Aminu 32 UNEMPLOYMENTANDOUTPUTDYNAMICSINNIGERIA
Aminu 32 UNEMPLOYMENTANDOUTPUTDYNAMICSINNIGERIA
net/publication/366824540
CITATION READS
1 199
3 authors, including:
Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:
All content following this page was uploaded by Aminu Umaru on 03 January 2023.
Abstract
This paper examines unemployment and output dynamic sin Nigeria through the use of unit root test,
cointegration and error correction techniques after which the ordinary least square technique was
employed. Data for the paper was data sourced from CBN statistical bulletin and National Bureau of
Statistics annual report for the period 1986-2014, the paper started by estimating the linear Okun’s
model using the transitory and permanent components of the unemployment and output series. Results
from the linear estimates suggest that the short-run relationship between output and unemployment is
negative particularly in agriculture, building, construction and trade, but that the long-run
relationship in all the sectors is positive. This result therefore supported the non-linearity hypothesis
in the dynamic relationship between unemployment and output. The paper therefore estimated a non-
linear Okun ‘s type model using the Generalised Method of Moments (GMM). The results confirmed
that the dynamic relationship between unemployment and output in Nigeria is non-linear and hump-
shaped. The threshold rate of unemployment was 16.76%, this implies that at unemployment rates
below the of 16.76%, the relationship is positive, and becomes negative at higher unemployment
rates. The paper therefore established that when unemployment rate is below the 16.76% threshold,
the economy experiences jobless growth. It was also found that output increases in the agriculture,
building, construction and trade sectors have the potential for employment generation but industrial
and service sectors all of which have no potential for employment generation. The paper therefore
recommended that policies that aim at raising output in these sectors would be more efficient in
reducing unemployment in Nigeria.
Key words: Unemployment, output, Okun’s law, dynamics, sectors
1.0 INTRODUCTION
Nigeria as a nation is endowed with huge human and natural resources. The country is richly
endowed with various mineral types all over the country. Huge amount of income is
generated annually from petroleum products. According to Musa (2010) more than 40 types
of solid minerals have been identified in over 500 locations in Nigeria. Despite Nigerian
huge human and natural resources the country remained largely underdeveloped. There are
numerous socio-economic challenges facing the country. The Nigerian economy has been
witnessing recovery which is immediately followed by recession and depression.
This situation in Nigeria is becoming disturbing. There are various macroeconomic policies
put in place by the government of Nigeria over the years but have been unable to achieve
sustained reduction in unemployment and sustained growth cannot be achieved. The poor
performance of the economy has engendered the need to manage the economy effectively.
The essence of macroeconomic management underlines the need for the existence of
government as a vital agent for economic development. However, it appears that government
intervention in Nigeria has not been able to solve the ills in the economy.
MAUTECH Journal of Economic Studies: Vol. 1 No. 1 2017 20
The perpetual economic crisis, with the attendant problems of high inflationary pressure, high
and unstable exchange rate, and high debt profile and deficit balance of payment is difficult
to explain. Against a high rate of unemployment and underutilization of resources, a large
public sector, low wages and poor working conditions, there has been an also persistent high
inflation rate in Nigeria. Also, unemployment and underemployment is prominent feature of
the Nigerian economy. Consequently, this undermines the full potentials of labour-surplus
economy where the labour surpluses have not been fully exploited.
Nigerian economy provided jobs for most Nigerian and absorbed a considerable number of
imported labour in the 1960s and early 1970s. The wage rate in the country compared
favourably with international standards and there was relative industrial stability in most of
the years. With the oil boom of the late 1970s, coupled with mass migration of people,
especially the active population (youth), to the urban centers seeking for white cola jobs.
Following the economic downturn in the early 1980s, the problems of unemployment
increased, this precipitated the introduction of the Structural Adjustment Programme (SAP).
The rapid depreciation of the naira exchange rate since 1986 and the inability of most
industries to obtain adequate raw materials required to sustain their output levels fuelled
inflation. There was rapid depreciation of the naira this situation caused sharp rise in the
general price level, leading to a considerable decline in real wages and increased poverty. The
low wages contributed to a weakening of the purchasing power of wage earners and declining
aggregate demand. Consequently, industries started to accumulate unintended inventories.
The growth of the Nigerian economy has been poor since the introduction of SAP (Structural
Adjustment Programme) in 1986. The continuous economic crisis reflected in high rates of
unemployment, high inflation rates, high level of corruption, exchange rates distortions, debt
overhang, to mention a few. Unemployment as a phenomena had eaten deep into the fabric of
the Nigerian economy over the years.
The trends in unemployment and output growth rates in Nigeria from 1986-2014 have been
puzzling. The data obtained from the Central Bank of Nigeria (CBN), 2014 Statistical
bulletin revealed that by 1986 economic growth rate stood at 3.1 percent, in 1987 the value
became negative -0.69 implying retrogression and was the least ever achieved for the period
under review; the highest economic growth rates achieved was 11.36 in 1990 after which the
rates had been abysmally lower until in 2003 when the growth rates hits 10.2 percent; from
2003 economic growth rate has been less than 10 percent, in 2012 the growth rate recorded
was 6.58. The trend in economic growth has been fluctuating over the years under review.
The trends in unemployment in Nigeria from 1986-2014 was also puzzling. The trend
revealed that by 1986 unemployment rate was 5.3 percent.
Based on the CBN data output and unemployment grow simultaneously over the years which
revealed that there is evidence of jobless growth in Nigeria. It is assumed theoretically that
when output is growing unemployment will reduce as well and if unemployment is increasing
output level will reduce. But this is not the case in Nigeria because as unemployment
increases output level also increases (Aminu, Manu & Salihu (2013). This study seeks to
examine the causes of such anti-theoretical behavior in Nigeria with the aim of finding
solution to the problem.
Studies conducted by (Garba, 2010, and Olowononi and Audu (2012), had examined the
nature and causes of unemployment in Nigeria and found disturbing trends. There are very
few studies which have been undertaken regarding unemployment and output dynamics in
MAUTECH Journal of Economic Studies: Vol. 1 No. 1 2017 21
Nigeria. Some of the existing studies employed descriptive statistics (see Olowononi and
Audu, 2012). Aminu and Anono, (2012), Bakare, (2012) and Rafindadi, (2012) conducted
similar studies and their findings were controversial especially in the area of the impact of
unemployment on the economic growth in Nigerian. A study conducted by Bakare (2012)
found negative relationship between unemployment and growth, Rafindadi (2012) also found
negative non-linear relationship between unemployment and output growth, Another study
was also conducted in the same vein in China by Chang-Shuai Li and ZI-Juan Liu (2012) on
unemployment rate, economic growth and inflation. The results revealed that unemployment
impacted negatively on growth while inflation impacted positively on growth in China. while
Aminu, Manu and Salihu (2013) found positive relationship between unemployment and
economic growth in Nigeria. The puzzling trends of economic growth rate and
unemployment rate in Nigeria and the controversial results obtained in the empirical results
provide the need to examine the relationship between unemployment and output in Nigeria.
According to Jhingan (2001) Economists distinguish between various types and theories of
unemployment; they include cyclical or Keynesian unemployment, frictional unemployment,
structural unemployment and classical unemployment. Some additional types of
unemployment that are occasionally mentioned are seasonal unemployment, hardcore
unemployment, and hidden unemployment; The U.S. Bureau for Labour Statistics measures
six types of unemployment. Though there were several definitions of voluntary and
involuntary unemployment in the economics literature. According Todaro (1992) Voluntary
unemployment was attributed to the individual’s decisions. Involuntary unemployment exists
because of the socio-economic environment (including the market structure, government
intervention, and the level of aggregate demand) in which individuals operate. In these terms,
most of frictional unemployment is voluntary, since it reflects individual search behaviour.
Voluntary unemployment includes workers who reject low wage jobs which is common in
Nigeria whereas involuntary unemployment includes workers fired due to an economic crisis,
industrial decline, company bankruptcy, or organizational restructuring. On the other hand,
cyclical, structural and classical unemployment are largely involuntary in nature. However,
the existence of structural unemployment may reflects choices made by the unemployed in
the past, while classical (natural) unemployment may result from the legislative and
economic choices made by labour unions or political parties.
According to Jhingan (2001) Frictional unemployment is the time period between jobs when
a worker is searching for or transitioning from one job to another. It is sometimes called
search unemployment and can be voluntary based on the circumstances of the unemployed
individual. Frictional unemployment is always present in an economy, so the level of
involuntary unemployment is properly the unemployment rate minus the rate of frictional
unemployment, which means that increases or decreases in unemployment are normally
under-represented in the simple statistics.
Structural unemployment occurs when a labour market is unable to provide jobs for everyone
who wants one because there is a mismatch between the skills of the unemployed workers
and the skills needed for the available jobs. Structural unemployment is hard to separate
empirically from frictional unemployment, except to say that it lasts longer.
He said that hidden or covered unemployment is the unemployment of potential workers that
is not reflected in official unemployment statistics, due to the way the statistics are collected.
In many countries only those who have no work but are actively looking for work (and
qualifying for social security benefits) are counted as unemployed.
Secondly, firms in countries that have stronger labour market regulations or strong unions
would find it difficult to lay-off workers in the face of transitory fall in output. Output in this
case will be more volatile than unemployment, and such countries will tend to have larger
Okun’s coefficient. In general therefore, the greater the labour market flexibility, the smaller
the Okun’s coefficient will be. The size of this coefficient would vary over time because the
relationship between output and unemployment depends on laws, technology, demographics
and preferences (see Blanchard, 2006).
Malley and Molana (2007) stated that from State zero, when unemployment rate rises in the
economy, either because of the efficiency wage premium giving to workers, or due to fear of
losing their jobs, workers will begin to raise their productivity by putting more effort, this
will lead to increase in output in the face of rising unemployment. To them if the net increase
in output as a result of increase in per-worker efficiency is greater than the output loss due to
the rising unemployment, then increase in output will be attributed to rising unemployment.
MAUTECH Journal of Economic Studies: Vol. 1 No. 1 2017 23
This is possible because as output decreases firms will disengage the least efficient workers,
therefore, output loss may be less than output gains as a result of increase in workers
efficiency. Finally, Malley and Molana (2007) concluded the link between unemployment
and output negative.
However some studies found positive relationship between unemployment and output
especially in Nigeria. Studies such as Arewa and Nwankanma (2013) investigated the
potential real GDP relationship and growth process of Nigerian economy: An empirical re-
evaluation of Okun’s law. They used VAR mechanism and found a positive relationship
between output gab and unemployment gab in Nigeria. Another study by Aminu, Manu and
Salihu (2013) investigated the impact of unemployment and inflation on economic growth in
Nigeria. They used OLS, Augmented Dickey-Fuller technique, Granger causality and
Johansen cointegration technique and found that both unemployment and inflation affected
economic growth positively in Nigeria. In the same vein Mahmoud (2013) conducted a study
on the impact of inflation and unemployment on Jordanian GDP. He employed simple
correlation coefficient and ANOVA and found that inflation impacted positively on Jordanian
GDP, while unemployment impacted negatively on Jordanian GDP. This controversy may be
attributed to the dominant manifestation of unemployment in Nigeria.
3.0 Methodology
This paper used multi-dimensional econometric procedure in estimating the effect of
unemployment and output dynamics in Nigeria. The Ordinary Least Squares (OLS)
techniques, and double log were employed to obtain the coefficients of the equation, the
double log technique was used in estimating the elasticities of various sectors on
unemployment, Augmented Dickey-Fuller tests was employed to test the unit root properties
of the series, after which Johansen cointegration test was employed to test the presence of
long-run relationship between output of various sectors of the Nigerian economy and
unemployment.
Models specification
This paper adopted model of growth by Aminu and Anono (2012) and incorporate
unemployment. The models estimated were specified as follows:-
MAUTECH Journal of Economic Studies: Vol. 1 No. 1 2017 24
LINEAR FORM
Model I: Response of unemployment to Aggregate GDP (Jobless growth)
UN = f(RGDP) ------------------------------------------------------------------------------------ (1)
Where RGDP is the gross domestic product and UN is unemployment rate. The model was
specified as follows
UN = α0+ α1RGDP + µ1 ------------------------------------------------------------------------ (2)
A piori expectation
It is expected that α0> 0 and α1< 0.
Decision Rule: The null hypothesis ϕ = 1, i.e. a unit root exist in RGDP, UN, AGR, IND,
BUC, SER and TRA (RGDP, UN, AGR, IND, BUC, SER and TRA are non-stationary) but
MAUTECH Journal of Economic Studies: Vol. 1 No. 1 2017 25
when ϕ < 1, i.e. a unit root does not exist in RGDP, UN, AGR, IND, BUC, SER and TRA
(RGDP, UN, AGR, IND, BUC, SER and TRA are stationary) . The decision rule as to
whether to accept the null hypothesis or not is that ADF statistics should be less than critical
t-value at certain percent level, and hence unit root exist; but if ADF statistics is greater than
the critical t-value at certain percent, then the null hypothesis is reject, hence, there is no unit
root and RGDP is stationary. This is similar to all the variables of the model.
Observations 29 29 29 29 29 29
Source: E-views 7
Table 4.1 shows that unemployment, agricultural output, industrial output, contribution of
building and construction to GDP, output of service sector and output of trade and commerce
in Nigerian were normally distributed as indicated by their Jarque-Bera values of 2.940489,
2.384860, 2.467022, 1.125142, 1.036651, and 1.673141 respectively and the probability
values of 0.229869, 0.303483, 0.291268, 0.569742, 0.595517 and 0.433194 respectively. The
null hypothesis that the data is normally distributed is accepted at 5 per cent significant level.
This implies that the data can be use for estimation.
Table 4.4: Estimates of the Linear Model and the Okun’s Law Coefficients for the
Various Sectors
∆𝑼𝒕 = 𝑪 + 𝜷∆𝑮𝑫𝑷𝒕 + 𝜺𝒕 Short-Run Long-Run
Okun’s Law Okun’s Law
Sectoral Output C 𝜷 Coefficient C 𝜷 Coefficient
(𝟏⁄𝜷) 𝟏⁄ )
𝜷
0.37 0.94 0.36 -0.01 -
RGDP 1.06 100
Agricultural 0.37 -0.51 -1.96 0.04 -0.01 -100
Industrial 0.37 0.64 1.56 0.15 -0.05 -20
Building and Constr 0.37 -1.86 -0.54 0.06 -0.02 -50
Services 0.37 1.01 0.99 0.13 -0.04 -25
Wholesale and Retail 0.37 -0.80 0.10 -0.03 -
-1.25 33.33
4.4. Relative Response of Unemployment to Sectoral Output
The estimated the linear model (Equation 3) using the permanent and transitory components
of sectoral output (Table 4.4). This allows us to, first, compare the relative employment
potential of the five sectors and, second, compare the short-run (columns 2-4) and long-run
(columns 5-7) behaviours of unemployment in response of output changes. Estimates of the
Okun’s Coefficient for the five sectors of the economy are also reported.
From Table 4.4, it can be observed that the short-run relationship between unemployment and
some sectoral output such as agricultural output, building and construction and trade and
commerce is negative, consistent with the theoretical expectation but the relationship between
unemployment and industrial output and service sector is positive and inconsistent with
theoretical expectation. This result implies that agricultural sector, building and construction
and trade and commerce are the only sector having the potential of reducing unemployment
in Nigeria while industrial sector and service sector have no potential for reducing
unemployment in Nigeria. The long-run relationship between unemployment and various
sectors of the Nigerian economy is however negative and consistent with theoretical
expectation. This paper revealed that in the long run all the five sectors of the Nigerian
economy have potential for reducing unemployment in Nigeria.
In terms of relative employment potential, larger β’s measure the elasticity of unemployment
with respect to respective sectoral output. In the short-run, the building and construction
appears to have greater unemployment-reducing potential follow by wholesale and retail
trade and the least employment- generating sector appears to be agriculture which is
attributed to the neglect of the sector and shifting to industrial and service that have no
potential for reducing unemployment in the country. The F-statistics value of 22.25767,
which measured the joint significance of the parameter estimates, was found statistically
significant at 1 per cent level as indicated by the corresponding probability value of
0.000000. This implies that all the variables of the model were statistically jointly and
significantly affected unemployment rate in Nigeria.
The R2 value of 0.8586 (85.86%) implied that 85.86per cent total variation in unemployment
is explained by the output of various sectors of the Nigerian economy. This indicated that
unemployment was significantly explained by the included variables and the model is fit in
explaining the relationship between the variables under consideration. Coincidently, the
goodness of fit of the regression remained very high after adjusting for the degree of freedom
as indicated by the adjusted R2 (R2 =0.8200 or 82.00%). The Durbin-Watson statistic 1.5078
in appendix i was observed to be higher than R2 0.8586 indicating that the model is non-
spurious (meaningful) therefore, it can be used for policy purpose. The Durbin-Watson
MAUTECH Journal of Economic Studies: Vol. 1 No. 1 2017 28
statistics 1.5078 shows that there was negligible presence of autocorrelation among the error
value because the value is tending toward 2.
This finding appears to contradict the general impression that agriculture and service sectors
have greater potential to generate employment than other sectors (e.g., Njoku 2011) and
(Rafindadi 2012) respectively. The present study shows that building and construction has the
relatively greater potential for reducing unemployment in Nigeria.
The implication of this finding is that if the agricultural, building and construction and
wholesale and retail trade were the main drivers of growth, the potential of jobless-growth
will be reduced.
The result above revealed that all the coefficients of the model have the expected signs and
are statistically significant as indicated by probability value of F-statistics of 0.0174. The J-
statistic for Hansen’s was used to test for validity of the overriding restriction and the
probability of j-statistic = 0.00000 suggested that the restrictions are valid at 5 per cent level
of significant.
The results therefore suggest that as output rises, unemployment will initially rise until a
certain threshold level of unemployment is reached when unemployment will begin to fall.
This evidence is also consistent with our earlier results from the linear model, which suggest
that the correlation between the long-run (permanent components of) output and
unemployment is positive, while the short-run correlation is negative. This is because, in the
long-run, unemployment is likely to be low as the economy is close to full employment. As
unemployment rises from such low levels, workers supply of higher effort will raise
productivity and the resultant output gain due to efficiency could be sufficiently large to
dominate the fall in output as a result of lay-offs.
The threshold level of unemployment below which the relationship is positive is calculated as
(see Malley and Molana, 2007):
𝛽 0.5968
U0= - 2𝛽1 = - 2(−0.0178) = 16.76
2
The result above shows the threshold rate of unemployment at which the relationship
between unemployment and output switches from positive to negative is about 16.76%. It is
the rate of unemployment below which the Okun’s law does not hold, but above which the
Okun’s law holds. This rate is close enough to the 10.59% found from the linear models of
the short-run and long-run relationship. The threshold range is therefore 10.59% - 16.76%
unemployment rate.
4.5 Dynamics Analysis using variance decomposition and impulse response
Impulse response function shows the effects of shocks on the adjustment path of the
variables. Forecast error variance decompositions measure the contribution of each type of
shock to the forecast error variance. Both computations are useful in assessing how shocks to
economic variables reverberate through a system.
MAUTECH Journal of Economic Studies: Vol. 1 No. 1 2017 29
Appendix iii shows the variance decomposition of all the variables of the model.
Unemployment responses 100 per cent to shock in itself but the response of other variables to
shock in unemployment is not significant and die out immediately. Unemployment response
more to shock in industrial sector follow by agricultural sector, service sector, trade and
commerce and lastly building and construction. The response of unemployment to shock in
agricultural sector is almost 27 per cent, to industrial sector is almost 32 per cent, to service
sector is almost 27 per cent, to shock in trade is almost 24 percent but to shock in building
and construction is almost 11 per cent. This implies that unemployment response more to
shock in itself follow by industrial sector.
REFERENCES
Adofu, I. (2010), ‘‘Accelerating Economic Growth in Nigeria, The role of Foreign Direct
Investment’’.Current Research Journal of Economic Theory.2(1),11-15.
Amin, A.A. (1998). Cameroon’s Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth.African Economic
Research Consortium’s Research Paper 85, Nairobi (November).
Aminu, U. and Anono, A.Z. (2012).An empirical Analysis of The Relationship between
Unemployment and Inflation in Nigeria from 1977-2009.Business Journal,
Economics and Review, Global Research Society. Pakistan. 1 (12), 42-61.
Aminu, U. and Manu, D. and Salihu, M. (2013). An Empirical Investigation into the Effect
of Unemployment and Inflation on the Growth in Nigerian.Interdisplinary Journal of
Research in Business. 2(12)
Arewa, A. and Nwakanma, P.C. (2013) Potential-Real GDP relationship and Growth process
of Nigerian Economy: An Enpirical Re-evaluation of Okun’s Law. European
Scientific Journal. 8(9) 25-33
Ayesha, W. and K. Rukhsana (2010) ‘‘The Impact of Inflation and Economic Growth on
Unemployment’’: Time series Evidence from Pakistan.Proceedings of 3rd
international Conference on Business Management (ISBN: 978-969-9368-07-3).
Bakare, A.S. (2012) Stabilization policy, Unemployment Crises and Economic Growth in
Nigeria.Universal Journal of Management and Social Sciences.2(4).
Balami, D.H (2006). Macroeconomic Theory and Practice.Salawe prints, Off Leventies,
Wulari, Maiduguri.
Brian, S. and V.R. Howard (2005) Modern Macroeconomic, Its Origins, Development and
Current State.Edward Elgar Publishing Limited. UK.
Chang-shuai, L. and .Zi-juan, L. (2012) The relationship among Chinese unemployment rate,
Economic growth and Inflation.Advances in Applied Economics and Finance, Vol.1,
No.1.World science Publishers.United states.
Dickey, D.A. and W.A. Fuller (1979), “Distribution of the Estimators for Autoregressive
Time Series with a Unit Root,” Journal of the American Statistical Association, 74,
427-431
Ekpo, A.H. (1995) ‘‘Public Expenditure and Economic Growth in Nigeria,1960-1992.’’ Final
Report, AERC, Nairobi, Kenya.
Engle, R.F. and C.W.J. Granger (1987), “ Cointegration and Error Correction:
Representation, Estimation and Testing,”Econometrica, 55, 251-276
Evans, P. and Karas, G. (1994) ‘‘Are Government Activities Productive? Evidence from a
Pannel of U.S States.’’The Review of Economic and Statistics LXXVI (1), February.
Faraji, K. and Kenani, M. (2011) ‘‘Impact of Inflation on Economic Growth: A Case study of
Tanzania’’.Asian Journal of Empirical Research, 3 (4):363-380.
Innocent, C.O., Nkechinyere, C.U., Ebele, N.and Geraldine, N. (2012), ‘‘Economic Growth
and Foreign Direct Investment in Nigeria: An Empirical Investigation. Journal of
Economics and Sustainable Development.ISSN : 2222-1700, 3(13). International
Labour Organization (ILO, 2001), Labour Statistics Yearbook, Geneva.
Jhingan, M. L. (2001) Advanced Economic Theory (11th Ed). Delhi: Vrinda Publications (P)
LTD.
Jhingan, M.L. (2002) Monetary Economics, 5th Revised and Enlarged, (Ed); Delhi: Vrinda
Publications (P) Ltd.
Joao, R.F. and Francisco, F.G. (2001), Does High Inflation Affect Growth in the Long and
Short Run?.Journal of Applied Economics, 4(1), 89-105
Krugman, P. (2009) “Growth and Unemployment in the USA” The New York Times,
2009/08/01
Lindbeck, A. (1992), Macroeconomic Theory and the Labour Market, European Economic
1eview, 36, 209-235
MAUTECH Journal of Economic Studies: Vol. 1 No. 1 2017 32
Malley, J. and H. Molana (2007) The Relationship between Output and Unemployment with
Efficiency Wages. German Economic Review, Vereinfur Social politik, vol. 8, pages
561-577
Munnell, A.H. (1990) ‘‘Why Has Productivity Growth Declined?Productivity and Public
Investment.’’New England Economic Review (January/March).
Ndiyo, N.A. and Ebong, F.S. (2003), ‘‘The Challenges of Openness in Developing
Economics: Some Empirical Lessons From Nigeria’’, NES 2003, Annual Conference.
Njoku, A. and. Ihgba, O. A. (2011) “Unemployment and Nigerian Economic Growth (1985-
2009)” Proceedings of the 2011 International Conference on Teaching, Learning and
Change International Association for Teaching and Learning (IATEL).
Odusola, F.A. (1996). ‘‘Military Expenditure and Economic Growth’’ The Nigerian Journal
of Economic and Social Studies 38 (1,2 and 3).
Olowononi, G.D. and Audu, I. (2012) ‘‘Unemployment, National security and sustainable
Development in Nigeria’’.Being a paper presented at ABU 50 Humanities
International Conference on National security, Integration and sustainable
Development in Nigeria Assembly Hall, ABU, Zaria, 19th- 20th November, 2012.
Omeke, P.C. and Ugwunyi, C.U. (2010) Money, Price and Output: A Causality Test for
Nigeria. American Journal of Scientific Research ISSN 1456-223X, Issue 8, pp.78-87.
Euro Journals Publishing, Inc.
Okun, Arthur M. (1962) Potential GNP: Its Measurement and Significance. Proceedings of
the Business and Economics Section of the American Statistical Association,
Washington, DC: American Statistical Association, pp 98-104.
Popovic, G. and Popovic, J. (2009) Inflation and Unemployment in the EU: Comparative
Analysis of Phillips Regularity. UDK 336.748.12, 331.56
Ratner, J.B. (1983). ‘‘Government Capital and the Production Function for US Private
Output.’’ Economic Letters 13.
Romer, C.D. (1996), ‘‘Changes in Business Cycles: Evidence and Explanations’’, Journal of
Economic Perspectives, Spring.
Sawtelle, B. (2007). ‘Analyzing the Link between Real GDP and Employment: An Industry
Sector Approach.”Business Economics 42(4): 46-54.
Solow, R.M. (2002) “Neoclassical Growth model” in B.Snowdon and H.R Vane (eds);An
Encyclopedia of macroeconomics, Cheltenham, UK and Northampton, MA, USA:
Edward Elgar.
Stock, J.H and Watson, M.W. (1999), ‘‘Forecasting Inflation’ ’National Bureau of Economic
Research NBER Working Paper 7023, March.
Todaro, M. (1992) Economics for a Developing World 2nd Ed. England: Longman Group,
U.K. Limited.
Vikesh, G. and Subrina, H. (2004) ‘‘Relationship Between Inflation and Economic Growth’’.
Working Paper, Reserve Bank of Fiji.Suva Fiji.
APPENDICES
Appendix i :Cointegration test results
Sample (adjusted): 1988 2014
Included observations: 27 after adjustments
Trend assumption: Linear deterministic trend
Series: UN AGR IND BUC SER TRA
Lags interval (in first differences): 1 to 1
(0.01602)
0.000000 0.000000 1.000000 0.000000 0.000000 -0.831590
(0.01818)
0.000000 0.000000 0.000000 1.000000 0.000000 -0.907723
(0.02262)
0.000000 0.000000 0.000000 0.000000 1.000000 -1.024309
(0.03286)
Adjustment coefficients (standard error in parentheses)
D(UN) -0.745123 2.135682 -0.648766 0.496723 1.186908
(0.23192) (0.67618) (0.45679) (1.00609) (1.12838)
D(AGR) -0.112437 -0.290782 -0.025389 0.616957 -0.023797
(0.07772) (0.22661) (0.15308) (0.33717) (0.37815)
D(IND) -0.280638 1.001899 -1.682275 0.862178 0.303644
(0.21016) (0.61273) (0.41393) (0.91169) (1.02251)
D(BUC) 0.385395 -0.273830 -0.480458 2.198975 -3.090874
(0.21785) (0.63514) (0.42907) (0.94503) (1.05990)
D(SER) 0.493723 0.292272 -0.931516 3.934077 -4.816950
(0.27201) (0.79306) (0.53575) (1.18000) (1.32344)
D(TRA) 0.159600 0.098801 -0.407220 2.391948 -2.217428
(0.10409) (0.30348) (0.20502) (0.45155) (0.50644)
Varia
nce
Deco
mposi
tion of
UN:
Perio
d S.E. UN AGR IND BUC SER TRA
Varia
nce
Deco
mposi
tion of
AGR:
Perio
d S.E. UN AGR IND BUC SER TRA
MAUTECH Journal of Economic Studies: Vol. 1 No. 1 2017 38
Varia
nce
Deco
mposi
tion of
IND:
Perio
d S.E. UN AGR IND BUC SER TRA
Varia
nce
Deco
mposi
tion of
BUC:
Perio
d S.E. UN AGR IND BUC SER TRA
Varia
nce
Deco
mposi
tion of
SER:
Perio
d S.E. UN AGR IND BUC SER TRA
Varia
nce
Deco
mposi
tion of
TRA:
Perio
d S.E. UN AGR IND BUC SER TRA
Chole
sky
Orderi
ng:
UN
AGR
IND
BUC
SER
TRA
MAUTECH Journal of Economic Studies: Vol. 1 No. 1 2017 40
IMPULSE RESPONSE
Resp
onse
of
UN:
Perio
d UN AGR IND BUC SER TRA
Resp
onse
of
AGR:
Perio
d UN AGR IND BUC SER TRA
Resp
onse
of
IND:
Perio
d UN AGR IND BUC SER TRA
Resp
onse
of
BUC:
Perio
d UN AGR IND BUC SER TRA
Resp
onse
of
SER:
Perio
d UN AGR IND BUC SER TRA
Resp
onse
of
TRA:
Perio
d UN AGR IND BUC SER TRA
Chole
sky
Orderi
ng:
UN
AGR
IND
BUC
SER
TRA