Deconstruction of Development
Deconstruction of Development
DECONSTRUCTING DEVELOPMENT
RUTH E. GORDON*
and JON H. SYLVESTER†
Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2 R
I. Constructing Development in Theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9 R
A. The Birth of a Paradigm . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9 R
B. The Discovery and Quantification of Global
Poverty . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11 R
C. The Meta-narrative of Modernization . . . . . . . . . . 15 R
D. Law and Development . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18 R
II. Constructing Development in Practice . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22 R
A. The Institutional Edifice . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 22 R
1. The World Bank . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23 R
2. The Evolving Role of the IMF in the Third
World . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26 R
B. Cycles of Conventional Wisdom . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29 R
1. The Golden Age of Development: 1950-
1970 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30 R
2. The Second Phase: Integrating Social and
Economic Elements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33 R
3. The Third World Debt Crisis and the Lost
Decade for Development (1980-1990) . . . . . 37 R
4. The Washington “Consensus” and the
“New” Conditionality . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44 R
III. Legal Constructions of Development . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49 R
A. Permanent Sovereignty Over Natural
Resources . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53 R
B. The New International Economic Order . . . . . . . 56 R
C. The Right to Development . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61 R
D. Reparations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64 R
IV. Deconstructing Development . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71 R
A. Positioning Development in the Western
Imagination . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 73 R
B. Constructing the Underdeveloped . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79 R
V. Conclusion: Envisioning a Post Development
World . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 86 R
*
Professor of Law, Villanova University School of Law, B.A., J.D., New York
University, LLM London School of Economics and Political Science
†
Professor of Law, Golden Gate University School of Law, B.A., Stanford
University, J.D, Harvard Law School, M.J., University of California at Berkeley
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 2 1-SEP-04 12:22
INTRODUCTION
1
Gustavo Esteva, Development, in THE DEVELOPMENT DICTIONARY: A GUIDE TO
KNOWLEDGE AS POWER 6 (Wolfgang Sachs ed., 1992).
2
See, e.g., GLOBALIZATION AND THE CHALLENGES OF THE NEW CENTURY: A
READER (Patrick O’Meara et al. eds., 2000); HERNANDO DE SOTO, THE MYS-
TERY OF CAPITAL: WHY CAPITALISM TRIUMPHS IN THE WEST AND FAILS EVERY-
WHERE ELSE (2000); ANTHONY GIDDENS, Runaway World: How Globalization Is
Reshaping Our Lives (1999); GLOBAL FORTUNE: THE STUMBLE AND RISE OF
WORLD CAPITALISM (Ian Vasquez ed., 2000); JOHN EATWELL & LANCE TAYLOR,
GLOBAL FINANCE AT RISK: THE CASE FOR INTERNATIONAL REGULATION
(2000); THOMAS L. FRIEDMAN, THE LEXUS AND THE OLIVE TREE (1999); KEVIN
BALES, DISPOSABLE PEOPLE: NEW SLAVERY IN THE GLOBAL ECONOMY (1999);
ADAIR TURNER, JUST CAPITAL: THE LIBERAL ECONOMY (2001); NOREENA
HERTZ, THE SILENT TAKEOVER: GLOBAL CAPITALISM AND THE DEATH OF DE-
MOCRACY (2001).
3
This article will use the terms Third World or Southern nations to identify what is
commonly referred to as the developing world. The Third World was initially an
ideological category, and a political strategy connoting nonalignment with either
the “First” or “Second” World. It also has a “political geographic content” in
that it describes “certain spaces or regions of the world possessing distinctive
demographic, economic and political characteristics in comparison with the First
or Second Worlds.” The Third World also identifies those nations and regions
that were historically subjected to colonialism. Finally, the Third World has been
defined in terms of a certain set of images including: “poverty, squalor, corrup-
tion, violence, calamities and disasters, irrational local fundamentalism, bad
smell, garbage, filth, technological ‘backwardness,’ or simply lack of modernity.”
See Keith Aoki, Space Invaders: Critical Geography, the “Third World” in Inter-
national Law and Critical Race Theory, 45 VILL. L. REV. 913, 925 (2000) (quoting
Balakrishnan Rajagopal, Locating the Third World in Cultural Geography, in
THIRD WORLD LEGAL STUDIES – 1998–99, at 1 (2000)). Therefore, while the
term Third World may be somewhat problematic, it is a more constructive term
than developing, underdeveloped or undeveloped nations. For a more detailed
discussion and analysis of the term “Third World,” see Karin Mickelson, Rhetoric
and Rage: Third World Voices in International Legal Discourse, 16 WIS. INT’L L.J.
353, 355–62 (1998).
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 3 1-SEP-04 12:22
4
Some argue that globalization is “little more than a repackaging of develop-
ment.’” For example, O’Hearn maintains that after a decade of discipline
through debt and disinvestments, the neo-liberal regime is even more powerful as
it now forces developing states themselves to agree that the market is the most
rational way to do things correctly. Denis O’Hearn, Tigers and Transnational
Corporations: Pathways from the Periphery?, in CRITICAL DEVELOPMENT THE-
ORY: CONTRIBUTIONS TO A NEW PARADIGM 117 (Ronaldo Munck & Denis
O’Hearn eds., 1999).
5
Esteva, supra note 1, at 7 (noting that even when development is disparaged or
critically appraised, the focus is generally on its ever-changing content or its im-
plementation – never on the concept itself).
6
For a detailed discussion of the debt crisis in sub-Saharan Africa, see Jon H. Syl-
vester, Impracticability, Mutual Mistake and Related Contractual Bases for Equi-
tably Adjusting the External Debt of Sub-Saharan Africa, 13 NW. J. INT’L L. &
BUS. 258 (1992); see also infra Part II. B and accompanying text. For a discus-
sion of World Bank and IMF programs, see infra Part II. A.
7
Of course this is not to say that each and every development project has been a
failure. Nonetheless, “[b]y the beginning of the 1990s, most people in sub-
Saharan Africa were poorer than they had been thirty years before. With a popu-
lation of about 500 million, nearly 300 million are living in absolute poverty. In
developing countries as a whole, nearly 800 million people do not get enough
food, and about 500 million are chronically malnourished. Almost, one-third of
the population of developing countries – about 1.3 billion – lives below the pov-
erty line. The infant mortality rate, at about 350 per 100,000 live births, is about
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 4 1-SEP-04 12:22
nine times higher than that in ‘advanced countries.’” Ray Kiely, The Crisis of
Development, in GLOBALISATION AND THE THIRD WORLD 24 (Ray Kiely & Phil
Marflect eds., 1998). See also Uma Kothari & Martin Minogue, Critical Perspec-
tives on Development: An Introduction, in DEVELOPMENT THEORY AND PRAC-
TICE CRITICAL PERSPECTIVES: CRITICAL PERSPECTIVES 4–5 (Uma Kothari &
Martin Minogue eds., 2002).
8
See infra Part II. B and accompanying text.
9
Full funding would not necessarily mean that development would ever achieve its
intended results, although it could mean an improvement in what has been
termed “basic needs,” such as minimal health care, potable water and the like.
Achieving even these modest goals, however, would not be a certainty, given how
projects are chosen and funded. See, e.g., William Easterly, The Cartel of Good
Intentions, 7/1/02 FOREIGN POL’Y 4049 (contending that for a variety of reasons,
large, flashy projects are the projects most often funded, while those that assist
with simple tasks such as maintaining infrastructure are ignored).
10
This is not to absolve industrialized countries of their share of blame for the gross
inequalities in the international community; for the disarray of destroyed socie-
ties and cultures; or for the poverty, violence and degradation that has accompa-
nied the development project. One criticism of the postmodern view of
development is that it encourages affluent countries to disengage, and does noth-
ing to assist the billion or more people who are living in absolute poverty; that it
would leave those people to their own devices. David Simon, Development Re-
visited, in DEVELOPMENT AS THEORY AND PRACTICE: CURRENT PERSPECTIVES
ON DEVELOPMENT AND DEVELOPMENT CO-OPERATION 17 (David Simon & An-
ders Närman eds., 1999). This is a fair argument that deserves serious attention.
See infra notes 431—34 and accompanying text for a response to this contention.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 5 1-SEP-04 12:22
11
Majid Rahnema, Towards Post-Development: Searching for Signposts, a New
Language and New Paradigms, in THE POST-DEVELOPMENT READER 384 (Majid
Rahnema & Victoria Bawtree eds., 1997) [hereinafter Rahnema, Towards Post-
Development].
12
For a discussion of the ways in which development has stripped many Third
World states of significant aspects of their sovereignty, see infra Part III; see also
Ruth Gordon, Saving Failed States: Sometimes a Neocolonialist Notion, 12 AM. U.
J. INT’L L. & POL’Y 903 (1997) [hereinafter Gordon, Saving Failed States].
13
Saving Failed States, supra note 12. Development confirms and validates racial
hierarchy, which explains in part why after the disintegration of the USSR, East-
ern Europe and the former Soviet Republics – whether industrialized or not –
were immediately understood to be in a different global category than the devel-
oping Third World. Ruth Gordon, Racing U.S. Foreign Policy, 17 NAT’L BLACK
L.J. 1 (2003) [hereinafter Gordon, Racing U.S. Foreign Policy]; cf. Kothari, supra
note 7, at 8 (maintaining that “the development project is expansionist and has
found new territory” for with the triumph of neoliberalism, development has
broadened its breadth to include the transitional economies of Europe and the
former Soviet Republics).
14
Saving Failed States, supra note 12, at 934.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 6 1-SEP-04 12:22
15
See infra Part I. C and accompanying text; Kothari, supra note 7, at 7–12.
16
Some development strategies such as micro-development, participation, and sus-
tainable development began life as “alternative development” strategies. These
alternative theories have been institutionalized and absorbed into mainstream
development theory and in the process watered down and stripped of any sem-
blance of their sometimes-radical origins. As reconstituted, they reproduce the
same power relationships found in conventional development theory and prac-
tice. Moreover, even these “alternative theories” generally originate in the West
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 7 1-SEP-04 12:22
and are then imposed on the Third World. Kothari, supra note 7, at 9–10. See
also infra notes 149—59 and accompanying text.
17
Michael Cowen & Robert Shenton, The Invention of Development, in POWER OF
DEVELOPMENT 7, 28 (Johanthan Crush ed., 1995).
18
Of course the level of control varies, given that some Third World countries are
larger, and more politically and economically powerful than others. Thus, this is
not to suggest that all Third World countries are homogenous or indistinguishable
from each other.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 8 1-SEP-04 12:22
19
ARTURO ESCOBAR, ENCOUNTERING DEVELOPMENT: THE MAKING AND UN-
THIRD WORLD 12–14 (1995).
MAKING OF THE
20
This article takes up the bold challenge posed by Professor Tayyab Mahmud in
his brilliant article: Postcolonial Imaginaries: Alternative Development or Alterna-
tives to Development?, 9 TRANSNAT’L L. & CONTEMP. PROBS. 25 (1999), and criti-
cally examines the post development literature.
21
Kiely, supra note 7, at 24 (criticizing the anti-development critique as romanti-
cizing pre-colonial cultures that may never have existed).
22
On problems with marginalizing and representing the other, see Uma Kothari,
Feminist and Postcolonial Challenges to Development, in DEVELOPMENT THEORY
AND PRACTICE CRITICAL PERSEPCTIVES, supra note 7, at 48–50.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 9 1-SEP-04 12:22
the lives and agency of others, and in the process perhaps reject
often unarticulated but crippling assumptions about “the
Other.”23 The objective is to pose different questions, to let
others pose questions, to learn to listen and to actually hear the
responses of others rather than assuming that the answers are
already known.
23
On constructing “the Other” in opposition to self, see EDWARD W. SAID, ORIEN-
TALISM 1–8 (1994).
24
The origins of development are quite complex, but a unitary meaning seemed to
congeal around the end of the Second World War. Development came to signify
indefinite growth, maturity and the capacity to grow without end. This expecta-
tion was based on a number of developmental hypotheses including “the omnipo-
tence of technique, the asymptotic assumption relating to science, the rationality
of economic mechanisms, and the presumption of social engineering as a prereq-
uisite for growth.” Michael Watts, “A New Deal in Emotions”: Theory and Prac-
tice and the Crisis of Development, in POWER OF DEVELOPMENT, supra note 17, at
44, 49–50.
25
For an extensive discussion of the concept of development before 1949, see
Cowen & Shenton, supra note 17, at 27; Watts, supra note 24, at 44. The mandate
system and later the trusteeship system were also precursors of development. Id.
See also Saving Failed States, supra note 12, at 940–53, on the mandate and trus-
teeship systems.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 10 1-SEP-04 12:22
26
ESCOBAR, supra note 19, at 3.
27
Truman’s plan facilitated the establishment of numerous “international institu-
tions, professions, organizations whose existence was dedicated to development.
Development was industrialized.” Watts, supra note 24, at 44–45.
28
Esteva, supra note 1, at 10. Indeed, “as a neocolonial discipline, the authoritative
discourse of development reproduces unequal relations by assuming the power to
label groups of people . . . in development we have constructed an entity called
the Third World.” KOTHARI, supra note 22, at 38.
29
Esteva, supra note 1, at 9.
30
In 1956, John Foster Dulles stated that defeat in the contest for development of
the underdeveloped countries “could be as disastrous as defeat in the arms race.”
CHRONICLE OF THE 20TH CENTURY 776 (Clifton Daniel ed., 1992). Indeed, the
introduction to a development economics textbook used in the U.S. in the early
1960s made the point rather bluntly: “the Cold War is not going very well for the
Western World. Soviet or Chinese influence is infiltrating into many of the un-
derdeveloped countries, in Asia, Africa, and Latin America.” 11 STEPHEN ENKE,
ECONOMICS FOR DEVELOPMENT (1963), quoted in 1 DEVESH KAPUR, THE
WORLD BANK: ITS FIRST HALF CENTURY 144 n. 10 (Brookings Institute 1997).
The World Bank was pressed into service to address this problem. See also infra
notes 94-95 and accompanying text discussing how the Cold War helped shaped
World Bank policies. See also ESCOBAR, supra note 19, at 34; Pierre de Senar-
clens, How the United Nations Promotes Development Through Technical Assis-
tance, in THE POST-DEVELOPMENT READER, supra note 11, at 190 (Noting that
just as the Marshall Plan was to contain the communist threat in Europe, eco-
nomic aid became part of American political strategy. The Cold War thus
animated and colored the development project, as anti-communist credentials be-
came a condition for assistance.).
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 11 1-SEP-04 12:22
31
Senarclens, supra note 30.
32
“At the end of the Second World War, the United States controlled approxi-
mately 70% of the world’s gold and foreign exchange reserves and 40% of indus-
trial output.” Kiely, supra note 7, at 26.
33
ESCOBAR, supra note 19, at 32 (noting that “1945 marked a profound transforma-
tion in world affairs” as the United States assumed the “undisputable position of
economic and military preeminence, placing under its tutelage the entire Western
system”).
34
ESCOBAR, supra note 19, at 28; Gordon, Racing U.S. Foreign Policy, supra note
13, at 1.
35
ESCOBAR, supra note 19, at 23–24; Majid Rahnema, Poverty, in THE DEVELOP-
MENT DICTIONARY, supra note 1, at 161.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 12 1-SEP-04 12:22
36
ESCOBAR, supra note 19, at 23 (quoting Wolfgang Sachs, The Archaeology of the
Development Idea, 23(4) INTERCULTURE 1–37 (1990)). The origins of standard of
living and the projection of global poverty are relatively new constructs that are
“encased in development plans, foreign aid reports and national accounts data
building in part on the Keynesian revolution.” Watts, supra note 24, at 51.
37
Rahnema, supra note 35, at 161.
38
ESCOBAR, supra note 19, at 23.
39
Senarclens, supra note 30.
40
Id. During the decades following the Second World War and throughout the
decolonization era, the idea of “convergence” – that the gap between the rich and
the poor would shrink – dominated thinking about development. There clearly
has been no such convergence and the entire idea appears to have been dis-
carded. See generally Lant G. Pritchett, Forget Convergence: Divergence, Past,
Present, and Future, 33 FIN. & DEV. 2 (1996); Jeffrey Williamson, Globalization,
Convergence, and History, 56 J. ECON. HIST. 277 (1996). For example, during the
last two decades, China and India have experienced faster income growth than
the world’s rich countries. Nonetheless, it would require another 100 years of
growth at rates higher than those of the U.S., for China and India to reach today’s
level of average income in the U.S. Nancy Birdsall, Life is Unfair: Inequality in
the World, 98 FOREIGN POL’Y 76 (1998).
41
Rahnema, supra note 35, at 158 (detailing the many ways in which a variety of
cultures define and perceive poverty).
42
Id. at 159. See also Ivan Illich, Needs, in THE DEVELOPMENT DICTIONARY, supra
note 1, at 88.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 13 1-SEP-04 12:22
43
ESCOBAR, supra note 19, at 24.
44
This assumption justified the basic tenets of intervention: poverty was too global
and delicate a matter to taken out of the hands of professionals and institutions
that were trained and empowered for this purpose; programs had to be charted in
terms of economic resources and needs; and the agents that would be primarily
responsible for designing and executing such strategies would be governments
and other institutions. Rahnema, supra note 35, at 164. Professor Rahnema ex-
plains that anti-poverty programs claim to be based on an assessment of needs,
but that within the global context, needs are identified in an abstract manner. Id.
45
Id.
46
Id. at 163. Thus impoverished wage earners focused their struggles on limited
objectives such as raising income. Labor unions were utilized while informal and
formal community organizations that had traditionally assisted the poor were dis-
regarded and ignored. Id.
47
Id.
48
ESCOBAR, supra note 19, at 24.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 14 1-SEP-04 12:22
49
Rahnema, supra note 35, at 163; Illich, supra note 42, at 88.
50
Nanda Shrestha, Becoming a Development Category, in POWER OF DEVELOP-
MENT, supra note 17, at 266. Except where noted, this account of life in Nepal
before and after development is from this fascinating chapter by Professor
Shrestha.
51
Rahnema, supra note 35, at 163.
52
Id.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 15 1-SEP-04 12:22
53
Shrestha, supra note 50, at 266. Professor Shrestha notes how a road that had
fallen into disrepair would have been mended through the collective efforts of the
village in the pre-development world. This sense of collective action disappeared
with the advent of development, as everyone waited for the developers to fix it.
54
Ted Lewellen, Deconstructing Development: Toward an Anthropological Defini-
tion of a Value-Laden Concept, Address at the Annual Meeting of the American
Anthropological Association at Washington, DC (Nov. 1997) ( noting that “many
currently ‘underdeveloped’ regions of the world were developing quite well
before their cultures were crushed or shifted in entirely new directions by West-
ern expansion since the 16th Century”).
55
See, e.g., Ziauddin Sardar, Development and the Locations of Eurocentrism, in
CRITICAL DEVELOPMENT THEORY, supra note 4, at 53; see also Richard Cam-
eron Blake, The World Bank’s Draft Comprehensive Development Framework
and the Micro-Paradigm of Law and Development, 3 YALE HUM. RTS. & DEV.
L.J. 159, 166 (2000) (stating “as developing countries created ‘economic, political,
and social institutions similar to those in the West,’ economic development would
inevitably result”); Aoki, supra note 3, at 927–28.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 16 1-SEP-04 12:22
56
OZAY MEHMET, WESTERNIZING THE THIRD WORLD: THE EUROCENTRICITY OF
ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT THEORIES 60 (2d ed. 1995) (noting traditional socie-
ties were viewed as exercising little control over their environment, as “lacking
the traits of modern persons, and as devoid of political consciousness or active
involvement in shaping their future.”)
57
Kothari & Minogue, supra note 7, at 7. Professors Kothari and Minougue con-
tend that successive development theories have simply been reformulations of
modernization theory, which they posit as the mega theory of development. Id.
at 7–8.
58
Sardar, supra note 55, at 52.
59
JAMES MITTELMAN & MUSTAPHA KAMAL PASHA, OUT FROM UNDERDEVELOP-
MENT REVISITED: CHANGING GLOBAL STRUCTURES AND THE REMAKING OF THE
THIRD WORLD 38 (1997).
60
Id. (paraphrasing W.W. ROSTOW, THE STAGES OF ECONOMIC GROWTH: A NON-
COMMUNIST MANIFESTO (1960)).
61
In the early years, all parties seemed to focus on increasing foreign aid from in-
dustrialized countries. See GABE S. VARGES, THE NEW INTERNATIONAL ECO-
NOMIC ORDER LEGAL DEBATE 3–4, 29 (1983). Adeoye Akinsanya & Arthur
Davies, Third World Quest for a New International Economic Order: an Over-
view, 33 INT’L L.Q. 208, 209 (1984) (Noting that “for the developing nations, the
realization of their economic backwardness and lack of progress in combating it
led them, at first, to press for more foreign aid from the industrial countries.”
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 17 1-SEP-04 12:22
The United Nations proclaimed the 1960s the “Development Decade” and an-
nounced, “less developed countries were to be assisted in achieving five percent
annual growth in aggregate national income through expanded international
trade and an annual flow of international assistance and capital.”).
62
MITTELMAN & PASHA, supra note 59, at 39; Sardar, supra note 55, at 52 (Noting
one early indicator of modernization was urbanization, despite the fact that the
overwhelming majority of the populations of the newly independent countries
were based in rural areas. Other indicators included literacy and voting. Based
on these indicators, the only road to modernization was industrialization.).
63
Sardar, supra note 55, at 52. Professor Mittelman and Pasha illustrate the impact
modernization theories can have by recounting the experiences of farmers in a
district in Tanzania. In this district, land is in short supply and most farmers inter-
plant bananas (the staple food) and coffee, because they do not have enough
acreage to plant them separately. The government’s agricultural extension of-
ficers, however, advised them to plant coffee separately because bananas draw
nitrogen and water from the soil and shade the coffee crop. This advice is based
on experiments performed in laboratories and benefits only a minority of wealth-
ier landowners who have enough land to segregate the crops and cultivate land
under conditions similar to those in the lab. Larger landowners are also likely to
mingle with government experts, which facilitate the kind of communication that
leads to the adoption of such changes. Peasants resist the proposed innovations
because they are useless or harmful to them. Government officers then regard
the peasants as traditional, meaning irresponsible, stupid and lazy. The Moderni-
zation hypothesis is then invoked to justify supporting the agents of change and
to legitimize coercing those now termed traditional peasants. MITTELMAN & PA-
SHA, supra note 59, at 39.
64
For a critique of progress, see José Marı́a Sbert, Progress, in THE DEVELOPMENT
DICTIONARY, supra note 1, at 192; Vincent Tucker, The Myth of Development: A
Critique of a Eurocentric Discourse, in CRITICAL DEVELOPMENT THEORY, supra
note 4, at 4–5 (Noting that progress as a concept became pre-eminent during the
French and English revolutions, as both nations set out to change the world and
the manner in which it was perceived. This worldview eventually came to be
perceived as self-evident and universally valid. The rights of man (albeit not all
men or any women) were championed, science appeared to be capable of captur-
ing nature and it was a period of exploration and experimentation. The new mis-
sion was modernity for the entire world and progress came to be fashioned in
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 18 1-SEP-04 12:22
would ultimately result in legal ideals and institutions similar to those in the
West”).
70
David Trubek & Marc Galanter, Scholars in Self-Estrangement: Some Reflections
on the Crisis in Law and Development Studies in the United States, 1974 WIS. L.
REV. 1062, 1071. Its earliest proponents placed “extreme reliance on law as an
agent of modernization and progress predicated on a study of the ideal types of
law and administration that could facilitate progress.” Lakshman Marasinghe,
Law and Development: A Jurisprudence for the Developing World, 8 DEV. EX-
PRESS 1, 2 (1998/1999).
71
Professor Tamanaha has summarized the law and development paradigm as
follows:
1) society is made up of individuals who consent to the state for their own
welfare; 2) the state exercises control over individuals through law, and it is
constrained by law; 3) laws are designed to achieve social purposes and do
not offer a special advantage to any individual or groups within the society;
4) laws are applied equally to all citizens; 5) courts are the primary legal
institution with the responsibility for defining and applying the law; 6) ad-
judication is based upon a comprehensive body of authoritative rules and
doctrines, and judicial decisions are not subject to outside influence; and 7)
legal actors follow the restraining rules and most of the population has in-
ternalized the law, and where there are violations of the rules enforcement
action will guarantee conformity
Tamanaha, supra note 68, at 473 (paraphrasing Trubek, supra note 70, at 1071).
72
Trubek, supra note 70, at 1073. Development was assumed to involve an increase
in man’s rational capacity to control the world, and thus in his ability to improve
his material well being. But “development” offered more than increased ration-
ality and material satisfaction; it also promised greater equality, enhanced free-
dom, and fuller participation in the community. As an ideal, therefore,
“development” held the promise of a life that would be richer in all ways for all
Third World people.
73
Blake, supra note 55, at 167.
74
Several factors contributed to the movement’s abrupt demise, including a sharp
drop in funding by both the public and private sectors in the United States. The
U.S. Agency for International Development and the Ford Foundation, for exam-
ple, were major funding sources for academic and fieldwork in law and develop-
ment; their financial support declined sharply in the early mid-1970s. Some
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 20 1-SEP-04 12:22
was the rupture of the coalition that had given the movement the
appearance of unanimity. Western academics and practitioners
who were the initial proponents of law and development had en-
joyed an initially positive reception from Third World leaders
and elites – many of whom were Western educated.75 By the
early 1970s, however, many political leaders and intellectuals in
the Third World had turned to dependency theory and other rad-
ical analyses of their circumstances, and were demanding a New
International Economic Order.76 In this context, law and devel-
opment was widely denounced as “reflect[ing] the ideological he-
gemony of Western capitalism and the dominant economic forces
of contemporary imperialism. . . .[and] as inadequate to explain
development or underdevelopment. . .”77 Moreover, although
the American experience was thought to exemplify the success of
law and development, many observers expressed “doubt that the
model accurately describe[d] legal life even in the United
States.”78
Long after widespread reports of the movement’s demise,
however, the core premises of law and development continue to
inform most Western thinking (both popular and official) about
observers believe this policy change reflected popular disillusionment and a gen-
eral loss of faith in government and the viability of overseas interventions – re-
sulting significantly from the Viet Nam war and Watergate. See Maxwell O.
Chibundu, Law in Development: On Tapping, Gourding and Serving Palm-Wine,
29 CASE W. RES. J. INT’L L. 167, 169 (1997).
75
Id.
76
Francis G. Snyder, Law and Development in the Light of Dependency Theory, 14
LAW & SOC’Y REV. 723, 727–28 (1980) (Discussing the two ways scholars reacted
to the lack of success of these philosophies. Some argued that their failure “was
the inevitable consequence of the transition to capitalist development. . . The
other elaborated a radical critique, suggesting that capitalist development in the
periphery would not reproduce the historical capitalist path. . . The first approach
is still followed by the majority of development practitioners.”).
77
Id. at 731; see also Aoki, supra note 3, at 928.
78
Trubek, supra note 70, at 1081. Critics of the movement also observed that “the
development equation contain[ed] a heavy social element, for which law is not
the complete answer.” Marasinghe, supra note 70, at 2. Of course, moderniza-
tion has continually reappeared in different guises. See supra notes 67–69 and
accompanying text.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 21 1-SEP-04 12:22
79
For example, the intersection of law and economic development in the Third
World continues to generate significant attention – as evidenced by a 1992 book
with precisely that title. The book was edited by P. Ebow Bondzi-Simpson who,
in the opening chapter, asserts that:
Now that the globe seems to be marching to one drum beat, that of the free
enterprise capitalist system, it follows that the legal institutions and prac-
tices that have fostered and sustained the triumph of the capitalist mode of
production, accumulation, distribution, and consumption are best suited for
other societies, appropriately modified at the margins to account for the
peculiar foibles of those societies.
82
In a 1989 report the World Bank identified bad government (including poor poli-
cies, incompetence and corruption) as the primary obstacle to economic develop-
ment in sub-Saharan Africa. See WORLD BANK, SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA: FROM
CRISIS TO SUSTAINABLE GROWTH: A LONG-TERM PERSPECTIVE STUDY (1989).
83
Chibundu, supra note 74, at 190–91.
84
Mary C. Tsai, Globalization and Conditionality: Two Sides of the Sovereignty
Coin, 31 LAW & POL’Y INT’L BUS. 1317 (2000); Anthony Galano III, International
Monetary Fund Response to the Brazilian Debt Crisis: Whether the Effects of Con-
ditionality Have Undermined Brazil’s National Sovereignty?, 6 PACE INT’L L.
REV. 323 (1994); JACQUES J. POLAK & CATHERINE GWIN, THE WORLD BANK
AND THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND: A CHANGING RELATIONSHIP
(1994). International Financial Institutions or IFIs increasingly embrace an ever-
widening array of governmental functions, such as judicial and public service re-
organization, government auditing functions, and labor and environmental con-
cerns. See Antony Anghie, Time Present and Time Past: Globalization,
International Financial Institutions, and the Third World, 32 N.Y.U. J. INT’L L. &
POL. 243, 266 (2000) [hereinafter Anghie, Time Present and Time Past] (noting
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 23 1-SEP-04 12:22
World Bank interference in any activity that involves development); see also
James Thuo Gathii, Good Governance as a Counter-Insurgency Agenda to Oppo-
sitional and Transformative Social Projects in International Law, 5 BUFF. HUM.
RTS. L. REV. 107 (1999) [hereinafter Gathii, Good Governance].
85
One means is through “conditionality” – the IFI practice of making loans condi-
tional on policy and/or structural changes by the borrowing state. Conditionality
allows the World Bank and the IMF to restrict credit if a country’s fails to comply
with the terms of its lending agreement. Tsai, supra note 84; POLAK & GWIN,
supra note 84. See infra notes 169-203 (detailing Structural Adjustment programs
during the 1980s) and accompanying text.
86
The World Bank and the IMF are also known as the Bretton Woods institutions,
because they were formed at Bretton Woods, New Hampshire in July 1944. The
two organizations have similar governance structures, operating according to a
weighted voting system that is based on contributions made by members. The
broad legal framework for the two institutions is also similar, with emphasis on an
ostensibly non-political character. See Anghie, supra note 84, at 269; Gathii,
Good Governance, supra note 84, at 225.
87
Cf. Balakrishnan Rajagopal, From Resistance to Renewal: The Third World, So-
cial Movements, and the Expansion of International Institutions, 41 HARV. INT’L
L.J. 529, 530 (2000) [hereinafter Rajagopal, From Resistance to Renewal]. Profes-
sor Rajagopal rejects the prevailing “functionalist” conception of international
institutions. He notes that the functionalist “theory explains the emergence of
international institutions as a result of a pragmatic necessity to serve concrete
functions. . . The central proposition of this theory is that institutions are born
and expand due to top-down policy decisions that correlate with the functional
needs of international society.” Not coincidentally, this top-down conception is
consistent with the perceived “hegemonic nature of international law as an elitist
discipline.”
88
Section I of Article I of IBRD’s Articles of Agreement states that the Bank is:
embarked on the Marshall Plan and took over most of the fi-
nancing for the reconstruction of Europe. With its role in Eu-
rope eclipsed,89 the Bank was left to pursue its secondary charge:
“the development of productive facilities and resources in less
developed countries.”90 But even this function, as originally con-
templated, bears little resemblance to the Bank’s contemporary
role in the Third World. The World Bank was intended to act as
an intermediary between prospective borrowers and prospective
investors, meaning it was to play the traditional role of a private,
commercial bank – except that its depositors and borrowers
would be member states.91 Under the terms of its Articles of
Agreement, the Bank was to make loans based exclusively on
“considerations of economy and efficiency;”92 it was expressly
prohibited from entertaining “political or other non-economic in-
fluences or considerations.”93
The Bank’s evolution into an Institution that touches on al-
most all aspects of the economic, social and political lives of its
borrowers has much to do with how development itself has
evolved over the last fifty years and with other factors such as the
post World War II struggle between capitalism and communism,
a struggle within which the World Bank was a critical weapon.94
regimes in Asia, Africa and Latin America. For example, Nicaragua, whose rul-
ing Samoza family was cooperating closely with the U.S. military, received 10
World Bank loans between 1951 and 1960. Guatemala, however, with three times
Nicaragua’s population, received no World Bank support until the overthrow of
its supposedly communist regime in 1955. Loans were used to build dams, high-
ways and other infra-structure projects that would facilitate economic growth. As
these projects failed to achieve their intended results, however, it became appar-
ent that securing the allegiance of Third World regimes – particularly oppressive
ones – would not necessarily pacify the populations who were subject to those
regimes, and thus there might be a need for direct programs to alleviate poverty.
In other words, preventing communist subversion in the Third World was going
to require programs to alleviate poverty within Third World countries, and this
was not being accomplished by the World Bank’s project-based lending in sup-
port of infrastructure; the required shift in policy began at the regional level.)
95
In 1959, U.S. President Eisenhower explained the establishment of the Inter-
American Development Bank as follows:
grown, its position in the affairs of its Third World members ex-
panded in tandem, and steadily and consistently grew ever
broader and deeper.97
97
See infra notes 112-228 and accompanying text for discussion of the “cycles of
conventional wisdom.”
98
The principal task originally assigned to the IMF was “to promote international
monetary cooperation” and “to give confidence to members by making the
Fund’s resources temporarily available to them under adequate safeguards.” Ar-
ticles of Agreement of the International Monetary Fund, art. I(i), I(v), 60 Stat.
1401, 29 U.S.T. 2203, as amended (1945), available at http://www.imf.org/external/
pubs/ft/aa/aa.pdf (last visited Nov. 16, 2003) [hereinafter IMF Articles of Agree-
ment]; see also Enrique R. Carrasco, Income Distribution and the Bretton Woods
Institutions: Promoting an Enabling Environment for Social Development, 6
TRANSNAT’L L. & CONTEMP. PROBS. 1 (1996); Daniel D. Bradlow, The World
Bank, the IMF, and Human Rights, 6 TRANSNAT’L L. & CONTEMP. PROBS. 47
(1996); Stephen Anthony, IMF Structural Adjustment Programs: An Economic
Evaluation, 3 GEO. PUBLIC POL’Y REV. 133 (1998).
99
Carreau, supra note 91 (Noting that in essence, the IMF’s member states agreed
to relinquish some of their sovereignty over their national monetary systems in
exchange for short-term assistance when needed, and for the stability the IMF
would bring to the international monetary system. The IMF’s normative powers
thus depended on the cooperation of its member states.).
100
Id. (also noting that this decision may have been in violation of the par value
system established in the IMF Articles of Agreement).
101
Id.
102
Bradlow, supra note 98, at 47.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 27 1-SEP-04 12:22
103
Carreau, supra note 91 (noting that IMF lending has always been conditional;
borrowers are required to adopt stabilization plans and to correct the types of
imbalances that were thought to have figured significantly in precipitating World
War II).
104
Professor Carreau observes:
Gradually and involuntarily, the IMF has lost its influence over its most
developed member states, which remain bound by very limited monetary
obligations since the collapse of the par value system in 1971 and which
have abstained from turning to the IMF for assistance. . . because of the
conditions imposed.
107
Rajagopal, From Resistance to Renewal, supra note 87, at 541.
108
Genoveva Hernandez Uriz, To Lend or Not To Lend: Oil, Human Rights, and the
World Bank’s Internal Contradictions, 14 HARV. HUM. RTS. J. 197 (2001).
109
Liberal critics generally accept the candor and validity of IFI goals of alleviating
poverty and improving standards of living in the Third World. See Operational
Directive 4.15: Poverty Reduction (1992), THE WORLD BANK OPERATIONAL
MANUAL 2 (1992) (stating that “sustainable poverty reduction is the Bank’s over-
arching objective”); Policy Development and Review Department, The Poverty
Reduction and Growth Facility (PRGF) – Operational Issues, International Mone-
tary Fund, at http://www.imf.org/external/np/pdr/prsp/poverty2.htm (last visited
Feb. 21, 2004) (proclaiming “poverty reduction efforts among low-income mem-
bers a key and more explicit element of a renewed growth-oriented economic
strategy” of the IMF). In their view, the problem is ineffective strategies and/or
improper implementation by IFIs themselves and/or by Third World govern-
ments. Some liberal critics also allege that IFIs are “out of touch” because they
are Western-dominated and unrepresentative. See, e.g., Oscar Shachter, The
Evolving Law of International Development, 15 COLUM. J. TRANSNAT’L L. 1
(1976).
110
Critics embracing a more radical perspective contend that IFIs are in place pri-
marily to maintain the international economic status quo, and to enable the coun-
tries of the industrialized North to continue exploiting the countries of the South.
See, e.g., Saving Failed States, supra note 12; David Greenberg, Law and Develop-
ment in Light of Dependency Theory, 3 RES. IN L. & SOC. 129, 152 (1980); James
Thuo Gathii, Africa’s Economic and Political Predicaments, 45 VILL. L. REV. 971,
1002 [hereinafter Gathii, Africa Predicaments]; Gathii, Good Governance, supra
note 84, at 224 (relating the hierarchical nature of the international order and
demonstrating that decisions to undertake national economic management have
been taken out of the hands of developing countries through structural adjust-
ment programs that are required for the continuance of foreign aid). Critics also
point out that eighty percent of U.S. aid to Africa, for example, is spent on Amer-
ican commodities, expertise, and subcontractors; only twenty percent of the
money ever leaves the U.S. It is also noteworthy that in 1989, the Bank em-
ployed 80,000 consultants on Africa with only one percent of them being African,
meaning the other ninety-nine percent come from outside the continent. Ernesto
Hernandez-Cata, Remark, Panel Three: The Role of Multi-Lateral Institutions in
African Development, 30 LAW & POL’Y INT’L BUS. 708, 711 (1999).
111
For example, Professor Balakrishnan Rajagopal contends that both the liberal
and radical critiques are useful but flawed. He believes that the liberal critique
(1) fails to acknowledge that IFI interventions in the Third World often worsen
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 29 1-SEP-04 12:22
circumstances by exacerbating class divisions that are already too broad, and (2)
is inadequate to explain not only the general failure of IFI poverty reduction
programs, but also the widespread popular resistance to those programs in the
Third World. He believes the radical critique, on the other hand, oversimplifies
complex and differing relationships, leads to “policy paralysis,” and fails to ex-
plain the continuing participation of legions of intelligent and genuinely well-in-
tentioned individuals in “development work.” Professor Rajagopal suggests an
alternative analysis that differs from the liberal and radical critiques. He main-
tains that just as the Third World is defined by the concept of development, IFIs
are defined by their mission, and the development project has become that mis-
sion. He continues:
IFIs have had a complex relationship with Third World resistance. . . .it is
the process by which [IFIs] have dealt with that resistance, and not so much
the resistance itself, that have revealed the centrality of the resistance to
the formation of the [IFIs’] changing institutional agendas. . .. This . . . is
hardly acknowledged by the [IFIs], who see their evolution as being gov-
erned purely by the laws of economics, finance, or their Articles of Agree-
ment. It matters less that poverty alleviation programs never alleviate
poverty or that conditionalities never achieve their stated goals. Rather,
these specific interventions . . . redound to the authority and expansion of
international institutions.
Rajagopal, From Resistance to Renewal, supra note 87, at 576.
112
The phrase “cycles of conventional wisdom” is borrowed from an article by
economist Paul Krugman that discusses the myriad models of development
promulgated by development specialists and how these models were developed.
He concludes that development specialists are a closed insular group that does
not rely upon proven methods or past experience, and appear unable to
accomplish modernization. Paul Krugman, Cycles of Conventional Wisdom in
Eocnomic Development, 72 INT’L AFFAIRS 717, 717 (1996).
113
Kothari & Minogue, supra note 7, at 1. Definitions of “development” abound.
Professor Simon asserts that these definitions are “contextual and contingent
upon the ideological, epistemological or methodological orientation of their pur-
veyors, and there has never been a consensus or unanimity about the meaning or
content of development.” Simon, supra note 10, at 17.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 30 1-SEP-04 12:22
114
Autonomous decision-making and implementation by both nations and peoples
were emphasized. Sardar, supra note 55. See also Rosemary McGee, Participat-
ing in Development, in DEVELOPMENT THEORY AND PRACTICE CRITICAL PER-
SPECTIVES, supra note 7, at 92.
115
Finite resources and the fragility of the global environment were additional fac-
tors to be considered and taken into account. Sardar, supra note 55, at 53. This
followed on the heals of the Stockholm Conference on the Environment in 1972
and was popularized by such publications as WORLD COMMISSION ON EMPLOY-
MENT, OUR COMMON FUTURE (1987).
116
“Liberalization” and “open markets” have become the driving force of develop-
ment. Sardar, supra note 55.
117
Cowen & Shenton, supra note 17, at 27.
118
The so-called “golden age of development” overlapped with the beginning of
what would be a series of United Nations Development Decades. Pursuant to a
request by President John F. Kennedy, the General Assembly of the United
Nations unanimously approved Resolution 1710, which declared the first
Development Decade in 1961. The goal was to attain, “in each under-developed
country a substantial increase in the rate of growth, with each country setting its
own target, taking as the objective a minimum annual rate of growth of aggregate
national income of 5 percent at the end of the Decade.” G.A. Res. 1710, U.N.
GAOR, 16th Sess., 1084th plen. mtg., at 17, U.N. Doc. A/5100 (1961); DUSAN
DJONOVICH, 1 RESOLUTIONS ADOPTED BY THE GENERAL ASSEMBLY, UNITED
NATIONS RESOLUTIONS (1972). In some respects, these resolutions reflect the
failures of development, the hopes of Third World nations, and convey the
progression of development in theory and practice.
119
MEHMET, supra note 56, at 63.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 31 1-SEP-04 12:22
120
ESCOBAR, supra note 19, at 24 (stating development theory was strongly influ-
enced by the neo-Keynesian consensus that dominated economic thinking and
practice in the post-War period); Paul Cammack, Neoliberalism, the World Bank
and the New Politics of Development, in DEVELOPMENT THEORY AND PRACTICE,
supra note 7, at 157, 161 (noting that it was assumed that states could and should
intervene directly in production and distribution, making development an active,
state-led process).
121
Cammack, supra note 120, at 157, 161; MEHMET, supra note 56, at 60.
122
MEHMET, supra note 56, at 96. This is quite ironic given the contemporary near-
religious devotion to the free market.
123
Cammack, supra note 120, at 157, 161; MEHMET, supra note 56, at 60.
124
MEHMET, supra note 56, at 96. Planners did not consider how countries would
administer these ambitious plans; indeed institution building was ignored and
Western planners utilized a “how to do” approach. Id.
125
Because underdeveloped countries were believed to be “trapped in a vicious cir-
cle of poverty and thus lacking capital, it would therefore have to come from
abroad.” ESCOBAR, supra note 19, at 40.
126
“Project lending” was aimed primarily at developing infrastructure; it was in-
tended to facilitate business by cultivating the factors necessary for economic
growth. Bank officials believed it was crucial to construct electric power plants
and roads because industry could not be developed without electricity and the
means to transport finished products. Thus in the absence of this kind of infra-
structure, most economic activities would be difficult if not impossible. For ex-
ample, good roads were necessary because no investor would want to invest in a
country if its products could not be transported. Sandra Blanco, Symposium: Part
One: Pursuing the Good Life: The Meaning of Development as It Relates to the
World Bank and the IMF, 9 TRANSNAT’L. & CONTEMP. PROBS. 109, 110 (1999).
Consequently, the Bank mainly financed dams, highways, and other large-scale
infrastructure projects. Tsai, supra note 84.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 32 1-SEP-04 12:22
127
ESCOBAR, supra note 19, at 36 (noting that technology not only “amplified mate-
rial progress, [but] would confer . . . a sense of direction and significance”; it was
the key to modernization and indeed the transfer of technology became an im-
portant component of the development project).
128
Id.
129
MEHMET, supra note 56, at 96. Institutional efficiency, indigenous history and
culture and critical issues such as land reform were not part of the planning pro-
cess; plans were generally derived in a vacuum. Id.
130
Blanco, supra note 126, at 111.
131
Id.
132
Esteva, supra note 1, at 13.
133
See discussion infra Part III. A.
134
The multiplying failures of the development project and other events supported
the dependency critique. For example, when internal forces extended state con-
trol over the economy through nationalizations, and sought to give workers and
farmers more of a share in national wealth, private investors would flee and for-
eign loans would be denied. This financial strangulation sometimes led to mili-
tary coups and military incursions into the political process. The repetition of this
course of events fueled radical intellectuals who emphasized the impact of impe-
rialism, which used political, military and economic dominance to control produc-
tion in foreign nations. They also emphasized the impact of external forces from
the economies of the “center” on the economies of the “periphery”, and focused
on domination and subordination in general, and specifically on the effects of
imperialism and colonialism. MITTELMAN & PASHA, supra note 59, at 44–45.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 33 1-SEP-04 12:22
135
See discussion infra Part II.A.
136
ESCOBAR, supra note 19, at 40.
137
Senarclens, supra note 30.
138
Blanco, supra note 126, at 111.
139
Carreau, supra note 91, at 1999.
140
This was also arguably a violation of its Articles of Agreement. The World Bank
Articles of Agreement provide that the World Bank’s lending policy is to be dic-
tated by purely financial considerations, meaning its funds can be lent only on
projects that are reasonably expected to generate sufficient funds to repay the
loan. Although it was believed these projects would contribute to the overall
development of member States, these projects could not be viewed as profit-ori-
ented. Indeed, many of these projects did not generate any income whatsoever.
Thus, the Bank increased its financial exposure, and borrowing members had to
utilize already limited foreign exchange resources to repay the Bank. Not sur-
prisingly, the Bank began to face defaults. Carreau, supra note 91, at 1999.
141
Jennifer N. Weidner, World Bank Study, 7 BUFF. HUM. RTS. L. REV. 193 (2001).
142
In 1970, the UN General Assembly declared the beginning of a Second Develop-
ment Decade (1971-1981) that called for a more equitable distribution of income
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 34 1-SEP-04 12:22
150
Id.
151
Id. at 92.
152
For example, “Micro-development” theorists advocated targeting the individual
rather than infrastructure and governments, on the premise that development
would occur when people were empowered to confront and address their pov-
erty. Once empowered, people would “organize themselves and overcome the
obstacles to their social, cultural and economic well-being” with foreign organiza-
tions relegated to a supportive role. Empirically, micro-development theory as-
sumes that poverty results from lack [of] access to resources that are essential to
the satisfaction of basic human needs,” and that this lack of access is a ‘product of
lack of power in social relations.’” See Blake, supra note 55, at 166. Micro-devel-
opment theorists also emphasize a more equitable distribution of international
economic power, which can occur only at the macro level. Russell Lawrence
Barsh, The Right to Development as a Human Right: Results of the Global Con-
sultation, 13 HUM. RTS. Q. 322, 327 (1991).
153
Endogenous development proposed that the distinctiveness of individual cultures
and societies should be at the center of determining the goals to be pursued. This
approach was generally accepted for a period of time, even though it was at odds
with core assumptions of the development project, which are universalistic. Es-
teva, supra note 1, at 15.
154
Sustainable development was defined as economic growth that takes account of
environmental concerns. See David P. Forsythe, The United Nations, Human
Rights, and Development, 19 HUM. RTS. Q. 334, 334 (1997). Like micro-develop-
ment, it had a social dimension, emphasizing that development is more than eco-
nomic growth. See also Blake, supra note 55, at 168; Forsythe, supra note 154, at
335. Both micro-development and sustainable development concentrate on edu-
cation and literacy, health services, poverty alleviation, environmental protection,
community cooperation and participation, and social and cultural cohesiveness;
success is not measured solely in terms of economic growth. Results can be in-
tangible, such as improved skills in communication, leadership or management; a
stronger sense of self; the establishment of civil liberties; or the increased ability
to leverage services from the state. Results can also be tangible, such as increases
in the production of agricultural or manufactured goods; a rise in family incomes;
a building used for organizational activities; or a road or water system. Id. at
166–68. The Stockholm conference on the environment was in 1972, and the no-
tion of sustainable development was further defined and cemented with the pub-
lication of the Brandt Report, entitled Our Common Future, supra note 115.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 36 1-SEP-04 12:22
155
MITTELMAN & PASHA, supra note 59, at 93. The problem was that neither theo-
rists nor NGOs bothered with the endogenous cultures from which successful
grassroots institutions might emerge. Id. See also McGee, supra note 114, at 92;
Majid Rahnema, Participation, in THE DEVELOPMENT DICTIONARY, supra note 1,
at 116 [hereinafter Rahnema, Participation].
156
“The complex relation between one particular problem and the other problems
would be established and then unified with the problem currently at the center of
the process.” Esteva, Development, in THE DEVELOPMENT DICTIONARY at 14.
157
Wolfgang Sachs, Environment, in THE POST-DEVELOPMENT READER, supra note
17, at 26 (noting that the ebb and flow of international development theories
generally follow political sensibilities in the West). For a discussion of the emer-
gence of “basic needs” as a development strategy, see Arturo Escobar, Planning,
in THE POST-DEVELOPMENT READER, supra note 17, at 137–39 [hereinafter Es-
cobar, Planning]; see also Illich, supra note 42, at 88–101.
158
Sachs, supra note 157, at 26.
159
McGee, supra note 114, at 92; Rahnema, supra note 155, at 116.
160
See Rajagopal, From Resistance to Renewal, supra note 87.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 37 1-SEP-04 12:22
161
For an analysis of participation, see Rahnema, supra note 155, at 116. The emer-
gence of these paradigms may also reflect the influence of NGOS. McGee, supra
note 114, at 92.
162
On December 5, 1980, the UN General Assembly approved Resolution 35/36
that established the need for a Third Development Decade for the 1980s. It
called for accelerating development, promoting economic and social develop-
ment, reducing disparities between Northern and Southern tier countries, and
early eradication of poverty and dependency. The definitive objective was the
“constant improvement of the well being of the entire population through full
participation in the process of development and the fair distribution of benefits to
women.” G.A. Res. 36, U.N. GAOR, 35th Sess., 83d plen. mtg., at 106, U.N.
Doc. A/RES/35/36 (1980). Part of the strategy included establishing a new inter-
national economic order, which would include industrialization and a more sta-
ble, equitable and effective international monetary system. OZMANCZYK, supra
note 142, at 528.
163
See infra notes 165–69 and accompanying text.
164
The crushing burden of this debt continues to cement the dependent status of the
poorest countries in the international financial system. The combined total exter-
nal debt of the Third World now exceeds two trillion dollars. See UNITED NA-
TIONS DEVELOPMENT PROGRAMME, HUMAN DEVELOPMENT REPORT 1999, at 196
(1999). The legion and, thus far, unsuccessful proposals for resolving the crisis
have included the “Baker plan”; the “Brady plan”; “debt-for-equity,” “debt-for-
nature,” and “debt-for-development” plans; “securitization”; and the
“Miyazawa,” “Mitterand,” and “Robinson” proposals. Sylvester, supra note 6, at
265–76. The program currently in effect is the Heavily Indebted Poor Countries
(“HIPC”) Debt Initiative. HIPC was launched by the World Bank and the IMF
in 1996, and then revised in 1999. Assistance provided by HIPC is in addition to
such relief as a debtor country may be able to arrange directly with creditors.
The World Bank’s web site outlines the initiative as follows:
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 38 1-SEP-04 12:22
Eligible countries will qualify for debt relief in two stages. In the first stage
the debtor country will need to demonstrate the capacity to use prudently
the assistance granted by establishing a satisfactory track record, normally
of three years. . . In the second stage . . . the country will implement a full-
fledged poverty reduction strategy, which has been prepared with broad
participation of civil society, and an agreed set of measures aimed at en-
hancing economic growth.
The World Bank Group, Ethiopia Receives Debt Relief Under HIPC Initiative:
Total Support Worth US$1.9 Billion, at http://www.worldbank.org/hipc/about
background.html (last visited July 13, 2003). The program now involves 42 coun-
tries: 34 in Africa, four in Latin America, three in Asia and one in the Middle
East. The World Bank Group, HIPC, HIPC Map, at http://www.worldbank.org/
hipc/about/map/map.html (last visited July 13, 2003). The results of the HIPC
Initiative remain to be seen. Its implementation to date, however, has been no
less top-down and inflexible than previous IFI programs, according to participat-
ing country government officials with whom one of the present authors has spo-
ken. Professor Thomas observes that, “[t]he debt burden is directly related to
world hunger and poverty because debtor governments must divert precious and
scarce resources to paying down external debt instead of meeting the pressing
needs of their populations.” Chantal Thomas, International Debt Forgiveness and
Global Poverty Reduction, 27 FORDHAM URB. L.J. 1711, 1712 (2000). Many
Third World governments spend more than twice as much servicing external debt
as they do on health and education. See Oxfam International Advocacy Offce &
UNICEF, Debt Relief and Poverty Reduction: Meeting the Challenge, § 2.1 (1999),
available at http://www.oxfam.org/eng/pdfs/pp9908_debt_relief_and_poverty_re-
duction.pdf (last visited Feb. 22, 2004). “In Zambia – where infant mortality
rates are increasing, over half a million children are out of school, and illiteracy is
rising – debt servicing claims more of the national budget that health and educa-
tion combined.” Id., at § 3.2 (emphasis omitted).
165
Jerome I. Levinson, A Perspective on the Debt Crisis, 4 AM. U. J. INT’L L. &
POL’Y 489 (1989).
166
Oil prices, which had increased five-fold between 1971 and 1974, doubled again in
1980. Id. at 491, 495–96.
167
By 1974, OPEC annual revenues exceeded $100 billion. Sylvester, supra note 6, at
264. The precariousness of the situation was compounded by political instability
in Middle East, the 1979 fall of the Shah of Iran, and double digit inflation in the
United States. Id.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 39 1-SEP-04 12:22
168
Id. at 265 (Noting that these developments affected Third World debtors in two
critical ways. First, a significant portion of the loans carried floating interest
rates, and these rates skyrocketed. Second, because of tight money and weak-
ened demand, Third World debtors had trouble selling their exports to raise reve-
nue. In 1982, Mexico made its historic declaration of inability to meet even the
interest payments on its external debts, and the “Third World debt crisis” was
well on its way to becoming a household phrase.)
169
Rajesh Swaminathan, Regulating Development: Structural Adjustment and the
Case for National Enforcement of Economic and Social Rights, 37 COLUM. J.
TRANSNAT’L L. 161 (1998); Anthony, supra note 98. Adjustment lending con-
sisted of six core objectives. These were: “[1] raising saving rates, [2] securing
financial stability, [3] liberalizing and opening economies to foreign trade, [4] re-
ducing state intervention and making markets more efficient, [5] reorienting gov-
ernment spending and improving revenue collection, and [6] mobilizing external
sources.” IMF Development and Review Department, Experience Under the
IMF’s Enhanced Structural Adjustment Facility, FIN. & DEV., Sept. 1997, at 32,
available at http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/1997/09/pdf/imf.pdf (last
visited Nov. 16, 2003).
170
Swaminathan, supra note 169; Bradlow, supra note 98; Anthony, supra note 98.
Organization of Economic Cooperation and Development (“OECD”) members
and countries such as Brazil, Mexico, South Korea, Taiwan and Thailand could
bypass the IMF and its constraints. Carreau, supra note 91, at 1996.
171
Swaminathan, supra note 169, at 178–79; Bradlow, supra note 98. The IMF’s Ar-
ticles of Agreement explicitly prohibits any consideration of a nation’s political
affairs in making loan determinations. Bradlow, supra note 98, Carreau, supra
note 91, at 1997. Indeed, the IMF was to only be concerned with attaining specif-
ically prescribed macroeconomic goals, rather than with how a Member State
actually reached those goals. Although conditions were always attached to IMF
lending, they were limited to macro-economic variables such as debt, money sup-
ply, and inflation. Id. But with its involvement in the Third World, these con-
straints began to dissolve, as the Fund’s primary role shifted to handling the
economies of developing countries and, more recently, countries in transition.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 40 1-SEP-04 12:22
179
Carrasco, supra note 98, at 38–39; Bradlow, supra note 98, at 57.
180
The bank turned to alleviating Third World poverty by promoting economic
growth.
181
IMF Articles of Agreement, supra note 98, art. 4(1); Bradlow, supra note 98, at
57.
182
Bradlow, supra note 98, at 57 (noting that in the 1980s, the Bank became heavily
involved in funding development projects in such spheres as health, education,
agriculture and housing).
183
Bradlow, supra note 98, at 47, 54.
184
Weidner, supra note 141, at 198–99; Bradlow, supra note 98, at 60.
185
See Bradlow, supra note 98, at 57; Uriz, supra note 108, at 205; Weidner, supra
note 141, at 198–99.
186
Carrasco, supra note 98, at 38–39; Tsai, supra note 84, at 1322.
187
The “seal of approval” earned by complying with World Bank and IMF credit
packages was critical to attaining private loans from the commercial banks of
developed countries. See Tsai, supra note 84, at 1322; Galano, supra note 84, at
339; Anne Orford, Locating the International: Military and Monetary Interven-
tions after the Cold War, 38 HARV. INT’L L.J. 443, 445 (1997).
188
Tsai, supra note 84, at 1322.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 42 1-SEP-04 12:22
189
3 THE WORLD BANK, supra note 175, at 134; George B.N. Ayittey, Aid for Black
Elephants: How Foreign Assistance Has Failed Africa, in PERPETUATING POV-
ERTY: THE WORLD BANK, THE IMF, AND THE DEVELOPING WORLD 115–16,
140–42 (Doug Bandow & Ian Vásquez eds., 1994).
190
Swaminathan, supra note 169, at 177–89.
191
See Anghie, Time Present and Time Past, supra note 84, at 252–53 (commenting
on adverse effects of IFI structural adjustment programs in the Third World.).
Somalia and Rwanda are two examples of states that were subjects of extensive
structural adjustment programs that may have contributed to their collapse. See
id. at 263.
192
With reductions in the size of governments, unemployment rose in countries
where the state was the largest employer, and privatizing state activities often
contributed to more hardships for the working poor. Swaminathan, supra note
169, at 180–82; Ayittey, supra note 189, at 140–41; Orford, supra note 187, at
470–71.
193
Swaminathan, supra note 169, at 180–82; Ayittey, supra note 189, at 140–41.
194
Orford, supra note 187, at 456; Swaminathan, supra note 169, at 181; Rajagopal,
From Resistance to Renewal, supra note 87, at 575; 3 THE WORLD BANK, supra
note 175, at 14–15, 46–48; PERPETUATING POVERTY, supra note 189, at 59–60.
195
For example, James Gathii opines that structural adjustment in Sub-Saharan Af-
rica primarily focused on producing a conducive framework within which the re-
payment of the debts owed by African states to international banks and lending
agencies is facilitated, and the unhindered influx of new international capital into
these countries is secured. Gathii, Good Governance, supra note 84, at 207.
196
Structural adjustment programs typically involved currency devaluations, pro-
ducer price increases, trade liberalization, privatization, and a range of specific
institutional changes prescribed under the heading of “good governance.”
Anghie, Time Present and Time Past, supra note 84, at 252–53. See also, Antony
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 43 1-SEP-04 12:22
203
Watts, supra note 24, at 58.
204
As had been the case since 1961, the UN General Assembly declared yet another
development decade, to begin on January 1, 1990. Resolution 45/199 again
declared the objective of accelerated development, calling for a surge in the pace
of economic growth in developing countries; a development process that is
responsive to social needs, seeks to reduce extreme poverty, promotes the
development and utilization of human resources and skills and is environmentally
sustainable; an improvement in international monetary, financial and trade
mechanisms in support of development; a strong and stable world economy with
sound national and international macroeconomic management; the strengthening
of international cooperation for development; and special efforts to assist the
least developed countries. G.A. Res. 199, U.N. GAOR, 45th Sess., 71st plen.
mtg., U.N. Doc. A/RES/45/199 (1990).
205
MITTELMAN & PASHA, supra note 59, at 42. It is sometimes termed the three Ds:
denationalization, deregulation, and devaluation. Id.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 45 1-SEP-04 12:22
206
For a discussion of these reports, which were promulgated throughout the 1990s,
see Cammack, supra note 120, at 157, 164.
207
The World Bank Group, CDF Proposal, A Proposal for a Comprehensive Devel-
opment Framework (A Discussion Draft) (Jan. 21, 1999) (memorandum from
James D. Wolfensohn, President, to the Board, Management, and Staff of the
World Bank Group), available at http://siteresources.worldbank.org/CDF/Re-
sources/cdf.pdf (last visited Feb. 22, 2004) [hereinafter “CDF Proposal”]; Blake,
supra note 55, at 160. According to this report, the World Bank would hence-
forth be guided by four guiding principles: (1) development goals and strategies
should be determined by individual member states, and not by the World Bank;
(2) development should be holistic in nature, so that growth focuses not just on
economic variables, but also on social and political implications; (3) the develop-
ment process should involve all actors affected by World Bank lending practices;
and (4) development policies should have a long-term focus. CDF Proposal,
supra this note, at 22–24. The Bank believes the CDF is an improvement over its
previous adherence to macroeconomic indicators as the sole gauge of a nation’s
economic health, while acknowledging that the CDF has not met with universal
approval. See, e.g., Uriz, supra note 108, at 205; Blake, supra note 55, at 177.
208
Structural aspects included good and clean governance, a well-organized financial
system, and an adequate social safety net to accommodate the short-term nega-
tive impact of some World Bank programs. CDF Proposal, supra note 207, at
10–12; see Blake, supra note 55, at 162.
209
Human aspects encompassed education, health, and population issues. CDF Pro-
posal, supra note 207, at 13–14; see Blake, supra note 55, at 162.
210
Physical characteristics for growth included quantifiable achievements in building
infrastructure, including adequate water and sewer systems, access to energy, ac-
cess and transportation inlays. CDF Proposal, supra note 207, at 15–18; see
Blake, supra note 55, at 163.
211
Sector-specific aspects of development referred to strategies to promote the ad-
vancement of rural, urban, and private sectors. CDF Proposal, supra note 207, at
18–20; Cammack, supra note 120, at 157, 164.
212
Cammack, supra note 120, at 157, 164.
213
Weidner, supra note 141, at 223–24; Blake, supra note 55, at 163.
214
NGOs had long been critical of – and largely ignored by – the international finan-
cial institutions. The Bank now invites selected NGOs to take part in develop-
ment projects. By 1999, 52% of Bank projects involved some type of NGO
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 46 1-SEP-04 12:22
participation. Weidner, supra note 141, at 220. A rather striking and wide-rang-
ing example of NGO participation in World Bank programs began in 1995 when
the Bank entered into a joint initiative with the Structural Adjustment Par-
ticipatory Review Initiative Network (SAPRIN). Today, SAPRIN works in 17
countries where it consults with World Bank officials on the effects of specific
lending arrangements. The objective of SAPRIN is to legitimize local knowledge
in the analysis of economic-reform programs and to make space for, and institu-
tionalize, grassroots involvement in macroeconomic decision-making. See Struc-
tural Adjustment Participatory Review International Network, at http://
www.saprin.org (last visited Nov. 16, 2003).
215
Kothari & Minogue, supra note 7, at 9.
216
Watts, supra note 24, at 58. The rationale behind building self-reliance was “the
desire to release those energies that permit ordinary people to take charge of
their lives.” Id.
217
Civil society is also central in the alternatives to development paradigm, which
has focused on “new social movements.” Id. at 58. Both the new development
economics of the 1990s and the anti-development paradigm assert alternative
strategies; both speak of an expanded role for civil society and both question the
form, function and character of the developmental state. Id. at 59.
218
Id. at 58.
219
Uriz, supra note 108, at 204. The good governance initiative was defined as “a
systematic effort to build pluralistic institutional structures, a determination to
respect the rule of law, and a vigorous protection of freedom of the press and
human rights.” Id.
220
Id. at 204–05 (noting that good governance has been criticized as entailing a vari-
ety of interventions that are inconsistent with the Bank’s mandate and, as a
doubtful solution to the multifaceted crises of the Third World). Professor Gathii
contends that “good governance” policies are based on the questionable assump-
tion that reducing governmental intervention in the economy will automatically
increase economic growth and personal freedom. The Organization of African
Unity and the Economic Commission on Africa identified external economic de-
pendence as a major factor in Africa’s poor economic performance in the Lagos
Report of 1980, and recommended that external dependence on Western coun-
tries be reduced and replaced with a self-sustaining development strategy based
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 47 1-SEP-04 12:22
on the maximum internal use of the continent’s resources. Gathii, Good Govern-
ance, supra note 84, at 109. Professor Gathii also maintains that the good govern-
ance agenda focuses too much attention on internal policy failures within Third
World countries and not enough on the historical and international economic fac-
tors that Southern governments believe are the primary causes of their current
difficulties. See Gathii, Africa Predicaments, supra note 110, at 1008 (noting that
African governments take the opposite view of IFIs and other proponents of the
good governance agenda; and contrasting the Lagos Report with the Berg Re-
port’s emphasis on improper economic policies pursued by African governments
as the main cause of the crisis.
221
See Gathii, Good Governance, supra note 84, at 108.
222
Cammack, supra note 120, at 164. This policy promoted a pattern of growth that
would utilize the most abundant asset possessed by the poor – their labor. The
prevailing logic is that governments should pursue policies that provide busi-
nesses (capital) across the globe with an adequate number of healthy and edu-
cated workers, and to impose disciplines that ensure these workers remain
available. Basic social services, such as primary education, health care and family
planning, which make it possible for the poor to work, are to be made available
and this would more easily allow capital to exploit the global labor market. Ben-
efits are to be targeted to potential workers, which then makes it difficult to sur-
vive outside of the labor market, and creates safety nets that propel workers back
into the market if they temporarily drop out.
223
Id. As Professor Cammack puts it, the CDF entails putting the poor to work, in
the name of poverty alleviation. Of course, it also means low wage workers for
global capital.
224
For example, governments should provide health care, education, nutrition and
family planning services, which are spheres that often are not well-served by the
private market. Id. at 166.
225
Id.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 48 1-SEP-04 12:22
226
State managed stabilization policies to prevent recession or depression have
given way to internationally managed policies of restructuring, often deliberately
inducing domestic recession; re-distributive taxation to bring about greater equal-
ity of incomes has been abandoned in favor fiscal reform that rewards entrepre-
neurship and accentuates inequality; measures to regulate prices have been
dropped; public control over labor and money markets has been systematically
stripped away; the indefinite extension of the sphere of wants to be satisfied by
public enterprise has been thrown into reverse and social security legislation has
been restructured to promote rather than work against market forces.” Id. at
164.
227
The IMF approach to the Third World has continued to evolve, but it has been
“less comprehensive” in its interventions in the name of development. Although
it is outside the scope of its mandate, the IMF expressly supports Third World
economic growth. The IMF also now includes poverty alleviation among its ma-
jor goals, although its Articles of Agreement do not contemplate this objective.
Carrasco, supra note 98, at 39–41; Rajagopal, From Resistance to Renewal, supra
note 87, at 569–74. The IMF created the Poverty Reduction and Growth Facility
(PRGF) in 1999. As described by the IMF, this new endeavor “aims at making
poverty reduction efforts among low-income members a key and more explicit
element of a renewed growth-oriented strategy.” Creation of the PRGF was sig-
nificant because it was the first time the IMF had officially declared that “growth-
policies should be implemented in a framework in which the pressing need to
reduce poverty is also a central objective.” International Monetary Fund, Policy
Development and Review Department, The Poverty Reduction and Growth Facil-
ity (PRGF) – Operational Issues (Dec. 13, 1999), at http://www.imf.org/external/
np/pdr/prsp/poverty2.htm (last visited June 7, 2002) [hereinafter PRGF]. Instead
of pursuing strictly macroeconomic objectives, “high quality” economic develop-
ment has become the IMF’s new emphasis, and “high quality” development in-
cludes considering the social and political consequences of IMF lending.
Carrasco, supra note 98, at 569–74. “Good governance” in borrowing countries is
also currently a stated goal of the IMF, and thus the IMF’s stated objectives are
now more similar to those of the World Bank. Id.; PRGF, supra note 227. Un-
like the World Bank the IMF has not formalized relations with NGOs. Bradlow,
supra note 98, at 77. The IMF continues to utilize adjustment lending. PGRF,
supra note 227. Yet even the IMF and World Bank acknowledge it is problem-
atic. See generally International Monetary Fund, Annual Report of the Executive
Board for the Financial Year Ended April 30, 1997, available at http://www.imf.
org/external/pubs/ft/ar/97/97imf.htm (last visited Feb. 22, 2004); WORLD BANK,
GLOBAL DEVELOPMENT FINANCE (1998).
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 49 1-SEP-04 12:22
228
See Anghie, Time Present and Time Past, supra note 84, at 252–53 (noting that IFI
loans are part of an adjustment lending process and are supposed to ameliorate
some of the consequences of the fundamental changes the Bank requires coun-
tries to undertake); Chua, supra note 80.
229
The emergence of a “Third World,” that stood separate and apart from the first
and second world also emerged during this era, as did the nationalizations of oil
companies, events that empowered and emboldened nations in the Middle East.
Given the raging Cold War, the time may also have been ripe to make demands
for social justice. The 1960s was also a time of political protest in the United
States and across Europe, and thus “demands” for justice were part of a larger
trend, so to speak.
230
At this point, the demand for reparations has only been articulated in limited
forums and within few documents. See infra notes 299-310 and accompanying
text for a discussion of reparations. It cannot be equated with the sustained
movements for Permanent Sovereignty over Natural Resources, the New Inter-
national Economic Order, or the Right to Development.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 50 1-SEP-04 12:22
231
Development law or the “law of development” was recognized as branch of inter-
national law in the 1960s. Héctor Gros Espiell, The Right of Development as a
Human Right, 16 TEX. INT’L. L.J. 189, 190 (1981). After 1960 the United Nations
began to give attention to the concept of development, and gradually shaped a
new juridical discipline, “the international law of development,” which attempted
to characterize, and make enforceable a system of rights and obligations. Id.
Not to be confused with the “law and development” discussed, see supra Part I.D,
the international law of development comprises principles promoting the eco-
nomic and social development of the Third World, while seeking to strengthen
and assert their position in international relations. Nina M. Eejima, Sustainable
Development and the Search for a Better Environment, a Better World: A Work in
Progress, 18 UCLA J. ENVT’L. L & POL’Y 99, 109 (1999/2000). Indeed, the law of
development rejects a key premise of law and development, holding instead that
“[t]he problem was not simply that economic and social institutions in the periph-
eral countries were not modern. . .but rather that these societies were character-
ized by. . . structures where the economic and social institutions were geared to
meet the demands of developed societies rather than the needs of the developing
societies.” Chibundu, supra note 74, at 191.
232
Although it gained widespread attention in the 1960s and 1970s, the roots of the
law of development go considerably deeper. Early antecedents include the
Drago Doctrne, by which Latin American states sought to prohibit armed foreign
(i.e., U.S.) intervention predicated on civil disputes. See Convention on Rights
and Duties of States, Dec. 26, 1933, art. 9, 49 Stat. 3097, 165 L.N.T.S. 19 (entered
into force Dec. 26, 1934). In 1902, Argentina’s Minister of Foreign Affairs in-
formed the United States that forcible U.S. intervention in Argentina to secure
payment of debts allegedly owed to private U.S. citizens and companies was un-
justified and dangerous. Argentine Republic: “Monroe Doctrine” and Diplomatic
Claims of European Powers, in UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF STATE, PAPERS
RELATING TO THE FOREIGN RELATIONS OF THE UNITED STATES, ISSUE 1903,
Argentine Republic: “Monroe Doctrine” and Diplomatic Claims of European
Powers 1–5 (1903) (note from Luis M. Drago to the U.S. Department of State).
Professor Richard Falk has observed that the concept of a state protecting its
nationals abroad has also been used “as a means to impose the external will of
richer and more powerful nations [on others].” Richard Falk, Historical Tenden-
cies, Modernizing and Revolutionary Nations, and the International Legal Order. 8
HOW. L. J. 128, 133 (1962).
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 51 1-SEP-04 12:22
233
The European origin of an international law that purports to be “universal” was
and remains a persistent underlying theme. See, e.g., T.O. Elias, Modern Sources
of International Law, in TRANSNATIONAL LAW IN A CHANGING SOCIETY: ESSAYS
IN HONOR OF PHILIP C. JESSUP 49 (Wolfgang Friedmann et al. eds., 1972); R.P.
Anand, Attitude of the Asian-African States Toward Certain Problems of Interna-
tional Law, 15 INT’L & COMP. L.Q. 55, 56 (1966); Jorge Castaneda, The Underde-
veloped Nations and the Development of International Law, 15 INT’L ORG. 38, 39
(1961); B. ROLING, INTERNATIONAL LAW IN AN EXPANDED WORLD 10 (1960);
JAMES L. BRIERLY, THE LAW OF NATIONS 44 (Oxford University Press 1997).
But the problem was not merely with the origin of the law; the problem was with
the law’s application. Judge Philip C. Jessup, in describing the need for revising
traditional international law, acknowledged the Third World view that “the rules
of law were developed by the exploiting imperialistic powers to promote their
interests at the expense of the countries which in earlier centuries were either
colonies or politically and militarily weak and provided important sources of raw
materials and perhaps labor to the exploiting powers.” Philip C. Jessup, Non-
Universal International Law, 12 COLUM. J. TRANSNAT’L L. 415, 419 (1973).
234
See Snyder, supra note 76, at 737 (quoting COLIN LEYS, UNDERDEVELOPMENT IN
KENYA: THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF NEO-COLONIALISM, 1964-1971 (1975))
(stating that underdevelopment theory is . . . partly a correction and partly an
expansion of Marx’s interpretation of history, an expansion of his method and
central ideas to a problem which, on a world scale, was still in embryo at his
death: the failure of the countries of Asia, Africa, and Latin America to follow a
path of autonomous, capitalist development, leading to their “regeneration” after
they had been brought within the world capitalist economy). Dependency the-
ory has been criticized as accepting the fundamental premises of the development
paradigm. Id.
235
See Chibundu, supra note 74, at 189.
236
Akinsanya & Davies, supra note 61, at 209–11 (noting that since it was estab-
lished in 1964 UNCTAD has been “one of the forums used by the developing
countries to press home their demand for a New International Economic Order”
and that it has become an “important intervener on behalf of less developed
countries in their relations with advanced industrial States” (quoting Robert S.
Walters, UNCTAD: Intervener Between Poor and Rich States, 7 J.W.T. L. 528
(1973))). UNCTAD’s recommendations are not legally binding, however. See
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 52 1-SEP-04 12:22
declared that “more than foreign aid, what was needed for the
Third World to break out of the vicious circle of poverty was a
change in the terms governing its relationship with the industrial
world”.237 Although largely rejected in the West,238 the interna-
tional law of development has been championed in the Third
World since the 1960s.239 It has been an avowedly activist move-
ment from its inception,240 and in due course, advocated a broad
also VARGES, supra note 61, at 3 (discussing how unification enabled developing
countries to be a force that could not be ignored).
237
See VARGES, supra note 61, at 3. Dependency theorists acknowledged that devel-
oped countries may at some time have been “undeveloped,” but argued that they
never played the role of the “underdeveloped” country within the world capitalist
system. See Snyder, supra note 76, at 748. The original centers of capitalism
established their wealth and their power through incorporating and exploiting
other parts of the world. The primary accumulation of capital in the metropoles
or center was fed through a drain of wealth from the satellite or peripheral coun-
tries, typically involving their colonization, a “surplus drain” which continues to
the present day even if its forms may have changed, and direct colonial rule is no
longer a necessary condition of this process.
Id. at 726 (quoting Harry Bernstein, Sociology of Underdevelopment vs. Sociol-
ogy of Development?, in DAVID LEHNMAN ED., DEVELOPMENT THEORY: FOUR
CRITICAL STUDIES (David Lehmann ed., 1979)); see also Makau Mutua, Critical
Race Theory and International Law: Convergence and Divergence, 45 VILL. L.
REV. 841, 850 (2000). Using critical race theory to evaluate international law,
Mutua states, “What the world has witnessed in the last five centuries is the
universalization of an international law that is particular to Europe and seeks not
universal justice, but an international legal order that erects, preserves and em-
braces European and American domination of the globe.” Id.
238
Third World leaders warned that the unequal distribution of power threatens
peace, and that permitting the existence of such a system could potentially give
rise to a “major worldwide revolution.” See VARGES, supra note 61, at 6. Given
the wholesale rejection of all aspects of the law of development, however, the
West apparently did not take this threat seriously, or perhaps believed it had
other mechanisms at its disposal to deal with outbreaks of violence.
239
See generally Schachter, supra note 109. Through the international law of devel-
opment, dependency theorists and their allies attempted to establish an enforcea-
ble system of rights and obligations based on international law.
240
According to Professor Espiell,
245
Perrez, supra note 242, at 1190.
246
G.A. Res. 1803, U.N. GAOR, 17th Sess., 1194th plen. mtg., U.N. Doc. A/5217
(1962), reprinted in 2 I.L.M. 223 (1963). Resolution 1803 was adopted by a vote
of eighty-seven to two, with twelve states abstaining. See KAMAL HOSSAIN, SUB-
RATA ROY CHOWDHURY EDS., PERMANENT SOVEREIGNTY OVER NATURAL RE-
SOURCES IN INTERNATIONAL LAW: PRINCIPLE AND PRACTICE 91 (1984); Perrez,
supra note 242, at 1191–92.
247
In 1952, Chile asserted the concept of permanent sovereignty over natural re-
sources at the U.N. Commission on Human Rights. U.N. Doc. E/CN.4/L.24
(1952). Also in 1952, The General Assembly passed Resolutions 523 (VI) and
626 (VII), the latter entitled: “Right to Exploit Freely Natural Wealth and Re-
sources.” G.A. Res. 523, U.N. GAOR, 6th Sess., 360th plen. mtg., Supp. No. 20,
U.N. Doc. A/2119 (1952); G.A. Res. 626, U.N. GAOR, 7th Sess., 411th plen.
mtg., U.N. Doc. A/PV.411 (1952). See HOSSAIN, supra note 246, at 2.
248
See JERZY MAKARCZYK, PRINCIPLES OF A NEW INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC OR-
DER: A STUDY OF INTERNATIONAL LAW IN THE MAKING 184, 198, 199 (1988).
249
See HOSSAIN, supra note 246.
250
See MAKARCZYK, supra note 248.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 55 1-SEP-04 12:22
251
See, e.g., Saudi Arabia v. Arabian American Oil Co., 27 I.L.R. 117 (Arb. Trib.
1958); Sapphire Int’l Petroleums Ltd. v. Nat’l Iranian Oil Co., 35 I.L.R. 136 (Cavin
Arb. 1963); Petroleum Dev. Ltd. v. Sheikh of the Abu Dhabi, 18 I.L.R. 144 (Arb.
Trib. 1951) – all enforcing the validity of long-term pro-Western concessions over
the objections of Third World hosts. Consequently, nationalizing these conces-
sions bound host states to pay prompt, adequate and effective compensation to
the alien owners.
252
See Perrez, supra note 242, at 1191–92.
253
See Patrick Norton, A Law for the Future or a Law for the Past? Modern Tribu-
nals and the Law of International Expropriation, 85 AM. J. INT’L. L. 474, 475–76
(1991); Stephen M. Schwebel, The Story of the U.N.’s Declaration on Permanent
Sovereignty over Natural Resources, 49 A.B.A. J. 463, 465 (1963) [hereinafter
Schwebel, Permanent Sovereignty]. The “Hull formula” refers to a pronounce-
ment by U.S. Secretary of State Cordell Hull in connection with a 1938 dispute
over Mexico’s nationalization of foreign-owned oil fields. See G. HACKWORTH, 3
DIGEST OF INTERNATIONAL LAW 655–65 (1942).
254
See G. Roy, Is the Law of the Responsibility of States for Injuries to Aliens a Part
of Universal International Law?, 55 AM. J. INT’L L. 863 (1961); M. BEDJAOUI,
TOWARD A NEW INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC ORDER (1979); F.V. GARCIA-
AMADOR, THE CHANGING LAW OF INTERNATIONAL CLAIMS 895–932 (1984).
255
G.A. Res. 1803, supra note 246, at 15. At the time of its adoption, the United
States delegation argued that the phrase “appropriate compensation” made “in
accordance with international law” meant “prompt, adequate and effective” com-
pensation as required under international law. Andrew T. Guzman, Why LDC’S
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 56 1-SEP-04 12:22
Sign Treaties That Hurt Them: Explaining the Popularity of Bilateral Investment
Treaties, 38 VA. J. INT’L L. 639, 649 (1998) (citing Schwebel, Permanent Sover-
eignty, supra note 253).
256
Subsequent state practice of paying what amounts to prompt, adequate and effec-
tive compensation, albeit often under pain of international economic ostracism or
worse military intervention, has reinforced the Hull formula. Industrialized
states can now point to extensive state practice to support their position, as well
as a series of bilateral investment treaties that require payment of prompt, ade-
quate and effective compensation. Guzman, supra note 255, at 648. That Third
World nations have taken these actions under pain of economic banishment ap-
pears to be besides the point.
257
Nicolass Jan Schriver, Sovereignty over Natural Resources: Balancing Rights and
Duties in an Interdependent World 3, 4 (2002).
258
G.A. Res. 3201, U.N. GAOR, 6th Special Sess., at 3, U.N. Doc. A/RES/
3201(s_VI) (1974).
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 57 1-SEP-04 12:22
259
G.A. Res. 3202, U.N. GAOR, 6th Special Sess., at 5, U.N. Doc. A/9559 (1974).
260
Report of the Second Committee, U.N. Doc. A/9946, 28 (Dec. 9, 1974) and U.N.
Doc. A/RES/3281 (XXIX) (Jan 15, 1975); G.A. Res. 3281, U.N. GAOR, 29th
Sess., 2315th plen. mtg., at 50, U.N. Doc. A/RES/3281 (1974).
261
VARGES, supra note 61, at 5, 37.
262
Id.
263
CERDS was adopted by a General Assembly vote of 120 to six, with 10 absten-
tions. Belgium, Denmark, the Federal Republic of Germany, Luxembourg, the
United Kingdom and the United States voted against the Charter. Austria, Ca-
nada, France, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Japan, the Netherlands, Norway and Spain
abstained. See RALPH STUART SMITH, THE UNITED STATES AND THE THIRD
WORLD: A DISCUSSION PAPER (1976).
264
In April 1972 President Echeverria of Mexico proposed that the United Nations
Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) draft a charter delineating
the economic rights of nations. In May 1972 UNCTAD voted to establish a
working group to draft such a charter; UNCTAD Res. 45 (III), U.N. Doc. TD/
180. The United States abstained from the vote, but agreed to participate in the
Working Group. See JOHN H. JACKSON ET AL., LEGAL PROBLEMS OF INTERNA-
TIONAL ECONOMIC RELATIONS: CASES, MATERIALS AND TEXT ON NATIONAL
AND INTERNATIONAL REGULATION OF TRANSNATIONAL ECONOMIC RELATIONS
§ 26.2, at 1166 (3d ed. 1995). The need for such a charter was explained by Mex-
ico’s Secretary of Foreign Relations:
Emilio O. Rabasa, Address Before the 68th Annual Meeting of the American
Society of International Law, in 68 AM. SOC’Y INT’L PROC. 302, 303–05 (1974).
265
See JACKSON, supra note 264, at 1166–67.
266
Marjorie Cohn, The World Trade Organization: Elevating Property Interests
Above Human Rights, 29 GA. J. INT’L & COMP. L 427, 438 (2001). Capital ex-
porting states voted against this provision and have never accepted it. Article
2(2)(c) of the Charter provides that each state has the right to:
269
See Akinsanya & Davies, supra note 61, at 211.
270
See supra note 233 and accompanying text for discussion in European origins of
international law. See also, e.g., Elias, supra note 233; Anand, supra note 233;
Castaneda, supra note 233, at 39; ROLING, supra note 233, at 5; BRIERLY, supra
note 233, at 44.
271
Makua wa Mutua, Why Redraw the Map of Africa: A Moral and Legal Inquiry, 16
MICH. J. INT’L L. 1113, 1140 (1995); see also Antony Anghie, Finding the Periph-
eries: Sovereignty and Colonialism in Nineteenth Century International Law, 40
HARV. INT’L L.J. 1 (1999).
272
Mexico’s Secretary of Foreign Relations appealed for support for the NIEO this
way:
Let us subject the fundamental economic elements for the future of world
development to the rule of law. . .. Let us codify norms and create an au-
thentic body of rules that will allow the international community to settle
disputes and control abuses. Law represents a force in itself that can be-
come a basic source of innovation for society.
Emilio O. Rabasa, The Charter of Economic Rights and Duties of States, 68 AM.
SOC’Y INT’L PROC. 302, 303–05 (1974) (address at joint luncheon with the Section
on International Law of the American Bar Association). Secretary Rabasa also
analogized specifically to various U.S. legislative measures such as the Social Se-
curity Act of 1935, the National Labor Relations Act of 1935, the Fair Labor
Standards Act of 1938, the Employment Act of 1946, and the Economic Opportu-
nity act of 1964 as establishing a principle of redistributing wealth for the protec-
tion and betterment of the disadvantaged within U.S. society. “Why not then
transfer the philosophy that has been the basis for this new process to the interna-
tional field?” he asked. Id.
273
See Charles N. Brower & John B. Tepe, Jr., The Charter of Economic Rights and
Duties of States: A Reflection or Rejection of International Law?, 9 INT’L LAW 295,
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 60 1-SEP-04 12:22
If the Charter turns out to be simply a statement of the alleged rights of the
developing countries and the alleged duties of the developed, it will be a
kind of bill of particulars, if not an indictment, which will have no more
impact on international economic affairs, not to speak of international law,
than a number of self-serving calls which developing countries have issued
in the past in UNCTAD and elsewhere.
278
G.A. Res. 128, U.N. GAOR, 41st Sess., Annex at 186, U.N. Doc. A/RES/41/128
(1983).
279
The right to development purports to operate both collectively at the interna-
tional level, and individually at the domestic level. This evolution – from collec-
tive to both collective and individual, and from international to both international
and domestic – was key to the transition from the law of development to the right
to development. Espiell, supra note 231, at 192. “After initiation of the process
designed to establish a law of development and the right to develop, conceived of
as a collective right, the idea of the right to development as a human right that is
a right belonging to individuals began to take shape.” Id. The results of this
transition can be seen in the International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights
(“ICCPR”) and the International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural
Rights (“ICESR”), G.A. Res. 2200A, U.N. GAOR, 21st Sess., Supp. No. 16, at
99, U.N. Doc. A/6316 (1966), both of which incorporate many of the principles of
the human right to development.
280
It also sought to empower individuals and sub-national groups within individual
countries. See G.A. Res. 128, supra note 278, at arts. 1.1, 2.1, 2.3 (stating that
individuals are the primary beneficiaries of the right, and that both individuals
and the state must work for “the constant improvement of the well-being of the
entire population and of all individuals, on the basis of their active, free and
meaningful participation in development and in the fair distribution of the bene-
fits resulting there from”).
281
See Mickelson, supra note 3, at 12 (quoting Keba M’Baye, First President of the
Supreme Court of Senegal, who emphasized this point in his 1972 speech intro-
ducing the right to development: “Economic growth must be accompanied by
socio-cultural progress; that means, in the simplest possible terms, that we must
give it a human dimension . . . growth is a necessary but not a sufficient condition
for the achievement of development”); Barsh, supra note 152, at 328 (stating that
participants of the Global Consultations concerned with the implementation of
the right to development were “especially critical of international development
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 62 1-SEP-04 12:22
strategies which have been ‘oriented merely towards economic growth and finan-
cial considerations’”); Forysthe, supra note 154, at 334.
282
The law of development asserted the need for a right of development similar to a
human right, but this right was thought to be a collective one – whereas human
rights are typically thought of as individual. Espiell, supra note 231, at 190.
283
See Bunn, supra note 277, at 1433; Mickelson, supra note 3, at 10; Espiell, supra
note 231, at 192 (all identifying Justice Keba M’Baye as author of the Right to
Development). This pronouncement was made in his inaugural lecture at the
Third Session of Instruction of the International Institute for Human Rights. Id.
284
Espiell, supra note 231, at 192 (quoting Keba M’Baye, Le Droit au développement
comme un droit de l’Homme, in 5 REVUE DES DROITS DE L’HOMME 503, 505
(1972)). Following M’Baye’s lead, Professor Juan Antonio Carrillo Salcedo of
Spain also identified the Right to Development as a human right. Carrillo
Salcedo, El Derecho al desarollo como un derecho humamo, in 25 REVISTA ESPA-
ÑOLA DE DERECHO INTERNACIONAL 119–25 (1972) (“The right of development
as a right of states and peoples must unavoidably be founded on the recognition
of the right of every man to a free and worthy life in his community. Every
human being has the right to live, which implies the right to aspire to an increas-
ingly better existence.”)).
285
Even the “development assistance” contributed by the North, he observed,
served principally to enable underdeveloped countries to become markets for
Northern goods and services. See M’Baye, supra note 284, at 15 (noting that
development assistance is “in many cases little more than a disguised export sub-
sidy,” designed to improve the underdeveloped countries’ ability to act as a mar-
ket for the finished or semi-finished products of the developed world);
Mickelson, supra note 3, at 381–83 (Addressing M’Baye’s observation that, “the
deep division between the South and North posed an increasing threat to interna-
tional stability, and hence raising the standard of living in poor countries could be
“a form of life insurance” for rich countries. M’Baye also stated that since indus-
trialized countries designed and benefited from the current international eco-
nomic system, they were responsible for its injurious consequences.) “Given
their power in the system and their utilization of that power to their own advan-
tage, the rich countries of the North should assume responsibilities for their ac-
tions.” Id. at 13 (quoting M’Baye, supra note 284, at 505, 521–22).
286
Mickelson, supra note 3, at 13 (quoting M’Baye, supra note 284, at 524).
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 63 1-SEP-04 12:22
287
Id. at 14 (quoting M’Baye, supra note 284, at 529). See also Espiell, supra note
231, at 192 (quoting M’Baye, supra note 284, at 515) (acknowledging M’Baye’s
belief that “[e]ach man has the right to live and the right to live better”).
288
It should be noted that in his 1972 speech, M’Baye expressed reservations con-
cerning efforts to legalize a human right to development. He maintained that
these efforts were unnecessary because the human right to development already
existed. He also feared proponents of the right might lose sight of the desired
end and find “victory” in a mere legal declaration. See Mickelson, supra note 3,
at 14. Accordingly, M’Baye opposed those who called for completing the Univer-
sal Declaration of Human Rights by proclaiming a Right to Development, be-
cause he regarded this as unnecessary, and perhaps even counterproductive: “[I]t
is hardly useful to encumber ourselves with a new proclamation, as if it were a
matter of creating a new right. The right to development is already inscribed in
international law.” Id. (quoting M’Baye, supra note 284, at 526).
289
Bunn, supra note 277, at 1436.
[I]n terms of international human rights law, the existence of the right to
development is a fait accompli. Whatever reservations different groups
may have as to its legitimacy, viability or usefulness, such doubts are now
better left behind and replaced by efforts to ensure that the formal process
of elaborating the content of the right is a productive and constructive
exercise.
Id. (quoting Philip Alston, Development and the Rule of Law: Prevention Versus
Cure as a Human Rights Strategy, in DEVELOPMENT, HUMAN RIGHTS AND THE
RULE OF LAW 31, 106 (International Commission of Jurists eds. 1981)). Propo-
nents of the right to development maintain that it has a rich legal foundation that
includes the Charter of the United Nations, the Universal Declaration of Human
Rights, the International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights, the
UNESCO Declaration on Race and Racial Prejudice and other international con-
ventions. Id.
290
See, e.g., Jack Donnelly, In Search of the Unicorn: The Jurisprudence and Politics
of the Right to Development, 15 CAL. W. INT’L L.J. 473, 478 (1985). Scholars
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 64 1-SEP-04 12:22
D. REPARATIONS
If one accepts the proposition that the Third World has been
severely and systematically exploited through arrangements that
include slavery and colonialism,294 then the idea of compensation
contesting its existence assert that these conventions merely make explicit refer-
ences to “development” which does not mean they support a right to
development.
291
Advocates reason that the lack of universal recognition or sanctions for non-ad-
herence does not render the UNDRD meaningless, given the initial rejection of
many new international human rights. Espiell, supra note 231, at 198 (“Conse-
quently it is evident that the inadequacies that still plague the juridical character-
istics of the right of development in general, and particularly as an individual
right, do not allow the possibility of denying its legal existence, though it is still
embryonic and imperfect.”)
292
One of the provisions of the Charter of Economic Rights and Duties of States
foreshadowed contemporary demands for reparations. Article 16 calls for resti-
tution based on the injuries caused by “colonialism, apartheid, racial discrimina-
tion, neocolonialism and all forms of foreign aggression, occupation and
domination.” G.A. Res. 3281, supra note 260.
293
M’Baye observed that since industrialized countries designed and benefited from
the current international economic system, they were responsible for its injurious
consequences See Mickelson, supra note 3, at 383 (“Given their power in the
system and their utilization of that power to their own advantage, the rich coun-
tries of the North should assume responsibilities of their actions.” (quoting
M’Baye, supra note 284)).
294
See, e.g., RODNEY, supra note 243.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 65 1-SEP-04 12:22
for that harm should hardly be remarkable.295 But calls for repa-
rations to the victims of slavery and colonialism have been ex-
tremely controversial.296 Drawing on the vigorously debated
movement in the U.S. for reparations to the descendants of Afri-
can slaves,297 the international struggle for reparations has been
295
Conceptually, reparations may be the simplest approach to international eco-
nomic justice. Black’s Law Dictionary defines reparation as both “[t]he act of
making amends for a wrong” and “[c]ompensation for an injury or wrong, esp.
for wartime damages or breach of an international obligation.” BLACK’S LAW
DICTIONARY 1301 (7th ed. 1999). Perhaps it is the natural successor to the NIEO
and the right to development, insofar as the simplicity of the demand for repara-
tions represents an evolutionary focusing and sharpening of the Third World
position.
296
This may be because the simplicity and directness of the idea leaves virtually no
room for obfuscation or for “spinning” compensation as charitable assistance.
Although reparations focus on repairing the injury suffered by victims, assigning
responsibility for payment seems to require the assignment of blame, and this
inevitably triggers belligerent resistance to reparations proposals. It explains, for
example, the European Union’s refusal, as recently as 2001, to apologize for
Western Europe’s substantial role in the Atlantic slave trade. At the 2001 World
Conference Against Racism, the lead E.U. negotiator, Belgian Foreign Minister
Louis Michel, equivocated thusly, “[s]lavery today is, of course, a crime against
humanity, slavery yesterday, in the past was of course. . . a very grave thing, a
very horrible thing. . .It is very difficult to consider that you can compare slavery
today to slavery in the past.” Europeans at U.N. Meeting Agree to Apology for
Slavery – But Not to Reparations, ST. LOUIS POST-DISPATCH (MISSOURI), Sept. 8,
2001, at 20.
297
The movement for reparations is really a collection of movements. See, e.g.,
RANDAL ROBINSON, THE DEBT: WHAT AMERICA OWES TO BLACKS (2000);
RICHARD F. AMERICA, PAYING THE SOCIAL DEBT: WHAT WHITE AMERICA
OWES BLACK AMERICA (1993) (in support of reparations); DAVID HOROWITZ,
UNCIVIL WARS: THE CONTROVERSY OVER REPARATIONS FOR SLAVERY (2003);
David Horowitz, Ten Reasons Why Reparations for Blacks is a Bad Idea for
Blacks – and Racist Too, 31 BLACK SCHOLAR 48 (2002) (opposing reparations).
The reparations movement within the United States has had the benefit of sub-
stantial scholarly analysis. For an excellent summary of legal issues and citations
to a wealth of writings on the topic, see Alfred L. Brophy, Some Conceptual and
Legal Problems in Reparations for Slavery, 58 N.Y.U. ANN. SURV. AM. L. 497
(2003). Much of the analysis focuses on substantive and procedural legal issues
that are specific to the U.S. legal system and on the anticipated legal battles over
reparations within the domestic U.S. context. See, e.g., Rhonda V. Magee, The
Master’s Tools, from the Bottom Up: Responses to African-American Reparations
Theory in Mainstream and Outsider Remedies Discourse, 79 VA. L. REV. 863
(1993); Adrienne D. Davis, The Case for United States Reparations to African-
Americans, 7 HUM. RTS. BR. 3 (2000); BORIS I. BITTKER, THE CASE FOR BLACK
REPARATIONS (2d ed. 2003); Graham Hughes, Reparations for Blacks?, 43
N.Y.U. L. REV. 1063 (1968). However, scholars in the U.S. – particularly within
the legal academy – have also done a great deal of theoretical work that is likely
to be useful in support of Third World demands for international reparations.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 66 1-SEP-04 12:22
Some of this work is litigation oriented, but based on principles that might also
conceivably resonate with the general public. Unjust enrichment is one such legal
principle – and a politically interesting option because it does not require blame
or fault; only (basically) that a benefit has been received and retained, and that
injustice will result if the benefit is not disgorged. See generally E. ALLAN FARNS-
WORTH, CONTRACTS (3d ed. 1999); DOUG RENDLEMAN, REMEDIES CASES AND
MATERIALS (6th ed. 1999). Difficulties with the technical application of the doc-
trine of unjust enrichment include calculating the benefit conferred and offsetting
any gain received by the plaintiffs, and tracing the benefit to its present holders.
Brophy, supra note 297, at 522. In light of the anticipated difficulty of achieving
reparations through litigation, some supporters of reparations for African Ameri-
cans are advocating a more overtly political approach that relies on the legislative
process. Id. at 523.
298
Held in September in Durban, South Africa, the 2001 WCAR was actually the
third in a series (and is thus sometimes referred to as the “Third World Confer-
ence Against Racism”). The first World Conference Against Racism was con-
vened in Geneva, Switzerland in August 1978, and attended by representatives of
125 countries, as well as observers from U.N. agencies, intergovernmental organi-
zations, and non-governmental organizations. REPORT OF THE WORLD CONFER-
ENCE TO COMBAT RACISM AND RACIAL DISCRIMINATION, U.N. Doc. A/CONF.
92/40, U.N. Sales No. E79.XIV.2 (1978) [hereinafter RACISM REPORT]. Because
of a 1975 General Assembly Resolution equating Zionism with racism and racial
discrimination, the United States and Israel boycotted the 1978 Conference.
G.A. Res. 3379, U.N. GAOR, 30th Sess., Supp. No. 34, at 83, U.N. Doc. A/10034
(1975); RACISM REPORT, supra note 298. See also U.S. Participation in the United
Nations, REPORT BY THE PRESIDENT TO CONGRESS FOR THE YEAR 1977, at 172
(1977). The first Conference focused mainly on South Africa, with a majority of
participating nations favoring strong international measures to oppose and dis-
mantle the apartheid regime. There was some disagreement regarding the nature
of the measures that should be taken against South Africa, and some (mainly
Western European) disagreement with the conference majority’s condemnation
of Israel’s treatment of the Palestinians. RACISM REPORT, supra note 298, at 15,
113, 129–30. A second World Conference to Combat Racism and Racial Dis-
crimination was held in August 1983. Geneva was again the venue, South Africa
and the Middle East were again the principal topics, and the United States again
chose not to attend because of the majority’s position on the latter. See id. As
with the first conference, Western commentators proclaimed the second confer-
ence a failure. See, e.g., Christopher N. Camponovo, Disaster in Durban: The
United Nations World Conference Against Racism, Racial Discrimination, Xeno-
phobia, and Related Intolerance, 34 GEO. WASH. INT’L L. REV. 659, 667 (2003)).
Despite majority agreement on its principal themes and conclusions, in 1997, the
General Assembly resolved to convene a third World Conference Against Ra-
cism, to be held in Durban, in the newly democratized South Africa. G.A. Res.
52/111, supra note 298.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 67 1-SEP-04 12:22
299
Regional conferences were held in Strasbourg, France; Santiago, Chile; Dakar,
Senegal; and Teheran, Iran. In addition, five regional expert seminars were held
in Geneva, Warsaw, Bangkok, Addis Ababa and Santiago during 1999 and 2000.
United Nations, World Conference Against Racism, Basic Information, The
World Conference Against Racism, Racial Discrimination, Xenophobia and Re-
lated Intolerance, at http://www.un.org/WCAR/e-kit/backgrounder1.htm (last vis-
ited May 22, 2002).
300
For example, the Asian Preparatory Conference in Teheran concluded that
“States which pursued policies or practices based on racial or national superior-
ity, such as colonialism or other forms of alien domination or foreign occupation,
slavery, the slave trade and ethnic cleansing, should assume responsibility . . . and
compensate the victims of such policies and practices.” Reports of Preparatory
Meetings and Activities at the International, Regional and National Levels, Report
of the Asian Preparatory Meeting (Tehran, Feb. 19-21, 2001), U.N. GAOR, Pre-
paratory Comm., 2d Sess., U.N. Doc. A/CONF.189/PC.2/9 (2001). At the Santi-
ago Regional Conference, representatives of countries in North, Central and
South America, and the Caribbean agreed to “take measures to alleviate inequi-
ties that still persist because of the shameful legacy of slavery.” The delegates
also condemned “the brutal crimes and injustices that were committed against
indigenous peoples and Africans and their descendants who were subjected to
slavery, the trans-Atlantic slave trade and other forms of servitude that today
could constitute crimes against humanity.” Reports of Preparatory Meetings and
Activities at the International, Regional and National Levels, Report of the Re-
gional Conference of the Americas (Santiago, Chile, Dec. 5-7, 2000), U.N. GAOR,
Preparatory Comm., 2d Sess., Annex IV-V, at 19, U.N. Doc. A/CONF. 189/PC.2/
7 (2001) [hereinafter Santiago Report].
301
These matters that were not addressed in the documents adopted by the Euro-
pean regional conference in Strasbourg. See Reports of Preparatory Meetings and
Activities at the International, Regional and National Levels, Final Documents of
the European Conference Against Racism (Strasbourg, France, Oct. 11-13, 2000),
U.N. GAOR, Preparatory Comm., 2d Sess., Annex IV-V, U.N. Doc. A/CONF.
189/PC.2/6 (2001). Only over the strenuous objections of the United States and
Canada, did the Santiago conference acknowledge that slavery was an interna-
tional crime, resulting in:
305
Report of the World Conference Against Racism, Racial Discrimination, Xenopho-
bia and Related Intolerance (Durban, Aug. 31-Sept. 8, 2001), U.N. ESCOR, at
5–27, U.N. Doc. A/CONF.189/12 (2002) [hereinafter Durban Report]. See also
Celina Romany & Katherine Culliton, The UN World Conference Against Ra-
cism: A Race-Ethnic and Gender Perspective, 9 HUM. BRTB No.2, at 14, 15
(2002); Nicole Itano, Former Colonies Calling for Reparations, CHRISTIAN SCI.
MONITOR, Sept. 5, 2001, at A-1, available at http://www.csmonitor.com/2001/0905/
p1s4-wogi.html. Proponents of reparations – notably the African delegates who
had met at the Dakar regional conference – also sought apologies for slavery and
colonialism, noting “other groups that were subjected to other scourges and injus-
tices have received repeated apologies from different countries, as well as ample
reparations, on a bilateral basis, from both public and private sources and lately
through certain international organizations.” Dakar Report, supra note 302, at ¶
29. Certain Native Americans, Holocaust victims, Japanese Americans interned
during World War II, and South Africans have obtained some form of reparations
in recent years. Brophy, supra note 297, at 499. Australia, Austria, France, Ger-
many, New Zealand, South Africa, and the United Kingdom – as well as religious
denominations and multinational corporations – have in recent years offered
apologies for past wrongs. William Bradford, With a Very Great Blame on Our
Hearts: Reparations, Reconciliation, and an American Indian Plea for Peace with
Justice, 27 AM. INDIAN L. REV. 1, 5–6 (2002/2003). Professor Brophy adds that
U.S. President Clinton “apologized for, was part of apologies for, or discussed
apologizing for slavery, the genocide in Rwanda, executions of civilians during
the Korean war, the United States’ support of Guatemala’s military while it com-
mitted genocide, medical experiments on African Americans at Tuskegee, radia-
tion experiments, and the deprivation of native Hawaiians’ land.” Brophy, supra
note 297, at 501. Professor Bradford has termed this an age of apology. Brad-
ford, supra note 305, at 5–6; Brophy, supra note 297, at 501. Apologies would not
be extended at this Conference, however. The U.S. delegation withdrew from the
Conference and did not endorse the final Declaration. Tom Lantos, The Durban
Debacle: An Insider’s View of the UN World Conference Against Racism, 26
FLETCHER F. WORLD AFF. 31, 48 (2002). European Union delegates avoided
apologizing, declined to offer reparations, and refused to acknowledge that the
trans-Atlantic slave trade was a crime against humanity at the time it occurred.
Michael Slackman, Divisive U.N. Race Talks End in Accord, L.A. TIMES, Sept. 9,
2001, at A1.
306
Durban Report, supra note 305, at 14. The Declaration also proclaimed that
“slavery and the slave trade are a crime against humanity.” Id.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 70 1-SEP-04 12:22
307
Id. at 158.
308
For example, Fode Dabor, an ambassador from Sierra Leone and a member of
the African negotiating committee at the Durban Conference, said, “[t]his is very
bad, very disappointing, but we all had to go along because no one wanted to
take the blame for the conference collapsing. We lost on everything, the question
of the apology, the question of the slave trade and the question of reparations.”
Slackman, supra note 305. Moreover, Western press accounts of the conference
were overwhelmingly negative – many amounting, in fact, to ridicule of the Con-
ference and the positions asserted by its majority. See, e.g., Lantos, supra note
305, at 48; Anne Bayesfsky, The U.N. World Conference Against Racism: A racist
anti-racism conference, American Society of International Law, PROCEEDINGS OF
THE ANNUAL MEETING 65–74 (2002); Camponovo, supra note 298, at 667.
309
Given the role of the U.S. and other European powers in the slave trade and the
lack of any real regret for their activities, perhaps this lack of support is not
surprising.
310
The Durban conference contributes importantly to strengthening the case that is
already supported by the great majority of the membership of the United Na-
tions. Samir Amin, World Conference Against Racism: A People’s Victory, 53
MONTHLY REV. 7, 20 (2001).
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 71 1-SEP-04 12:22
311
See, e.g., LOUIS HENKIN, HOW NATIONS BEHAVE, LAW AND FOREIGN POLICY (2d
ed. 1979).
312
Tucker, supra note 64, at 1.
313
As Professors Kothari and Minogue note, when development is explored as an
idea, one is in the realm of theory. When objectives are established, one is de-
lineating the process by which ideas are turned into practice. Examining actual
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 72 1-SEP-04 12:22
practice entails analysis of these activities. Of course, even the idea of develop-
ment is contested territory. Kothari & Minogue, supra note 7, at 12. The mean-
ing of development in practice is also contested. See supra Part II B for
discussion of the cycles of conventional development policy wisdom.
314
This term is used is used in the broader Foucauldian sense of discourse:
The key feature is that the world is not simply “there” to be talked about,
rather it is through discourse itself that the world is brought into being. It
is also in such a discourse that speakers and hearers, writers and readers,
come to an understanding about themselves, their relationship to each
other and their place in the world (the construction of subjectivity). It is
the “complex of signs and practices which organizes social existence and
social reproduction”. . . There are certain unspoken rules controlling which
statements can be made and which cannot within the discourse, and these
rules determine the nature of the discourse. . .. These rules concern such
things as classification, the ordering and distribution of that knowledge of
the world that the discourse both enables and delimits.
Ideas, attitudes, and values that represent the interests of a group or class
of people. These ideas are expressed through the arts, and in all of the
ways in which a group within a society displays its perception of the
world. . .. Ideas do not express realities so much as the values of the people
who control society. They are false in that they claim truth and universality
even though they are rooted in historically based economic relationships.
Analyzing an ideology consists . . . of discovering how dominant systems of
ideas relate to the actual needs, demands, and self-descriptions of the rul-
ing class.
317
The entire idea of development epitomizes modernity, which has been described
as follows:
SARUP, supra note 316, at 94; Jane L. Parpart, Post-Modernism, Gender and De-
velopment, in POWER OF DEVELOPMENT 253 (Jonathan Crush, ed. 1995).
318
Tucker, supra note 64, at 2 (Postulating that it may be because the “myth of de-
velopment” is part of the social imaginary of Western societies, that despite the
transfer of goods, gadgets, capital, technology, hospitals and roads, the economic
and socioeconomic accomplishments of the West have not necessarily been repli-
cated in Third World countries. He also notes that the economic, social and polit-
ical transformations of the Third World are inseparable from the production and
reproduction of meanings, symbols and knowledge that is cultural reproduction.).
319
Id.
320
For critical analysis of these and other widely accepted development concepts,
see THE DEVELOPMENT DICTIONARY, supra note 1.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 74 1-SEP-04 12:22
321
See Sardar, supra note 55, at 44 (“Western civilization is not located in a geo-
graphical space, for in these days of globalization it envelopes the globe with its
desires, images, politics, and consumer and cultural products.”).
322
ASHCROFT ET AL., supra note 314, at 91. By the eighteenth century, the concept
of Europe was solidly constructed as a sign of superiority and as being in opposi-
tion to the rest of the world’s cultures. Eurocentrism is also present in the very
existence of such fields as anthropology, in the assumptions and practices of
Christianity through mission education and mission activity, and in the assumed
superiority of Western mathematics, cartography, art and numerous other cul-
tural and social practices which have been claimed, or assumed to be based on a
universal, objective set of values. Id. at 91–92.
323
For instance, the West defines “civilization” by reference to technology, thereby
measuring other civilizations by technological capabilities. The Eurocentric idea
of nation-state has been deemed to be the only desirable and legitimate form of
political organization, forcing non-Western societies to organize in this manner.
Groups without a state are viewed as people without a home, such as the Kurds,
gypsies and Jews before the state of Israel was established. Freedom is defined in
a way that does not incorporate basic needs such as hunger and housing or the
subordination of freedom for more eminent goals such as community and tradi-
tion. Instead the focus is the individual – which is the epitome of the Western
view of freedom. All of these Eurocentric categories play an intrinsic role in
development. Sardar, supra note 55, at 49.
324
ASHCROFT ET AL., supra note 314, at 91–92.
325
The non-West includes intellectuals, academics, writers, thinkers, novelists, politi-
cians and decision-makers in Asia, Africa and Latin America who use the West as
the yardstick for measuring the social and political progress within their own soci-
eties. Accordingly, the non-West promotes Eurocentrism, both wittingly and un-
wittingly, and colludes in its own victimization while simultaneously maintaining
the global system of inequality. Sardar, supra note 55, at 44.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 75 1-SEP-04 12:22
326
Whether employing such terms as First World and Third World, or describing
developed nations as post-industrial societies or as nations in the throes of ad-
vanced capitalism and the non-West as merely industrializing, Eurocentrism can-
not be expunged from the concept of development. “Development continues to
mean what it has always meant: a standard by which the West measures the non-
West.” Id. at 49.
327
Notwithstanding the at times dubious motivations of its proponents, moderniza-
tion or progress as defined by the West is not by definition objectionable – al-
though its desirability can certainly be debated. Indeed, it has been the subject of
much debate. For a variety of perspectives, see THE POST-DEVELOPMENT
READER, supra note 11. Rather, it is to suggest that although the dominant West-
ern view is only one perspective, it has been held to be the universal point of
reference and the only perspective deemed worthy of shaping countless lives for
the last fifty-five years; other views have been dismissed as invalid or irrelevant.
Esteva, supra note 1, at 6.
328
For a discussion of natural law in both its traditional and modern permutations,
see Brian Bix, Natural Law, in A COMPANION TO PHILOSOPHY OF LAW AND LE-
GAL THEORY 223 (Dennis Patterson ed., 1999).
329
For example, despite the challenges dependency theory presented to the prevail-
ing economic order, it shared many of the underlying premises of the moderniza-
tion discourse, never questioning the desirability of development and conceiving
of it in terms of economic growth, industrialization and liberal democracy.
Tucker, supra note 64, at 14. The postmodern critique itself can be criticized as
being part of the Western imagination and Western discourse and its demolition
of such grand narratives as religion, tradition and history may be inimical to the
interests of the non-West for it is these things that make the non-West, the non-
West. Sardar, supra note 55, at 45.
330
Professor Kiely warns that dismissing development as Eurocentrism is “too sim-
plistic, for it homogenizes both the West and the Third World and reduces the
latter to passive recipients of the ideas of the former. It then becomes difficult to
imagine how the people of the Third World could behave in any way other than
being simple puppets of the West.” He contends that a satisfactory analysis of
development would regard it not only as a European creation, but also as a re-
flection of the responses, reactions and resistance of the people who are its ob-
jects. He cautions that critics be careful to not reduce development to an idea
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 76 1-SEP-04 12:22
336
See, e.g., Teodor Shanin, The Idea of Progress, in THE POST-DEVELOPMENT
READER, supra note 11, at 65.
337
Tucker, supra note 64, at 7.
338
MITTELMAN & PASHA, supra note 59, at 38. See supra notes 55–69 and accompa-
nying text on Modernization theory.
339
Sardar, supra note 55, at 49.
340
Tucker, supra note 64, at 7. Under the rubric of modernization, Westernization
gained the status of a universal goal and destiny. Progress became not only inevi-
table, but also obligatory and orthodox development hinged on the absolute cer-
tainty of universal modernity. To the “West development” and “modernization”
characterized efforts by those in the Third World whom they implicitly assumed
to be destined to achieve their levels of consumption. Id. See also Jose Maria
Sbert, Progress, in THE DEVELOPMENT DICTIONARY, supra note 1, at 192.
341
Colonialism was legitimized and grounded in part on a racial discourse that de-
fined white Europeans as a superior race with a superior culture, and other races
as inferior and in need of being civilized by whites. See Gordon, Saving Failed
States, supra note 12, at 908–09; Gordon, Racing U.S. Foreign Policy, supra note
13, at 14–15. This raises questions regarding the role of race and culture in con-
structing development as discourse, as the largely colored colonized world be-
came the colonized and then the underdeveloped “Other.” While race is only
one of many factors, it is an additional means to separate developers from the
Other. It may make it is easier to view such peoples as incapable and, implicitly,
as inferior. See, e.g., Leonard Frank, The Development Game, in THE POST-DE-
VELOPMENT READER, supra note 11, at 262 (A Canadian described the make-up
of his development project assessment “team,” which included an American, a
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 78 1-SEP-04 12:22
Korean, a Japanese, a Dane, and a Bangladeshi, thrown in only for color. He also
admits his surprise and discomfort when the Other looked too white). Certainly
there are also issues of class, and Third World elites also generally promote the
development project. It has also been demonstrated that development theory
and practice is gendered. See, e.g., Kothari, supra note 22, at 39. Yet the Third
World is largely the colored world and thus it is at least worth questioning the
degree to which race figures into the international hierarchy that development
epitomizes. Power within development discourse resides in the West, and more
specifically in international institutions that are dominated by western, and pri-
marily white, nations. This is not to say that these Institutions do not employ
people from many nations, including people of color from all parts of the world.
Nonetheless, the policies that emanate from these institutions are formed in
Western capitals and institutions. Markets now dominate, because the U.S. has
decided that markets dominate. To work in these Institutions one must believe in
the models they propound. Alternative views are simply absorbed, watered-
down co-opted, or dismissed.
342
Gordon, Saving Failed States, supra note 12 (discussing trusteeship and colonial-
ism as part of the civilizing mission and the white man’s burden of uplifting the
natives); Parpart, supra note 317, at 261.
343
In its simplest formulation, “post-colonial” or “postcolonial” refers, chronologi-
cally, to the post independence period. However, since the late 1970s, the term
has had a more complex meaning and is utilized to discuss the various cultural
effects of colonization. See ASHCROFT ET AL., supra note 314, at 186.
Postcolonial theory has been described as an “umbrella term for diverse critical
approaches that deconstruct Western thought, and refers not to a simple periodis-
ation but rather to a methodological revisionism that enables a wholesale critique
of Western structures of knowledge and power.” Kothari, supra note 22, at 39.
For a discussion of the shifting and sometimes vague distinctions between
postcolonial and post-colonial, see ASHCROFT ET AL., supra note 314, at 186–92.
344
Kothari, supra note 22, at 36–37 (noting that there may not be a clear distinction
between the before of colonialism and the after of independence, that can be
viewed as two sharply contrasting periods separated by the moment of
decolonization).
345
Indeed, as early as 1937, one colonial governor said, “the exploitation theory. . . is
dead, and the development theory has taken its place.” Bernard Bordillon, The
African Producer in Nigeria, West Africa, Jan 30, 1937, at 75, cited in 1 DEVESH
KAPUR ET AL, supra note 30, at 96 n. 35. It took a while after the governor’s
insight for the rhetoric to change, but change it did. See Kothari, supra note 22, at
37 (discussing the extent to which the end of colonialism may or may not have
signaled an end to empire, although it did effectively suggest the end of a specific
form of imperialism even as imperial interest and global reach continued to be
present).
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 79 1-SEP-04 12:22
346
Parpart, supra note 317, at 261. This language then provides the rationale for the
neo-classic market-oriented reforms being forced on Third World governments
with the promise that they will reconstruct their economies. Id.
347
Escobar, Planning, supra note 157, at 135.
348
While colonial discourse constructed an obligation to undertake the white man’s
burden and civilize the natives, such considerations were clearly secondary to the
economic and political aspects of colonialism. With development, the West now
had an obligation, and indeed was morally obligated to intervene in the Third
World and modernize the underdeveloped.
349
Kothari, supra note 22, at 39. Professor Kathari continues that “the boundaries
and distinctions that formerly marked the power relations between colonizers
and the colonized continue to be played out, and are reinscribed on the relation-
ship between development and administrators and recipients of aid.” Id.
350
Sbert, supra note 340, at 192.
351
Tucker, supra note 64, at 13 (noting that the media is based in Western nations
and is accompanied by the overwhelming dominance of European and North
American Universities, foundations, institutes and research resources. Western
scholars can obtain grants to study in the Third World, while it is more difficult
for Third World scholars to study in the West, and when they do; they are social-
ized into the dominant paradigms of Western thinking. The unequal relationship
that persists between the West and the Third World is an integral part of this
process).
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 80 1-SEP-04 12:22
352
Id.
353
That the Other is lacking, deficient and inferior follows from a colonial discourse
that viewed certain races and peoples as inferior and in need the benefits of civili-
zation dispensed by their colonizer. See generally Gordon, Saving Failed States,
supra note 12; BASIL DAVILSON, THE BLACK MAN’S BURDEN AFRICA AND THE
CURSE OF THE NATION-STATE (1993).
354
On “helping,” see Marianne Gronemeyer, Helping, in THE DEVELOPMENT DIC-
TIONARY, supra note 1, at 53.
355
ESCOBAR, supra note 19, at 40–41.
356
Id. at 41 (noting that “abnormalities were identified, such as the illiterate, the
underdeveloped, the malnourished, small farmers, or landless peasants, which de-
velopment would later treat and reform”).
357
Additional subjects included cities, rural areas, housing, schools, factories, hospi-
tals, towns, regions and habitat. These ever-proliferating categories came from a
range of sources, including governments, universities, research centers and the
expanding international institutional edifice. Other categories and objects, such
as cultural attitudes and values and the existence of racial, religious, geographic,
or ethnic factors that were believed to be associated with backwardness, were
later introduced, but with more caution or surreptitiously. Id. at at 41–42. Pro-
fessor Escobar notes that the never-ending specification of problems required
detailed observation at all levels of a particular society, and accordingly complete
profiles of countries were developed and elaborated. Id. at 42. The techniques
for gathering this data have been refined and expanded. Indeed a cursory exami-
nation of the World Bank’s Website confirms this, for complete country profiles
of most countries can be found covering a wealth of information. See infra notes
378–79 and accompanying text for discussion in the reliability of this data and its
place in World Bank analysis.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 81 1-SEP-04 12:22
358
“Client categories” were created and proliferated as populations were consist-
ently and continually found to be lacking and in need of treatment and reform.
ESCOBAR, supra note 19, at at 41.
359
Tucker, supra note 64, at 7. Development planners and practitioners often dis-
miss as inconsequential the voices of the individuals whose impoverishment they
seek to address. Kothari, supra note 22, at 39.
360
There is a close connection between control over knowledge and assertions of
power. For example, Western scientific knowledge is represented as universally
valid and thus applicable to all, but not everyone qualified as an expert.
361
ESCOBAR, supra note 19, at 41; Tucker, supra note 64, at 7. Adaptation became a
key concept, for peoples and groups had to adapt. Id.
362
See Anders Narman & David Simon, Introduction, in DEVELOPMENT AS THEORY
AND PRACTICE CURRENT PROSEPCTIVES ON DEVELOPMENT AND DEVELOPMENT
CO-OPERATION 8 (David Simon et al. eds., 1999). For a revealing account from
inside the development community, see Frank, supra note 341, at 262. This ac-
count of how a multinational team of experts approved a project to develop a
rural area on the North-West frontier of Afghanistan demonstrates that when the
“facts” do not fit reality, reality is ignored; that local knowledge is purposely ig-
nored when it would mean that expert knowledge is unnecessary; that areas can
be “hot” for all sorts of reasons, having very little to do with the needs of local
people; and that the objects of development are presumed to be people of color
(Mr. Frank notes his surprise that these people were not the colored people he
usually encountered on such missions). See also ESCOBAR, supra note 19, at 41.
Moreover, the expert focus on promoting change at any cost raises issues of cul-
tural imperialism.
363
ESCOBAR, supra note 19, at 45. Escobar queries: why cash crops (to generate
foreign exchange, and thus to obtain capital and technology) and centralized
planning, instead of participatory and decentralized approaches; why agricultural
development based on large mechanized farms, instead of alternative agricultural
systems based on smaller farms, ecological considerations, integrated cropping
and pest management; why rapid economic growth, but not internal markets to
satisfy the needs of the masses of people; why capital intensive, but not labor
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 82 1-SEP-04 12:22
intensive solutions. Some of these choices are now being considered, given the
profound disasters facing many developing countries and their developers. But
this reconsideration still takes place within the developmental framework. Id. at
43.
364
The historical and cultural location of the “expert” may make it impossible to
shake off this status, by simply adopting participatory techniques, for it is a ques-
tion of political power. Kothari, supra note 22, at 39. For a detailed critique of
participation, see Rahnema, supra note 11, at 116.
365
ESCOBAR, supra note 19, at 41 (noting that communities responded to the devel-
opment agenda in myriad ways that sometimes incorporated resistance, and there
were manifold failures as developers tried and failed to bring about moderniza-
tion); Kothari, supra note 22, at 39 (noting development planners and practition-
ers often dismissed as inconsequential, the voices of the individuals whose
impoverishment and marginality they were seeking to address); Tucker, supra
note 64, at 7–8 (Observing that development was not conceived of as a cultural
process. Rather culture was a “residual variable that would disappear with the
advent of modernization. Thus it is unsurprising that development has wrecked
havoc on Third World cultures, ironically in their name and in their interest.
These multiple and varied encounters “were subsumed under the category of tra-
dition, an essentially pejorative term that denoted divergence from the generally
accepted norms of reason and progress.”).
366
Tucker, supra note 64, at 13.
367
ESCOBAR, supra note 19, at 41.
368
Esteva, supra note 1, at 13. See generally THE DEVELOPMENT DICTIONARY,
supra note 1 (deconstructing such familiar “devspeak” terms as, inter alia, plan-
ning, participation, poverty, progress, population, needs, helping, and
development).
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 83 1-SEP-04 12:22
369
Kothari, supra note 22, at 38; ESCOBAR, supra note 19, at 41 (remarking that it is
“Western dominated institutions that determine the practices and procedures for
all problems, theories, or objects that surface and are then named, analyzed and
eventually transformed into a policy or a plan”).
370
ESCOBAR, supra note 19, at 41.
371
Within the broad parameters of the policies set by the West, Third World coun-
tries may have some agency over the specifics and emphasis of projects. See
Frank, supra note 341, at 262.
372
Kothari, supra note 22, at 39.
373
The following discussion of Egypt can be found in Timothy Mitchell, The Object
of Development America’s Egypt, in POWER OF DEVELOPMENT 129–57 (Jonathan
Crush ed., 1995). Professor Mitchell contends that the following description of
Egypt can be found in almost any study of Egypt produced by an American or an
international development agency:
The geographical and demographic characteristics of Egypt delineate its
basic problem. Although the country contains about 386,000 square miles,
. . . only a narrow strip in the Nile Valley and its Delta is usable. This area
of 15,000 square miles – less than 4 percept of the land – is but an elon-
gated oasis in the midst of desert. Without the Nile, which flows through
Egypt for about a thousand miles without being joined by a single tribu-
tary, the country would be part of the Sahara. Crammed into the habitable
area is 98 per cent of the population . . . the population has been growing
rapidly and is estimated to have doubled since 1947.
The popularity of this image of space and numbers is summed up in a World
Bank report: “These two themes – the relatively fixed amount of usable land and
the rapid growth of the population – will be seen as leitmotifs in the discussion of
Egypt’s Economic problems.” The additional image of a traditional rural world
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 84 1-SEP-04 12:22
protein consumption exceeding that found in most middle and high-income coun-
tries. The problem is that the shift has come in higher levels of food consumption
among the better off, and most especially a higher consumption of meat, which
means that food production has in part shifted to food for animals that are then
slaughtered and sold as meat. It is the switch to meat consumption, rather than
an increase in population that has required the dramatic increase in food imports.
Id. at 132–36.
377
The image of a narrow strip of fertile land crammed with millions of inhabitants
enables the analysis of Egyptian economic development to quickly eclipse the
issue of access to land, because with so many people occupying so little space the
problem appears to be explained. Images are painted of millions of tiny parcels
and not enough land to go around. (The average size of a holding is two feddans,
94% of all owners have less than five feddans each, and only 0.2 percent have at
least 50 feddans each.) But given the extremely fertile soils, year-round sunshine
and permanently available irrigation water, very high yields can be obtained from
two or even three crops a year and thus holdings of less than five feddans are not
as small as they may seem and are well above the minimum farm size required for
a family farm to feed itself (estimated at 0.8 feddans). These figures also fail to
mention that the remaining six percent of landowners, with holdings from five
feddans up to the legal limit of 50 feddans per individual or 100 feddans per
family with dependent children, controlled 33 percent of the country’s agricul-
tural area and this concentration is increasing. It may also be that these official
figures, which rely on village land registers, under-represent the concentration of
landholding. Id. at 136–39.
378
For a discussion of how World Bank data and studies are created and utilized, see
Gavin Williams, Modernizing Malthus: the World Bank, Population Control and
the African Environment, in POWER OF DEVELOPMENT, supra note 17 (analyzing
a World Bank report on sub-Saharan Africa and noting how data and impressive
looking tables are often included, but bare little relation to the report, that much
of the research that is commissioned is of poor quality and when it is good, it is
not used or is shaped to fit pre-determined outcomes). See also Frank, supra note
341, at 262.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 86 1-SEP-04 12:22
379
The development project never sees itself as part of the problem and therefore
developers rarely acknowledge responsibility for development’s many failures.
The World Bank acknowledges failures, but seldom acknowledges its involve-
ment in such failures. Typically the blame is placed on its partner governments,
and sometimes on the people themselves. An example can be found in the World
Bank’s analysis of sub-Saharan Africa, which in itself is questionable given the
great variety of cultures, conditions, environmental settings and other factors that
can be found in Africa. The Bank does not ask whether whole approaches, such
importing chemical and mechanical technologies, might be inappropriate. In-
stead it recommends more of the same. The environmental consequences of
World Bank strategies are rarely considered. Instead, African women are identi-
fied as a cause of environmental damage. The Bank overlooks the consequences
of mechanized farming and chemical fertilizers, and of damns and irrigation
projects. The Report on Sub-Saharan Africa also draws no distinction between
pastoralists and cultivators, or between capitalist farms and peasant smallhold-
ings. Moreover, World Bank projects consistently privilege large-scale farmers
who are politically influential, easier to reach and responsive to advice from pro-
ject officials. Williams, supra note 378, at 158, 165. Much credit is claimed for
perceived successes, however, such as the so-called Asian miracles of South Ko-
rea, Taiwan, Singapore, and Hong Kong. This too is a constructed space for it is
doubtful that these “successes” had anything to do with the prescriptions ad-
vanced by development agencies. See O’Hearn, supra note 4, at 113–34.
380
Professor Mitchell notes:
The present of the non-West is the past of the West, and the future of
developing countries is the present of the West. When the non-West
reaches the point of development, it has already become the past of the
West, meaning the non-West has no real future since its future is already
known in Europe and America. Parts of the non-West are the distant, pre-
industrial revolution past of the North. The West was not just history; it is
remade in the present and reconstructed in the future. . . . At each stage, it
is internalized more and more and becomes an integral part of the global
consciousness. As such, the future has been colonized by the West. . . . The
future is defined in the image of the West. . . taking us towards a single,
determined future. . . . An illusion of accelerated movement is produced to
create an illusion of inevitability and to shroud the Eurocentric dimension
of the exercise. Conventionally, the colonization of the future was known
as Westernization. Now it goes under the rubric of globalization. The pro-
cess that is transforming the world into the proverbial global village, rap-
idly shrinking distances, compressing space and time, is also shaping the
world in the image of a single culture and civilization. In this Eurocentric
vision of the future, technology is projected as an autonomous and desira-
ble force. Its desirable products generate more desire; its second-order
side effects require more technology to solve them. Thus there is a perpet-
ual feedback loop and this self-perpetuating momentum has locked us in a
linear, one dimensional trajectory that has foreclosed the future of the non-
West.
Id.
382
Tucker, supra note 64, at 3.
383
Id.
384
For a discussion of the gap between theoreticians and practitioners, see Narman
& Simon, supra note at 362, at 1–2 (Noting practitioners are preoccupied with
action, which is often not placed in a larger context, while academics are con-
cerned with understanding. Politician, planners and administrators would prefer
to not question development because it would threaten international consensus,
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 88 1-SEP-04 12:22
392
Practitioners do usually agree, however, that development should have a human
face, and that target populations should be permitted to participate in planning
programs and implementing them. Rahnema, supra note 11, at 381.
393
Id. (Noting that there is a real danger that the many plausible arguments against
development will be used to take funds that would be used for development and
direct them to other uses. Perhaps it is better to spend the funds on agricultural
projects, food, shelter and health care, however questionable such spending may
be from philosophical point of view, than on say security and weapons. But are
they not connected. Can repressive states obtain funds more easily when security
requests are coupled with requests for development assistance.). The recent
spectacle at the UN, with the U.S. bribing or threatening states with development
aid to persuade them to vote for a resolution to use force against Iraq, really
crystallizes this point. See, e.g., Henry J. Richardson, III, U.S. Hegemony, Race,
and Oil in Deciding United Nations Security Council Resolution 1441 on Iraq, 17
TEMP. INT’L L.J. 27 (2003).
394
The so-called “Asian tigers” are often presented as proof that development can,
and eventually will, work. The economies of South Korea, Thailand, Singapore,
Hong Kong, and Taiwan are frequently offered as proof of the viability of the
Washington consensus and the triumph of export led growth based on markets.
Yet the rapid modernization of these nations had little to do with the interna-
tional development paradigm. For a devastating critique of the viability, sus-
tainability and perhaps the myth of the Asian Tigers, see O’Hearn, supra note 4,
at 117.
395
Rahnema, Towards Post-Development, supra note 11, at 381. Professor Rahnema
was the UN Representative in Mali and coordinator of other development
projects. She also notes that the bulk of the world’s resources are being utilized
for arms and repressive governments and she questions whether or not these
funds might be better spent on development projects, even if they are flawed.
396
Kiely, supra note 7, at 36. Professor Kiely maintains that the idea that needs and
poverty are solely social and cultural constructions, mistake the word for the
world and can create conditions wherein a positive local politics of empowerment
slides fitfully into an amoral politics of indifference. Id. In other words, it may
cause the rich to simply disengage. See also Jan Nederveen Pieterse, My Para-
digm or Yours? Alternative Development, Post-Development, Reflexive Develop-
ment, 29 DEV. & CHANGE 343 (1998).
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 90 1-SEP-04 12:22
397
Simon, supra note 10, at 17.
398
Both authors have visited Southern countries and witnessed the need for these
“comforts,” and thus take these criticisms very seriously. See Sylvester, supra
note 6.
399
It is maintained that the anti-development thesis does not take us “beyond the
dualisms of modernity and tradition, and dominant and dominated” and is rather
vague about alternatives as it romanticizes local cultures. Kiely, supra note 7, at
36–37. Professor Kiely notes that the idea that development always undermines
authentic cultures “can itself be considered a form of cultural imperialism, based
on a long tradition of romanticizing the ‘Other.’“ Id.
400
See, e.g., Narman & Simon, supra note 362, at 8. Professors Narman and Simon
point out that silence is often taken for lack of knowledge, while it could really
arise out of courtesy, a desire to not disagree or offend or to disclose information
considered too private. Indeed the targets of development have been quite inge-
nious in filtering the advice and instructions received from development profes-
sionals. They have not been as passive as might be thought and have been able to
be selective in accordance with their own needs and perceptions through their
cultural filters.
401
Given the amount of control exercised by international financial institutions over
the economies, politics and societal choices in the nations of the Third World, it
does not seem to be too far from colonialism. Indeed the discourse of racial,
social, political and cultural superiority that justified colonialism, underlies the
development discourse. Gordon, Saving Failed States, supra note 12, at 926.
402
It has been argued that nations do not necessarily participate in the globalization
project “as nations inevitably on their way to modernity, but as pragmatic and
strategic actors in a much more restricted game that is governed by free trade,
specializing in what can be done without the aid of protection, privatization, and
living within ones means.” O’Hearn, supra note 4, at 117.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 91 1-SEP-04 12:22
403
Escobar posits that there is little point in speculating in the abstract about the
character of a post-development era, for if we accept that critical thought must be
situated, then a discussion of these issues should be practice-oriented, engaging
with the political claims and actions of oppositional movements. See Escobar,
Imagining a Post Development Era, supra note 388, at 211, 216.
404
Simply put, “would the Third World have been better off without development
assistance?” See, e.g., Narman & Simon, supra note 362, at 7.
405
Id.
406
Of course, it is international capital that has decided that Western workers no
longer will do certain types of work. Chantel Thomas, Globalization and the Pro-
duction of Hierarchy, 33 U.C. DAVIS L. REV. 1451 (2000) (discussing when corpo-
rations relocate to the Third World in search of cheap labor, less governmental
regulation and the like).
407
See, e.g., Narman & Simon, supra note 362, at 1–2.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 92 1-SEP-04 12:22
408
See Illich, supra note 42, at 88 (discussing the evolution of needs in development
discourse, as it evolved from food, clothing, materials for housing and mechanical
power into a measurable standard such as Gross National Product and then into
notions of absolute poverty and minimum levels of human decency).
409
Rahnema, Towards Post-Development, supra note 11, at 377, 379. The pre-devel-
opment world was also the colonized world and colonialism was a destructive
force that disrupted communities, changed cultures and had complex effects
across very complex cultures. Thus developers did not confront pristine societies
untouched by the West. See Ruth Gordon, Growing Constitutions, 1 U. PA. J.
CONST. L. 528 (1999).
410
Gordon, Saving Failed States, supra note 12, at 930–35.
411
See supra notes 35–54 and accompanying text on poverty.
412
Illich, supra note 42, at 88, 96 (Noting in “traditional poverty, people could rely
on finding a cultural hemlock,” but development is a process which “lifts people
out of their traditional cultural commons,” dissolving such cultural bonds. Many
are sinking deeper and deeper into an abyss of worsening poverty from which
they will never be able to rise and meet their new needs.).
413
For a discussion of the modern-traditional dichotomy, see ESCOBAR, supra note
19, at 75–80; Escobar, Planning, supra note 157, at 135–36.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 93 1-SEP-04 12:22
414
Cultures change, but development viewed tradition and Third World cultures as
impediments to modernization and thus to be eradicated in favor of develop-
ment. Indeed development can be visualized as a process by which people are
lifted out of their cultural commons. In this transition, cultural bonds are dis-
solved, even though culture can continue to tinge development in superficial ways
– one need only observe rural people recently transplanted to the megacities of
the Third World. ESCOBAR, supra note 19, at 75–80; Escobar, Planning, supra
note 157, at 135–36.
415
McGee, Participating in Development, in DEVELOPMENT THEORY at 93, 95–96.
(Noting early orthodoxy when the “development agency conceived, designed,
funded, managed, implemented and evaluated the project from somewhere
outside its boundaries”; and there were the project beneficiaries –undifferenti-
ated, passive recipients of goods and services provided through project channels.
People – whether in the agency or in the beneficiary population – were scarcely
acknowledged to be there.” Beginning the 1980s higher levels of “participation”
came into vogue, but even these interventions were problematic.).
416
See Doug J. Porter, Scenes from Childhood the Homesickness of Development
Discourses, in POWER OF DEVELOPMENT, supra note 17, at 63 (noting that dis-
course analysis at minimum might make development workers aware of their
practices).
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 94 1-SEP-04 12:22
417
This analysis does not take account of situations involving war or similar conflicts.
The responsibilities of the international community in any such situation necessa-
rily differ from that in times of peace, regardless of where a particular nation
stands on the modernization scale.
418
Racial difference on the international stage cannot be equated with notions of
race in the United States. But it is equally clear that a racial discourse partly
inspired colonial discourse and is not irrelevant in foreign policy. It certainly
colors perceptions of the developing world, which is inevitably seen as the
colored world. Gordon, Critical Race Theory, supra note 331. It is also acknowl-
edged that development practitioners come from all over the world and thus may
be people of color. This does not mean race is irrelevant, but that it may be that
its effect is more complex and difficult to sort out.
419
Tucker, supra note 64, at 3.
420
Sardar, supra note 55, at 44. The West defines freedom, progress, law, tradition,
community science, what is real and what it means to be human. Non-Western
societies must accept these definitions or cease to exist. Id.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 95 1-SEP-04 12:22
421
Participation attempts to incorporate the voice of development’s target in the
process of development. For a discussion of the evolution of “participation,” see
McGee, supra note 114, at 93. See also Rahnema, Participation, supra note 155,
at 116; Minogue & Kothari, Conclusion, supra note 391, at 185–86.
422
Rahnema, Towards Post-Development, supra note 11, at 377, 379. See also Rich-
ard Douthwaite, Is it Possible to Build a Sustainable World, in CRITICAL DEVEL-
OPMENT THEORY, supra note 4, at 158–60 (detailing why the current global
economic system is unsustainable).
423
See, e.g., Eduardo Galeano, To Be Like Them, in THE POST-DEVELOPMENT
READER, supra note 11, at 214.
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 96 1-SEP-04 12:22
424
Often when these questions are raised, the immediate response is that everyone
wants what the West offers and the person raising the question is queried about
whether he or she would give up their Western life-style. Third World scholars
are similarly interrogated, and if they reside in the West, are presented as proof
that all peoples desire life in the West. For those born and raised in Western
countries, this is truly an unfair question, for few are willing to change their entire
way of life, especially when that life has always been posited as superior and the
alternative posited as inferior. The Western brain drain is certainly a reality, as
Western educated elites seek jobs in the North. And while it is true that many
elites have embraced development wholeheartedly, not all Third World elites
have migrated to the West. Moreover, it may be difficult to straddle the morass
left in the wake of development, which has left many with few viable economic
options besides re-settling in the West. Leaving may be the only reasonable
course, and thus many leave even as they make their life work helping those left
behind. Finally it is not argued that the West is inferior and undesirable and no
one would choose it. Indeed many have and many undoubtedly will. What is
posed is how to give people the choice to direct the change, or lack thereof, that
will govern their lives.
425
This would include, if not prioritize, the waste and environmental degradation
wrought by the industrialized world.
426
While the demonstrations and other actions against globalizations are more or
less ridiculed in the United States by the American media, this resistance has
continued and is perhaps expanding.
427
Escobar, Imagining a Post Development Era, supra note 388, at 211, 217.
428
Escobar notes that these new social movements are often compared with the old,
meaning “modernization or dependency; politics centered around traditional ac-
tors like parties, vanguards, and the working class who struggle for the control of
the state, and towards a view of society as composed of more or less immutable
structures class relations that only great changes (i.e. massive development
\\server05\productn\W\WIN\22-1\WIN106.txt unknown Seq: 97 1-SEP-04 12:22
432
See supra notes 6, 164–68 and accompanying text. For an excellent anysis of the
debt problem in Africa, see Chris N. Okeke, The Debt Burden:An African Per-
spective, 35 INT’L LAW 1489 (2001); Susan George, How the Poor Develop the
Rich, in THE POST-DEVELOPMENT READER, supra note 11, at 207 (detailing how
the debt drains funds from the Third World and enriches the industrialized
world).
433
See, e.g., Ruth Gordon, Humanitarian Intervention by the United Nations: Iraq,
Somalia, and Haiti, 31 TEX. INT’L L.J. 43 (1996).
434
Rahnema, Towards Post-Development, supra note 11, at 384. Industrialization
might be rejected by some, welcomed by others or it might be restructured to
meet local needs; other alternatives would be on the table. Health care and other
basic social services might be embraced, or perhaps reshaped and then supported.