
The budget set consists of all bundles of goods that the consumer can
afford at given prices and income. We assumed that there are only two
goods, but this assumption is more general than it seems. The budget
line is written as plxl +p2x2 = m. It has a slope of -pl/p2, a vertical
intercept of m/p2, and a horizontal intercept of m/pl. Increasing income
shifts the budget line outward. Increasing the price of good 1 makes the
budget line steeper. Increasing the price of good 2 makes the budget line
flatter. Taxes, subsidies, and rationing change the slope and position of
the budget line by changing the prices paid by the consumer.
209
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
equation for the new budget line in terms of the original prices
and income.
210
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
CONTENTS
1.0 Introduction
2.0 Objectives
3.0 Main Content
3.1 Cardinal Utility Theory
3.2 Ordinal Utility Theory
3.3 Diamond-Water Paradox
3.4 Principle of Optimisation
4.0 Conclusion
5.0 Summary
6.0 Tutor-Marked Assignment
7.0 References/Further Reading
1.0 INTRODUCTION
2.0 OBJECTIVES
211
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Assumptions
212
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
There are three basic weaknesses in the cardinalist approach. They are:
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
MUx = Px
If the marginal utility of x is greater than its price, the consumer can
increase his welfare by purchasing more of unit x. Similarly, if the
marginal utility of unit x is less than its price, the consumer will increase
his total satisfaction by cutting down the quantity of x and keeping more
of his income unspent. Therefore, he attains the maximisation of his
utility when MUx = Px. If there are more commodities, the condition for
the equilibrium of the consumer is the equality of the ratios of the
marginal utilities of the individual commodities to their prices:
213
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Total Utility
Total utility, as the term indicates, is the utility derived from all units of
a commodity consumed. Suppose that a person consumes 10 oranges. In
this case, the total utility is obtained by adding the utility derived from
each unit of orange. In our example (Table below), the total utility
derived from the first six oranges is 21 (21 = 6 + 5 + 4 + 3 + 2 + 1).
Marginal Utility
Symbolically,
MU =ΔTU/ΔC where,
TU = total utility
ΔTU = change in total utility (TUn – TUn-1)
C = consumption and ΔC = 1 unit or
Symbolically,
Where,
In our example (Table 2.1), the marginal utility of the 4th orange is
MU4 = TU4 – TU3= 18 – 15 = 3. Figure 2.8 details the path of total
utility and marginal utility curves. The total utility curve rises initially
and after certain stage, the curve starts declining. At this stage, the
marginal utility curve enters into the negative zone.
214
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
TU
&
MU
TU
No of Oranges
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
The law of diminishing marginal utility states that the utility derived
from each successive unit of a commodity diminishes. To put it simply,
even the most beautiful place of the world or the sweetest music can
make you feel bored after certain stage. The law further states that when
an individual consumes more of a commodity the total utility increases
at a decreasing rate. However, after certain stage, the total utility also
starts decreasing and the marginal utility becomes negative (Table 2.1).
This means that the individual does not need the commodity further.
215
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
she consumes more and more of it. After certain stage, the individual is
not willing to consume the commodity anymore.
Rationality: For the law to hold well, the consumer must be a rational
economic man. In addition, the law assumes that the consumer’s mental
condition remains normal during the process of consumption.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
216
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Assumptions
Symbolically,
If A > B, then B ≯A
> = Greater than
≯ = Not Greater than.
217
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
A1
Z
W N
x
0 x2 B B1 C
x1 x3
Fig. 2.9: The Revealed Preference
218
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
If A > B, then B ≯ A
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
219
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Assumptions
Indifference Curves
III
II
I
x
220
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
221
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
y
Substitution Effect
Income Effect
A
II
0 x
x1 x11 B x2 b1
Fig. 2.10b: Indifference Curve showing Income and
Substitution Effect
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
223
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
3.4.1 Introduction
224
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
The equilibrium principle: Prices adjust until the amount that people
demand of something is equal to the amount that is supplied.
Let us consider these two principles. If people are free to choose their
actions, it is reasonable to assume that they will try to choose things they
want rather than things they don't want. Of course there are exceptions
to this general principle, but they typically lie outside the domain of
economic behaviour. The second notion is a bit more problematic. It is
at least conceivable that at any given time peoples' demands and
supplies are not compatible, and hence something must be changing.
These changes may take a long time to work themselves out, and, even
worse, they may induce other changes that might "destabilise" the whole
system.
This kind of thing can happen, but it usually doesn't. In the case of
apartments, we typically see a fairly stable rental price from month to
month. It is this equilibrium price that we are interested in, not in how
the market gets to this equilibrium or how it might change over long
periods of time. It is worth observing that the definition used for
equilibrium may be different in different models. In the case of the
simple market we will examine here, the demand and supply equilibrium
idea will be adequate for our needs. Typically, equilibrium will require
that the economic agents' actions must be consistent with each other.
How do we use these two principles to determine the answers to the
questions we raised above?
225
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Suppose that the next highest price that anyone is willing to pay is #490.
Then if the market price were #499, there would still be only one
apartment rented: the person who was willing to pay #500 would rent an
apartment, but the person who was willing to pay #490 would not. And
so it goes. Only one apartment would be rented if the price were #498,
#497, #496, and so on until we reach a price of #490. At that price,
exactly two apartments would be rented: one to the #500 person and one
to the #490 person. Similarly, two apartments would be rented until we
reach the maximum price that the person with the third highest price
would be willing to pay, and so on.
Here, the price is depicted on the vertical axis and the number of people
who are willing to pay that price or more is depicted on the horizontal
axis. Another way to view the diagram is to think of it as measuring how
many people would want to rent apartments at any particular price. Such
a curve is an example of a demand curve-a curve that relates the quantity
demanded to price. When the market price is above #500, zero
apartments will be rented. When the price is between #500 and #490,
one apartment will be rented. When it is between #490 and the third
highest reservation price, two apartments will be rented, and so on. The
demand curve describes the quantity demanded at each of the possible
prices.
226
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Reservation Price
No of Apartments
Fig. 2.10c: Demand Side Analysis
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
Here we have to think about the nature of the market we are examining.
The case to consider here is where there are many independent landlords
who are out to rent their apartments for the highest price the market will
bear. We will refer to this as the case of a competitive market. Other
sorts of market arrangements are certainly possible. Consider the case
where there are many landlords who all operate independently. It is clear
that if all landlords are trying to do the best they can and if the renters
are fully informed about the prices the landlords charge, then the
equilibrium price of all apartments in the inner ring must be the same.
The argument is not difficult. Suppose instead that there is some high
price, ph, and some low price, pl, being charged for apartments. The
people who are renting their apartments for a high price could go to a
landlord renting for a low price and offer to pay a rent somewhere
between ph and pl. A transaction at such a price would make both the
renter and the landlord better off. To the extent that all parties are
seeking to further their own interests and are aware of the alternative
prices being charged, a situation with different prices being charged for
the same good cannot persist in equilibrium. But what will this single
equilibrium price be? Consider a situation where a price is picked, and
question on how many apartments will be supplied at that price was
asked.
227
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
The answer depends to some degree on the time frame in which we are
examining the market. If we are considering a time frame of several
years, so that new construction can take place, the number of apartments
will certainly respond to the price that is charged. But in the "short run"-
within a given year, say the number of apartments is more or less fixed.
Reservation Price
Supply
s No of Apartments
Fig. 2.10d: Supply Side Analysis
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
We now have a way of representing the demand and the supply side of
the apartment market. Let us put them together and ask what the
equilibrium behaviour of the market is. We do this by drawing both the
demand and the supply curve on the same graph (Figure 2.10e).
228
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Reservation Price
Supply
p* Demand
s No of Apartments
Fig. 2.10e: Market Equilibrium
In this graph, we have used p* to denote the price where the quantity of
apartments demanded equals the quantity supplied. This is the
equilibrium price of apartments. At this price, each consumer who is
willing to pay at least p* is able to find an apartment to rent, and each
landlord will be able to rent apartments at the going market price.
Neither the consumers nor the landlords have any reason to change their
behaviour. This is why we refer to this as equilibrium; no changes in
behaviour will be observed.
Similarly, suppose that the price of apartments is some p greater than p*.
Then some of the apartments will be vacant: there are fewer people who
are willing to pay p than there are apartments. Some of the landlords are
now in danger of getting no rent at all for their apartments. Thus they
will have an incentive to lower their price in order to attract more
renters.
If the price is above p* there are too few renters; if it is below p* there
are too many renters. Only at the price p* is the number of people who
229
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
At the price p* the landlords' and the renters' behaviours are compatible
in the sense that the number of apartments demanded by the renters at p*
is equal to the number of apartments supplied by the landlords. This is
the equilibrium price in the market for apartments.
Once we have determined the market price for the inner-ring apartments,
we can ask who ends up getting these apartments and who is exiled to
the farther-away apartments. In the market equilibrium, everyone who is
willing to pay p* or more gets an apartment in the inner ring, and
everyone who is willing to pay less than p* gets one in the outer ring.
The person who has a reservation price of p* is just indifferent between
taking an apartment in the inner ring and taking one in the outer ring.
The other people in the inner ring are getting their apartments at less
than the maximum they would be willing to pay for them. Thus the
assignment of apartments to renters is determined by how much they are
willing to pay.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
4.0 CONCLUSION
230
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
5.0 SUMMARY
This unit focused on consumer behaviour, and topics that capture how
rational consumers behave were discussed. In particular, ordinal and
cardinal utility theory was discussed, with special attention to the
quantification of utility through marginal and diminishing marginal
utility, before countering it with revealed preference hypothesis and the
indifference curves. The concept of diamond-water paradox was visited
in order to better understand the theory of value, and why diamond
commands higher price than water which is essential to life. Finally, the
principle of optimisation which focuses on the rationality of consumers
and decision maker in the economy was discussed. Consumers want to
maximise their utility while firms want to minimise their cost of
production. In order to analyse these two concepts, the demand and
supply side analysis was applied to apartment demand in order to arrive
at equilibrium.
231
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
CONTENTS
1.0 Introduction
2.0 Objectives
3.0 Main Content
3.1 Laws of Production
3.2 The Production Process
3.3 Production Function
3.4 Technological Progress
3.5 Objectives of a Firm
3.6 Equilibrium of the Firm
3.7 Substitution among Inputs
3.8 Diminishing Marginal Returns
3.9 Diminishing Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution
4.0 Conclusion
5.0 Summary
6.0 Tutor-Marked Assignment
7.0 References/Further Reading
1.0 INTRODUCTION
Put differently, the technical conditions facing the firm are summarised
in the production function. The production function is a mathematical
statement of the physical relationship given by technology, between a
232
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
firm’s input of productive resources and its output of goods and services
per unit of time. A firm’s production function establishes the
relationship between the rate of flow of output and the rate of flow of
corresponding inputs needed to produce it, given existing technology.
Where X1, X2, X3, …,Xn represents quantities of various inputs and Q
represents the quantity of goods they can generate per unit of time.
2.0 OBJECTIVES
The law of variable proportions states that, “in the short run, output
will change as one input is varied while the others are held constant.”
For example, if you are preparing a meal, you know that a little bit of
salt will make the food taste better. A bit more may make it tastier still.
Yet, at some point, too much salt will ruin the meal. As the amount of
the input (salt) varies, so does the output - the quality of the meal. The
law of variable proportions deals with the relationship between the input
of productive resources and the output of final products. This law helps
answer the question: How is the output of the final product affected as
more units of one variable input or resource are added to a fixed amount
of other resources?
A farmer, for example, may have all the land, machines, workers, and
other items needed to produce a crop. However, the farmer may have
some questions about the use of fertilizer. How will the crop yield be
affected if different amounts of fertilizer are added to fixed amounts of
the other inputs? In this case, the variable input is the fertilizer added per
acre. Of course, it is possible to vary all the inputs at the same time. The
farmer may want to know what will happen to output if the fertilizer and
other factors of production are varied. Economists do not like to do this,
233
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
Total Product
The second column in the production schedule in Table 3.1 shows total
product, or total output produced by the firm. The numbers indicate that
the plant barely operates when it has only one or two workers. As a
result, some resources stand idle much of the time. As more workers are
added, however, total product rises. More workers can operate more
machinery, and plant output rises. Additional workers also mean that the
workers can specialise. For example, one group runs the machines,
another handles maintenance, and a third group assembles the products.
By working in this way - as a coordinated whole - the firm can be more
productive.
As even more workers are added output continues to rise, but it does so
at a slower rate until it can grow no further. Finally, the addition of the
eleventh and twelfth workers cause total output to decline because these
workers just get in the way of the others. Although the ideal number of
workers cannot be determined until costs are considered, it is clear that
the eleventh and twelfth workers will not be hired.
234
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
6 110 18.3 20
7 129 18.3 19
8 138 17.3 9 Stage II
9 144 16 6
10 148 14.8 4
Average Product
235
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Marginal Product
In Stage I, the first workers hired cannot work efficiently because there
are too many resources per worker. As the number of workers increases,
they make better use of their machinery and resources. This results in
increasing returns (or increasing marginal products) for the first five
workers hired. As long as each new worker hired contributes more to
total output than the worker before, total output rises at an increasingly
faster rate. Because marginal output increases by a larger amount every
time a new worker is added, Stage I is known as the stage of increasing
returns. Companies, however, do not knowingly produce in Stage I for
very long. As soon as a firm discovers that each new worker adds more
output than the last, the firm is tempted to hire another worker.
The third stage of production begins when the eleventh worker is added.
By this time, the firm has hired too many workers, and they are starting
to get in each other’s way. Marginal product becomes negative and total
plant output decreases. Most companies do not hire workers whose
addition would cause total production to decrease. Therefore, the
number of workers hired would be found only in Stage II. The exact
236
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
number of workers hired depends on the cost of each worker. If the cost
is low, the firm should hire at least six, but no more than 10, workers.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
X! = f(L)
X!
X = f(L)
X
L
(a)
Fig. 3.2a: Technological Progress
X0
X0
L
(b)
Fig. 3.2b: Technological Progress
237
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Technical progress may also change the shape of the isoquants. Hicks
have distinguished three type of technical progress, depending on its
effect on the rate of substitution of the factors of production. They are:
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
238
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Finally, output may less than double when all inputs double. This case
of decreasing returns to scale applies to some firms with large-scale
operations. Eventually, difficulties in organising and running a large-
scale operation may lead to decreased productivity of both labour and
capital. Communication between workers and managers can become
difficult to monitor as the workplace becomes more impersonal. Thus,
the decreasing returns case is likely to be associated with the problem of
coordinating tasks and maintaining a useful line of communication
between managers and workers.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
With two inputs that can be varied, a manager will want to consider
substituting one input for another. The slope of each isoquant indicates
how the quantity of one input can be traded off against the quantity of
the other, while output is held constant. When the negative sign is
removed, we call the slope the marginal rate of technical substitution
(MRTS). The marginal rate of technical substitution of labour for capital
is the amount by which the input of capital can be reduced when one
extra unit of labour is used, so that output remains constant. This is
analogous to the marginal rate of substitution in consumer theory. The
MRTS is always measured as a positive quantity.
With diminishing MRTS, that is, the MRTS falls as we move down
along the isoquants. The mathematical implication is that isoquants, like
indifference curves, are convex, or bowed inward. This is indeed the
case for most production technologies. The diminishing MRTS tells us
that the productivity of any one input is limited. As more and more units
of labour are added to the production process in place of capital; the
productivity of labour falls. Similarly, when more capital is added in
place of labour, the productivity of capital falls. Production needs a
balanced mix of both inputs.
239
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Based on the above discussion, we can infer that the MRTS is closely
related to the marginal products of labour MPL and capital MPK. To see
how, imagine adding some labour and reducing the amount of capital
sufficient to keep output constant. The additional output resulting from
the increased labour input is equal to the additional output per unit of
additional labour times the number of units of additional labour.
(MPL)*(∆L) + (MPK)*(∆K) = 0
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
4.0 CONCLUSION
From our discussion so far on the theory of production, we can infer the
following:
240
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
5.0 SUMMARY
The law of variable proportions was discussed, and you should have
understood that when one input is increased while others are held
constant, output will increase in the short run. This law deals with the
relationship between the inputs of productive resources and the final
product. The production functions describe the relationship between
changes in output to different amounts of a single input while other
inputs are held constant. The concept of total and marginal product was
discussed; the effect of technological progress on production was also
discussed.
241
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
CONTENTS
1.0 Introduction
2.0 Objectives
3.0 Main Content
3.1 Implicit and Explicit Cost
3.2 Internal and External Economies of Scale
3.3 Constrained Cost Minimisation
4.0 Conclusion
5.0 Summary
6.0 Tutor-Marked Assignment
7.0 References/Further Reading
1.0 INTRODUCTION
2.0 OBJECTIVES
242
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Explicit Costs
Implicit Costs
The distinction between accounting and economic profit stems from the
difference between implicit and explicit costs. To the accountant, profit
is simply the excess of total revenue over historical cost, i.e., cost of the
firm for which actual payments have been effected in the past or for
which the firm is committed to future payments. This accountant’s
restriction on costs to explicit cost has the advantage of ensuring
objectivity.
243
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
For example, examine the profit position of Ajibola and Sons Ltd.,
whose revenue and cost data are given as:
Less:
244
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
C = ƒ(Q)
Q = ƒ(I)
Where I = resources/inputs.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
Marginal Cost
245
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Note that total cost (TC) = Fixed Cost (FC) + Variable Cost (VC).
Variable Costs
Variable costs are the costs of such inputs as raw materials, intermediate
inputs and labour, all of which vary as output varies over time.
Marginal Cost
Marginal cost is the change in total cost that comes from making or
producing one additional item. The purpose of analysing marginal cost
is to determine at what point an organisation can achieve economies of
scale. The calculation is most often used among manufacturers as a
means of isolating an optimum production level. Put differently,
manufacturing concerns often examine the cost of adding one more unit
to their production schedules. This is because at some point, the benefit
of producing one additional unit and generating revenue from that item
will bring the overall cost of producing the product line down. The key
to optimising manufacturing costs is to find that point or level as quickly
as possible.
MC
Fixed Costs
Fixed costs, indirect costs or overheads are business expenses that are
not dependent on the level of goods or services produced by the
business. They tend to be time-related, such as salaries or rents being
paid per month, and are often referred to as overhead costs.
Fixed costs are not permanently fixed; they will change over time, but
are fixed in relation to the quantity of production for the relevant period.
For example, a company may have unexpected and unpredictable
246
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
expenses unrelated to production; and warehouse costs and the like are
fixed only over the time period of the lease. There are no fixed costs in
the long run, because the long run is a sufficient period of time for all
short-run fixed inputs to become variable.
Average Costs
Similar to the above, the average cost (AC) or cost per unit of output
will first fall and eventually rise. It will initially fall because the fixed
costs can be spread over larger and larger outputs, thus leading to lower
and lower overhead cost per unit of output. However, average cost will
rise because of the diminishing marginal productivity of variable factors
which are being increased while fixed factors are kept constant. It may
also be due to the rising prices and costs of the scarce inputs or raw
materials as more and more are demanded. So the AC curve will first
fall from a high level and eventually rise, giving a U-shape. The
relationship between marginal cost and average cost is such that when
average cost is falling, marginal cost is below average cost, and when
average costs is rising, marginal cost is above it. All this implies that
marginal costs cuts average costs at the minimum or turning point of
average cost. In other words, when marginal cost is less than average
cost, it pulls down average costs, and when marginal cost is higher than
average cost, it pulls up average cost.
MC
MC
AC
A
Q
Fig. 3.3b: Marginal and Average Cost
Another aspect of average cost is its behaviour in the long run. In the
short run, some costs are fixed which relative to the installed production
capacity. In the long run all costs are variable since the production
capacity of plant size can be varied to suit demand. Thus, the long run
average cost (LAC) will be the locus of points of the lowest attainable
average cost of production for every output level using various plants
sizes. Thus LAC curve will envelop the short run average costs curves
247
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
LAC
When average cost decreases with input using appropriate plant sizes,
the industry is said to be characterised by decreasing cost or increasing
returns and when average costs are constant, we have constant returns.
But when long run average cost rises with output, we have increasing
cost or decreasing returns in the industry. Since marginal cost is less
than average cost when average cost is falling, it means that a situation
when marginal cost is less than average cost implies decreasing costs or
increasing returns or existing economy of scale.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
248
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
result in driving up the price of certain key raw materials. This will
entail extra cost for raw materials on all the firms. Similarly, if several
firms are located in a geographical zone, this may attract the extension
of railroad services to that region. This will cheapen the cost of
transportation to all the firms in the area. This could not have occurred if
just one or a few firms expanded their scale of production.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
P1 = ƛƒ1
P2 = ƛƒ2
249
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Thus, the first order condition that the price ratio of the inputs must
equal the ratio of their marginal products is met. This is to say that the
slope of the isocost must equal the slope of the related isoquants.
4.0 CONCLUSION
From our discussion so far on the theory of firm, we can infer the
following:
5.0 SUMMARY
The concept of implicit and explicit cost was discussed. The accounting
and economic profit concept was reviewed. From an accounting point of
view, once marginal revenue is greater than the cost, the company is
making profit. However, from an economist’s point of view, when
marginal revenue is equal to marginal cost, the firm is in equilibrium,
and thus competitive profit exists for the firm. Variable costs are those
cost of inputs which may vary over time, while fixed costs are the costs
of machinery and other fixed assets.
250
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
251
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
CONTENTS
1.0 Introduction
2.0 Objectives
3.0 Main Content
3.1 The Model
3.2 Backward Bending Labour Supply
3.3 Assumptions and Caveat
3.4 Inverted S-shaped Labour Supply Curve
4.0 Conclusion
5.0 Summary
6.0 Tutor-Marked Assignment
7.0 References/Further Reading
1.0 INTRODUCTION
or
252
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
OBJECTIVES
For example, Shola can earn a wage of N10 an hour, and there’s 24 x 7
= 168 hours in the week. If she works 20 hours a week, she can
consume 20 x N10 = N200 in goods and services a week and have 168 –
20 = 148 hours of leisure time left. However, if she works 40 hours a
week, she can consume 40 x N10 = N400 in goods and services a week
but only has 168 – 40 = 128 hours of leisure time left. This means that
Shola’s choice between working (a) 20 hours a week and (b) 40 hours a
week is actually a choice between (a) consuming N200 in goods and
services and enjoying 148 hours of leisure and (b) consuming N400 in
goods and services and enjoying 128 hours of leisure. Which will Shola
pick? She will pick the consumption-leisure combination that she likes
the best. If she is the easygoing type, she probably likes leisure more
than consumption, will pick (a), and work 20 hours a week. If she is the
driven type, she probably likes consumption more than leisure, will pick
(b), and work 40 hours a week.
253
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
C
N1680
-10
168 hours l
254
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
C
N1680
-10
N400
128 168 l
L = 40
We have so far assumed that Shola earns all her income and
consequently pays for all her consumption by working. But she may
earn income from non-labour sources-interest from savings accounts or
bonds, dividends from stocks, welfare payments, etc. Suppose Shola
earns N200 in non-labour income each week. This is income she earns
no matter how much she works, so we can account for it by adding
N200 in extra consumption at each level of labour supply:
255
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
C
N1880
N200
168 l
C
wT + y
y
T l
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
256
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
257
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
The above analysis only examines the effect of changing wage rates on
workers already subject to those rates-that is, only these individuals'
labour supply response was considered. It did not consider the additional
labour supplied by workers working in other sectors (or unemployed),
who are now more attracted to the jobs in the sector paying higher
wages. Thus, for a given market, the wage at which the labour supply
curve bends backward may be higher than the wage at which a given
worker's curve bends back.
On the other hand, for the aggregate labour market, that is, a labour
market without "other sectors" for workers to come from, the original
story of the backward-bending labour-supply curve applies, except to
the extent that some workers suffer from involuntary unemployment.
Assumptions
Caveat
Higher pay for overtime hours can reduce or negate the effect of a
backward bending labour supply curve, by increasing wages only for
hours worked beyond a certain amount. Overtime maintains the
substitution effect at high labour supply, but the income effect from
wages increasing on all previous hours worked is eliminated. Thus
higher hourly overtime pay can cause workers to work more hours than
they would if the higher rate was paid on all hours.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
Analyse the backward bending labour supply and state the assumptions
and caveats.
At very low wage levels-that is, near the subsistence level-the supply
curve may also be curved backwards for a completely different reason.
This effect creates an "inverted S" or "backward S" shape: a tail is added
258
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
at the bottom of the labour-supply curve shown in the graph above with
the quantity of labour-time supplied falling as wages rise. In this case,
because families face some minimum level of income needed to meet
their subsistence requirements, lowering wages increases the amount of
labour-time offered for sale. Similarly, a rise in wages can cause a
decrease in the amount of labour-time offered for sale: individuals take
advantage of the higher wage to spend time on needed self-or family-
maintenance activities.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
3.0 CONCLUSION
4.0 SUMMARY
259
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
260
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
CONTENTS
1.0 Introduction
2.0 Objectives
3.0 Main Content
3.1 Perfect Competition
3.2 Monopolistic Competition
3.3 Monopoly
4.0 Conclusion
5.0 Summary
6.0 Tutor-Marked Assignment
7.0 References/Further Reading
1.0 INTRODUCTION
2.0 OBJECTIVES
261
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
(ii)
AC
MC
P P = AR = MR
q
0
q0
Fig. 4.1: Profit-Maximising Equilibrium of the
Firm in a Perfect Market
262
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
The short run is the period during which some costs are fixed,
particularly the fixed capital formation. Once the plant has been
installed, the cost has been incurred and it cannot significantly vary as
the firm varies its output within the output capacity of the plant. If the
firm discovers that the investment is not worth it, it cannot throw it away
as long as something can be salvaged from the investment.
In other words, if the revenue from the business covers more than the
cost of variable inputs (variable cost), it does not pay to close down the
business even if total cost exceeds revenue and losses are being
sustained. If the firm should shut down, the loss would be fixed costs of
operation. We can show this formally as:
Profit (PR) is revenue (R) – Cost (C)
That is:
PR = R – C
Loss = TC – TR
Since VC – R is negative.
263
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Since the firm intends to maximise profit, it will shut down in the long
run if loss is being sustained. In the long run, all costs are variable. The
firm can change its investment decisions in the long run; it can
experiment with different plant sizes to search for the most suitable one;
it can try various methods of production or alternative technologies. If
after this entire maneuver, the firm still sustains a loss, it is predicted
that it will shut down. So, the condition for continued operation in the
long run is that revenue must cover all costs or profit must not be
negative.
i.e., R ≥ C implying AR ≥ AC
PR = R – C ≥ 0 implies also that R ≥ C or AR ≥ AC
P = AR
q
0
q0
Fig. 4.2: Long Run Equilibrium of the Profit-
Maximising Firm in a Perfect Market
264
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
MC
P Profit
ATC
atc
P
MR
0 Q
mc
Q
So, the short run and long run equilibrium condition of monopolistically
competitive firm with profit maximising goal are respectively:
265
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
3.3 Monopoly
The monopoly is a situation where a single firm is the market for a given
commodity or is an industry. In reality, we can speak of a monopoly
firm when the supply is dominated by the firm. The firm is said to be the
industry in the case of monopoly. The market is monopolised because of
the existence of a barrier to entry for other firms.
Demand curve is the price line or the average revenue (AR) curve. Since
the AR or demand is falling with output, the marginal revenue (MR)
must be below it, pulling it down. It is the general principle that when
the average of any variable is falling, the marginal is below the average
to pull it down, and when the average is rising, the marginal is above it
to pull it up.
266
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
MC ATC2
1
P
ATC1
P1
Q1 Q
MR
4.0 CONCLUSION
267
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
5.0 SUMMARY
268
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
CONTENTS
1.0 Introduction
2.0 Objectives
3.0 Main Content
3.1 Price Discrimination
3.2 Bilateral Monopoly
3.3 Monopsony
4.0 Conclusion
5.0 Summary
6.0 Tutor-Marked Assignment
7.0 References/Further Reading
1.0 INTRODUCTION
2.0 OBJECTIVES
269
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
(i) the producers or sellers can control the supply to the market
(ii) the markets or buyers for which discriminatory prices are charged
are or can be segregated to prevent resale between them.
270
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
271
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Where qA and qB are the quantities sold in the two markets and RA(qA)
and RB(qB) is the revenue functions for both markets.
Equation (4) and (5) show that profit is maximised when MRA = MRB
= MC of output as a whole. If the MR’s are not equal, the monopolist
can increase profit without affecting his TC by shifting sales from the
market with low MR to the one with high MR.
272
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
The bilateral monopoly model, with a single buyer and a single seller,
can be used to analyse many types of markets, but it is most relevant for
factor markets, especially those for labour services. The bilateral
monopoly model was developed to explain assorted labour markets
operating in the early days of the U.S. industrial revolution, the late
1800s and early 1900s. During this period, large industrial activities
(factories, mines, lumber operations) commonly created monopsony
markets by dominating the labour market of a given community (a so-
called company town). The expected monopsony outcome, especially
low wages, inevitably resulted.
273
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Athletic Labour Services: Perhaps the factor markets that come closest
to the bilateral monopoly model are those involving the labour services
of professional athletes. Players in each league are also represented by a
players’ union, including the National Football League Players
Association. While the wage rates tend to be significantly higher for
athletes than for factory workers, the underlying process is much the
same.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
3.3 Monopsony
274
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Characteristics
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
275
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
4.0 CONCLUSION
5.0 SUMMARY
276
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
277
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
CONTENTS
1.0 Introduction
2.0 Objectives
3.0 Main Content
3.1 Collusive and Non-Collusive Oligopoly
4.0 Conclusion
5.0 Summary
6.0 Tutor-Marked Assignment
7.0 References/Further Reading
1.0 INTRODUCTION
2.0 OBJECTIVES
This model addresses the case of not so many numbers of firms in the
market, such that each firm believes or assumes that its activity will not
278
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
alter the market price for the product. So the firm then attempts to
maximise its profit, holding the price constant. In this case, the marginal
revenue is constant and equal to the price. The profit maximising
equilibrium of the firm is then given by MC = P. This oligopoly model
tends to produce minimum profit and the largest output among all types
of oligopoly models, as illustrated in Figure 4.5
MC
P
MR
AC
AR
Q
MR = MC MC = P
Fig. 4.5: Equilibrium of Bertrand oligopoly model at
MC=P
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
In the Cournot classical model, the firm assumes that other firms will
not change their output as it changes its own output. On that count, the
firm maximises profit by equating the marginal cost (MC) to its
marginal revenue (MR). The reality is, however, that other firms will
change their output and this forces price and the marginal revenue of the
firm down, requiring the firm to reduce its output as a reaction to the
other firms’ action. So, initially, the firms will tend to produce more
than the collusion oligopoly and realise less profit. They will however
achieve equilibrium eventually. This can be illustrated by the
intersection of reaction curves of the firms in a duopoly model.
P = f(Q1, Q2)
279
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
280
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
AR
P1
P2
P3
Qty of commodity
Q1 Q3 Q2 Qc x per unit
MR1
MR2
Fig. 4.6: The Cournot Model
Assume Firm I enter the market first with market demand and marginal
revenue curves represented by AR and MR1 respectively. Operating as a
pure monopolist, he will produce an equilibrium output 0Q1 where
MR=MC=0, and sell at a per unit price of OP1. This is a monopoly price
and the firm secures a monopoly profit. Note that if pure competition
prevailed, the market equilibrium output would be 0Qc since MC=0 and
P=0.
Now, assume that firm II enters the market believing that firm I’s output
will be invariant at 0Q1, he regards AQc as the remaining market
demand. Introducing his MR curve (MR2) from point A, the profit
maximising output for firm II (Q1Q) is half the remaining market (AQc)
which is one fourth of the entire market. He then equates his MR and
MC at output level 0Q2. His price is 0P2. Both firms now sell at the
price 0P2.
Firm I in turn assume that firm II’s output will remain fixed at Q2C2
which is ¼ of the entire market. Thus the total market demand he now
faces becomes 3/4., which is equivalent to 0Q2. He now proceeds to
maximise his profit by producing half of the market which is ½ of ¾ of
the market. This process continues until a limit or convergence point is
reached. In equilibrium, the two duopolists will produce two thirds of
the competitive output (2/3 Qc) and charge two thirds of the monopoly
price (2/3 P1). Their joint profit is 2/3 of the monopoly profit.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
281
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Edgeworth’s Model
(i) The rival firm cannot sell more because it has reaches its capacity
limit.
(ii) An increase in price will increase profits.
Consequently one of the firms will raise its price to a point where it
maximises its profits in the remaining markets. The others will
presumably follow suit, but to a level slightly below that of the first
firm. The first firm naturally reacts with another price cut. As the
process continues, the price level falls back to the lower limit. At this
point, the opportunity for any of the firms to gain once more by raising
price recurs and price goes up again. This Edgeworth proposed, goes on
and on, as long as each firm adheres to the assumption of zero
conjectural variation in prices on the part of rival firms.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
What are the major differences between the Cournot model and the
Edgeworth model?
Stackelberg Model
Suppose “n” represents the number of firms in the oligopoly market, and
then the profit of each firm “I” depends directly on its own output levels
of other firms. Thus given that:
282
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
:
Qi = ƒi(Q1, Q2, Q3, . . . Qn); I = 1, 2, 3, . . ., n,
the equilibrium of the profit maximising oligopoly firms are respectively
given by:
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
How can you predict the reaction of a rival firm under Stackelberg
model?
Tacit collusion can be obtained through many strategies: One is the price
leadership, where the leading firm fixes price and others follow, and so
competition is largely non-price but by advertisements and other
methods. Another strategy is sharing of markets by regions, by quotas in
an informal manner. Tacitly, also, firms may not engage in price war
and each operates to stabilise price and only compete through other
strategies like advertisement. The kinked demand model is consistent
with the collusion model as with other models.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
Given that:
284
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Where Q = QA + QB
CA = 4000 – 20QA + 0.2QA2 and
CB = 3000 + 15B + 0.25QB2
Kink
If any firm attempts to raise its price, others are not likely to follow,
with the consequence that the firm will lose a lot of customers to its
competitors. So, there is a tendency for prices to cluster at or a little
above the kink. Except when there is a case of price leadership by a
dominant firm, price increase by one firm will not be followed by
others. When there is a recognised leader and price leadership exists, a
price increase by the dominant firm may be followed by the others,
leading to a new kink on the demand curve.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
285
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
4.0 CONCLUSION
5.0 SUMMARY
286
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
287
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
CONTENTS
1.0 Introduction
2.0 Objectives
3.0 Main Content
3.1 Assumptions of Linear Programming
3.2 Advantages and Limitations
3.3 Construction of the Model
3.4 Canonical Tableaux
3.5 Introduction to Simplex Algorithm/Method
4.0 Conclusion
5.0 Summary
6.0 Tutor-Marked Assignment
7.0 References/Further Reading
1.0 INTRODUCTION
288
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Max ƒ(x) = cx
Subject to Ax ≤ b, x ≥ 0.
More generally,
Max Z= P1X1 + P2X2
Subject to
x1 ≥ 0, x2 ≥0, . . . , xn ≥ 0.
2.0 OBJECTIVES
289
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Advantages
Limitations
290
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
X1 ≥ 5
y1 = x1 – 5
x1 = y1 + 5
x2 + 2x3 ≤ 3
-x4 + 3x5 ≥ 2
x2 + 2x3 + s1 = 3
-x4 + 3x5 + s2 = 2
s1, s2 ≥ 0
z1 = z 1 + - z1 -
z1+, z1- ≥0
291
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
The first row defines the objective function and the remaining rows
specify the constraints. If the columns of A can be rearranged so that it
contains the identity matrix of order p (the number of rows in A) then
the tableau is said to be in canonical form. The variables corresponding
to the columns of the identity matrix are called basic variables while the
remaining variables are called non-basic or free variables. If the non-
basic variables are assumed to be 0, then the values of the basic
variables are easily obtained as entries in b and this solution is a basic
feasible solution.
292
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Subject to
Stage 1
Pj - - 200 240 0 0 ϴ
Activity Resources X1 X2 S1 S2 -
0 S1 2400 30 15 1 0 160
0 S2 2400 20 [30] 0 1 80
Zj 0 0 0 0 0
Pj - Zj - 200 240 0 0
Stage 2
0 S1 1200 19.95 0 1 -0.45 60.15
240 X2 80 0.67 1 0 0.03 119.4
293
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
The bolded row and column are both our pivot row and column, while
the pivot element is acquired by observing the highest value in row Pj –
Zj and the lowest values in column ϴ. The pivot value is the value is
block bracket ([30]) in stage 1.
200x1 + 240x2
200 (60.2) + 240 (39.7) = 21,568.
This maximises the value Z. i.e., revenue is maximise at the production
of 60.2x1 and 39.7x2 goods.
294
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
4.0 CONCLUSION
5.0 SUMMARY
The concept of linear programming problem is that of choosing
nonnegative values of certain variables so as to maximise or
minimise a given linear function, subject to a given set of linear
inequality constraints.
In order to construct the model, the transformation of a linear
program to one in standard form may be required.
The standard form of presenting a linear problem was discussed.
Similarly, the simplex algorithm method of analysing linear
programming was discussed.
295
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
296
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
CONTENTS
1.0 Introduction
2.0 Objectives
3.0 Main Content
3.1 Assumptions of the Walrasian System
3.2 The Household and Consumer Equilibrium
3.3 Two Interdependent Markets Moving to General
Equilibrium
3.4 Efficiency in Exchange and the Advantage of Trade
3.5 Theory of Distribution (Wage, Rent, Profit and Interest)
4.0 Conclusion
5.0 Summary
6.0 Tutor-Marked Assignment
7.0 References/Further Reading
1.0 INTRODUCTION
2.0 OBJECTIVES
297
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
298
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
(1)
(2)
In general equilibrium, the MRS for the two commodities is the same
for all consumers regardless of their preferences, age, sex or wealth.
Households sell productive factors to the business firms. They maximise
their utility by selling their factors to the highest bidder, and equilibrium
in the factor market is attained in the same manner as above.
Consumers Equilibrium
(3)
299
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Equation 3 states that MRSxy for the two consumers are identical and
must equal the price ratios of the products.
(4)
And MR = MC (5)
Where w = wage rate
r = cost of capital.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
6.82
SM
6.75
6.35
D*M
6.00 D’M
DM
No of Movie
Q’M Q’’M Q*M QM Tickets
(a)
The movie tax affects the market for DVD’s because movies and DVD’s
are substitutes. A higher movie price shifts the demand for DVD’s from
DV and D’V in the part (b) of the diagram. In turn, this shift causes the
rental price of DVD’s to increase from N3 to N3.5.
The original demand for movies presumed that the price of DVD’s was
unchanged at N3. But because that price is now 3.5, the demand for
movies will shift upward, from DM to D’M in part (a) of the diagram.
The new equilibrium price of movies is N6.75, instead of N6.35, and the
quantity of movie tickets purchased has increased from Q’M to Q’’M.
Thus a partial equilibrium analysis would have underestimated the effect
of the tax on the price of movies. The DVD market is so closely related
to the market for movies that to determine the tax’s full effect, we need a
general equilibrium analysis.
Fig. 5.1: Supply and Demand curves for (a) Movie Tickets and
(b)DVD’s
Price (N) Sv
3.58
3.50
3.00
D*M
D’M
DM
No of DVD’s
Qv Q’v Q*v
(b)
301
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Our analysis is not yet complete. The change in the market price of
movies will generate a feedback effect on the price of DVDs that, in
turn, will affect the price of movies, and so on. In the end, we must
determine the equilibrium prices and quantities of both movies and
DVDs simultaneously. The equilibrium movie price of N6.82 is given in
part (a) of the diagram above by the intersection of the equilibrium
supply and demand curves for movie tickets (SM* and DM*). The
equilibrium DVD price of N3.58 is given in part (b) of the above
diagram by the intersection of the supply and demand curve for DVDs
(SV and DV*). These are the correct general equilibrium prices because
the DVD market supply and demand curves have been drawn on the
assumption that the price of movie tickets is N6.82. Likewise, the movie
ticket curves have been drawn on the assumption that the price of DVDs
is N3.58. In other words, both sets of curves are consistent with the
prices in related markets, and we have no reason to expect that the
supply and demand curves in either market will shift further. To find the
general equilibrium prices in practice, we must simultaneously find two
prices that equate quantity demanded and quantity supplied in all related
markets. For our two markets, we need to find the solution to four
equations (supply of movie tickets, demand for movie tickets, supply of
DVDs and demand for DVDs).
Note that even if we were only interested in the market for movies, it
would be important to account for the DVD market when determining
the impact of a movie tax. In this example, partial equilibrium analysis
would lead us to conclude that the tax will increase the price of movie
tickets from N6 to N6.35. A general equilibrium analysis, however,
shows us that the impact of the tax on the price of movie tickets is
greater: it would in fact increase to N6.82.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
302
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Advantage of Trade
There is thus room for mutually advantageous trade because Tola values
clothing more highly than Bola does, whereas, Bola values food more
highly than Tola does. To get another unit of food, Bola would be
willing to trade up to 3 units of clothing. But Tola will give up 1 unit of
food for ½ unit of clothing. The actual terms of trade depend on the
bargaining process. Among the possible outcomes are trade of 1unit of
food by Tola for anywhere between ½ and 3 units of clothing from Bola.
Suppose Bola offer Tola 1 unit of clothing for 1 unit of food, and Tola
agrees, both will be better off. Tola will have more clothing, which he
values more than food. Whenever two consumer’s MRS’s are different,
there is room for mutually trade because the allocation of resources is
inefficient. Through trading, both consumers will be made better off.
303
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
Write an essay on how efficient trade can be carried out between two
consumers with different initial allocations.
Wage
304
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
305
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
Rent
Rent is that portion of the produce of the earth, which is paid to the
landlord for the use of the original and indestructible powers of the soil.
It is often, however, confounded with the interest and profit of capital,
and, in popular language, the term is applied to whatever is annually
paid by a farmer to his landlord.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
4.0 CONCLUSION
5.0 SUMMARY
306
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
307
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
CONTENTS
1.0 Introduction
2.0 Objectives
3.0 Main Content
3.1 Criteria of Social Welfare
3.2 Social Welfare Maximisation
3.3 Individualistic Social Welfare Functions
3.4 Fair Allocation
3.5 Envy and Equity
4.0 Conclusion
5.0 Summary
6.0 Tutor-Marked Assignment
7.0 References/Further Reading
1.0 INTRODUCTION
2.0 OBJECTIVES
308
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
W = U A + UB + UC
309
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
310
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
being considered, which will benefit some (gainers) and hurt some
(losers). One can ask the gainers how much money they would be
prepared to pay in order to have the change and the losers how much
money they would be prepared to pay in order to prevent the change. If
the amount of money of the gainers is greater than the amount of the
losers, the change constitutes an improvement in welfare, because the
gainers could compensate the losers and still have some net gain. Thus,
the Kaldor-Hicks compensation criterion states that a change constitutes
an improvement in social welfare if those who benefit from it could
compensate those who are hurt, and still be left with some net gain.
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
The condition for social welfare maximisation in the simple two factors,
two commodities, and two consumer model is stated below.
311
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
W = W(ui(xi), . . ., un(xn)).
312
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
313
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
w1/2
Good 2 Person B
IC’s
Fair Allocation
w2/2 w2/2
Swapped Allocation
Person A
w1/2
Good 1
SELF-ASSESSMENT EXERCISE
314
ECO 431 ADVANCED MICROECONOMICS
4.0 CONCLUSION
From our discussion so far, we can infer that:
5.0 SUMMARY
The concept of social welfare was reviewed, with extensive discussion
on different criteria of social welfare. Pareto efficient allocation and the
criteria emphasise the allocation efficiency in the society. Different
conditions for social welfare maximisation were also discussed before
individualistic social function was reviewed. Finally, fair allocations as
well as envy and equity concept of the social welfare were discussed.
Lipsey, et al. (2008). Economics. (13th ed.). Upper Saddle River, NJ:
Pearson.
315