Alter & Meunier 2009
Alter & Meunier 2009
JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide
range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and
facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].
Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
https://about.jstor.org/terms
American Political Science Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and
extend access to Perspectives on Politics
The increasing density of international regimes has contributed to the proliferation of overlap across agreements, conflicts among
international obligations, and confusion regarding what international and bilateral obligations cover an issue. This symposium
examines the consequences of this "international regime complexity" for subsequent politics. What analytical insights can be gained
by thinking about any single agreement as being embedded in a larger web of international rules and regimes? Karen Alter and
Sophie Meunier s introductory essay defines international regime complexity and identifies the mechanisms through which it may
influence the politics of international cooperation. Short contributions analyze how international regime complexity affects politics
in specific issue areas: trade (Christina Davis), linkages between human rights and trade (Emilie Hafner-Burton), intellectual prop-
erty (Laurence Heifer), security politics (Stephanie Hofmann), refugee politics (Alexander Betts), and election monitoring (Judith
Kelley). Daniel Drezner concludes by arguing that international regime complexity may well benefit the powerful more than others.
number, level of detail, and subject matter of Following David Victor and Kal Raustialas analysis of
international agreements have grown exponentially"regimes complexes," we call this growing phenomenon
in recent decades. From peacekeeping to telecom- "international regime complexity."1 International regime
munication standards, from the monitoring of electionscomplexity refers to the presence of nested, partially over-
to the protection of endangered species, it seems that everylapping, and parallel international regimes that are not
policy issue is nowadays the subject of multiple trans- hierarchically ordered. Although rule complexity also exists
border agreements. The proliferation of international agree-in the domestic realm, the lack of hierarchy distinguishes
ments multiplies the number of actors and rules relevantinternational regime complexity, making it harder to resolve
for any given decision of international cooperation. The where political authority over an issue resides.2
Inter-American Development Banks spaghetti bowl of We are not the first to point out the need to think of
Trade Agreements, shown in Figure 1 captures, perhaps ininternational cooperation as a complex system.3 But while
the extreme, this emerging density and complexity of inter-this need is readily admitted, few studies and even fewer
national governance. theories are available to guide scholars in thinking about
the consequences of this complexity. The state-centric bias
of international relations, combined with a tendency to
focus on the origin rather than the implementation of
Karen J. Alter is Associate Professor of Political Science at
formal rules, leads political scientists to focus overwhelm-
Northwestern University ([email protected]).
ingly on the causes of international regime complexity.
Sophie Meunier is Research Scholar in Public and Inter-
We are, however, more interested in its consequences.
national Affairs at Princeton University (smeunier@
How is the sheer complexity of international gover-
Princeton.edu). They thank the Niehaus Center for Global-
nance today, with its multiple set of rules and institutions,
ization and Governance at Princeton University and the
affecting international politics? Does international regime
Northwestern University Institute on Complex Systems for
complexity impact decision-making and political strat-
funding their project meetings. Thanks to David Dana,
egies, as well as empower some actors and interest groups?
Gary Goertz, Jim Mahoney, Jacqueline McAllister, Uri
How does complexity enhance or undermine the effective-
Wilensky, and the participants of meetings at Princeton,
Northwestern, and American Political Science Association ness of international regimes? More generally, what ana-
lytical insights can be gained by thinking about any single
conventions for their challenges and feedback. Thanks to
agreement as being embedded in a larger web of inter-
David Steinberg for his research support, and Nancy Bar-
national rules and regimes? These questions, and others,
thélémy, David Steinberg, and the Roberta Buffet Center
are raised by the reality that, increasingly, international
for International and Comparative Studies for administra-
governance occurs via a multitude of nested, partially over-
tive support. Thanks also go to three anonymous reviewers
lapping, and parallel trans-border agreements.
for their useful comments.
14 Perspectives on Politics
redefined during implementation because the actors who interpretations come to dominate over time? Which actors
implement agreements have different priorities and are are able to influence interpretations and prioritization
subject to different pressures than are the policy-makers across agreements? When does a rule or an interpretation
who designed the deal in the first place. International harden and become difficult to shift through refraining
regime complexity adds a new twist to implementation or reinterpretation?
politics: international regime complexity reduces the clarity
of legal obligation by introducing overlapping sets of legal International Regime Complexity Enables "Chessboard
rules and jurisdictions governing an issue. Lawyers refer to Politics" - Cross Institutional Political Strategies. We asked
this problem as the "fragmentation" of international law.21 our contributors to consider the counterfactual question -
Where state preferences are similar, lawyers overcome frag- what would have been a likely outcome if parallel and
mentation by crafting agreements that resolve conflicts overlapping institutions did not exist? From this exercise
across regimes, and thus legal ambiguity is transitory. Where we could see that even where decision-makers do not
preferences diverge, states block attempts to clarify the actively reference other institutions, parallel regime poli-
rules and thus ambiguity persists, allowing countries to tics could sometimes explain the timing and content of
select their preferred rule or interpretation. the policies adopted. In some cases, the greatest action
With the rules themselves or the hierarchy across rules took place outside of the central institution of focus.
remaining fundamentally ambiguous, agreements get We use the concept of "chessboard politics" as a more
defined and redefined across time and space. In her con- open way of explaining how international regime com-
tribution to our symposium, Emilie Hafner-Burton finds plexity alters the strategic playing field. Once a density
that during the implementation stage, opponents of human threshold is reached,22 the existence of multiple institu-
rights linkages to trade agreements have used the Vienna tions with authority over an issue allows moves made in a
Convention on the Law of Treaties to strip out the human single international institution to reposition pawns, knights,
rights requirements demanded by the European Parlia- and queens within other institutions. Sometimes reposi-
ment. But this strategy is only used when the human rights tioning is done intentionally, and sometimes it occurs
linkages become a barrier in bilateral relations, and thus incidentally.
for many agreements the linkage remains. In Stephanie A number of our contributors identified forum-shopping
Hofmann's study of European Defense and Security Pol- strategies where actors select the international venues based
icy (ESDP), preference divergence created significant ambi- on where they are best able to promote specific policy
guity in the "Berlin Agreements," which affected operations, preferences, with the goal of eliciting a decision that favors
creating delays and confusion on the ground. In the case their interests. In her contribution to this symposium,
of refugee policy analyzed by Alexander Betts, United Judith Kelley analyzes a case where governments shopped
Nations policy became redefined over time to take into for election monitors they believed would render the most
account developments in parallel domains - migration and favorable declaration for them. In Hafner-Burton's study
security policies. In all of these cases, the formal texts of trade and human rights, forum shopping was a means
remained the same. Only in examining implementation for voices excluded from one venue (the European Parlia-
were the transformations, either made possible or compli- ment has no role in World Trade Organization negotia-
cated by international regime complexity, revealed. tions) to impose their preferences in a different venue (the
European Parliament must approve bilateral trade agree-
Implementation Politics Lessons ments between the EU and individual countries). Not
Lesson 1. International regime complexity contributes to only did the European Parliament gain a voice, but the
international law fragmentation and rule ambiguity. Where different bargaining context for the bilateral agreements
state preferences are similar, states will coordinate to cre- limited the ability of weaker recipient states to veto the
ate a clear set of rules. Where preferences diverge, ambi- linkage between trade and human rights. In her study of
guity will persist, allowing countries to select their preferred the trade regime, Christina Davis explains the reasons why
interpretation. different forums have different politics, and thus the fac-
tors that shape actor choices and outcomes in different
Lesson 2. Because states can select which rules to follow forums.
and because each international venue allows a different set We also identified cross-institutional political strategies
of actors to be part of the political process, implementa- where actors promoted agenda across multiple inter-
tion politics will end up defining which international agree- national institutions to influence policy outcomes. Whereas
ments become salient, and the meaning of international forum-shopping is focused on achieving a desired out-
agreements. come within a given regime (a favorable decision, for exam-
ple), regime-shifting is designed to reshape the global
Next steps. The next question to ask is from the sea of structure of rules.23 According to Larry Heifer, when devel-
overlapping agreements, which agreements and which oping countries were out-maneuvered within the World
16 Perspectives on Politics
advice, and to fund and encourage the types of activities opposed to collectivities of individuals, develop expecta-
undertaken to influence problem framings and solution tions, norms, shared goals, and differentiated roles for mem-
descriptions. bers.33 International regime complexity contributes to
creating small group environments by multiplying the
number of international venues, and thus the occasions
Bounded Rationality Lessons. Lesson 1 . International
regime complexity can create a heightened role for for state representatives to interact. Because international
informers - experts, lawyers, and NGOs - which help agreements are technical, diplomacy is a skill, and lan-
states manage rule and institutional confusion. guage knowledge is useful for international bargaining, it
is increasingly the case that a single office and even a single
individual will handle multiple portfolios. The more valu-
Lesson 2. International regime complexity can increase
able expertise becomes, the more we will find that the
actors' reliance on heuristics. Therefore, the way to influ-
same individual is crafting a country's policy for multiple
ence actor behavior is to create problem framings and
institutions. Indeed, over the arc of an individual career,
problem answers for governments. Because international
the same person may well serve in multiple capacities -
regime complexity contributes to rule ambiguity and allows
for instance as a state representative, a member of a non-
for cross-institutional strategies, complexity creates oppor-
governmental organization, and an IO official.
tunities for political actors to shift framings.
Scholars have studied small group environments to
understand how repeated interactions shape creativity, risk
Lesson 3. Causal complexity makes it harder to identify
taking, and trust across actors. Complexity scholars focus
clear cause and effect relations, complicating the task of
on the nature of networked connections, examining how
identifying optimal policies and assigning accountability
differences in the connections (degrees of separation or
for problematic decisions. Feedback effects, because they
other types of differences) affect outcomes.34 For example,
play out over time, are more likely to become defining of Brian Uzzi finds that firms that create "small world" net-
policy and politics where bounded rationality is present.
works, where producers and suppliers are connected by
few degrees of separation, behave differently than firms
Next steps. We need to study further the roles, influence
that do not create small world supplier networks.35 Soci-
and behavior of the actors who help states and IOs find
ologists focus on how sub-cultures develop within small
their way through complex terrains - the lawyers, NGOs,
groups, and how familiarity of members shapes informa-
and sub-contractors, with awareness of what is going on
tion processing, decision-making, and behavior of actors
at the ground level. We need to better understand within the group.36 Political analysts have imputed policy
heuristics - informal methods, ideologies, ideas, and rules
styles and outcomes to small group dynamics.37
of thumb. How are heuristics generated and changed?
All of these literatures argue that smallness creates deeper
When and how do heuristics shape decision-making? How
connections among actors, providing multiple advan-
do heuristics vary across states, cultures and time? Once
tages. Small groups can be imbued with trust, which leads
we know more about the heuristics states use, the formal
to a willingness to solve problems collectively and makes
approaches of complexity studies can help us think about
taking risks less costly. These factors facilitate innovation
how heuristics play out over time, and about how chang-
and also increase the value of reputation. Yves Dezalay and
ing heuristics and assumptions may alter outcomes.
Bryant Garth show how small group dynamics help explain
the development and rapid spread of the "Washington
International Regime Complexity Generates Small Consensus" (a set of economic best practices) within
Group Environments multinational institutions and individual states to create
We tend to assume that international cooperation will be rapid policy change across a number of developing coun-
the opposite of a small group environment because of the tries.38 Antonin Cohen and Mikael Rask Madsen have
large number and heterogeneity of states involved. The shown how small group dynamics were also behind the
typical assumptions in international relations analysis - explosion of supra-national agreements and legal mecha-
that states are the unit of analysis, that "where you stand nisms in Europe in the 1950s.39 In this symposium, Davis
depends on where you sit" (that title or nationality defines suggests that the small group dynamic of trade negotia-
the perspective the actor brings into the room)32 - also tions may increase the value of reputation across agreements.
obscure the extent to which small groups are shaping inter- Small group environments can also present potential
national cooperation. By focusing on the names as well as dangers - group think, in-group/outgroup rivalry, and a
titles of actors, network analysis can reveal the small groups failure to fully monitor and respond to what goes on
operating in international policy domains. outside of embedded networks. The dangers can gener-
Small groups involve face-to-face interactions where the ate the types of decision-making pathologies Michael Bar-
group is small enough and interaction is sufficient for nett and Martha Finnemore observe within multilateral
40
institutions.
members to develop perceptions of each other. Groups, as
18 Perspectives on Politics
In addition to strategic efforts to shift multiple inter- alence of legal and illegal exit - non-compliance, regime
national game boards, our contributors found that changes avoidance, or withdrawal from an IO. International regime
within one institution could reverberate across parallel insti- complexity can also make it easier for states to abandon an
tutions. The international cooperation game board may inconvenient obligation. Betts finds that international
shift as actors meet and are informed by their experiences regime complexity combines with ambiguity to allow states
in multiple forums (leading to changes in their policy to escape the inconvenient UN refugee institutions. Hafner-
preferences) and because events in one arena can reverber- Burton shows how the Vienna Convention for Treaties
ate in ways that states cannot fully anticipate or control. was used to strip away the bilateral human rights provi-
In Betts' analysis, the seemingly unrelated issue of security sions inserted by the European Parliament. And if parallel
and migration came to define what was possible when it regimes provide substitutable benefits, states will also lose
came to dealing with refugees, leading the United Nations less by giving up any one agreement.
High Commission on Refugees to reinterpret how it under-
stood its mandate. In Davis' contribution, regional and Feedback Effects Lessons. Lesson 1. International regime
issue specific trade agreements were not per se designed to complexity creates competition among institutions and
undermine multilateral trade deals, but nonetheless such actors. Competition can have negative effects - turf bat-
agreements sapped support for World Trade Organization tles and a failure to coordinate efforts. Competition can
(WTO) talks because in removing the easier issues, multi- also have positive effects - increasing total resources,
lateral negotiations became harder and fewer actors had a spreading risk, allowing experimentation. Competition
direct stake in their success. also increases the options of aid recipients, allowing them
Accountability politics is another sort of systemic feed- to pick and choose which organization can service their
back effect. On the one hand, international regime com- needs.
plexity blurs which institution is authoritative, and thus
makes it harder to assess which actors or institutions to Lesson 2. International regime complexity increases the
hold accountable. On the other hand, international regime chances of unintentional reverberations - changes in one
complexity can create access for more actors, and thereby institution having effects in parallel domains.
be a force for greater political accountability. For the issue
of Intellectual Property, it was clear that the TRIPs agree- Lesson 3. International regime complexity makes it harder
ment did not meet the needs and desires of developing to locate which institution or actor is responsible for an
countries to have access to inexpensive medicines and to issue, and thus it can undermine accountability.
protect indigenous technologies. Heifer's discussion of how
regime-shifting ended up altering global intellectual prop- Lesson 4. International regime complexity can increase
erty rules can be read as an example of international rules the value of loyalty, because what states do in one arena
being adjusted to take greater account of the interests of will affect perceptions of others (e.g., states, citizens, firms)
developing countries. While the requirements of TRIPs in other arenas.
were not relaxed in any fundamental ways, developing
countries were able to lock in more flexibility than Amer- Lesson 5. International regime complexity facilitates exit
ican and European IP interests may have preferred, and via non-compliance, regime shifting, or withdrawal from
they were thus able to resist aspects of U.S. pressure to IOs.
adopt TRIPS-plus bilateral agreements.
It is also possible for popular accountability politics to Next steps. When is competition beneficial, and when is
redefine state preferences. Betts found that governments it pathological? Where is non-compliance a form of
responded to popular concerns about influxes of foreign- accountability politics, part of maintaining a fragile equi-
ers by strategizing to keep refugees from entering their librium? Where is non-compliance destructive of the nor-
territories, and by finding ways to avoid classifying a per- mative order or an indication of regime failure?
son as a refugee. One result was that states end up sending
individuals back to contexts where their safety cannot be This discussion has identified a number of ways in which
assured. Another result is that the UNHCR developed the reality of international regime complexity can alter in-
new strategies to prod states to address the issue of inter- ternational politics. We do not expect the abovementioned
nally displaced people. factors to matter when there is a general consensus on an
Albert Hirschman famously identified three forms of issue, since consensus will either be reflected in overlap-
political behavior - exit, voice, and loyalty.45 Davis hypoth- ping, nested and parallel agreements, or rules will quickly
esizes that international regime complexity could increase be coordinated to resolve ambiguities and contradictions
loyalty, in Hirschmans sense of the term, by increasing across agreements. Thus, when the problem is diagnosed
the reputation costs of breaking any one agreement. Inter- the same way by diverse actors and the understanding of
national regime complexity also arguably increases the prev- the solution is similar and agreed upon, international regime
20 Perspectives on Politics
have the resources to work more easily through maze of this fragmentation. Their reports are available on-
rules and players. But because complexity creates open- line: http://untreaty.un.org/ilc/guide/ l_9.htm
ings for non-state actors to influence outcomes, and because 22 Pierson 2004, 83-87.
not all chessboard politics can be calculated or controlled, 23 Heifer 2004, 14.
international regime complexity matters even for power- 24 Raustiala and Victor 2004, 301.
ful states. The lack of any ordering principle for inter- 25 Abbott and Snidai 1998; Helfer 1999; Alter and
national legal obligations means that no deal is supreme, Vargas 2000; Diehl, Ku, and Zamora 2003;
and no multilateral outcome inherently more authorita- Walders and Pratt 2003; Heifer 2004; Hafner-
tive. Furthermore, powerful actors will still be interacting Burton 2004; Jupille and Snidai 2006; Busch 2007;
with actors who participate in and are shaped by politics Davis 2007.
in other domains, so that over time powerful actors will 26 Jones, Boushey, and Workman 2006, 57-9.
have to deal with the reality of parallel institutions that 27 Pierson 2004, 38-40; Jacobs and Teles 2007.
they cannot control. 28 Hawkins and Jacoby 2006.
29 Hawkins et al. 2006.
30 Newman 2008.
Notes 31 Haas 1992; Dezalay and Garth 2002; Sikkink 2003;
1 Raustiala and Victor 2004, 279. Slaughter 2004.
32 Alison
2 Alter and Meunier 2006, 365, 377. The lack of hier- 1969,711.
33 Harrington and Fine 2000, 313.
archy comes from the reality that there is no agreed
upon supreme international authority - in fact or 34 in
Amaral and Ottino 2004, 151-7.
35 Uzzi 1997a, 1997b.
law. International law has "conflict of law" rules of
36 Harrington and Fine 2000, 2006.
thumb that can resolve unintentional conflicts among
37 Janis 1972; Katzenstein 1985.
rules, but these conventions do not resolve the prob-
lem of no supreme international legal authority, 38 Dezalay and Garth 2002.
39 Cohen and Madsen 2007; Madsen 2007.
which is why conflict of laws conventions are unable
to establish a international law hierarchy when 40 Barnett and Finnemore 1999; Barnett and
Finnemore 2004.
states fundamentally disagree about which rule or insti-
41 Haas 1964; Haas 1990.
tution they prefer. International lawyers worry about
this problem; see Kingsbury 1999. 42 Cojan 2008.
3 Young 1996; Aggarwal 1998; Snyder and Jervis 43 Bob 2002.
44 Carpenter 2007.
1993; Putnam 1988; Evans, Jacobson, and Putnam
1993; Waltz 1979. 45 Hirschman 1970.
4 Haas 1964. 46 Ragin 2000, 120-145.
5 Young 1996; Abbott and Snidai 2003.
6 Young 1996; Mansfield and Reinhardt 2003.
References
7 Aggarwal and Spiegel 1997; Abbott and Snidai
1998; Aggarwal 1998; Aggarwal and Fogarty 2005. Abbott, Kenneth, and Duncan Snidai. 1998. Why states
8 Raustiala and Victor 2004. act through formal international organizations. Jour-
9 Amaral and Ottino 2004, 147-8. nal of Conflict Resolution 42 (1): 3-32.
10 Macy and Wilier 2002, 145-150.
11 Watts 2003. The Impact of International Law on Intern
12 Powers et al. 2007. Cooperation, ed. E. Benvenisti and M. Hir
13 Keck and Sikkink 1998; Zanini 2002; Slaughter bridge: Cambridge University Press.
2004; Pedahzur and Perliger 2006; Carpenter 2007; Aggarwal, Vinod K. 1998. Institutional Desig
Newman 2008. Complex World: Bargaining, Linkages and N
14 Gould 2003, 265. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
15 Axelrod 1984; Axelrod and Keohane 1986. Aggarwal, Vinod, and Edward Fogarty. 200
16 Axelrod 1997. of interregionalism: The EU and North A
17 Dooley and van de Ven 1999; Morel and Ramanu- Journal of European Integration 27 (3): 20.
jam 1999. Aggarwal, Vinod K., and Charles E. Morriso
18 Macy and Wilier 2002. Asia-Pacific Crossroads: Regime Creation and
19 Ibid., 146. ofAPEC
20 Aggarwal 1998. Aggarwal, Vinod K., and Mark M. Spiegel
21 The International Law Commission has working games: Strategic interaction in internation
groups and subcommittees that seek to overcome rescheduling. Journal of Economic Literatu
22 Perspectives on Politics
Jacobs, Alan, and Steven Teles. 2007. The perils of European Data Privacy Directive. International Orga-
market-making: The case of British pensions. In Creat- nization 62 (1): 103-30.
ing Competitive Markets: The Politics of Regulatory Pedahzur, Ami, and Arie Perliger. 2006. The changing
Reform, ed. M. K. Landy, M. A. Levin, and M. M. Sha- nature of suicide attacks - A social network perspec-
piro. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press. tive. Social Forces 84 (4): 1987-2008.
Janis, Irving Lester. 1972. Victims of Groupthink; A Pierson, Paul. 2004. Politics in Time: History, Institutions
Psychological Study of Foreign-Policy Decisions and and Social Analysis. Princeton: Princeton University
Fiascoes. Boston: Houghton. Press.
Jones, Bryan D., Graeme Boushey, and Samual Work- Powers, Kathy, Gary Goertz, John P. Willerton, and
man. 2006. Behavioral rationality and the policy Tatiana Vashchilko. 2007. "Treaty Nestedness and
processes: Toward a new model of organizational Complex Security Institutions" July 7, available at
information processing. In The Oxford Handbook of SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract = 1000241
Public Policy, éd. M. Moran, M. Rein, and R. E. Putnam, Robert. 1988. Diplomacy and domestic poli-
Goodin. Oxford: Oxford University Press. tics; the logic of two level games. International Orga-
Jupille, Joseph, and Duncan Snidai. 2006. "The Choice nization 42 (3): 427-60.
of International Institutions: Cooperation, Alterna- Ragin, Charles C. 2000. Fuzzy-Set Social Science. Chi-
tives and Strategies." July 7. Available at SSRN: cago: University of Chicago Press.
http://ssrn.com/abstract = 1 008945 Raustiala, Kal, and David Victor. 2004. The regime
Katzenstein, Peter J. 1985. Small States in World Mar- complex for plant genetic resources. International
kets: Industrial Policy in Europe. Cornell Studies in Organization 58 (2): 277-309.
Political Economy. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Sikkink, Kathryn. 2003. International law and social
Press. movements: Towards transformation - A typology of
Keck, Margaret E., and Kathryn Sikkink. 1998. Activists relations between social movements and international
beyond Borders: Advocacy Networks in International institutions. American Society of International Legal
Politics. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Proceedings 97 (2003): 301-05.
Kingsbury, Benedict. 1999. Is the proliferation of inter- Slaughter, Anne-Marie. 2004. A New World Order.
national courts and tribunals a systemic problem? Princeton: Princeton University Press.
New York University Journal of International Law and Snyder, Jack L., and Robert Jervis. 1993. Coping with
Politics 31: 679-96. Complexity in the International System. Pew Studies in
Macy, Michael W, and Robert Wilier. 2002. From Economics and Security. Boulder: Westview Press.
factors to actors: Computational sociology and agent- Uzzi, Brian. 1997a. Social structure and competition in
based modeling. Annual Review of Sociology 28: interfirm networks: The paradox of embeddedness.
143-66. Administrative Science Quarterly 42 (March): 35-67.
Madsen, Michael Rask. 2007. From Cold War instru-
ment to supreme European court: The European zational decline. International Journal of S
Court of Human Rights at the crossroads of inter- Social Policy 17 (7/8): 111-55.
national and national law and politics. Law & Social Walders, Lawrence W, and Neil C. Pratt. 20
Inquiry 32 (I): 137-59. remedy litigation - Choice of forum and
Mansfield, Edward, and Eric Reinhardt. 2003. Multilat- law. Saint Johns Journal of Legal Comment
eral determinants of regionalism: The effects of 51-74.
GATT/ WTO on the formation of preferential trad- Waltz, Kenneth N. 1979. Theory of Internat
ing arrangements. International Organization 57 (4): Reading, Mass.: Addison- Wesley Publishi
829-62. Watts, Duncan J. 2003. Six Degrees: The Sci
Morel, Benoit, and Rangaraj Ramanujam. 1999. Connected Acre. 1st ed. New York: Norton
Perspective - Through the looking glass of complex- Young, Oran. 1996. Institutional linkages in
ity: The dynamics of organizations as adaptive and national society: Polar perspectives. Global
evolving systems. Organization Science: A Journal of 2 (1): 1-24.
the Institute of Management Sciences 10 (3): 16. Zanini, Michele. 2002. Middle Eastern terro
Newman, Abraham. 2008. Building transnational civil netwar. Peace Research Abstracts 39 (2): 15
liberties: Transgovernmental entrepreneurs and the
24 Perspectives on Politics