0% found this document useful (0 votes)
37 views

Slides TKT CA Comparative-statics-analysis-2Credits

This document provides an overview of a mathematical economics course including information about the lecturer, course structure, assessment, and resources. It covers topics like comparative statics analysis, dynamic analysis using differential equations, and linear programming. Sample economic models and equilibrium concepts are presented, such as partial market equilibrium, IS-LM schedules, and complementary/substitutable goods.

Uploaded by

Linh Trần Gia
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
37 views

Slides TKT CA Comparative-statics-analysis-2Credits

This document provides an overview of a mathematical economics course including information about the lecturer, course structure, assessment, and resources. It covers topics like comparative statics analysis, dynamic analysis using differential equations, and linear programming. Sample economic models and equilibrium concepts are presented, such as partial market equilibrium, IS-LM schedules, and complementary/substitutable goods.

Uploaded by

Linh Trần Gia
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 80

Mathematical Economics (2 Credits)

PART I: COMPARATIVE STATICS ANALYSIS

Hà Văn Hiếu

University of Economics and Law

10th October 2022

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 1 / 80


Introduction

Lecturer
Dr. Hà Văn Hiếu,
Faculty of Economic Mathematics, UEL.
Email: [email protected].

Students
This module is taken by 413CA.

Given your very varied backgrounds, you will need to


stay focused,
work with your team,
become practised at communicating your own insights and
challenges...

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 2 / 80


All about MAT1008

1 Part I: What is Mathematical Economics [Chapters 1 & 2]


The nature of Mathematical Economics.
A review on MEB (aka Toán cao cấp) [code: MAT1001]: Matrices,
Differentiation, Integration, Optimization and applications in
Economics.
2 Part II: Dynamic Analysis [Part 5 - chapters 14-19]
Differential Equations and Difference Equations.
3 Part III: Linear Programming Problem [Introduction to Operation
Research, Chapters 3-5]
The graphical method & the simplex method.
Solving Linear Programming Problem by Excel solver.

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 3 / 80


How to pass?

1 Minimum attendance: 80%.


2 No smartphone, no cigarette, etc.

Forms of Assessments Types of Collaboration Weights


Attendance, assignments Individual, team 30%
Midterm Individual 20%
Final exam Individual 50%
Table 1: Super important table

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 4 / 80


Resources

The main recommended text is


Alpha C. Chiang, Fundamental Methods of
Mathematical Economics, 3rd Edition,
McGraw-Hill, Inc., 2005.
https://lms.uel.edu.vn/
Other resources:
1 Raymond A. Barnett; Calculus for Business, Economics, Life
Sciences and Social Sciences, 13th edition.
2 Frederick S. Hillier, Introduction to Operations Research, 10th
edition, McGraw-Hill, 2015.
3 PGS.TS. Hoàng Đình Tuấn; Giáo trình Mô hình Toán Kinh tế;
NXB Thống kê, Trường Đại học Kinh tế Quốc dân.

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 5 / 80


Create your team!

413, 413C, 413CA https://lms.uel.edu.vn

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 6 / 80


Week 1 - The nature of Mathematical Economics

Definition
Mathematical economics is the application of mathematical methods to
represent theories and analyze problems in economics. Often, these
applied methods go beyond simple geometry and may include
differential and integral calculus, difference and differential equations,
matrix algebra, mathematical programming, or other computational
methods. [Wikipedia]

1 What is the difference between mathematical economics and


literary economics?
2 What is the advantage of mathematical economics?
3 What is the difference between mathematical economics and
econometrics?
Ref: p2-4

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 7 / 80


Economic models

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 8 / 80


Ingredients of a Mathematical model

Variables: something that can take on different values, example:


price, profit, revenue, etc. Each variable can assume various values
and presented by a symbol: Endogenous - value is determined by
the model and exogenous - value is determined outside the model.
An economic variable can be exogenous in some models and
endogenous in others. Symbols: x, y, z, t. dependent variables and
independent variables.
Constants: a magnitude that does not change. Variables frequently
appear in combination with fixed number or constants. Symbols:
1, 2, 3, a, b.
Parametric constants or parameters: a, b - supposed to represent a
given constant. However, it can take virtually any value. A
parameter is nevertheless to be regarded as a variable of a model.

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 9 / 80


Ingredients of a Mathematical model - 2

Equations: something that express the relation between variables:


definitional equations - set up identity between two alternate
expressions that have exactly the same meaning, behavioral
equations - specify the manner in which a variable behaves in
response to changes in other variables, conditional equation - state
requirements to be satisfied.
Example

π =R−C (definitional equation)


C = 75 + 10Q (behavioral equation)
Qd = Qs (conditional equation)

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 10 / 80


Examples - Partial market equilibrium

Law of supply and demand


supply and demand pull against each other until the market finds an
equilibrium price.


 P = P (Qs )
P = P (Qd )
Qs = Qd

Determine:
endogenous,
exogenous
variables.
Behavioral,
conditional
equations.
Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 11 / 80
Examples - IS-LM schedule

Y =C +I +G
C = C(Y )
I = I(Y )
I = I(r)
M s = Md

Determine:
endogenous,
exogenous
variables.
Behavioral,
conditional
equations.
Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 12 / 80
Elementary Linear Algebra and Analysis

Matrices, systems of equations, vectors: Markov chains, Leontief


Input-output models, linear models.
Analysis: differentiation, integration, implicit functions: (partial)
marginal values, (partial) elasticities, marginal (elasticity) rates of
substitution, (un)constrained optimizations and economical
interpretations.

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 13 / 80


A Summary of MEB (aka Toán Cao cấp)

Matrices and systems of linear Equations: Supply-demand


equilibrium models, Leontief I/O model, the National income
determination model, IS-LM model.
Differentiation: the first-order derivatives - marginal values,
elasticities, the second-order derivatives - differentials -
Optimization in Economics.
Partial differentiation: the first, second-order derivatives, marginal
values, elasticities, rates of substitution - geometric interpretation
of partial derivatives. Implicit functions.
Integration: (in)definite integral, rules, integral by parts, improper
integrals, economical applications: producer, customer’s surpluses;
from a marginal function to a total function, net investment and
capital formation.
Optimization: constrained, unconstrained optimization, Lagrange
multiplier: Utility maximization and production maximization.
Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 14 / 80
Partial Market Equilibrium - One commodity

One-commodity model:

Qd = Qs
Qd = a − bP (a, b > 0)
Qs = −c + dP (c, d > 0)

Equilibrium solution:
a+c ad − bc
P∗ = , Q∗ =
b+d b+d
Hence, to be economically meaningful, the model should contain
the additional restriction that ad > bc.
More exercises: p34

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 15 / 80


Two-commodity Market model

Two-commodity model:

Qd1 = Qs1
Qd1 = ao − a1 P1 + a2 P2 (ao , a1 > 0)
Qs1 = −bo + b1 P1 + b2 P2 (bo , b1 > 0)
Qd2 = Qs2
Qd2 = αo − α1 P1 + α2 P2 (αo , α1 > 0)
Qs2 = −βo + β1 P1 + β2 P2 (βo , β1 > 0)

Find the equilibrium prices and quantities.


More exercises: p45

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 16 / 80


Complementary and Substitutable goods

Qd1 = ao − a1 P1 + a2 P2
Qd2 = −αo + α1 P1 + α2 P2

1 If the goods are substitutable, then an increase in the price of


good 2 would mean that consumers would switch from good 2 to
good 1, causing Qd1 to increase. Substitutable goods are therefore
characterised by a positive value of a2 , α2 .
2 On the other hand, if the goods are complementary, then a rise in
the price of either good would see the demand fall, so a2 , α2 is
negative.

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 17 / 80


National-Income Determination model

Y = C + Io + G o
C = a + bY (a > 0, , 0 < b < 1)

where Y and C stands for the endogenous variables national income


and consumption expenditure, respectively, and Io and Go represent the
endogenously determined investment and government expenditures.
With taxation T :

Y = C + Io + Go
C = a + b(Y − T ) (a > 0, 0 < b < 1)
T = d + tY (d > 0, 0 < t < 1)

Solve the model.

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 18 / 80


IS - LM Schedule

Y = C + Io + G o
C = a + bY (a > 0, , 0 < b < 1)

IS-LM schedule (with interest rate r and money supply Mo :

Y = C + I + Go
C = a + bY (a > 0, 0 < b < 1)
I = cr + d (c < 0, d > 0)
Mo = k1 Y + k2 r + k3
(k1 , k3 > 0, k2 < 0)

Solve the model. More exercises: p47


Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 19 / 80
Leontief Input-Output Model

“ What level of output should each


of the n industries in an economy
produce, in order that it will just be
sufficient to satisfy the total
demand of that product?"

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 20 / 80


Structure of an Input-Output model
Assumptions:
1 Each industry produces only one homogeneous commodity, - if an
industry produces two different commodities or uses two different
possible factor combinations, then that industry may be broken
down into two separate industries.
2 Each industry uses a fixed input ratio (or factor combination) for
the production of its output.
3 Production in every industry is subject to constant returns to scale.
It follows that
in order to produce each unit of the j-th commodity, the input
need for the i-th commodity must be fixed amount, which we shall
denote by aij , and refer to as an input coefficient.
For example, a32 = 0.35 means that 0.35$ worth of the third
commodity is required as an input for producing a $ worth of the
second commodity.
Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 21 / 80
Structure of Input-output Model - 2

Coefficient matrix:
 
a11 a12 ··· a1n
 a21 a22 ··· a2n 
A= .
 
.. .. .. 
 .. . . . 
an1 an2 · · · ann

Each column sum represents the partial input cost and must be
less than 1.
Final demand is a column vector b, including consumer demand,
government expenditure and export - import activities.
Let’s denote by xi the output level of industry i. Then

(I − A)x = d orx = (I − A)−1 d

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 22 / 80


The existence of nonnegative solutions

I − A is nonsingular (or invertible)


x∗ is positive.
The leading principal minors of a matrix
 
b11 b12 ··· b1n
 b21 b22 ··· b2n 
B= .
 
.. .. .. 
 .. . . . 
bn1 bn2 · · · bnn

are |B1 | = b11 and

b11 b12 b13


b11 b12
|B2 | = , |B3 | = b21 b22 b23 , . . . , |Bn | = det B
b21 b22
b31 b32 b33

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 23 / 80


The existence of nonnegative solutions - 2

Hawkins and Simon theorem


Given (1) an n × n matrix B with bij ≤ 0 for any i ̸= j, i.e. with all
off-diagonal elements non-positive), and (2) an n × 1 vector d ≥ 0;
there exists an n × 1 vectors x∗ ≥ 0 such that BX ∗ = d, if and only if

|Bm | > 0 for all 1 ≤ m ≤ n

i.e., if and only if the leading principal minors of B are all positive.

As a corollary, the Input-output model has positive solution if and only


if the leading principal minors of the Leontief matrix I − A are all
positive.
More exercises: p120

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 24 / 80


Static Analysis

Economic equilibrium is a condition or state in which economic


forces are balanced, i.e. characterized by a lack of tendency to
change. It is for this reason that the analysis of equilibrium is
referred to as static analysis. For example: Equilibrium in
market model (or supply-demand model), in National-Income
Determination model, IS-LM model, Input-Output model, Markov
chain.
Disadvantages: no analysis on the actual process of adjustments
and readjustments of the variables ultimately leading to the
equilibrium state.
The shifts of the equilibrium state pertain to a type of analysis
called comparative statics and the question of attainability and
stability of equilibrium falls within the realm of dynamic analysis.

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 25 / 80


Statics, Comparative statics and Dynamic Analyses

Statics analysis

Comparative analysis
Initial assumed the equilibrium is attained
Equilibrium

Dynamic analysis
whether the equilibrium is attained

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 26 / 80


Comparative Analysis

1 Comparative Analysis:
Rate of change: Differentiation, marginal value.
Rate of percentage change: Differentiation, elasticity.
Rate of substitution: implicit derivatives, marginal substitution,
Elasticity substitution.
2 Comparative Statics Analysis:
Integration.
Optimization.

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 27 / 80


Differentiation

Differentiation: the first-order derivative,

f (x + ∆x) − f (x)
f ′ (x) = lim
∆x→0 ∆x

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 28 / 80


Rules of Differentiation

The sum and the difference rules, the product and the quotient
rules, the chain and the inverse rules.

f ′g − f g′
(f /g)′ =
(f ± g)′ = f ′ ± g ′ g2
(f g)′ = f ′ g + f g ′ df du
(f (u))′ = ×
du dx
f ′g − f g′
(f /g)′ = (f −1 )′ = 1/f ′
g2

Example
1 Given y = u3 + 2u, where u = 5 − x2 , find dy/dx by the chain rule.
2 Given y = 4x5 + x3 + 2x. Is x uniquely determined for each value
of y? If true, x can be considered as a function of y. Determine the
derivative of the later function, i.e. dx/dy.

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 29 / 80


The second-order Derivative, the Convexity

The second-order derivative:

f ′′ (x) = (f ′ )′

Concave and Convex:

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 30 / 80


Partial Differentiation

Let
f (x, y) = x2 y
Then

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 31 / 80


Notations

Notations
Let
z = f (x, y).
Then the partial derivative of f w.r.t. (with respect to) x is writtern as

∂z ∂f
or or fx
∂x ∂x

Example
Let
f (x, y) = x2 y
Then
∂f
= 2xy and fy = x2
∂x

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 32 / 80


Second-order derivatives
There are four second-order partial derivatives.
The function obtained by differentiating twice w.r.t. x:
∂2z ∂2f
or or fxx
∂x2 ∂x2
The function obtained by differentiating twice w.r.t. y:
∂2z ∂2f
or or fyy
∂y 2 ∂y 2
The function obtained by differentiating first w.r.t. x and then
w.r.t. y:
∂2z ∂2f
or or fyx
∂y∂x ∂y∂x
The function obtained by differentiating first w.r.t. y and then
w.r.t. x:
∂2z ∂2f
or or fxy
∂x∂y ∂x∂y
Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 33 / 80
Examples

Example
Find expressions for the second-order partial derivatives of the
functions

a. f (x, y) = 5x4 − y 2 b. f (x, y) = x2 y 3 − 10x

Example
Find expressions for the partial derivatives f1 , f11 and f21 in the case
when
f (x1 , x2 , x3 ) = x1 x2 + x51 − x22 x3

Young’s theorem
If fxy and fyx are both continuous then

fxy = fyx

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 34 / 80


Total Differentials
Let z = z(x, y) be a function of two (independent) variables x and y.
Then
∆z = z(x + ∆x, y + ∆y) − z(x, y)
= z(x + ∆x, y + ∆y) − z(x, y + ∆y) + z(x, y + ∆y) − z(x, y)
∂z ∂z
≈ ∆x + ∆y
∂x ∂y
When ∆x, ∆y → 0, we have
∂z ∂z
dz = dx + dy.
∂x ∂y
This is defined as the total differential of z.
Example
Determine the total differential of z = x2 + y 3 and estimate the change
on z at (xo = 50, yo = 50) when both inputs increase by 1 unit.
Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 35 / 80
Rules of Total Differential

dk = 0 (constant-function rule)
d(cun ) = cnun−1 du (power-function rule)
d(u ± v) = du ± dv (sum-difference rule)
d(uv) = udv + vdu (product rule)
u 1
d = 2 (vdu − udv) (quotient rule)
v v

Example
Determine the total differentials of the following functions:

a) z = xy d) z = xex
b) z =x+y e) z = Axα y β
c) z = ex+y f) f = Axα y β + z(M − ax − by)
Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 36 / 80
Second-order Total Differentials

Given z = f (x, y), then

d2 z = fxx dx2 + 2fxy dxdy + fyy dy 2

Example
Given z = x3 + 5xy − y 2 , then

dz = (3x2 + 5y)dx + (5x − 2y)dy


d2 z = 6xdx2 + 10dxdy − 2dy 2

At the point (x = 1, y = 2), we have

dz = 13dx + dy and d2 z = 6dx2 + 10dxdy − 2dy 2

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 37 / 80


Total Derivatives - 1 variable

Let y = f (x, w) be a function where x = g(w). Then y is a


function of w and
dy dx ∂y dx ∂y
= fx + fw = +
dw dw ∂x dw ∂w
The above equation can be obtained by firstly differentiation the
function y totally and then dividing through by dw.
Let y = f (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn , w) where x1 , . . . , xn are functions of w.
Then
dy ∂y dx1 ∂y dx2 ∂y dxn ∂y
= + + ··· + +
dw ∂x1 dw ∂x2 dw ∂xn dw ∂w

Example
Determine the total derivative of z = y ln ex where y = x2 .

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 38 / 80


Total Derivatives - 2 variables
Let y = f (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn , u, v) where x1 , . . . , xn are functions of
u, v. Then
dy ∂y ∂x1 ∂y ∂x2 ∂y ∂xn ∂y
= + + ··· + +
du ∂x1 ∂u ∂x2 ∂u ∂xn ∂u ∂u
Since y can be considered as a function of 2 independent variables
u and v, we should use another notation for the total derivative,
instead of dy/du.
ðy ∂y ∂x1 ∂y ∂x2 ∂y ∂xn ∂y
= + + ··· + +
ðu ∂x1 ∂u ∂x2 ∂u ∂xn ∂u ∂u

Example
Determine the total derivatives of z = y1 ex1 + y2 sin(2x2 ) where
y1 = x1 + x2 and y2 = x1 x2 .

More exercises: page 193-194.


Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 39 / 80
Optimization

Stationary points:

f ′ (x) = 0

Local maximum:
 ′
f (x) = 0
f ′′ (x) < 0

Local minimum:
 ′
f (x) = 0
f ′′ (x) > 0

Stationary point of inflection:


 ′
f (x) = 0

f ′′ (x) = 0
Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 40 / 80
Higher-order Derivative Test

f ′ (xo ) ̸= 0: xo is not local maximum or minimum.


f ′ (xo ) = 0, f ′′ (xo ) > 0: local minimum.
f ′ (xo ) = 0, f ′′ (xo ) < 0: local maximum.
f ′ (xo ) = 0, f ′′ (xo ) = 0, f ′′′ (xo ) ̸= 0: inflection point.

N th-Derivative test
Let f (x) be a function so that we can its N -th derivative. Assume that
there is a point xo so that f ′ (xo ) = · · · = f (N −1) (xo ) = 0 and
f (N ) (xo ) ̸= 0.
1 If N is odd then xo is an inflection point.
2 If N is even and f (N ) (xo ) < 0 then xo is a local maximum point.
3 If N is even and f (N ) (xo ) > 0 then xo is a local minimum point.

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 41 / 80


Higher-order Derivative Test - Practice

Example
Find the stationary values of the following functions:

(a) y = x3 (b) y = −x4 (c) y = x6 + 5

Determine by the N th-derivative test whether they represent local


maximum, minimum, or inflection points.

More exercises: page 254

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 42 / 80


Unconstrained Optimisation

One variable Two variables

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 43 / 80


Saddle points vs Max-min points

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 44 / 80


Second-order Derivatives test

1 Solve the simultaneous equations



fx (x, y) = 0
fy (x, y) = 0

to find the stationary points.


2 2 > 0 at (a, b) then the function
If fxx > 0, fyy > 0 and fxx fyy − fxy
has a minimum at (a, b).
3 2 > 0 at (a, b) then the function
If fxx < 0, fyy < 0 and fxx fyy − fxy
has a maximum at (a, b).
4 2 < 0 at (a, b) then the function has a saddle point at
If fxx fyy − fxy
(a, b).

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 45 / 80


Second-order condition in Total Differentials approach

Let z = f (x, y) be a 2-variables function which has a stationary point


(xo , yo ), i.e. fx (xo , yo ) = fy (xo , yo ) = 0 or df (xo , yo ) = 0.
If d2 f (xo , yo ) > 0 for arbitrary values of dx and dy, not both zero,
then (xo , yo ) is a local minimum point of f .
If d2 f (xo , yo ) < 0 for arbitrary values of dx and dy, not both zero,
then (xo , yo ) is a local maximum point of f .
If the sign of d2 f (xo , yo ) is positive for some values of dx and dy,
but negative for others, then (xo , yo ) is a saddle point of f .

Example
Find the extreme value(s) of z = x2 + xy + 2y 2 + 3.

More exercises: p300-301.

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 46 / 80


2-Variable Case

Let
z = f (x1 , x2 , x3 )
Then
dz = f1 dx1 + f2 dx2 + f3 dx3
d2 z = f11 dx21 + f12 dx1 dx2 + f13 dx1 dx3
+f21 dx2 dx1 + f22 dx22 + f23 dx2 dx3
+f31 dx3 dx1 + f32 dx3 dx2 + f33 dx23
Once again,
x∗ = (x∗1 , x∗2 , x∗3 ) is a stationary point if df (x∗ ) = 0.
x∗ is local minimum if d2 z(x∗ ) > 0 for arbitrary dx, dy, dz, not all
zero.
x∗ is local maximum if d2 z(x∗ ) < 0 for arbitrary dx, dy, dz, not all
zero.
x∗ is saddle if d2 z(x∗ ) changes its sign.

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 47 / 80


Hessian determinant test - Leading principal minors

z = f (x1 , x2 , x3 )
Then
d2 z = f11 dx21 + f12 dx1 dx2 + f13 dx1 dx3
+f21 dx2 dx1 + f22 dx22 + f23 dx2 dx3
+f31 dx3 dx1 + f32 dx3 dx2 + f33 dx23
The symmetric Hessian determinant:

f11 f12 f13


|H| = f21 f22 f23
f31 f32 f33

whose leading principal minors are

f11 f12
|H1 | = f11 |H2 | = |H3 | = |H|
f21 f22

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 48 / 80


Hessian Determinant test
By using the theory of quadratic forms (p304), we get
Hessian determinant test for 3-variables case
If x∗ is a stationary point of z, i.e. dz(x∗ ) = 0, then the following
statement is hold:
 
∗ ∗ maximum
z ≡ z(x ) is a if
minimum
|H1 | < 0, |H2 | > 0, |H3 | < 0 (d2 z negative definite)
 

|H1 | > 0, |H2 | > 0, |H3 | > 0 (d2 z positive definite)

Example
Find the extreme values of the following functions.
z = x21 + 3x22 − 3x1 x2 + 4x2 x3 + 6x23
z = x1 x3 + x21 − x2 + x2 x3 + x22 + 3x23
z = x41 − 16x21 + x22 + x2 x3 + x23
Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 49 / 80
n-Variable Case

z = f (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn )
The total differential will then be
dz = f1 dx1 + f2 dx2 + · · · + fn dxn
The Hessian
f11 f12 ··· f1n
f21 f22 ··· f2n
|H| = . .. .. ..
.. . . .
fn1 fn2 · · · fnn

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 50 / 80


Constrained Optimization
Let us consider a consumer with the simple utility function
U = x1 x2 + 2x1
To render the optimization problem meaningful, a budget constraint
should be incorporated into the problem. If the consumer intends to
spend a given sum, say, $60, on the two goods and if the current prices
are
P1 = 4, and P2 = 2,
then the budget constraint can be expressed by
4x1 + 2x2 = 60
The problem now is to

optimize U = x1 x2 + 2x1
subject to
4x1 + 2x2 = 60

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 51 / 80


An illustration by Graph

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 52 / 80


Example - Practice

Solve
optimize U = x1 x2 + 2x1
subject to
4x1 + 2x2 = 60

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 53 / 80


Constrained Optimization and Lagrange-multiplier

optimize U = x1 x2 + 2x1
subject to
4x1 + 2x2 = 60

Idea of the method: is to convert a constrained optimization


problem into a form of unconstrained optimization problem.
The (corresponding) Lagrangian function of is of 3-variables:

L(x, y, λ) = x1 x2 + 2x1 + λ(60 − 4x1 − 2x2 )

For then the first-order condition for unconstrained optimization


will consist of the set of simultaneous equations:

Lλ = 60 − 4x1 − 2x2 = 0
L1 = x2 + 2 − 4λ = 0
L2 = x1 − 2λ = 0

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 54 / 80


Lagrange-multiplier method

optimize z = f (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn )
subject to
g(x1 , . . . , xn ) = c
It follows that the Lagrangian function will be
L = f (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ) + λ[c − g(x1 , x2 , . . . , xn )]
for which the first-order condition will consist of the following (n + 1)
simultaneous equations:
Lλ = c − g(x1 , . . . , xn ) = 0
L1 = f1 − λg1 = 0
······
Ln = fn − λgn = 0
If x = (x∗1 , . . . , x∗n ) is a solution of the constrained optimization then
there is λ∗ so that (x∗1 , . . . , x∗n , λ∗ ) is a root of the above system.
Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 55 / 80
The case of more than one constraint
When there is more than one constraint, the Lagrange-multiplier
method is equally applicable, provided we introduce as many such
multipliers as there are constraints in the Lagrangian function. For
example,

optimize z = f (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn )
subject to
g(x1 , . . . , xn ) = c and h(x1 , . . . , xn ) = d

Then we can define:


L = f + λ[c − g(x1 , . . . , xn )] + µ[d − h(x1 , . . . , xn )]
The first-order condition consists of
Lλ = c − g(x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ) = 0
Lµ = d − h(x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ) = 0
Li = fi − λgi − µhi (i = 1, 2, . . . , n)
Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 56 / 80
The Bordered Hessian

optimize z = f (x, y)
subject to
g(x, y) = c

The bordered Hessian:


0 gx gy
|H| = gx Lxx Lxy
gy Lyx Lyy
 
maximum point
(x∗ , y ∗ )
is a of z subject to g(x, y) = c
minimum point
0 gx gy  
>0
if and only if gx Lxx Lxy (ref. p358)
<0
gy Lyx Lyy

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 57 / 80


n-Variable Case

0 g1 g2 ··· gn
g1 L11 L12 ··· L1n
optimize z = f (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ) |H| = g2 L21 L22 ··· L2n
subject to .. .. .. .. ..
. . . . .
g(x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ) = c gn Ln1 Ln2 ··· Lnn

L = f (x1 , . . . , xn ) + λ(c − g(x1 , . . . , xn ))

Condition Maximum Minimum


First-order Lλ = L1 = · · · = Ln = 0 Lλ = L1 = · · · = Ln = 0
necessary
Second-order |H2 | > 0, |H3 | < 0,
sufficient |H4 | > 0, . . . , (−1)n |Hn | > 0 |H2 |, |H3 , . . . , |Hn | < 0
Remark. H is an (n + 1) × (n + 1)-matrix, |Hi | is the first (i + 1) × (i + 1)
principal minor.

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 58 / 80


Multiconstraint Case

optimize z = f (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn )
subject to
g j (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ) = cj for j = 1, .., m

0 g1 g2 ··· gn
g1 L11 L12 ··· L1n
|H| = g2 L21 L22 ··· L2n
.. .. .. .. ..
. . . . .
gn Ln1 Ln2 · · · Lnn

L = f (x1 , . . . , xn ) + λ1 [c1 − g 1 (x1 , . . . , xn )]+


+ · · · + λm [cj − g j (x1 , . . . , xn )]

The same second-order sufficient condition is applicable to this case as


well.
Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 59 / 80
Constrained optimisation on Production functions

Let us suppose that a firm wants to maximise output and that the
production function is of the form

Q = f (K, L)

Let the costs of each unit of capital and labour be PK and PL ,


respectively. So if the firm has a fixed amount, M , to spend on these
inputs, then
K · PK + L · PL = M

maximise Q = f (K, L)
subject to
K · PK + L · PL = M

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 60 / 80


Constrained optimisation on Production functions

maximise Q = f (K, L)
subject to
PK K + P L L = M

At the point A, the maximum point,


PL At the maximum point
(based on the line) MRTS =
PK PL MPL MPL MPK
= or =
MPL PK MPK PL PK
(based on the curve) MRTS =
MPK

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 61 / 80


Constrained optimisation on Production functions

At the maximum point

PL MPL
=
PK MPK

MPL MPK
=
PL PK

So when output is maximised subject to a cost constant,


the ratio of the input prices is equal to the ratio of their marginal
products.
the ratio of marginal product to price is the same for all inputs.

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 62 / 80


Constrained optimisation on Utility functions

At the maximum point

P1 U′
M aximise U = U (x1 , x2 ) = x′ 1
P2 Ux2
subject to
P1 x1 + P2 x2 = M
Ux′ 1 U′
= x2
P1 P2
So when utility is maximised subject to a budgetary constraint,
the ratio of the prices of the goods is equal to the ratio of their
marginal utilities.
the ratio of marginal utility to price is the same for all goods
consumed.

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 63 / 80


Practice Problem

Example
An individual’s utility function is given by U = x1 x2 where x1 and x2 denote
the number of items of two goods, G1 and G2. The prices of the goods are $2
and $10, respectively. Assuming that the individual has $400 available to
spend on these goods, find the utility-maximising values of x1 and x2 . Verify
that the ratio of marginal utility to price is the same for both goods at the
optimum.

Example
A firm’s total cost function is given by

TC = 3x21 + 2x1 x2 + 7x22

where x1 and x2 denote the number of items of goods G1 and G2,


respectively, that are produced. Find the values of x1 and x2 which minimise
costs if the firm is committed to providing 40 goods of either type in total.

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 64 / 80


Practice Problems
Example
A consumer’s utility function is given by

U (x1 , x2 ) = 2x1 x2 + 3x1

where x1 and x2 denote the number of items of two goods G1 and G2 that are
bought. Each item costs $1 for G1 and $2 for G2. Use Lagrange multipliers to
find the maximum value of U if the consumer’s income is $83. Estimate the
new optimal utility if the consumer’s income rises by $1.

Example
Use Lagrange multipliers to find expressions for x1 and x2 which maximise
the utility function
1/2 1/2
U = x1 + x2
subject to the general budgetary constraint

P1 x 1 + P2 x 2 = M
Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 65 / 80
Differentiation - Marginal values and Elasticities

Marginal value:
the absolute change on f
≈ f ′ (x)
the absolute change on x
Interpretation: The marginal value of f at x = xo estimates the
absolute change of f when the variable x increases by 1 unit.
Elasticity:
the percentage change on f x
≈ f ′ (x) ×
the percentage change on x f (x)

Interpretation: The elasticity of f at xo estimates the percentage


change of f when the variable x increases by 1%.
The demand is said to be (unit, in)elastic at xo if
|ϵd (xo )|(=, <) > 1.

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 66 / 80


Partial Differentiation - Partial Marginal values and
Elasticities

Given an economical function f (x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ),


The partial marginal value of f with respect to the variable
(w.r.t.) x1 :
∂f the absolute change on f

∂x1 the absolute change on x1
The partial elasticity of f with respect to the variable (w.r.t.) x1 :

x1 the percentage change on f


fx′ 1 × ≈
f (x1 , . . . , xn ) the percentage change on x1

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 67 / 80


Substitution Rates

The marginal rate of substitution (MRS) is the amount of an


input needed to increase to maintain the level of the output when
another input falls down to 1 unit.
Example. Given a product function Q = Q(K, L), the marginal
rate of technical substitution, denoted by MRST, at (Ko , Lo ) is
the amount of capital needed to add to maintain the output
Qo = Q(Ko , Lo ) when the amount of labour is reduced by 1 unit.
Example. Given a utility function U = U (x1 , x2 ), the marginal
rate of commodity substitution, denoted by MRCT, is the amount
by which one input needs to increase to maintain a constant value
of utility when the other input decreases by 1 unit.

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 68 / 80


Marginal rate of Commodity substitution

If y = y(x1 , . . . , xn ) is an implicit
function given by

F (y, x1 , . . . , xn ) = 0

then
∂y F′
= − x′1
∂x1 Fy
Given U = U (x1 , x2 ). Then

dx2 Ux1
MRCS = − =
dx1 Ux2

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 69 / 80


Comparative statics analysis on Market model

∂P ∗ 1
=
Q = a − bP (demand) ∂a b+d
∂P ∗ a+c
Q = −c + dP (supply) =−
∂b (b + d)2
∂P ∗ 1
=
Equilibrium: ∂c b+d
∂P ∗ a+c
=−
∂d (b + d)2
a+c ad − bc
P∗ = , Q∗ =
b+d b+d

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 70 / 80


Integration

Integration: (in)definite integral, rules, integral by parts.

Applications: producer, customer’s surpluses; from a marginal


function to a total function; net investment and capital formation.

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 71 / 80


Consumer’s surplus

Consumer’s surplus is the excess cost that a person would have been
prepared to pay for goods over and above what is actually paid.

ZQo
CS = −Qo Po + f (Q)dQ
0

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 72 / 80


Consumer’s surplus - from Investopedia

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 73 / 80


Producer’s surplus

Producer’s surplus is the excess revenue that a producer has actually


received over and above the lower revenue that it was prepared to
accept for the supply of its goods.

ZQo
PS = Qo Po − g(Q)dQ
0

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 74 / 80


Producer’s surplus - from Investopedia

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 75 / 80


Investment and Capital formation

Net investment, I, is defined to be the rate of change of capital


stock, K, so that
dK
I=
dt
Here, I(t) denotes the flow of money, measured in dollars per year,
and K(t) is the amount of capital accumulated at time t as a
result of this investment flow and is measured in dollars.
If the fund is to provide a continuous revenue stream for n years at
an annual rate of S dollars per year, then the present value can be
found by evaluating the definite integral
Zn
P = Se−rt/100 dt
0

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 76 / 80


Marginal functions to Original functions
Since MC = (TC)′Q , MR = (TR)′Q , we have
Z Z
TC = MCdQ, TR = MRdQ

Example
a. A firm’s marginal cost function is M C = 2. Find an expression for
the total cost function if the fixed costs are 500. Hence find the
total cost of producing 40 goods.
b. The marginal revenue function of a monopolistic producer is
M R = 100 − 6Q. Find the total revenue function and deduce the
corresponding demand function.
c. Find an expression for the savings function if the marginal
propensity to save is given by MPS = 0.4 − 0.1Y −1/2 . and savings
are zero when income is 100.
More exercises: p470
Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 77 / 80
Dynamic Analysis

Dynamic Analysis is a type of analysis in which the object is either to


trace and study the specific time paths of the variables or to determine
whether, given sufficient time, these variables will tend to converge to
certain equilibrium values.
In a dynamic analysis, the question of “attainability" is to be
squarely faced, rather than assumed away.
On salient feature of dynamic analysis is the dating of the
variables, which introduces the explicit consideration of time into
the picture. This can be done in two ways: time can be considered
either as a continuous variable or as a discrete variable.

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 78 / 80


Projects

Team work
(Discrete) Markov chain in Economics and Finance.
Applications of Linear Algebras.

Projects
Leontieff I-O model and applying in Economics and/or Finance: an
evidence in Vietnam (Ref. (1) Using Solow and I-O models to determine the
Factors impacting Economic Growth in Ho Chi Minh City - Nguyen Thi
Canh; (2) Vietnam Economic Structure Change Based on Vietnam
Input-Output Tables 2012 and 2016 - Bui Trinh).

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 79 / 80


Any question?

Thank you!

Hà Văn Hiếu (UEL) Mathematical Economics 10th October 2022 80 / 80

You might also like