0% found this document useful (0 votes)
22 views33 pages

Lec1 UtilityMax

This document provides an overview of the theory of consumer choice, covering three main topics: the budget constraint, preferences and utility, and choice. It defines the budget constraint and how it changes with income and prices. It introduces indifference curves and utility functions to represent preferences, and defines concepts like marginal utility and the marginal rate of substitution. It then discusses how consumers maximize utility subject to their budget constraint, finding the optimal choice where the marginal rate of substitution equals the price ratio at the tangency point of an indifference curve and the budget line.

Uploaded by

ebbamork
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
22 views33 pages

Lec1 UtilityMax

This document provides an overview of the theory of consumer choice, covering three main topics: the budget constraint, preferences and utility, and choice. It defines the budget constraint and how it changes with income and prices. It introduces indifference curves and utility functions to represent preferences, and defines concepts like marginal utility and the marginal rate of substitution. It then discusses how consumers maximize utility subject to their budget constraint, finding the optimal choice where the marginal rate of substitution equals the price ratio at the tangency point of an indifference curve and the budget line.

Uploaded by

ebbamork
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 33

Lecture 1: The Theory of Consumer Choice

Alfonso Irarrazabal
August, 2023

1
Introduction
Overview

In this lecture, we will cover three topics

◦ Budget Constraint
◦ Preferences and Utility
◦ Choice

2
Budget Constraint
Budget Constraint

◦ Suppose the consumer can choose between two goods x1 and


x2 with prices p1 and p2 . Suppose the consumer has money to
spend m.
◦ The budget constraint for the consumer is

p 1 x1 + p 2 x2 ≤ m

◦ To find the budget line we solve for x2 as a function of x1


(with equality in the budget equation).

3
Budget Constraint

◦ The budget line is the set of bundles that cost m.


◦ The slope of the budget line measures the opportunity cost of
consuming good 1, ie: to consume one more unit of good 1
she has to give up p2 /p1 units of good 2.

4
Budget Constraint: A Change in Income

◦ An increase in income m implies that the consumer now can


afford more of both goods.

5
Budget Constraint: A Change in Price

◦ An increase in p1 moves the budget line inward.

6
Preferences and Utility
Preferences

◦ Consumer theory can be described in terms of preferences.


We will describe preferences using indifference curves.
◦ The shaded area represents those bundles weakly preferred to
(x1 ,x2 ). The indifference curve is the set of bundles for which
the consumer is indifferent.

7
Utility

◦ A utility function is a way to assign a number to every


possible consumption bundle such that more preferred bundles
get assigned a larger number to less-preferred bundles.
◦ If a consumer has utility function u(x1 , x2 ) then she will be
indifferent between two bundles if they are assigned the same
utility.
◦ An example of such utility is u(x1 , x2 ) = x1 x2 .
◦ Say you consume x1 = 2 and x2 = 3, then you get utility
u(x1 , x2 ) = 6.
◦ If you consume x1 = 2 and x2 = 5, then you get utility
u(x1 , x2 ) = 10, a higher utility than before.

8
Utility: Monotonic Transformation

◦ A monotone transformation of a utility function is a utility


function. For example, if u(x) is a utility function, and f (y ) is
a monotone transformation, then f (u(x)) is a utility.
◦ Examples of monotone transformations are multiplication for a
constant (f (u) = 3u), raising to power (f (u) = u 3 ), taking
logs (f (u) = log(u)) etc.
◦ Consider utility u(x1 , x2 ) = x1 x2 and a monotonic
transformation log(u), then log (u(x1 , x2 )) = log(x1 ) + log(x2 )
is a utility that represents the same preferences as
u(x1 , x2 ) = x1 x2 .

9
Utility Function

◦ Consider several indifference curves. How can we know that a


utility function can represent indifferences curves?
◦ If preferences are monotonic then the line through the origin
must intersect each indifference curve only once.

10
Utility: Plot Preferences

◦ Suppose the utility is given by u(x1 , x2 ) = x1 x2 . We can


compute the indifference curves as x2 = xk1 .
◦ How would the indifference curve of u a (x1 , x2 ) = x12 x22 look
like? Answer: the same! as u a (x1 , x2 ) = u(x1 , x2 )2

11
Utility: Perfect Substitutes

◦ Two goods are perfect substitutes if the consumer is willing to


substitute one good for the other at a constant rate.
◦ Preferences for perfect substitutes can be represented by a
utility function of the form u(x1 , x2 ) = ax1 + bx2 .
◦ For example u(x1 , x2 ) = x1 + x2 . Then, the indifference curve
is x2 = k − x1

12
Utility: Perfect Complements

◦ Perfect complements are goods that are always consumed in


fixed proportions.
◦ Preferences for perfect complements can be represented by a
utility function of the form u(x1 , x2 ) = min(ax1 , bx2 ).

13
Utility: Cobb-Douglas Preference

◦ Cobb-Douglas utility has the following form u(x1 , x2 ) = x1c x2d .


◦ This preference is very popular in economics/finance and it is
a utility that generates a well-behaved preference.

14
Marginal Utility and MRS

◦ Consider a consumer who is consuming two goods (x1 , x2 ).


How does this consumer’s utility change as we give her a little
more of good 1?
◦ This rate of change is called the marginal utility with respect
to good 1.
◦ Mathematically,
∂u(x1 , x2 )
MU1 =
∂x1
◦ For example, for u(x) = x1 x2 we have that MU1 = x2 and
MU2 = x1 .

15
Marginal Rate of Substitution

◦ A related concept, is the slope of the indifference curve (at a


point) or marginal rate of substitution (MRS).
◦ The MRS can be interpreted as the rate at which a consumer
is just willing to substitute a small amount of good 2 for good
1.
◦ Mathematically,

∂u/∂x1 MU1
MRS = =
∂u/∂x2 MU2

◦ For example, for u(x) = x1 x2 we have that MRS = x2 /x1 .


◦ Similarly, for u(x) = log x1 + x2 we have that MRS = 1/x1 .

16
Utility: MRS

◦ The MRS is the slope of the indifference curve (a negative


number)

17
Convexity of Indifference Curves

◦ The indifference curve is convex if any line joining two points


above u1 is also above u1 . A convex utility has diminishing
MRS everywhere.
◦ In (b) the curve does not have diminishing MRS everywhere
(concave indifference curve)

18
Choice: Utility Maximization
Utility: Optimal Choice and MRS

◦ The optimal choice of the consumer means to find the best


bundle the consumer can afford.
◦ The figure shows that at (x1∗ , x2∗ ) the consumer is achieving
the highest utility given the budget constraint.

19
Solving for the Optimal Choice

◦ One way to solve it is by using


p1
MRS(x1∗ , x2∗ ) =
p2

that is where the slope of the indifference curve (MRS) equals


the slope of the budget constraint (p1 /p2 ).
◦ You can solve for (x1∗ , x2∗ ) using the ”tangency” condition
MRS(x1∗ , x2∗ ) = pp12 and the equation for the budget constraint
p1 x1 + p2 x2 = m.

20
An example

1/2 1/2
◦ Consider the utility u(x1 , x2 ) = x1 x2 and the budget
constraint 2x1 + x2 = 100.
1
◦ It is helpful to take logs u t (x1 , x2 ) = 2 log(x1 ) + 12 log(x2 ).
◦ Then, optimality implies
x2 p1
=
x1 p2
and 2x1 + x2 = 100.
◦ Replacing the optimality condition x2 = 2x1 into the budget
constraint gives x1 = 25 and x2 = 50.

21
Optimal Choice: Perfect Substitutes

◦ If p2 > p1 , then x1∗ = m/p1 and x2∗ = 0.


◦ If p2 < p1 , then x1∗ = 0 and x2∗ = m/p2 .
◦ If p2 = p1 , then any bundle that satisfies the budget
constraint is optimal.

22
Optimal Choice: Perfect Complements

◦ Optimal choice is independent of prices.


◦ Once you know the proportion under which goods are
consumed, you can use the budget constraint to solve for
quantities.

23
Utility Maximization

◦ We can also solve the U-max problem by using Lagrangian


method. Suppose the consumer chooses to consumer x1 and
x2 in order to maximize utility u(x1 , x2 ) subject the budget
constraint.
◦ This problem can be written as

max u(x1 , x2 )
x1 ,x2

st:
p 1 x1 + p 2 x2 = m

24
U-max: Lagrangian

◦ We setup an auxiliary Lagrangian function

L = u(x1 , x2 ) − λ(p1 x1 + p2 x2 − m)

where λ denotes the Lagrangian multiplier.


◦ The optimal choice (x1∗ , x2∗ ) satisfies the three first-order
conditions:
∂L
= ux1 (x1∗ , x2∗ ) − λp1 = 0
∂x1
∂L
= ux2 (x1∗ , x2∗ ) − λp2 = 0
∂x2
∂L
= p1 x1∗ + p2 x2∗ − m = 0
∂λ
∂u(x1∗ ,x2∗ ) ∂u(x1∗ ,x2∗ )
where ux1 (x1∗ , x2∗ ) = ∂x1 and ux2 (x1∗ , x2∗ ) = ∂x2

25
Utility Maximization: An Example

◦ Let’s consider the Cobb Douglas utility u(x1 , x2 ) = x1c x2d .


Since utility function are only defined up to a monotonic
transformation it is convenient to take logs.
◦ This way the Lagrangian for this problem can be written as

max c log x1 + d log x2


x1 ,x2

st:
p 1 x1 + p 2 x2 = m

◦ The trick is usually to solve for λ first.

26
Utility Maximization: An Example

◦ To solve for optimal x1∗ and x2∗ we setup an auxiliary


Lagrangian function

L = u(x1 , x2 ) − λ(p1 x1 + p2 x2 − m)

where λ denotes the Lagrangian multiplier.


◦ The optimal choice (x1∗ , x2∗ ) satisfies the three first-order
conditions:
c
− λp1 = 0
x1
d
− λp2 = 0
x2
p 1 x1 + p 2 x2 − m = 0

27
Utility Maximization: An Example

◦ Use the first two FOCs

c = λp1 x1
d = λp2 x2

◦ Plug the demands x1 = c/(λp1 ) and x2 = c/(λp2 ) into the


budget constraint to get an expression of λ

c + d = λ(p1 x1 + p2 x2 − m) = λm

which gives
c +d
λ=
m

28
Utility Maximization: An Example

◦ Substitute into the FOCs for x1 and x2


c m
x1 =
c +d p1
c m
x2 =
c +d p2
◦ The Cobb Douglas utility has the property that the fraction of
the expenditure spent on good x1 is constant
p 1 x1 p1 c m c
= =
m m c + d p1 c +d
◦ Similarly, the fraction of her income that the consumer spends
on good 2 is d/(c + d).

29

You might also like