0% found this document useful (0 votes)
22 views

CH 3

The document discusses concepts related to modeling consumer preferences in economics including preference relations, indifference curves, assumptions about preferences, and examples of different types of preferences. Preference relations define how bundles of goods are ranked, indifference curves represent sets of equally preferred bundles, and assumptions ensure preferences can be logically modeled.

Uploaded by

ecs
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
22 views

CH 3

The document discusses concepts related to modeling consumer preferences in economics including preference relations, indifference curves, assumptions about preferences, and examples of different types of preferences. Preference relations define how bundles of goods are ranked, indifference curves represent sets of equally preferred bundles, and assumptions ensure preferences can be logically modeled.

Uploaded by

ecs
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 26

8/22/2015

Chapter Three
Preferences

Rationality in Economics
• Behavioral Postulate:
A decisionmaker always chooses its most
preferred alternative from its set of
available alternatives.
• So to model choice we must model
decisionmakers’ preferences.

1
8/22/2015

Preference Relations
• Comparing two different consumption
bundles, x and y:
• strict preference: x is more preferred than is y.
• weak preference: x is as at least as preferred as is
y.
• indifference: x is exactly as preferred as is y.

Preference Relations
• Strict preference, weak preference and
indifference are all preference relations.
• Particularly, they are ordinal relations; i.e.
they state only the order in which bundles
are preferred.

2
8/22/2015

Preference Relations
• > denotes strict preference so
x > y means that bundle x is preferred strictly to
bundle y.
• ~ denotes indifference; x ~ y means x and y are
equally preferred.
• ≥ denotes weak preference;
x ≥ y means x is preferred at least as much as is y.

Preference Relations
• x ≥ y and y ≥ x imply x ~ y.

• x ≥ y and (not y ≥ x) imply x > y.

3
8/22/2015

Assumptions about Preference


Relations
• Completeness: For any two bundles x and
y it is always possible to make the
statement that either
x ≥ y
or
y ≥ x

Assumptions about Preference


Relations
• Reflexivity: Any bundle x is always at least
as preferred as itself; i.e.

x ≥ x.

4
8/22/2015

Assumptions about Preference


Relations
• Transitivity: If
x is at least as preferred as y, and
y is at least as preferred as z, then
x is at least as preferred as z; i.e.

x ≥ y and y ≥ z x ≥ z.

Indifference Curves
• Take a reference bundle x’. The set of all
bundles equally preferred to x’ is the
indifference curve containing x’; the set of
all bundles y ~ x’.
• Since an indifference “curve” is not always
a curve a better name might be an
indifference “set”.

5
8/22/2015

Indifference Curves
x2 x’ ~ x” ~ x”’
x’

x”

x”’

x1

Indifference Curves
x2 z> x > y
x

x1

6
8/22/2015

Indifference Curves
I1 All bundles in I1 are
x2
x strictly preferred to
all in I2.
z
I2

All bundles in I2 are


y strictly preferred to
I3
all in I3.
x1

Indifference Curves
x2
WP(x), the set of
x bundles weakly
preferred to x.

I(x) I(x’)

x1

7
8/22/2015

Indifference Curves
x2
WP(x), the set of
x bundles weakly
preferred to x.
WP(x)
includes
I(x) I(x).

x1

Indifference Curves
x2
SP(x), the set of
x bundles strictly
preferred to x,
does not
include
I(x) I(x).

x1

8
8/22/2015

Indifference Curves Cannot


Intersect
x2 I2 From I1, x ~ y. From I2, x ~ z.
I1 Therefore y ~ z.

x
y
z

x1

Indifference Curves Cannot


Intersect
x2 I2 From I1, x ~ y. From I2, x ~ z.
I1 Therefore y ~ z. But from I1
p
and I2 we see y z, a
contradiction.
x
y
z

x1

9
8/22/2015

Slopes of Indifference Curves


• When more of a commodity is always
preferred, the commodity is a good.
• If every commodity is a good then
indifference curves are negatively sloped.

Slopes of Indifference Curves


Good 2
Two goods
a negatively sloped
indifference curve.

Good 1

10
8/22/2015

Slopes of Indifference Curves


• If less of a commodity is always preferred
then the commodity is a bad.

Slopes of Indifference Curves


Good 2
One good and one
bad a
positively sloped
indifference curve.

Bad 1

11
8/22/2015

Extreme Cases of Indifference


Curves; Perfect Substitutes
• If a consumer always regards units of
commodities 1 and 2 as equivalent, then
the commodities are perfect substitutes
and only the total amount of the two
commodities in bundles determines their
preference rank-order.

Extreme Cases of Indifference


Curves; Perfect Substitutes
x2
Slopes are constant at - 1.
15 I2
Bundles in I2 all have a total
8 of 15 units and are strictly
preferred to all bundles in
I1 I1, which have a total of
only 8 units in them.
8 15 x1

12
8/22/2015

Extreme Cases of Indifference


Curves; Perfect Complements
• If a consumer always consumes
commodities 1 and 2 in fixed proportion
(e.g. one-to-one), then the commodities
are perfect complements and only the
number of pairs of units of the two
commodities determines the preference
rank-order of bundles.

Extreme Cases of Indifference


Curves; Perfect Complements
x2
45o Each of (5,5), (5,9)
and (9,5) contains
5 pairs so each is
equally preferred.
9
5 I1

5 9 x1

13
8/22/2015

Extreme Cases of Indifference


Curves; Perfect Complements
x2
45o Since each of (5,5),
(5,9) and (9,5)
contains 5 pairs,
each is less
9 I2 preferred than the
bundle (9,9) which
5 I1 contains 9 pairs.

5 9 x1

Preferences Exhibiting
Satiation
• A bundle strictly preferred to any other is a
satiation point or a bliss point.
• What do indifference curves look like for
preferences exhibiting satiation?

14
8/22/2015

Indifference Curves Exhibiting


Satiation
x2
Satiation
(bliss)
point

x1

Indifference Curves Exhibiting


Satiation
x2
Satiation
(bliss)
point
Better

x1

15
8/22/2015

Indifference Curves Exhibiting


Satiation
x2
Satiation
(bliss)
point
Better

x1

Indifference Curves for


Discrete Commodities
• A commodity is infinitely divisible if it can
be acquired in any quantity; e.g. water or
cheese.
• A commodity is discrete if it comes in unit
lumps of 1, 2, 3, … and so on; e.g. aircraft,
ships and refrigerators.

16
8/22/2015

Indifference Curves for


Discrete Commodities
• Suppose commodity 2 is an infinitely
divisible good (gasoline) while commodity
1 is a discrete good (aircraft). What do
indifference “curves” look like?

Indifference Curves With a


Discrete Good
Gas-
oline Indifference “curves”
are collections of
discrete points.

0 1 2 3 4 Aircraft

17
8/22/2015

Well-Behaved Preferences
• A preference relation is “well-behaved” if
it is monotonic and convex.
• Monotonicity: More of any commodity is
always preferred (i.e. no satiation and
every commodity is a good).

Well-Behaved Preferences
• Convexity: Mixtures of bundles are (at
least weakly) preferred to the bundles
themselves. E.g., the 50-50 mixture of the
bundles x and y is
z = (0.5)x + (0.5)y.
z is at least as preferred as x or y.

18
8/22/2015

Well-Behaved Preferences --
Convexity.

x2 x

x2+y2 x+y is strictly preferred to


z=
2 both x and y.
2
y
y2
x1 x1+y1 y1
2

Well-Behaved Preferences --
Convexity.

x2 x
z =(tx1+(1-t)y1, tx2+(1-t)y2)
is preferred to x and y
for all 0 < t < 1.
y
y2
x1 y1

19
8/22/2015

Well-Behaved Preferences --
Convexity.
Preferences are strictly convex
x when all mixtures z
x2
are strictly
z preferred to their
component
bundles x and y.
y
y2
x1 y1

Well-Behaved Preferences --
Weak Convexity.
x’ Preferences are
z’ weakly convex if at
least one mixture z
is equally preferred
x to a component
z
y bundle.
y’

20
8/22/2015

Non-Convex Preferences

x2
The mixture z
z is less preferred
than x or y.
y2
x1 y1

More Non-Convex Preferences

x2
The mixture z
z is less preferred
than x or y.
y2
x1 y1

21
8/22/2015

Slopes of Indifference Curves


• The slope of an indifference curve is its
marginal rate-of-substitution (MRS).
• the marginal rate of substitution is the rate
at which a consumer is ready to give up
one good in exchange for another good
while maintaining the same level of utility.
• How can a MRS be calculated?

Marginal Rate of Substitution


x2
MRS at x’ is the slope of the
indifference curve at x’

x’

x1

22
8/22/2015

Marginal Rate of Substitution


x2
MRS at x’ is
lim {Dx2/Dx1}
Dx1 0
Dx2 x’ = dx2/dx1 at x’

Dx1

x1

Marginal Rate of Substitution


x2 dx2 = MRS  dx1 so, at x’, MRS
is the rate at which the
consumer is only just willing to
exchange commodity 2 for a
x’ small amount of commodity 1.
dx2
dx1

x1

23
8/22/2015

MRS & Ind. Curve Properties


Good 2
Two goods
a negatively sloped
indifference curve

MRS < 0.

Good 1

MRS & Ind. Curve Properties


Good 2
One good and one
bad a positively
sloped indifference curve

MRS > 0.

Bad 1

24
8/22/2015

MRS & Ind. Curve Properties


Good 2
MRS = - 5
MRS always increases with x1
(becomes less negative) if and
only if preferences are strictly
convex.

MRS = - 0.5 Good 1

MRS & Ind. Curve Properties


x2 MRS decreases
MRS = - 0.5
(becomes more negative)
as x1 increases
nonconvex preferences

MRS = - 5
x1

25
8/22/2015

MRS & Ind. Curve Properties


MRS is not always increasing as x1
x2
increases nonconvex
preferences.
MRS = - 1
MRS
= - 0.5
MRS = - 2

x1

26

You might also like