Gunitskiy Columbia 0054D 10116
Gunitskiy Columbia 0054D 10116
Vsevolod Gunitskiy
COLUMBIA UNIVERSITY
2011
© 2011
Vsevolod Gunitskiy
All rights reserved
ABSTRACT
What causes democratic waves? This dissertation argues that sudden shifts in the
distribution of power among major states can help explain the wave-like spread of
democracy over the past century. These hegemonic shocks lead to bursts of regime
change by creating unique incentives and opportunities for domestic reforms, and
imposition, enable rising great powers to expand networks of trade and patronage,
I find strong statistical support for the idea that shifts in hegemonic power have
World War I, the Great Depression, and World War II. The First World War
effectiveness to rulers on the battlefield and the factory floor, creating new states on
the ruins of autocratic empires, and increasing the organizational power of women
and working-class men. The wave also sowed the seeds of its own demise as rulers
welcomed the reforms dissolved as the crisis passed. The economic rise of Nazi
Germany and the crisis of liberal capitalism in the Great Depression inaugurated a
fascist wave in the 1930s. In this period, fascist institutions penetrated the
the structure of modern democratic regimes. Growing fascist power and influence
at the outset of World War II. The outcome of that war produced not one but two
rising great powers, the United States and the Soviet Union. Reflecting this duality,
the war’s aftermath witnessed two distinct waves of institutional reforms that
embodied the competing visions offered by the two superpowers. Despite the
and emulation (by outsiders impressed with the self-evident success of the two
systems).
reforms, this dissertation argues that regime success in the twentieth century is
deeply tied to rapid changes in the global distribution of power, a relationship often
List of Figures…………………...………………………………………………………..ii
List of Tables……………………………………….…………………………….………iii
Acknowledgments….……………………...…………………....…………..…….……iv
Chapter 1
Introduction: A Century of Shocks and Waves……………………………………..…1
Chapter 2
Testing the Effects of Hegemonic Power…………………………………………..…57
Chapter 3
The Alchemy of War: A Case Study of World War One………………………..…112
Chapter 4
A Low Dishonest Decade: A Case Study of the Great Depression………………..181
Chapter 5
Two Ways of Life: A Case Study of World War Two………………………………301
Chapter 6
Conclusion: Beyond the Great Plateau…………………………………………...…373
Bibliography…….…………………………………………………………………..…383
i
LIST OF FIGURES
ii
LIST OF TABLES
iii
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
Thanks must go first of all to my advising committee – Jack Snyder, Ken Waltz, and
Tanisha Fazal. Jack Snyder has overseen this project from the very beginning; his
the dissertation along the way. Ken Waltz has been an enormous influence on my
views about theory in international relations, and that influence suffuses these
pages in ways that citations cannot capture. The clarity and richness of his work
sets a standard for all scholars of political science. Tanisha Fazal has been
knowledge of statistical procedures. Between the three of them they have provided
place to write this dissertation. Valuable conversations with Richard Betts, Virginia
Page Fortna, Robert Jervis, and Pablo Pinto helped me to frame and augment the
arguments. Without their help and the generosity of my advisors this work would
not be possible. Since debt, as Disraeli warned, is the prolific mother of folly, I
hasten to claim sole credit for the shortcomings, weaknesses, and omissions found
in these pages.
iv
This project owes an intellectual debt to Samuel Huntington. A disagreement
of his work on the Third Wave, the high quality and originality of his scholarship
ensured that these disagreements always produced fruitful points of departure and
Political Science Association, the American Political Science Association, and the
University of Texas at Austin and Jim Mahon at Williams College offered extremely
its completion almost as much as I have. Her support has been responsible for
much more than these pages, and no dedication can adequately capture the value
of that support.
v
"The winds and waves are always on the side
of the ablest navigators."
Edward Gibbon, 1776
vi
Sources:
Edward Gibbon (1776) Decline and Fall of the Roman Empire, Chap. 68
Oswald Spengler (1932), Man and Technics, London: Allen and Unwin, p.37
Samuel Huntington (1982) “American Ideals versus American Institutions” Political
Science Quarterly 97.1:1-37
vii
1
CHAPTER 1
The rise and decline of democracy over the past century has been marked by
turbulent bursts of reform that swept across many countries in a relatively short
great upheaval, not steady and gradual change, have been the hallmark of
1
Lucretius, De Rerum Natura, 50 B.C.E
2
Quoted in Isiah Berlin (1958/69) Four Essays on Liberty, p.1
3
Trevor Kletz (1993) Lessons from Disaster: How Organizations Have no Memory
and Accidents Recur, Gulf Professional Publishing, p. 70
4
Samuel Huntington (1991) The Third Wave: Democratization in the Late
Twentieth Century, University of Oklahoma Press
2
the international system. While many explanations for democracy have looked at
domestic factors like economic growth, civil society, and class relations, I argue
that the real push for democracy comes from volatility in the international system.
My central thesis is that periods of sudden rise and decline of great powers create
shocks” have a crucial and often-ignored effect on the spread and retreat of
democratic reforms, and can explain the waves of democratization that have
waves has often been noted, but not easily explained. Huntington himself did not
seek to provide a theory of democratic waves, but only to describe what he thought
were the varied causes of the last bout of reforms. As he wrote in the introduction,
the book was “an explanatory, not a theoretical, work.”5 Though the argument is
“enticing in its scope and seductive in its pretense,” one scholar noted, “its
outlines specific causal mechanisms that lead to their appearance, and tests the
argument using both statistical analysis and case studies of the first three
5
Huntington 1991:xiv
6
Gerardo L. Munck (1994) “Review: Democratic Transitions in Comparative
Perspective” Comparative Politics 26.3, p. 357
3
hegemonic shocks of the twentieth century – World War I, the Great Depression,
and World War II. The puzzle I seek to answer is: what explains the causes of
in space and time? (See Figures 1.1 and 1.2) For that matter, why do regime
transitions of all types seem to occur in waves, including communism and fascism?
(Figures 1.3 and 1.4) And finally, why do the reforms associated with democratic
the spread of democracy is charted over time. Figure 1.1 (following page) tracks the
average annual level of democracy between 1900 and 2000.7 As the graph shows,
democratic peaks following the two World Wars and the Soviet collapse.
7
Measured as an average of the Polity IV index of democracy and SIP, the Scalar
Index of Politics, combines the executive restraint components of the Polity IV
score with Vanhannen’s measure of popular participation See Scott Gates, Håvard
Hegre, Mark P. Jones, and Håvard Strand (2006) “Institutional Inconsistency and
Political Instability: Polity Duration, 1800-2000” American Journal of Political
Science 50.4:893-908
4
The two major alternatives to democracy in the twentieth century – fascism and
communism – have also spread and retreated in wave-like patterns. A fascist wave
swept Europe in the 1930s, and a wave of Communist transitions followed the
5
Soviet victory in World War II. Although non-democratic regimes lack well-
developed quantitative indices like Polity, the global spread of fascism and
8
See Appendix 1 in Chapter 2 for classifications of fascist and communist regimes.
The share of power was calculated using the Composite Index of National
Capabilities, or CINC, discussed in Chapter 2.
6
Examining the causes of these waves is essential not only for understanding
how democracy spreads, but also for judging the efficacy of external regime
promotion pursued by the United States and other great powers. Much of U.S.
policy during the Cold War was guided by the fear of a Communist wave that
would begin in Asia and eventually wash up on the shores of California. More
recently, the 2003 invasion of Iraq by the U.S. and its allies was sparked at least in
part by the Bush Administration’s belief in their ability to spark democratic waves
through forced regime change.9 When domestic reforms are embedded in the
domestic actors inside any single country. Policies that attempt to influence
This dissertation makes three related arguments about the causes of institutional
waves. First, I argue that abrupt hegemonic transitions in the international system –
that is, the sudden rise and decline of dominant countries – create unique
incentives and opportunities for waves of domestic reforms. These critical junctures
9
As George Bush said in a speech several months after the fall of Baghdad. “Iraqi
democracy will succeed – and that success wills send forth the news, from
Damascus to Tehran – that freedom can be the future of every nation…The
establishment of a free Iraq at the heart of the Middle East will be a watershed
event in the global democratic revolution.” President’s remarks at the 20th
Anniversary of the National Endowment for Democracy, United States Chamber of
Commerce, Washington DC, November 6, 2003.
7
not only alter the hierarchy of great powers, but also shape the evolution of
domestic regimes. Namely, a sudden shift in the distribution of relative power that
favors a particular hegemon creates a wave of domestic reforms that reproduce the
institutional features of that hegemon’s regime. The outcomes of these shocks have
that have little direct contact with the great powers themselves. I find powerful
support for this idea in both large-n statistical analysis and detailed case studies of
have defined the past century are the products of these geopolitical cataclysms.
Second, the paper outlines three causal mechanisms through which hegemonic
shocks create waves of domestic reforms. First, hegemonic shocks create temporary
example, the Communist wave in eastern Europe in the late 1940s would not have
been possible without a Soviet victory in the Second World War, accompanied by
the country’s rapid increase in relative power on the European continent. Second,
hegemonic shocks allow rising hegemons to expand their networks of trade and
the shock will be diminished in their ability to exercise influence beyond their
national borders. The Soviet collapse, for example, disrupted patronage networks in
many African states in the mid-1990s, leading their citizens to question the
legitimacy of their rulers. “The wind from the east,” said Gabon’s ruler Omar
8
Bongo in 1990, “are shaking the coconut trees in Africa.”10 Shocks thus create
of coalitions within many countries at once, even in those countries not directly
affected by the shock. Third, hegemonic shocks reveal information about relative
better under duress, shocks legitimize certain regimes and make them more
to a hegemonic shock will find their regimes discredited and abandoned by former
demands inoculation.
Because hegemonic competition is a game of relative gains and losses, the rise
Through the mechanisms described above, the rising hegemons are able to impose
their regimes on others through brute force, to influence the institutional choices of
these states more indirectly through patronage and trade, or to simply sit back and
watch the imitators climb onto the bandwagon. The declining hegemons,
capacity to coerce erodes, their ability to influence and maintain allies through
trade and patronage declines, and the legitimacy of their regime as a model of
10
Quoted in Eric S. Packham (2004) Africa in War and Peace, Nova Publishers, p.
209
9
A third set of arguments examines why so many democratic reforms that take
place within these waves fail to consolidate, creating anti-democratic rollbacks. All
catastrophic reversal after 1918, a severe one after 1945, and a partial but
persistent one after 1991. The reasons for these failed consolidations, I argue, stems
from the dynamics that create the wave in the first place. The outcome of a shock
in which a democratic hegemon emerges triumphant – as was the case with the
United States in the three cases above – creates extremely strong but temporary
incentives for democratization, including within states that would not have made
such a transition otherwise. These states adopt democratic institutions despite the
cooperation, and past experience with democratic “rules of the game”. New elites,
moment of crisis dissolve as the crisis fades away. Like a victorious international
alliance that disintegrates once its purpose has been served, these domestic
coalitions struggle to hold together after the initial post-shock period – as was the
case, for example, in Germany after 1918. As a result, the shock produces a case of
10
which states that are unlikely to consolidate a democracy try to adopt it regardless
after waves, therefore, are linked to initial transitions that create the wave in the
first place.
Relevance
ways. First, it offers a theory for the temporal and geographic clustering of
domestic reforms. Although institutional waves have been a central feature in the
evolution of modern regimes, there are surprisingly few attempts to explain their
causes. This omission stems partly from the way democracy has been studied in the
Domestic factors alone, however, cannot account for the rapid and simultaneous
theories that focus on the internal determinants of domestic reforms, I argue that
regime success in the twentieth century is deeply tied to rapid changes in the
requires a systemic theory of democratization – that is, a theory that examines how
linkages among states and changes in the international system shape and constrain
the incentives and opportunities for domestic reforms. Because it steps outside the
11
and in some instances they are essential for understanding regime reforms. But
there are times when systemic pressures have important and long-lasting effects on
the evolution of domestic regimes. At such times, the interaction of external and
domestic factors becomes crucial for explaining regime change. It may well be
therefore, is not to explain away internal factors but to examine how they interact
world. The beginnings of the third wave in Southern Europe and later Asia and
Latin America were not associated with sudden shifts in hegemonic capability. The
11
Peter Gourevitch (1978) “The Second Image Reversed: The International Sources
of Domestic Politics” International Organization 32.4: 881-911
12
great power politics that were motivated by fear of Soviet decline and Gorbachev’s
attempts to reverse that decline. Yet it was a precursor to the Soviet collapse rather
than a symptom of it. Hegemonic shock dynamics are clearly visible, however, in
the African wave of democratization after 1991. The so-called Color Revolutions in
the post-Soviet space or the ongoing wave of popular protests in the Arab world
also represent instances of waves that were not produced by shocks. Scholars have
protests, but the sudden rise or decline of great powers has not played a major role
in their explanations.
Not all waves, then, are caused by hegemonic shocks. At the same time, every
reforms. Shocks are therefore a sufficient but not a necessary cause of institutional
democratic waves that followed World War I and the Soviet collapse, the fascist
wave of the 1930s, or the two waves toward democracy and communism after
World War II – in each instance, shifts in the distribution of hegemonic power have
produced bursts of transformation that affected many countries around the world.
Many countries undergo democratic transitions, but far fewer are able to sustain the
reforms that accompany these transitions. As Przeworski et al. (2000) have argued,
13
consolidations are easier to explain – countries are much more likely to sustain
relatively equal, and have a sizeable middle class. By contrast, transitions occur in
compositions, and with many different types of class coalitions.12 While there
to explain democratic transitions. Transitions are easy to do, but hard to explain;
have argued that factors leading to democratic transitions may be different from
My argument both builds upon this literature and departs from it in some ways.
democratic overstretch. At the same time, I argue, the wave sows the seeds of its
own demise, creating incentives that disappear as the shock fades. Thus the factors
that create an artificially high number of transitions also create the failed
consolidations that follow. The causes of transitions and consolidations are indeed
12
Adam Przeworski, Michael E. Alvarez, Jose Antonio Cheibub, and Fernando
Limongi (2000) Democracy and Development: Political Institutions and Well-Being
in the World, 1950-1990, Cambridge University Press
14
processes.
comparative politics – two strands of theory that share common affinities but rarely
hegemonic wars and their effects on war propensity and foreign policy.13 The study
As I hope to show, the intersection of these fields can usefully illuminate the causes
of domestic transformations. How democracy spreads can tell us about the nature
of democracy itself.
can refer to a single paramount state, one associated with the provision of global
public goods and control of the commons. But it can also refer to one of several
great powers.14 I adopt the latter definition – in this dissertation, a hegemon refers
13
The classic texts are A.F.K. Organski (1958) World Politics, Knopf and Robert
Gilpin (1981) War and Change in Global Politics, Cambridge University Press. For
two more recent edited volumes, see Jonathan Friedman and Christopher Chase-
Dunn, eds. (2005) Hegemonic Declines: Present and Past, Paradigm Publishers and
William R. Thompson, ed. (2009) Systemic Transitions: Past, Present, and Future,
Palgrave-Macmillan.
14
The Oxford English Dictionary maintains this ambivalence, defining a hegemon
as “a leading or paramount power,” where “leading” implies the possibility of
15
that sense a hegemon as used here is a more exclusive term than the Correlates of
War definition of a “major power”, but more inclusive than the single-state
definition adopted by, for example, Gilpin (1981) or Mearsheimer (2001).15 The
salient characteristic of a “pole” is that it is not merely a major power, but a leading
state with the capacity to impose regimes, influence other great powers, and inspire
institutional imitators. Following the general view that the system was multipolar
until World War Two and bipolar until the Soviet collapse,16 hegemons between
the years 1816 and 2000 were labeled as: US 1898-2000; Russia/USSR 1816-1991;
1905-1945.
power among the leading states in the international system. The term expands on
economic crises or imperial collapses – any period in which the power of one
hegemon rises or declines significantly against the others. Gilpin saw hegemonic
wars as “the ultimate test of change in the relative standing of the powers in the
producing clear winners and losers, hegemonic shocks clarify the balance of power
and allow opportunities for the creation of new global orders. In doing so, they also
institutions. They are rare and relatively brief, but they play a pivotal role in
shaping the evolution of political and social institutions. Karl Polanyi, for instance,
focuses his attention on the former.18 The notion of critical junctures parallels the
of relative stasis are punctuated by bursts of sudden and dramatic changes. Stephen
Krasner, for example, notes that political development of states often follows an
over the basic rules of the game rather than allocation within a given set of rules.”19
17
Gilpin 1981: fn.80
18
Karl Polanyi (1944/2001) The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic
Origins of Our Time, Boston: Beacon Press, p.4
19
Stephen Krasner (1984) “Approaches to the State: Alternative conceptions and
historical dynamics.” Comparative Politics 16, p. 234. See also Stephen Krasner
(1988) “Sovereignty: An institutional perspective” Comparative Political Studies 21,
p. 66-94; Paul Pierson (2004) Politics in Time: History, Institutions, and Social
Analysis, Princeton University Press; Peter J. Katzenstein (1985) Small States in
17
moments of crisis deep partisan attachments are formed which persist over long
Skowronec defines such moments as "a sporadic, disruptive event that suddenly
challenges a state's capacity to maintain control and alters the boundaries defining
politics are periodically interrupted by crises that shape the content and likelihood
enormous incentives and opportunities for change; in doing so they disrupt the
flow of politics as usual and define the parameters of future reforms. As rare but
crucial events, they have left a deep imprint on the evolution of domestic regimes
in relative power among the hegemons. This was operationalized by summing the
Capabilities) scores among great powers, yielding the graph below.22 This variable
power among major states changes over time. It improves on existing measures that
See also Stephen Skowronek (1995) "Order and Change" Polity 28.1:91-96;
Sheldon D. Pollack (2010) War, Revenue, and State Building: Financing the
Development of the American State, Cornell University Press, p. 33. In sociology,
Ann Swindler distinguishes between “settled” and “unsettled” time. Ann Swidler
(1986) “Culture in Action: Symbols and strategies” American Sociological Review
51.2, p. 273-86. Stinchcombe 1965:153ff examines a variety of social
organizations like college fraternities, banks, and trade unions. He notes that
organizations of a particular type tend to be established in bursts, and that the
forms they adopt tend to persist for a long time. Arthur Stinchcombe (1965) “Social
Structure and Organizations” in James G. March, ed., Handbook of Organizations,
Chicago: Rand McNally
22
See Chapter 2 for an extended discussion.
19
There are three immediately visible spikes: 1917-1922, 1940-1947 (with some
case selections of World War I, World War II, and the Soviet Collapse (a future
case study not included in this dissertation). Although it does not appear on the
graph above, I have also added a case study of the Great Depression, for the
following reasons. First, due to the way the CINC index is constructed, it is likely to
Second, consistent with the demands of the theory, even when measured via CINC
relative U.S. power begins to decline beginning in the mid-1920s and especially
after 1929, while German power increases dramatically after Hitler’s ascent to
power in 1933. The period of the Great Depression thus provides an important and
20
dependent variable.23
The table below identifies the winning and losing hegemons in the wake of
each shock. Identifying their regime types also makes a prediction about what type
of institutional wave we should expect. For example, the joint victory by the US
and USSR in World War II would lead us to expect two waves of reforms, one
In each of the four cases the content of the waves produced by the shocks are
consistent with the expectations of the theory. The sudden rise of a great power
produced waves of reforms that reflect that state’s regime, while periods of sudden
decline produced waves away from the hegemon’s regime. The outcomes of these
shocks consecrate the regimes of wining hegemons and discredit the losing
23
See Chapter 2 for a discussion of the case selection.
21
Jervis points out, their biggest weakness is underestimating the power and
waves. Each wave examined in this dissertation has contained common patterns
that have recurred across time. History does not repeat itself, as Mark Twain
declared, but it does rhyme, and these rhymes reveal themselves in the
“frequently occurring and easily recognizable causal patterns” that are less general
than laws but more general than descriptive case studies.25 Residing at the middle
24
Robert Jervis (1997) System Effects: Complexity in Political and Social Life,
Princeton University Press, p.103
25
Jon Elster (1998) “A Plea for Mechanisms” p.45-73 in Peter Hedstrom and
Richard Swedberg, eds., Social Mechanisms: An Analytical Approach to Social
Theory, Cambridge University Press, p. 24. Paul Pierson likewise argues for the
study of mechanisms as the goal of social science. See Pierson 2004:5-6, 99.
26
Jon Elster (1983) Explaining Technical Change: A Case Study in the Philosophy of
Science, Cambridge University Press, p.24.
22
the relevant international context and how this influences prospects for
The first way in which shocks lead to waves is by increasing opportunities for
power, shocks create windows of opportunity for rising hegemons to impose their
weaken the hegemon’s ability to sustain foreign regimes upheld by force. Examples
Soviet takeover of Eastern Europe and North Korea after World War II, or the
American occupation of Japan and Germany until 1952 and 1955, respectively.
27
Charles Cameron (2010) “What is Political Science” p.216 in Andrew Gelman
and Jeronimo Cortina, eds., A Quantitative Tour of the Social Sciences, Cambridge
University Press.
28
Kristian Gleditsch and Michael D. Ward. (2006) "Diffusion and the International
Context of Democratization" International Organization 60.4, p.916
23
Shocks lower the costs of occupation, in two ways. In cases of military shocks,
when the army has already been mobilized, the fixed cost of mobilization required
for foreign occupation has already been met. Interventions after major wars occur
at a time when the rising hegemons are not only at their most powerful and most
committed to changing the global order - but also when they are most able to do
so. Second, since shocks suspend the normal rules of the international order, they
may provide a window of legitimacy for foreign military occupations. In his book
Embracing Defeat, the historian John Dower has argued that the success of the U.S.
occupation of Japan after World War II was shaped at least in part by the nature of
the war that proceeded it, and the decisive defeat that brought the war to an end.29
due to the nature of the war and the total defeat that accompanied its conclusion.
Likewise, the Soviet occupation of Eastern Europe in the early aftermath of World
War II was legitimized in part by the nature of the Soviet victory in that conflict.
These factors simply do not come into play with interventions that occur in the
Stalin’s remark about the division of Europe after World War II is a distillation of
imposes on it its own social system. Everyone imposes his system as far as his army
29
John Dower (1999) Embracing Defeat: Japan in the Wake of World War II, W.W.
Norton & Company
30
Stalin made the remark to the Yugoslavian military mission to Yalta in 1944, as
24
their own regimes through the use of outside interventions. As Peceny puts it, “the
practice of the liberal great powers over the past century is filled with illiberal
behavior…The United States has backed dozens of dictatorial regimes over the past
century and only made active efforts to promote democracy during a third of its
have argued that democracies prefer to establish stable and friendly regimes -
rather than democratic ones - in the countries that they have occupied.32
the wake of hegemonic shocks and those that occur in the course of “normal”
politics. If the above arguments are correct, military hegemonic shocks should
other states (“mimetic” imposition). In other words, we would expect to see spikes
immediately following both world wars. This effect can be tested directly by
looking at the rate of coerced regime promotions after military shocks. As I show in
the next chapter, the data in fact confirms that great powers act differently after
shocks. Using a dataset by John Owen (2010), I examined the rates of mimetic
later recalled by one of its members. See Milovan Djilas (1962) Conversations with
Stalin, Harmondsworth, p. 90-1.
31
Mark Peceny (2010) “Democratizing During Hard Times: Germany’s Transition
to Democracy in the Wake of the First World War” Paper presented at the 106th
Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, September 2-5,
2010, Washington, D.C, p.5-6
32
Bruce Bueno de Mesquita, Alastair Smith, Randolph M. Siverson, and James D.
Morrow (2003) The Logic of Political Survival, MIT Press
25
great powers are much more likely to occur in the wake of military hegemonic
shocks.
much more likely to promote their own regimes in the wake of shocks – of the 31
their own regimes (about 94 percent) of the time. 33 Of the 41 cases of hegemonic
intervention during non-shock years, they imposed their own regime in 27 cases
(about 66 percent). In other words, in an average shock year there were 4.8
33
Shock years are counted as the last year of the war and the following two years,
or 1918-1920 and 1944-1946, for a total of six shock years. The two exceptions are
Japan in Russia (1918) and the USSR in Austria (1945).
26
In short, great powers do act differently after hegemonic shocks. They are more
likely to impose regimes during hegemonic transitions, and when they do so they
are much more likely to impose their own regimes than during non-shock years.
The reasons for this, as suggested above, stem from the temporary decrease in the
costs and changed conditions for regime impostions that occur in the wake of
hegemonic shocks.
interstate wars, and systemic peace. Lo, Hashimoto and Reiter (2008), for example
find that peace is more durable following interstate wars in which the loser
interventions that take place in the wake of hegemonic shocks from those that do
not.
changing the institutional preferences and power bases of domestic actors within
the affected countries. Immediately after World War II, for example, Communist
parties appeared to be gaining ground in France and Italy. The US Marshall Plan
34
A difference-of-means test between mimetic hegemonic impositions in shock vs.
non-shock years reveals (unsurprisingly) that the difference is statistically
significant.
35
Nigel Lo, Barry Hashimoto, and Dan Reiter (2008) “Ensuring Peace: Foreign-
Imposed Regime Change and Post-War Peace Duration, 1914-2001” International
Organization 62.4:717-36
27
communism and toward liberal democracy, so that by 1948, with the influx of
American money and institutional infrastructure, Communist parties had lost much
of their support. “The United States spent little of its hegemonic power trying to
coerce and induce other governments to buy into American rules and institutions,”
notes Ikenberry. “It spent much more time and resources trying to create the
conditions under which postwar European governments and publics would remain
The Marshall Plan became the most prominent way in which the United States
exercised its influence and promoted liberal democratic regimes in the years
the American institutional model. By the end of the program in 1952, the United
States had spent $13 billion, more than all previous American foreign aid put
together. The largest impact of the Marshall Plan resided not with the amount of the
disbursements but with the conditions attached to them. Along with collaborators
in western Europe, U.S. aid officials sought to prevent national politicians “from
economies.”37 In doing so, Marshall aid nudged center-left parties toward social
democracy rather than communism. It was “an economic program but the crisis it
36
G. John Ikenberry (2000) After Victory: Institutions, Strategic Restraint, and the
Rebuilding of Order After Major Wars, Princeton University Press, p.202
37
Victoria de Grazia (2005) Irresistible Empire: America’s Advance through
Twentieth-Century Europe, Harvard University Press, p.345-6
28
Europe was both immediate and long-lasting. In Austria, for example, local
communists (supported by Soviet forces, who still occupied the eastern half of the
country) “never made any dent in the popularity of Americans and their aid,” notes
Judt. “[T]he latter put food in people's mouths and this was what mattered most.” In
Greece, the $649 million in aid extended in the spring of 1948 “made the
difference between survival and destitution.” It “supported refugees and staved off
hunger and disease,” and provided half of the country’s gross national product in
democratic wave in western Europe was made possible by the rare combination of
American influence and commitment (both political and economic) in the years
rising great powers can take advantage of hegemonic shocks to advance the
construction of global institutions which act as conduits for their influence. While
38
Tony Judt (2005) Postwar: A History of Europe Since 1945, Penguin Press, p.97.
As Kennedy notes, “it took no genius to see that the raison d'etre for the plan was
to convince Europeans everywhere that private enterprise was better able to bring
them prosperity than communism.” Kennedy 1989:377
39
Judt 2005:96
29
opportunities for great powers to create new global and regional orders. Thus in the
wake of the war, both the Soviet Union and the United States used their enormous
power and influence to construct a new institutional architecture that helped them
perpetuate control and influence over the states embedded within it.
domestic groups in those states. For example, the collapse of the Soviet Union led
to the demise of communism as a viable path for state development in Africa. The
collapse of the Soviet Union undercut the legitimacy of its institutions and its ability
were faced with shrinking funds, and were forced to cut social spending, which led
to an increase in popular protests, which (along with elite defection) led to political
liberalization and multiparty elections.40 In this way, systemic and domestic factors
40
Previous work has shown that the stability of autocratic states often rests on the
rulers’ ability to maintain clientelist networks through selective patronage. When
potential rivals can be co-opted, there is no incentive to deviate from the status
quo; but the disruption of these patronage networks paves the way for democratic
reforms. See Barbara Geddes (1999) “What Do We Know About Democratization
After Twenty Years?” Annual Review of Political Science 2:115-44.
30
In other cases, shocks may produce shifts in institutional preferences even without
direct hegemonic involvement. The very existence of a global crisis can influence
and lowering the barriers to collective action. They may discredit incumbent elites,
forcing them to bargain with the masses, or encourage states to look for new
institutions to deal with future problems.41 In a case study that I examine in more
women and laborers because their cooperation was essential for the victorious
41
The logic of hegemonic shocks suggests that the effect of interstate war on
domestic institutional reforms is mediated by war outcomes, rather than a universal
impulse toward democracy, which is perhaps why the literature has not found
consistent links between war and democracy. Edward D. Mansfield and Jack
Snyder (2010) “Does War Influence Democratization?” p.23-49 in Elizabeth Keir
and Ronald Krebs, eds., In War’s Wake: International Conflict and the Fate of
Liberal Democracy, Cambridge University Press.
31
this aspect of neorealism has rarely been explored, emulation is one of the major
and anarchically structured, it will select for states that are able to successfully
ensure their own security. Those who do not will fall by the wayside.42 In addition,
the international system shapes behavior through socialization, and the two
processes are mutually reinforcing – “statesmen learn because they see the
system creates competitive pressures that over time select for domestic institutional
would expect to see institutions that increase the state’s chances of survival (by
while institutions that perform poorly and endanger the state’s chances of survival
will lose credibility. To employ Waltz’s own oligopoly metaphors: saying that the
42
Waltz 1979: 71, 91, 118-119
43
Jervis 1997:104. See also Waltz 1979:74-77, 92, 127-128
32
saying that a firm’s internal organization does not matter because the market
the international structure will select certain institutional features of states over
others.
of military emulation in South America in the 19th century. 44Starting in the 1880s,
South American countries began imitating various elements of the German army
states were too diverse to explain such convergence. Instead, he argues, the causes
external security environment that all states must face. Cross-national emulation, he
argues is “a product of the underlying nature of the international system, not the
Emulation is thus a strategy that can increase the adopting state’s security. It
(Resende-Santos focuses only on the first element and, as I will argue shortly, does
44
Joao Resende-Santos (2007) Neorealism, States, and the Modern Army,
Cambridge University Press. See also Colin Elman, The logic of emulation: The
diffusion of military practices in the international system. PhD dissertation,
Columbia University.
45
Resende-Santos 2007:4
33
so for the wrong reasons.) First, emulation can be used to strengthen the state
against both internal and external threats. Emulating states hope to repeat some of
the rising hegemon’s dramatic success and in doing so improve their own
institutional fitness. Discussing the adoption of free trade policies based on the
British model during the 1850s, a deputy in the French National Assembly asked:
"When such a powerful and enlightened nation not only puts such a great principle
into practice but it is also well known to have profited by it, how can its emulators
fail to follow the same way?”46 In that sense institutional emulation is a strategy of
internal strengthening.
Second, imitating a more powerful peer can allow a state to curry favor with it
and to participate in the international system that the hegemon creates and
though a looser one than signing treaties or forging official alliances. As Markoff
puts it, “Weak states depend on stronger ones and may bid for favor by mimicking
their political structures.”47 The unique advantage of emulation is that it can enable
Why should hegemonic shocks make such emulation more likely? Shocks
46
Quoted in William J. Bernstein (2008) A Splendid Exchange: How Trade Shaped
the World, New York: Atlantic Monthly Press, p.314. Or, as William McNeil puts
it “Any human skill that achieves admirable results will tend to spread from its
place of origin by taking root among other people who encounter the novelty and
find it better than whatever they had previously known or done.” William McNeil
(1992/1994) The Pursuit of Power, University of Chicago Press, p.147
47
John Markoff (1996) Waves of Democracy: Social Movements and Political
Change, Pine Forge Press, p. 32
34
rthe relative effectiveness of competing regime types. Despite the potential benefits
theory, war is said to reveal private information about actors' capability and
resolve, information that cannot be credibly verified through bluffs and cheap talk
before the fight. Similarly, hegemonic shocks reveal information about the relative
strength of competing regime types, information not credible through cheap talk.48
legitimacy; the giant’s clay feet are revealed for all to see.
During the Cold War, for example, both sides extolled the virtues of their
outside its borders, did not become apparent to world audiences (and most
scholars) until after the system’s dramatic collapse in 1989. Similarly, both world
48
The information revealed through hegemonic shocks cannot be said to be
“private” in the conventional sense, since actors want to keep private information
hidden, while hegemons actively attempt to convince outsiders of the effectiveness
of their regimes in order to gain influence and followers. What the two ideas share
in common is the concept of “cheap talk” – regime efficacy cannot be credibly
conveyed by persuasion alone, and it takes a shock to convincingly show which
regimes perform better under duress, regardless of what the hegemons claim
beforehand. Part of the importance of hegemonic shocks is that they credibly – and
dramatically – reveal this information to foreign audiences.
35
non-democratic states. In both cases the democratic side (and in one case the
that democratic regimes would prove inferior to centralized ones on the theater of
battle.49
best practices may or may not prove effective… because of faulty copying, failure
simply the lack of the necessary human skill and know how. 50 Another source of
failed emulation, I would argue, is the skewed incentives that arise as a result of
Research in political psychology has repeatedly shown that statesmen and political
49
While democratic victory in World War I temporarily put this argument to rest,
the rapid ascent of fascism in the 1930s (accompanied by democracy’s decline)
resurrected old concerns. Thus Aldous Huxley argued in a 1936 essay that "A
democracy which makes or even effectively prepares for modern, scientific war
must necessarily cease to be democratic. No country can be really well prepared
for modern war unless it is governed by a tyrant, at the head of a highly trained and
perfectly obedient bureaucracy." Aldous Huxley (1936) “Ends and Means: An
Inquiry into the Nature of Ideals and into the Methods Employed for Their
Realization”
50
Resende-Santos 2007:7
36
misjudge their own effectiveness at bringing out the desired political reforms.51
These cognitive biases contribute to the emulation of winning regime types in the
wake of hegemonic shocks. But they also lead to the failed consolidations that
follow, as leaders optimistically adopt democratic regimes even when the domestic
democratic consolidation.52
competing regimes. Whether the signals are correctly interpreted, or whether they
accurately reflect the factors the created the outcome, is a different matter. As
Markoff puts it, “If organizations that have done well have accounting departments,
soon all will, even if no one is sure that accounting departments made the leaders
emulation more likely. “In the face of major threats, military emulation is the
quickest and most dependable way to increase power and bolster security,” he
writes. “Timing, pace, and scale will correspond with the timing and magnitude of
external threats…the higher and more intense the threat level, the deeper and more
51
See Thomas Gilovich, Dale Griffin, and Daniel Kahneman, eds. (2002) Heuristics
and Biases, Cambridge University Press. On the last bias, see Robert Jervis (1976)
Perception and Misperception, Princeton University Press, p.344-8
52
Exploring the role of institutional emulation in the wake of hegemonic shocks
presents a fruitful area of research that connects the micro-foundations of diffusion
mechanisms with macro-historical structural shifts in the international system.
53
Markoff 1996:32. See also John Meyer, John Boli and George Thomas (1997)
“World Society and the Nation-State” The American Journal of Sociology 103:144-
81.
37
sustained the adverse shift in the external security environment, the more rapid and
large scale the emulation.”54 But his own evidence suggests that emulation takes
place immediately after major wars, not in the period preceding them. “In the
makes clear in the next sentence that he’s talking about the aftermath of wars:
“…such wars often trigger significant changes in the local or international balance
emerges only after the crisis is resolved. The specific timing and content of military
techniques. Prussia, Austria and Russia copied the French after Napoleon’s
victories. France emulated Prussia after its victory in the Franco-Prussian wars.58
54
Resende-Santos 2007:8
55
Resende-Santos 2007:13
56
Resende-Santos 2007:13
57
Resende-Santos 2007:6
58
Resende-Santos 2007:13. In one paragraph Resende-Santos makes a similar
argument that curiously undercuts his main thesis: “Given their preoccupation with
competitive effectiveness, states prefer to emulate only practices and technologies
demonstrated to be the most effective among synchronic alternatives. In the area of
military emulation, states use battlefield performance, especially victory in war, as
the truest observable measure of effectiveness. States thus emulate the military
system that emerges victorious in great power wars….Proven success in war
provides states with a closer approximation of the true utility of certain military
practices. It reduces the uncertainties that surround such practices.”(Resende-
Santos 2007:7; emphasis added)
38
on persuasion or socialization, but it also takes a slightly different view about its
causes than the standard neorealist view. It is the reduction of uncertainty and the
emulation, rather than the increased competition in the international system that
precedes them. And while the outcomes of hegemonic shocks reveal information
about which systems function more effectively under duress, that information may
decades, states have admired and mimicked a variety of other regimes, particularly
those that had emerged triumphant in periods of hegemonic transition. The Soviet
Union, for instance, inspired followers after World War II because “the Soviet
Union’s victory over Nazi Germany, a country most observers had seen in 1939
and 1940 as an industrial giant, suggested that the Soviet system had considerable
real-world vigor.”59 Likewise, the decline of liberal capitalism in the 1930s led
many states, including the United States, to move closer to the statist policies of the
national socialists, who thrived and attracted followers during this period. As
Schivelbusch notes:
59
Gale Stokes (1993) The Walls Came Tumbling Down: The Collapse of
Communism in Eastern Europe, Oxford University Press, p.8
39
I’ve argued, the answer has to do with the dynamics of waves themselves. The
unique circumstances that allow the wave to occur in the first place also sow the
seeds of the wave’s decline. Hegemonic shocks create immense but temporary
Alternatively, they may have unsteady procrustean institutions imposed upon them
stable democracy. In the immediate aftermath of the shock, these domestic pre-
requisites become less important, allowing for the creation of a wave of democratic
transformations.
But the relative importance of systemic and domestic factors changes as the
new regimes move toward consolidation. The international incentives that created
60
Wolfgang Schivelbusch, Three New Deals: Reflections on Roosevelt’s America,
Mussolini’s Italy, and Hitler’s Germany, 1933-1939; transl. from German by
Jefferson Chase, Henry Holt and Co., 2006, p.11
40
these institutional reforms. The nature and composition of social coalitions, the
begin to play a more important role. At least some of the transformations begin to
fail as idiosyncratic, country-specific internal factors start to take hold. Such failed
consolidations are particularly likely in the fragile new states created by the
democratic governance and are often plagued by fragile institutions that buckle
under the weight of political tensions. They can fall prey to ethnic violence, to
populist unrest, to cycles of civil war or government coups. Mansfield and Snyder
41
argue that new democracies are more prone to nationalism and aggression. This
rhetoric to shore up the support of the masses, and the fragile new institutions
frequently collapse under their weight.61 In new states created by World War I, for
social groups brought together in artificially bounded territories. The initial shock,
of Communist regimes in eastern Europe, for example, was made possible only by
physical occupation. As soon as the coercive grip loosened, the unwilling members
difficult to discuss failures of consolidation because the entire wave crested and fell
so rapidly in a space of less than fifteen years. But a large number of fascist regimes
were also created and upheld by outside coercion - namely, the creation of a
Festung Europa by German armies and the East Asian Co-Prosperity Sphere by their
Japanese equivalents.
61
Jack L. Snyder (2000) From Voting to Violence: Democratization and Nationalist
Conflict, W.W. Norton and Company; Edward M. Mansfield and Jack L. Snyder
(2007) Electing to Fight: Why Emerging Democracies Go to War, The MIT Press
42
Alternative Explanations
the causes of democratic waves. Part of the problem stems from the literature’s
like the international system or diffusion among states in shaping regime outcomes.
development, elite pacts, mass movements, civil society, party coalitions, electoral
systems, national culture, federalism, ethnic and linguistic diversity, class relations,
fertile ground for theories of institutional change, democracy’s relationship with the
62
Geoffrey Pridham (1995) “Democratic Transition and the International
Environment” in Geoffrey Pridham, ed., Transitions to Democracy: Comparative
Perspectives from Southern Europe, Latin America, and Eastern Europe, UK:
Dartmouth Publishing Group, p. 445. “The literature of sociology and political
science, with its overriding stress on why democratization has advanced in some
places more than others, has obscured the profoundly transnational dimension of
democratization.” Markoff 1996:20. Similar lamentations about theories of
democracy ignoring external forces can be found in more recent articles as well:
see Jon C. Pevehouse (2002) “Democracy from the Outside-In? International
Organizations and Democratization” International Organization 56.3, fn. 15;
Michael McFaul, “The Fourth Wave of Democracy and Dictatorship:
43
The domestic variable bias in democratization studies stems partly from the
history of the field itself. The first comparative studies of political development
America and later in Asia, Eastern Europe, and Africa. But while the subject area
then attempting to find commonalities or patterns within those cases, while at the
same time emphasizing the differences that set their country or region apart from
others.
hard to compare results across studies. Their efforts at causal theorizing had
causal models. In some cases their empirical tests relied on a small set of variables,
acerbic 1999 review of the literature by Barbara Geddes noted that “scholars have
thus far have been confusingly complicated, careless about basic methodological
fragmentation, a small but growing body of literature has moved away from the
is driven at least partly by forces originating outside a country’s borders, rather than
called them, emphasize the influence of the international environment and links
among states in shaping domestic reforms. They sought to link external factors to
domestic actors, who would not disappear from the analysis but serve as important
64
Munck 1994:122
65
Geddes 1999:117
66
Daniel Brinks and Michael Coppedge (2006) “Diffusion Is No Illusion: Neighbor
Emulation in the Third Wave of Democracy” Comparative Political Studies 39:463-
89
45
often cannot be understood apart from examining the influence of the international
emulation.
Yet even most systemic theories of regime change do not address the puzzle of
institutional waves directly. There exists, for example, a healthy debate on the
promotion. But the influence of foreign aid alone cannot explain the clustering of
regime transitions without recourse to some other variables. In other words, even if
waves suggests that the influence of foreign aid varies widely over time – and this
At the same time, hegemonic shocks are clearly not the only existing
explanation for democratic waves. Alternative explanations that most closely fit the
description can be divided into three categories: historical, bellicist theory, and
diffusion models.
Historical Explanations
The historical explanation denies (or at least does not engage) the possibility of
historians, who stress the contingency and uniqueness of historical events. “Men
46
wiser and more learned than I have discerned in history a plot, a rhythm, a
predetermined pattern. These harmonies are concealed from me,” writes H.A.L.
Fisher in the preface to his “History of Europe. “I can see only one emergency
following upon another...and only one safe rule for the historian: that he should
recognize in the development of human destinies the play of the contingent and
the unforeseen...”67
The historical type of explanation was also put forth by Huntington in the The
Third Wave. Huntington argued that the famous “third wave” of democratization
resulted from a combination of factors, both internal and external. These included
actions by the Catholic Church and other powerful external actors, the loss of
modernization, and “demonstration effects”. I will not repeat the criticisms put
forth in the very beginning of the chapter except to reiterate that Huntington,
There is no doubt that history stubbornly resists the straitjacket of theory. “Many
a beautiful theory,” wrote Thomas Huxley, “was killed by an ugly fact.” And the
search for law-like regularities is indeed a fruitless one, since human society is far
too complex to submit itself to nomological principles. But this does not mean that
all attempts to theorize about the social world must be abandoned. Jon Elster
invokes the French historian Paul Veyne’s objection against grand theory. Suppose,
67
H.A.L. Fisher (1970) A History of Europe
47
of Louis XIV by invoking a general social science theory. We might start by looking
for factors that seem most salient, beginning perhaps with the generalization “kings
who impose high taxes become unpopular”. But in order to take care of
counterexamples from other reigns and eras, the general statement will have to
saddled with numerous caveats, exceptions, and qualifications, the final result of
which is “a chapter in the history of the reign of Louis XIV with the amusing feature
of being written in the present and the plural” rather than in the past tense and the
singular.68
Because laws establish relations between variables (and in the natural sciences,
often to a very precise degree), they can be obtained through induction alone and
invented, not discovered”70 “No laws are possible in sociology, for the number of
cases is far smaller than the number of variables effecting the outcome," writes
68
Jon Elster (1999) Alchemies of the Mind, Cambridge University Press
69
Waltz 1979:5
70
Waltz 1979:7
48
Michael Mann.71 In short, Veyne makes the mistake of thinking that facts determine
theories, whereas in fact a number of theories can fit a given set of facts. Henri
Poincaré made this point about the primacy of theory when he wrote in Science
and Hypothesis: “Science is built up with facts, as a house is with stones. But an
Laws and theories are tightly connected in the natural sciences precisely because
explain it. But because there are no laws in the social sciences, theories can only
be generated through carefully crafted assumptions, and then seeing if they hold up
encounter exceptions and anomalies, their real test, as Waltz argues, is whether
they tells us something useful about the world. If not, they should be rejected as a
weak explanation of outcomes (as in fact almost all social science theories are).73
The question then becomes not whether a theory is realistic, but whether it’s useful.
In that sense, “theory is fruitful because it goes beyond the necessarily barren
71
Michael Mann, The Sources of Social power, vol.1; quoted in “Delving into
Democracy’s Shadows” by Scott McLemme, The Chronicle of Higher Education,
Sep.17 2004. http://chronicle.com/free/v51/i04/04a01001.htm
72
Henri Poincare, Hypothesis and Science. Online at http://spartan.ac.brocku.ca/
~lward/Poincare/Poincare_1905_10.html. Stanley Hoffman makes a similar point:
“Collecting facts is not enough…it is not helpful to gather answers when no
questions have been asked first.” Stanley Hoffman, “International Relations: The
Long Road to Theory” cited in John Lewis Gaddis (1992) “International Relations
Theory and the End of the Cold War” International Security 17.3, p.14
73
See also Imre Lakatos (1970) “Falsification and the Methodology of Scientific
Research Programmes” in Lakatos and Musgrave, Criticism and the Growth of
Knowledge, Cambridge University Press
49
hypothetico-deductive approach.”74
The result is that social science theories can only make general predictions. A
mentioned in the beginning of the chapter, it cannot account for all instances of
more likely in the wake of shocks. It makes testable predictions about the
connect shocks to waves. It can be tested (as I do in this dissertation) through both
empirical analysis and careful examination of case studies. A state that fails to
democratize in the wake of a shock presents an anomaly but does not invalidate
major – possible fatal – problem for the theory. In that sense, social science
theories are falsifiable, but in a different sense than natural sciences theories, which
can be invalidated with the discovery of a single black swan. Social science
theories simplify the world by isolating the most salient factors. As such, they
require both boldness and humility – the boldness of a simplifying assumption, and
With this aside in mind, I now move on to the two alternative theoretical
74
Waltz 1979:11
50
Bellicist Theory
building, they have direct implications for the evolution of domestic regimes.
First, bellicist theories ignore the effect of non-military crises on the propensity
for institutional reforms. Second, explanations that focus on the influence of major
wars upon state development are ambiguous about their effects on regime
mobilization strategy, which in turn shapes its regime type. Hintze, a scholar of the
Prussian state, argued that constant preparation for war led to a standing army and
for democracy.75 According to this argument, then, mobilization for war – conflict
the corollary that relative isolation from interstate conflict produces democracy.76
75
Otto Hintze (1975) The Historical Essays of Otto Hintze, Felix Gilbert, ed.,
Oxford University Press
76
See also e.g., Brian M. Downing (1992) The Military Revolution and Political
Change: Origins of Democracy and Autocracy in Early Modern Europe, Princeton
University Press; William R. Thompson (1996) "Democracy and Peace: Putting the
51
But an opposing school of thought argues that mobilization for war produces
instance, have argued that warfare led to the need for increased revenue, which
general, then, mobilizing for war can force states to grant rights to previously-
excluded social groups in exchange for their cooperation and increased revenue.
Finally, the extensive literature on democratic peace reverses the causal arrow
normative mechanisms. And other studies find no visible connection between war
It may be that all of these arguments are true to some extent, but there is not
much room for a coherent theory of institutional waves among the confused and
endogenous causal arrows. In short, while bellicist theories can help explain the
timing of waves (they happen in the aftermath of major wars), they cannot account
for the waves’ direction toward or away from democracy or other regime types. To
account for the content of the waves, we must turn to the incentives produced by
Diffusion Models
By far the most common factor used to explain democratic waves involves
began in American politics, with Walker’s (1969) foundational work on the spread
of policy innovations across American states.80 Later work has examined the spread
“demonstration effects” fall into this category of explanation. Much of this literature
These theories are systemic at heart because they refuse to treat individual
80
Jack L. Walker (1969) “The Diffusion of Innovations among the States” American
Political Science Review 63.3:880-99.
81
See, e.g., Kristian Skrede Gleditsch and Michael D. Ward, “Diffusion and the
International Context of Democratization”, International Organization Fall 2006, p.
911-933; Peter T. Leeson and Andrea M. Dean (2009) “The Domino Theory: An
Empirical Investigation” American Journal of Political Science 53.3:533-51. Harvey
Starr (1991) “Democratic Dominoes: Diffusion Approaches to the Spread of
Democracy in the International System” Journal of Conflict Resolution 35.2:356-81.
53
via regional and global effects, often through very sophisticated quantitative
democratization.”82 And while statistically plausible, this result does not tell us
much about the specific mechanisms that lead to diffusion. As Narizny points out,
the agents, methods, or motives of change. As a result, their causal mechanisms are
severely undertheorized.”83
The current literature on diffusion in some ways resembles the early literature
The most recent trend in studies of diffusion has been to move away from
aggregative empirics and toward the concrete mechanisms that produce these
cross-border effects.84 In a direct sense, that is also the goal of this dissertation. I
82
John O'Loughlin, Michael D. Ward, Corey L. Lofdahl, Jordin S. Cohen, David S.
Brown, David Reilly, Kristian S. Gleditsch, Michael Shin (1998) “The Diffusion of
Democracy, 1946–1994,” Annals of the Association of American Geographers
88.3:545–574
83
Kevin Narizny (2006) “Democratization, Capitalism and Hegemony”,
unpublished manuscript, p.3
84
See, e.g., the discussion of elite learning in Beissinger 2007.
54
diffusion that stems from the effects of hegemonic shocks. To explain the dynamics
of this diffusion I focus on the causal mechanisms that lead to the spread of regimes
associated with the rising hegemon. While diffusion may explain the direction of
institutional reforms (neighbors follow neighbors, etc), it cannot explain the timing
The rest of the dissertation proceeds as follows. Chapter 2 empirically tests the
large-n statistical analysis. This chapter will begin by defining and operationalizing
my variables, stating hypotheses, and then testing them with OLS and fixed-effects
regressions. The goal of this chapter is to examine the general patterns of the
level, and domestic reforms at the country level. I then compare how my systemic
Next, chapters 3 through 5 offer case studies of the first three hegemonic shocks
55
of the twentieth century – World War I, the Great Depression, and World War II.
Each of these shocks produced waves of reforms that differed in their duration,
intensity, and content. The three chapters employ process-tracing and comparative
changes in countries around the world. While there is a large secondary literature
on the causes and effects of these shocks, and likewise a large literature on the
evolution of domestic regimes over the twentieth century, there is surprisingly little
overlap between the two. One of the goals of this dissertation is to bring the two
democratic wave that followed World War. Chapter 4 examines the crisis of
Western capitalism in the Great Depression, and the shift away from liberal
institutional waves following World War II, when both the US and the USSR
oversaw two distinct waves of transformations toward their respective regime types.
implications for the current and future state of international relations. The financial
crisis that began in 2008 re-awakened many of the same fears that observers
expressed in the 1930s. Does state capitalism, as exemplified by the rise of China,
the earlier challenges of communism and fascism? And how would a future shock
chapter will also discuss the implications for the U.S. policy of external regime
CHAPTER 2
This chapter examines the relationship between hegemonic power and the spread
studies, the goal of this chapter is to examine the general patterns of the interaction
between hegemony and regime change across the international system in the years
between 1900 and 2000. A multivariate regression model that tracks changes in the
hegemonic power of the United States reveals that it has a strong positive effect on
democratization both at the systemic level and within individual countries, even
58
communist Soviet Union are strongly and negatively associated with decreases in
the average level of democracy within countries and in the international system as
and national power. I also discuss the definition and measurement of the salient
hegemonic power (and shifts in the levels of hegemonic power). After a brief
overview of systemic patterns (which show very strong support for an association
control variables commonly associated with democratization. This allows for the
creation of a multivariate model that tests domestic arguments on their own terms
effect on democratization both inside countries and around the world as a whole.
often suffers from an omitted variable bias, and that future studies of democracy
and other regime reforms should take into account the effects of the rise and
1
In the model, these include economic development, cross-border diffusion effects,
regime history, geographic region, colonial history, and national culture.
59
Defining Democracy
Robert Dahl (1971) has influentially argued that the two core attributes of
participation (broad and inclusive access to voting).2 This is the definition I adopt
here.3 Given the above, the first question is whether democracy should be
best be summarized by the words of writer Amiri Baraka (1962): “A man is either
one: when the dividing line is sharp and clear, when the grey area between the two
2
Robert Dahl (1971) Polyarchy, Yale University Press. See also Michael Coppedge,
Angel Alvarez, Claudia Maldonado (2008) “Two Persistent Dimensions of
Democracy: Contestation and Inclusiveness” The Journal of Politics 70.3, p. 632-
647.
3
For a partial list of conceptualizations and measurements of democracy, see Gary
Goertz (2006) Social Science Concepts: A User’s Guide, Princeton University Press,
p.8-9.
4
Adam Przeworski, Michael E. Alvarez, Jose Antonio Cheibub, and Fernando
Limongi (2000) Democracy and Development: Political Institutions and Well-Being
in the World, 1950-1990, Cambridge University Press. For another argument in
favor of a dichotomous measures of democracy, see Mike Alvarez, Jose Antonio
Cheibub, Fernando Limongi and Adam Przeworski (1996) “Classifying Political
Regimes” Studies in Comparative International Development 31:3-36
5
“Tokenism” in Kulchur, Spring 1962
60
cases is small, and when few important cases fall into that grey area.6 On these
criteria, democracy fails to qualify on all three grounds. Likewise, Elkins (2000)
Measuring Democratization
democratic regimes which (unlike Freedom House, for example) covers the time
span examined in the argument. Polity codes annual information on regime and
authority characteristics for all independent states (with a population over 500,000)
from 1800 to 2004. Regimes are measured on a scale from -10 (strongly autocratic)
6
Jack Donnely (2006) Realism and International Relations, Cambridge University
Press, p. 88. Epstein et al reject a dichotomous measure of democracy on similar
grounds. See David L. Epstein, Robert Bates, Jack Goldstone, Ida Kristensen and
Sharyn O'Halloran (2006) “Democratic Transitions” American Journal of Political
Science 50.3: 551-569. Kellstedt and Whitten (2009) likewise argue that
continuous variables are more appropriate in the case of democracy. Paul M.
Kellstedt and Guy D. Whitten (2009) The Fundamentals of Political Science
Research, Cambridge University Press, p. 96.
7
Zachary Elkins (2000) “Gradations of Democracy? Empirical Tests of Alternative
Conceptualizations” American Journal of Political Science 44.2:287
61
chief executive. (To make analysis easier, I have recoded it on a scale from 0 to
20). At the systemic level, I measured democratization as the total global average of
year.
democracy at the expense of participation.8 The United States, for example, has
received a perfect score since 1871, despite the enfranchisement of women (1920),
African-Americans (de jure in 1869, but de facto in 1965), and citizens aged 18-
21(1971) since that period. For this reason, and as a check on the robustness of the
results, I also include a measure of democratization called SIP, or the Scalar Index
of Politics. SIP combines the executive restraint components of the Polity IV score
and global levels of fascism and communism in the system were measured using
the total power (as measured by CINC; see below) of communist and fascist states.
8
Geraldo Munck and Jay Verkuilen (2002) “Conceptualizing and Measuring
Democracy: Evaluating Alternative Indices” Comparative Political Studies 35.1:5-34
9
SIP is described and employed in Scott Gates, Håvard Hegre, Mark P. Jones, and
Håvard Strand (2006) “Institutional Inconsistency and Political Instability: Polity
Duration, 1800-2000” American Journal of Political Science 50.4:893-908.
62
wave as a group of transitions between two regime types that occur within a
specified period of time and that significantly outnumber transitions in the opposite
10
Huntington defines a democratic wave as “a group of transitions from
nondemocratic to democratic regimes that occur within a specified period of time
and that significantly outnumber transitions in the opposite direction during that
period.” (Huntington 1991:15) I define institutions as mechanisms employed by
states to deal with problems of enforcement, security, coordination, and credible
commitment. They are public rules that organize relationships among individuals,
groups, and states. This definition follows the historical-institutionalist approach.
See Kathleen Thelen (1999) “Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Politics”
Annual Review of Political Science 2:369-404. On credible commitment via
legislatures, see Douglass North and Barry R. Weingast, "Constitutions and
Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in
Seventeenth-Century England." Journal of Economic History 49:803-832. States
employ and reform institutions to increase their external security and internal
stability, not always successfully. Central banks, courts, electoral rules and social
welfare programs are all examples of various state institutions. Institutions are not
“normally distributed” across states in the system. Instead, certain combinations of
63
independence between 1810 and 1825, the communist wave in Asia following
World War II or, reaching deeper into time, the spread of parliamentarianism
Since Huntington first described them, the notion of democratic waves has
most prominent dissenters. 13 They criticize Huntington for using a measure based
on the percentage of democratic states, and find no evidence for waves when using
the criterion of transitions rather than institutional changes. However, their analysis
is problematic for two important reasons: first, they employ a dichotomous measure
transitions measured with dichotomous variables are sensitive to where one makes
the cut.14 Two, most importantly, their time of analysis is limited to the years 1950-
1990. Since two of the three democratic waves occur before their period, the
Figure 2.1 tracks the average annual Polity IV and SIP scores since 1900. In
waves, with democratic peaks following the two World Wars and the Soviet
collapse. (The two measures are highly correlated, as expected, but Polity
consistently over-estimates the level of democracy in the system.) The waves also
appear when using other metrics, such as the proportion of countries that are
Figures 2.2 and 2.3; in the latter case, the rollback of the second wave disappears).
13
Democracy and Development, p.40-45
14
Other measures (notably, Huntington’s) do find waves even when using a
dichotomous variable.
65
Figure 2.1 Average global democracy, Polity and SIP scores, 1900-2000
(standardized to 0-100)
Figure 2.3 Total number of democratic states (with democracies defined as states
with a Polity score of 7 or more)
fascism and communism – have also spread and retreated in wave-like patterns.
(Figures 2.5, 2.5, 2.6) A fascist wave swept Europe and other parts of the world in
the 1930s, and a wave of Communist transitions followed the Soviet victory in
like Polity, the global spread of fascism and communism can be estimated by
charting the percentage of world power held by fascist and communist states since
1900. (The share of power was calculated using CINC, discussed below.)
67
Figure 2.4: Communist and fascist shares of global power, 1900-2000 (measured
by CINC)
Figure 2.6: Number of fascist and communist states, as a proportion of all states in
the international system
The existence of these waves presents the central puzzle to be explained. I now
Power has remained a contested term in political science, even when confined to
15
There is an extensive literature in international relations on the meaning and
measure of national power. See Gregory F. Treverton, Seth G. Jones (2005)
“Measuring National Power” RAND Conference Proceedings; available online at
http://www.rand.org/pubs/conf_proceedings/2005/RAND_CF215.pdf; Ashley J.
Tellis, Janice Bially, Christopher Layne, Melissa McPherson (2000) “Measuring
National Power in the Postindustrial Age”, RAND; Kelly M. Kadera and Gerald L.
Sorokin (2004) “Measuring National Power” International Interactions 30, 211-230;
David Baldwin (1989) The Paradoxes of Power, Basil Blackwell; Richard J. Stoll
69
power,” wrote Hans Morgenthau, “poses one of the most difficult and controversial
measure of relative national power should capture the features salient to the
particular theory under consideration.17 In this case, relative national power means
the power to coerce (to successfully impose regimes upon others), to influence
through trade and patronage, and to inspire institutional imitators, which assumes a
of relative national power would then focus on material resources that proxy for
Both military and economic measures of national power are flawed in their own
and Michael D. Ward, eds. (1989) Power in World Politics, Lynne Rienner; Michael
Handel (1981) Weak States in the International System, Frank Cass; Kjell Goldmann
and Gunnar Sjöstedt, eds. (1979) Power, Capabilities, Interdependence: Problems
in the Study of International Influence, Sage Publications. For non-materialist
approaches to the study of national power, see Michael Barnett and Raymond
Duvall (2005) “Power in International Politics” International Organization 59.1:39-
75; Michael Barnett and Raymond Duvall, eds. (2005) Power in Global
Governance, Cambridge University Press; Felix Berenskoetter and M.J. Williams,
eds. (2007) Power in World Politics, Routledge; Rodney Bruce Hall (2003) “Moral
Authority as a Power Source” International Organization 51.4:591-622.
16
Hans Morgenthau (1948) Politics Among Nations, Ch.1, New York: Alfred A.
Knopf
17
David Collier and Robert Adcock (1999) “Democracy and Dichotomies: A
Pragmatic Approach to Choices about Concepts” Annual Review of Political
Science 2: 537-565. On the primacy of concept analysis and case selection for
choosing methods of statistical inference, see Gary Goertz (2006) Social Science
Concepts: A User’s Guide, Princeton University Press. On “essentially contested”
concepts, see Walter Gallie (1956) “Essentially Contested Concepts” Proceedings of
the Aristotelian Society 56:167-98.
18
On the importance of the link between economic growth and military power, see
Paul Kennedy (1987) The Rise and Fall of Great Powers: Economic Change and
70
inefficiencies within militarily powerful states like the Soviet Union.19 Thus a
national power. CINC defines power as “the ability of a nation to exercise and
resist influence”. Stipulating that power and material capabilities are not identical,
the codebook nonetheless argues that “given their association it is essential that we
try to define the latter in operational terms so as to understand the former.”20 CINC
includes all states from 1816 to 2001 and incorporates six variables: total
population, urban population, iron and steel production, energy consumption (after
1859), number of military personnel, and military expenditure. The variables fall
into three categories of two variables each - demographic, industrial, and military.21
Military Conflict From 1500 to 2000, Random House. See also Emilio Casetti (2008)
“The Long-Run Dynamic of the Nexus between Military Strength and National
Power: An Econometric Analysis” Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society vol.
2008
19
This is particularly the case when military technology relies on technological and
economic investment. The historian Martin Walker has persuasively argued that the
lack of mass consumption in the USSR blunted the incentive for technological
advancement, which in turn prevented the country from successfully competing
with the United States in military technology. See Martin Walker (1995) The Cold
War: A History, Henry Holt and Company.
20
CINC Codebook, p.1; David J. Singer, Stuart Bremer, and John Stuckey (1972)
"Capability Distribution, Uncertainty, and Major Power War, 1820-1965." p. 19-48
in Bruce Russett, ed., Peace, War, and Numbers, Beverly Hills: Sage
21
Total population reflects the idea that “a large population can have a larger army,
maintain its home industries during times of war, and absorb losses in wartime
71
Where data was missing and the change rate could reasonably be assumed to be
categories are subject to criticism, particularly, as Wohlforth puts it, the “implicit
assumption that the wellsprings of national power have not changed since the
dawn of the industrial age”.23 But while Wohlforth correctly proposes to expand the
concept to include such measures as the number of patents granted or the number
of internet hosts per 1000 people, these additions are inappropriate for the time
frame of my analysis. Besides being an internally consistent measure that spans the
transitions.
easier than a state with a smaller population.” (Codebook p.21) Urban population
is a proxy for modernization: it is associated “with higher education standards and
life expectancies, with industrialization and industrial capacity, and with the
concentrated availability of citizens who may me mobilized during times of
conflict.” (p. 27)
22
CINC Codebook, p. 2. Geographic components of power (island, peninsular, and
land-locked states) were deemed too dyad-specific to be useful for cross-national
comparison, because they look at the relationships among states instead of national
characteristics. (p.3) Natural resources like arable land, climate, and other variable
availability are, according to the authors, already reflected in the indicators. (p.3)
23
William C. Wohlforth (1999) “The Stability of a Unipolar World” International
Security 24.1: 5-41. See also William C. Wohlforth (1987) “The Perception of
Power: Russia in the Pre-1914 Balance” World Politics 39.3:353-381.
72
Defining Hegemons
entity. I adopt the former definition – in this dissertation, a hegemon refers to a state
used here is a more exclusive term than the Correlates of War definition of a
“major power”, but more inclusive than the single-state definition adopted by, for
24
The first recorded usage in the OED, in 1904, implies several such states: “The
hegemon of the western hemisphere is the United States.”
25
The COW coding of major powers also omits countries during “shock years”, the
very period when their fortunes would shape institutional waves. The full COW
coding is USA 1898-2000; UK 1816-2000; France 1816-1940, 1945-2008,
Germany 1816-1918, 1925-1945, 1991-2008, Austria-Hungary 1816-1918, Italy
1860-1943, Russia 1816-1917, 1922-2008, China 1950-2008, Japan 1895-1945,
1991-2008. Mearsheimer (2001), on the other hand, defines a hegemon as “a state
that is so powerful that it dominates all the other states in the system”. John
Mearsheimer (2001) The Tragedy of Great Power Politics, W.W. Norton and
Company, p.40. (At the same time, Mearsheimer’s list of “the five dominant great
powers of the past 150 years” (p. 169) is very similar to mine, so this may be a
matter of semantics: United States 1800-1990; USSR 1917-1991; United Kingdom
1792-1945; Germany 1862-1945; and Japan 1868-1945.)
For other single-state definitions, see Robert Gilpin (1981) War and Change in
World Politics, Cambridge University Press, p.29 and William C. Wohlforth (1993)
The Elusive Balance: Power and Perceptions During the Cold War, Cornell
University Press, p.12-14. William Fox (1944) defined superpowers as countries
that possessed great capabilities and could challenge and fight each other on a
global scale. In his view, in 1943 the US, the UK, and the USSR were superpowers.
See William Fox (1944) The Super-Powers: the United States, Britain, and the
Soviet Union—their responsibility for peace. Harcourt, Brace Co. In the dissertation
I use the term “hegemon” and “great power” interchangeably.
73
The salient characteristic of a “pole” is that it is not merely a major power, but a
leading state with the capacity to impose regimes, influence other great powers,
and inspire institutional imitators. Following the general view that the system was
multipolar until World War Two and bipolar until the Soviet collapse26, hegemons
between the years 1816 and 2000 were labeled as: US 1898-2000; Russia/USSR
and Japan 1905-1945.27 When testing the effects of hegemonic shocks in the
multivariate model below, fascist hegemons (Germany and Japan) are restricted to
the period 1933-1945, while the communist hegemon (that is, the USSR) is
restricted to the period 1923-1990 – after all a hegemon cannot inspire institutional
Shocks clarify the balance of power, and in doing so reveal the leaders of the
international system. Theorists have argued that the balance of power is most
transparent after major wars, since, as Gilpin writes, “a hegemonic war is the
ultimate test of change in the relative standing of the powers in the existing
26
See, e.g., Waltz (1979) or Kennedy (1987) “The multipolar world of 1885 was
replaced by a bipolar world as early as 1943.” (Kennedy 1987:197, orig. emphasis)
27
A dataset extending beyond 2000 will have to grapple with the rise of China and
(to a lesser extent) India, but I consider the period between 1991 and 2000 to be
one of unchallenged American unipolarity.
28
Gilpin (1981) fn.80
74
shifts in the balance of power. I define a hegemonic shock as a sudden shift in the
distribution of relative power among the leading states in the international system.
Since the definition of a hegemon was discussed above, here I will focus on the
literature, “shocks” have traditionally been defined in the same way that Justice
Potter Stewart defined obscenity – we know them when we see them. In practice,
this has meant defining certain pre-designated years as “shock years” and using
dummy variables to separate them from non-shock years for the purposes of
regression analysis. For example, Gates et al (2007) define shock years in their
scores among the hegemons. More precisely, hegemonic volatility (HV) for a given
n
#i=1| CINC i, t " CINC i, t"1 |
HVt =
n
where n is the number of hegemonic states in a given year. This variable captures
measures that use dummy variables for pre-designated shock years. The figure
below shows hegemonic volatility smoothed over time (an average of that year’s
1917-1922, 1940-1947 (with some reverberations continuing into the 1950s), and
1989-1995. These represent my case selections of World War I, World War II, and
the Soviet Collapse (a case study to be completed at a later date). Although it does
not appear on the graph above, I have added another case, the Great Depression,
for the following reasons. First, due to the way the CINC index is constructed, it is
factors. Second, consistent with the demands of the theory, even when measured
via CINC relative U.S. power begins to decline beginning in the mid-1920s and
76
especially after 1929, while German power increases dramatically after Hitler’s
ascent to power in 1933. (See Figure 2.8) The period of the Great Depression thus
for the spread of democratization. While clarifying the case selection, hegemonic
regime types. The testable hypotheses that flow from examining hegemonic shocks
focus on the rise and fall of individual great powers. Namely, we would expect a
77
rise in power of a democratic hegemon (in this case, the United States 1900-2000)
decline in the power of the democratic hegemon, on the other hand, should lead to
a decrease in democratization. Similarly, the rise and fall of the communist and
fascist hegemons should lead to a rise and fall in the spread of communism and
fascism.
Conversely:
H2: A rise in the relative power of a hegemon leads to the spread of the hegemon’s
regime type around the world.
H2.1: The intensity of the hegemonic rise affects the magnitude of regime spread.
power for the state representing each regime type – democratic (the United States),
fascist (Nazi Germany) and communist (Soviet Russia). In the case of the U.S., the
total hegemonic power in a given system-year. In the case of Germany and the
USSR, their hegemonic share was calculated similarly, but only for those years in
which the hegemons actually represented the alternative regime types (USSR 1922-
1991, Germany 1933-1945), since these are the time periods salient to the theory
at hand. I used a single hegemon to represent each regime type, since they were
the leading representatives of their regimes that inspired others to follow suit, and
78
since it was their sudden rise and decline, as documented in the case studies, that
drive the waves. As a robustness check, the regression results were also tested with
France, and the U.S.) instead of only the United States, and all fascist great powers
(Germany and Japan). This operationalization was highly correlated with the one
used here, and produced very similar results. (See footnote 33, below.)
Figure 2.9: Shares of hegemonic power bounded by salient regime spans, United
States (1900-2000), Soviet Union (1922-1991), and Germany (1933-1945).
79
Change in US share of 1-year change in the U.S. share of 0.0073 0.0563 -0.105 0.427
hegemonic power hegemonic power
(cgusshare)
Average change of US share A 5-year average of change in the 0.0070 0.0274 -0.024 0.112
of hegemonic power U.S. share of hegemonic power
(avchusshare) (current year plus the four previous
years). Captures the overall trends
associated with hegemonic shocks.
German share of hegemonic German CINC score as a proportion 0.193 0.051 0.111 0.269
power, 1933-45 of the total CINC of hegemonic states
(grshare) in a given system-year
Average German share of A 5-year average of German share of 0.185 0.047 0.117 0.245
hegemonic power hegemonic power (current year plus
Nazi Germany
Bivariate Model
relationship between the amount of relative power wielded by the hegemons and
the spread of democratic, fascist, and communist states around the world. The U.S.
for example, a 10% increase in the share of U.S. hegemonic power is associated
with an increase in the global democratization average by nearly 0.7 points. (See
Coefficient
IV DV (std error)
U.S. share of Total average global Polity IV score, excluding the 6.95 (0.22)***
hegemonic power US
(1900-2000)
U.S. share of Total average Sip score, excluding the US 0.272
hegemonic power (0.026)***
(1900-2000)
Russian share of Global proportion of power, communist states 0.314
hegemonic power (excluding the USSR) (0.05)***
(1918-1991)
German share of Global proportion of power, fascist states 0.033
hegemonic power (excluding Germany) (0.01)***
(1933-1945)
Table 2.3. Systemic effects of hegemonic power.
81
Multivariate Model
The bivariate results are suggestive, but they cannot account for the influence of
other factors on democratization, nor can they provide much evidence of a causal
relationship between the two variables. Including GDP data in the results above,
for example, has some significant effects on the coefficients. To account for such
growth and political development is among the most robust findings in political
science, although scholars continue to debate the precise mechanisms that connect
the two. Economic development was measured by two factors – the log of per
capita GDP, and the level of urbanization. Per capita GDP data was taken from
population. Both population measures were obtained from the CINC dataset. In the
regression model the two economic development variables were lagged by a year.
Diffusion – the tendency for states to adopt the institutions of their neighbors –
account for its influence in a statistical model. Diffusion was measured in two ways
democracy over the previous year. This data was obtained from the replication
dataset by Gleditsch and Ward (2006).29 The diffusion variables, like the economic
variables – the number of years a country had existed with a democratic regime,
and the number of years it had existed with an autocratic regime. This data was
democracy. The spread of democracy has varied with geographic regions (see
because they control for “false diffusion.” As Brinks and Coppedge put it: “Any
become, or remain democratic; and this regional tendency could appear to be the
product of democratic diffusion within the region.”30 Geographic data was coded
by hand. Finally, colonial history and national culture were also coded by hand as
29
Kristian Gleditsch and Michael D. Ward. (2006) "Diffusion and the International
Context of Democratization" International Organization 60(4): 911-933.
Replication archive available at http://privatewww.essex.ac.uk/~ksg/publ.html.
30
Brinks and Coppedge (2006)
83
dummy variables. Five dummy variables were created to distinguish among former
British, French, Portuguese, Spanish or Dutch colonies. (Of these, former British
country was coded 1 if it had been one of those colonies, and 0 otherwise. Five
Catholic, Muslim, Greek Orthodox, and Buddhist countries, the country’s religion
serving as a proxy for national culture. (Of these, predominantly Muslim countries
are thought to have a consistently lower propensity for democracy.) Since the
British colony and Muslim variables are the most theory-relevant, most regressions
included only those two variables to avoid a including variables less salient for
testing the theory. Data for colonial history and national culture was coded using
data from the CIA World Factbook. Table 6 provides the summary statistics for
these control variables (excluding the geographic and national culture dummies.)
models is the U.S. share of hegemonic power. The first model uses just one
additional control variable, the log of per capita GDP in thousand of dollars, lagged
significant (as it is in the other model variations). A ten percent increase in the
share of US power is associated with a 0.68 rise in the average country’s Polity
score.
The second model adds variables that control for regional and neighborhood
previous year, and the percent of a country’s democratic neighbors (also lagged by
a year). It also includes regional dummies to account for regional diffusion (not
adds regime duration to the control variables in Model 2, in order to account for
institutional inertia within countries. Previous research has shown that experience
autocracy. Model 4 adds variables that account for colonial history (a series of
dummies for British, French, Portuguese, Spanish, and Dutch colonies; not shown)
85
Finally, Model 5 uses the control variables in Model 4 but uses change in US share
of hegemonic power as the main independent variable (the derivative of the level
democracy.
Table 2.5: Country-level effects of hegemonic power. All variables measured 1900-
2000. DV is Polity score, rescaled to 0-20. * significant at the 90% level; **
significant at the 95% level; ***significant at the 99% level
86
As the below results show, the share of U.S. hegemonic power, and changes
different specifications, and using a variety of control variables. The U.S. share of
hegemonic power appears to have an effect at the individual country level, and this
effect remains significant even when all other variables are included. In line with
(they have been omitted from the display to simplify the presentation.)31 The share
robust standard errors, and when a lag of the dependent variable is included in the
analysis.32 It remained significant for both measures of democracy, the Polity and
the SIP score. The models were also run using an alternative measure of
31
In general, French, Spanish and Portuguese colonies have negative coefficients;
British and Dutch colonies have positive but statistically insignificant coefficients.
32
Including a lag of the dependent variable is not generally recommended because
it is highly correlated with the DV and inflates the r-squared. It can be used as a
robustness check, however, since it “soaks up” a lot of the variance and can reveal
which variables remain significant when the lag is included.
87
regime type, measures of hegemonic shares were expanded to included other great
Model 5 was re-run with fixed effects, yielding the results below.
33
To do so I created a variable called demshare, which included the share of
hegemonic power of the democratic great powers – the U.S., Britain, and France;
and fascshare, which included the share of hegemonic power of Germany and
Japan between the years 1933-1945. Since the USSR was the only communist great
period during this period, this variation was not necessary for communist regimes.
Demshare had a similar effect on the average level of democracy as the U.S. share,
and was substantively and statistically significant in the model variations used
above. (Not surprisingly, since the correlation coefficients between usshare and
demshare was 0.67) Likewise, when fascshare is substituted for grshare in the fixed-
effects model, the coefficient is negative (as expected) and statistically significant at
the 95% confidence interval.
88
German hegemonic power are substituted as the main independent variable, their
coefficients are large and statistically significant but negative, as the theory
predicts.34
tested directly by looking at the rate of coerced regime promotions after military
promotion by great powers in the closing months and immediately following both
world wars.
promotion (CRP). Measurement is slightly complicated by the fact that there are
two equally valid ways to count these cases – the number of promoters or the
number of targets. First, we might add up the number of states imposing regimes
upon others, then see how many of those states are hegemons, and then see how
many of those hegemons were imposing their own regimes. Second, we might add
34
As a robustness check, the fixed-effects models were run with two variations of
the main independent variable: a one-year change in the level of hegemonic
power, and the average five-year change in the share of hegemonic power. These
models were also run with a lag of the dependent variable on the right-hand side.
In all cases, the main independent variable remained statistically significant.
89
up the number of states experiencing or undergoing CRPs, then see how of those
cases involve hegemons, and how many cases in that subset were countries
they are not always equivalent – a number of states may try to impose a regime on
a single state (Albania in 1912 for example); conversely, a single state may try to
impose a regime on more than one state during the same year (USSR in 1945).
The list of promoters and targets was taken from Owen 2002 and 2010 and
supplemented by a few cases left out of the dataset.35 To obtain a rough measure of
overall regime promotion intensity, I multiplied the two measures together, so that,
for example, if two countries were promoting a regime in three other states, the
total intensity score was six. The total regime promotion intensity for all states is
35
See John Owen (2002) “The Foreign Imposition of Domestic Institutions”
International Organization 56.2:375-409 and John Owen (2010) The Clash of Ideas
in World Politics: Transnational Networks, States, and Regime Change 1510-2010,
Princeton University Press. I have added four omitted cases: USSR in Mongolia
(1921); US in Nicaragua (1954), US and Britain in Iran (1953), and US in Chile
(1973). These do not significantly affect the results since all but the first instance
were not mimetic impositions.
90
There are three visible spikes (after the two world wars and another in the late
1960s.) The next step is to isolate those instances of regime coercion in which great
powers are promoting their own regimes. The frequency of mimetic impositions by
Graphing the salient variable yields the posited results: mimetic regime impositions
by great powers are much more likely to occur in the wake of military hegemonic
shocks.36 The table below breaks down the number of promotions by the relevant
categories (“shock” years are counted as the last year of the war and the following
two years, or 1918-1920 and 1944-1946, for a total of six shock years):
36
Great power impositions in general are much more likely after hegemonic
shocks. The graph of total regime impositions (mimetic and non-mimetic) by great
powers is virtually identical to Figure 2.11. It is displayed in Appendix 4.
92
regime coercion in the twentieth century: of the 121 instances of regime coercion
during this period, great powers were promoters in 72 of the cases. However, great
and in 31 of those cases the promoter was a great power.37 Moreover, great powers
are much more likely to promote their own regimes in the wake of shocks – of the
intervention during non-shock years, they imposed their own regime in 27 cases
(about 66%). Dividing by the number of years, in an average shock year there were
37
The number of impositions is higher than the umber of countries promoting
regimes because in many instances the same country (particularly the US and the
USSR) attempted to impose its regime on multiple countries.
38
The two exceptions being Japan in Russia (1918) and the USSR in Austria (1945).
93
4.8 mimetic impositions by a great power, and only 0.28 such impositions in an
In short, great powers act differently after hegemonic shocks. They are more
likely to impose regimes during hegemonic transitions, and when they do so they
are more likely to impose their own regimes than in non-shock years. The reasons
for this, as suggested in the previous chapter, stem from the temporary decrease in
the costs and increased likelihood of success in the wake of hegemonic shocks.
These findings both complement and build upon the recent literature on
external regime impositions. Over the past decade or so, perhaps inspired by the
has been pessimistic about the effect of coerced regime imposition on domestic
stability. For example, Pickering and Peceny (2006) examine regime promotions by
the U.S., Britain, France, and the U.N. Between 1946 and 1996. 40 “Most scholars
doubt that military intervention can lead to democracy,” they write. “Many are
They find that UN interventions are more likely to result in democracy than
They argue, however, that this relationship is driven by three cases in the
39
A difference-of-means test between mimetic hegemonic impositions in shock vs.
non-shock years reveals (unsurprisingly) that the difference is statistically
significant.
40
Jeffrey Pickering and Mark Peceny (2006) “Forging Democracy at Gunpoint”
International Studies Quarterly 50:539-559
41
Pickering and Peceny 2006:539
94
Caribbean, only one of which (Panama in 1989) created a stable democracy. They
conclude that there is “little evidence that military intervention by liberal states
helps to foster democracy in target countries” and argue that “the evidence
presented here offers a cautionary tale for those determined to forge democracy at
implications for the survival of the intervening leader and the type of government
institutions in the target states that interventions are most likely to produce.
Examining state and UN interventions between 1946 and 2001, they find that
external military intervention “does little to promote democracy and often leads to
its erosion and the substitution of largely symbolic reforms”. 44 Likewise, in a study
of superpower interventions during the Cold War, Easterly et al (2008) find that
intervention by either the United States or the USSR both decreased the likelihood
cases of regime imposition since 1920 and find that interventions increase the risk
of civil war because they damage the infrastructural power of the state.46 They
42
Pickering and Peceny 2006:539,556
43
Bruce Bueno de Mesquita and George W. Downs (2006) “Intervention and
Democracy” International Organization 60:627-49
44
Bueno de Mesquita and Downs 2006:647
45
William Easterly, Shanker Satyanath, and Daniel Berger (2008) “Superpower
Interventions and their Consequences for Democracy: An Empirical Inquiry” NBER
Working Paper 13992, p.1
46
Goran Peic and Dan Reiter (2010) “Foreign-Imposed Regime Change, State
Power and Civil War Onset, 1920-2004” British Journal of Political Science
95
conclude that interventions that follow interstate wars and change the target state’s
complicated by the problem of selection effects - since outsiders are more likely to
intervene in states that are experiencing problems, these targets of intervention are
also more likely to experience failed consolidations and civil wars afterwards,
an unpublished working paper, Downes (2011) accounts for these selection effects
through matching procedures, and finds that foreign interventions can promote
regime stability when outside powers are seeking to restore previous rulers.
However, when they are seeking to depose the current ruler and install a new
government, civil war becomes more than three times as likely. This happens
impositions of domestic regime occur in waves, and describes three such waves
47
Peic and Reiter 2010:22
48
For a similar approach to examining the effects of peace-keeping on civil wars,
see Virginia Page Fortna (2008) Does Peacekeeping Work? Shaping Belligerents’
Choices after Civil War, Princeton University Press
49
Alexander B. Downes (2011) “Catastrophic Success:Foreign-Imposed Regime
Change and Civil War” Working Paper, draft March 29, 2011, p.1
50
John M. Owen (2010) The Clash of Ideas in World Politics: Transnational
Networks, States, and Regime Change 1510-2010, Princeton University Press
96
regime types - the first between 1520 and 1650 (catholics vs. protestants); the
second between 1770 and 1850 (republics vs. constitutional monarchies vs.
absolute monarchies; and the third between 1917 and the present day (democracy
vs. fascism vs. communism. Owen argues that the incidence of foreign regime
promotion “rises steeply during periods of great-power struggle, either hot or cold
different conclusion about the causes of the waves of regime impositions. These
regime types, but they occur in the immediate aftermath of the struggle rather than
during its course. In particular, mimetic regime impositions by great powers occur
once the struggle has been decisively concluded via interstate war. Great powers
most notably, during the Cold War - but these interventions are far less
concentrated in time. At least for the twentieth century, Owen’s argument requires
struggles, but mimetic impositions occur directly after these struggles, and tend to
be more clustered in time. These latter sorts of imposition are what produce the
51
Owen 2010:24
52
Owen 2010:27
97
and emulation) to the larger waves of regime change that follow hegemonic
shocks.
These results also have some implications for the study of state death and the
associated with buffer states caught between states with enduring rivalries.53
Hegemonic shocks have also frequently been associated with the death and birth of
states – World War I, for instance, destroyed the continental empires of central and
eastern Europe and created a number of new nation-states from their remnants. The
fascist wave culminated in the forced annexation and death of a number of states
across Europe. Hegemonic shocks, in other words, may create unique conditions
Fazal has also argued that violent state death has virtually ceased after 1945
because of a norm against conquest. This suggests that while shocks create
incentives for hegemonic coercion, the nature of that coercion (that is, whether it
international system – and that these shifts are guided by the changing behaviors of
the rising hegemons. The same mechanisms that lead to institutional waves may
also create cascades of norm change. Because norms are inherently social
constructs, and because they are associated with persuasion instead of power,
53
Tanisha Fazal (2007) State Death: The Politics and Geography of Conquest,
Occupation, and Annexation, Princeton University Press
98
literature to conflate power with coercion – and since social constructs cannot be
coerced, material power does not play an important role in these discussions. Yet
power can and does influence normative changes in complicated ways, some of
which may have nothing to do with brute force. States may imitate the norms of
rising hegemons for similar reasons that they imitate their institutions – to copy
their success, to attract allies, or to gain legitimacy in the eyes of their peers.
Hegemonic shocks can thus shift the normative preferences of domestic actors and
prominent example, the sudden collapse of the Soviet Union discredited the
normative basis for communism among its fellow travelers in the developing world,
contributing to a normative shift toward democracy. Today, illiberal states pay lip
service to the importance of national elections even when the elections themselves
are subject to a variety of political constraints. In this case, the sudden decline in
with persuasion while conflating power with coercion ignores the complexity of
these influences.
Overall, the above analysis suggests that the literature on regime impositions
would benefit from a closer look at its interaction with interstate war and the
between external impositions, interstate wars, and systemic peace. Lo, Hashimoto
and Reiter (2008), for example find that peace is more durable following interstate
warranted, but they may benefit from distinguishing interventions that take place in
the wake of hegemonic shocks from those that do not. Interventions after major
wars occur at a time when the rising hegemons are at their most powerful and most
are not. The U.S. occupation of Germany encountered no native opposition at least
in part due to the nature of the war and the total defeat that accompanied its
conclusion. In his book Embracing Defeat, the historian John Dower has argued
that the success of the U.S. occupation of Japan after World War II was shaped at
least in part by the nature of the war that proceeded it, and the decisive defeat that
brought the war to an end.55As I will argue in Chapter 5, the Soviet occupation of
Eastern Europe was legitimized in part by the nature of the Soviet victory in that
conflict. These factors simply do not come into play with interventions that occur
in the absence of major interstate wars. In short, the effect of hegemonic shocks on
54
Nigel Lo, Barry Hashimoto, and Dan Reiter (2008) “Ensuring Peace: Foreign-
Imposed Regime Change and Post-War Peace Duration, 1914-2001” International
Organization 62.4:717-36
55
John Dower (1999) Embracing Defeat: Japan in the Wake of World War II, W.W.
Norton & Company
100
the propensity for external impositions to produce lasting regime change requires
future consideration.
Conclusion
pay close attention to a particular systemic influence that shapes and constrains
domestic regime outcomes – the hegemonic share of power, and sudden changes
within the level of that power. This variable remains significant under a number of
model specifications and measures of the dependent variable. In the case studies
that follow, I will examine the effects of hegemonic power in more detail, focusing
Austria - 1933-1944
Bulgaria - 1934-1944
Germany - 1933-1944
Hungary - 1938-1944
Italy - 1922-43
Japan - 1936-1945
Portugal - 1934-73
Romania - 1940-44
Spain - 1936-75
Albania - 1939-1944
Belgium – occupied May 28 1940 to end of 1944 (1940-44)
Czechoslovakia - 1939-1944
Denmark - 1940-44
France May 1940 to December 1944
Greece April 1941 to October 1944 (1941-44)
The Netherlands - May 10 1940 to beginning of 1945 (1940-44)
Norway - 1940-44
Poland October 1939 to early 1945 (1940-44)
Yugoslavia (incl independent state of Croatia 1941-43) – April 17, 1941 to May
1945 (1941-44)
Philippines - April 1942 to December 1944 (1942-44)
Thailand - December 1941 to June 1944 (1942-44)
Afghanistan - 1978-1991
Albania - 1946-1991
Angola - 1976-1992
Benin - 1976-1989
Bulgaria - 1947-1990
Cambodia - 1976-1991
China since 1950
Congo - 1970-1991
Cuba since 1959
Czechoslovakia - 1948-1989
Ethiopia - 1975-1990
Eastern Germany - 1950-1990
Greece - 1948-49
Grenada - 1979-1983
102
Hungary - 1950-1989
Laos since 1976
Mongolia - 1925-1991
Mozambique - 1975-1990
North Korea since 1948
Poland - 1945-1989
Romania - 1948-1989
Somalia - 1976-1990
USSR - 1921-1991
Republic of Vietnam - 1954-1975
Yemen’s People Republic - 1968-1989
Vietnam since 1976
Yugoslavia - 1945-1991
103
Figure A1: Regional variations in the spread and retreat of democracy, 1900-2000.
56
See, e.g. John O'Loughlin, Michael D. Ward, Corey L. Lofdahl, Jordin S. Cohen,
David S. Brown, David Reilly, Kristian S. Gleditsch, Michael Shin (1998) “The
Diffusion of Democracy, 1946-1994” Annals of the Association of American
Geographers 88.4:545-574
104
Despite the differences, at least some of the waves are present in all the regions. In
the Western countries, which democratized earliest, there is a peak around World
War I and a trough in the 1930s, culminating in an all-time low in the early years
of World War II and a rapid democratic recovery at the end of the war. Central and
Eastern Europe experiences a rapid increase, followed by rollback, after both wars;
spread of democracy in the early 1990s. Sub-Saharan Africa, on the other hand,
states at the beginning of the century) and declines throughout most of the
twentieth century as new states enter the region, but experiences a rapid wave in
the 1990s. Asia experiences bursts of democratization after World War II and
during the 1990s. Central and South America stagnate during much of the
twentieth century, and experience democratic waves in the 1990s; the Caribbean
decline and recovery in the 1960s. The Middle East shows distinct waves, with
rollbacks, in the early years of the twentieth century and after World War II,
hegemony (measured in two ways: the level of U.S. hegemonic share, and the
change in the level of US hegemonic share averaged over the preceding five years).
The first two columns show the results of a simple bivariate regression for each
105
region. The last two columns show regression results that include a measure of the
The results show a strong relationship between the two variables, with some
Africa, although the effect is weaker in the Caribbean. When regional wealth is
57
Includes Western Europe, Scandinavia, and the settler colonies: U.S., Canada,
Australia, and New Zealand.
106
taken into account, the relationship remains strong everywhere except in Asia (and
This appendix replicates the results found in Gleditsch and Ward (2006) and adds a
first replicate Model 1 (found on page 925) of the article, then replicate the same
model with the addition of a variable that captures changes in the level of
American hegemonic power. They employ a Markov chain model that looks at
democracy. A replication of their results thus offers a direct test of the idea that
hegemonic power has an effect on the spread of democracy distinct from diffusion
processes as a whole. It also biases the results against a positive finding for my
variable, since the variables they use (see table below) are likely to correlate very
closely with variables associated with the effects of hegemonic power. Second, the
independent variable used in the model is dichotomous, which doesn’t capture the
transitions. For these two reasons, the replication is thus a “hard case” for my
theory, since the model is biased against positive results for my variables.
variable used in the replication, two are not statistically significant. A third,
58
Kristian Skrede Gleditch and Michael D. Ward (2006) “Diffusion and the
International Context of Democratization” International Organization 60.4:911-933
108
statistically significant, and shows that increases in the rate of U.S. hegemonic
power make democracies less likely to break down, consistent with the predictions
generated by the theory. The result is substantively large – the coefficient of this
variable is bigger than any of the other independent variables used in their model.
These results suggest that at the very least levels of hegemonic power deserve a
Here, the beta coefficient represents the likelihood that a democracy will
endure, while the gamma coefficient represents the likelihood that an autocracy
down (contrary to their prediction, with beta = -0.550) but also significantly
decreases the likelihood that autocracies will endure (with gamma = -0.687)
59
The gamma coefficient is calculated by adding the beta coefficient and the alpha
coefficient (the coefficient of the interaction term for that variable).
109
Next, I replicated this model with the addition of a measure of U.S. hegemonic
power. I used three variations: a lag of the U.S. share of hegemonic power
(lusshare), change in the share of U.S. hegemonic power (chusshare), and a running
(avchusshare). Ex ante, the last measure appears to be the most likely candidate,
since it measures changes in the rate of change over a five year-period and thus is
significant at the 10% level and more importantly, possessed the expected signs:
Here, a sudden increase in the US share of power increases the likelihood that
democracies will endure. (The other two measures were not statistically significant,
although substantively they had the expected signs.) The coefficient (in bold) is very
coefficient is larger than all the other variables except the global proportion of
110
democracies. It also decreases the likelihood that autocracies will endure, but the
effect is not statistically significant. Given the aforementioned factors that bias the
quantitative studies should further examine the effects of hegemonic power on the
This graph shows the intensity of regime impositions by great powers. It is virtually
identical to Figure 2.11, but includes both mimetic and non-mimetic impositions.
The graph demonstrates that all hegemonic interventions cluster after hegemonic
CHAPTER 3
“The year 1918 marked a bright and conspicuous date in the annals of
our history. After a series of successes which seemed to forecast their
eventual triumph, our aggressors suddenly foundered in a cataclysm
which at a single blow destroyed the oldest monarchies of Europe.”
-- Gustave Le Bon (1921)1
The first democratic wave of the twentieth century found an unexpected origin in
the immense destruction of the Great War. The postwar flowering of democratic
regimes on the European continent was a period of hope born from tragedy, a
accompanied the end of the war was intense, widespread, ambitious – and
1
Gustave Le Bon (1921) The World in Revolt: A Psychological Study of Our Times,
transl. by Bernard Miall, New York: The Macmillan Company, p.9
2
T.V. Smith (1927) “Review of Democracy Under Revision by H.G. Wells” The
Social Service Review 1.4:665
113
European states emerged from the ruins of collapsed empires (See Figure 3.1) and
suffrage. At the same time, semi-democracies like Britain and Belgium expanding
voting rights to previously excluded groups like women and working-class men.
The spirit of postwar democratic optimism was so strong that a year after the
armistice, British politician and historian James Bryce wondered whether the “trend
toward democracy now widely visible is a natural trend, due to a general law of
social progress”.3
3
James Bryce (1921) Modern Democracies, Vol.1, New York: Macmillan, p.24.
114
believe that an era of democracy had indeed dawned on the continent. The
poet writing in 1919 could not “dare to speak of kings and queens / Democracy is
now the card”.4 Returning to the United States after his triumphant European tour,
heart and understanding” of both masses and rulers, and imagined the Founding
Fathers “looking on with a sort of enraptured amazement that the American spirit
The wave of postwar democratization was driven by two factors related to the
outcome of the war. First, the collapse of ill-glued6 monarchical empires created a
ability to mobilize masses and triumph over powerful enemies, the leaders of these
new states looked to democratic institutions as the way to harness the postwar spirit
4
Richard de Gallienne (1919) “Ballade of the Modern Bard” Harper’s Magazine,
October, p. 761
5
Woodrow Wilson, Speech of September 6 1919, quoted in G. John Ikenberry
(2000) After Victory: Institutions, Strategic Restraint, and the Rebuilding of Order
After Major Wars, Princeton University Press, p.158
6
To borrow Jacques Barzun’s description of Austria-Hungary. Jacques Barzun
(2000) From Dawn to Decadence: 500 Years of Western Cultural Life from 1500 to
the Present, Harper Perennial, p.690
115
international and domestic respectability. “Four great empires in Europe, all ruled
by ancient dynasties, crash to the ground,” wrote Bryce, “and we see efforts made
to build up out of the ruins new States, each of which is enacting for itself a
theater and now loomed large across the continent. By joining the democratic
camp, the new states also hoped to secure American financial assistance and
Wilson’s democratic vision provided the ideological basis for the reforms.
Europeans “who had been long tried, confused, bereaved,” write Palmer et al,
“were stirred by Wilson’s thrilling language in favor of a higher cause.”9 In the new
and legitimacy.10
Second, the war led to democratizing reforms via the mobilization of women
and labor in partial democracies. As leaders of the Allied countries soon realized,
7
Bryce 1921:4-5. These were the Hohenzollern, Austro-Hungarian, Russian and
Ottoman empires.
8
J.M. Roberts (1999) Twentieth Century: The History of the World, 1901 to 2000,
Viking, p.283
9
R. R. Palmer, Joel Colton, and Lloyd S. Kramer (2002) A History of the Modern
World, 9th edition, McGraw-Hill, p.687-8
10
In an empirical analysis, Gates et al find that states created by the war were
much more democratic that the average pre-war regime. Scott Gates, Håvard
Hegre, Mark P. Jones, Håvard Strand, “Democratic Waves? Global Patterns of
Democratization, 1800-2000,” paper prepared for delivery at the National Political
Science Conference, January 2007, Trondheim, Norway, p.14. For similar
arguments, see Palmer et al 2002:746 and Raymond Sontag (1970) A Broken
World: 1919-39, HarperCollins, p.66.
116
prolonged, materiel-heavy war. For the first time since the wars of Napoleon,
demanded mass armies, and industry absorbed massive amounts of labor. Triumph
would require the cooperation of the labor class. For workers, this newfound
expectation that a higher standard of living “must emerge with the coming of
led to victory, they would be rewarded with political freedom and welfare
measures. As the hostilities ended, labor was more unified, better organized, “and
in a position to back its demands with threats.”12 The Allied victory cemented the
wartime bargain and made the expansion of political rights inevitable in the short
term.
In the space of a few years, the alchemy of war had transformed the laborer into
a union worker, the housewife into a suffragette, the emperor into a relic. At the
onset of the conflict, Europe had only three states that could be called
democracies; by the end, the number had grown to sixteen. (See Figures 3.2 and
3.3)13
11
Dietrich Rueschmeyer, Evelyne Huber Stephens, and John D. Stephens (1992)
Capitalist Development and Democracy, University of Chicago Press, p. 91-2; See
also Sandra Halperin (2004) War and Social Change in Modern Europe: The Great
Transformation Revisited, Cambridge University Press, p.154
12
Halperin 2004:171
13
Norman Davies (1996) Europe: A History, Oxford University Press, p. 943. The
precise numbers vary with differing definitions of democracy, but the overall trend
117
remains the same. According to Nancy Berneo, by 1920 twenty-six out of twenty-
eight European states were parliamentary democracies. (She notes that by 1938,
thirteen of these democracies had become dictatorships.) Nancy Bermeo (1997)
“Getting Mad or Going Mad? Citizens, Scarcity and the Breakdown of Democracy
in Interwar Europe” Center for the Study of Democracy, paper 97.06. Huntington
(1991:17) writes that 17 countries had adopted democratic institutions between
1915 and 1931, but only four of these had retained them through the 1930s.
Peceny notes that the number of democracies “nearly doubled” in 1919, although
almost all of these new democratic regimes collapsed by the end of the 1930s.
Mark Peceny (2010) “Democratizing During Hard Times: Germany’s Transition to
Democracy in the Wake of the First World War” Paper presented at the 106th
Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, September 2-5,
2010, Washington, D.C., p.1.
118
But the countries that formed the democratic wave of 1918-1923 pursued two
distinct trajectories. New states formed from imperial ruins adopted radically
democratic institutions but saw failures and reversals in the late 1920s and the
1930s. The causes for this failure, as I argue later in this chapter, were embedded in
the dynamics that created the wave in the first place. The outcome of the war had
and social conditions for democratic consolidation were absent. Optimistic leaders,
swept up in the tide of national self-determination and democratic rhetoric after the
119
war adopted institutions that their countries had little chance of sustaining. These
stability, ethnic cooperation, and past experience with democratic “rules of the
caused by the Great Depression. But even inside countries where economic
collapse was the final nail in democracy’s coffin, problems began well before
1929. “The new states hatched at Versailles,” writes Tony Judt, “were fragile and
were short-lived, unstable, and ineffective. Interwar Romania, for example, saw
and cultural illiteracy prevailed,” writes Fritz Stern. “[T]here was an insufficient
economic and social conditions and democratic politics.”16 The defeat of the
and eastern European countries that socially and economically (except for
Czechoslovakia) were not ready for them and hence they did not last long.”17
14
Tony Judt (2005) Postwar: A History of Europe Since 1945, Penguin Press, p.195
15
Andrew C. Janos (1970) “The One-Party State and Social Mobilization” in
Samuel Huntington and Clement Moore, eds., Authoritarian Politics in Modern
Society: The Dynamics of Established One-Party Systems, Basic Books, p. 207
16
Fritz Stern (1997) “The new democracies in crisis in interwar Europe” in Axel
Hadenius, ed., Democracy’s Victory and Crisis, Cambridge University Press, p.17
17
Huntington 1991:86. I discuss Czechoslovakia as an exception that proves the
rule later in this chapter.
120
before the war – many in western and northern Europe – successfully expanded
their suffrage and developed the first elements of the welfare state. In contrast to
their east and central European peers, states like Canada, Belgium, and Great
Britain managed to consolidate their postwar democratic gains with few internal
reversals. These states, Frieden notes, “faced fewer postwar difficulties than eastern
and central Europe.” Even territories most affected by fighting like Belgium and
northern France saw the rapid resumption of economic activity. Despite a recession
Europe had essentially recovered.”18 Most of these states also had substantial
experience with democracy and a large middle class that moderated political
volatility. In these countries, the major shift toward autocracy came two decades
later, during the Nazi occupation at the beginning of World War II. By contrast,
“the little countries that emerged from the collapse of the old land empires in 1918
were poor, unstable, insecure – and resentful of their neighbors.”19 The main long-
term effect of the war, therefore, was to make proto-democracies more democratic
without creating any sustainable new democracies. It did, however, give many
countries a preview of democratic institutions that would return later in the century
The remainder of the chapter is divided into four sections. I first examine the
18
Jeffry A. Frieden (2006) Global Capitalism: Its Fall and Rise in the Twentieth
Century, W.W. Norton, p.138-9
19
Judt 2005:4
121
hegemonic transition that occurred as a result of the war, focusing on the decline of
France, and particularly the United States. I then turn to a study of the mobilization
next section examines the creation of new democracies out of the ruins of
European empires. Finally, I examine the failed consolidations and the democracy
The war’s outcome raised the prestige of democratic institutions for old and
new states alike. The postwar shift in the distribution of power (see Figure 3.4)
made democratic regimes more powerful, more able to exercise global influence,
and more appealing all at once. It was the Great War, argues Fritz Stern, “that saw
the battlefield and on the factory floor, it suggested that democratic institutions
20
Stern 1997:15
122
Figure 3.4: US and German shares of hegemonic power, 1900-1930. The period
between 1918 and 1923 shows a rapid hegemonic transition with a German
decline and an American surge.
This outcome seemed far from inevitable in 1914. The conventional wisdom of
the day argued that democracy was paralyzed by checks and balances and stymied
mobilizing men and resources for a major conflict. This idea of “democratic
defeatism” persisted since the earliest writings on politics.21 In his account of the
Alexis de Tocqueville, E.H. Carr, George Kennan, and Walter Lippmann all shared
21
Michael Desch (2002) “Democracy and Victory: Why Regime Type Hardly
Matters” International Security 27.2, p.5
22
See especially the discussion of the Sicilian debate. Thucydides, The
Peloponnesian War, book 7
123
the belief that democratic institutions failed to adequately prepare countries for
wars. Even democracy’s supporters admitted that its benefits “are not secured
without very considerable sacrifices,” as the U.S. Assistant Secretary of War for
Industrial Relations wrote in 1916. “As a political system it is clumsy and inefficient
rule:
“Today the great war is being waged between German autocracy and English
science under democratic control,” concluded the author. “We shall not know
until after the terms of peace have been announced which of the two is the more
efficient.”25 This view reflected the perception of many political leaders. As Senator
Henry Cabot Lodge noted in 1915,“if democracy is not both able and ready to
defend itself it will go down in subjection before military autocracy because the
latter is then the more efficient.”26 The vital test of any regime, wrote the historian
23
Ernest Martin Hopkins (1916) “Democracy and Industry” Annals of the American
Academy of Political and Social Science, Vol.65, p.60
24
Robert W. Bruere (1917) “Can Democracy Be Efficient?” Harper’s Magazine
195.2, p. 821. This idea has a long history, stretching back to Aristotle’s Politics,
and made a forceful return in the Great Depression.
25
Bruere 1917, p. 825
26
Henry Cabot Lodge (1915) “Force and Peace” Annals of the American Academy
124
and diplomat George Beer in 1916, is not the character of its internal politics but its
fail in this crisis, its fate would be sealed and America would become the last
bulwark of free government.”27 President Wilson too saw the war as a test for
democracy and a struggle between two competing visions of the future. In a 1918
speech, he described the United States as the “practitioner of the new creed of
mankind” and Germany as the “most consistent practitioner of the old”. The war,
he said, was a “battle to determine whether the new democracy or the old
autocracy shall govern the world.”28 As the United States entered the fight,
So, at last, the giant democracies of western Europe and the giant
absolutisms of central Europe confronted each other on the fields of
France and Flanders in life and death grapple….Democracy or
dynasty will be sovereign, from this time on.29
The war provided the century’s first Manichean confrontation between two rival
ideologies of the state. Now that monarchy has passed into the realm of
challenge to democracy. But at the start of the century, conservative autocracy still
held sway in much of Europe and “dynasty” was the default form of government for
new states. Norway chose a king after gaining independence from Sweden in 1908,
as did Albania when it seceded from Turkey in 1913. With the exception of France
and Switzerland, until 1914 continental Europe remained monarchical; despite the
spread of parliaments, “parliamentary control over political life was far from
guaranteed; emperors and kings still ruled through their chancellors and prime
ministers.”30
enlightened monarchy. As the historian Paul Kennedy notes, on the eve of the war
Germany was the only great power that combined “the modern, industrialized
contemporaries as the model of a scientific and highly organized state.32 Urging the
typifying “the greatest military efficiency the world has ever seen.”33
30
Palmer et al 2002:587
31
Paul Kennedy (1989) The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers: Economic Change
and Military Conflict from 1500 to 2000, New York: Random House, p.214
32
The widespread American admiration of Imperial Germany, and particularly its
administrative efficiency, is documented in Ido Oren (2003) Our Enemies and US:
America’s Rivalries and the Making of Political Science, Ch 1, Ithaca: Cornell
University Press. As Oren notes, prominent pre-war American political scientists
like John Burgess and Woodrow Wilson admired elements of the German regime,
and the decisive break with the Germanophile tradition came as a result of the
conflict between the two countries.
33
Oswald Garrison Villard (1916) “Preparedness Is Militarism” Annals of the
American Academy of Political and Social Science Vol.66, p.217. In a study of pre-
war military reforms, Resende-Santos notes that Imperial Germany provided the
model of military emulation for Japan, Chile, Ecuador, Argentina, Bolivia,
Paraguay, and Brazil. Joao Resende-Santos (2007) Neorealism, States, and the
126
Redfield argued in 1915, Germany had become one of the three great global
traders of the day, along with Great Britain and the United States.34 Moreover, the
competence, utilizing her resources in men and material more effectively than
work. It was not highly organized in the German sense.” And while he was
conceded that the United States “did not use the scientific methods of Germany,
This Teutonic capacity for organization was often linked to the centralized
nature of the German state. Thorstein Veblen, in his 1915 book Imperial Germany
and the Industrial Revolution, sought to explain Germany’s “industrial advance and
high efficiency”.36 How, Veblen asked, did the country achieve such a dominant
economic position on the continent in so brief a time? The answer was to be found
system. England’s industrialization was achieved slowly, haltingly, and with the
centralized state was able to “concentrate and push forward the economic
classes.37
Germany’s pre-eminence before the war made its defeat all the more
momentous, its disgrace all the more visible. It lost the war, the empire, and any
prestige it had gained during its rise over the past five decades. Its economy was in
ruins, its political leadership discredited. Just before the war “German commerce
Hamburg Chamber of Commerce in 1920. But the war “brought the powerful
machinery of our commerce to a sudden stop…. On account of the war and the
subsequent peace treaty of Versailles our commerce has lost its means of
percent of its pre-war levels. The loss of the Saar region and Alsace-Lorraine
37
Walter Gurian (1939) “Review: Aspects of German Policies” The Review of
Politics 1.4, p.495
38
F.H. Witthoefft (1920) “Our Commercial Situation” Annals of the American
Academy of Political and Social Science Vol. 92, p.96
128
course of a few years, Germany “plunged from a position on the world market that
was second only to Britain, and threatening to replace it,” wrote the economic
historian Paul Hehn, “to almost a second or third-class power.”40 Its political
If the war offered a powerful test of rival regimes, its outcome supplied a clear
and dramatic answer. Germany’s precipitous decline dealt “a last blow to the
other hand, emerged as the clear winner. Only democracies had endured the
conflict with their political systems intact, and “now stood alone in appearing to
maintain political continuity,” notes Markoff.43 France, Britain, and the United
States “towered over the world,” writes Sontag. “Very quickly, it became usual to
speak of the Big Three – Woodrow Wilson, David Lloyd George, and Georges
Clemenceau – as the peacemakers who would shape a new and better world on
39
M.J. Bonn (1920) “The Main Features of Germany’s Economic and Financial
Situation” Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, Vol.92,
p.106
40
Paul N. Hehn (2002) A low dishonest decade: the great powers, Eastern Europe,
and the economic origins of World War II, 1930-1941, Continuum, p.395)
41
Sontag 1970:1
42
Palmer et al 2002:696
43
John Markoff (1996) Waves of Democracy: Social Movements and Political
Change, Pine Forge Press, p. 74
129
exclusively by democracies.45 In the wake of the war, “the power and prestige
Among the victors, the United States was the greatest beneficiary of the war – in
fact, the only great power besides Japan to benefit from the fighting.47 “The new
postwar distribution of power,” wrote Ikenberry, “left the United States as the
preeminent state.”48 This shift in the global hierarchy was widely noted by
contemporaries. “The change since 1914 in the international position of the United
States,” wrote the financial editor of the New York Times in 1926, “[is] perhaps the
The war forced Europe to rely on American capital, loans, technology, supplies,
and political leadership. “The war devastated Europe but made the United States
the world’s principal industrial, financial, and trading power.”50 The volume of
finance shifted from London to New York. As Keynes reported to the British
44
Sontag 1970:2
45
Roberts 1999:271, 283.
46
Markoff 1996: 74
47
Kennedy 1987:327
48
Ikenberry 2000:119-20
49
Alexander Dana Noyes (1926) The War Period of American Finance, New York:
Putnam, p. 436-7, quoted in Frieden 2006:129.
50
Frieden 2006:132
130
cabinet shortly after the war: “It is hardly an exaggeration to say that in a few
months’ time the American executive and the American public will be in a position
to dictate to this country on matters that affect us more dearly than them.”51
Between 1914 and the end of the war the country’s stock of gold almost doubled,
The economic power of the United States, already apparent by the turn of the
factor in world prosperity.”53 The country “seemed to have all the economic
advantages which some of the other great powers possessed in part, but none of
1913 Germany, Britain, France, and Belgium produced “substantially more” than
the United States; by the late 1920s the U.S. “was outproducing these countries by
nearly half.”55 It produced almost 40 percent of the world’s coal and more than half
had a relatively high standard of living. In addition, the U.S. enjoyed the
51
John Milton Cooper (1976) “The Command of Gold Reversed” Pacific Historical
Review 45.2, p. 219-21, quoted in Frieden 2006:134. See also Halperin 2004:32
52
Arthur Walworth (1977) America’s Moment, 1918: American Diplomacy at the
End of World War I, New York: Norton, p.4
53
Roberts 1999:340
54
Kennedy 1987:243
55
Frieden 2006:132
56
Roberts 1999:340. Kennedy notes that in the 1920s the U.S. had a larger output
than the other six great powers combined. Kennedy 1987:328, citing Hillmann,
“Comparative Strength of the Great Powers” in Toynbee, ed. World In March 1939,
p.421-22.
131
resources - “in all these areas, the United States was unrivaled in size and
efficiency.”58
strength, which had been relatively small compared to a Europe at the end of a
dynamism allowed it quickly to match the Europeans once it was drawn into the
war.”59 During the time of its direct involvement in the war, between April 1917
and November 1918, the United States produced an immense supply of munitions
machine guns, 410 artillery units, 2700 tons of toxic gas, and 3850 airplane
engines per month.60 In 1915, the American army comprised 100,000 soldiers and
112,000 National Guardsmen, one-twentieth the size of the German Army. By the
end of the war, it managed to mobilize over 4.2 million people through universal
conscription. Of those, just over 2 million reached France and 1.4 million saw
active combat.61
57
Kennedy 1987:327
58
Ikenberry 2000:120
59
Ikenberry 2000:120
60
Leonard P. Ayres (1919) The War with Germany: A Statistical Summary.
Washington DC: Government Printing Office.
61
Colin Nicholson (2001) The Longman Companion to the First World War,
Longman, p. 248
132
Through its armies, loans, and supplies of material, the United States had
determined the outcome of the war and now appeared poised to shape its
had decided the conflict.”62 Its power loomed large on the continent; the American
itself” and its role shifted “from a passive observer of the slow collapse of the
Europe” and saw America’s dramatic rise as an opportunity to spread its institutions
to the Old World.64 “When the war is over we can force them to our way of
thinking,” he told Colonel House in 1917, “because by that time they will, among
by its success, and the prospect of American financial support encouraged other
additional impetus for reforms. “The world looked with awe and expectation to one
man – the president of the United States,” writes Palmer. “Wilson occupied a lone
62
Palmer et al 2002:687
63
Walworth 1977:4
64
Walworth 1977: 17
65
Quoted in Arthur S. Link (1979) Woodrow Wilson: Revolution, War, and Peace,
Harlan Davidson, p.80; quoted in Ikenberry 2000:122
133
was received “as the man who would lead civilization out of its wasteland.”66
The Great War created a number of new states that adopted democratic
before the war, among both former autocracies like Germany and partial
democracies like Britain. Explanations that focus on the influence of major wars
upon state development are ambiguous about their effects on regime outcome. This
ambiguity can be clarified somewhat if the effects of war are separated into two
diverge even within the same war – preparing for major conflict can lead to
forces. Much of the bellicist literature is concerned with the effects of mobilization
on state development. An early example is the writings of Otto Hintze and John
Seeley, members of the so-called German historical school. They stressed that a
shapes its regime type. Hintze, a scholar of the Prussian state, argued that constant
preparation for war led to a standing army and a centralized state, while relative
oceans, created the internal opportunity for democracy.67 Seeley likewise argued
66
Palmer et al 2002: 687-8
67
Otto Hintze (1975) The Historical Essays of Otto Hintze, Felix Gilbert, ed.,
134
that the hostility of the external environment shaped the state through the need for
secure, thallasocratic state like Britain or the United States avoided universal
service in the formative years of their history, and therefore adopted relatively
autocratic:
According to this argument, then, mobilization for war – conflict or constant threat
thereof – leads to centralization of authority and despotism, with the corollary that
school of thought has long argued that mobilization for war produces democratic
wrote Walt Rustow, “because it has made necessary the marshalling of additional
human resources.”71 North and Weingast, for instance, have argued that warfare
led to the need for increased revenue, which forced the monarchy to cede
sovereignty, the king was soon able to raise much more war revenue than in the
pre-Parliament days. With their property rights credibly secured, wealth holders felt
comfortable to lend and invest their capital.73 As North and Weingast suggest, this
capacity and set it on the long path toward global hegemony.74 The overall effect of
Science 47.2: 234-247. Michael Colaresi and William R. Thompson (2003) “The
Economic Development-Democratization Relationship: Does the Outside World
Matter?” Comparative Political Studies 36.4: 381-403. Karen Rasler and William R.
Thompson (2005) Puzzles of the Democratic Peace Theory: Theory, Geopolitics,
and the Transformation of World Politics, New York: Palgrave. William R.
Thompson (1996) "Democracy and Peace: Putting the Cart before the Horse?"
International Organization 50.1: 141-174.
71
Dankwart A. Rustow (1970) “Transitions to Democracy: Toward a Dynamic
Model” Comparative Politics 2.3, p.348. He cites Bertrand de Jouvenel (1948) On
Power as an example of this view.
72
Douglass C. North and Barry R. Weingast (1989) “Constitutions and
Commitment: The Evolution of Institutional Governing Public Choice in
Seventeenth-Century England”, The Journal of Economic History, Vol.49:803-832
73
On credible binding through constitutions, see Jon Elster (1984) Ulysses and the
Sirens, Cambridge University Press
74
Montesquieu long ago noted that freer states were able to levy more taxes. “It is a
general rule that taxes may be heavier in proportion to the liberty of the subject,”
he wrote in The Spirit of the Laws. “In moderate countries there is an indemnity for
the weight of the taxes, which is liberty. In despotic countries there is an equivalent
for liberty, which is the lightness of the taxes.” Baron de Montesquieu (1748/1949)
The Spirit of the Laws, vol.1, bk.13, ch.12: “Relation between the Weight of Taxes
136
England’s wars in the seventeenth century, therefore, was to shift the locus of
power from king to parliament. Similarly, French wars in the next century
eventually forced the bankrupt king to gather the Estates-General, sparking the
events that led to the French Revolution. In general, then, mobilizing for war can
development of the state, argued that the wars of 1792-1815 helped create a
modern warfare and social revolution.75 This was undoubtedly true in World War I.
Across Europe, the necessities of wartime mobilization gave women and working-
class men an unprecedented opportunity to gain political power and press for
social reforms. In return for their participation in the trenches and on the factory
floors, these groups were able to extract political concessions like voting rights and
and Liberty”, transl. by Thomas Nugent, New York: Hafner Publishing Company,
p.214. Absolutist regimes were forced to compromise with local power-holders,
leading to unequal tax burdens and inefficiencies. See Perry Anderson (1974)
Lineages of the Absolutist State, London: NLB; Hillay Zmora (2001) Monarchy,
Aristocracy, and the State in Europe 1300-1800, Routledge. The idea that taxation
follows representation is more than a revolutionary slogan; Montesquieu called it
“a rule derived from nature that never varies.” (Montesquieu 1748/1949:214)
75
Gianfranco Poggi (1978/2004) The Development of the Modern State: A
Sociological Introduction, Stanford University Press, p. 91
137
welfare provisions. The postwar expansion of suffrage, the growth of unions, and
the rise of labor parties in these countries was made possible by mass conscription
and the wartime economy, which shifted the balance of power within European
The war indeed ushered in a period of social change. As Barzun notes, “Class
barriers lost rigidity; conventions were relaxed. The soldier was cut loose from his
nine-to-five at the office or six-to-four at the factory, as well as from home and its
constraints.”77 For the well-off, Palmer writes, “it became embarrassing to show
their comforts too openly. It was patriotic to eat meagerly and to wear old clothes.
War gave a new impetus even to the idea of economic equality, if only to enlist
rich and poor alike in a common cause.”78 Writing in 1921, a journalist described
the wartime period in Britain as a “social revolution”: “Caste was for a time
were making munitions with factory girls. A great, strong, spiritual wind seemed to
76
Eric Hobsbawm (1994) The Age of Extremes: A History of the World, 1914-1991,
Vintage Books, p.49
77
Barzun 2001:699
78
Palmer et al 2002:681
79
Philip Gibbs (1921) “The Social Revolution in English Life” Harper’s Magazine,
April, p. 561. The war had, Gibbs writes, empowered the “small traders, little
manufacturers, business adventurers without capital or power” (Gibbs 1921:562)
138
“one man, one gun, one vote”.80 In Canada, the mass mobilization for war was a
wage it created a leveling impulse in all aspects of social and political life.
ordinary men and women was needed if the war was to go on.
Mass conscription for the trenches drained workers from the factories and
created constant labor shortages. At the same time, the voracious consumption of
tremendous increase in demand for factory labor.82 Like never before, war had
“extended its tentacles deep to the rear, spreading from the trenches into the fields,
the mines, and the factories."83 The American industrialist Howard E. Coffin wrote
in 1916: "Twentieth century warfare demands that the blood of the soldier must be
mingled with three to five parts of the sweat of the man in the factories, mills,
mines, and fields of the nation in arms."84 In short supply and high demand,
workers gained more bargaining leverage, and the need for a steady supply of ships
and cannons meant that labor unrest and industrial strikes could become
80
Downing 1992:253. Downing also notes that throughout history mass
conscription has acted as a catalyst for liberalization and franchise expansion.
81
Rueschmeyer et al 1992:279
82
Markoff 2006: 84
83
Martin van Creveld (1989) Technology and War: From 2000 B.C. to the Present,
Free Press, p. 163.
84
Quoted in Elizabeth Keir (2010) “War and Reform: Gaining Labor’s Compliance
on the Homefront” in Elizabeth Keir and Ronald Krebs, eds., In War’s Wake:
International Conflict and the Fate of Liberal Democracy, Cambridge University
Press, p.139.
139
and the wartime economy strengthened the unity and organization of labor, men
and women alike, shifting the balance of power within European societies in its
favor.86 “In fighting for democracy abroad we are gaining two of the biggest
Council of National Defense in 1918. “The first is the recognition of the rights and
dignity of labor, and the other is women's freedom, because never before have we
so clearly realized that the output of the machine is just as essential to victory as
the gun at the front.”87 This process was even more pronounced in England,
Harriman argued. “At this moment 1,413,000 women are replacing men in
industry in England,” she wrote. “Women, with the help of improved automatic
machinery, are able to do the work previously done by fully skilled workers.”88 The
need for mass armies also contributed to the push for democratization.
“The State demanded the men it chose and sent them to Europe; it cannot deny
them a fair measure of freedom and happiness.”89 As a result of these forces, writes
85
Keir 2010:139 in Keir and Krebs, eds.
86
Halperin 2004:71. Rueschemeyer et al (1992:92) likewise argue: “The war and
its outcome changed the balance of power in society, strengthening the working
class and weakening the upper classes.”
87
J. Borden Harriman (1918) “How England Meets Her Labor” Annals of the
American Academy of Political and Social Science Vol.78, p.80
88
Harriman 1918:81
89
Lindsay Rogers (1919) “The Literature of Reconstruction” The Sewanee Review
27.1:112
140
of the men in the trenches and the women and men in the factories. Talk about
concerned that continuing the war with Germany might release democratic forces
(or in his words, “spell ruin for the civilized order”) that in 1917 he urged a peace
The reciprocal bargain forged by the war undermines the often-repeated claim
nationalism over class solidarity.92 During the war, labor conflicts “continued
unabated and, in many places, increased in both number and intensity.” 93 The war
and reflected a growing desire “that a better standard of living for the masses must
emerge with the coming of peace.”94 In Britain and other countries, it was widely
recognized that the war could not be won without the support of the workers. Their
participation had been “for the first time the critical condition for victory,” and it
had been “felt to be so by politicians, civil servants, trade unionists, and the
press.”95 At the end of the war, labor was more unified, better organized, “and in a
90
Markoff 2006:85
91
Quoted in Keir 2010:161 in Keir and Krebs, eds.
92
Halperin 2004:154; see Halperin 2004:154 fn. 14 for examples of this fallacy.
93
Halperin 2004:154
94
Rueschemeyer et al 1992:91-2. See also Halperin 2004:154
95
P. Abrams (1963) “The Failure of Social Reforms: 1918-1920” Past and Present
24, p.43-64; Cited in Halperin 2004:151
141
position to back its demands with threats.”96 Given their new status, Halperin
notes, workers had reason to believe – and in some cases were promised – that
“through their patriotism and sacrifices, they might win the rights for which they
had struggled for over a century.”97 The postwar democratic reforms, argues
Charles Tilly, came about when “citizens (including female citizens) who bore the
terrible costs of war bargained with war-battered states for rights they had
previously lacked, which their military and civilian service visibly justified.”98
autocracy” argument appears to fit wars before the nineteenth century, and
wars since Napoleonic times, and deals with war’s effects on institutional
But mobilization still tells only a part of the story about the effects of warfare on
domestic development. While the scholars noted above stress the role of worker
mobilization, they tend to ignore the all-important factor of the outcome of the war.
96
Halperin 2004:171
97
Halperin 2004:154-5. See also Eric Hobsbawm (1990) Nations and Nationalism
Since 1780: Programme, Myth, Reality, Cambridge University Press, p.120-30
98
Charles Tilly (2007) Democracy, Cambridge University Press p. 64-65
142
were adopted was contingent on which regime actually won. A German victory, in
Germany or in Europe as a whole – much less likely.99 In the case of World War I,
it was the interaction of the states’ mobilization strategies and the eventual victory
of one particular mobilization strategy over another. As Elizabeth Kier has argued,
states pursue different strategies to mobilize the people during war. They can
coerce workers into participation through martial law and harsh enforcement of
labor regulations, closing off opportunities for democratic reform. Another strategy,
however, is to bargain with labor by offering them political rights and including
Where outcomes matter – and where the bellicist theories of the state connect
mobilization strategies chosen in wartime. “The workers in the mass,” wrote the
editor of the Observer in 1919, “had to be assured a thousand times than in the
event of victory of their freely-accepted discipline over the more forced and serf-like
drill of the German system, unprecedented efforts would be made to raise the
contingent on a favorable outcome for those states that adopted the bargaining
99
“[I]t is difficult to imagine a more democratic outcome,” writes Peceny, “had
Germany emerged victorious from the war.” Peceny 2010:5. See also Fritz Fischer
(1967) Germany’s Aims in the First World War, New York: W.W. Norton.
100
Kier 2010 in Kier and Krebs, eds.
101
J.L. Garvin (1919) The Foundations of Peace, London: Macmillan, p.323-4;
quoted in Halperin 2004:159; emphasis added
143
strategy of mobilization. Had the Central Powers won the war, this strategy would
are less effective at mobilizing their populations for major war. The outcome of the
war provided a demonstration effect about the efficacy of competing strategies and
the institutional choices that accompanied those strategies. The bargaining strategy
was vindicated by the victory of the democratic great powers, while the coercive
A second, closely related path through which the outcome of the war affected
domestic reforms was by putting pressure on losing regimes. As other scholars have
pointed out, defeat can discredit losing elites, forcing them to bargain with the
masses or risk being thrown out of office entirely. 102 Shocks such as revolutions and
states and thereby weaken the elites that have the most to lose from
leaders found themselves replaced in 1918 via a popular rebellion backed by the
army. Austria, Hungary, and Bulgaria also adopted democratic institutions at the
end of the war. The democratic great powers, on the other hand, found their
102
Edward D. Mansfield and Jack Snyder (2010) “Does War Influence
Democratization?” p.23-49 in Keir and Krebs, eds. They do not find a link between
war and democratization. Skocpol (1979) has also argued that defeat in war creates
internal pressures for reform, and is in fact a necessary pre-requisite for
revolutionary regime transformations.
103
Tilly 2007:40
144
maintained political continuity during and after the war – and their ability to do so
further enhanced the prestige of democratic institutions in the period following the
war. The crisis of defeat dislodged existing regimes, while the triumph of victory
solidified them.
In short, mobilization for war produced great hopes for social and political
change, and its outcome led to increasingly vehement demands for it.104 By the
power. In Weimar Germany, Austria, Sweden, and other states, socialist parties and
coalitions led their people’s transitions to new governments; Labour took power in
Britain in 1923, and the left won in France in 1924. In many cases, socialist parties
104
There is a large literature on why war outcomes favor democracy. My main
concern here, however, is not the why but the how – that is, not why democracy
won, but how this democratic victory vindicated certain mobilization strategies,
discredited autocratic rulers, and created incentives for democratic reforms. On
why major wars result democratic victories, see Mitchell et al (1999), who argue
that the dominant systemic effect of war is to increase democratization because
“non-democracies are more likely to experience regime change than democracies
as a result of war.” Sarah Mitchell, Scott Gates and Håvard Hegre (1999) "Evolution
in Democracy-War Dynamics." Journal of Conflict Resolution 43.6, p. 789. See also
Ricardo Sanhueza (1999) “The Hazard Rate of Political Regimes” Public Choice
98.3-4, p. 337-367. Bueno de Mesquita et al (1992) argue that regime
transformations are twice as frequent during and immediately after wars, and that
most of these transformations affect autocracies. Bruce Bueno de Mesquita,
Randolph Siverson, Gary Woller (1992) “War and the Fate of Regimes: A
Comparative Analysis” American Political Science Review 93.4, p. 638-46. See also
Dan Reiter and Allan C. Stam (2002) Democracies at War, Princeton University
Press. As Gates et al 2007:11 put it, “Given democracies’ general propensity to win
wars and autocracies’ greater propensity to expire in defeat, war is associated with
greater democratization.” See Desch (2002) for a dissent.
145
labor parties to the forefront of political action, the war helped usher in a number
elements of the welfare state were becoming more common. Belgium introduced
its first welfare legislation after the war, and Britain expanded its unemployment
insurance provisions in 1922.106 In Sweden, the German defeat in the war led to the
capitulation of the Swedish Conservatives, who had been stalling political reforms.
Unlike their counterparts in Germany, Swedish conservative did not have the
option of allying with a powerful landed upper class, and were politically isolated.
After the war they agreed to the introduction of universal suffrage and a
suffrage in the three decades before the war. All of these had been put down, often
with force. During the war, however, the government needed labor’s support and
gave the Socialist party a ministry. By the end of the war Belgium had adopted
Only two European countries had allowed female suffrage before World War I,
105
Sheri Berman (2006) The Primacy of Politics: Social Democracy and the Making
of Europe’s Twentieth Century, Cambridge University Press, p. 97; Frieden
2006:170
106
Halperin 2004:156-7
107
Rueschemeyer et al 1992:93
108
Markoff 2006:73-4
146
Finland in 1906 and Norway in 1913. But between 1917 and 1924, over two
of women, writes Palmer, was the “most conspicuous innovation” of the postwar
period.109 Charles Beard, writing in 1927, noted that World War I, “supposed to
demonstrate manly valor at its highest pitch, accelerated the movement for woman
suffrage. Nearly all the new states created after that conflict conferred on women
the right to vote.” He concluded: “The feminist genie is out of the bottle.”110
Women received the right to vote in all the new states created by the war
Belgium, and other countries. (see Table 3.1, below) As with other forms of postwar
reforms, the role of the war was crucial in furthering their cause; its influence is
particularly visible, for example, in Canada’s expansion of the franchise, where the
vote was first extended to women in uniform, then to women with close male
relatives in the military, and finally, at the end of the war, to all female citizens.111
109
Palmer et al 2002:744
110
Charles Beard (1927) “Democracy Holds its Ground”, Harper’s Magazine,
November, p. 681
111
Markoff 2006:85
147
Year Country
1917 Canada, Russia
1918 Austria, Azerbaijan, Georgia, Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania, Germany,
Hungary, Kyrgyzstan, Poland, Great Britain112
1919 Belgium, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Sweden, Ukraine, Albania, Isle
of Man, Belarus
1920 Czechoslovakia, United States
1921 Burma, Sweden, Armenia
1922 Ecuador, Ireland
1924 Kazakhstan, Mongolia, Saint Lucia, Tajikistan
Table 3.1 Female Suffrage Expansion, 1917-1924113
The war had drawn women into the labor force and demonstrated their
capacity to do “jobs which it had been thought only men could do.”114 The
insatiable need for troop replacements meant that women now streamed into
offices and factories. In the United States, the Council of National Defense
in the workplace, prompting journalist Ida Tarbell to write that “this was the first
time in history that a government had called a country’s woman-power into co-
operation. The summons made its impression. It was ‘recognizing’ women. The
112
Suffrage extended to women over 28; full female suffrage extended in 1928.
113
Iceland and Denmark extended suffrage in the 1910s; Greece also extended
female suffrage in the 1920s.
114
Palmer et al 2002:682. As Vinen notes, “The idle wife or daughter was one
aspect of the bourgeois rentier society that the First World War destroyed.” Richard
Vinen (2000) A History in Fragments: Europe in the Twentieth Century, Da Capo
Press, p. 113
115
Ida M. Tarbell (1917) “Mobilizing the Women” Harper’s Magazine, p. 842
148
The number of women in the labor force was bound to fall after the war, as
veterans made their way back to the job market.116 But this experience in both
world wars was part of a social process in which women’s work was redefined and
women’s daily lives were reoriented around the national economy.117 Just as the
demand for labor empowered common laborers, it gave women a first chance at an
independent living. A journalist noted in 1921: “Any girl with her hair hanging
down her back or tied into a pigtail could get a wage that her father would have
Women were indispensable to ‘war work’ and not solely as nurses and
entertainers of the troops, but as chauffeurs, bureaucrats, factory hands,
and ‘farmerettes’. They showed that they could perform as well as men
– often more conscientiously – in the reserved precincts of the male. It
was impossible after the war to deny them the vote by arguing their
incapacity.119
The increasing influence of labor also made female voters an appealing source
unrest, rapid social changes, and explosive union growth. “For those conservative
politicians who believed that women were intrinsically more conservative than
116
Vinen is skeptical about the effects of war on female political empowerment at
the workplace and the voting booth. Although female employment increased as a
result of the war, this was always meant as a temporary measure: “Women’s jobs
were often in industries such as munitions, where workers were bound to be laid
off after the war…It was part of the wartime consensus eventually established in
most countries between unions, employers and government that the employment of
women should not be continued in peacetime.” (Vinen 2000:110)
117
Palmer et al 2002:682
118
Gibbs 1921:561
119
Barzun 2000:699-700
149
the working classes had to be given the vote, it seemed to some to be safer to give
it to women, too.”120 Vinen in fact argues that female enfranchisement was not a
direct outcome of the war itself but a moderating counterweight to the postwar
labor movement, and that “the women who were most readily enfranchised – the
relatively old, property owners and war widows – were all welcomed into the
revolutionary male proletariat” who was gaining his suffrage around the same
time.121 The histoical evidence suggests that women did support center-right
parties; in the Weimar Republic, for instance, women strongly supported the Centre
Party but rejected the “boisterous and aggressively masculine” Nazi Party.122 The
war thus spurred female suffrage both by mobilizing women in the workplace and
From the Ashes of Empires: World War I and the New Democracies
As the Great War neared its conclusion in the fall of 1918, a group of
dignitaries from central and eastern European nations, calling themselves the Mid-
120
Markoff 2006:87
121
Vinen 2000:116
122
Vinen 2000:117
123
Jacques Barzun suggests another, more general factor – the disruption of normal
social routines brought by the war: “Watchful neighbors having scattered, each
spouse, now separated, gained sexual freedom if it was wanted, or at least escape
from a bad marriage…These freedoms, soon taken for granted, furthered the
feminist movement.” Barzun 2000:699
150
Independence for Middle Europe, which promised “that the sufferings of the world
war shall not have been in vain” and that the principles of liberty, democracy, and
that had killed millions and devastated a continent, reflected the high hopes for
new democracies in the immediate aftermath of the war. The great European
their place rose a number of new states that saw democracy as a way to modernize
their societies and harness the spirit of national self-determination. “The war broke
the old land empires of Europe, while inspiring dreams of new ones,” wrote the
historian Timothy Snyder. “It replaced the dynastic principle of rule by emperors
124
The New York Times (1918) “Independence Hall Sees Nations Born” October
27, p.6.
125
Timothy Snyder (2011) Bloodlands: Europe Between Hitler and Stalin, New
York: Basic Books, p.1
151
Ukrainian, and Lithuanian regions by the post-war settlement, emerged from the
outset as a multi-ethnic state in which a third of the population was not ethnically
Polish. Like its neighbors, Poland began with a constitution “which contained
For the long-suffering Ottoman Empire, the war had been disastrous. Romania,
Bulgaria, and especially Greece received most of its European territory, which was
now reduced to a toehold on the Bosporus. Its Arab lands were taken away to
become League of Nations mandates (only the Hejaz, now known as Saudi Arabia,
independent, while Italy received islands in the Aegean. Only Istanbul and the
126
Sontag 1971:67
152
strict financial controls that had so angered the Ottomans in the previous century.
country’s pre-war elites and led to the swift rise of Mustafa Kemal, who launched a
successful campaign for Turkish independence. Within two years, and with Soviet
help, the Ataturk drove off the Greeks and their western allies. Armenia was
reconquered and split with the Soviet Union. A secular Turkish republic was
declared in 1923.
Kemal was first and foremost a modernizer rather than a democratizer, but in
democracy’s brief glory days of the early 1920s, the two concepts could not help
but overlap, and his reforms reflected this temporary fusion. The 1924 constitution
Religion was purged from public and political life, though personal freedom of
religion was protected by the state. The law was secularized in a code based on the
Swiss model, the caliphate being officially abolished in 1924. To Kemal and his
followers, “the war demonstrated just how calamitous delay had been”.127 Here as
in central Europe it took the shock of a war for old elites to become discredited,
The defeated Russian Empire, like an old map peeling at the edges, shed a
number of territories along its periphery. The February revolution revealed the full
127
Frieden 2006:97
153
movements. In the north, Finland finally gained full autonomy and all three Baltic
after more than a century of absence. In the Caucasus, the Russian collapse created
the democratic republics of Armenia, Georgia, and Azerbaijan. The latter became
the first Muslim nation to grant political rights to women, and adopted a Parliament
Within Russia itself, the war led to a moderate regime “made up of liberal
It lasted only eight months, from February to October 1917, when a Bolshevik
coup pre-empted what would have been the Russian Republic’s founding elections.
The Russian case represents a compressed version of the sequence, where the
consolidation occurred very quickly. As in Germany, the transition itself was only
made possible by the extraordinary shock of the war, which brought together a
coalition of domestic actors that would not have ordinarily shared the overthrow of
monarchy as a common goal.130 The role of the army in this improvised coalition
128
Armenia adopted female suffrage in 1921, three years after Georgia and
Azerbaijan.
129
Palmer et al 2002:674
130
As Skocpol writes: “Born and tempered in warfare, insulated from, and supreme
against, the forces of society, the Russian state could only succumb through
massive defeat in total war. Thus World War I was to be a necessary cause – as
well as the occasion – of the revolutionary crisis that brought Imperial Russia to its
154
was particularly decisive. In the failed 1905 revolution it was used to suppress
revolts, but after the battlefield defeats of 1917, “the dissolution of the army and the
villages to join in, and often lead, the land seizures.”131 A magazine article from the
time noted the broad assent for reforms at all levels of the army, where the
rank and file: “[T]he ease with which aristocratic regiments were won over to the
cause of democracy, and more especially the responsive attitude of officers of the
court battalions and of the General Staff, was as much of a surprise to the
and riots throughout the city, and the Provisional Government was established. It
introducing “the full panoply of civil liberties and setting in train the
Moderates and includes only two Socialists,” while the ultra-conservatives, the so-
called Blacks, were not represented at all.134 Western observers welcomed the
assurance has been added to our hope for the future peace of the world by the
wonderful and heartening things that have been happening within the last few
But the war would undermine the provisional government just as it did the
monarchy that preceded it. Urban workers demanded industrial reform, national
estates and land redistribution, and the military pushed for a peace treaty. “On all
these issues the Provisional Government had to repudiate the wishes of the people,
and by so doing, it forfeited all popular support for its authority.”136 Because the
government failed to exit the war, the army left the pro-government coalition.
Because it failed to undertake industrial and land reforms, it lost the laborers and
the farmers. “Because it was unwilling and unable to abandon the war and to
sanction or stop the agrarian revolts, the Provisional Government could not escape
having its flimsy political bases swept away, as social conflicts deepened and
disorder spread in the cities, at the fronts, and in the countryside.”137 By November
the situation became so untenable that Lenin and the Bolsheviks were able to seize
134
Cahan 1917:47
135
Woodrow Wilson (1917) The President’s Address to Congress, April 2, 1917;
reprinted in The New York Times, April 3 1917, p.1
136
Bobbitt 2003:28
137
Skocpol 1979:210
156
In Finland, after a four-month civil war and a brief experiment with monarchy,
within the tsarist empire had provided the country with an aristocratic leadership,
mostly Swedish in origin, that “had learned to lead rather than dominate the mass
democracy in which the condition of the lower classes was steadily improved”
The three Baltic states all declared independence in 1918 and quickly moved to
put in place constitutions, parliaments, and universal suffrage (all three granted
women the right to vote the same year). Their constitutions provided for
The state supported the cooperative movement, and the private estates of Baltic
Germans were transferred to landless peasants.140 By 1925, for example, more than
138
Sontag 1971:67
139
Daina Stukuls Eglitis (2007) “The Baltic States: Remembering the Past, Building
the Future” in Sharon L. Wolchik and Jane L. Curry, eds., Central and East
European Politics: From Communism to Democracy, Rowman and Littlefield, p.
234
140
Sontag 1971:67
157
entrepreneurship.”141
The Austro-Hungarian empire was shorn of territories and separated into two
principal successor states, Austria and Hungary, as well as two new multi-ethnic
states: Czechoslovakia for Northern Slavs (Czechs and Slovaks), and Yugoslavia for
Free elections in February 1919 brought together a coalition of urban Socialists and
Serbia as punishment for allying with the Axis powers. In November 1918, the
democratic government was unable to deal with demands from competing groups
and was replaced five months later by a Bolshevik “Republic of Councils”. Five
outlawing the Communist Party and limiting Jews’ access to universities (anti-
Semitism was permitted partly because so many Communists had been Jews).
Sontag suggests that the 1920s was a period “of rule for and by the old agrarian
141
Federigo Argentieri (2007) “Hungary: Dealing with the Past and Moving into the
Present” in Sharon L. Wolchik and Jane L. Curry, eds., p. 234
142
Sontag 1971:62-3
158
aristocracy, behind the forms of popular rule,” in which dissent from aristocratic
least the “machinery of democracy” until the 1930s, meaning it had a constitution,
changes sweeping across central and eastern Europe. Wilhelmine Germany was a
The new Weimar Republic, by contrast, adopted universal suffrage for all male and
female citizens over twenty. In July 1919, after several months of deliberation, a
only “universal, equal, direct, and secret” 145 suffrage, but also proportional
representation, and procedures for recalls, referenda, and ballot initiatives. The
Kaiser was replaced by a popularly elected president, and a national legislature, the
Reichstag.146
In sum, nearly all of the new states that were created (or resurrected, in Poland’s
suffrage, and proportional representation. The war not only drastically undermined
the power and legitimacy of monarchy, but also demonstrated that democratic
institutions could be efficient and resilient in a crisis, and that they could challenge
143
Sontag 1971:62
144
Palmer et al 2002:746
145
Beard 1927:682
146
Palmer et al 2002:749; Richard J. Evans (2004) The Coming of the Third Reich,
Penguin Press, p.80, 83
159
and even defeat modern centralized autocracies both on the battlefield and the
factory floor. At the end of the war, power and ideology combined to create a
moment when democracy appeared to be the way forward. The dramatic shift in
the distribution of power among the major states was accompanied by a shift in
volatile (in the case of Communism). A fledgling communist regime had appeared
in Russia after the country’s brief flirtation with liberal democracy, but it was the
product of a war-born minority-forged coup facing a bitter civil war and foreign
invasion, a “tyranny nourished by misery” rather than a viable path for economic
hegemonic shocks, seemed unambiguous. The “obvious victors has been the major
western democracies of the day, and the great losers were what politicians called
147
For other surveys of the post-1919 balance, see Anton W. DePorte (1977)
Europe Between the Superpowers: The Enduring Balance, Chapter 3, Yale
University Press; David Thomson (1967) Europe Since Napoleon, New York: Alfred
Knopf, p. 622ff; Graham Ross (1991) Great Powers and the Decline of the
European State System, 1914-1945, Chapters 3-6, New York: Longman
148
Roberts 2008:283. Thomas Mann’s intellectual trajectory in this period reflects
the growing acceptance of democratic ideals. His 1918 Confessions of an
Unpolitical Man typified the way German politicians and intellectuals, in the words
of Fritz Stern, “denounced democracy as bourgeois hypocrisy and insisted that their
own system of politics was morally and pragmatically superior.” Stern 1997:16.
While he supported the Kaiser and denounced liberalism during World War I, his
1923 Von Deutscher Republik encouraged Germans to support the new Weimar
Republic and became an ardent opponent of the Nazis during the 1930s.
149
Sontag 1970:1
160
widespread consensus on the attraction of democracy would not resurface until the
Soviet collapse seven decades later. It seemed to offer a path to both domestic and
international legitimacy, and for those rulers who saw little value in such trifles, it
was seen as a way to modernize, strengthen, and stabilize their own fragile new
states and societies, and ingratiate themselves with the new democratic hegemon.
Part of the motivation for new states to undertake liberalizing reforms was the
prospect of economic incentives and security guarantees from the United States,
the ostensible champion of the new democratic order. But in the aftermath of the
war, the United States offered little more than inspiring rhetoric, choosing to turn
Wilson’s rhetoric, Ikenberry writes, “was not backed up by offers of economic and
military assistance that might have made his settlement ideas more attractive and
credible”152 – and, perhaps, more durable. This was a mistake that American
policy-makers explicitly sought to correct after World War II. The consolidation of
150
Markoff 2006:87.
151
Peceny 2010:2-3
152
Ikenberry 2001:155
161
fragile regimes was made all the more difficult by the absence of material support
its political aspirations and the near-complete failure of these aspirations in the face
of later crises and reversals. Even before the Great Depression produced an
authoritarian wave in the 1930s, despots and dictators began ascending to power
across Europe and around the world. Fledgling democracies fell in Russia (1917),
Hungary (1919), Italy (1922), Bulgaria (1923), Poland (1926), Portugal (1926),
Lithuania (1926) and Yugoslavia (1929). In addition, the new states of Armenia,
Georgia, and Azerbaijan, which had also adopted democratic institutions, were
reabsorbed back into the Russian empire by 1922, this time under a Communist
aegis. The optimistic period after the war, Ikenberry writes, “was a democratic high
inherent in the dynamics of the initial wave. First, the shock of the war had brought
These ad hoc domestic alliances could not be sustained once the immediate crisis
had passed. Like a victorious international alliance that dissolves once its purpose
is served, these domestic coalitions struggled to hold together after the initial
transition period. As the pro-reform class coalitions and party alliances forged by
153
Ikenberry 2001:155
162
the shock of the war faded, Europe entered what Karl Polanyi called “the counter-
When, in Central Europe, the social structure broke down under the
strain of war and defeat, the working class alone was available for the
task of keeping things going. Everywhere power was thrust upon the
trade unions and Social Democratic parties: Austria, Hungary, even
Germany, were declared republics although no active republican party
had ever been known to exist in any of these countries before. But
hardly had the acute danger of dissolution passed and the services of
the trade unions became superfluous than the middle classes tried to
exclude the working class from all influence on public life.154
A second, related reason for the failure was the overexpansion of democratic
leaders of new states adopted institutions that had little chance of being
154
Karl Polanyi (1944/2001) The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic
Origins of Our Time, Boston: Beacon Press, p. 196; emph. added
155
As Markoff notes, some postwar leaders likely “sought merely a democratic
appearance, in order to appease challenging social movements and appear
respectable within the international community.” (Markoff 2006: 87) In these
“Potemkin” cases, some backsliding was inevitable since the democratic
institutions were a temporary façade for placating domestic challengers and foreign
peers. The overexpansion of democratic institutions as a byproduct of powerful (but
temporary) pro-democracy global norms echoes the backsliding of democratic
movements after the end of the Third Wave in the mid-1990s.
163
“to a large extent accidents of the war.” None of them, with the exception of
the war “were as divided within their new frontiers as they had been within the old,
and were separated from one another by even greater hostility than they had
156
Roberts 2008:312
157
Aron 1951/ 2002:146
158
Palmer et al 2002:745
164
nationhood.”159
Walter Bagehot, writing about France’s Third Republic, once noted that
parliamentary government often fails because it requires “that a nation should have
nerve to endure incessant discussion and frequent change of rulers.”160 For the
states of interwar Europe, such nerve required, in the words of Fritz Stern, “a
psychological stamina for ambiguity and uncertainty,” an attitude that that could
not sustain enough adherents in the interwar period.161 With the disappearance of
conducive for its consolidation, the momentum for democratization could not be
sustained.
Russia, for example, began its revolutionary path in 1917 with a turn to
Alexander Kerensky, leader of the Provisional Government. “Six weeks ago Russia
“She now is one of the most advanced democracies in the world.”162 But liberal
159
Francois Furet (1999) The Passing of an Illusion: The Idea of Communism in the
Twentieth Century, University of Chicago Press, p.58
160
Walter Bagehot (1874/1965) Bagehot’s Historical Essays, edited by Norman St.
John-Stevas, New York: Anchor Books, p. 449-50. Quoted in Fritz Stern (1992) The
Failure of Liberalism: Essays on the Political Culture of Modern Germany, Columbia
University Press, p.xxiv.
161
Stern 1997:20
162
Quoted in James L. Slayden (1917) “Disarmament and International Courts
Prerequisites to a Durable Peace” Annals of the American Academy of Political and
Social Science, Vol.72, p.100
165
among the largely agrarian population. Russia’s lack of a stable middle class meant
that anti-system parties like the Bolshevik could take advantage of peasant anxieties
to undermine support for the Provisional Government. Promising peace for soldiers
unpopular war) and bread for peasants, the Bolsheviks were able to manipulate
decisions, and lack of middle-class support, replaced only nine months later by a
dismantle it in practice.
The collapse of the Russian empire created a temporary vacuum of power along
is peripheries. As a result, a number of new states sprung from its periphery that
February 1918, Azerbaijan, Georgia, and the eastern (Russian) portion of Armenia
nationality had wanted its own state, Wilson told the Azeri delegation at the Paris
them to form a union in order to achieve international recognition. When the union
split apart after only three months later, its constituent members created three
universal suffrage (including female suffrage – the first Muslim country to do so). In
January 1920 the Allied Supreme Council formally recognized the new states, but
by that point the Bolshevik state was re-asserting its former territorial claims. The
Red Army occupied Azerbaijan in April 1920, Armenia (with Ottoman forces) in
December 1920, and Georgia in March 1921, ending their brief attempts at
crisis of the war created self-destructing democracies. The war had temporarily
weakened a losing hegemon to such an extent that sovereign states began peeling
from its peripheries. But as the country stabilized itself after a civil war, these new
territories were rapidly re-absorbed into the old empire, which had by now
Across eastern and central Europe, new countries were plagued by weak and
and a catalyst for the autocratic turn of that decade – was a problem for many of
these states from the start. In the Baltics, fragmented legislatures composed of a
coalitions. In Estonia between 1919 and 1933 an average government lasted eight
months.163 The lack of political leadership was made worse by the absence of
unifying native figures during the period of Russian domination.164 Lithuania was
163
Eglitis 2007:234-5
164
Sontag 1971:67
167
through the 1930s, however, and cannot be considered part of the post-war
1934) can be more properly attributed to the Great Depression and the
Poland also experienced paralyzing party factionalism in the postwar years, and
admired for his role in restoring Polish independence and in the war with the new
Soviet Union. Pilsudski acted as the country’s Chief of State until 1922, withdrew
from politics in the following year and seized dictatorial power in 1926, ruling until
his death in 1935.166 Hungary was another country in which a weak parliament
created the space for an authoritarian turn, although in this case the collapse was
much quicker. In October 1918 the liberal leftist count Mihaly Karolyi led the
Once again, the domestic conditions inside the country were not conducive for
discontent among the elites by preserving a prewar-size civil service that operated
165
Eglitis 2007:234
166
Sontag 1971:67
167
Stanley G. Payne (1995) A History of Fascism, 1914-1945, University of
Wisconsin Press, p.26
168
dvoevlastiye in 1917 that inhibited the parliament from exercising its authority and
undermined its rule in both cases. Hungary’s Social Democrats, for instance,
punitive armistice quickly drained public support for the new regime, until a
months after Karolyi’s revolution. This in turn led to foreign intervention and a
In Bulgaria, postwar politics were dominated by the Agrarian Union until its
the peasants, who comprised nearly eighty percent of the population. 168 Despite
his popularity with the peasants, Stamboliyski found no support among either the
small middle class or the military. His party formed its own militia, called the
Orange Shirts, who intimidated the political opposition. As one of the Central
Powers in the war, Bulgaria was subject to a harsh peace treaty that reduced its
territory, limited its army to twenty thousand men, and forced it to pay a hundred
168
Payne 1995:133
169
increasingly unpopular with right-wing factions and the army, who finally carried
out a coup in June 1923. While Stamboliyski pursued a peaceful foreign policy and
genuinely sought to secure the political rights of the Bulgarian peasantry, his rule
exhibited a heavy hand in dealing with those who disagreed with his policies. As
with other countries in the region, Bulgaria’s political atmosphere was too volatile
to maintain even a semblance of democracy, though in this case the downfall came
Democracy failed not only in new states but also in places like Portugal, which
had some history with liberal constitutional rule, although of the oligarchic rather
than democratic sort. For a few years after the war, the Republican parliamentary
regime plodded along, “registering the greatest cabinet instability of any state in
Europe, accompanied by high inflation, a massive public debt, and only minimal
on consensus and compromise, was not suited for the fractious, multi-ethnic
politics of Yugoslavia after 1919. It had existed since that time under the name of
169
Payne 1995:143
170
when King Alexander – himself a Serb who found governing increasingly difficult
long as it did, with political compromise so difficult to achieve in “so complex and
the crisis passed. In his push for making the world safe for democracy, Woodrow
began to seem more inevitable, the country’s leaders began backing democratic
reforms in the hopes of securing a more favorable agreement with the Allies,
particularly from the United States. In September 1918, General Erich Ludendorff
170
Charles Tilly (2004) Contention & Democracy in Europe, 1650-2000, Cambridge
University Press, p.230-31
171
Payne 1995:144
171
dictatorship that ran the country during the last two years of the war.172 He
anticipated that the hegemonic influence exerted by the United States would allow
democracy. Along the same lines, in October 1918 the Kaiser asked the liberal
negotiations with the Entente powers. (As a signal of his democratic intentions, the
Democrats for the first time in German history.) During this period, Wilson
notes, “this external pressure helped generate the incremental steps” taken by the
power shifted to the elected Reichstag while the Chancellor, the Cabinet and the
executive branch no longer reported to the Kaiser.173 These steps were taken with
the hope that American influence would lead to more tolerable surrender terms for
States. After the war ended, however, Wilson lost his bargaining leverage both with
the Allies (and with France in particular) and among the United States congress,
who accused Wilson of leniency and pushed for a harsher peace. France insisted
172
Peceny 2010:9, See also Evans 2004:61; Martin Kitchen (1976) The Silent
Dictatorship: The Politics of the German High Command under Hindenburg and
Ludendorff, 1916-1918. London: Croom Helm; Klaus Schwabe (1985) Woodrow
Wilson, Revolutionary Germany, and Peacemaking, 1918-1919, transl by Rita and
Robert Kimber, University of North Carolina Press
173
Peceny 2010:11
172
democratization in central and eastern Europe fell by the wayside as France began
influence, regardless of their internal regime.) Britain’s Liberal Party was more
conservative coalition that demanded a much more punitive peace. Wilson lost
even the support of his own Congress, as the Republicans won both houses in
midterm elections held days before the signing of the Armistice in November 1918.
During the election, the Republicans had accused Wilson of being soft on
The Allied victory thus not only destroyed the legitimacy of Germany’s
November of 1918, but also created incentives for erstwhile German conservatives
before the end of the war resulted from “the contingent commitment to democracy
republican Germany would earn a more lenient peace agreement than one
a favorable outcome in postwar negotiations with the Allies. When that outcome
174
Peceny 2010:14. See also Arno J. Mayer (1967) Politics and Diplomacy of
Peacemaking: Containment and Counterrevolution at Versailles, 1918-1919, New
York: Alfred A. Knopf
175
Peceny 2010:1
173
failed to materialize, the incentive for democratization among the army and the
conservative elites faded as well, providing another blow to the uneasy pro-
“Weimar coalition” – the Majority Social Democrats, the catholic Center party, and
the liberal German Democratic party – was saddled with blame for the punitive
judgment brought upon the country at Versailles. These three parties had been the
foremost proponents of democratization before the war, and their failure to secure
a tolerable peace crippled their ability to govern through the 1920s. Between 1919
(the last time the Weimar coalition gained an electoral majority) and 1933, the
Reichstag did not sustain a majority government and was constantly challenged by
anti-system parties from both the extreme left and the extreme right. The initial
popularity of the Social Democrats stemmed in large part from middle-class voters
who saw a strong Social Democratic party as a defense against labor unrest and a
democratic reforms offered by the Weimar Coalition for that reason, as the
[T]he General Staff agreed with the Majority Social Democrats under
Friedrich Ebert that the threat of the revolutionary workers’ and
soldiers’ council would best be warded off if they worked in tandem
to secure a stable parliamentary democracy…this was an act of
expediency, not of faith….Within a short space of time, however, the
workers’ and soldiers’ councils had faded from the political scene,
and the need for compromise with the forces of democracy seemed
to many leading officers to have lost its urgency.177
176
Peceny 2010:12. See also F.L. Carsten (1972) Revolution in Central Europe:
1918-1919, University of California Press
177
Evans 2004:97.
174
Business interests likewise stood behind democratic reforms for reasons that
were bound to disappear as the Communist threat receded. “Like other elements of
the Wilhelmine establishment,” writes Evans, “big business accepted the Republic
because it seemed the most likely way of warding off something worse.”178 But as
industrialists, the aristocracy and the forces of democracy began to diverge. The
Social Democrats’ representation in the Reichstag fell from an all-time high of 38%
in the 1919 elections to around 25% over the next decade.179 “The widespread
feeling after 1923 that the threat of a Bolshevik revolution had receded,” writes
Evans, “meant that the bourgeois parties were no longer so willing to compromise
with the Social Democrats in the interests of preserving the Republic as a bulwark
against Communism.”180
Between 1919 and 1933 the country saw twenty different cabinets, each lasting
on average less than eight months. Unstable coalitions created constant squabbles
and weakened the parliament’s ability to govern, “since all they could settle on was
the lowest common denominator and the line of least resistance.”181 While the
reforms, this influence did not materialize in the aftermath of the war and fatally
178
Evans 2004:112-3, citing Henry Ashby Turner, Jr. (1985) German Big Business
and the Rise of Hitler and Gerald D. Feldman (1966) Army, Industry, and Labor in
Germany, 1914-1918, Princeton University Press
179
Evans 2004:88. After gaining 163 votes in the 1919 founding elections, the
Social Democrats received 102 votes in 1920.
180
Evans 2004:96
181
Evans 2004:83
175
crippled the governing Weimar Coalition. In short, the crisis of the war generated
two incentives for liberalization – fear of Communism and hope for an American-
led settlement – that disappeared in the postwar years, undermining the effort to
In the interwar period, Czechoslovakia was the exception that proved the rule.
dual executive designed to keep the president weak, guarantees of individual rights
Slovaks, it stood apart as the only east European state that retained democratic
institutions through the 1930s.184 In the second half of the 1930s it was an island of
1939.
182
Sharon L. Wolchik (2007) “The Czech and Slovak Republics: Two Paths to the
Same Destination” p.192 in Wolchik and Curry, eds
183
Lloyd Cutler and Herman Schwartz (1991) “Constitutional Reform in
Czechoslovakia: E Duobus Unum?” The University of Chicago Law Review 58.2, p.
513
184
For an opposing view, see Andrea Orzoff (2009) Battle for the Castle: The Myth
of Czechoslovakia in Europe, 1914-1948, Oxford University Press; Mary Heinmann
(2011) Czechoslovakia: The State That Failed, Yale University Press
176
of the party coalitions. The so-called petka, a five-party coalition that ruled the
coherence and internal stability through the petka. Its members met regularly to
advise the prime minister and shape cabinet policies. These sessions ensured that
internal disagreements did not spiral out of control, prevented cabinet crises at
the government to maintain unity in the eyes of public opinion, and created rigid
discipline and a locus for political action when necessary.186 As a result, the
continent.
E.H. Carr later wrote in The Twenty Years Crisis: “The liberal democracies scattered
throughout the world by the peace settlement of 1919 were the product of abstract
theory, stuck no roots in the soil, and quickly shriveled away.”187 Across much of
185
Wolchik 2007:193
186
R. J. Crampton (1997) Eastern Europe in the Twentieth Century – And After,
New York: Routledge, p.63
187
E.H. Carr (1939/1964) The Twenty Years Crisis: 1919-1939, Harper Perennial,
p.27.
177
Europe, democracies “had to operate in a world in which it had many enemies, old
and new,” writes Roberts. “It had not been a widespread form of government
before 1914 and many Europeans were soon regretting the passing of the regimes
under which they had previously lived.”188 The political and economic instability in
writes:
universal acclaim, reality soon showed that these hopes had created the
democratic version of a stock market bubble on the European continent, one that
was bound to burst as the decade set in. Extraordinary ad hoc domestic coalitions
that came together to create the initial wave dissolved as the immediate crisis of the
188
Roberts 2008:284
189
Frieden 2006:134
178
Conclusion
The First World War produced the century’s first democratic wave by
working-class men. With its reliance on industrial production at home and mass
armies at the front, the war made the support of workers and conscripted soldiers
crucial for waging the war. The connection between mass mobilization and
democracy was not predetermined, but mobilization did open up opportunities for
The defeat of autocracies and the emergence of the United States as a new
premise of the Versailles treaty – the idea of democracy as the answer to the
problems of modernity – was not established by the outcome of the war. The
democracies that emerged from the war were “never secure in their claims of
legitimacy in those states where this legitimacy was most closely tested.”190 The
Soviet Union after 1923 and Germany after 1933 – two states excluded from the
negotiations at Versailles – would in time offer their own visions of the modern
state. By the end of the 1930s, democracy appeared discredited and moribund.
Given the general tenor of that period, can we separate the democratic backlash of
the 1920s from the authoritarian, fascist-inspired wave of the 1930s? These
190
Bobbitt 2003:40
179
distinctions are not always easy to draw, but one essential difference was the
conservatives moved away from democracy to preserve the old order and exclude
the masses from political life. By the next decade, revolutionary conservatives
sought to demolish the old order, to bring the masses into politics, and to
The postwar democratic wave sowed seeds of its own demise as rulers and
the changes dissolved as the crisis passed. In addition, those rulers who saw
democratization as a way to ingratiate themselves with the United States were met
liberal democracy embraced the liberal creed because they thought Wilson and the
victorious Allies would provide material benefits to those who jumped on the
democratic bandwagon,” writes Peceny. “Over time, the failure of the liberal great
powers to reward other states for embracing liberal institutions…led those who
Wilson had hoped that Europe would accept his vision for the world “more by
191
Peceny 2010:3
180
moral and ideological appeal,” as Ikenberry puts it, “than by the exercise of
American power or diplomatic tact.”192 In the end, that hope proved elusive. The
failure of the post-war wave can therefore be explained in part by the rising
relying instead on the expectation that emulation alone would create a world safe
for democracy.
In failing to resolve the major dilemma of the twentieth century – the design
and legitimacy of the modern nation-state – World War I was the first a series of
outcome of these confrontations were shaped in large part by sudden shocks to the
global distribution of power and the incentives for reform they created in states
around the world. In the end, the war was “indeed a victory for democracy, though
a bitter one,” writes Palmer. “For the basic problems of modern civilization,
no answer.”193 Its outcome inaugurated a struggle for influence and legitimacy that
ended only when the last remaining alternative imploded in 1991. But in the late
1920s, Europe’s first democratic experiment teetered on the edge of failure. It was
the Great Depression that sent it into the abyss of the interwar years.
192
Ikenberry 2001:155
193
Palmer el al 2002:696
181
CHAPTER 4
book was actually a eulogy for what Schumpeter saw as a dying system. Although
it was the ever-evolving nature of capitalism that made it the best system for
increasing productivity and standards of living, Schumpeter did not believe that
1
A.D. Lindsay (1951) The Essentials of Democracy, Oxford University Press, p.7,
quoted in Fritz Stern (1997) “The new democracies in crisis in interwar Europe” in
Axel Hadenius, ed., Democracy’s Victory and Crisis, Cambridge University Press.
2
W.H. Auden (1939) “September 1, 1939” in Another Time
182
universal hostility to its own social order.” The replacement of the petit bourgeois
defunctionalized and absentee ownership does not call forth moral allegiance as
the vital form of property did.” And even as the progress of capitalism corroded its
own moral legitimacy, it spurred an alienated and hostile class of intellectuals who
further undermined the system’s appeal and incited movements that would call for
its replacement.3
process” and therefore associated with its failure, their decline would be
Schumpeter did not believe that the fractious nature of democracy was equipped to
handle the conflicts of complex modern societies, since “the democratic method
never works at its best when nations are much divided on fundamental questions of
socialism and fascism, in which socialism would eventually emerge as the winner.
because of the system’s inherent inability to resolve serious class conflict, but also
3
Joseph A. Schumpeter (1942) Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy, p.143,142,
151. Page numbers refer to the third edition, New York: Harper and Row, 1950.
183
that followed the onset of the Great Depression in 1929 and accelerated with the
Nazi ascent to power in 1933. Moreover, this reversal of fortune was directly tied
to the differences between fascist and democratic institutions. All across Europe,
writes Sheri Berman, “the political and economic policies and appeals offered by
fascists and national socialists proved to be widely popular. Tapping into the
widespread longing for some alternative to the reigning capitalist system and for an
end to class conflict and social divisions, fascists and national socialists managed to
The wave of fascism that swept the world after 1933 was the result of a growing
especially the United States – and their vibrant non-democratic rivals, Nazi
4
Schumpeter 1942:297-8
5
Sheri Berman (2006) The Primacy of Politics: Social Democracy and the Making
of Europe’s Twentieth Century, Cambridge University Press, p.151
6
Jeffry A. Frieden (2006) Global Capitalism: Its Fall and Rise in the Twentieth
Century, W.W. Norton and Company, p. 228
184
Germany and the Soviet Union. Amid the decay and fear of the 1930s (Auden’s
“low, dishonest decade”) the latter two stood as beacons of hope and models of
growth for leaders and masses alike. They had loudly rejected the conventional
politics and economics associated with the Great Depression, and presented
Electoral triumphs in 1933 and a fascist victory in the Spanish civil war three years
later “showed that fascists could win both in the polling booth and on the
battlefield. For many people, democracy did not seem up to the dynamic new
challenge.”7 The years of the Great Depression were a time “when the idea of
Parliament as a fraud and a folly, a slow-footed relic of a dying age, was a standard
This chapter traces the growth in influence of authoritarian movements and the
world in the decade between 1933 and 1943. Since Soviet relative power grew less
slowly in this period, and the adoption of Communist institutions did not reach
critical mass until after the war, in this chapter I focus primarily on the influence of
fascism.
In its timing and content, the wave of reforms conformed to the expected
7
John Markoff, Waves of Democracy: Social Movements and Political Change, Pine
Forge Press, 1996, p.77
8
Adam Gopnik (2010) “Finest Hours” The New Yorker, August 30, p.81.
185
inefficient. At the same time, as Germany began to increase its share of relative
power and eliminated the pernicious scourge of unemployment, other states began
particularly into South America and Eastern Europe, also drew states into its orbit.
Germany and Italy also attempted to extend their influence through the financial
support of a number of fascist movements in Europe, the Middle East, and Latin
America. The onset of World War II began the final, coercive phase of the fascist
wave, as Germany and Japan set up a number of puppets and tutelary regimes
Thus all three mechanisms of emulation, influence, and coercion (in that
general order) contributed to the fascist wave between 1933 and 1943. In this
period, a number of states adopted fascist institutions and expressed admiration for
Austria, Spain, Hungary, Romania, and Japan, and to a lesser extent Portugal and
Greece. The list expanded greatly during Nazi takeovers between 1938 and 1943.
At its height in the summer of 1942, the fascist order – fascist states, its occupied
territories, colonies, satellites, puppets and tutelary regimes – included half the
world’s population, or “virtually all of Europe and the Middle East and much of
Asia and Africa.”9 Hitler’s empire alone “stretched from the Mediterranean to the
9
Frieden 2007:215
186
Arctic, from the English Channel to the Black Sea and almost the Caspian.”10
The timing of the fascist wave also demonstrates the importance of hegemonic
(although his regime was not consolidated until several years later and opposition
newspapers continued until 1925). But as with the Russian revolution of 1917, a
new ideology alone could not inspire a fascist wave without an accompanying
popularity until after 1933. Stanley Payne, a prominent historian of fascism, noted
the paucity of philofascist groups in the 1920s, concluding that “the major diffusion
Romania, for example, was formed in 1927 but did develop any significant
efforts failed during the 1920s but succeeded in the following decade, encouraged
The growing power of Germany meant that it could also exercise influence in
more direct but not coercive ways. This took the form of increasing trade ties with
regions that did not have established relations with Western colonial powers,
10
Randall Schweller (1998) Deadly Imbalances: Tripolarity and Hitler’s Strategy of
World Conquest, Columbia University Press, p.1
11
Stanley G. Payne (1995) A History of Fascism, 1914-1945, University of
Wisconsin Press, p.290
12
Payne 1995:138, 268
187
particularly in Latin America and central Europe. In Latin America, for example,
Germany’s share of imports grew from 7.3% to 16.2% between 1932 and 1938.13
This enabled Germany to intervene in the economic affairs of its trading partners;
in Eastern Europe, for example, it forced Romania to reserve its mineral oils for
German power revived, neutrality became much more difficult for its neighbors,
who were forced to move closer toward a regime they may not have wished to
imitate otherwise.
But focusing on the overt expansion in influence and territory omits the more
subtle channels through which fascist influence manifested itself in nominally non-
fascist states. Beginning in the early 1930s, political leaders all over the world
political mobilization and strong executive rule were all hallmarks of statist
innovations that took hold in the 1930s and later became essential components of
national socialists – such as the notion of a “people’s party” and an economic order
that aimed to control but not destroy capitalism – became central features of
13
Hartmut Elsenhans (1991) “The Great Depression of the 1930s and the Third
World” International Studies 28.3, p.279
14
Elsenhans 1991:279
188
regime. More than any other regime type of the twentieth century, fascism eludes a
concise definition. The historian Stanley Payne calls it “the vaguest of the major
Defining fascism is a difficult task; although during the height of its appeal it drew
many intellectuals into its orbit, it lacked the theoretical and intellectual tradition of
certain leaders called themselves fascists without embracing any of its institutional
features. Others rejected the label even as they assiduously imitated elements of
fascist regimes. At the same time, and particularly after World War II, “people of
every political persuasion, and especially socialists and communists, have tended
“program”. There were important differences even within the two archetypal states,
15
Berman 2006:151
16
Payne 1995:3; Furet 1999:3
17
Furet 1999:187
18
Peter H. Merkl (1980) “Comparing Fascist Movements” in Stein Ugelvik Larsen,
Bernt Hagtvet, and Jan Petter Myklebust, eds., Who Were the Fascists: Social Roots
of European Fascism, Oslo: Universitetsforlaget, p. 752
189
Italy and Germany. The German authoritarians were, strictly speaking, Nazis rather
than fascists. Whereas for fascism economy and society existed to exalt the state,
for Nazis the state was the paramount instrument through which culture, politics
and economics served to exalt the Aryan race. Its apotheosis was the Volk and the
Volksgemeinschaft rather than the government - and although this distinction was
more than cosmetic, its practical consequence in both cases led to the total
subjugation of the individual to the state apparatus. In this chapter I use the term
“fascism” to refer to both variants, following Payne’s advice to treat the word as “as
a general type or generic phenomenon for heuristic and analytic purposes.” The
fascist regime, he writes, “is an abstraction which never existed in pure empirical
form but constitutes a conceptual device which serves to clarify the analysis of
economy and the individual. It arose as a response and a challenge not only to
political will. In this it overlapped with communism, its sworn enemy. But while it
rejected the primacy of capitalism over politics, it never went so far as to abandon
19
Payne 1995:4
190
scale finance capitalism, and found many supporters among small landowners. As
presented threat from the left, while monopolies and large landowners threatened
the small property-owners from the right.)20Also unlike communism, fascism saw
than socioeconomic classes. And while Communism sought to break free from the
chains of the past, fascists sought a return to a mythical, prelapsarian age, free of
yesteryear, but this resemblance was only partial. As documented in the previous
chapter, democratic breakdowns began to occur soon after World War I. Given the
general authoritarian bent of the period, how does one separate democratic
difficult to trace in some cases. But with the exception of Italy, until 1933 what
replaced democracy in these states was traditional conservative rule. It is here that
Depression meant that authoritarian leaders could no longer remain content with
20
William Brunstein and Marit Berntson (1999) “Interwar Fascist Popularity in
Europe and the Default of the Left” European Sociological Review 15.2, p. 174. As
they put it, “no fascist movement became a major political party without having
mobilized the class of small property-owners….where the left abandoned small
property-holders by taking a maximalist stand on defence of small property, an
opening occurred for another party to defend small property rights (e.g. fascist
parties). By contrast, where the left took up the defence of small property, new
parties could not establish a foothold.” Brustein and Berntson 1999:162
191
the classical authoritarian model. Instead of merely defending the status quo, the
government now had to step in to stimulate the economy with welfare programs
and deficit spending. The mobilization of popular support replaced the innate
In short, the populist authoritarian regimes of the 1930s moved away from their
of fascist institutions. “The 1930s and 1940s were the period of fascist success,”
writes the historian Hugh Seton-Watson. “Inevitably fascist policies and institutions
certain outward trappings of fascist style-to present a more modern and dynamic
image, with the hope of attaining broader mobilization and infrastructure.”22 This
process was not synonymous with fascism – but, Payne notes, “it would be grossly
borrowed the public aesthetics, the choreography, and the semiotics of fascism,
along with a new approach to political economy that emphasized the primacy of
21
Hugh Seton-Watson (1979) “The Age of Fascism and its Legacy” in George L.
Mosse, ed., International Fascism: New Thoughts and New Approaches, Sage
Publications, p.365. He cites as some “obvious examples” Gombos’ Hungary,
Stojadinovic’s Yugoslavia, and King Carol’s Romania.
22
Payne 1995:290. Harold Macmillan in 1933 euphemistically named this
selective imitation “orderly capitalism” (quoted in Schivelbusch 2006:12)
23
Payne 1995:15. Even when authoritarianism did not mean fascism, “it became
common for authoritarian regimes to imitate certain aspects of the fascist style.”
Payne 1995:290
192
political will over the national economy.24 Fascists and authoritarians had common
enemies – big business, liberalism, Jews, and communists – categories that often
overlapped in the muddled rhetoric of the times. Common goals led to “numerous
sometimes even cases of outright fusion, especially between fascists and the radical
reforms, the fascist model presented a natural path for development. The kings of
Romania, Bulgaria, Greece, and Yugoslavia “ruled with the support of local
conservatives needed the fascists' mass base; the fascists needed the conservatives'
credibility with big business.”26 And although the new authoritarians of the 1930s
rarely approached the Third Reich’s “total coordination of all political, economic,
Unlike the classic conservatives who fetishized tradition, fascists sought a break
24
This process parallels the creation of hybrid democracies of the past two
decades. These are states that have adopted the outward trappings of democracy
without undergoing more fundamental government reforms. In both instances such
adaptation shows the increasing power and legitimacy of a winning regime type
after a hegemonic shock. Fascism in the 1930s and democracy in the 1990s (as
well as in the early 1920s) had appeared so dominant and ascendant a regime that
political leaders felt compelled to imitate their institutions even when they did not
wish to actually transform their governments.
25
Payne 1995:16
26
Frieden 2006:210
27
Palmer et al 2002:800
193
from the old authoritarian ways of rule. Masses would be mobilized rather than
shut out of politics. The sentiments that led to mass uprisings in nineteenth-century
Europe would now be vented into new channels of discontent through spectacular
rallies. Even though they were not always successful in this pursuit, fascist
poorly mobilized liberal groups or the sectarian exclusiveness and reliance on elite
their original ideas they often closely resemble old-fashioned conservatives, but
belong not to the idealized past but to the modern age,” writes Hugh Seton-
Watson. “Their outlook may be nostalgic, and it is certainly elitist, but as a political
force they are more democratic than oligarchic.”29 As Rothermund points out, the
fascist cult of the leader “was more primitive and barbarian than the Italian and
German monarchies of prewar times. On the other hand it was very modern in its
use of the mass media and in its support of science and technology.” 30 Frieden
28
Payne 1995:12
29
Seton-Watson 1979:357-8
30
Dietmar Rothermund (1996) The Global Impact of the Great Depression, 1929-
1939, Routledge, p.139
194
Fascism was thus both a refutation of the past and the embrace of a pastoral,
idealized simulacrum of that past. It rejected a vulgar and decadent modernity even
negation of the world in which it resided (Hitler was, in the words of lapsed Nazi
world anew. It was a particularistic, national creed that sought - and found -
imitators in countries and colonies spread widely around the world. (In 1928
Mussolini famously declared that fascism was “not for export” before embarking, a
combine a broad populism with a belief in the power of a select oligarchy: “The
appeal to the entire people and nation, together with the attempt to incorporate the
masses in both structure and myth,” writes Payne, “was accompanied by a strong
formal emphasis on the role and function of an elite, which was held to be both
31
Frieden 2006:211
32
Quoted in Furet 1999:187
33
Payne 1995:463. By 1934 Mussolini was promoting the ideology of “universal
fascism”.
195
fascist ‘ideology’ which attracted all kinds of people – often for very different
reasons. In this respect,” he argues, “fascism shared many traits with other populist
movements which also drew strength from diffuse sets of ideas rather than from
intellectual clarity.”35
But even if the ideas were diffuse, even if fascism is best conceptualized as a
of its family traits, and what was that philosophy? One distinguishing feature the
glorification of war and the militarization of party politics. For fascists “war was an
since it was born out of the failure of peacemaking of World War I. Martial virtues
suffused daily politics, finding expression in militia and paramilitary groups (the so-
the military insignia, terminology, and rituals that reinforced the idea of national
struggle; and even in the “male chauvinism and the tendency to exaggerate the
masculine principle in almost every aspect of activity.”37 Another feature was the
34
Payne 1995:14
35
Rothermund 1996:140
36
Wolfgang Schivelbusch (2006) Three New Deals: Reflections on Roosevelt’s
America, Mussolini’s Italy, and Hitler’s Germany, 1933-1939, Metropolitan Books,
p. 39
37
Payne 1995:13
196
authoritarian leader and a cult of personality are obviously not limited to fascist
and subordination,” writes Payne, “so that all fascist movements came to espouse
between the society and the economy, and this was its other distinctive trait that
would later be adopted and absorbed by liberal democracy - transforming it, in the
industrial capital to the needs of the state and the nation, in the process “creating a
welfare schemes and labor programs that aimed to create full employment. Trade
eliminated, wages were kept down, production stepped up and full employment
38
Payne 1995:14; See also Seton-Watson 1979:368
39
Payne 1995:10
197
was quickly achieved.”40 Fascists’ relationship with business was not entirely
antagonistic; while they placed controls on the economy and encouraged autarky,
Given the above elements, which countries in the 1930s would qualify as
fascist? The answer is not found in a simple enumeration of who converted and
who resisted. The division was never that clear-cut. As Payne puts it:
A strict definition would limit the list of fascist states to one - Italy. At the same
movements which played a leading part in Europe in the 1930s and 1940s, and
which historians ought to see in their relations to each other.” 43 More expansive
definitions would also include Germany, Austria, Japan, Hungary, Romania, Spain,
Latin America, and philofascist movements expanded their influence in the Middle
East.
40
Rothermund 1996:139
41
Frieden 2006:213
42
Payne 1995:462
43
Seton-Watson 1979:357
198
manifested itself not in the often small vote shares of fascist movements, but in the
German ability to solve the problems of unemployment and social unrest through
state planning attracted a great deal of interest and admiration, and spurred
imitation driven by the need to compete in the international arena. Wrote Karl
the ideological underpinnings that shaped their creation. The most widely adopted
injected political control into the national economy. This subordination of the
economic by the political took the form of extensive regulation, state planning
committees, industrial subsidies, price and wage controls, job creation programs,
A major difference between the fascist regimes and countries like France,
Sweden and the United States was that they chose to co-opt the labor movement
rather than destroy it. But the fundamental goal and the method by which the goal
was reached was still borrowed from fascist innovations – the establishment of a
mixed economy in which the state would regulate economic activity in order to
44
Karl Manheim (1940) Man and Society in an Age of Reconstruction, New York,
p. 338; quoted in Wolfgang Schivelbusch 2006:190
199
avoid the vices of capitalism. As Schivelbusch notes, the policy discussions in the
world’s remaining democracies “show how willing many people within the liberal
camp were to try to save the situation by jettisoning liberal ballast. Some suggested
Britain “was a uniquely gloomy and fearful era, a morbid age that saw the future of
civilization in terms of disease, decay, and death” and experienced a loss of faith in
the free-market system.46 Central planning seemed to be the answer, and held
much appeal in the 1930s: “The successes of the planned economies in the 1930s
unregulated after the chaos of the slump.”47 These fears extended to issues of
everyday governance, such as public infrastructure; “There was much angst in the
1930s…about the speed with which fascist Italy and Germany were building
[roads], leaving muddled, democratic Britain in the dust.”48 “The mere efficiency of
such a system, the elimination of waste and obstruction, is obvious,” wrote George
Orwell about fascism in 1939. “However horrible this system may seem to us, it
45
Schivelbusch 2006:11-12
46
The Economist (2009) “Britain between the wars: A sense of dread” April 25,
p.86, citing Richard Overy (2009) The Morbid Age: Britain Between the Wars,
Allen Lane. Kennedy (1987:316) notes that Britain’s “ailing economy was shaken to
its roots by the world-wide slump after 1929.”
47
Alan Booth (1999) “The British Reaction” in W.R. Garside, ed., Capitalism in
Crisis: An International Perspective on the 1930s, Palgrave Macmillan, p.47
48
The Economist (2009) “Review of Joe Moran (2009) On Roads: A Hidden
History,” June 20, 2009, p. 89
200
works.”49
manifested itself in institutional imitation. The only categorically fascist party in the
whose ranks peaked at fifteen thousand and whose members, many of whom
German immigrants, never stood the chance of winning actual political office.
German institutions by the New Dealers. In a case study of the United States
presented later in the chapter, I document the many ways in which American
intellectuals, civil servants and politicians expressed admiration for Nazi reforms
while rejecting the racial, authoritarian, and aggressive aspects of that regime. For
now a few examples will suffice. Rexford Tugwell, a member of Roosevelt’s brain
trust, openly expressed his admiration for Soviet planning and fascist corporatism.
as “the cleanest, neatnest [sic], most efficiently operating piece of social machinery
I’ve ever seen. It makes me envious.”50 As late as 1938, Roosevelt ordered a report
material against the Third Reich, but as a source of information and inspiration”.51
49
George Orwell (1941) “The Lion and the Unicorn”, original emphasis
50
Michael Vincent Namorato, ed. (1992) The Diary of Rexford G. Tugwell: The
New Deal, 1932-1935, New York, p. 139. Quoted in Schivelbusch 2006:32.
51
Norbert Gotz and Kiran Klaus Patel (2006) “Facing the Fascist Model: Discourse
and the Construction of Labour Services in the USA and Sweden in the 1930s and
1940s” Journal of Contemporary History 41.1, p.62-3
201
Thanking the American ambassador in Berlin for the report, he wrote: “All of this
helps us in planning, even though our methods are of the democratic variety!’”52
beginning of the war, and particularly after the Axis defeat in 1945. Any hint of
German influence was expunged from official statements. For example, when the
and actually integrated some of its elements into the Civilian Conservation Corps,
“there was no public outcry…By 1941 that would have been unthinkable.” Instead,
“The openness that had marked the late 1930s had vanished. In the face of the
to the American public.”53 The surprising extent of fascist institutional influence has
predictable if self-serving reasons. After the war, “memories of the New Deal’s
common roots with its enemies were repressed, and postwar America was free to
“Despite the horror of the Nazi period, or rather because of it, the parallels
between the German experience and those of other countries are important,” writes
crisis of the 1930s. “The economic policy experimentation of the early years of the
Nazi period is an enhanced form of what Sweden, the United States, and France
52
Quoted in Gotz and Patel 2006:63
53
Gotz and Patel 2006:65, 71
54
Schivelbusch 2006:14
202
were groping toward in the 1930s and what most of Western Europe and North
American pursued after World War II: a mixed economy, with fiscal stimulus,
demand stimulus and corporatist market regulation in the 1930s.”56 The fact that
the United States does not diminish the fact that it served as an institutional model
Decades later, with the benefit of hindsight and an instinctual moral revulsion
to fascism, it is difficult to appreciate how much sway this ideology had held in the
1930s. Here the prism of history can distort just as it clarifies. The historian
When we read of Lloyd George returning from a talk with Hitler filled
with praise for his host; when we recall the kind words Churchill had
for what Nazism was doing within Germany even while he was
warning of the menace of Nazi foreign policy; when we reconstruct
the many laudatory things Lord Halifax, so kindly and decent a man,
said in his conversations with Hitler in 1937; and when we note that
the same enthusiasm can be found in supposedly discerning
observers from other countries, then we marvel, because we see,
marching endlessly to their death, the millions of victims of Nazi
racism.57
Yet until the invasion of Czechoslovakia, Sontag notes, the Nazi revolution was
a largely bloodless affair. Until the late 1930s it had only a “few easily ignored
55
Peter Gourevitch (1986) Politics in Hard Times: Comparative Responses to
International Economic Crises, Cornell University Press, p.140
56
Gourevitch 1986: 25
57
Raymond Sontag (1971) A Broken World, 1919-1939, Harper and Row, p.265
203
victims”; few inside Germany had actually been killed or imprisoned and even for
1938.58 This relatively peaceful rise stood in stark contrast to Stalin’s Great Purges,
which took the lives of millions. Culturally, “the surface of German national life
had a color and enthusiasm absent from Russian life”. Geopolitically, “the shift in
the international position of Germany was more obvious than the rise of Russian
national power.”59
As a result of these factors, the Soviet Union was slower to attract imitators.
Most political leaders sought to contain capitalism in the fascist style, not to destroy
period, its real moment of triumph did not arrive until the defeat of fascism in
World War II. And while the defeat of Axis powers led to an abrupt rejection of
fascist ideology in all but a few “risible backwaters”, in the late 1930s fascism
communism nor liberal democracy had had anything like the reproductive and
among all but the hardcore communists that “if a choice must be made, Nazi rule
would be less horrible than Soviet rule” – a view shared not only by the middle and
upper classes, but even the workers and peasants, who “found little to envy in the
58
Sontag 1971:266
59
Sontag 1971: 268
60
Frieden 2006:215
204
shadow of German power which lay on central and southeastern Europe.”61 For all
these reasons, the majority of this chapter focuses on the diffusion of fascist
that follows.
democratic model championed by Britain and the United States. Originating in the
U.S., the Great Depression was seen as “the inevitable result of international, free-
system.62 Not only did the U.S. play the leading role in the financial crisis, it also
suffered more from it than other leading powers. According to Paul Kennedy,
meant that the downturn “hurt it much more than any other advanced economy.”63
Between 1929 and 1933 money income fell by 53 percent. The country’s GNP was
below 1929 levels throughout the decade, and remained there until 1941.
million just four years later, bringing with it a serious threat of social
61
Sontag 1971: 269-70
62
Schivelbusch 2006:105
63
Paul Kennedy (1987) The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers: Economic Change
and Military Conflict from 1500 to 2000, Random House, p.329
64
P. Fearon (1993) “Hoover, Roosevelt and American economic policy during the
205
share of global manufacturing had dropped to its lowest level since 1910.65 For the
first time in the country’s history, more people were leaving the United States than
entering it.66
At the same time, the 1930s witnessed a rapid revival of German power.
Examining the shifts in national power during the interwar period, Kennedy
concluded that the relative power of the United States in the 1930s was “in inverse
ratio to that of both the USSR and Germany. That is to say, it was inordinately
strong in the 1920s, but then declined more than any other of the Great Powers
during the depressed 1930s.”67 Between 1933 and 1939 “Europe lived under the
and France were hurt badly by World War I, and public opinion pressed for peace.
In the mid-1930s Britain and France were decreasing military expenditures, even as
Figure 4.1: Germany vs. the United States. German relative power increases
steadily between 1933 and 1943, while American power decreases until the later
1930s, before recovering and increasing quickly in the early 1940s
Figure 4.2: Number of fascist states, 1930-1945. The number rises steadily between
1933-1930, then quickly increases with the onset of the war, and begins to collapse
as the war nears its conclusion.
207
Figure 4.3: Annual global democracy score (measured by SIP) vs. percent of global
power (measured by CINC) under fascist regimes, 1930-1945. As the share of
power held by fascist states increases, the global average democracy score
declines.
208
Figure 4.4: US Power (measured by CINC) and the annual global democracy score
(measured by SIP), 1930-1945. Both fall until the late 1930s; US power begins to
recover in the early 1940s, and global democracy begins to increase toward the
end of the war.
Europe, Weimar Germany was mired in unemployment and discontent; the Soviet
Union had just barely survived a civil war, foreign invasions and economic
collapse, and spent most of the 1920s retreating from socialism through its New
Economic Plan, which sought to establish market relations between the cities and
the countryside. The crisis of 1929 “hit Germany particularly hard.”69 Between
1929 and 1933, industrial production declined by nearly a half and national
income by a third; the collapse of the stock market depressed both savings and
69
Berman 2006:141
209
than six million Germans – over a third of the labor force – were unemployed.71
Germany’s decline in the late 1920s made its rise after 1933 seem all the more
spectacular. If 1989 was the great turning point for modern democracy, 1933
would prove to be the fascist annus mirabilis. The ascent of the National Socialists
expansion, and the quick end of unemployment. Between January 1933 and July
1935, employment rose from 11.7 million to 16.9 million.72 By 1939, policies of
Meanwhile, industrial production had more than doubled. “In 1933 Germany was
a disarmed and isolated power; by 1939 all Europe trembled in fear of German
power.”73
policies and institutional reforms, and particularly with their eagerness to abandon
the economic and political orthodoxies associated with liberal democracy. “The
pursuit of new paths was a point of pride rather than a difficult break from tradition.
This allowed them to try out program after program until they figured out what
70
Berman 2006:141
71
Sontag 1971: 261
72
Harold James (1993) “Innovation and conservatism in economic recovery: the
alleged ‘Nazi recovery’ of the 1930s” in Garside, ed., p.70
73
Sontag 1971: 261
74
Frieden 2006:212; Dissatisfaction with orthodox politics and economics
210
Goering declared: “We do not recognize the sanctity of some of these so-called
economic laws.”75 Instead, the Nazis pursued an active policy of massive state
relationship with the economy. Under the new policies, and in stark contrast with
subject to the primacy of political and social goals as defined by the national
leadership.” The Nazis shared “an ideological conviction that economic policies
should be integrated with an overall concept of the role of the state. For Hitler
overcome by political will.”76 In early 1935, the Volkischer Beobachter, the official
hands of the politicians. Where capitalism still believes itself untouched, it has
first year, half a million farm and community jobs were created for young adults,
encouraged many fascist converts. Marcel Deat and Jacques Doriot of France and
Paul de Man of Belgium joined the fascists after becoming frustrated with the left;
Oswald Mosley, founder of the British Union of Fascists, founded his group after
leaving both the Conservative and the Labor Party. Richard Vinen (2000) A History
in Fragments: Europe in the Twentieth Century, De Capo Press, p.167
75
Quoted in Vinen 2000:179
76
W.R. Garside (1993) “The search for stability: economic radicalism and financial
conservatism in 1930s Europe” in Garside, ed., p. 20
77
Quoted in James (1993:90) in Garside, ed.
211
another half a million to build public works like roads and bridges. Employees
were ordered to cut wages and received subsidies for new hires.78 The destruction
of labor unions was an important step in this process. While gaining security, the
German workers lost their freedoms. Collective bargaining ended in 1933, and
even switching jobs became difficult by the end of the decade.79 After the Nazis
“destroyed the labor movement and instituted a reign of terror in the workplace,”
businesses did not have to worry about inflationary wage increases.80 The
businessmen that its problems were over: “no more strike waves; no more
Bolshevik threat; no more political instability. All this gave capitalists strong
out of mattresses and foreign bank accounts and sank it into a now-hospitable
business climate.”81
An often forgotten aspect of the National Socialist reforms was that they were
truly socialist. Hitler’s policies “benefited around 95 percent of all Germans. They
did not experience National Socialism as a system of tyranny and terror but rather
reforms and the “real possibility for social advancement” account for the regime’s
78
Frieden p. 203
79
Sontag 1971: 264
80
Frieden p. 203
81
Frieden p. 212
212
high level of mass support.82 These social reforms included free higher education,
help for families and children, pensions, health insurance, and a general expansion
controls over prices, wages, jobs, foreign trade, and the money market. As a result
income between 1928 and 1938.84 Such aggressive stimulus policies would not
have been possible in a liberal democracy without threatening serious inflation, but
prevent price and wage increases."85 The Nazis consciously avoided a Communist-
capitalists would be allowed social status and a measure of profits, as long as they
continued to abide by the rules set by the political leadership and submitted
The rapid recovery thus took on a peculiarly Nazi-inspired path in the view of
82
Gotz Aly (2005) “Die Wohlfuhl-Diktator”Der Spiegel , Oct 2005, p.56; quoted in
Berman 2006:147
83
Berman 2006:147
84
Garside in Garside 1993:21
85
Quoted in Frieden 2006:203
86
Peter Hayes likens capitalism in Nazi Germany to a game of poker in which “the
house shuffles, deals, determines the ante and the wild cards, and can change them
at will,” a game in which “there is a ceiling on winnings, which may be spent only
as the casino permits and for the most part only on the premises.” Peter Hayes
(1987) Industry and Ideology, quoted in James (1993:91) in Garside, ed.
213
encouraged this perception, which served to legitimize their regime and increase
its attractiveness to foreign leaders searching for a way out of the Depression.
Foreign observers, in turn, concluded that these policies worked best in a system
that abandoned the chaos of democracy for the order and stability of fascism. In the
preface to the 1936 German edition of his General Theory, Keynes himself
suggested that his policies were "much more easily adapted to the conditions of a
The Great Depression was the only hegemonic shock of the twentieth century
in which democracy did not emerge as one of the winners – instead, it was widely
perceived to be its culprit. Democracy “seemed to have spent its vitality and
devolved into an economic order that increasingly polarized society into rich and
poor,” a system that appeared as unsuited for modern mass society as feudalism
had become for industrializing states a century earlier.88 The Depression “not only
challenged America’s economy and its political system, but also undermined the
central myths and beliefs on which the system was founded.”89 This sentiment
87
Quoted in Frieden 2006:212
88
Schivelbusch 2006:44.
89
Morris Dickstein (2009) Dancing in the Dark: A Cultural History of the Great
Depression, W.W. Norton. Peter Gourevitch notes: ““In its ability to disrupt
existing political alignments, the Depression rivaled war.” (Gourevitch 1986: 160)
Not only did the crisis begin in the United States, but it was the widely
acknowledged lack of U.S. economic leadership that both made the Depression
worse and further undermined the legitimacy of the American system. In 1939,
E.H. Carr wrote: “In 1918 world leadership was offered, by almost universal
consent, to the United States…[and] was declined.” Carr (1939) The Twenty Years’
214
extended far beyond America itself. “The panic which seized Europe west of Russia
in 1931 was not simply a financial panic,” wrote Sontag. “It was a crisis of
confidence. The accepted precepts for directing the life of man in society seemed
suddenly not to work.”90 The shock of the Great Depression "disproved cultural
modern democracy.91 “It was obvious that laissez-faire capitalism was finished,”
wrote George Orwell in 1940, “and that there had got to be some kind of
reconstruction.”92 A Los Angeles Times article from 1935 declared: “All Europe is
swinging either to the Communist or Fascist side, with the old parliamentary
government in eclipse…”93 In the same year, New Yorker editor E.B. White wrote:
“The experts say that capitalism is out,” and sardonically offered three alternatives:
The remainder of this chapter focuses on tracing fascist influence and emulation
in Europe and around the world. The case studies focus in turn on Europe, Asia, the
Middle East, Latin America, and the United States. I conclude with a brief
discussion of the coercive phase of the fascist wave, beginning roughly in 1938.
Europe served as the locus of fascist imitation, and has thus received the most
attention from scholars of comparative fascism. By the middle of the decade, “most
“countries across southern, central, and eastern Europe – from Portugal to Latvia
lending and a fall in commodity prices. This resulting budget crises and restive
94
E.B. White (1935) “Notes and Comment: The Talk of the Town” The New Yorker,
March 9, p.9
95
Payne 1995:264
96
Frieden 2006:196
216
Hungary
Fascism arrived later in eastern Europe, allowing governing elites in the region
to learn from the Italian and German experiences. This allowed them to keep
revolutionary fascists “at bay by alternately repressing them and stealing their
ideas.”98 A 1939 report to the British Foreign Office noted that the popularity of
fascist ideas in Hungary has led the government to borrow elements of their
established total control only after German occupation (the Arrow Cross in
Hungary, the Iron Guard in Romania), “they also penetrated and influenced”
these regimes “were pervaded by fascist ideas and practices, blended into more
conservative authoritarianism.”100
Among all the states in interwar Europe, “Hungary probably took the prize for
97
Frieden 2006:229
98
Michael Mann (2004) Fascists, Cambridge University Press, p.238. See also Vigo
(1975) for an edited collection of reports by British diplomats that elaborate on this
strategy.
99
John Keyser (1939), in Vigo (1975:354)
100
Mann 2004:238
217
significant political force for the first time. As a result, by the 1930s Hungary
included (starting with the most moderate) the old conservative upper class, the
socialist movements who advocated imitation of fascist elements, and the fascist
Arrow Cross movement of Ferenc Szalasi, which became the country’s largest
At the grass-roots level, a number of fascist organization with the label “national
founded in 1931, seeking to introduce Nazi social reforms into Hungary. In 1933,
three other national socialist parties appeared: the Hungarian National Socialist
Agricultural Laborers and Workers Party, the Hungarian National Socialist People's
Party, and Count Fidel Palffy’s National Socialist Party, whose attempts to form a
Hungarian SA and SS were banned by the government. The leaders of the three
apart over disagreements about the treatment of Jews. The infighting continued
through the mid-1930s, and none of the movements failed to make an impression
101
Payne 1995:267
102
Payne 1995:267-9
218
on a national scale.103
Italy for inspiration appeared in the early 1920s but failed to capture the public’s
imagination during the relative stability of the decade. Gombos, the leader of the
so-called Szeged fascists (named after the city of the communist counter-
revolution), was forced to moderate his views to such an extent that Miklos Horthy,
the country’s regent for most of the interwar period, felt comfortable in co-opting
him as the Defense Minister in 1929, whereupon Gombos dissolved the main
The most significant (and also the most radical) Hungarian fascist movement
was the Arrow Cross or Hungarist organization founded by Ferenc Szalasi. Szalasi’s
Fatherland with Magyar as its official language. This design, however, required a
great leader to carry it out, and somewhat like his Romanian counterpart Codreanu,
that role. This grand vision also required a war to bring it to life, necessitating the
emphasis on martial virtues in daily life that came to define other fascist regimes of
the period. Like other revolutionary autocrats, Szalasi viewed war as “a utopian
cataclysm” that would “introduce the new millenarian world order to be led by
Hungarism”. The Arrow Cross stood for corporatism in economic life and a
103
Payne 1995: 270-1
104
Payne 1995:269
219
The impact of the Great Depression led to the proliferation of the above-
mentioned groups and forced Horthy to abandon the moderate conservatism of the
official visit to Italy, “establishing a pro-Italian tilt for the remainder of his
name and extending its reach throughout the country. He also established a youth
organization and a political militia, the Advance Guard, with a membership of sixty
thousand. This trend was accelerated by Hitler’s ascent to power in 1933, after
which, as in other states in Europe and around the world, “Nazi influence quickly
increased.”107 Gombos moved both the party and the state closer toward fascism,
and the country as a whole “into the orbit of Hitler’s Germany.”108 He visited Hitler
within a month of his election. Economic agreements that followed tied Hungary
105
Payne 1995:272-3
106
Payne 1995:269
107
Payne 1995:269
108
Federigo Argentieri (2007) “Hungary: Dealing with the Past and Moving into the
Present” p.216 in Sharon L. Wolchik and Jane L. Curry, eds., Central and East
European Politics: From Communism to Democracy, Rowman and Littlefield
220
three years Hungary would be reorganized into a national socialist state.”109 His
plans were disrupted, however, by a sudden illness and death at the end of 1936.
His successor, Kalman Daranyi, was a right-wing radical who stopped short of
revolutionary fascism.
The focus on Nazi activity in Hungary thus shifted away from the state, and
toward Szalasi after Gombos’ death. He visited Germany in 1936, and a few
months later “national socialist activity became even more visible in Hungary.”110
Szalasi's followers began organizing militias and calling for a coup, which led to
Szalasi’s brief arrest in 1937 and a forcible dissolution of his party, but this only
raised his status among the national socialists. In the same year his reconstituted
movement was joined by nine other like-minded off-shoots, merging into a greater
Hungarian National Socialist party. By 1938 his movement, generally known as the
Arrow Cross, had become an obvious threat to the state, and Hrothy moved to
protect himself by strengthening the powers of the executive. He gave himself the
now regent for life, and the country’s regime as a whole moved to the right. To
appease the radical right, the government increased military spending and
restricted Jewish rights. The government also formed a political party designed to
outflank the Arrow Cross from the right, the called the Movement of Hungarian Life
109
Payne 1995:270
110
Payne 1995:273
221
(MEM).111
Hungarian history,” the Arrow Cross formed a coalition ticket with other national
socialist parties, although it had officially been dissolved by the government earlier
twenty-five and women under thirty) who formed the bulk of Nazi support, despite
fielding candidates in only half of the electoral districts, and despite “more than a
quarter of the popular vote. The national socialists were now the largest political
force in Hungary, with the Arrow Cross as the country’s largest independent party.
1932. Germany had in fact sent funds to assist the Arrow Cross electoral
Despite the electoral success, the Arrow Cross was now deadlocked with the
government, which remained fully in control and would not countenance radical
experimentation. Szalasi, now in jail, tried to set his party on a legal path to power,
111
MEM was a typical example of a common ploy used by right-wing regimes to
forge a top-down political movement “that would employ some of the trappings of
fascism to rally support but would in fact be controlled by the state from above.”
(Payne 1995:275)
112
Payne 1995:275. The number of enfranchised voters had increased by nearly 50
percent in the last elections.
113
Payne 1995:276
222
As in Austria, Romania, Baltics, and other states, the state’s move toward the right
the authoritarian trappings and ideology of its most dangerous opponents. The
rapid rise of German power on the continent meant that “Hungarian revisionists
came to favor a German alliance,”115 and the country entered the war on the side of
Austria
Austrian fascism. In the 1930 elections the Nazis received 3 percent of the vote,
while the radical right Heimwehr movement received more than 6 percent. In that
year Heimwehr leaders adopted the Korneuburg Oath, which called for a
Styrian Heimwehr Walter Pfrimer, speaking about the reasons behind the
manifesto’s adoption, said: “On all sides the conviction was evident that here in
In the 1932 elections the Nazis amassed 16.4 percent of the vote, drawing
114
Payne 1995:276
115
Mann 2004:245
116
Payne 1995:247
117
quoted in Ludwig Jedlicka (1979) “The Austrian Heimwehr” p. 223-40 in
George L. Mosse, ed., International Fascism: New Thoughts and New Approaches,
Sage Publications, p.234
223
support away from more moderate right-wing movements. With none of the parties
receiving a plurality of votes, the new Christian Social leader Engelbert Dollfuss
was forced to bring the Heimwehr (increasingly influenced by the Nazis) into his
Heimwehr. Both the extreme right (the Nazis) and the extreme left (the Socialists)
were outlawed. After the defeat of a Socialist coup in February 1934, the Austrian
Nazis, who now were the chief opponents of the regime, launched a campaign of
terrorism that culminated in an attempted coup and the murder of Dollfuss in July
1934. The end result was a total suppression of the Nazis, but the government had
already shifted toward a corporatist, proto-fascist regime “copied from the Italian
model.”118 As in other cases in central and eastern Europe, the ruling government
elements of their institutions. The German historian Ulrich Eichsstädt wrote that
Austria had already begun the path toward fascism after March 1933.119 In that
year, both Dollfuss and the Heimwehr leader Stahremberg promised Mussolini that
they would move toward fascism. Hoping to become the regime’s protector,
118
Seton-Watson in Mosse, 365
119
Quoted in Jedlicka 1979:233
120
Payne 1995:247-9
224
one, the second such document to be adopted in Europe (after Portugal’s charter of
seven corporate bodies. Independent political groups were outlawed; the only legal
formed by Dollfuss in 1933 along “the lines of the fascist and national-socialist
parties.”121 In the following few years, Austria’s regime acquired “some of the outer
Fatherland Front organized a paramilitary group called the Frontmiliz in 1936, and
the following year created an elite militia called the Sturmkorps, modeled after
Germany’s SS. While the regime “copied from the methods used in Germany and
and Portugal (following the maxims of the papal encyclical Quadragesimo Anno)
rather than the militant, pagan, racist-biological variant of Nazi Germany.123 With
the Anschluss of March 1938, Austria was incorporated into the greater Third
Reich, and a number of former Heimwehr leaders were given high positions in the
SS.124
Romania
Like Hungary, Romania by the late 1930s was home to one of the largest native
fascist movements on the continent, the Legion of the Archangel Michael, also
121
Jedlicka 1979:237
122
Payne 1995:250
123
Jedlicka 1979:237-8
124
Payne 1995:250-2. Jedlicka 1979:235
225
known as the Iron Guard. Romania was a territorial beneficiary of the Great War,
whose settlement doubled the country’s size. This expansion, however, created a
newly multiethnic state that faced enormous social and economic problems.
Divisions within the ruling Peasant Party after 1926 produced an ineffective
government that was unable to carry out reforms, and when the Depression struck,
a group of army officers engineered the return of King Carol, who had abdicated in
constitution, Carol was an admirer of Mussolini and quickly moved to eliminate the
Peasant Party. In the following years, internal party divisions, prompted in part by
breakdown.”125
League (LANC) and the National Agrarian Party led by the poet Octavian Goga.
1932 was a direct attempt to emulate the Nazis.126 But the major new political
movement to appear after the collapse of the Peasant Party was the fascist Legion of
the Archangel Michael. It was led by Corneliu Zelea Codreanu, who left the LANC
for not being sufficiently revolutionary. In 1930 the group formed a youth
125
Payne 1995:278
126
Payne 1995:279
226
movement called the Iron Guard, and it was under this name that the group has
become more commonly known. The Legion’s leadership “had a strong sense of
affinity with (as well as differences from) the Italian and German movements and
occasionally used the term fascist to refer to themselves.”127 The Romanian version
of fascism embraced the Orthodox Church and declared it a crucial part of the
national organism, while Codreanu himself took on the role of a mystic warrior
who would lead the rebirth of Romania through spiritual and physical war. Other
than this religious component, the Legion “is generally classified as fascist because
it met the main criteria of any appropriate fascist typology,” while its leaders felt a
“common identity and partially parallel goals with other fascists.”128 The exaltation
corporative assembly, and sought a more collective basis for the national economy.
For several years after its founding in 1927 it remained “a tiny sect, a common
experience for most fascist movements in the 1920s.”129 But 1932-33 brought
increasing Nazi influence and popular support. After the rapid growth in the Nazi
vote in Germany’s 1932 elections, links with Romania quickly increased. The 1933
elections brought a wave of intimidation and assault from the Legion, and the party
was banned by the government, its leaders arrested. But their popularity was now
growing rapidly, and Payne estimates their support at two hundred thousand votes,
127
Payne 1995:138
128
Payne 1995:280
129
Payne 1995:282
227
which would have made them the third largest political movement in the country.
The following year the group reconstituted itself as the All for the Fatherland
movement.130
As in other states in the region, the threat of revolutionary fascism led the
moderate, semi-liberal government to move to the right. Corrupt elections gave the
functioned “as a controlled polity with only limited representation.”131 In the mid-
1930s, the government attempted to co-opt the Iron Guard by forming a parafascist
youth group, the Straja Tarii (Guards of the Fatherland), but its artificiality made
popular support nearly impossible. By 1936 the government gave up trying to co-
opt Codreanu and dissolved all political militias in 1936, membership in the Legion
continued to grow steadily, with over two hundred thousand members by the end
of 1937. At that point “German influence reached a new level.” Though the
Legion’s leaders noticed the differences between themselves and Nazism, they
were convinced that both their country’s and their party’s future lay with the
In Romania’s last elections before the war, in December 1937, the Fatherland
Front received nearly 16% of the vote, with unofficial counts at 25%, despite the
corrupt and partially manipulated elections. This result would have entitled them to
66 seats, but King Carol dissolved the parliament via a royal coup in February
130
Payne 1995:286
131
Payne 1995:284
132
Payne 1995:284-6
228
1938.133 Other political parties were outlawed; Codreanu and his top Legionnaires
were executed. The Legion’s new leaders hoped to inflame an insurrection against
the king, but the Army’s loyalty held firm. The irony that had played out in Austria,
Hungary, the Baltics, and other places repeated itself in Romania: “the Legion,
The government’s victory was short-lived, however. In September 1940 the king
appointed General Ion Antonescu to the position of prime minister, who quickly
forced the king’s resignation and assumed control. Antonescu ruled as the head of
prime minister Antonescu. At this point the Legion became the only legal political
movement in the country, with key positions staffed by former members of the Iron
over the causes of their failure.”135 Romania formally joined the Axis alliance in
June 1941 and Antonescu continued to govern Romania until his arrest in 1944.136
133
Giovanni Capoccia (2005) Defending Democracy: Reactions to Extremism in
Interwar Europe, Johns Hopkins University Press, p.8
134
Payne 1995:289
135
Eugen Weber (1979) “The Men of the Archangel” p. 317-43 in George L. Mosse,
ed., International Fascism: New Thoughts and New Approaches, Sage Publications,
p.319
136
Cyprian Blamires, Paul Jackson (2006) World Fascism: A Historical
Encyclopedia, Vol.1, ABC-Clio, p.49
229
Spain
For the first two decades of the twentieth century, Spain remained a feeble but
parties. Between 1909 and 1923 the country witnessed a succession of thirty-four
military dictatorship that lasted for the next eight years. Lacking a clear program or
along with the monarchy in April 1931, resulting in the creation of the Second
Spanish Republic. It was the only new European regime to move “against the tide
of authoritarian and fascist politics” of the 1930s.137 Between 1931 and 1933 the
conservative backlash. The election of 1933 produced a victory for the center-right,
the elections of February 1936 a “Popular Front” of left-wing parties (including the
Fascist movements had been percolating in Spanish political life several years
before the war. Calvo Sotelo, the spokesman for the rightist opposition whose
137
Payne 1995:254
138
Roberts 1999:318
230
murder triggered the start of the war, had been calling for an authoritarian
critics referred to his goals as fascist.”139 But the more successful and ultimately
more durable fascist movement in Spain was the Falange Espanola (Spanish
businessmen, who “went shopping during the summer of 1933 for the leader of a
emergence of Jose Antonio Primo de Rivera, oldest son of the former dictator. Over
the previous few years, de Rivera had shifted away from conservative monarchism
and toward Italian-style fascism, which served as “the vehicle for giving form and
by his father.”140
The Falange’s program, released at the end of 1934, called for a thoroughly
corporatist state and “exhibited all the main points of fascist doctrine”.141 De Rivera
was occasionally ambivalent about the violence associated with fascism, and
case of an interwar leader who rejected the fascist label yet “never renounced the
139
Payne 1995:256
140
Payne 1995:256, 259
141
Payne 1995:261
142
Payne 1995:263. As he emphasizes, despite certain unique features Spanish
231
The outcome of the civil war led to the establishment of a nationalist military
regime headed by Francisco Franco and based on Falangist principles; its 1934
program now became official state doctrine. The choreography of Franco rallies
imitated Hitler and Mussolini, as did a number of institutions and party agencies,
(MinCulPop).143
The regime began to move away from categorical fascism as Hitler’s fortunes
began to ebb, though Payne notes that if Hitler had succeeded, “there seems little
doubt that Franquism would have become…more radical and overtly fascist in
fascist state and more “an old-fashioned military dictatorship with bureaucratic and
capitalist support.”146
Portugal
minister in 1932, four years after the military dictatorship installed him as finance
Falangism shared “nearly all the general qualities and characteristics that would
compose an inventory of generic fascism.” Payne 1995:261
143
Payne 1995:267
144
Payne 1995:267
145
Payne 1995:267
146
Seton-Watson in Mosse 1979: 365
232
minister. He remained in office until 1968, after a stroke led to his retirement.
represent economic interests. A directly elected national assembly was also put in
place, with regular elections that were carefully controlled by the state.
The Syndicalists (also known as the Blue Shirts from their adopted uniform)
after the Nazis ascent to power in 1933. In that same year, Salazar began his Estado
created his own student youth movement, the Accao Escolar Vanguarda (Student
Action Vanguard, or AEV), closed the Blue Shirt newspaper offices and removed
their leaders from government positions. At the same time, its moderate members
were invited to join the regime, where for the rest of the decade they “constituted a
sort of de facto fascistic pressure group within the state syndical system).”147 By
1934 Salazar had succeeded in splitting the movement, and it was officially
dissolved later in the year. Its remnants attempted a failed revolt against the regime
147
Payne 1995:315
233
civil war that began in 1936 “carried his Estado Novo a little further in that
and a paramilitary auxiliary, which both used the Nazi salute. Some scholars have
argued that Salazar’s regime cannot be considered truly fascist because it avoided
marches, rallies, and mass mobilization in general. But as David Raby argues, “this,
in a sense, can be seen as the other side of the coin of fascism” – fascist regimes
pursued intense mobilization when they faced a real threat from the radical left or
were preparing for a mass wartime effort – neither of which applied to the Salzar
Greece
Between 1917 and 1936 Greece was “more similar to a Latin American country
monarchy in 1936 began a period of intensified discord, and after the main parties
failed to reach an agreement the king appointed as prime minster the nationalist,
148
Payne 1995:316
149
David L. Raby (1991) Fascism and Resistance in Portugal: Communists, Liberals
and Military Dissidents in the Opposition to Salazar, 1941-1974, Manchester
University Press, p.4
150
Payne 1995:318
234
1936.151 Metaxas had not been popular – his party had received only 3% of the
votes in a national election three months earlier. His appointment led to a series of
strikes that Metaxas used to issue an emergency decree and seize absolute power.
parties were abolished; trade unions came under state control and a corporative
structure was introduced, complete with price controls and extensive economic
hours, maternity leave, and stricter work safety standards. In November 1936,
Metaxas also created a mass youth movement called the National Youth
Organization (EON). His regime employed the fascist salute and occasionally
lacking mass mobilization, and Metaxas told a British official that Salazar’s Portugal
rather than Nazi Germany provided the closest model for emulation). Nevertheless,
Metaxas aspired to join the nationalist, anti-liberal wave of the period, loosening
ties with Britain while moving closer to Italy and Germany.152 Nevertheless, Hitler
Finland
Fascist expression in Finland took the form of the Lapua movement, founded in
151
Capoccia 2005:8
152
Payne 1995:319-20
235
called for a more nationalist, pious, and authoritarian state, and a restructuring of
1929 and 1932, Lapua had an “enormous impact on the choices and strategies of
the governmental parties.”154 It pressed the cabinet and the parliament to pass anti-
1930. Lapua then moved on to attacking the more centrist Social Democratic party,
and in its 1932 Tampere program declared itself ready to use violence to achieve
this goal. While it did not compete in elections, it exerted a strong influence on the
country’s main conservative party, the National Coalition (NC). The NC, a founding
party of the Finnish republic, had always displayed a hesitant attitude toward
support continued even while all other conservative parties distanced themselves
from Lapua after its turn against the Social Democrats. As a result, between 1929
and 1932 Lapua had “a substantial impact on Finnish democratic institutions from
The party was banned after a failed 1932 coup, but quickly reorganized itself as
the People’s Patriotic Movement (IKL), which was similarly nationalist and anti-
153
Its precursor, the anti-Bolshevik Academic Karelia Society, never had more than
a few thousand members. (Payne 1995:311) As in many countries, it took the Great
Depression and the rise of Nazi Germany to bolster a sizeable fascist following.
154
Capoccia 2005:43
155
Capoccia 2005:44
236
democratic. IKL modeled itself directly after Nazis, taking as its core tenet the idea
advocated the banning of political parties; individual freedoms and class interests
would be replaced by a powerful central authority and subsumed into the organic
corporatist system rather than electoral democracy. IKL members wore military
uniforms and had a youth organization modeled after the Jugend, but were careful
to avoid political violence due to the very real risk of a government ban.156
At its peak in the 1936 elections the IKL received 8.3 percent of the vote, but
was never able to achieve mass popularity; by the end of the decade its vote
Coalition. In fact, it went further than Lapua in actually taking control of the NC
shortly after its creation in 1932; the NC did not return to classical pro-
parliamentary conservatism until 1935. Until then, the IKL’s influence “went well
Poland
death in 1935. Pilsudksi had taken power in a 1926 coup after a period of
156
Capoccia 2005:45
157
Payne 1995:311-2. Capoccia 2005:45 puts the peak figure at 7 percent.
158
Capoccia 2005:46
237
establish a full dictatorship. In 1928 he founded the the Nonparty Bloc for the
need for political violence and a strong central leader. Its moderate members
looked to Mussolini as a model, while the more radical (usually younger) members
were influenced by Nazism.160 The OUN received material support from Germany,
Ukrainians. The other significant fascist organization of the period was the Polish
the Spanish model from which it took its name and influenced by the political
After Pilsudki’s death in 1935, the government was controlled by the so-called
“Colonels” - members of the Polish army and Pilsudski allies who emphasized
authoritarianism and state control over the economy. Political repression increased,
159
Payne 1995:321
160
Paul Robert Magocsi (1996) A History of Ukraine, University of Toronto Press, p.
621
161
Payne 1995:322
238
especially toward ethnic minorities. The 1935 constitution gave the president
increased powers while limiting the role of parliament. While direct elections were
maintained, that year the opposition parties boycotted the regime. Meanwhile,
decade the state owned 40% of the country’s banking capital and 20% of the
industrial capital.162
In 1937 the Colonels constructed another national unity party to replace BBWR,
called the Camp of National Unity (OZN), a “crypto-fascist government party” that
attracted nationalists and university students with its program of clericalism, anti-
Semitism, and nationalism.163 Colonel Adam Koc, placed in charge of building this
party, was impressed by the Falanga and placed one of its leaders in charge of the
League of Young Poland, OZN’s youth section. OZN also began to advocate a
included the call for a one-party state and purge of opposition leaders) displeased
some of the moderate Colonels, who forced Koc’s resignation and ended OZN’s
The Baltics
In Lithuania, the main fascist movement was the Iron Wolf Association, the
162
Payne 1995:322
163
Paul N. Hehn (2002) A low dishonest decade: the great powers, Eastern Europe,
and the economic origins of World War II, 1930-1941, Continuum, p.65
164
Payne 1995:322
239
coup brought to power president Antanas Smetona of the more moderate National
Christian Democratic Party. After 1931 Smetona tried to co-opt the Wolves by
increased power. But in 1934 Voldemaras and Iron Wolf members attempted an
organization.165 The Iron Wolves had been suppressed, but as in other European
cases, the state had achieved this only by adopting some of the institutional reforms
Like Lithuania, Estonia and Latvia managed to avoid fascism through pre-
Estonia, the elected president Konstantin Pats seized power in 1934 after an
Veterans League (EVL, a paramilitary holdover from the 1917-8 war with the USSR)
disbanded the EVL and arrested its leaders. The following year political parties
of corporatist institutions such as the Chamber of Labour, which took over the
165
Payne 1995:323-4
240
functions of the labor unions, curtailed since 1934.166 After 1938 Estonia managed
the previous year. Ulmanis. Political parties were outlawed and opposition
institutions based on the fascist model in Italy, but did not pursue the partial re-
liberalization that occurred in Estonia.168 Both regimes, which Georg von Rauch
may indeed have averted worse ills,” but they did so through adapting the
Yugoslavia
dissolving the parliament and abolishing the constitution. After his assassination in
regency. Milan Stojadinovic, prime minister from 1935 to 1939, made an attempt
166
Georg von Rauch (1974) The Baltic States: the years of independence: Estonia,
Latvia, Lithuania, 1917-1940, University of California Press, p.155
167
Payne 1995:324
168
Rauch 1974:155
169
Rauch 1974:154; Payne 1995:325
241
Its members wore green shirts and called Stojadinovic “Vodja”, or “Leader”. In
1938 he assured Galeazzo Ciano, the Italian foreign minister, that his movement
would develop along the lines of Italian fascism, although in general he tried to
them catering to the specific interests of Serbs, Croats, or Slovenes (although a few
radical group was Yugoslav Action, which called for a state-directed economy and
(Convention). Like its predecessor, Zbor preached nationalism and corporatism, but
received only about one percent of the vote in both the 1935 and 1938 elections.
By the end of the decade it developed contacts with Nazi Germany, attempted
several insurrections, and was again suppressed by the government at the end of
1940.171
The most protofascist and consequential of the Yugoslav nationalist groups was
partnership with Macedonian terrorists, the group was responsible for the
170
Payne 1995:325
171
Payne 1995:325-6
242
goals and protofascist characteristics”. Like Zbor, the movement was repressed by
the Yugoslav government, but after the German takeover in 1941 it was given the
reigns of power in Croatia and developed “into one of the most destructive of all
Bulgaria
movement until its overthrow by a military revolt in 1923. Until 1934, the country
land distribution promoted internal stability.173 That year, a radical right-wing group
of military officers called Zveno (the Link) took power in a short-lived coup, but
were soon thrown out by the royalists, who inaugurated “a controlled but still semi-
pluralist parliamentary regime” that lasted until the death of King Boris in 1943.174
Bulgarian National Socialist Party, and the Bulgarian National Legions. But the only
fascist group to achieve any measure of popularity was the Ratnitsi (Warriors), a
1939. Although the king moved to suppress both the Communists and the radical
right, the rapid rise and menacing territorial ambitions of Nazi Germany forced him
172
Payne 1995:325, 326
173
Payne 1995:326
174
Payne 1995:327
243
authoritarian regime, but at the price of moving further to the right. Restrictions on
Jewish economic activity appeared in 1939. When the Iron Guard took control of
Romania the following year and instituted a number of anti-Jewish measures, the
Bulgarian government adopted the Law of the Defense of the Nation, “so as not to
Europe, King Boris took to calling himself Vozhd (Leader) in imitation of the Fuhrer.
All in all, the country was “unable to create an original and effective ideology that
could mobilize the people, and had instead committed itself to following the fascist
Ireland
The new Irish Republic lacked a real fascist movement. One contender was the
National Guard, a group formed in 1932, but this was “essentially a chowder and
175
Payne 1995:327
176
Quoted in Marshall Lee Miller (1975) Bulgaria During the Second World War,
Stanford University Press, p.94-5
177
Miller 1975:92
178
Payne 1995:306
244
In 1935 General Eoin o'Duffy, a former national police chief, founded the National
Corporate Party (NCP, aka the Blueshirts) that was modeled more explicitly along
Nazi lines. The NCP tried to establish links with continental fascists and even sent a
pro-Nationalist battalion to fight in the Spanish civil war. For a time it even
attracted the support of W.B. Yeats, who wrote a series of marching songs for the
group.179 But the party never developed a durable following, and disappeared after
Switzerland
Switzerland had three philofascist movements, one for each of the country’s
ethnic group: the Union Nationale for French speakers, the Lega Nazionale
Ticinese for Italian speakers, and the National Front for German speakers. Of these,
the latter was the most genuinely fascist, although it remained small. Its stronghold
was the Schaffhausen district, where the party received 27 and 12.2 percent of the
vote in 1933 and 1935, respectively (in 1935 it succeeded in electing a deputy to
the Swiss National Council, the only time it was able to do so).180 Switzerland was
officially neutral during the war, but remained friendly toward Germany and
Denmark
179
Cyprian Blamires, Paul Jackson (2006) World Fascism: A Historical
Encyclopedia, Vol.1, ABC-Clio, p.344
180
Payne 1995:309
245
Despite internal disputes, the party received 1.8 percent of the vote and three
parliament seats in the 1939 elections.181 Denmark did not join the fascist wave
Netherlands
The main Dutch fascist movement was the National Socialist Movement (NSB),
founded in 1931. It developed “the full panoply of fascism, with elaborate rituals
and a party militia,” but rejected racism and welcomed Dutch Jews into the party.
Dutch national principle. The NSB was able to take advantage of the depression to
gain nearly 8 percent of the vote in the Dutch provincial elections of 1935, the
After this high point, the group began to acquire more fascist elements and its
popularity went into decline. “Conservative supporters were alienated, while the
economic conditions improved, the NSB went into steady decline, gaining only 4.2
percent of the vote in the national elections of 1937 and losing most of that in the
Iceland
Since Iceland’s economy depended almost entirely on fish exports, the decline
181
Payne 1995:307-8
182
Payne 1995:302
183
Payne 1995:302
246
of export prices brought about severe unemployment and social disruption. The
Icelandic Nationalist Movement (INM), the country’s fascist party, saw itself as the
maintain order, protection of national health through racial selection and breeding,
end of class warfare, compulsory labor duty for all citizens, and, above all, the
elevation of the national interest above individual or group needs. Other political
parties would be abolished, with the Icelandic Communist Party (founded in 1930)
as its main target. The Allting, the country’s national parliament, would likewise be
dissolved and replaced by a corporate state. This state would then provide full
employment through industrial subsidies and loans and ensure a decent standard of
living for each citizen. The INM used the swastika as its emblem, and its members
frequently expressed their admiration for Hitler, “the poor common man who
Despite the country’s economic problems, the INM failed to attract many
followers. It received only 0.7 percent of the vote in 1934 (proportionally much
less than even its Danish and Norwegian counterparts) and failed to gain a single
seat. By 1937 it did not even bother to participate in elections; its quasi-military
marching squad made their final appearance in May 1938, and in that year the
184
Asgeir Gudmundsson (1980) “Nazism in Iceland” in Stein Ugelvik Larsen, Bernt
Hagtvet, and Jan Petter Myklebust, eds., Who Were the Fascists: Social Roots of
European Fascism, Oslo: Universitetsforlaget, p. 743-5
247
Norway
in 1933, was “by far the most important of the Scandinavian proto-Nazi
movements.”186 It had a party militia, called the Hird, and called for a corporative
system. The party received 2.2 and 1.8 percent of the vote in the 1933 and 1936
provided the party with financial support.187 Norway became part of the coercive
phase of the fascist wave in April 1940, whereupon it remained a Nazi puppet
Belgium
“If I had a son,” Adolf Hitler told Leon Degrelle, the founder and leader of
Belgian Rexism, “I would wish him to be like you.”188 The Rexists represented the
with the moderation of Belgian Catholicism, founding Christus Rex in 1935. It was
both communists and finance capitalists were its sworn enemies. Financial
capitalism would be tamed, central banks tightly controlled; class solidarity would
185
Gudmundsson (1980) in Larsen, ed., p. 749; Payne 1995:308
186
Payne 1995:308
187
Payne 1995:308
188
Quoted in Pierre-Henri Laurent (1979) “Belgian Rexism and Léon Degrelle” p.
295-315 in George L. Mosse, ed., International Fascism: New Thoughts and New
Approaches, Sage Publications, p.295
248
strengthened. The Rexists advocated support for the middle and working classes
unemployment.189
frank and openly provocative.”190 His leadership led the movement to an early
electoral success - in the 1936 elections his party “stunned the Belgian electorate”
by winning 37 (of 202) parliamentary seats.191 This included about a third of all
right-wing votes and a quarter of the votes in the Walloon cantons (its main source
of support) and Brussels.192 This success was short-lived, however. The following
year, an overly confident Degrelle lost his bid for prime minister by a humiliating
margin. The movement never regained its previous popularity; the multi-ethnic
nature of the Begian state precluded a national following, since Flemish nationalists
drained off right-wing support. After 1936 Rexism moved increasingly toward
fascism and received substantial foreign subsidies from Hitler and Mussoini;
Degrelle visited Hitler and Germany and expressed support for the conservatives in
the Spanish civil war. By 1940 Degrelle was an active Nazi collaborator and led a
189
Capoccia 2005:41
190
Laurent 1979:309
191
Brustein and Berntson 1999:159
192
Laurent 1979:297
249
scholars continue to debate whether the regime was truly fascist or simply a
authoritarianism, argued that “both the similarities and the differences” between
political thought. Given the institutional focus of my approach, and the instances of
Japan had greatly profited from World War I, when Allied munition contracts,
demands for Japanese shipping, and the opening of markets previously accessible
only to Western colonial powers combined to give the country a rapid boost of
193
Laurent 1979:295
194
G.J. Kasza (1984) “Fascism from below? A Comparative Perspective on the
Japanese Right, 1931-1936” Journal of Contemporary History 19.4, p.607-27
250
concomitant rise of nationalism. The Depression had led to the collapse of silk
exports, and millions of farmers suffered from the decline in demand for their
goods. Manufacturing was also affected, and by 1932 half of Japanese factories
proliferated - Lebow estimates their number at 750 by 1936.197 Like their European
because of their repugnance for contemporary party politics and the free market
economy”, wrote Richard Ned Lebow. “They imagined that fascism would be more
efficient, avoid debilitating clashes between unions and companies and strengthen
democracy had “lost its spirit and decayed into a mechanism which insists only on
that the Italian and German models offered “a form of more democratic
In 1931, a group of right radical army officers called the Land-Loving School
195
Kennedy 1987:299
196
Roberts 1999:358
197
Richard Ned Lebow (2008) A Cultural Theory of International Relations,
Cambridge University Press, p.406
198
Lebow 2008:406
199
Nakano Seigo (1995) "The Need for a Totalitarian Japan" in Roger Griffin, ed.,
Fascism, Oxford University Press. p.239
251
launched a wave of assassinations, hoping to trigger the collapse of what they saw
who rallied against imperial expansion, the militant nationalists’ hold on political
and economic power was secure, and “the Japanese government took on many
and the state began pursuing a policy of rapid industrialization and the
with China in 1937 was the last nail in democracy’s coffin. State authority was
control over the economy and society.203 Thus, unlike its Italian or German
counterparts, Japanese fascism did not sweep into power via a mass movement;
instead, it was adopted by the state “from above”, and imposed upon the country
Just as Prussia had served as a model of military reform after the Meiji
200
Payne 1995:332
201
Frieden 2006:214
202
Frieden 2006:215
203
Payne 1995:333
204
Lebow 2008:407
252
interest groups. Japanese trade associations were structured after German state
cartels, as was the state women’s association, the state youth organization, and the
China
Chinese fascism was spurred by the Japanese invasion of 1931, which led to the
emergence of several nationalist groups. The most prominent of these were the
Blue Shirts (aka the Kai-tsu P’ai faction), who can be described as the fascist wing
for most of the interwar period. Created in 1932, the Kai-tsu P’ai were originally a
left-wing group but came to admire Nazi economic and social policies. They
industrialization, and thus they “admired European fascism and were influenced by
correctly, as it turned out) the spread of fascism across the entirety of Europe.207 In
1936 their leader, Wang Jingwei, visited Germany and upon his return wrote that
205
Payne 1995:335
206
Payne 1995:337-8
207
William C. Kirby (2001) “China” in Stein Ugelvik Larsen, ed., Fascism Outside
Europe: The European Impulse against Domestic Conditions in the Diffusion of
Global Fascism, Boulder: Social Science Monographs, p.247
253
fascist states “have already expanded their national vitality and augmented their
leading spokesman for the group argued in 1937 that "Whatever we may think
about fascist and Nazi methods and policies, we must recognize the fact that their
leaders have secured the enthuisiastic support of their respective nations, and while
these regimes may have done "foolish, unwise, and even cruel things," Hitler and
Mussolini had done “more in a few years than many countries have done in
decades.”209 These sentiments found support among the general public - as early as
1933 a newspaper editorial argued that “fascism is the only tool of self-salvation of
nations on the brink of destruction…China cannot but imitate the fascist spirit
of…Italy and Germany.”210 The Nazis’ organic view of the nation fit nicely with
1936, the country’s leadership ought to “do very much the same sort of work as has
interest of the nation.211 In 1937 the group helped mobilize resistance to the
Japanese invasion of the mainland, but were soon dissolved by Chiang, who saw
208
Quoted in Kirby (2001:255) in Larsen, ed.
209
Quoted in Kirby (2001:255) in Larsen, ed.
210
Quoted in Kirby (2001:246) in Larsen, ed.
211
Quoted in Kirby (2001:256) in Larsen, ed.
212
Payne 1995:337
254
European fascism as movements in any other part of the world.”213 This was
emerged.214 Both German and Italian propaganda machines were active in the Arab
world. In Payne’s view, “European fascism was taken more seriously in the Middle
East than anywhere else in the world” save for Japan, South Africa, and Bolivia.215
In Saudi Arabia, King Abdul Aziz sought and received German arms and contacts.
Syrian and Iraqi delegations attended Nurenberg party congresses. Mein Kampf was
movements” appeared in the region by the end of the decade (white in Iraq, tan in
Lebanon, blue and green in Egypt, and white, gray and iron in Syria). The three
most prominent movements in the region inspired by fascism were Syria’s Socialist
Nationalist Party, Iraq’s Futuwa movement, and the Young Egypt movement. All
213
Payne 1995:352; see also Lukasz Hirszowicz (1966) The Third Reich and the
Arab East, London: Routledge & Kegan Paul Pubs
214
Payne 1995:352
215
Payne 1995:353; this influence proved to be more durable in that region than in
any other. By the 1980s “the regimes of Gadhafi in Libya and of Saddam Hussein
in Iraq would have more characteristics of a classic fascist regime than any others
in the world.” Payne 1995:353
216
Payne 1995:352
255
three believed in their nation’s superiority; all three stressed self-sacrifice, martial
virtues, and territorial expansion; all three praised both German Nazism and Italian
Fascism.217
Interwar Syria saw a flowering of radical pro-fascist youth groups like the Syrian
Socialist Nationalist Party (PPS) and the Iron Shirts. The PPS, founded in 1932, was
totalitarianism with a strong leader at the helm. The party adopted the Hitler salute,
a curved swastika (zawba’a) as their symbol, and even sang their anthem to the
tune of "Deutschland über alles”.218 It’s worth noting that while the party’s founder,
Antun Saadeh, professed admiration for Hitler, he argued that his was not a fascist
is neither a Hitlerite nor a Fascist one, but a pure social nationalist one. It is not
such rejection was incompatible with the party’s explicit adoption of Nazi
symbolism, organizational methods, and political program. But like many of his
217
Payne 1995:352. See also E. Marston (1959) "Fascist Tendencies in Pre-War
Arab Politics: A Study of Three Arab Political Movements," Middle East Forum,
35:19-35. Martin Kramer (1986) "Congresses of Collaboration: Islam and the Axis,
1938-1945" in Islam Assembled: The Advent of the Muslim Congresses, p.157-165
218
Daniel Pipes (1992) Greater Syria, Oxford University Press, p.100-101; Ehud
Yaari (1987) “Behind the Terror” Atlantic Monthly, June 1987.
219
Quoted in Gotz Nordbruch (2009) Nazism in Syria and Lebanon: the
ambivalence of the German option, 1933-1945, Taylor & Francis, p.45
256
tool of foreign influence, which would lead to attacks from the country’s traditional
conservatives. Where fascist parties were banned by the country’s rulers, foreign
who founded the Palestinian national movement and supported the 1941 coup in
Iraq. Amin al-Husayni fled to Nazi Germany and “actively assisted” the German
war effort.220 In nearby Lebanon, the political leader Pierre Gemayel founded the
Kataeb Party in 1936 after being inspired by the order and discipline of German
political life, which he witnessed first-hand during that year’s Olympic games.221
The country’s Tan Shirts (whose outfits were, confusingly, white, according to some
techniques.222
Iraq
In interwar Iraq, political conflict centered around the rivalry of the pro-British
Hashemite group and a number of pro-fascist movements such as the White Shirts,
who viewed Nazi Germany as the sole power capable of challenging British
colonial rule in the region. This view was particularly strong among the Iraqi
220
Israel Gershoni and James Jankowski (2009) Confronting Fascism in Egypt:
Dictatorship versus Democracy in the 1930s, Stanford University Press, p.274
221
Robert Fisk (1990) Pity the Nation: The abduction of Lebanon. New York:
Nation Books, p.65
222
Gershoni and Jankowski 2009:273-4, see also fn2 p. 321
257
military elite, culminating in the pro-Nazi coup of April 1941. Even before the
takeover, the country’s radical youth movement al-Futuwwa was explicitly based
Nazi rally, and soon after hosted the Hitler Youth leader Baldur von Schirach.
Leading Iraqi intellectuals like Sami Shawkat praised the success of martial
patriotism instilled among the German youth; Shawkat himself advocated violence
as a means to Arab unity, and was a leading force in al-Futuwwa. The pan-Arabic
al-Muthanna club in Baghdad hosted speeches that praised fascist ideology and
staged a pogrom in Baghdad that killed approximately 180 of its Jewish residents.
Throughout this period, Germany made a concerted propaganda push among Iraqi
outlets; Germany’s representatives had direct contacts with three of the country’s
The Iraqi regime itself established close ties with Nazi Germany; Rashi Ali al-
Gailani, the country’s prime minister between 1933-35 and again in 1940, was the
country’s leading advocate for rapprochement with fascism and staffed his cabinets
223
A British report from 1946 documented the reorganization of the al-Futuwwa
along the lines of its German counterpart. See Matthew Elliot (1996) Independent
Iraq: The Monarchy and British Influence, 1941-1958, London: I.B. Tauris, p.46
224
Orit Bashkin (2008) The other Iraq: pluralism and culture in Hashemite Iraq,
Stanford University Press, p.58. For overviews of Nazi influence in Iraq, from
which I have drawn for the above, see also Robert Lewis Melka (1966) The Axis
and the Arab Middle East: 1930-1945, University of Minnesota, p. 62; Walter
Laquer (1956) Communism and nationalism in the Middle East, Praeger, p.179;
Phoebe Marr (1985) "The Development of Nationalist Ideology in Iraq, 1921-1941"
The Muslim World 75.2:85-101
258
direct links with Nazi Germany via Italian intermediaries. By this point Great
Britain was concerned about al-Gailani strong anti-British views, threatened trade
sanctions, and forced him to resigned in early 1941, although he recaptured power
in a coup only two months later. Germany was now providing direct material
Iran
Reza Shah’s regime in Iran shared numerous similarities with European fascism.
Dubbed “the Mussolini of Islam” by the home press, he welcomed Hitler’s rise to
changing the country’s name from Persia to Iran - “Land of the Aryans”. He praised
the Nuremberg Race Laws of 1936, and the country witnessed sporadic pogroms in
1938. In 1936 the Germany finance minister Hjalmar Schacht made a state visit,
followed by the leader of the German youth movement the following year, which
resulted in an exchange program between the Hitler youth and its Iranian
counterpart. As the country began moving into the German economic sphere,
relations with the previously dominant Britain quickly deteriorated. In 1937 Iran,
along with Turkey and Afghanistan, signed the Saadabad Friendship Pact, which
gave Germany preferential treatment in trade and access to Iranian raw materials;
Iran in turn received German credits, trade concessions and (beginning in 1938)
225
Cyprian Blamires, Paul Jackson (2006) World Fascism: A Historical
Encyclopedia, Vol.1, ABC-Clio, p.343
259
weapons and military planes. A secret agreement in 1939 made Iran a provider of
food and natural resources for the Third Reich. At the end of 1939 Iran also signed
a Treaty of Friendship with Japan, although it remained officially neutral during the
beginning of World War II and entered the war on the Allied side in September
1943.226
Egypt
Egypt was another state where fascist influence was profoundly felt during this
period. As Payne notes, “there was much pro-German sentiment in Egypt.”227 Egypt
has also attracted the most attention from scholars of Arab fascism, possibly due to
its vibrant intellectual life in the 1920s and 1930s. For this reason, and because it
stands as such a representative case of fascist influence outside Europe, the rest of
this section is devoted to a more detailed case study of Egyptian politics during this
period.
The historian Nadav Safran argued that 1920s Egypt experienced a “progressive
phase” during the 1920s, when leading intellectuals advocated the social and
226
Cyprian Blamires, Paul Jackson (2006) World Fascism: A Historical
Encyclopedia, Vol.1, ABC-Clio, p.342-3
227
Payne 1995:352; see also Shimon Shamir (1976) “The Influence of German
National Socialism on Radical Movements in Egypt” in J.L. Wallach, ed. (1975)
Germany and the Middle East, 1835-1939, Tel Aviv, p. 200-204
228
Nadav Safran (1961) Egypt in Search of Political Community; summarized in
Israel Gershoni and James Jankowski 2009:6-7
260
in 1923 and elected a prime minister the following year. But a decade later, Safran
undermined the country’s exports. In addition, the country felt a strong sense of
Egypt mirrored the ideological evolution of many states between the wars. As
Safran writes:
The historian P.J. Vatikiotis similarly argues that “the temporarily successful
societies….The echo in Egypt was quite resounding.”230 This echo was expressed
229
Gershoni and Jankowski 2009:7, citing Safran (1961:192); see also p. 187-193
230
P.J. Vatikiotis (1991) The History of Modern Egypt, Johns Hopkins University
Press, p. 315, see also p.187-193. The Egyptian scholar Afaf Lutfi al-Sayyid-Marsot
likewise writes: "the crisis of democracies in the West had shaken the faith of many
in the value of democracy. Admiration for Fascism grew when Mussolini made the
trains run on time and forced the slackers to swallow castor oil. Some Egyptians
believed that these methods might have more success in Egypt than those of the
democratic institutions." (Gershoni and Jankowski 2009:8, citing Afaf Lutfi al-
Sayyid-Marsot (1977) Egypt’s Liberal Experiment, 1922-1936, University of
California Press, p. 229; see also p.227-31)
261
by the rapid rise of political groups that advocated the rejection of liberalism, the
use of violence, and the adoption of a fascist regime to deal with democratic
corruption. The most prominent of these was the Muslim Brotherhood and the
unity, the demand for autocratic politics, a quasi-military and uniformed youth
can be found directly in the writings of its members. Hasan al-Banna, the group’s
founder, wrote an essay praising the "militarism" and "masculinity" of the Nazis,
which he argued would serve as a model for the Muslim Brothers. Banna was also
impressed by the centralized nature of the Fascist and Nazi regimes, their
movement’s Fifth Congress, he argued that the country’s political parties were
artificial creations that divided the nation and produced self-serving factions.233 He
repeated this view in an editorial, arguing that "the existence of the party system
231
Gershoni and Jankowski 2009:211
232
Gershoni and Jankowski 2009:211; the text is Hasan al-Banna, “Hal Nahnu
Qawm Amaliyun?” JIM, Jumada al-Ula 19, 1353, as quoted in Zakaria Sulayman
Bayumi (1979) al-Ikhwan al-Muslimun, Cairo, p. 192-3
233
Gershoni and Jankowski 2009:227
262
Nazi influence was also found in the movement’s direct links with its European
brought them into contact with Germany, which sought to influence the movement
through financial support. Documents seized by the British in 1939 showed that
the Brotherhood had received secret subsidies from the German News Agency in
Young Egypt, the country’s other prominent fascist movement, was also directly
political outlook, use of public violence, and fealty to a central leader they “bore
Although the two groups shared similar outlooks, Young Egypt went even
further than the Brotherhood in its denunciation of parliamentary rule and embrace
partisanship upon the body politic. The cure, for al-Nahil, was a dictatorship. This
234
Quoted in Gershoni and Jankowski 2009:228
235
Gershoni and Jankowski 2009:213
236
Gershoni and Jankowski 2009:238. Describing the group’s features, they add
that they “closely paralleled the practices of Italian Fascism, German Nazism, and
the other fascist movements found on the northern side of the Mediterranean by the
1930s.”
263
excellent doctor.... This excellent doctor is the dictator."237 Al-Nahil gave the
examples of Hitler and Mussolini as doctors par excellence who had restored
After the tainted elections of March 1938, Young Egypt intensified their
agreed with his contemporaries that the system had failed to provide for the
nation’s needs:
The leader of Young Egypt, Ahmad Husayn, also expressed repeated and open
admiration for the Fascist political system. In 1938, he referred to the “miracles” of
emulated. Moreover, Husayn argued that fascism and Nazism “were the bearers of
much the same values as those that Young Egypt was trying to instill in the Egyptian
237
Quoted in Gershoni and Jankowski 2009:246
238
He elaborated: “The people are starving, yet the deputies wax eloquent; the
country is threatened with danger from within and without, yet the minutes of the
sessions contain only idle debates that delay more than they expedite affairs."
239
Quoted in Gershoni and Jankowski 2009:247-8
264
people – faith and action.”240 Their miracles had been achieved because of "a
creed, a faith, a belief in themselves; this is what Young Egypt summons you to
itself as following the political trajectory of its German and Italian counterparts.242
While Young Egypt denied connections with outside fascist powers, British
reports from 1935 state that the movement had accepted Italian money passed
through a magazine that served as the outlet for Italy’s state propaganda in Egypt.
The British also report that the group had accepted Italian money for a propaganda
trip to Europe in 1935. When Egypt’s prime minister pursued a partial ban of the
group the following year, he justified it on the grounds that the movement was
In short, fascist influence in interwar Middle East found many adherents among
economic revival, internal stability, and projection of national unity. Many of the
which perhaps explains why historiography has generally downplayed its influence
in the region. Nevertheless, the hegemonic transition of the 1930s was expressed
here in a wave of popular movements that imitated fascist ideology. Emulation and
influence (in the form of Nazi-sponsored subsidies and propaganda trips) were the
240
Gershoni and Jankowski 2009:249
241
Quoted in Gershoni and Jankowski 2009:249
242
Gershoni and Jankowski 2009:249
243
Gershoni and Jankowski 2009:239-40
265
two mechanisms by which the hegemonic shock manifested itself in the region.
replace traditional oligarchs.244 Within a year after 1929, exports fell on average by
40 percent, and foreign investment declined sharply. As national incomes fell, the
political regimes in Latin America fell between 1930 and 1934; between 1930 and
1933 the continent experienced the largest number of coups, uprisings, and
democratic (though elitist) regimes and six dictatorships. By the end of the
following decade, the region had fifteen dictatorships and five democracies.246
The fundamental causes of this authoritarian turn were the onset of the
244
Peter H. Smith (2005), Democracy in Latin America: Political Change in
Comparative Perspective, Oxford University Press, p.28.
245
Roberts 1999:374-5
246
Paul W. Drake (1994) “International Factors in Democratization” paper
presented at the Center for Advanced Study in the Social Sciences, Juan March
Institute, Madrid (November 4, 1994), p.4
266
composition of most states, and low levels of mass mobilization dampened the
spread of fascist ideology. But as in other regions, leaders of Latin American states
were able to borrow institutional elements of fascist and communist states without
I hasted to add that the above-quoted Payne does not consider the similarities
sufficient to consider these regimes fascist (with the partial exception of Argentina),
Like their European counterparts, the new caudillos rejected democracy and
looked toward fascist solutions for their problems. Borrowing from Italian and
took the form of protecting domestic markets and, inevitably, a greater role for the
state. 248 Although Soviet planning was also a source of admiration, its influence
remained limited not only because the leaders were instinctively anti-Left but also
because preventing a slide toward communism ensured the cooperation of the old
247
Payne 1995:340.
248
Elsenhans 1991:284. Roberts 1999:375
267
oligarchies.249
Brazil
After a decade of instability, Brazil underwent a military coup in 1930. For the
next fifteen years, the country was ruled by Getulio Vargas, “a nationalistic dictator
with semifascist leanings.”250 Vargas did not develop his own national party, but
which were the Acao Integralista Brasileira (Brazilian Integralist Action or AIB).
Founded in 1932, the Integralists were the country’s main fascist movement and
the first popular mass movement in the country’s history. It was a highly centralized
and hierarchical group headed by a charismatic leader named Plinio Salgado, who
cultivated a Hitler-like appearance. Its members wore green shirts and used the
Nazi salute; they advocated a corporatist (“integral”) and authoritarian state. The
fascism,” and in the mid-1930s they “generated more support than any other
trade ties with the country. In the five years after 1933, it became the second-
largest importer of Brazilian coffee and cocoa, and the largest market for the
249
Roberts 1999:376
250
Frieden 2006:226
251
Payne 1995:345-6
268
modeled after the Italian and Portuguese regimes of Mussolini and Salazar. Vargas
parties, and substantially increased his decree powers. He also cultivated good
relations with Nazi Germany.252 As in many European cases, the Integralists came
suppressed its more radical competitors (as had been the case, for instance, with
the Portuguese National Syndicalists after Salazar’s shift to the right). The
movement was officially dissolved in 1937, and after two failed coup attempts was
decisively suppressed.253
Argentina
General Jose Uriburu’s takeover of Argentina in 1930 marked the country’s first
dictatorship of the century. He has been preceded by General Irigoyen, who came
meant opposition to any interference with free trade and a refusal to deal with the
Great Depression through political measures. 254 His inaction allowed Uriburu to
take control with the help of the far-right Argentine Patriotic League, a nationalist,
reforms that included a corporatist regime and a state militia called the Legion
252
Rothermund 1996:141-2
253
Payne 1995:346
254
Rothermund 1996:141
269
Civica.255
new regime into power in 1943. They imposed a dictatorship and pursued a
foreign policy more favorable to the Axis; during the war, the government “was
more sympathetic to Germany and Italy than was any other major government in
the Western Hemisphere.”256 The defeat of the Axis two years later forced them to
moderate their policies, and in the 1950s this moderation eventually took the form
Chile
(MNS, aka the Nacis). Founded by the half-German Jorge Gonzales von Marees in
1932, the Nacis argued for a corporatist economy and a stronger, more centralized
executive. In that year Chile began a return to liberal democracy after years of
political unrest that followed the onset of the Depression. Rising unemployment
and declining exports led to the resignation of dictator Carlos Ibanez del Campo in
1931, after which the Nacis “became a small but important actor in the political
development of the country.”258 Naci militias clashed with left-wing radicals and
their political leaders successfully stood for public office; in the 1935 municipal
255
Payne 1995:347
256
Payne 1995:347
257
Frieden 2006:226
258
Mario Sznajder (1993) “A Case of Non-European Fascism: Chilean National
Socialism in the 1930s” Journal of Contemporary History Vol.28, p.270
270
elections the party elected two candidates to city councils, and in the 1937
following year, twenty-nine Nacista municipal council members were elected into
office, mainly in large cities. Thus in just six years, the movement “became a
political force to be taken into account, not only because of its electoral
competitiveness but also because of its activism and violence “ which resembled its
parliament; the attempt mobilized anti-fascsit sentiment and helped the formation
Mexico
the Depression. At the grass-roots level, the most important Mexican philo-fascist
(despite attacks from the state), land and income redistribution, and a corporatist
state.260 At their peak in 1943 they reached a membership of over half a million,
259
Sznajder 1993:271-2
260
Roger Griffin (1993) The Nature of Fascism, Routledge, p.149
261
Payne 1995:343
271
The most prominent fascist movement in Mexico were the Gold Shirts, founded
and anti-Communist, and who “directly aped German and Italian styles”.262 In this
period Mexico itself was evolving into a one-party corporatist state and the
leadership was thus able to co-opt much of the Gold Shirts’ support. In the early
1930s, president Plutarco Elfas Calles “toyed with the idea of fascistizing aspects of
the Mexican regime” and encouraged the creation of a quasi-military force, the
is, British and American) oil wells and placed the public sector at the center of his
industrial policy. “[I]n part to defuse American concern, [he] invoked Roosevelt's
Peru
The most prominent fascist movement in Peru was the Union Revolucionaria
(UR), which used the fascist salute and developed a party militia called the Black
Shirts. The UR, modeling themselves after Mussolini’s Italy, were anti-democratic,
populist, and nationalist, but after a failed bid in the 1936 elections the party
262
Payne 1995:342
263
Payne 1995:342
264
Frieden 2006:226
272
gradually lost support.265 Following its demise, the Peruvian Fascist Brotherhood
became the major outlet of Peruvian fascism, led by the former prime minister Jose
quickly faded after Peruvia entered the war on the side of the Allies.266
Bolivia
Bolivia was one of the least developed countries in the region, and had lost a
war with Paraguay in 1935, making it one of the likelier candidates for supporting
alternatives, and the fascist option received increasing support. The influence of
Italian and German ideas “was often admitted by Bolivian leaders” and a radical
The country had its own version of the Falange, the Falange Socialista Boliviana
(FSB). The group was founded in 1937 and looked toward Spain and Italy as
foreign policy it leaned toward Germany and Italy, seeing them “as allies in
265
Payne 1995:343
266
Philip Rees (1990) Biographical Dictionary of the Extreme Right Since 1890,
Simon and Schuster, p.324
267
Payne 1995:343-4
273
that took power in 1943 “immediately adopted a pro-Axis policy and included
values, the United States seems to offer a difficult case for the theory of hegemonic
social science theory can always find confirming instances, its real test is how it
deals with the hard cases – that is, those cases where we would not expect the
dynamics predicted by the theory to be present.269 (The classic case is the 1894
should expect to see a growing acceptance of fascism in the United States, and the
At the mass level, the increasing support for fascist ideas in the United States
was reflected in the growth of pro-German organizations and the rise of nationalist
movements like the Black Legion, an offshoot of the Klan. Anti-semitism was also
This sentiment reflected a major plank of the Nazi platform, the elimination of class
American Review, a major intellectual outlet espousing the virtues of fascism in the
268
Payne 1995:344
269
Waltz 1979
274
1930s, wrote: “If the State as to be the symbol of an organic folk then it followed
that divisive opposition within the nation could not be tolerated.”270 In practice this
writing in the Review about the dangers of “free-thinking Jews”, argued: “The
population should be homogenous; where two or more cultures exist in the same
career of Father Coughlin. Coughlin, who blamed the Jews for the Depression and
enjoyed the second-largest radio audience in the country (after Roosevelt’s fireside
speeches), frequently quoted Goebbels and praised the Nazis’ quest for full
National Union for Social Justice whose 1936 candidate received nearly 900,000
votes. After the mid-1930s, Coughlin became the country’s foremost public
apologist for Franco, Mussolini and Hitler, while his followers organized local
Christian Front paramilitary groups. He was finally silenced by the Church in early
1942.272
The only other significant and ideologically fascist grass-roots movement in the
270
Albert E. Stone, Jr. (1960) “Seward Collins and the American Review: Experiment
in Pro-Fascism, 1933-37” American Quarterly 12.1, p.10
271
Quoted in Stone 1960:11
272
Payne 1995:351
275
watered-down Nazi Party for the United States.” 273 Despite bizarre attempts to
“cross over” by juxtaposing images of the Founding Fathers with swastikas, the
and naturalized Germans. An Italian equivalent was the Fasci all'Estero, an even
ideology (seen as hateful and aggressive) from its institutions (seen as novel and
effective), emphasizing their desire to discard the former while emphasizing the
latter. The bulk of the evidence for fascist emulation comes from the openly
admitted admiration of fascist reforms by the American political and social elite in
the 1930s. During this period, fascist institutions attracted praise not only from
bureaucrats, and senior political leaders including Roosevelt himself. Although this
admiration and desire for emulation was often tempered by the need to preserve
the reforms of the Roosevelt revolution. In tracing this influence, I will focus first on
the scholars and intellectuals, and then discuss imitation of fascist institutions at the
273
Payne 1995:351
274
Payne 1995:351
276
democracy around the world. “Democracy is waning before the steady stride of
consumer advisory board. More surprising than this oft-repeated observation was
Ogburn’s reaction to it. “I look forward to the decline of democracy and to the rise
of a system of government that will utilize some of its principles, but will
government, and advocated price fixing boards to keep price increases from
overtaking purchasing power. “The government that is speediest is the one that will
survive,” he continued. “An executive with the power to act such as that given
President Roosevelt will meet requirements of speedy action and will be able to
cope with rapid changes. A dictator can represent better than a legislature…”275
sentiment among American scholars and intellectuals of the 1930s. In his history of
the discipline of American politial science, Ido Oren repeatedly demonstrates how
and Soviet institutions during the 1930s. The reformist mood of the period, which
“diagnosed America as seriously but not terminally ill” led political scientists to
search for solutions in the authoritarian success stories. During the Depression,
275
Chicago Daily Tribune (1933) “Democracy Giving Way to New Government
Plan, Says Ogburn”, August 26, p. 4.
277
Germany and the USSR represented “models of administrative efficiency and social
planning,” and in a time of deep social and economic crisis, American intellectuals
“were understandably curious about political and social forms emerging elsewhere
in the world as they earnestly (though not always critically) searched for
political scientists, APSA presidents, and journal editors. The vast majority were not
actual fascists or communists – they did not call for a proletarian revolution or a
nationalistic dictatorship, and often hastened to point out the regimes’ more
institutions and hateful ideology.277 They favorably portrayed Nazi and Soviet
regimes as laboratories for economic, social, and political experiments, and urged
the US to “emulate what they regarded as the more positive aspects of the Fascist
American democracy of the period. Since German public administration had long
276
Ido Oren (2002) Our Enemies and US: America’s Rivalries and the Making of
Political Science, Cornell University Press, p. 18, 48. In doing so, they “expressed
positive curiosity about, and even downright admiration of, certain Nazi policies
and practices” (Oren 2002:47)
277
Oren 2002:87
278
Oren 2002:58. See also Robert Allan Skotheim (1971) Totalitarianism and
American Social Thought, Holt, Reinhart, and Winston.
278
phrase “Fabian Fascism” to describe his proposals for the future of the New Deal.
communism for those who need it.”279 Professor Roger Wells, in a 1935 APSR
article, “commended the Nazis for rescuing German municipal government from
the “excesses of the multi-party [Weimar] system.”280 In a 1936 book, former APSA
the revolutionary institutions erected in Italy, Germany, and Russia, with an eye
autocracy”. One such advantage, according to Willoughby, was the Nazis’ ability
“at a stroke” to attain “the superior advantages of the unitary over the multiple
[federal] form of government.”281 A 1936 APSR article, noting the shift in power
from American states to the federal government, proposed that “this process of the
279
Quoted in Schivelbusch 2006:37, citing W.P. Montague (1934) in Actes du
huitiéme congrés international de philosophie á Prague, 2-7 septembre 1934,
Prague, 1936, p. 481.
280
Oren 2002:80, citing Roger Wells (1935)
281
Oren 2002:82, citing W. F. Willougby (1936) The Government of Modern
States, rev. ed., New York: D. Appleton, vi, p. 111
279
The Nazis “have acted where others have merely planned and studied,” the author
“simply means stopping action. One thing we can learn from the dictatorships
which are springing up all over the Europe is that there are times and emergencies
when we must have action,” he told a newspaper. “We have reached a stage in our
leadership.”284
Seward Collins, editor of the American Review, became one of the more
“The question of politics,” he wrote in the inaugural issue, “resolves itself, broadly,
fascism was “the revival of monarchy, property, the guilds, the security of the
282
Albert Lepawsky (1936) “The Nazis Reform the Reich” American Political
Science Review 30.2, p.324
283
Lepawsky 1936:348
284
Quoted in Oren 2002:77
285
Quoted in Stone 1960:3
280
family and the peasantry, and the ancient ways of European life.”286 His
disenchantment with liberal capitalism and democracy after the Great Depression.
For them, the economic collapse was deeply connected to the “pluto-democratic”
right now is to get more and more power for the President, whoever holds the
office,” Seward wrote. “I hope it may be Roosevelt for some time to come.”289
continuing authority, within which tradition might grow. Democracy lives from day
to day. Dictatorship thinks only of the immediate future. Monarchy can both guide
Related to the desire for monarchy was a need to limit suffrage, which was
286
Quoted in Stone 1960:9
287
One contributor summarized this view in one sentence: “Democratic institutions
are, in fact, the political expression of the phase of capitalism economics.” Quoted
in Stone 1960:7
288
Quoted in Stone 1960:6
289
Quoted in Stone 1960:7
290
Quoted in Stone 1960:8
281
portrayed as a return to the ideals of the Founding Fathers. “If we are to retain any
sort of free, representative government that guarantees liberty and justice with
Soviet ideas also found admirers during this period. Imitation of Soviet
practices found fewer supporters than its German counterparts, since the country’s
complete rejection of capitalism (in contrast to Germany’s attempts to tame it) was
gained a significant following on U.S. college campuses, which have remained its
strongest bastions to this day. Gabriel Almond, whose friends fought in the Lincoln
brigades during the Spanish civil war, wrote his 1938 dissertation as a critical
Seymour Martin Lipset, Herbert Simon, Ithiel de Sola Pool, and other scholars who
291
Quoted in Stone 1960:10
292
Oren 2002:18. Almond’s dissertation was published sixty years later; see Gabriel
Almond (1938/1998) Plutocracy and Politics in New York City, Boulder: Westview.
In it, Almond argues that because of the disproportionate political influence of the
very wealthy, “it was an error to speak of the American political system as a
democracy.” p. xxii.
293
Oren 2002:18. Transcripts of Robert Dahl and David Easton interviews, APSA
Oral History Collection, University of Kentucky Library; Herbert Simon (1991)
Models of My Life, New York: Basic. Seymour Martin Lipset (1999) “Out of
Alcoves” Wilson Quarterly (winter 1999); biography of Ithiel Pool in American
282
the Soviet Union and noted with admiration that Soviet reforms had produced ”a
It was only after America’s entry into World War II and the onset of the Cold
War that the discipline of political science discarded its infatuation with German
and Russian models and shifted toward nationalist conservatism. Once these
regimes became direct rivals to the United States, political scientists “developed
amnesia regarding their past accomodationism and reached a consensus that these
accomodationist reviews and articles were featured in APSR as late as the end of
1939. The discipline’s flagship journal ceased publishing such items only after the
public intellectuals. In seeking to break from the liberal orthodoxy of the past, the
Roosevelt administration also looked toward solutions within Nazi Germany and
Soviet Russia. Roosevelt came into office determined to reshape the structure of
American government. "The nation was more than ready,” writes the historian
Arthur Schlesinger. “Many people had an anguished sense of crisis. For some,
problems, and sought to use state planning and corporatist institutions as the
logical solutions to the economic crisis. Both fascism and the New Deal relied on
“Hitler and Roosevelt were both charismatic leaders who held the masses in their
sway – and without this kind of leadership, neither National Socialism nor the New
Deal would have been possible.”298 Roosevelt wholeheartedly rejected the ideology
of fascism, but his decision to breach the long-standing norm of presidential term
limits was but one small manifestation of a growing acceptance of the need for a
economy with limited social insurance into a regulated mixture of public and
fascist and communist institutions, a fact that the administration did not seek to
hide. They did stress, however, that this imitation was pragmatic and policy-
oriented, not ideological. In October 1933, Roosevelt told his Secretary of the
297
Arthur Schlesinger (2003) The Coming of the New Deal, Vol.2, Mariner Books
298
Schivelbusch 2006:49
284
Interior, Harold Ickes: “What we are doing in this country were some of the things
that were being done in Russia and even some things that were being done under
Hitler in Germany. But we are doing them in an orderly way.”299 The racial and
totalitarian aspects of Nazi policy did not find mainstream admirers across the
Atlantic, but in politically more neutral areas such as a labor services and business
cartelization, argued Gotz and Patel, “the USA was interested in Germany’s
experiences.”300
fiscal tightening. The dollar was taken off the gold standard and devalued. Within a
build large-scale public works, regulate industrial prices, and encourage businesses
to cartelize and set prices. “These early measures smacked to many of fascism,”
according to Frieden, and led to opposition in the Supreme Court, which declared
government regulation entered new spheres of business life, from electric utilities to
banking and monetary policy. “The consensus among political scientists and
economists of the time,” writes Schivelbusch, “was that the United States under
299
Quoted in Lewis S. Feuer (1962) “American Travelers to the Soviet Union, 1917-
32: The Formation of a Component of New Deal Ideology” American Quarterly 14,
p.147
300
Gotz and Patel 2006:63
301
Frieden 2006:233
285
consolidation, transformed itself into a postliberal state.”302 The fixing of prices and
production in the oil and airline industries; the establishment of the Securities and
Exchange Commission, the Wagner Act of 1935, and the National Labor Relations
Act of 1936 – all these were parts of an effort, according to Peter Gourevitch, to
inject corporatism into a liberal political economy. “Agriculture, labor, and some
shelter from unrestrained market forces.303 Arthur Schlesinger, in The Coming of the
New Deal, recounts an anecdote about Roosevelt’s second fireside char, in which
business. While preparing the speech, an aide said to him, “You realize, then, that
you're taking an enormous step away from the philosophy of equalitarianism and
hadn't proved to be bankrupt, Herbert Hoover would be sitting here right now. I
never felt surer of anything in my life than I do of the soundness of this passage.”304
Economic planning by the state thus became a major element of New Deal
reforms. “By 1933 the advocates orderly planning, who had been gaining converts
Adjustment Act (AAA) and the National Industrial Recovery Act (NIRA) of 1933
were two major elements of early New Deal recovery programs. Both sought to use
302
Schivebusch 2006:14
303
Gourevitch 1986:152
304
Quoted in Schlesinger 1993:98
305
Fearon in Garside 1993:127
286
“[T]he competitive system is breaking down ... The comfortable theory of the
identity of mass prosperity with the unrestricted pursuit of private gain no longer
overproduction in industry and agriculture. The AAA thus introduced price and
production controls to farmers, who “had always believed that their task was to
grow as much food and fibre as possible.”307 The NIRA, AAA’s industrial
associations that had been reconstituted by the codes as ‘modern guilds,’ those
fluent in the jargon may well have recognized the reference to the corporatist
Many of these major reforms took Italy and Germany as a source of inspiration.
James Whitman notes that “a startling number of New Dealers had kind words for
306
E.S. Mead and B. Ostrolenk (1933) Voluntary Allotment. Planned Production in
American Agriculture, University of Pennsylvania Press, p.1, quoted in Fearon in
Garside 1993:127
307
Fearon in Garside 1993:129
308
Fearon in Garside 1993:133. By early 1935, 546 basic codes and 185
supplementary codes covered about 95 per cent of the industrial work force.
309
Schivelbusch 2006:30
287
Tugwell, a member of Roosevelt’s brain trust, openly spoke out about the virtues of
the fascist order, as did internal NRA studies.311 Decrying the ideological
[sic], most efficiently operating piece of social machinery I’ve ever seen. It makes
me envious.”312 An NRA bureaucrat wrote in 1935: “The Fascist Principles are very
similar to those which we have been evolving here in America and so are of
The similarities between the early New Deal reforms and fascist corporatism
comparisons were made not only by Roosevelt’s opponents (although they often
liberal journalist Mauritz Hallgren noted: “We in America are bound to depend
310
James Q. Whitman (1991) “Of Corporatism, Fascism, and the New Deal” The
American Journal of Comparative Law 39.4, p. 747. See also John Diggins (1966)
“Flirtation with Fascism: American Pragmatic Liberals and Mussolini’s Italy”
American Historical Review 71, p.487-506
311
Whitman 1991:747
312
Michael Vincent Namorato, ed. (1992) The Diary of Rexford G. Tugwell: The
New Deal, 1932-1935, New York, p. 139. Quoted in Schivelbusch 2006:32
313
Janet C. Wright, “Capital and Labor Under Fascism” National Archives, Record
Group 9, Records of the National Recovery Administration, Special Research and
Planning Reports and Memoranda, 1933-35, Entry 31, Box 3. Quoted in
Schivelbusch 2006:203-4
314
Quoted in Whitman 1991:748
288
more upon the State as the sole means of saving the capitalist system. Unattended
are being forced rapidly and definitely into Fascism…”.”315 A 1934 article in the
North American Review noted: “The New Dealers, strangely enough, have been
employing Fascist means to gain liberal ends. The NRA with its code system, its
regulatory economic clauses and some of its features of social amelioration, was
Liberal journalist and civil rights leader Oswald Garrison Villard wrote in the
Political Quarterly: “No one can deny that the entire Roosevelt legislation has
enormously enhanced the authority of the President, given him some dictatorial
powers, and established precedents that would make it easy for any successor to
Mr. Roosevelt, or for that gentleman himself, to carry us far along the road to
fascism or state socialism.”317 A 1934 article in Haper’s noted: “It is in the very
nature of planned recovery, its methods and its objectives, that we find the
tendency which, if developed to its logical conclusion, arrives at the fascist stage of
economic control. Mild measures have failed and by their failure have prepared the
way for accentuating the tendency toward fascist control.”318 And George Soule,
315
Mauritz Hallgren (1933) Spectator, August 18, p. 211. Cited in Schivelbusch
2006:28
316
Roger Shaw (1934) “Fascism and the New Deal” North American Review 238,
p. 559. Quoted in Schivelbusch 2006:28).
317
Oswald Garrison Villard (1934) Political Quarterly 5, p. 53-54. Cited in
Schivelbusch 2006:29).
318
J. B. Matthew and R. E. Shallcross (1934) “Must America Go Fascist?” Harpers
Magazine 169, p. 4. Cited in Schivelbusch (2006, p. 29)
289
the liberal editor of The New Republic, wrote in his 1934 book The Coming
American Revolution: “We are trying out the economics of Fascism without having
expansion, sometimes called the second New Deal, which included social
insurance and job-creating government programs. In that year Congress passed the
Social Security Act, creating the country’s first system of national insurance. 320 It
also approved a five billion dollar allocation for unemployment relief, the largest
echoing the concerns of many political leaders around the world.321 And like many
other leaders, Roosevelt was intensely interested in the German solution to this
work projects that required little or no skills. After 1933, “it was Hitler’s
practice. Even more problematic was the fact that the Third Reich advertised the
319
George Soule (1934) The Coming American Revolution, New York, p. 294.
Cited in Schivelbusch 2006:29).
320
Frieden 2006:234
321
Gotz and Patel 2006: 57
290
influential, and some experts saw it as a model for other, similar organizations
throughout the world.”323 As a result, the German labor service “left a deep
sought to train air mechanics for the Civilian Conservation Corps (CCC), they
devoted to aviation, as organizational models. The New York Times reported on the
introduced into the CCC, “the Nazi experience had obviously been a source of
inspiration”.325
All these measures dramatically increased the power of the federal government.
when they had been only a third of these in the late 1920s.326 The New Deal
“provided the most important extension of the power of the federal authorities over
322
Gotz and Patel 2006:57, 59
323
Gotz and Patel 2006:59
324
Gotz and Patel 2006:59. They conclude (p.62-3) that “these developments show
an unexpected willingness to study the Third Reich as a source for policy ideas.”
325
Gotz and Patel 2006:63
326
Frieden 2006:235
291
American society and the states that had ever occurred in peacetime and one that
was to prove irreversible.”327 In their reliance on the power of the state, American
“Commentators freely noted areas of convergence among the New Deal, Fascism,
and strong central leadership and a growing acceptance of collectivism were all
common features of these institutional bundles, although the American version had
retained far more individual civil liberties than its European counterparts.
continued to oppose the expansion of government power but preserved the major
reforms of the 1930s, “a tacit admission that the New Deal had not intended to
destroy capitalism but to preserve and revive it.”329 Democracy had survived only
327
Roberts 1999:369
328
Schivelbusch 2006:13
329
Palmer et al 2002:777
292
The final phase of the fascist wave was characterized by territorial conquests,
annexations, and the creation of satellites, puppets, and tutelary regimes. It was at
this point that the wave reached an all-time peak. In the summer of 1942 the fascist
order encompassed half the world’s population, or “virtually all of Europe and the
Middle East and much of Asia and Africa.”330 Fascist territories in Festung Europa
“stretched from the Mediterranean to the Arctic, from the English Channel to the
Black Sea and almost the Caspian.”331 In Asia, Japan had established puppets in
Institutional waves that spread via coercion are the most dramatic and least
domestic changes. The coercive fascist wave spread via the sheer, newly-acquired
power of hegemonic fascist states – Germany, Japan, and to a lesser extent Italy. It
was the first such attempt since Napoleon’s bid for European hegemony, which had
left a deep imprint on the institutions of affected states. Like other coercive
authoritarian waves (for example, the postwar Communist wave in eastern Europe),
its consolidation dynamics differ from those of democratic waves. Coercive waves
tend to fail because other states eventually balance against the coercive hegemon,
as was the case with the Napoleonic wars. The end of the fascist wave came not
from failed consolidation but from external forces; namely, defeat by the Allied
330
Frieden 2006:215
331
Randall Schweller (1998) Deadly Imbalances: Tripolarity and Hitler’s Strategy of
World Conquest, Columbia University Press, p.1
293
forces. In the rare case where a coercive wave endures, as in postwar Eastern
Europe, it must be continuously held together by the hegemon or risk falling apart
from its sphere. Autocratic and democratic regime consolidations in the wake of
Fascist Italy was the first to use direct annexation to spread its regime via
coercion. Mussolini envisioned his regime as a return to the glory of Ancient Rome,
complete with grand visions of territorial expansion. In October 1935 Italy invaded
Ethiopia; the following year the new colony was merged with Somalia and Eretria
(Italian possessions since 1889) to form Italian East Africa, an entity that lasted until
1941.333 In April 1939 Italy took over Albania (until its liberation in November
1944). With the onset of general war, Italy made attempts at Egypt, Tunisia, and
Greece between 1940 and 1943. It added British Somaliland to its conquests in
Germany’s attempts were far more successful, in line with its far greater share of
military power. At the peak of Nazi success in Europe, only Switzerland, Sweden,
Finland, Britain, and Ireland remained free. Hitler’s victories between 1938 and
1941 “gave him control of the greater part of continental Europe, something
332
In rare cases a coercive wave maintained by a hegemonic actor can consolidate,
but it does so only by becoming a single political entity, as in the case of China or
Japan. These are cases in which the balancing mechanisms fail. See Victoria Hui
(2005) War and State Formation in Ancient China and Early Modern Europe,
Cambridge University Press. John A. Ferejohn and Frances McCall Rosenbluth, eds.
(2010) War and State Building in Medieval Japan, Stanford University Press.
333
Vaclav Smil (2010) Why America is Not a New Rome, MIT Press, p.10
294
unprecedented since the height of Napoleon's power.”334 The conquest was part of
a plan to establish a fascist order all over Europe, with a dominant Germany greatly
September 1938, the Munich agreement gave Germany Sudetenland, the German
region of Czechoslovakia. A few months later, Hitler offered Poland satellite status,
and after a refusal signed the Nazi-Soviet Pact that carved up Poland and the
Baltics between the two rivals. Poland was invaded and taken over in a matter of
weeks in August-September 1939, setting the stage for the lull of the “phony war”
In May 1940, Hitler invaded and defeated France. Norway, Denmark, Belgium,
Holland and Luxembourg were also conquered that spring. Three small territories
taken by Belgium in 1919 were re-annexed, as well as bits from western Poland
incorporated into the Reich. In April 1941, the Germans over-ran Yugoslavia and
German and Italian military occupation, a puppet regime in Serbia, and a satellite
state governed by the Ustashi in Croatia. Further east, in the Baltic states, Ukraine
and western USSR, Nazi occupation led to the creation of “overarching military
334
Payne 1995:375. “The Germans controlled almost exactly the same
geographical area as Napoleon. Organizing a new "continental system," they made
plans to govern, exploit, and coordinate the resources, industry, and labor of
Europe.… In every country they found sympathizers, collaborators, or
"quislings"…” (Palmer et al 2002:812)
295
occupation authorities, special German economic agencies, and the SS racial and
police administration.” 335 The initially successful invasion of the Soviet Union in
June of 1941 marked the apogee of Hitler’s power and the peak of the fascist wave.
In November of that year Japan launched a series of its own invasions and a raid on
Pearl Harbor.
cajoled” Romania, Bulgaria, and Hungary into joining the Axis and became junior
partners in the fascist coalition.336 Yugoslavia and Greece were occupied in April
The Axis also pushed into North Africa. An Italian campaign eastward from
Libya crossed into Egypt in September 1940, but a British counteroffensive swept
them out a few months later; the British also took over Ethiopia and dismembered
Italian East Africa. But the elite Afrika Korps under the command of General
Rommel reversed Italian losses, attacking Libya and forcing their way through
Egypt, where the British made a final stand with the Suez Canal at their back.337
Hitler “recognized the need for certain allies, for acquiescent satellite states,
and for friendly neutrals,” and this produced :a new configuration of states under
German leadership and/or domination that the Nazi press sometimes hailed as the
335
Payne 1995:377
336
Palmer et al 2002:815
337
Palmer et al 2002:816
338
Payne 1995:376
296
Hitler’s invasion of the Soviet Union in June 1941 inaugurated a new stage in
the expansion of the war, aided by Romania, Hungary and Finland in the side of
297
the Axis. Bulgaria was friendly to Germany, providing economic cooperation and
free transit for German troops, and receiving a slice of Yugoslavia as a reward. New
fascist satellite states included Slovakia (1939), Vichy France (1940) and Croatia
(1941).339 Of the five official neutrals, three collaborated with the Fascist regime in
neutral, given Franco’s fascist sympathies. The Nordic countries received the most
“lenient” treatment out of all occupied states – Denmark was permitted to retain its
autonomy until later in 1943, and the Netherlands were governed by a civilian
Hong Kong, and Malaya. Moving over land through Malaya, they captured
Singapore two months later. By 1942 they conquered the Philippines, Malaya, the
Netherland Indies, New Guinea, the Aleutians, and Burma. They controlled the
Indian Ocean and threatened both India and Australia. The goal was the creation of
a Greater East Asia Co-Prosperity Sphere under Japanese leadership and without
But the defeat and unconditional surrender crushed any hopes for fascism as an
alternative regime path. Not only had Germany’s share of relative power collapsed
339
Payne 1995:376
340
Payne 1995:377
341
Palmer 2002:817
298
in the wake of the defeat, but the decline was the result of a dramatic military
Nearly all fascist movements, with only a few minor exceptions, had
appealed to war as the ultimate test, the nation's most validating
mission. To have failed in the final test of what was largely even
though not exclusively – a fascist war put the seal on the inviability
and self-destructiveness of the fascist enterprise…the final defeat was
so thorough and unconditional that fascism was itself discredited to a
degree unprecedented among major modern political
movements…342
In the aftermath of the next hegemonic shock, the United States and the USSR had
emerged as winners, while Germany was utterly defeated and its regime lost all
legitimacy among former imitators. The century’s third hegemonic shock had left
communism. Because both had proven victorious, both regimes experienced waves
of domestic reforms in their favor in the years following the end of the war – a
Conclusion
The rapid growth of Germany and the USSR in the 1930s was directly tied to
their institutional innovations – the same innovations that vividly set them apart
from the stagnating liberal democracies of the same period. As a result, the statist
Berman observed:
342
Payne 1995:436-7
299
The dynamics of the hegemonic transition of the 1930s were thus a direct
during this period. Even would-be liberals were persuaded by the seemingly
miraculous German recovery. “In my view what China needs is an able and
idealistic dictator,” wrote a Chinese political scientist in 1934. “There are among us
some people, including myself, who have undergone long periods of liberal
distasteful. But if we want to make China into a strong modern nation, I fear there is
Besides attracting countless overt and covert imitators, fascism expanded its
influence via increasing economic power, and coerced a number of territories into
fascist rule. Under attack from both the extreme left and the extreme right, capitalist
unanticipated by either its critics or by many of its supporters. Democracy had now
defeated its second great competitor of the twentieth century, after the triumph over
monarchy failed to establish a stable democratic world. But another alternative still
343
Berman 2006:5
344
Quoted in Charles Kurzman (2008) Democracy Denied, 1905-1915:
Intellectuals and the Fate of Democracy, Harvard University Press, p.253
300
remained, and in the wake of World War II this final challenger seemed poised to
CHAPTER 5
“At the present moment in world history nearly every nation must choose
between alternative ways of life.”
-- Harry S Truman (1947)1
“Whether the Marxist situations all over the world become Communist
preserves depends mostly on the relative strength and policies of the
Western and the Soviet camps.”
-- Adam Ulam (1960)2
For Germans the year 1945 became known as stunde null – zero hour, the period
Cleaved by the force of two messianic powers, Germany became the symbol of a
struggle between competing visions that offered two mutually exclusive utopias.
This chapter examines the aftermath of the largest military conflict of the twentieth
century, the power transition that came in its wake, and the waves of institutional
1
"Address to Joint Session of Congress on Aid to Greece and Turkey," 12 March
1947. Public Papers of the Presidents of the United States: Harry S. Truman,
January 1 to December 31, 1947 (Washington, D.C.: United States Government
Printing Office, 1963), pp. 176-80.
2
Adam Ulam (1960) The Unfinished Revolution: An Essay on the Sources of
Influence of Marxism and Communism, Vintage Books, p.10.
302
Alone among the hegemonic shocks of the twentieth century, World War II
produced not one but two rising great powers, the United States and the Soviet
Union. Each emerged with its military, economy and global reputation greatly
strengthened by the joint triumph over the Axis. Reflecting this duality, the war’s
aftermath witnessed two distinct waves of institutional reforms that embodied the
in their content, both regime waves diffused through a mixture of coercion (through
occupation and nation-building), influence (via the expansion of trade, foreign aid,
rising great powers can take advantage of hegemonic shocks to advance the
opportunity to wipe the slate clean. In the wake of the war, both the Soviet Union
and the United States used their enormous power and influence to construct a new
institutional architecture that helped them perpetuate control and influence over
This chapter first examines the power transition that took place in the years
immediately following the war, and the resulting forces that promoted waves of
303
regime change in its wake. I then turn to the mechanisms of coercion, influence
and emulation though which the Soviet Union and the United States pursued
regime reforms and attracted regime imitators in countries around the world in the
The war had profoundly altered the international distribution of power. Europe
had ended the war shaken and defeated, even within the victorious allied
members. Postwar per capita GDP among the continental Allies was less than 80
percent of its 1939 levels, and in most it was lower than in the early 1920s.3
“Morally and economically Europe has lost the war,” wrote the British writer Cyril
light we all grew up…has fallen down; the side-ropes are frayed, the centre pole is
broken, the chairs and tables are all in pieces, the tent is empty, the roses are
France and Britain, first-rank European powers for centuries, were reduced to
physical in the case of France. The descent of the latter from the ranks of great
powers was made clear by the humiliating defeat of June 1940, followed by four
3
Jeffry A. Frieden (2006) Global Capitalism: Its Fall and Rise in the Twentieth
Century, W.W. Norton and Company, p. 261
4
Cyril Connolly in the journal Horizon, September 1945; quoted in Tony Judt
(2005) Postwar: A History of Europe Since 1945, Penguin Press, p.206
304
against German aggression and perhaps even the Soviet menace further east. But,
as historian Tony Judt writes in his history of postwar Europe, “in six traumatic
forever. France ceased to be not just a Great Power but even a power, and despite
De Gaulle's best efforts in later decades it has never been one since.”5
Britain fared little better. Its victory “revealed Britain's decline, and Roosevelt
did nothing to halt it,” notes Francois Furet. “Britain emerged with honor but in a
weakened condition, heroic but anemic, less and less sure of its mastery over the
the two superpowers, at least in the closing stages and immediate aftermath of the
war.7 But fighting had left the country nearly bankrupt and no longer able to
maintain its far-flung empire. Great Britain “emerged from six years of total war
exhausted, impoverished, and numb.”8 It had become the largest debtor nation in
the world, and in the process shed approximately a quarter of its national wealth.9
5
Judt 2005:113
6
Francois Furet (1999) The Passing of an Illusion: The Idea of Communism in the
Twentieth Century, University of Chicago Press, p.362
7
A 1944 book by political scientist William T.R. Fox, Superpowers, which
introduced the term, carried the subtitle “the United States, Britain, and the Soviet
Union – their responsibility for peace”. Similarly, in the following year political
scientist David J. Dallin published a book titled The Big Three: United States,
Britain, and Russia (New Haven: Yale University Press).
8
Paul Johnson (2009) Churchill, Viking Press, p.143
9
G. John Ikenberry (2000) After Victory: Institutions, Strategic Restraint, and the
Rebuilding of Order After Major Wars, Princeton University Press, p.167
305
In doing so, it “fell to secondary status after World War II: America and Russia
eclipsed her; she was shorn of empire; her economy suffered; and she no longer
exrted decisive influence upon the structure of the international system,” write van
Wingen and Tilemma.10 “Great Britain's moment was past,” writes Roberts. “Her
For the defeated Axis states, feared conquerors only three years earlier, the
decline was far more dramatic. Their industries were in ruins, their people
scattered, the reputations of their regimes irretrievably damaged not only by their
defeat but also by their conduct during the war. Per capita industrial output in the
postwar Axis countries was less than half of its prewar levels; in Italy and Japan this
set output back to its 1910 levels, in Germany to roughly 1890. German living
standards, roughly equal to those of Great Britain before the war, were barely one-
Nor were the conditions in western Europe propitious for recovery. Economic
a time when Europe had lost its ability to pay for these imports. Its empires, which
10
John Van Wingen and Herbert K. Tillema (1980) “British Military Intervention
after World War II: Militance in a Second-Rank Power” Journal of Peace Research
17.4, p.291
11
Robert 1999:440
12
Frieden 2006:261; as Frieden puts it, the war “had thrown back the winners'
economies twenty-five years, while those of the losers had lost forty, fifty, even
seventy-five years.”
306
disintegrating. At the same time, the Cold War had pushed them out of markets in
central and eastern Europe. Compounding the damage was the fact that the
continent had also lost the ability to raise money from foreign investments, which
had been sold to pay for the war.13 By 1945, western Europe, the former locus of
agencies.14
had failed.15 That regime, so recently a paragon of efficiency and order, was now in
the words of a 1945 New York Times editorial “a beaten and discredited system.”16
In its place stood two rival ideologies whose representative countries emerged
victorious from the war. The United States and the Soviet Union began the postwar
period with the strength and reputations greatly enhanced. Militarily, the Red Army
had achieved a stunning victory over Germany. The defeat of Nazi Germany, a
“suggested that the Soviet system had considerable real-world vigor.”17 This
triumph played a key role in the attraction exerted by Communism in the years
13
Frieden 2006:261
14
Roberts 1999:448
15
Schivelbusch 206:189
16
The New York Times (1945) “Democracy on the March”, October 14, p.E8
17
Gale Stokes (1993) The Walls Came Tumbling Down: The Collapse of
Communism in Eastern Europe, Oxford University Press, p.8.
307
following the conflict. Despite the importance of American participation, the war
had been won on the Eastern Front – the graveyard of 506 Nazi divisions and 10
million German soldiers (compared to 3.6 on the Western Front). With its victory,
the Soviet Union annexed territory from Finland in the north, Poland in the center,
and Bessarabia from Romania; Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania were re-absorbed after
Czechoslovakia and the occupation of Sakhalin, Manchuria, and North Korea gave
More importantly, the Red Army dominated the continent and occupied an
unbroken cordon sanitaire from the Baltic to the Black Sea. By the middle of 1945
every country east of the USSR except Greece had governments led either by
occupied Poland, Bulgaria, Romania, and Czechoslovakia; it was the first to enter
Berlin. Only the quick advance of General Montgomery blocked the Red Army
from moving north through Germany toward Denmark; by this point it “constituted
the greatest military force Europe had ever seen.”19 The military triumph “had
proved its military strength, its social cohesion, the patriotism of its population. It
Communism had won the war and thus a new lease on history.”20 Its armies “had
proved far better instruments for the extension of international communism than
18
Kennedy 1987:361-2
19
Judt 2005:117
20
Furet 1999:350
308
revolution had ever been.”21 The end of the war “inaugurated the short period – a
German juggernaut left a power vacuum in central and eastern Europe, which the
Figure 5.1: Soviet share of hegemonic power, 1930-1960. Soviet power increased
rapidly in the second half of the 1940s.
The Soviet economy, though shaken by the war, was recovering rapidly; living
standards improved (albeit from a very low point), and between 1945 and 1950
21
Roberts 1999:440
22
Furet 1999:361
309
were especially important since they signaled the viability of the system to
audiences in the developing world. "The USSR now is one of the mightiest
countries of the world,” declared Molotov in 1946. “One cannot decide now any
serious problems of international relations without the USSR."24 The defeat of the
Nazis “more than reversed the disastrous post-1917 slump in Russia's position in
that of the period 1814-1848, when its great army had been the gendarme of east-
central Europe.”25 Despite the devastation of the war, the Soviet Union emerged as
the most formidable military power (in conventional weapons) on the European
continent. At the end of the war it had four million active soldiers and the control
of territories far larger than its pre-war or even pre-Soviet boundaries.26 Even
admiration for its success. “No one can deny…[that] the ruthlessness of the Soviet
leaders paid dividends,” wrote Granville Hicks, a lapsed Marxist who had
those who argue that the Soviet regime must be virtuous because it triumphed in
23
By 1949 industrial production also exceeded prewar levels everywhere in Eastern
Europe. Frieden 2006:274-5
24
Quoted in Kennedy 1987:365
25
Kennedy 1987:361
26
Palmer et al 2002:835-6
27
Granville Hicks (1946) “The Spectre that Haunts the World” Harper’s Magazine,
June, p.537
310
The war had proven to be Communism's greatest challenge and, through the
very magnitude of that challenge, its savior. The victory “combined the two gods
that make or break historical times: power and ideas,” allowing the USSR to
midst of plenty – remain in the forefront of people's minds,” wrote Raymond Aron
in 1944. “At the same time, the efficiency of the Communist regime's performance
during the war has refuted some classical arguments on the inevitable decadence
inherent in a bureaucratic economy.”29 A rise in power meant not only the power
to coerce, but also the power to attract, both through the allure of communism and
they put the blame.”30 If capitalism represented the past, communism held the
promise of a bright future, particularly for European intellectuals who witnessed the
decay of the old bourgeois order. It “excited intellectuals in a way that neither
Hitler nor (especially) liberal democracy could hope to match,” writes Judt. It was
universal and transcendent goals. Its crimes were excused by many non-
28
Furet 1999:349
29
Raymond Aron (1944/2002) “The Secular Religions” in The Dawn of Universal
History: Selected Essays from a Witness to the Twentieth Century, Basic Books,
transl. by Barbara Bray, p.194
30
Hicks 1946:537
311
This potent combination of material success and ideological appeal enabled the
USSR to both coerce its neighbors and to attract admirers within them, sometimes
at the same time. “Say what you will – the Communists were more intelligent,”
wrote Milan Kundera, recalling how he, along with half the nation, cheered the
Soviet takeover of Czechoslovakia in 1948 (the half, he writes, that was “the more
dynamic, the more intelligent, the better half.”) Communism managed to capture
program, a plan for a brand-new world in which everyone would find his place.
The Communists’ opponents had no great dream; all they had was a few moral
principles, stale and lifeless, to patch up the tattered trousers of the established
Poland, anti-fascist resistance politics leaned to the left.34 For that reason, the end
of the war was “even more of a political victory for the Communist idea than for
31
Judt 2005:216
32
Milan Kundera (1979/1999) Book of Laughter and Forgetting, New York:
HarperCollins, p.11
33
Eric Hobsbawm (1994) The Age of Extremes: A History of the World, 1914-1991,
Vintage Books, p.166
34
As Hobsbawm puts it: “In each country the fascist and radical Right and
conservatives, the local rich and others whose main terror was social revolution,
tended to sympathize, or at least not to oppose, the Germans…” Hobsbawm
1994:165.
312
More generally, as Raymond Aron pointed out shortly before war’s end, the
twentieth-century faiths. The idea that “the postcapitalist economy would give birth
to a new, egalitarian human order transcends knowledge and derives from an act of
As long as men see politics as the vehicle of their fate, they will
actively worship the regimes that, dangling before them an illusory
future, reflect their desires and console them for their
disappointments. As long as troubled masses think themselves
betrayed or exploited, men will dream of liberation, and the image of
their dream will be the face of their god.37
Communism embodied that dream in the image of the Soviet Union and its
The United States held an undeniable advantage over the Soviet Union in
economic and industrial development (more on that below). But when it came to
cultural appeal, “the Communists did not even need to take the initiative,” wrote
35
Furet 1999:356
36
Aron 1944/ 2002:181
37
Aron 1944/ 2002:193
38
Aron (1954) “From Marxism to Stalinism” in Aron 2002:203
313
Judt. “Fear of American domination, of the loss of national autonomy and initiative,
brought into the 'progressive' camp men and women of all political stripes and
deadly combination.”39
This element of the post-war Soviet appeal is often lost in the focus on Soviet
coercion in Eastern Europe. The Soviet Union exerted its influence not only through
the armies camped out on the banks of the Elbe, but also through the cultural and
to all the secret of what made humanity divine after God had receded – namely,
Francois Furet. “To possess both liberty and knowledge of that liberty: now here
was an intoxicating brew for moderns deprived of God…If the Soviet political
economy evoked such infatuation, it was not only because it formed an almost
because it revealed a moral idea, a regenerated humanity, delivered from the curse
of profit.”40
Yet without the wartime triumphs, Communism might have shared the fate of
other alluring and failed prophecies of modernity, and indeed seemed to be on the
way to doing so in the 1930s. After all, the ideological attractions of communism
were in place well before 1945, having been set down my Marx and Engels a
century earlier. The appeal of these ideas had brought forth a swathe of Communist
39
Judt 2005:220
40
Furet 1999:26,154
314
parties and sympathizers across Europe even before 1917. But the expected wave
vintages for the Communist idea,” wrote Furet, “because they were accompanied
by the most powerful god in history – that of victory.”41 Despite initial setbacks,
“the USSR had out-produced and out-fought the Nazi colossus, ripping the heart
from the magnificent German military machine,” writes Judt. “For its friends and
foes alike, the Soviet victory in World War Two bore witness to the Bolsheviks'
achievement. Stalin's policies were vindicated, his pre-war crimes largely forgotten.
Success, as Stalin well understood, is a winning formula.”42 In short, it was the rise
of the Soviet Union and its ascent to superpower status after World War II that
paved the way for a credible communist alternative around the world. This path
was forged both by force and sincere, hopeful imitation. Stalin had “won the war,
transformed the Soviet Union into an empire and a superpower, and made the
Communist idea more influential than it had ever been,” wrote Furet. “His
As Raymond Aron pointed out, “The divisions of the Red Army would inspire
less apprehension if they were not seen to act in the service of an idea. It is the
41
Furet 1999:361
42
Judt 2005:165-6
43
Furet 1999:439)
315
combination of an empire risen suddenly on the ruins of the European nations and
an apparently universal message that spreads a kind of terror throughout the non-
Communist world.”44 The post-WWII period was thus a moment when ideological
and material power came together to give communism both an aura of normative
attraction and the prestige of a triumphant victor. “The image of the Soviet Union,
when decked out in all the prestige of power and ideology,” wrote Furet, “had
The other major beneficiary of the war was the United States. Spurred by vast
increases in military expenditures, its gross national product rose from $88.6 billion
in 1939 to $135 billion in 1945 (in constant 1939 dollars). Between 1940 and
1944, U.S. industrial production expanded by over 15 percent per year, a faster
rate than at any other period in its history.46 The continental United States had been
untouched by the war, its oceans providing immunity from physical destruction;
“America's fixed capital was intact, her resources greater than ever.”47 Output of
goods grew by over 50 percent during the war, while the country’s manufacturing
base expanded by nearly 50 percent.48 At the end of the war, the U.S. owned $20
44
Aron 1954/2002:203
45
Furet 1999:350
46
As Kennedy notes, among the great powers the United States “was the only
country which became richer – in fact, much richer – rather than poorer because of
the war.” Kennedy 1987:357-8
47
Roberts 1999:448
48
W. Ashworth (1975) A Short History of the International Economy Since 1850,
London, p.268. Quoted in Kennedy 1987:357
316
billion of the world’s $33 billion of gold reserves. It was the world’s largest creditor
country and biggest source of international liquidity, with the ability to provide
capital to countries that needed it desperately.49 It was the home of over half of the
world’s economic production, the globe’s biggest exporter, supplier of half of the
petroleum and food production.50 Its merchant fleet, a third of the size of Europe in
1939, was more than twice as large by 1947.51Domestic standards of living actually
rose during the war.52 “Economically,” Kennedy writes, “the world was its oyster.”53
Of the three major winners of the war, the United States “remained far and away
the United States had 12.5 million servicemen, 7.5 million of them abroad; sixty-
nine divisions in Europe and twenty-six in Asia and the Pacific. With the landing on
Normandy, it had organized and executed “one of the most spectacular military
operations in history.”55 After the occupation of Italy, American forces had liberated
France, Belgium, and the Netherlands, and conquered half of Germany. Outside of
the sphere of Soviet dominance, the United States possessed total command of the
global commons, on the water and in the air. It maintained 1200 major warships,
49
Roberts 1999:448
50
Ikenberry 2001:167
51
Frieden 2006:261
52
Roberts 1999:448
53
Kennedy 1987:358
54
Furet 1999:362
55
Furet 1999:362
317
significantly more than the Royal Navy. “In both its carrier task forces and its
Marine Corps divisions,” writes Paul Kennedy, “the United States had amply
demonstrated its capacity to project its power across the globe to any region
accessible from the sea.”56 It also had an overwhelming command of the air, with
over 2000 heavy bombers and over a thousand long-range B-29s. Most
devastation upon any future enemy as horrific as that which had occurred at
Hiroshima and Nagasaki.”57 This image of superiority was “reinforced by the pleas
support.”58
shifted dramatically over the course of the war. In 1939 the combined economies
of Europe, Japan and the USSR were twice the size of the United States; by 1946
the U.S. was larger than all of them together. The steel production of Germany,
Britain and the USSR combined totaled less than half of the U.S., having been 15
percent larger only seven years earlier.59 “The United States emerged from the war
unusually powerful in relation to the European great powers and Japan,” writes
Ikenberry:
America's allies and the defeated axis states were battered and
diminished by the war, whereas the United States grew more
powerful through mobilization and war. The American government
56
Kennedy 1987:358
57
Kennedy 1987:358
58
Kennedy 1987:358-9
59
Frieden 2006:261-2
318
was more centralized and capable, and the economy and military
were unprecedented in their power and still on an upward swing. In
addition, the war itself had ratified the destruction of the old order of
the 1930s, eliminated the alternative regional hegemonic ambitions
of Germany and Japan, and diminished the viability of the British
imperial order.60
The American victory had proven democracy’s ability to triumph over a feared and
level of existence,” wrote the New York Times, “it becomes apparent that democracy has
not only held its own, but is stronger than ever and carries a greater appeal to more
people than ever before.”61 In his defeat Hitler joined the long list of those who had
dismissed the ability of democratic states to effectively manage an economy and win
capacity for action, not to mention the economic and technological potential, of the
John Kenneth Galbraith noted: “During World War II it was widely believed that the
ruthlessly exercised power of the German dictatorship was a major source of strength and
one manifestation was its ability to command more than seven million workers from all
convincing fashion. At the end of the Great War, German territory had never been
60
Ikenberry 2001:167
61
The New York Times (1945) “Democracy on the March”, October 14, p.E8
62
Hobsbawm 1994:41
63
John Kenneth Galbraith (1967) The New Industrial State, New York: Houghton
Mifflin, p.142-3
319
occupied by foreign troops. In 1945, military defeat was total, and widely
surrender and lasting post-war occupation were accepted conditions for ending the
hostilities. And unlike in 1919, the United States played a more visible and vital
role in ending the war. “[I]ts resources and technology were vital for winning,”
notes Ikenberry. “Its political leadership was more critical than it had been during
World War I.”64 By providing crucial military assistance to both Great Britain and
the USSR, it secured itself a position of strength in bargaining over post-war goals
the very target of that expansion, Europe itself. European leaders were willing to
pay the price of American hegemony in exchange for avoiding the perils of
to the Allies powers, its own military participation, its economic dominance and
the threat of Soviet occupation all meant that it could dictate the terms of the post-
The fact that American power had grown and European flagged made
it clear that the United States would have its way with the rest of the
world. At Versailles and after, Woodrow Wilson and his colleagues
had faced European intransigence on issue after issue and had been
forced to conciliate on such important matters as German
reparations. Now America's Western Allies were at the mercy of the
United States.66
The rapid rise of American power and its defeat of Nazi Germany served as a
64
Ikenberry 2001:169
65
Ikenberry 2001:193
66
Frieden 2006:262
320
“proved that America could defeat evil on a global scale….Victory in World War II
was therefore a victory not just for an alliance, but also for the American way of life
itself. It had outproduced and outgunned its enemies; now the time had come to
transform both enemies and friends in one's own image.”67 Its position meant that it
would be instrumental in deciding the future course of Europe and the developing
world. “Europe and Japan were crushed or exhausted,” writes Frieden, “the United
States was wealthy and powerful, and its involvement would determine the speed
recovery, their economies looked toward the United States as a source of capital,
67
Odd Arne Westad (2005) The Global Cold War: Third World Interventions and
the Making of Our Times, Cambridge University Press, p. 20-21
68
Frieden 2006:262
69
Roberts 1999:448
321
Figure 5.2: American share of hegemonic power, 1930-1960. U.S. relative power
increased rapidly during the war, peaking in the late 1940s.
extraordinary dominance of the U.S. position. "The U.S. is in the position today
where Britain was at the end of the Napoleonic wars," wrote British Foreign
Europeans and Asiatics know that both the quality and the rhythm of their lives
depend upon decisions made in Washington,” wrote British scholar Harold Laski
70
“The Chargé in the United Kingdom [Gallman] to the Secretary of State," 16 June
1947, Foreign Relations of the United States, 1947, Vol. 3, pp. 254-55. Quoted in
Ikenberry 2000:168. As Kennedy points out, “simply because much of the rest of
the world was either exhausted by the war or still in a stage of colonial
"underdevelopment," American power in 1945 was, for want of another term,
artificially high, like, say, Britain's in 1815.” Kennedy 1987:357, orig. emph.
322
that same year. “On the wisdom of those decisions hangs the fate of the next
generation."71 U.S. policy-makers anticipated and actively planned for the post-war
world. As a wartime policy memo put it: “The successful termination of the war
against our present enemies will find a world profoundly changed in respect of
relative national military strengths.... After the defeat of Japan, the United States
and the Soviet Union will be the only military powers of the first magnitude.”72 In a
1948 State Department review of American foreign policy, George Kennan wrote:
"We have about 50% of the world's wealth but only 6.3% of its population.... Our
real task in the coming period is to devise a pattern of relationships which will
national security."73
In sum, the outcome of the war both transformed and clarified the distribution
courses are not the same,” wrote Alexis de Tocqueville of Russia and the United
States in 1835, “yet each of them seems marked by the will of Heaven to sway the
71
Harold J. Laski, "America – 1947”, Nation, Vol. 165 (December 13, 1947), p.
641. Quoted in Ikenberry 2001:168
72
Quoted in Kennedy 1987:357, citing M. Matloff (1959) Strategic Planning for
Coalition Warfare, 1943-1944, Washington, D.C., p.523-4.
73
"Memorandum by the Director of the Policy Planning Staff [Kennan] to the
Secretary of State and Under Secretary of State [Lovett]," 24 February 1948, Foreign
Relations of the United States, 1948, Vol. 1, p. 524. Quoted in Ikenberry 2001:169
323
destinies of half the globe.”74 A hundred and ten years later, his prediction was
swiftly coming true. The Soviet Union and the United States were the only two
states that had risen in stature because of the war, and now towered in strength and
prestige above the rest of the world. “It became common to speak of the two
overshadowing all other states, including the nations of western Europe long
The nature of the power transition and the ensuing competition between the
victors dictated active global involvement by the two emerging superpowers. Fear
of economic decay and European instability required the United States to prop up
capitalist export markets. Fear of future military invasions required the Soviet Union
exporting their regimes to other countries, and their universalist and messianic
expert Adam Ulam, the best characterization of the competition between the
United States and the USSR is “a race between the social and economic
dynamisms of the two societies.”76 A key element of that race was each hegemon’s
74
Alexis de Tocqueville (1834) Democracy in America
75
Palmer et al 2002:835-6
76
Adam Ulam (1960) The Unfinished Revolution: An Essay on the Sources of
Influence of Marxism and Communism, Vintage Books, p.299
324
communist regime expansion was uniquely tied to the welfare of the Soviet Union,
both because it required the unceasing coercion of eastern European satellites and
because only Soviet power and continued growth could credibly demonstrate the
and a source of its aggressiveness, was “an assertive policy designed to illustrate
Europe from the destruction of the war and the ability to demonstrate its
States and the USSR thus “needed to change the world in order to prove the
universal applicability of their ideologies, and the elites of the newly independent
states proved fertile ground for their competition,” writes Arne Westad. This
compunction lent a messianic tinge to their foreign policies and further catalyzed
77
As Frieden puts it, “Economic trends in the Soviet Union and its allies were
especially important because the Communist world was expanding outside
Europe.” (Frieden 2006:275)
78
Ulam 1960:292
79
Westad 2005:4-5
325
crisis, and both offered a vision for political and social development that
transcended national boundaries. The United States made a transition from the
international skies are still dark with the clouds of disagreement among the war’s
victors, there is one encouraging sign which is unmistakable, and that is the
new level of existence, it becomes apparent that democracy has not only held its
own, but is stronger than ever and carries a greater appeal to more people than
ever before.”80 When Turkey ended a long period of single-party rule in 1945 and
Menderes explained the shift in terms that clearly revealed the demonstration
80
The New York Times (1945) “Democracy on the March” October 14, page E8.
81
Adnan Menderes, Cumhuriyet, 18 July 1946, quoted in Kemal H. Karpat,
Turkey's Politics (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1959), p. 140, n. 10.
Quoted in Samuel Huntington (1982) “American Ideals versus American
Institutions” Political Science Quarterly 97.1, p.33
326
Figure 5.3: Average global level of democracy (1930-1970, using Polity IV). The
graph shows the century’s second democratic wave. The global level of democracy
rose rapidly in the second half of the 1940s and began to decline in the late 1950s.
327
Figures 5.4 and 5.5: Another measure of the postwar democratic wave. Figure 5.4
shows the total number of democratic states (states with a Polity score of at least 7)
while Figure 5.5 shows the number of democratic states as a proportion of all states
in the international system. Both the absolute and the relative number of
democratic states increases rapidly in the mid-1940s.
328
Figure 5.6: Communist share of global power. The chart shows the communist
wave beginning in the mid-1940s. The dashed line represents total global power
(measured in CINC) held by all communist states; the solid line below represents
global power held by communist states excluding the Soviet Union. The communist
share of power increases rapidly between the mid-1940s and the early 1950s.
329
Figures 5.7 and 5.8: Another measure of the postwar communist wave. Figure 5.7
shows the total number of communist states, while Figure 5.8 shows the number of
communist states as a proportion of all states in the international system. Both the
absolute and the relative number of communist states increases rapidly in the mid-
1940s.
330
The Soviet Union, meanwhile, offered a radically different and (to many) an
suffered terribly from the war, but its military successes left it dominant east of the
Rhine, and by the end of the war Soviet industrial plant was going strong,” writes
Frieden. Communists “also emerged from the war with a vastly improved
reputation. While many Socialists, Christian Democrats, and others had behaved
movements and parties.”82 Thus in the period immediately after the end of the war,
“Stalinist Communism, victorious over the Fascist dictators, reached its greatest
socialist world of Communist-led countries gave hope to millions that there was
indeed a way to avoid the impersonality of capitalism's market forces and their
tendency to work against the interests of the poor and powerless.”84 It is the rise of
The coerced Sovietization of Eastern Europe was the most visible aspect of the postwar
communist wave. It was a clear manifestation of newfound Soviet power and the direct
result of Red Army occupation and control of the region. As such, this coercive aspect of
the communist wave was both crucial in increasing the number of communist states
82
Frieden 2007:263
83
Furet 1999:160
84
Frieden 2006:275-6
331
around the world and least interesting in terms of theoretical analysis. “It would be foolish
to ask what secret affinity – perhaps it was the peasant majority or the Slav community, for
example – predisposed the countries of Eastern Europe to follow in the path of the
Communists,” wrote Raymond Aron in 1954. “Any country liberated by the Russian army,
even France, Britain, or Spain, would have met the same fate.”85 Nevertheless, the forced
conversion of Eastern Europe was not a monolithic or instantaneous process. The native
popularity of communism varied widely from one country to the next, and in some places
memoirs testify). Even those who rejected communist ideology saw opportunities in the
rapid growth of institutions of the state and the party. The creation of new jobs meant that
“men from humble backgrounds suddenly had powers and privileges that they could not
previously have dreamed of.”86 Even the postwar purges in Eastern Europe provided a
potential rivals with denunciations both fantastic and readily accepted – a grim replica of
USSR’s Great Purges barely a decade earlier. “Astonishing as it seems in retrospect, the
period when communist rule in eastern Europe was at its most brutal was also the period
during which many intelligent and well-meaning individuals thought that it was a good
thing,” writes Vinen. “This partly explains how it was possible to bring about rapid
And indeed the changes wrought in Eastern Europe between 1945 and 1948
85
Aron 1954/ 2002:226
86
Vinen 2000:341
87
Vinen 2000:339
332
(when Tito’s break with Stalin marked the end of the first stage of the post-war
wave) were dramatic and all-encompassing. The reforms of this period, writes Gale
Stokes:
About a hundred million people had passed into Soviet jurisdiction in the years
following the war. The Soviet bloc, as it came to be known, included Yugoslavia,
occupied half of Germany that became the German Democratic Republic. These
rough replicas assimilated the salient features of the Soviet state: a one-party
propagated by the political leadership; show trials and purges of local communists
(in those states where the Red Army exercised direct influence); and “the most
The political subordination of a territory began with the arrival of the occupying
88
Stokes 1993: 8
89
Hobsbawm 1994:394-5. These features also re-appeared in China, Cuba, and a
number of short-lived imitators in Africa, Asia, and Latin America during the 1970s.
333
army, so that the Red Army began exercising control over many of these states well
before the end of actual hostilities.90 Nevertheless, in few cases did the communist
come to power through sheer force and intimidation. Hobsbawm, for example,
notes that while the regime transformations in Europe “all were made possible by
the victory of the Red Army,” in only four cases – Poland, East Germany, Romania,
and Hungary – were the reforms “imposed exclusively by the force of that army.”91
enjoyed widespread indigenous support (which later enabled them to break away
from the Soviet sphere of dominance). 92 Nowhere did the communists constitute
the majority of the electorate, “but what they lacked in numbers, they made up for
country in the region with a large and organized mass of industrial workers –
communists received 38 percent of the vote, while the Social Democrats received
Russophile sentiment.95 Everywhere the old elites had been discredited, the upper
classes removed from state bureaucracies; in the former Axis states of Hungary,
Romania and Bulgaria the quisling and philofascist governments were overthrown;
and in many countries around the region “the Soviet occupiers were at first
90
Palmer et al 2002:837
91
Hobsbawm 1994:395
92
Hobsbawm 1994:395-6
93
Vinen 2000:342
94
Halperin 2004:253
95
Hobsbawm 1994:170
334
welcomed as liberators and harbingers of change and reform.”96 The youth and the
intelligentsia drew inspiration from “building a new world on what was so visibly
the total ruin of the old.”97 The arrival of Communist regimes, “whether they came
mainly or partly with the support of the Soviet bayonets, were led by people
the Kremlin and were only too glad to avail themselves of the help, advice, and
Moreover, the Soviets did not immediately appear to pursue hard-line policies –
bound partly by his wartime alliances, Stalin had assured the West that the region
would follow neither Soviet-style socialism nor Western capitalism, but a “people’s
bourgeois who would build mixed economies.99 An echo of the social democracy
and made the initial push for reforms more palatable to both the West and cautious
observers in Eastern Europe. This also meant that the early period of Soviet
influence enjoyed the unspoken assent of the United States. And in many ways, its
strategy “really was reassuringly moderate.”100 Just like inside Russia itself after the
1917 revolution, the communists tread lightly at first – agrarian reforms focused on
96
Judt 2005:130
97
Hobsbawm 1994:396
98
Ulam 1960:262
99
Frieden 2006:274
100
Judt 2005:131
335
was for the most part left alone (except for the confiscation of “fascist” property,
especially in eastern Germany) and the USSR did not pursue a policy of economic
Even in countries where coercion played a greater role, and where a communist
government was imposed by the army, “the new regime initially enjoyed a
unpopular party and government, the very energy and determination which both
people in the backward agrarian states of the region who sought a quick path to
modernity.103 “[T]he Soviet economic recipe also seemed to suit them, and their
new rulers launched themselves into the task of economic construction with
genuine enthusiasm,” writes Hobsbawm. “Indeed, the success of the new regimes
in this task was hard to deny….Who could doubt that countries like Bulgaria or
Yugoslavia were advancing far more rapidly than had seemed likely, or even
possible before the war?”104 One of the paradoxes of postwar eastern Europe was
that between 1945 and 1948, a time of great repression, political intimidation,
show trials, and executions, was also the time when “enthusiasm for communism
was most intense and in which some eastern Europeans, often those who had
101
Judt 2005:131
102
Hobsbawm 1994:396
103
Exceptions to this rule included the future East Germany, Czechoslovakia, and to
a lesser extent Hungary.
104
Hobsbawm 1994:377, 396
336
suffered for their beliefs under earlier regimes, made the deliberate choice to attach
the fate of their countries to that of the Soviet Union.”105 The dynamics that drove
of coercion but (particularly in the earliest stages) also reflected the increased
successes. “It is true that the Communist part dictatorship was brought to the small
dissident Gaspar Miklos Tamas, “but we should admit that we were ready for it.”106
The consolidation of Soviet control over the region thus proceeded in steps.
governments. The standard tactic was to form an alliance with other left-wing or
Fatherland Front. In cases where those parties refused to join a fictitious coalition,
Popular Front tactics of the 1930s in France, Spain and elsewhere. The coalitions
“would exclude and punish the old regime and its supports but would be cautious
105
Vinen 2000:338
106
Quoted in Stokes 1993:7
107
Roberts 1999:451
108
Hicks 1946:540
109
Judt 2005:130-1
337
war’s end, such coalition governments ran every country in eastern Europe.
these ill-glued creations.110 This dominance enabled them to hold key positions in
the army, the courts, and the policy, as well as the crucial ministries of justice and
the interior. As opposition leaders realized too late, political control rather than
specific policies would shape the outcome. “The Communists secure the critical
positions in the united front and in the government that it organizes,” wrote
Granville Hicks in 1946. “The ministry of the interior, for example, which usually
controls the censorship, and the ministry of justice, which has charge of the police,
allowed them to buy the loyalty of the peasants) as well as positions in trade
From the start, power-sharing was a tactical, temporary choice. As East German
Communist leader Walter Ulbricht told his followers in 1945: “It's quite clear – it's
got to look democratic, but we must have everything in our control.”113 Control of
the security forces – the army and the police – enabled Communists to use political
110
Palmer et al 2002:872
111
Hicks 1946:540. This tactic, as Hicks noted, was doubly advantageous: “it gives
Communists greater influence than their numbers warrant, and at the same time
saves them from the assumption of full responsibility – and saves Russia, as well.”
112
Judt 2005:131. By contrast, Judt notes, they gave their socialist, agrarian and
liberal coalition allies offices of the president, prime minister, and foreign minister,
which “reassured Western observers.”
113
Quoted in Judt 2005:131.
338
“made a mockery of Stalin's pledge at Yalta to hold "free and unfettered elections"
electoral rules; in the January 1947 Polish elections, for example, Peasant Party
became apparent that coalitions governments “could, in fact, do little more than
behave as Soviet puppets. Something like a communist bloc was already appearing
in 1946.”116 By the middle of that year, an observer could write that the Soviet
Union “can not only assert, as any great power might do, that it has a right to
exercise direct control over certain of the individuals who rule those countries.
authority…” 117
Soviet need for a buffer zone meant it could not trust previously hostile East
European states to set up their own regimes. “The only acceptable outcome for
Stalin was the establishment…of governments that could be relied upon never to
from the governments of Hungary, Romania and Poland (all three had been
114
Palmer et al 2002:872)
115
Vinen 2000:251
116
Roberts 1999:451
117
Hicks 1946:540
118
Judt 2005:130
339
into outright intimidation and persecution. Between 1945 and 1947 political
office. By the following summer, seven of the twenty-two members of the party’s
Hungary, the secretary the Smallholders’ Party was arrested by Soviet authorities in
February 1947.121
Non-socialist leftist parties were the easiest targets, since they could be always
overlapped with the communists and who had also suffered under fascist rules.
These parties could not be credibly accused of fascist collusion and enjoyed the
allegiance of the region’s working class, and so had to be handled in more delicate
ways. They were urged to join communist-socialist “union” governments under the
119
Judt 2005:132
120
Judt 2005:132
121
Vinen 2000:251-2
122
Judt 2005:132
340
into the fold did not protect the socialist partners from criticism – during Romania’s
February congress marking the fusion of the two parties, the Communist leader
Soviet smears. By the end of year, the Socialist parties were hopelessly divided, “so
that long before they disappeared they had ceased to be an effective political force
in their country.”123 Between 1945 and 1948 Communist parties replaced coalition
voter fraud and political intimidation. Policies shifted to reflect more hard-line
the region, the first in Bulgaria, in December 1947 and the last in Poland in July
1952. They were turned into police states, ruled by local Communist parties under
throughout the bloc.”124 The countries adopted Five-Year plans, with wildly
ambitious goals. By 1948 the state had nationalized large firms and companies,
took total control over economic planning (which emphasized heavy industry),
restricted external trade, and took over (through force or taxation) any private
business employing more than fifty people.125 Starting in 1949, the policy of land
123
Judt 2005:133
124
Judt 2005:169
125
Frieden 2006:274
341
redistribution that had briefly mollified the peasants was replaced by land
January 1949, itself a response to the Marshall Plan, further speeded up the
In a few short years, Stalin succeeded in populating the region with what
transformation was driven primarily by the enormous power of the Soviet Union,
manifested most directly by the lengthy occupation of the region by the Red Army.
sentiment that drew upon the successes of the Soviet regime in liberating the region
from Nazi occupation. But the heavy hand of the occupation was bound to alienate
native Communist supporters, just as German cruelty a few years earlier drove off
potential allies in Ukraine and elsewhere. Defaulting to the use of force was
126
Judt 2005:167-9
127
Halperin 2004:256
128
Quoted in Judt 2005:167
342
of their countries.129
Often these desires for transformations ran parallel with Soviet goals. The
Soviet Union had intended. But the spread of communist regimes in the region
Yugoslavia, “the general tenor of Soviet policies toward Tito was having a
occasionally reinforced by popular protests and Red Army interventions. Once the
source of that coercion was removed in the late 1980s, communist regimes
disappeared from the region in a wave as swift as the one that installed it in the first
place.
heightened but temporary period of influence and approval. The period offered a
window of opportunity for increased influence and emulation, some of which was
admiration, gained from the Red Army's victory over Hitler, that haloed the
Communist idea immediately after World War II did not long remain intact,” wrote
129
Ulam 1960:263
130
Ulam 1960:264
343
merely ephemeral capital with uncertain returns; the history of Communism was
coercion, the appeal of communism and its subsequent spread in the developing
world was based to a much larger degree on the desire to emulate Soviet success
and to benefit from the superpower’s largesse and expanded influence. The Soviet
dramatic defeat of a feared military juggernaut, the swift rise to the status of an anti-
rural countries who had just thrown off the shackles of colonial bondage. Soviet-
rapid catching up,” writes Furet. “It furnished a body of Western ideas capable of
Marxism-Leninism.”133
In most places this adoption took place without the support (albeit often with
the tacit or explicit encouragement) of the Soviet Union. Communist ideas found
131
Furet 1999:396
132
Aron (1957) “Nations and Empires” in Aron 2002:54
133
Furet 1999:370
344
fertile ground in Asia, Africa, and the Middle East – regions in which nationalism,
wrote Raymond Aron, was “weak against the attraction of a universalist ideology
Europe, which proceeded “thanks to advances by the Red Army” with China,
where the communist party won with very little direct Soviet support – less than the
Kuomintang had received form the United States. “In Southeast Asia and in the
Middle East, China and the Soviet Union, respectively, are capable of eliminating
The communist wave outside Europe achieved its most visible successes in
(while the Americans occupied the south of the country, recreating the division of
Germany in an Asian setting). The People’s Republic of China was created in 1949,
following years of fighting between the Kuomintang and the communists, led by
Mao and supported by Soviet arms. The First Indochina War (1946-1954) created a
communist-led North Vietnam after fighting by Ho Chi Min with the support of the
Soviets and the Chinese. The Hukbalahap (Huk) communist-led rebellion in the
Philippines made a serious bid for power during the late 1940s before being
1948 that was put down by the nationalists. In Malaysia, communist forces fought a
war with the colonial government from 1948 until 1960. And all over the region,
134
Aron 1957/2002:54
345
Democracy, on the other hand, came with the baggage of history and colonial
In the Middle East, too, communist ideology began to attract a much greater
degree of support after the war, especially among nationalists and intellectuals.
Communist parties made large gains in Egypt, Palestine, Syria, Lebanon, Iraq, and
September 1947, while welcoming Indonesia and Vietnam into the “anti-
imperialist camp,” Chairman of the Union Soviet Andrei Zhdanov labeled Egypt,
Syria and India as “sympathizing” with it.138 For the secular intellectuals within the
135
Hobsbawm 1994:435
136
Walter Z. Laqueur (1955) “The Appeal of Communism in the Middle East”
Middle East Journal 9.1, p.21
137
Laqueur 1955:17-18
138
Hobsbawm 1994:227. The address was notable, as Hobsbawm notes, for a
complete lack of reference to China.
346
of the Middle East.”139 Explaining its draw for Arab intellectuals, the Lebanese
foreign minister Charles Malik listed the following in a 1957 interview: "Its social
vision, its total character, its total interpretation of life – its messianic idea, namely,
that it is the wave of the future. Also, the promises it holds – that it will solve all
For similar reasons, the communist creed resonated with the masses in
developing nations far more than democratic or capitalist ideals. “Without having
read a word of Marx or Lenin,” wrote Adam Ulam, “an illiterate peasant who is
his loss of property and status, and an antagonism toward the people and authority
personifying the mysterious forces that have made his previous social existence
world.” On the other hand, Western democracy, “the product of a long industrial
139
Laqueur 1955:25
140
Interview with Charles Malik, Foreign Minister of Lebanon, "How to Beat
Communism in the Middle East," U.S. News and World Report, March 29, 1957, p.
88. Quoted in Marver H. Bernstein (1957) “Review: The Appeal of Communism in
Arab Countries” World Politics 9.4, p.624
347
whose evils could be attributed to the impersonal forces of capitalism. But it also
offered something in exchange beyond a bête noire: “Just as it exploits the nostalgia
for a past ruined forever by the capitalists, it appeals to the impatience for the
accordingly: “Professional agitators will raise more recruits among the poverty-
stricken crowds of Asia than among the workers of General Motors. The
capitalistic a society is, and the less developed its productive forces, the more
An ideological panacea for the masses and the intellectuals, communism also
absolutism. “Fortified by the Soviet precedent, the tyrant of the second half of the
twentieth drew his legitimacy from an emancipatory ambition,” wrote Furet. “He
led his country to socialism via a new version of modern democracy freed of its
141
Ulam 1960:284-5, orig. emph.
142
Aron 1954/2002:210, 228
348
and elite domination, communism found resonance among a large swath of social
groups – the public, the intelligentsia, and the political elite – in the developing
today's world.” By contrast, “liberalism as practiced and preached in the West can
Laqueur noted in 1956, “could not inspire the masses, and it did not give firm
Eastern Europe, had been in place well before 1945. The surge of communist
influence and emulation in the developing world could take place only once
ideology had become coupled with power and success. Noting that World War II
“brought a great upsurge in Middle Eastern Communism,” Laqueur noted that “one
of the main reasons for this growth in influence appears to be, in retrospect, the
emergence of the Soviet Union as one of the two great world powers and the
downfall of Nazi Germany and Fascist Italy.”146 In the Middle East as elsewhere,
“Communist support has been further strengthened by the example of the Soviet
143
Furet 1999:371
144
Ulam 1960:285, 287, orig. emph.
145
Walter Z. Laqueur (1956) Communism and Nationalism in the Middle East, New
York: Frederick A. Praeger, Inc., p. 275. Quoted in Bernstein 1957:627.
146
Laqueur 1955:17
349
could transform itself within a single generation into a world power of great
industrial strength.”147
Alone, ideas could inspire movements and set the groundwork for changes to
come, but were less successful in transforming regimes and upending institutions in
countries around the world. As the case of fascism between 1922 and 1933 and
communism between 1917 and 1945 demonstrated, ideas were more than
abstractions – they could introduce new regimes and set very real-world precedents
(in the form of the Bolshevik Revolution and the March on Rome) – but, crucially,
in isolation they did not lead to institutional waves. The immense impact of
with the strength of example. An example that was recent and dramatic, one that
led to the collapse and ruin of some great powers while uplifting others, held that
much more sway. The power shifts that accompanied the aftermath of hegemonic
shocks served as indisputable proof that some examples were worth following
more than others, and fundamentally (if temporarily) transformed both the
opportunities and incentives for domestic reforms. For the developing world of the
postwar era, the hegemonic shock of the war transformed communism from an
appealing if abstract vision to a concrete, viable model for economic and political
147
Bernstein 1957:628
350
development.148
This was particularly true in the case of economic reforms. The post-war
government expansion during war, diffused into the politics of much of the
developing world, notably in France but also in Britain and the United States. In
offering a new option for development, it had replaced the fascist alternative which
found some adherents among populists and nationalists but was discredited by the
outcome of the war. The western European option of social democracy, with its
promise of “incremental” reform, was “too modest for those looking for a radical
solution to the grinding poverty of the poor regions...” The people of these nations
could now “examine the differences between centrally planned socialism and
market capitalism to see which better suited their conditions. Up to then the
principal division of the world had been rich industrial countries and poor agrarian
countries. Now there was a second dimension and two possible paths toward
path to economic transformation – and to many in the developing world, this path
was superior to the one offered by capitalism. “Moscow was not only a more
148
As Hobsbawm (1994:350) notes, “the example of the U.S.S.R. provided an
alternative model of "development." Never did that example look more impressive
than in the years after 1945.”
149
Frieden 2006:275
351
but it also seemed a more suitable model, especially for countries lacking both in
private capital and a large body of private and profit-oriented industry.”150 The
economic appeal of communist institutions in the developing world thus drew from
some of the same sources of strength as its ideological appeal. Leaders in newly-
formed nations “believed only public action could lift their economies out of
following the inspiration of the Soviet Union, they were to see the way forward as
agrarian past through state planning – a process that, moreover, had been stamped
planning did not even require a full-fledged belief in the political ideology of
was adopted first in Latin America during the 1930s and later in newly liberated
colonies in Asia in the 1940s, the Middle East and North Africa in the 1940s and
1950s, and sub-Saharan Africa in the late 1950s and 1960s.152 This strategy implied
direct investment, and an active industrial policy that promoted domestic markets.
In Asia and Africa, with little native manufacturing, local industries needed even
150
Hobsbawm 1994:376. He notes that some ex-colonies adopted Soviet economic
planning without necessarily embracing its political program.
151
Hobsbawm 1994:177
152
Frieden 2006:320
352
more protection and encouragement from the state than in Latin America. In these
that approached the Soviet Union in its scope. India, for example, “emulated
aspects of Soviet planning, using a series of five-year plans to guide the country's
and 1964 and had spent time in the USSR during the 1920s, encouraged extensive
state investment in manufacturing. Between 1951 and 1966, during the country’s
three five-years plans, the state accounted for half of all industrial investment. In
Egypt, after Nasser’s socialist government took control in the 1952 revolution, the
state nationalized the country’s banks and insurance companies as well as most
industry (the state owned ninety percent of factories employing more than ten
workers, and accounted for nearly half of industrial output and a third of the labor
force.155
chance for survival lay in coexisting with the nationalist sentiment,” wrote Furet.
153
Frieden 2006:318
154
Frieden 2006:314
155
Frieden 2006:318
353
But by the late 1940s, “it had exhausted the credit it had drawn from the
generalized hatred of Germany. It was all very well for Soviet propaganda to
denounce the allegedly vengeful West Germans, but the time had passed when
like the Red Army.”156 Just as Communist expansion rolled to a stop in Eastern
Europe against the borders of American infuence, the developing world “now
became the central pillar of the hope and faith of those who still put their faith in
erupt, a seismic field whose tremors announced the major earthquakes to come.”157
years following the war. But as the attraction of Communism faded, and the Soviet
Union’s capacity to coerce more governments into its mold had been contained,
the wave crested. The communist bloc “showed no sign of significant expansion
between the Chinese revolution and the 1970s,” by which point China had split
from the Soviet Union.158 There were several more expansions of the communist
world, notably in Cuba in 1959 and Africa in the 1970s, “but substantially the
156
Furet 1999:410
157
Hobsbawm 1994:436
158
Hobsbawm 1994:227-8
159
Hobsbawm 1994:373
354
Europe served as an example of how a rising hegemon can take advantage of the
democratic liberties in the history of the world,” argued Samuel Huntington, “came
influence, and emulation – but in the case of Western Europe direct coercion
played a much less prominent role. This did not necessarily imply a more benign
motivation on the part of the United States. First, its economy was in far better
shape than the Soviet Union’s, giving it more room to use financial incentives to
convert countries into its camp. Second, it faced a different set of motivations in
doing so. Both superpowers sought followers to legitimize the universalist nature of
their respective regimes. But beyond that basic goal, they had a very different set of
concerns and priorities. Unlike the Soviet Union, the U.S. did not seek a protective
security buffer, within which the incentives of the populace would take a back seat
to the necessity for a cordon sanitaire governed by pliable, unquestioning and loyal
regimes. The United States emerged from the war with a large and competitive
to the 1930s, and in Europe it saw a large potential market for its wares.161 Its
physical security was assured; but its economic well-being depended on securing
export markets. A European dollar shortage prevented the continent from buying
160
Huntington 1982:26
161
Frieden 2006:262
355
American goods, endangering the recovery and opening the way to Communist-led
discontent.162 America’s turn outward after 1945 can thus be explained as much by
its rise in power (and the corresponding decline of its former rivals) as by the
determination to avoid the turmoil of the interwar years or fear of Soviet power.
The price for its unmatched dominance was a danger of diminished export
destinations. American officials agreed, noted the historian Melvyn Leffler, that
materials, and the rehabilitation of much-if not all-of Eurasia along liberal capitalist
lines."163
Coercion, of course, was not entirely absent from the spread of democracy. The
U.S. occupied Germany, and Japan. Particularly in the latter two cases, the U.S.
institutions. As the title of a 1957 book declared, these countries were “forced to be
free.”164 With the partial exception of South Korea, Huntington writes, “where
was the most direct way in which the United States wielded its influence. The U.S.
162
Victoria de Grazia (2005) Irresistible Empire: America’s Advance through
Twentieth-Century Europe, Harvard University Press, p. 346. As she explains, “This
shortfall was blamed on the trade gap between the two areas, which in turn was
blamed on Europe's perennially flagging economic output.” The first goal of U.S.
aid was therefore to raise productivity through investments in industrial
infrastructure (power plants, electric grids, ports and the like).
163
Melvyn P. Leffler (1984) "The American Conception of National Security and the
Beginning of the Cold War, 1945-48," American Historical Review 89.2, p. 349-56.
Quoted in Ikenberry 2001:180
164
John D. Montgomery (1957) Forced To Be Free: The Artificial Revolution in
Germany and Japan, University of Chicago Press
165
Huntington 1982:26
356
established bases and stationed military personnel throughout Western Europe. Its
military authorities made crucial decisions about institutional reforms and policies,
Other means of influence were less direct. The CIA, for example, funded the
Christian Democrats in the 1948 Italian election to help ensure their victory over
the left-wing Popular Democratic Front and the Italian Socialist Party.167 While
Europe, Ikenberry notes that the U.S. “did attempt to use its material resources to
pressure and induce Britain and the other industrial democracies to abandon
payments.” Aid was tied to specific conditions that conformed to policies pursued
by the U.S. For example, an (ultimately failed) 1946 agreement “obliged the British
States knew it held a commanding position and sought to use its power to give the
Still, outside of Germany and Japan, influence rather than coercion was the
166
Even so, Vinen argues, its power to coerce was self-limited. “Even in Germany
in 1945, the American army was subject to the constraint of a civilian government
and the rule of law.” (Vinen 2000:259)
167
“We had bags of money that we delivered to selected politicians, to defray their
political expenses, their campaign expenses, for posters, for pamphlets," a CIA
operative told CNN in a 1998 documentary. The New York Times (2006) “F. Mark
Wyatt, 86, C.I.A. Officer, Is Dead”, July 6. A secret CIA report detailing these
activities was presented to the Pike Committee in 1975 and appeared in their
report, published two years later.
168
Ikenberry 2001:200
357
order of the day in Europe. “The United States spent little of its hegemonic power
trying to coerce and induce other governments to buy into American rules and
institutions,” notes Ikenberry. “It spent much more time and resources trying to
create the conditions under which postwar European governments and publics
would remain moderate and pro-Western.”169 The Truman Doctrine and the
Marshall Plan were the two primary instruments for creating these favorable
conditions. Both were announced in the spring of 1947, and both sought to assert
American leadership while rolling back the spread of communist regimes. (Other
scale; these included the CIA, private corporations, and U.S. trade unions.)170
Officially, only Turkey and Greece would receive American assistance, but
Truman’s address committed the United States to helping all “free peoples” of the
aid”.171 Following the announcement of the Truman doctrine, the U.S. used foreign
help national elites resist Communist pressure (military aid comprised 95 percent of
169
Ikenberry 2001:202
170
Vinen 2000:260
171
See Public Papers of the Presidents of the United States - Harry S. Truman, 1
January to 3I December I947 (Washington, 1963), PP.176-80, for the full text of
Truman’s speech. For a discussion of how the Truman Doctrine signaled an
unprecedented U.S. involvement in global politics, see Michael Cox and Caroline
Kennedy-Pipe (2005) “The Tragedy of American Diplomacy? Rethinking the
Marshall Plan” Cold War Studies 7.1:97-134.
172
Westad 2005:26
358
visit to Europe, became the most prominent way in which the United States
exercised its influence and promoted liberal democratic regimes in the years
institutional model. By the end of the program in 1952, the United States had spent
$13 billion, more than all previous American foreign aid put together. Germany,
Britain and France received the largest absolute amount, but for smaller countries
like Italy and Austria it amounted to a larger relative share of the economy
(between July 1948 and June 1949, 14 percent of Austria’s income came from
Marshall Aid).173 In some of these smaller states, the aid amounted to more than a
The largest impact of the Marshall Plan resided not with the amount of the
disbursements but with the conditions attached to them. Along with collaborators
in western Europe, U.S. aid officials sought to prevent national politicians “from
economies.”175 In doing so, Marshall aid nudged center-left parties toward social
argued in 1946: "It is definitely in the interest of the United States to see that the
present left movement throughout the world, which we should recognize and even
173
Judt 2005:91. In 2009 dollars, the aid amounted to about $113 billion.
174
Frieden 2006:268
175
de Grazia 2005:345-6
359
zones. “U.S. policymakers knew the Kremlin was not the cause of postwar
turbulence, but they feared that Moscow would exploit it,” writes Christopher
Layne. “In particular, Washington feared that Communist parties would come to
The push for democratic regimes in Western Europe was never explicitly
of American influence was neither productive nor necessary for achieving its goals,
American aid and protection that any insensitive pressure from that quarter would
document from 1946 put it, pro-American policy in Italy “would be a judicious
not be a one-shot cure, but should consist of a kind word, a loaf of bread, a public
176
Quoted in Ikenberry 2001:202
177
Ikenberry 2001:202
178
Layne 2006:56
179
Judt 2005:97
360
tribute to Italian civilization, then another kind word, and so on, with an
occasional plug from the sponsors advertising the virtues of democracy American
style.”180 As befitting the purposes of the plan, countries with strong communist
parties received the most generous financial assistance. The attempts by Ireland to
secure Marshall aid funds, on the other hand, were “undermined by the fact that
In short, the Marshall Plan “was an economic program but the crisis it averted
was political.”182 As Kennedy notes, “it took no genius to see that the raison d'etre
for the plan was to convince Europeans everywhere that private enterprise was
better able to bring them prosperity than communism.”183 Indeed, the impact of
by Soviet forces, who still occupied the eastern half of the country) “never made
any dent in the popularity of Americans and their aid,” notes Judt. “[T]he latter put
food in people's mouths and this was what mattered most.” In Greece, the $649
million in aid extended in the spring of 1948 “made the difference between
survival and destitution.” It “supported refugees and staved off hunger and disease,”
and provided half of the country’s gross national product in 1950.184 Across Europe,
180
A State Department document from 1946; quoted in John Lamberton Harper
(1986) American Influence and the Reconstruction of Italy, 1945-1948, Cambridge
University Press, p.109; quoted in Vinen 2000:258
181
Vinen 2000:259
182
Judt 2005:97
183
Kennedy 1987:377
184
Judt 2005:96
361
providing a means for general economic recovery. Economic growth surged in the
second half of the 1940s, inaugurating a golden age for western Europe that lasted
for the following two decades. Dutch industrial and agricultural production
surpassed 1938 levels by 1948, while France, Austria and Italy reached the same
The democratic wave in western Europe was built on a desire for postwar
stability and (in some cases) a history of democratic government, but it was made
political and economic) in the years immediately following the war. In pursuing the
communism beyond the Elbe. But the economic and geopolitical success of the
around the world whose leaders sought to capture a piece of American largesse,
ingratiate themselves into the emerging institutional infrastructure, and emulate the
185
Judt 2005:96. See also Kennedy 1987:377 for a similar appraisal.
362
Latin America and (to a lesser extent) to Asia. In neither region was
democratization was in some cases short-lived, lacking the structural domestic pre-
conditions or U.S. support for democratic leaders. As the Cold War went into full
swing, democratic institutions took a back seat to stability and loyalty to U.S.
interests.
In the few years immediately following the war, however, a number of states
Europe, coercion was an element of the wave, most prominently in Japan but to a
lesser degree is South Korea. The American occupation of Japan, which lasted from
1945, General MacArthur ordered the abrogation of the Peace Preservation of Law
of 1925, which had been used to arrest and silence critics of the government.
Higher Police (sometimes known as the “thought police”) was dissolved, and
political prisoners were released from jail. The Japanese cabinet resigned in protest,
but a week later the new premier Shidehara Kijuro, “met MacArthur for the first
time and received a succinct order that made the previous directive seem mild.”
The government was ordered to promote liberal education in schools and labor
After 1947, gnawing fear of communist influence in Japan led U.S. occupation
immediately after the end of the war. While democratic institutions survived, in this
pattern Japan mirrored the trajectory of many developing states in the postwar
years. As long as cooperation with the Soviet Union was possible, democratization
became the first priority. But as the confrontation hardened, “protecting” countries
Harvey put it, when forced to choose between democracy and stability “the US
always opted for the latter.”188 Less than two years after his election in July 1948,
South Korean president Syngman Rhee began assuming dictatorial powers in a fight
against communism, backed by the United States. The Korean War allowed him to
consolidate his grip on power, and a democracy was not introduced in South Korea
186
John Dower (1999) Embracing Defeat: Japan in the Wake of World War II, W.W.
Norton & Company, p.81
187
The voting age was lowered from 25 to 20, and the total electorate had more
than doubled. Roberts 1999:517
188
David Harvey (2003) The New Imperialism, Oxford University Press, 2003, p.
39-40. Quoted in Kathleen Weekley (2006) “The National or the Social? Problems
of Nation-Building in Post-World War II Philippines” Third World Quarterly 27.1,
p.90
364
until 1987.189 As Fareed Zakaria notes, “after brief flirtations with democracy after
The same scenario was played out in Latin America with a marginally better
rate of success. In fact, the postwar wave of democracy in Latin America represents
American development. The first stage, which took place between 1944 and 1946,
and elections with high levels of participation. In the second phase, which spanned
the years between 1946 and 1948, democracy suffered setbacks as the upper
classes and military leaders, alarmed by the political gains made by the lower and
the onset of the Cold War made stability and anti-Communism a higher priority
than democratization.
reforms, via both popular rebellions and elite reforms. Suffrage was expanded in
Colombia, Brazil, and Peru. Though it was not always universal, since literacy
qualifications excluded people in poor rural areas, postwar suffrage was in general
more democratic than in the 1920s. Ecuador and Costa Rica also turned to
democracy in the late 1940s, as did (briefly) Bolivia. In Argentina, Colombia, Peru
189
Although Huntington optimistically argues that throughout the mid-1950s, “a
moderately democratic system was maintained.” Huntington 1982:30
190
Fareed Zakaria (1997) “The Rise of Illiberal Democracy” Foreign Affairs 76.6, p.
27
365
“popularly chosen governments.”191 Venezuela held the country’s first free election
inaugurating the country’s first experience with democracy (until a military coup
d’etat a year later.) A popular uprising in Guatemala in July 1944 brought the
removal of the thirteen-year dictatorship of Jorge Ubico. Brazil carried out its “first
Getulio Vargas announced electoral reforms earlier that year. In the same year,
and Juan Peron, a large (several hundred thousand strong) demonstration in the
revolt removed the nationalist military government in the summer of 1946 and
In short, as one observer noted in 1946, the last year of the war and its
191
Huntington 1991:18. The inclusion of Argentina is debatable, although the
country did expand suffrage. For instance, between 1943 and 1946 Peron’s
government shut down 110 publications. David Williams Foster, Melissa Fitch
Lockhart, Darrell B. Lockhart (1998) Culture and Customs of Argentina,
Greenwood Publishing Group, p. 62. Peter Smith does not include it among his list
of countries that belonged to the second wave in Latin America - Costa Rica,
Venezuela, Bolivia, Brazil, Peru, and Ecuador. Peter Smith (2005) Democracy in
Latin America: Political Change in Comparative Perspective, Oxford University
press, p.32
192
Leslie Bethell and Ian Roxborough (1992) Latin America Between the Second
World War and the Cold War, 1944-1948, Cambridge University Press, p.5
366
countries than perhaps in any single year since the Wars of Independence.”193 By
mid-1946, only five governments in the region “could not claim to be in some
as the driving force for the region’s postwar democratization. After 1944, “the
Soledad Laoeza.195 “The second democratic wave across South America was
essentially the result of the Allied victory in the Second World War,” argues George
Philip.196 The American victory in the war and its dramatic rise to superpower status
193
William Ebenstein (1946) “Political and Social Thought in Latin America” in
Arthur P. Whitaker, ed., Inter-American Affairs 1945, New York, p.137. Quoted in
Bethell and Roxborough 1992:5
194
Bethell and Roxborough 1992:5.
195
Soledad Loaeza (2009) “Too close for conflict: Mexican authoritarianism as a
response to US power, 1944-1949” Paper Presented at the 2009 APSA Annual
Meeting. Toronto, Canada, September 3-6, 2009, p.2
196
George Philip (1996) “Democratic Institutions in South America: Comparative
and Historical Perspectives” Third World Quarterly 17.4:713. On this point, see
also Paul W. Drake (1989) “Debt and Democracy in Latin America, 1920s-1980s”
in Barbara Stallings and Robert Kaufman, eds., Debt and Democracy in Latin
America, Westview Press.
367
chapter. (During the war Washington began to withdraw its support of authoritarian
governments in the region – support that returned with the onset of the Cold War.)
leading to “the widespread hope for a postwar bonanza.”197 Finally, the democratic
a general spirit of political liberalization. As Hal Brand notes, starting with the
Atlantic Charter in 1951 the notion of a New Deal for the world “had a
that period. Internal pressures and external encouragement came together between
ambitiousness varied from country to country, but the general trend was
unmistakable.”198
As in Asia, however, these democratic gains were not consolidated. “The new
order was fragile, though, and as it turned out, temporary.”199 Not a single country
197
Paul W. Drake (1994) “International Factors in Democratization” paper
presented at the Center for Advanced Study in the Social Sciences, Juan March
Institute, Madrid (November 4, 1994), p.5
198
Hal Brands (2010) Latin America’s Cold War, Harvard University Press, p.13-14.
As he notes, “In Guatemala and El Salvador demonstrators read from the UN
charter. Honduran protestors invoked the Four Freedoms and the Atlantic Charter
and wore headscarves bearing the UN emblem.”
199
Brands 2010:14
200
Philip 1996:713
368
decade following 1946, anti-democratic domestic forces violently pushed back any
gains made in the wake of the war. The region’s economic and military elites felt
severely threatened by reforms that tended to empower the lower and middle
classes, and by the end of the decade “the conservative classes mobilized to check
The political evolution of Mexico between 1944 and 1949 provides a typical
example. Between 1944 and 1946 the government of Avila Camacho introduced a
number of major reforms. The military was pushed out of politics and electoral
system and “the beginning of a new age for Mexico, characterized by civilian
These reforms were taken to “prepare the country to meet the challenges of a new
war transformation of the United States” to superpower status.203 But as the Cold
War ramped up, U.S. priorities shifted toward encouraging domestic stability.
201
Brands 2010:14
202
Loaeza 2009:13
203
Loaeza 2009:3-4
369
the nation’s official party. The single-party state had returned, and the moment of
after the war as part of the general trend of democratization in the region. Given the
conservative nature of the country’s domestic politics, it was World War II that
But the later years of the decade marked a period of reversal for the women’s
exclusion of their progressive elements. With Chile’s lurch to the right in 1947, “the
liability by the centrist and right-wing women’s groups. They now began to exclude
the leftist feminists. These internal conflicts eventually led to the dissolution of the
women’s movement.”205
The rise and decline of the Chilean women’s movement was thus intimately
linked to shifts in the international system. As elsewhere, the end of the war led to a
while the onset of the Cold War and the reassertion of power by right-wing elites
ruptured the fragile alliances that were forged in the early period.
204
Corinne Antezana-Pernet (1994) “Peace in the World and Democracy at Home:
The Chilean Women’s Movement in the 1940s” in David Rock, ed., Latin America
in the 1940s: War and Postwar Transitions, University of California Press, p.166-7
205
Antezana-Pernet 1994:167
370
In sum, the postwar reforms in Latin America, driven by the American victory
internal dynamics, the reassertion of power by the region’s elites, and the onset of
the Cold War pushed the wave back and reversed many of these democratic gains.
Conclusion
The postwar redistribution of power, while not the only catalyst for domestic
transformations, influenced many of the regime reforms that took place in the war’s
aftermath. The hegemonic shock that discredited the fascist alternative and
replaced an ailing multipolar system with a bipolar one also had a momentous
impact on the evolution of regimes in many countries around the world. The
and spurred a number of followers, most notably in China but also in a number of
developing countries in Asia, Africa and the Middle East. In Latin America, too,
communist and socialist powers temporarily increased in popularity after the war,
region’s rightward turn later in the decade. “Stalin had emerged from his victory
over Hitler far stronger than ever before,” writes Judt, “basking in the reflected glory
of ‘his’ Red Army, at home and abroad.”206 As Raymond Aron noted in 1944,
communism “profits from and will go on profiting from the enormous prestige
reflected on the Soviet regime and people by the victories of the Russian armies.”207
206
Judt 2005:174
207
Aron 1944/2002:194
371
The United States also greatly increased in influence and prestige in the years
in Latin America. Both countries used its military might to impose their own
regimes on others through coercion (though the Soviet Union came to rely on force
to a greater extent than the United States). Both countries used their economic
influence to exert political pressure and encourage other states to copy their
institutions (and here the roles were reversed, with the U.S. relying on its economic
prowess more than the recovering Soviet Union). Both countries benefited from the
prestige endowed to them by their victory and the emulation it inspired in leaders
and movements around the world. Both created and used international institutions
regimes. Here the record was mixed. The communist regimes in eastern Europe
manifesting itself in brutal invasions to put down attempts at reform – “tanks before
teatime” in the case of the 1968 Prague Spring. When the source of that coercion
was removed with the changes in Gorbachev’s foreign policy, the regimes
collapsed like a house of cards. In the case of the United States, democratic
ensured economic revival and political stability. Yet states in Latin America failed
372
to sustain their brief move toward democracy in the mid-1940s. Once again, the
waves. In the latter, consolidation was secured through continuous military force;
in the former, a democratic overstretch produced a wave that was bound to roll
back as the incentives and opportunities associated with the hegemonic shock
Chapter 6
“We see long dim vistas stretching in many directions of the forest,
but of none can we descry the end.”
-- James Bryce (1921)1
“There was no certainty; only the appeal to that mocking oracle they called
History, who gave her sentence only when the jaws of the appealer
had long since fallen to dust.”
-- Arthur Koestler (1941)2
As this dissertation has argued, the twentieth century has been shaped by a series of
confrontations between great powers, and the competing visions of the state
1
James Bryce (1921) Modern Democracies Vol.1, p.11
2
Arthur Koestler (1941/2006) Darkness at Noon, transl. by Daphne Hardy, New
York: Scribner
3
E.M. Forster (1951/1976) “What I believe” in Two Cheers for Democracy,
Penguin Books, p.84
374
what a modern state ought to look like. In this they are, to borrow Marx’s
description of revolution, the midwives of history. The period between 1919 and
1991 marked a series of struggles between the three modern conceptions of the
state. Each culminated with a shock to the political landscape, each shock leaving
piecemeal and often unsuccessful, but the very undertaking showcased the brief
power of the rising hegemon in the immediate aftermath of the shock. World War I
set the stage by marking the last breath of the monarchical empires of eastern and
central Europe. Around the world, the war’s outcome signaled the end of monarchy
as a model for development, and – for a brief moment – thrust democracy into the
But the disappointing and tentative aftermath of the war led to a search for new
alternatives. Its outcome displayed a “total lack of consensus among the three great
victors about the new international order they were imposing,” writes Furet. “At
ends, or even its means.”4 The Great War not only opened an opportunity for a
Communist ascent in one of the ailing empires, but also planted the seed for a
fascist revolt against the shortcomings of liberal democracy. Democracy was the
war’s short-lived offspring, but communism and fascism were its enduring progeny.
These challengers – the two “great totalitarian temptations” of the century, in the
4
Furet 1999:58-9
375
words of Fritz Stern5 – offered alternative paths to modernity that at various points
Yet less than five decades after helping democracy expunge the fascist
alternative, communism itself left the world stage with a quiet implosion. Both
challengers exited from the world stage defeated, discredited, and ready to adopt
the institutions of their former rival. Neither fulfilled its self-appointed destiny to
forge a new world on the ruins of the old. “Today it is hard to realize that they are
such recent ideologies,” writes Furet, “for they seem outmoded, absurd, deplorable,
century.”6
enhancements and extensions of the theory. The most obvious is expanding the
universe of cases to include the last hegemonic shock of the twentieth century – the
Soviet collapse. The analysis of this shock can help shed some light not only on the
wave of democratization in the mid-1990s, but also on the rise of hybrid regimes
since that period. As the post-Soviet democratic wave crested and subsided, a
5
Stern 1997:21
6
Furet 1999:23
376
particularly multi-party elections, but as Levitsky and Way put it, these are
rulers faced real electoral challenges, “despite the opposition contesting a lopsided
political arena.”
pointed out, some autocratic regimes in the 1960s and 1970s also incorporated
7
Brownlee 2009:518
8
Steven Levitsky and Lucan A. Way (2002) “The Rise of Competitive
Authoritarianism” Journal of Democracy 13.2, p.53. See also Steven Levitsky and
Lucan A. Way (2010) Competitive Authoritarianism: Hybrid Regimes After the Cold
War, Cambridge University Press. Earlier writings on hybrid regimes include Fareed
Zakaria (1997) “The Rise of Illiberal Democracy.” Foreign Affairs 76.6: 22-43;
Thomas Carothers (2002) “The End of the Transition Paradigm” Journal of
Democracy 13.1:5-21; Larry Diamond (2002) “Thinking About Hybrid Regimes”
Journal of Democracy 13.2:21-35; Andreas Schedler (2002) “The Menu of
Manipulation” Journal of Democracy 13.2:36-50; Marina Ottaway (2003)
Democracy Challenged: The Rise of Semi-Authoritarianism. Washington, DC:
Carnegie Endowment for International Peace. Later writings include Andreas
Schedler, ed. (2006) Electoral Authoritarianism: The Dynamics of Unfree
Competition, Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner; Marc Morjé Howard and Philip G.
Roessler (2006) “Liberalizing Electoral Outcomes in Competitive Authoritarian
Regimes” American Journal of Political Science 50.2:365- 81; Jason Brownlee
(2009) “Portents of Pluralism: How Hybrid Regimes Affect Democratic Transitions”
American Journal of Political Science 53.3:515-532
377
As Schedler noted:
The sheer number of these regimes is also unique in the history of political
elections.11 By the end of the century it was becoming clear that these hybrid
regimes were a new and stable form of modern autocracy rather than a transitional
stage.12
The Soviet collapse created a powerful motivation for autocrats to adopt the
formal institutions associated with democracy. As Levitsky and Way note, “Western
alternative regime models and created strong incentives for peripheral states to
middle class, poverty, and absence of civil society all contributed to these
9
Diamond 2002:23-4
10
Schedler 2002:361
11
Schedler 2002:47
12
Levitsky and Way 2002:52; Brownlee 2009:517
13
Levitsky and Way 2002:61
378
the results of failed democratic transitions sparked by the Soviet collapse. A study
of the post-Soviet wave could help illuminate the dynamics that led to emergence
The universe of cases need not be confined to the twentieth century. I have
Hedley Bull’s definition, “sufficient contact between them, and have sufficient
measure – as parts of a whole.”14 By these criteria, Bull argues a world system did
not really emerge until World War One. “Throughout human history before the
nineteenth century there was no single political system that spanned the world as a
whole.” But since the late nineteenth century, “order on a global scale has ceased
to be simply the sum of the various political systems that produce order on a local
scale; it is also the product of what may be called a world political system.”15
system” of “world-wide scope” a decade before World War I.16 “From World War I
onward,” writes Tilly, “it becomes increasingly difficult to separate the European
14
Hedley Bull (1977/2003) The Anarchical Society: A Study of Order in World
Politics, 3rd ed, Columbia University Press, p.9
15
Bull 1977/2003:19-20
16
Harold Mackinder (1904) “The Geographical Pivot of History” The Geographical
Journal 23.4, p.422. “Every explosion of social forces,” he wrote, “will be sharply
re-echoed from the far side of the globe…” Mackinder 1904:422
379
system from the world system of states that was forming rapidly.”17
But even if the world was not a unified system until World War I, the study of
hegemonic shocks does not require a global unit of analysis. By the earlier
definition, Europe had become its own state system at the end of the 17th century if
not before. The hegemonic shock of the Napoleonic Wars and its reverberations
throughout Europe thus offers another case study of an early institutional wave. As
Furet notes, the clash between revolutionary France and monarchical Europe
“initiated the era of democratic war”.18 For decades before the French revolution,
statesmen warned that it would become necessary to bring the majority of the
population under the control of the state, to replace patronage with centralized
authority mediated by the rule of law and financed by a far-reaching tax system.
The revolution confronted European rulers with these facts. At its peak, Napoleonic
France “looked like a country where modern representative institutions, the rule of
patriotism and effectiveness on the battlefield,” writes Hosking. And while this
republican institutions during the wars was partially reversed by the Holy Alliance,
17
Charles Tilly (1990) Coercion, Capital, and European States, AD 990-1992,
Blackwell, p. 179. Likewise, Schweller describes the creation of the international
system as a process that “subsumed the entire earth, such that nothing remained
outside of it. This process began roughly one hundred years ago, after the Age of
Discovery that witnessed European expansion across the oceans to new lands.”
Randall L. Schweller (2010) “Ennui Becomes Us” The National Interest 105, p.28
18
Furet 1999:48
19
Geoffrey Hosking (2001) Russia and the Russians: A History, Belknap Press of
Harvard University Press, p.240-241
380
but the lessons of popular mobilization for democratic reforms remained in place.
After a century of relative peace during which European energy was directed
The analysis of shocks and their effects on domestic reforms can also be
***
defeated its challengers. The number of democracies around the world stood at an
all-time high. Yet since 1995, and despite occasional outbursts, the level of
democracy in the world appears to have reached a Great Plateau. And after a
period of unchallenged unipolarity during the 1990s, the hegemon that has
embodied democracy around the world once again finds itself facing the prospect
of a new ideological struggle over the prevailing archetype of a modern state. The
Great Recession that began in 2008 revived the possibility of a search for
20
Azar Gat (2007) “The Return of Authoritarian Great Powers” Foreign Affairs
86.4:59-69; Joshua Kurlantzick (2008) “State Inc” The Boston Globe, March 16;
Joshua Kurlantzick (2008) “Democracy on the Wane” The Boston Globe,
381
shocks can tell us anything about the future, it’s the fact that a gradual Chinese
ascent poses a much lesser challenge to liberal democracy than a sudden rise of
relative Chinese power. The greatest danger facing the future of democracy is
therefore a sudden decline in American power, influence, and prestige. For better
or for worse, the future of democracy is tied to the future of American power.
Far from being buried in the old struggles of the past century, the lessons of
regime promotion by external means. As the case of World War I demonstrates, the
Europe contributed to the collapse of new democracies and paved the way for the
rise of fascism in the 1930s. Those mistakes were corrected in the settlement
following World War II. Yet during the Cold War American foreign policy had an
September 14; Larry Diamond (2008) The Spirit of Democracy: The Struggle to
Build Free Societies Throughout the World, Basic Books; Larry Diamond (2008)
“The Democratic Rollback: The Resurgence of the Predatory State” Foreign Affairs
87.2:36-48; Ian Bremmer (2009) “State Capitalism Comes of Age: The End of the
Free Market?” Foreign Affairs 88.3:40-55; Marcus Walker (2009) “After the Wall: A
Debate Over Democracy's Reach” Wall Street Journal - Eastern Edition, October
29, p. A17; Azar Gat (2009) Victorious and Vulnerable: Why Democracy Won in
the 20th Century and How it is Still Imperiled, Rowman & Littlefield; Stefan Halper
(2010) The Beijing Consensus: How China’s Authoritarian Model Will Dominate the
Twenty-First Century, Basic Books. See Wolfgang Merkel (2010) “Are Dictatorships
Returning? Revisiting the ‘democratic rollback’ hypothesis” Contemporary Politics
16.1:17-31 for a dissent.
382
international system shape this development will remain an important aspect of the
in contemporary foreign policy, the causes and dynamics of democratic waves can
provide important insights into the effectiveness of these policies, whether they are
pursued through sanctions, foreign aid, or forced regime change. Policies that
actors inside any single country if domestic reforms are embedded in a larger
The lessons of hegemonic shocks also warn against the triumphalist reading of
economic crises and to emerge triumphant in their wake. When democracies fail to
do so, as during the Great Depression, the tide of popular and elite opinion shifts
BIBLIOGRAPHY
Mike Alvarez, Jose Antonio Cheibub, Fernando Limongi and Adam Przeworski (1996) “Classifying
Political Regimes” Studies in Comparative International Development 31.2:3-36
Corinne Antezana-Pernet (1994) “Peace in the World and Democracy at Home: The Chilean
Women’s Movement in the 1940s” in David Rock, ed., Latin America in the 1940s: War and
Postwar Transitions, University of California Press
Federigo Argentieri (2007) “Hungary: Dealing with the Past and Moving into the Present” p.215-231
in Sharon L. Wolchik and Jane L. Curry, eds., Central and East European Politics: From Communism
to Democracy, Rowman and Littlefield
Raymond Aron (2002) The Dawn of Universal History: Selected Essays from a Witness to the
Twentieth Century, Basic Books, transl. by Barbara Bray
Leonard P. Ayres (1919) The War with Germany: A Statistical Summary. Washington DC:
Government Printing Office.
Walter Bagehot (1874/1965) Bagehot’s Historical Essays, ed. Norman St. John-Stevas, New York:
Anchor Books
William J. Bernstein (2008) A Splendid Exchange: How Trade Shaped the World, New York:
Atlantic Monthly Press
J. Samuel Barkin and Bruce Cronin (1994) “The State and the Nation: Changing Norms and the
Rules of Sovereignty in International Relations” International Organization 48.1:107-130.
Michael Barnett and Raymond Duvall (2005) “Power in International Politics” International
Organization 59.1:39-75
Jacques Barzun (2000) From Dawn to Decadence: 500 Years of Western Cultural Life from 1500 to
the Present, Harper Perennial
384
Orit Bashkin (2008) The other Iraq: pluralism and culture in Hashemite Iraq, Stanford University
Press
Charles Beard (1927) “Democracy Holds its Ground” Harper’s Magazine, November, p.680-91
George Louis Beer (1916) “America's International Responsibilities and Foreign Policy” Annals of the American
Academy of Political and Social Science, Vol.66:71-91
Mark R. Beissinger (2007) “Structure and Example in Modular Political Phenomena: The Diffusion of
Bulldozer/Rose/Orange/Tulip Revolutions” Perspectives on Politics 5:259-76
Felix Berenskoetter and M.J. Williams, eds. (2007) Power in World Politics, Routledge
Sheri Berman (2006) The Primacy of Politics: Social Democracy and the Making of Europe’s
Twentieth Century, Cambridge University Press
Nancy Bermeo (1997) “Getting Mad or Going Mad? Citizens, Scarcity and the Breakdown of
Democracy in Interwar Europe” Center for the Study of Democracy, paper 97.06
Marver H. Bernstein (1957) “Review: The Appeal of Communism in Arab Countries” World Politics
9.4
Leslie Bethell and Ian Roxborough (1992) Latin America Between the Second World War and the
Cold War, 1944-1948, Cambridge University Press
Cyprian Blamires, Paul Jackson (2006) World Fascism: A Historical Encyclopedia, Vol.1, ABC-Clio
Philip Bobbitt (2003) The Shield of Achilles: War, Peace, and the Course of History, Anchor Press
Gustave Le Bon (1921) The World in Revolt: A Psychological Study of Our Times, transl. by Bernard
Miall, New York: The Macmillan Company
M.J. Bonn (1920) “The Main Features of Germany’s Economic and Financial Situation” Annals of the American
Academy of Political and Social Science, Vol.92:106-11
Alan Booth (1999) “The British Reaction” in W.R. Garside, ed., Capitalism in Crisis: An International
Perspective on the 1930s, Palgrave Macmillan
Hal Brands (2010) Latin America’s Cold War, Harvard University Press
Daniel Brinks and Michael Coppedge (2006) “Diffusion Is No Illusion: Neighbor Emulation in the
Third Wave of Democracy” Comparative Political Studies 39:463-89
Jason Brownlee (2009) “Portents of Pluralism: How Hybrid Regimes Affect Democratic Transitions”
American Journal of Political Science 53.3:515-532
Robert W. Bruere (1917) “Can Democracy Be Efficient?” Harper’s Magazine 195.2 (May), p.821-26
385
William Brunstein and Marit Berntson (1999) “Interwar Fascist Popularity in Europe and the Default
of the Left” European Sociological Review 15.2: 159-178
Bruce Bueno de Mesquita, Randolph Siverson, Gary Woller (1992) “War and the Fate of Regimes: A
Comparative Analysis” American Political Science Review 93.4:638-46
Bruce Bueno de Mesquita, Alastair Smith, Randolph M. Siverson, and James D. Morrow (2003) The
Logic of Political Survival, MIT Press
Bruce Bueno de Mesquita and George W. Downs (2006) “Intervention and Democracy”
International Organization 60:627-49
Hedley Bull (1977/2003) The Anarchical Society: A Study of Order in World Politics, 3rd ed,
Columbia University Press
Walter Dean Burnham (1999) "Constitutional Moments and Punctuated Equilibria" Yale Law Review
108: 2237-77
Abraham Cahan (1917) “Living Landmarks of the Russian Revolution” Harper’s Magazine, June, p.
47-56
Charles Cameron (2010) “What is Political Science” in Andrew Gelman and Jeronimo Cortina, eds.,
A Quantitative Tour of the Social Sciences, Cambridge University Press
Giovanni Capoccia (2005) Defending Democracy: Reactions to Extremism in Interwar Europe, Johns
Hopkins University Press
Thomas Carothers (2002) “The End of the Transition Paradigm” Journal of Democracy 13.1:5-21
E.H. Carr (1939/1964) The Twenty Years Crisis: 1919-1939, Harper Perennial
F.L. Carsten (1972) Revolution in Central Europe: 1918-1919, University of California Press
Emilio Casetti (2008) “The Long-Run Dynamic of the Nexus between Military Strength and National
Power: An Econometric Analysis” Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society vol. 2008, p.1-19
Chicago Daily Tribune (1933) “Democracy Giving Way to New Government Plan, Says Ogburn”,
August 26, p. 4
David Collier and Robert Adcock (1999) “Democracy and Dichotomies: A Pragmatic Approach to
Choices about Concepts” Annual Review of Political Science 2: 537-565
David Collier and John Gerring, eds. (2009) Concepts and Method in Social Science, Routledge
David Collier and Steven Levitsky (2009) “Democracy: Conceptual Hierarchies in Comparative
Research” in David Collier and John Gerring, eds. Concepts and Method in Social Science,
Routledge
386
Michael Coppedge, Angel Alvarez, Claudia Maldonado (2008) “Two Persistent Dimensions of
Democracy: Contestation and Inclusiveness” The Journal of Politics 70.3, p. 632-647
Michael Cox and Caroline Kennedy-Pipe (2005) “The Tragedy of American Diplomacy? Rethinking
the Marshall Plan” Cold War Studies 7.1:97-134
R. J. Crampton (1997) Eastern Europe in the Twentieth Century – And After, New York: Routledge
Martin van Creveld (1989) Technology and War: From 2000 B.C. to the Present, Free Press
Lloyd Cutler and Herman Schwartz (1991) “Constitutional Reform in Czechoslovakia: E Duobus
Unum?” The University of Chicago Law Review 58.2:511-53
Michael Desch (2002) “Democracy and Victory: Why Regime Type Hardly Matters” International
Security 27.2
Larry Diamond (2002) “Thinking About Hybrid Regimes” Journal of Democracy 13.2:21-35
Larry Diamond (2008) “The Democratic Rollback: The Resurgence of the Predatory State” Foreign
Affairs 87.2:36-48
Larry Diamond (2008) The Spirit of Democracy: The Struggle to Build Free Societies Throughout the
World, Basic Books
Morris Dickstein (2009) Dancing in the Dark: A Cultural History of the Great Depression, W.W.
Norton
John Diggins (1966) “Flirtation with Fascism: American Pragmatic Liberals and Mussolini’s Italy”
American Historical Review 71, p.487-506
Frank R. Dobbin (1993) "The social construction of the Great Depression: Industrial policy during
the 1930s in the United States, Britain, and France" Theory and Society 22.1:1-56
Hristina Dobreva (2006) “Second Image Reversed” Reexamined, Ph.D. dissertation, Simon Frasier
University
Jack Donnely (2006) Realism and International Relations, Cambridge University Press
John Dower (1999) Embracing Defeat: Japan in the Wake of World War II, W.W. Norton &
Company
Brian Downing (1992) The Military Revolution and Political Change: Origins of Democracy and
Autocracy in Early Modern Europe, Princeton University Press
Paul W. Drake (1989) “Debt and Democracy in Latin America, 1920s-1980s” in Barbara Stallings
and Robert Kaufman, eds., Debt and Democracy in Latin America, Westview Press
387
Colin Elman, The logic of emulation: The diffusion of military practices in the international system.
PhD dissertation, Columbia University.
Paul W. Drake (1994) “International Factors in Democratization” paper presented at the Center for
Advanced Study in the Social Sciences, Juan March Institute, Madrid (November 4, 1994)
William Easterly, Shanker Satyanath, and Daniel Berger (2008) “Superpower Interventions and their
Consequences for Democracy: An Empirical Inquiry” NBER Working Paper 13992
The Economist (2009) “Britain between the wars: A sense of dread” April 25, p.86
The Economist (2009) “Review of Joe Moran (2009) On Roads: A Hidden History,” June 20, 2009,
p. 89
Daina Stukuls Eglitis (2007) “The Baltic States: Remembering the Past, Building the Future” p.233-
252 in Sharon L. Wolchik and Jane L. Curry, eds., Central and East European Politics: From
Communism to Democracy, Rowman and Littlefield
Hartmut Elsenhans (1991) “The Great Depression of the 1930s and the Third World” International
Studies 28.3:273-90
Jon Elster (1983) Explaining Technical Change: A Case Study in the Philosophy of Science,
Cambridge University Press
Jon Elster (1984) Ulysses and the Sirens, Cambridge University Press
Jon Elster (1998) “A Plea for Mechanisms” p.45-73 in Peter Hedstrom and Richard Swedberg, eds.,
Social Mechanisms: An Analytical Approach to Social Theory, Cambridge University Press
David L. Epstein, Robert Bates, Jack Goldstone, Ida Kristensen and Sharyn O'Halloran (2006)
“Democratic Transitions” American Journal of Political Science 50.3: 551-569
Richard J. Evans (2004) The Coming of the Third Reich, Penguin Press
Tanisha Fazal (2007) State Death: The Politics and Geography of Conquest, Occupation, and
Annexation, Princeton University Press
P. Fearon (1993) “Hoover, Roosevelt and American economic policy during the 1930s” in W.R.
Garside, ed., Capitalism in Crisis: An International Perspective on the 1930s, Palgrave Macmillan
John A. Ferejohn and Frances McCall Rosenbluth, eds. (2010) War and State Building in Medieval
Japan, Stanford University Press
E.M. Forster (1951/1976) “What I believe” in Two Cheers for Democracy, London: Penguin Books
Lewis S. Feuer (1962) “American Travelers to the Soviet Union, 1917-32: The Formation of a
Component of New Deal Ideology” American Quarterly 14.2:119-49
388
Martha Finnemore and Kathryn Sikkink (1998) “International Norm Dynamics and Political Change”
International Organization 52.4:887-917
Robert Fisk (1990) Pity the Nation: The abduction of Lebanon. New York: Nation Books
Virginia Page Fortna (2008) Does Peacekeeping Work? Shaping Belligerents’ Choices after Civil War,
Princeton University Press
William Fox (1944) The Super-Powers: the United States, Britain, and the Soviet Union—their
responsibility for peace. Harcourt, Brace Co.
Jeffry A. Frieden (2006) Global Capitalism: Its Fall and Rise in the Twentieth Century, W.W. Norton
Jonathan Friedman and Christopher Chase-Dunn, eds. (2005) Hegemonic Declines: Present and
Past, Paradigm Publishers
Francois Furet (1999) The Passing of an Illusion: The Idea of Communism in the Twentieth Century,
University of Chicago Press
John Lewis Gaddis (1992) “International Relations Theory and the End of the Cold War”
International Security 17.3:5-58
John Kenneth Galbraith (1967) The New Industrial State, New York: Houghton Mifflin
Walter Gallie (1956) “Essentially Contested Concepts” Proceedings of the Aristotelian Society
56:167-98
Richard de Gallienne (1919) “Ballade of the Modern Bard” Harper’s Magazine, October, p. 761
W.R. Garside (1993) “The search for stability: economic radicalism and financial conservatism in
1930s Europe” in W.R. Garside, ed., Capitalism in Crisis: An International Perspective on the 1930s,
Palgrave Macmillan
Azar Gat (2007) “The Return of Authoritarian Great Powers” Foreign Affairs 86.4:59-69
Azar Gat (2009) Victorious and Vulnerable: Why Democracy Won in the 20th Century and How it is
Still Imperiled, Rowman & Littlefield
Scott Gates, Håvard Hegre, Mark P. Jones, and Håvard Strand (2006) “Institutional Inconsistency
and Political Instability: Polity Duration, 1800-2000” American Journal of Political Science
50.4:893-908
Scott Gates, Håvard Hegre, Mark P. Jones, Håvard Strand (2007) “Democratic Waves? Global
Patterns of Democratization, 1800-2000,” paper prepared for delivery at the National Political
Science Conference, January 2007, Trondheim, Norway
Barbara Geddes (1999) “What Do We Know About Democratization After Twenty Years?” Annual
Review of Political Science 2:115-44
Israel Gershoni and James Jankowski (2009) Confronting Fascism in Egypt: Dictatorship versus
Democracy in the 1930s, Stanford University Press
389
Philip Gibbs (1921) “The Social Revolution in English Life” Harper’s Magazine, April, p. 560-68
Franklin H. Giddings (1917) “The Bases of a Just and Enduring Peace” Annals of the American
Academy of Political and Social Science, Vol.72:83-88
Robert Gilpin (1981) War and Change in World Politics, Cambridge University Press
Kristian Gleditsch and Michael D. Ward. (2006) "Diffusion and the International Context of
Democratization" International Organization 60.4:911-933
Gary Goertz (2006) Social Science Concepts: A User’s Guide, Princeton University Press
Kjell Goldmann and Gunnar Sjöstedt, eds. (1979) Power, Capabilities, Interdependence: Problems
in the Study of International Influence, Sage Publications
Gary Goertz (2004) International Norms and Decision Making: A Punctuated Equilibrium Model,
Rowman & Littlefield
Norbert Gotz and Kiran Klaus Patel (2006) “Facing the Fascist Model: Discourse and the
Construction of Labour Services in the USA and Sweden in the 1930s and 1940s” Journal of
Contemporary History 41.1:57-73
Peter Gourevitch (1978) “The Second Image Reversed: The International Sources of Domestic
Politics” International Organization 32.4:881-911
Peter Gourevitch (1986) Politics in Hard Times: Comparative Responses to International Economic
Crises, Cornell University Press
Victoria de Grazia (2005) Irresistible Empire: America’s Advance through Twentieth-Century Europe,
Harvard University Press
Asgeir Gudmundsson (1980) “Nazism in Iceland” in Stein Ugelvik Larsen, Bernt Hagtvet, and Jan
Petter Myklebust, eds., Who Were the Fascists: Social Roots of European Fascism, Oslo:
Universitetsforlaget
Rodney Bruce Hall (2003) “Moral Authority as a Power Source” International Organization
51.4:591-622
Stefan Halper (2010) The Beijing Consensus: How China’s Authoritarian Model Will Dominate the
Twenty-First Century, Basic Books
Sandra Halperin (2004) War and Social Change in Modern Europe: The Great Transformation
Revisited, Cambridge University Press
Michael Handel (1981) Weak States in the International System, Frank Cass
390
J. Borden Harriman (1918) “How England Meets Her Labor” Annals of the American Academy of
Political and Social Science Vol.78, p.80-85
Paul N. Hehn (2002) A low dishonest decade: The great powers, Eastern Europe, and the economic
origins of World War II, 1930-1941, Continuum
Mary Heinmann (2011) Czechoslovakia: The State That Failed, Yale University Press
Granville Hicks (1946) “The Spectre that Haunts the World” Harper’s Magazine, June, p.536-42
Otto Hintze (1975) The Historical Essays of Otto Hintze, Felix Gilbert, ed., Oxford University Press
Eric Hobsbawm (1990) Nations and Nationalism Since 1780: Programme, Myth, Reality, Cambridge
University Press
Eric Hobsbawm (1994) The Age of Extremes: A History of the World, 1914-1991, Vintage Books,
p.49
Ernest Martin Hopkins (1916) “Democracy and Industry” Annals of the American Academy of
Political and Social Science, Vol.65:57-67
Geoffrey Hosking (2001) Russia and the Russians: A History, Belknap Press of Harvard University
Press
Marc Morjé Howard and Philip G. Roessler (2006) “Liberalizing Electoral Outcomes in Competitive
Authoritarian Regimes” American Journal of Political Science 50.2:365- 81
Victoria Hui (2005) War and State Formation in Ancient China and Early Modern Europe,
Cambridge University Press
Samuel Huntington (1982) “American Ideals versus American Institutions” Political Science
Quarterly 97.1:1-37
Samuel Huntington (1991) The Third Wave: Democratization in the Late Twentieth Century,
University of Oklahoma Press
Aldous Huxley (1936) “Ends and Means: An Inquiry into the Nature of Ideals and into the Methods
Employed for Their Realization”
G. John Ikenberry (2000) After Victory: Institutions, Strategic Restraint, and the Rebuilding of Order
After Major Wars, Princeton University Press
Andrew C. Janos (1970) “The One-Party State and Social Mobilization” in Samuel Huntington and
Clement Moore, eds., Authoritarian Politics in Modern Society: The Dynamics of Established One-
Party Systems, Basic Books
Harold James (1993) “Innovation and conservatism in economic recovery: the alleged ‘Nazi
recovery’ of the 1930s” in W.R. Garside, ed., Capitalism in Crisis: An International Perspective on
the 1930s, Palgrave Macmillan
Ludwig Jedlicka (1979) “The Austrian Heimwehr” p. 223-40 in George L. Mosse, ed., International
Fascism: New Thoughts and New Approaches, Sage Publications
391
Robert Jervis (1997) System Effects: Complexity in Political and Social Life, Princeton University Press
Tony Judt (2005) Postwar: A History of Europe Since 1945, Penguin Press
Kelly M. Kadera, Mark J. C. Crescenzi, and Megan L. Shannon (2003) “Democratic Survival, Peace,
and War in the International System” American Journal of Political Science 47.2, p. 234-247
Kelly M. Kadera and Gerald L. Sorokin (2004) “Measuring National Power” International
Interactions 30, 211-230
G.J. Kasza (1984) “Fascism from below? A Comparative Perspective on the Japanese Right, 1931-
1936” Journal of Contemporary History 19.4, p.607-27
Peter J. Katzenstein (1985) Small States in World Markets: Industrial Policy in Europe, Cornell
University Press
Elizabeth Keir (2010) “War and Reform: Gaining Labor’s Compliance on the Homefront” p.139-61
in Elizabeth Keir and Ronald Krebs, eds., In War’s Wake: International Conflict and the Fate of
Liberal Democracy, Cambridge University Press
Elizabeth Keir and Ronald Krebs, eds. (2010) In War’s Wake: International Conflict and the Fate of
Liberal Democracy, Cambridge University Press
Paul M. Kellstedt and Guy D. Whitten (2009) The Fundamentals of Political Science Research,
Cambridge University Press
Paul Kennedy (1989) The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers: Economic Change and Military Conflict
from 1500 to 2000, New York: Random House
William C. Kirby (2001) “China” in Stein Ugelvik Larsen, ed., Fascism Outside Europe: The
European Impulse against Domestic Conditions in the Diffusion of Global Fascism, Boulder: Social
Science Monographs
Martin Kitchen (1976) The Silent Dictatorship: The Politics of the German High Command under
Hindenburg and Ludendorff, 1916-1918. London: Croom Helm
Stephen Krasner (1984) “Approaches to the State: Alternative conceptions and historical dynamics”
Comparative Politics 16.2:223-46
Arthur Koestler (1941/2006) Darkness at Noon, transl. by Daphne Hardy, New York: Scribner
392
Milan Kundera (1979/1999) Book of Laughter and Forgetting, New York: HarperCollins
Joshua Kurlantzick (2008) “Democracy on the Wane” The Boston Globe, September 14
Charles Kurzman (2008) Democracy Denied, 1905-1915: Intellectuals and the Fate of Democracy,
Harvard University Press
Walter Z. Laqueur (1955) “The Appeal of Communism in the Middle East” Middle East Journal 9.1
Walter Z. Laqueur (1956) Communism and Nationalism in the Middle East, New York: Frederick A.
Praeger, Inc.
Imre Lakatos (1970) “Falsification and the Methodology of Scientific Research Programmes” in
Lakatos and Musgrave, Criticism and the Growth of Knowledge, Cambridge University Press
Stein Ugelvik Larsen, Bernt Hagtvet, and Jan Petter Myklebust, eds. (1980) Who Were the Fascists:
Social Roots of European Fascism, Oslo: Universitetsforlaget
Stein Ugelvik Larsen, ed. (2001) Fascism Outside Europe: The European Impulse against Domestic
Conditions in the Diffusion of Global Fascism, Boulder: Social Science Monographs
Pierre-Henri Laurent (1979) “Belgian Rexism and Léon Degrelle” p. 295-315 in George L. Mosse,
ed., International Fascism: New Thoughts and New Approaches, Sage Publications
Richard Ned Lebow (2008) A Cultural Theory of International Relations, Cambridge University Press
Peter T. Leeson and Andrea M. Dean (2009) “The Domino Theory: An Empirical Investigation”
American Journal of Political Science 53.3:533-51
Albert Lepawsky (1936) “The Nazis Reform the Reich” American Political Science Review 30.2:324-
50
Steven Levitsky and Lucan A. Way (2002) “The Rise of Competitive Authoritarianism” Journal of
Democracy 13.2:51-65
Steven Levitsky and Lucan A. Way (2010) Competitive Authoritarianism: Hybrid Regimes After the
Cold War, Cambridge University Press
Nigel Lo, Barry Hashimoto, and Dan Reiter (2008) “Ensuring Peace: Foreign-Imposed Regime
Change and Post-War Peace Duration, 1914-2001” International Organization 62.4:717-36
Soledad Loaeza (2009) “Too close for conflict: Mexican authoritarianism as a response to US power,
1944-1949” Paper Presented at the 2009 APSA Annual Meeting. Toronto, Canada, September 3-6,
2009
Henry Cabot Lodge (1915) “Force and Peace” Annals of the American Academy of Political and
Social Science, Vol.60, p.197-212
Los Angeles Times (1935) “Democracy Wane Seen: Europe Declared in Two Camps” September 21,
p. A8
393
Harold Mackinder (1904) “The Geographical Pivot of History” The Geographical Journal 23.4:421-
37
John Markoff (1996) Waves of Democracy: Social Movements and Political Change, Pine Forge
Press
Phoebe Marr (1985) "The Development of Nationalist Ideology in Iraq, 1921-1941" The Muslim
World 75.2:85-101
Edward M. Mansfield and Jack L. Snyder (2007) Electing to Fight: Why Emerging Democracies Go to
War, The MIT Press
Edward D. Mansfield and Jack Snyder (2010) “Does War Influence Democratization?” p.23-49 in
Elizabeth Keir and Ronald Krebs, eds., In War’s Wake: International Conflict and the Fate of Liberal
Democracy, Cambridge University Press
Arno J. Mayer (1967) Politics and Diplomacy of Peacemaking: Containment and Counterrevolution
at Versailles, 1918-1919, New York: Alfred A. Knopf
Michael McFaul, “The Fourth Wave of Democracy and Dictatorship: Noncooperative Transitions in
the Postcommunist World” World Politics, Vol. 54.2, January 2002, p. 212-244
John Mearsheimer (2001) The Tragedy of Great Power Politics, W.W. Norton and Company
Wolfgang Merkel (2010) “Are Dictatorships Returning? Revisiting the ‘democratic rollback’
hypothesis” Contemporary Politics 16.1:17-31
Peter H. Merkl (1980) “Comparing Fascist Movements” in Stein Ugelvik Larsen, Bernt Hagtvet, and
Jan Petter Myklebust, eds., Who Were the Fascists: Social Roots of European Fascism, Oslo:
Universitetsforlaget,
John Meyer, John Boli and George Thomas (1997) “World Society and the Nation-State” The
American Journal of Sociology 103.1:144-81
Marshall Lee Miller (1975) Bulgaria During the Second World War, Stanford University Press
Sarah Mitchell, Scott Gates and Håvard Hegre (1999) “Evolution in Democracy-War Dynamics”
Journal of Conflict Resolution 43.6, p. 771-92
John D. Montgomery (1957) Forced To Be Free: The Artificial Revolution in Germany and Japan,
University of Chicago Press
Hans Morgenthau (1948) Politics Among Nations, New York: Alfred A. Knopf
Anson D. Morse (1887) “The Cause of Secession” Political Science Quarterly 2.3
394
George L. Mosse, ed. (1979) International Fascism: New Thoughts and New Approaches, Sage
Publications
Geraldo Munck and Jay Verkuilen (2002) “Conceptualizing and Measuring Democracy: Evaluating
Alternative Indices” Comparative Political Studies 35.1:5-34
The New York Times (1918) “Independence Hall Sees Nations Born” October 27, p.6
The New York Times (1945) “Democracy on the March”, October 14, p.E8
The New York Times (2006) “F. Mark Wyatt, 86, C.I.A. Officer, Is Dead”, July 6
Colin Nicholson (2001) The Longman Companion to the First World War, Longman
Gotz Nordbruch (2009) Nazism in Syria and Lebanon: the ambivalence of the German option,
1933-1945, Taylor & Francis
Douglass C. North and Barry R. Weingast (1989) “Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of
Institutional Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England” The Journal of Economic
History, Vol.49:803-832
John O'Loughlin, Michael D. Ward, Corey L. Lofdahl, Jordin S. Cohen, David S. Brown, David
Reilly, Kristian S. Gleditsch, Michael Shin (1998) “The Diffusion of
Democracy, 1946-1994” Annals of the Association of American Geographers 88.4:545-574
Ido Oren (2003) Our Enemies and US: America’s Rivalries and the Making of Political Science,
Ithaca: Cornell University Press
Andrea Orzoff (2009) Battle for the Castle: The Myth of Czechoslovakia in Europe, 1914-1948,
Oxford University Press
John Owen (2002) “The Foreign Imposition of Domestic Institutions” International Organization
56.2:375-409
John Owen (2010) The Clash of Ideas in World Politics: Transnational Networks, States, and Regime
Change 1510-2010, Princeton University Press
R. R. Palmer, Joel Colton, and Lloyd S. Kramer (2002) A History of the Modern World, 9th edition,
McGraw-Hill
395
Mark Peceny (2010) “Democratizing During Hard Times: Germany’s Transition to Democracy in
the Wake of the First World War” Paper presented at the 106th Annual Meeting of the American
Political Science Association, September 2-5, 2010, Washington, D.C
Goran Peic and Dan Reiter (2010) “Foreign-Imposed Regime Change, State Power and Civil War
Onset, 1920-2004” British Journal of Political Science
Jon C. Pevehouse (2002) “Democracy from the Outside-In? International Organizations and
Democratization” International Organization 56.3:515-49
George Philip (1996) “Democratic Institutions in South America: Comparative and Historical
Perspectives” Third World Quarterly 17.4:707-23
Jeffrey Pickering and Mark Peceny (2006) “Forging Democracy at Gunpoint” International Studies
Quarterly 50:539-559
Paul Pierson (2004) Politics in Time: History, Institutions, and Social Analysis, Princeton University
Press
Mark E. Pietrzsyk (2002) International Order and Individual Liberty: Effects of War and Peace on the
Development of Governments, University Press of America
Richard Pipes (2008) “Banished: ‘The Forsaken’ by Tim Tzouliadis” The New York Sun, July 30
Gianfranco Poggi (1978) The Development of the Modern State: A Sociological Introduction,
Stanford University Press
Karl Polanyi (1944/2001) The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our
Time, Boston: Beacon Press
Sheldon D. Pollack (2010) War, Revenue, and State Building: Financing the Development of the
American State, Cornell University Press
Geoffrey Pridham (1995) “Democratic Transition and the International Environment” in Geoffrey
Pridham, ed., Transitions to Democracy: Comparative Perspectives from Southern Europe, Latin
America, and Eastern Europe, UK: Dartmouth Publishing Group
Adam Przeworski, Michael E. Alvarez, Jose Antonio Cheibub, and Fernando Limongi (2000)
Democracy and Development: Political Institutions and Well-Being in the World, 1950-1990,
Cambridge University Press
David L. Raby (1991) Fascism and Resistance in Portugal: Communists, Liberals and Military
Dissidents in the Opposition to Salazar, 1941-1974, Manchester University Press
Karen Rasler and William R. Thompson (2005) Puzzles of the Democratic Peace Theory: Theory,
Geopolitics, and the Transformation of World Politics, New York: Palgrave
396
Georg von Rauch (1974) The Baltic States: the years of independence: Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania,
1917-1940, University of California Press
William C. Redfield (1915) “America’s International Trade as Affected by the European War” Annals
of the American Academy of Political and Social Science Vol. 60:1-16
Philip Rees (1990) Biographical Dictionary of the Extreme Right Since 1890, Simon and Schuster
Dan Reiter and Allan C. Stam (2002) Democracies at War, Princeton University Press
Joao Resende-Santos (2007) Neorealism, States, and the Modern Army, Cambridge University Press
J.M. Roberts (1999) Twentieth Century: The History of the World, 1901 to 2000, Viking
David Rock, ed. (1994) Latin America in the 1940s: War and Postwar Transitions, University of
California Press
Lindsay Rogers (1919) “The Literature of Reconstruction” The Sewanee Review 27.1:109-13
Dietmar Rothermund (1996) The Global Impact of the Great Depression, 1929-1939, Routledge
Dietrich Rueschmeyer, Evelyne Huber Stephens, and John D. Stephens (1992) Capitalist
Development and Democracy, University of Chicago Press
Ricardo Sanhueza (1999) “The Hazard Rate of Political Regimes” Public Choice 98.3-4:337-367
Wolfgang Schivelbusch (2006) Three New Deals: Reflections on Roosevelt’s America, Mussolini’s
Italy, and Hitler’s Germany, 1933-1939, Metropolitan Books
Arthur Schlesinger (2003) The Politics of Upheaval, 1935-1936, vol.3 of The Age of Roosevelt,
Boston: Mariner Books
Arthur Schlesinger (2003) The Coming of the New Deal, 1933-1935, vol.2 of The Age of Roosevelt,
Boston: Mariner Books
Klaus Schwabe (1985) Woodrow Wilson, Revolutionary Germany, and Peacemaking, 1918-1919,
transl by Rita and Robert Kimber, University of North Carolina Press
Randall Schweller (1998) Deadly Imbalances: Tripolarity and Hitler’s Strategy of World Conquest,
Columbia University Press
Randall L. Schweller (2010) “Ennui Becomes Us” The National Interest 105:27-38
John Seeley (1896) An Introduction to Political Science, London and New York: Macmillan and Co.
Accessed online at http://www.archive.org/details/ introductiontopo00seel
Nakano Seigo (1995) "The Need for a Totalitarian Japan" in Roger Griffen, ed., Fascism, Oxford
University Press
397
Hugh Seton-Watson (1979) “The Age of Fascism and its Legacy” in George L. Mosse, ed.,
International Fascism: New Thoughts and New Approaches, Sage Publications
Andreas Schedler, ed. (2006) Electoral Authoritarianism: The Dynamics of Unfree Competition,
Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner
David J. Singer, Stuart Bremer, and John Stuckey (1972) "Capability Distribution, Uncertainty, and
Major Power War, 1820-1965." p. 19-48 in Bruce Russett, ed., Peace, War, and Numbers, Beverly
Hills: Sage
Theda Skocpol (1979) States and Social Revolutions: A Comparative Analysis of France, Russia, and
China, Cambridge University Press
Stephen Skowronek (1982) Building A New American State: The Expansion of National
Administrative Capacities, 1877-1920, Cambridge University Press
James L. Slayden (1917) “Disarmament and International Courts Prerequisites to a Durable Peace”
Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, Vol.72, p.92-100
Vaclav Smil (2010) Why America is Not a New Rome, MIT Press
Peter H. Smith (2005), Democracy in Latin America: Political Change in Comparative Perspective,
Oxford University Press
T.V. Smith (1927) “Review of Democracy under Revision by H.G. Wells” The Social Service Review
1.4:665-6
Jack L. Snyder (2000) From Voting to Violence: Democratization and Nationalist Conflict, W.W.
Norton and Company
Timothy Snyder (2011) Bloodlands: Europe Between Hitler and Stalin, New York: Basic Books
Harvey Starr (1991) “Democratic Dominoes: Diffusion Approaches to the Spread of Democracy in
the International System” Journal of Conflict Resolution 35.2:356-81
Fritz Stern (1997) “The new democracies in crisis in interwar Europe” in Axel Hadenius, ed.,
Democracy’s Victory and Crisis, Cambridge University Press
Richard J. Stoll and Michael D. Ward, eds. (1989) Power in World Politics, Lynne Rienner
Albert E. Stone, Jr. (1960) “Seward Collins and the American Review: Experiment in Pro-Fascism,
1933-37” American Quarterly 12.1:3-19
Gale Stokes (1993) The Walls Came Tumbling Down: The Collapse of Communism in Eastern
Europe, Oxford University Press
Mario Sznajder (1993) “A Case of Non-European Fascism: Chilean National Socialism in the 1930s”
Journal of Contemporary History 28.2:269-96
398
Ida M. Tarbell (1917) “Mobilizing the Women” Harper’s Magazine, November, p. 841-47
Ashley J. Tellis, Janice Bially, Christopher Layne, Melissa McPherson (2000) “Measuring National
Power in the Postindustrial Age”, RAND
William R. Thompson (1996) "Democracy and Peace: Putting the Cart before the Horse?"
International Organization 50.1, p. 141-174
William R. Thompson, ed. (2009) Systemic Transitions: Past, Present, and Future, Palgrave-
Macmillan.
Thucydides (431 B.C.E/1972), The Peloponnesian War, New York: Penguin Classics
Charles Tilly (1990) Coercion, Capital, and European States, AD 990-1992, Blackwell
Charles Tilly (2004) Contention & Democracy in Europe, 1650-2000, Cambridge University Press
Gregory F. Treverton, Seth G. Jones (2005) “Measuring National Power” RAND Conference Proceedings;
available online at http://www.rand.org/pubs/conf_proceedings/
2005/RAND_CF215.pdf
Adam Ulam (1960) The Unfinished Revolution: An Essay on the Sources of Influence of Marxism and
Communism, Vintage Books
Oswald Garrison Villard (1916) “Preparedness Is Militarism” Annals of the American Academy of Political and
Social Science Vol.66, p.217-24.
Richard Vinen (2000) A History in Fragments: Europe in the Twentieth Century, Da Capo Press
Marcus Walker (2009) “After the Wall: A Debate Over Democracy's Reach” Wall Street Journal -
Eastern Edition, October 29, p. A17
Martin Walker (1995) The Cold War: A History, Henry Holt and Company
Arthur Walworth (1977) America’s Moment, 1918: American Diplomacy at the End of World War I,
New York: Norton
Eugen Weber (1979) “The Men of the Archangel” p. 317-43 in George L. Mosse, ed., International
Fascism: New Thoughts and New Approaches, Sage Publications
Kathleen Weekley (2006) “The National or the Social? Problems of Nation-Building in Post-World
War II Philippines” Third World Quarterly 27.1:85-100
399
Odd Arne Westad (2005) The Global Cold War: Third World Interventions and the Making of Our
Times, Cambridge University Press
E.B. White (1935) “Notes and Comment: The Talk of the Town” The New Yorker, March 9, p.9
James Q. Whitman (1991) “Of Corporatism, Fascism, and the New Deal” The American Journal of
Comparative Law 39.4:747-78
John Van Wingen and Herbert K. Tillema (1980) “British Military Intervention after World War II:
Militance in a Second-Rank Power” Journal of Peace Research 17.4:291-303
F.H. Witthoefft (1920) “Our Commercial Situation” Annals of the American Academy of Political
and Social Science Vol. 92, p.96-98
William C. Wohlforth (1987) “The Perception of Power: Russia in the Pre-1914 Balance” World
Politics 39.3:353-381
William C. Wohlforth (1993) The Elusive Balance: Power and Perceptions During the Cold War,
Cornell University Press
William C. Wohlforth (1999) “The Stability of a Unipolar World” International Security 24.1: 5-41
Sharon L. Wolchik (2007) “The Czech and Slovak Republics: Two Paths to the Same Destination”
p.191-214 in Sharon L. Wolchik and Jane L. Curry, eds., Central and East European Politics: From
Communism to Democracy, Rowman and Littlefield
Ehud Yaari (1987) “Behind the Terror” Atlantic Monthly, June 1987
Fareed Zakaria (1997) “The Rise of Illiberal Democracy” Foreign Affairs 76.6:22-43