0% found this document useful (0 votes)
12 views

EC2B3 Topic 10 Lecture Slides

Uploaded by

cherryyu.ny
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
12 views

EC2B3 Topic 10 Lecture Slides

Uploaded by

cherryyu.ny
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 21

EC2B3 Macroeconomics II

Topic 10: Financial Markets and Fiscal Policy


(Week 11)

Kevin Sheedy
LSE
Winter Term 2024
Fiscal policy
Fiscal policy
• We have studied how monetary policy affects the economy
• But monetary policy may sometimes be ineffective, e.g. at lower bound
• Governments may be able to use fiscal policy as an alternative
• To manage aggregate demand and try to stabilize business cycles
• For example, tax cuts or increased public spending in recessions
• What determines the impact of fiscal policies on real GDP?
• There are some reasons to think the effects might be small:
• Government budget constraint: more debt means higher taxes in the future
• ‘Crowding out’: expansionary fiscal policy raises interest rates, which displaces
private consumption and investment expenditure, reducing overall boost to GDP
• We also explore some reasons why effects might be larger: ‘multipliers’
3
Budget constraints and Ricardian equivalence
• Household present-value budget constraint:
𝐶′
Current taxes cut 𝐶′ 𝑌′ − 𝑇′
𝐶+ =𝑌−𝑇+
from 𝑇1 to 𝑇2 1+𝑟 1+𝑟
• Passes through (𝑌 − 𝑇, 𝑌 ′ − 𝑇 ′ ), shifts right
• Government present-value budget constraint:
1+𝑟 𝐺′ 𝑇′
1 𝐺+ =𝑇+
𝐶 ′∗ 1+𝑟 1+𝑟
• Unless 𝐺 or 𝐺 change, lower 𝑇 means 𝑇 ′ rises

𝑌′ − 𝐺 ′ • Eliminating taxes from two budget constraints:
𝐶′ 𝑌′ − 𝐺 ′
𝑌 ′ − 𝑇1′ 𝐶+ =𝑌−𝐺+
1+𝑟 1+𝑟
𝑌 ′ − 𝑇2′ • 𝑌 − 𝑇, 𝑌 ′ − 𝑇 ′ down and to right; no shift in
budget constraint as (𝑌 − 𝐺, 𝑌 ′ − 𝐺 ′ ) constant

𝐶 • Ricardian equivalence: no change in 𝐶
𝐶∗ 𝑌 − 𝐺 𝑌 − 𝑇1 𝑌 − 𝑇2
• Save tax cut because future taxes higher 4
‘Crowding out’
• Ricardian equivalence does not rule out a direct
𝑟 increase in public spending 𝐺 raising real GDP
• Consider temporary increase in 𝐺 (𝐺 ′ unchanged)
𝑌1𝑠
𝐺↑ 𝑌2𝑠 • Analysis in closed economy: 𝑌 𝑑 = 𝐶 𝑑 + 𝐼 𝑑 + 𝐺
𝐶𝑑 ↓ 𝑁𝑠 ↑ • Higher 𝐺 directly shifts 𝑌 𝑑 rightwards
• But increases tax burden: 𝑇 + 𝑇 ′ /(1 + 𝑟) up
• Wealth effects: Lower 𝐶 𝑑 , higher 𝑁 𝑠
𝑟2 • But only temporary increase in 𝐺, so desire for
𝑟1
consumption smoothing means 𝐶 𝑑 falls by less
𝑌2𝑑
• Overall, 𝑌 𝑑 shifts to the right
𝑌1𝑑
• 𝑌 𝑠 also shifts right (due to wealth effect on 𝑁 𝑠 )
• Increase in 𝐺 boosts GDP 𝑌, but less than 1-for-1
𝑌 • 𝑌 𝑑 shifts by larger amount than 𝑌 𝑠 : 𝑟 rises
𝑌1 𝑌2
• Higher interest rate reduces 𝐶 𝑑 and 𝐼 𝑑
• ‘Crowding out’ effects reduce impact on 𝑌 5
Keynesian multipliers: Aggregate
demand with credit constraints
Aggregate demand multiplier
• Demand shocks affect real GDP 𝑌 in the models seen so far
• Higher GDP means higher income: which means higher
consumption and even higher demand, higher GDP, and so on…?
• But this feedback loop, or ‘multiplier’, did not feature in earlier
analysis of the output demand curve:
• Valid when households do not face credit constraints and level of
employment is socially optimal (meaning 𝑀𝑃𝑁 = 𝑀𝑅𝑆𝑙,𝐶 )
• Under these conditions, only the direct effect of shocks in making households
better off or worse off should matter for consumption demand
• But in New Keynesian model, 𝑀𝑃𝑁 > 𝑀𝑅𝑆𝑙,𝐶 , so more employment and
income is a net gain for households: consumption demand rises with 𝑌
• And credit constraints imply higher 𝑌 makes some households better off 7
Consumption with binding credit constraint
• Assume some households face a binding
𝐶′
maximum borrowing limit :
• Cannot get enough current income to pay for
desired consumption, and cannot borrow
enough against future income
𝑌′ − 𝑇′
• Budget constraint truncated
𝐶 ′∗ • Not all are constrained: some are savers

• For credit-constrained households:


• Current consumption 𝐶 rises 1-for-1
with disposable income 𝑌 − 𝑇
• Diagram shows case where current income 𝑌
Maximum
borrowing
rises, but argument works for tax changes too
• Current consumption does not
𝐶
respond to future taxes 𝑇 ′
𝑌1 − 𝑇 𝑌2 − 𝑇 𝐶1∗ 𝐶2∗ • Ricardian equivalence fails
8
Output demand with multiplier
• Consumption demand 𝐶 𝑑 is now directly a function of income 𝑌
• Sensitivity of 𝐶 𝑑 to higher 𝑌 is marginal propensity to consume (𝑀𝑃𝐶):
𝜕𝐶 𝑑 (𝑌)
𝑀𝑃𝐶 =
𝜕𝑌
• 𝑀𝑃𝐶 for aggregate consumption is a weighted average of the 𝑀𝑃𝐶 of 1
for credit-constrained households and the lower 𝑀𝑃𝐶 of savers
• Output demand in closed economy is 𝑌 𝑑 = 𝐶 𝑑 (𝑌) + 𝐼𝑑 + 𝐺
• Consumption demand 𝐶 𝑑 (𝑌) depends on income 𝑌
• In equilibrium, aggregate income equals aggregate demand: 𝑌 = 𝑌 𝑑
• Plot expenditure function 𝑌 𝑑 against output and income 𝑌
𝜕𝐶 𝑑 (𝑌)
• Gradient is marginal propensity to consume , between 0 and 1
𝜕𝑌 9
Keynesian multiplier effect
• In equilibrium, level of output demand lies
𝑌𝑑
on the 45∘ line where 𝑌 𝑑 = 𝑌
45∘
• Any factors affecting 𝑌 𝑑 other than income
𝑌 shift the expenditure line 𝑌 𝑑 vertically
𝑌2𝑑
Direct effect of
demand shock 𝑌1𝑑 • 𝑀𝑃𝐶 between 0 and 1 boosts effect on 𝑌 𝑑
𝑌2 Direct effect
𝑀𝑃𝐶 Total effect =
1 1 − 𝑀𝑃𝐶
𝑌1
Multiplier • 𝑌 𝑑 curve in (𝑌, 𝑟) space shifts by more
effect horizontally when a demand shock occurs
• Amplifies effect of demand shocks on 𝑌
• Keynesian ‘multiplier’ effect
𝑌
𝑌1 𝑌2 • 𝑌 𝑑 is also now flatter: more sensitive to 𝑟
10
Fiscal policy: Multipliers
versus crowding out
Multipliers versus crowding out
• What might change earlier analysis of weak effect of fiscal policy?
• Supply-side effects of government expenditure on infrastructure:
• If raise current TFP, boost 𝑁 𝑑 and 𝑌 𝑠 ; if raise future TFP, boost 𝐼 𝑑 and 𝑌 𝑑
• 𝑌 𝑑 could shift by more than 𝐺 increases; 𝑌 𝑠 shift is larger than wealth effect
• Some households are credit constrained: multiplier effects on demand
• Prices are sticky and monetary policy is accommodative
• Re-examine fiscal policy with focus on second and third of these
• Temporary increase in government expenditure 𝐺
• Financed by borrowing: no rise in current taxes 𝑇, only higher 𝑇 ′
• Credit-constrained households consume disposable income
• Monetary policy maintains constant real interest rate 𝑟 12
Effects of a fiscal stimulus
• If no credit constraints, horizontal shift of 𝑌 𝑑 is
𝑟 𝑌1𝑠
𝑌2𝑠 smaller than increase of 𝐺
• ‘Crowding out’ due to higher future taxes

𝑟2∗ • With credit-constrained households, shift of 𝑌 𝑑


becomes larger and can exceed increase of 𝐺
𝑟1 𝑀𝑀
• Credit-constrained households have 𝑀𝑃𝐶 of
1 from current disposable income 𝑌 − 𝑇
• Do not react to higher future taxes 𝑇 ′
𝑌2𝑑
• Wealth effect from higher tax burden reduces
𝑌1𝑑 𝐶 𝑑 only for those not credit constrained

𝑌 • Monetary policy holds 𝑟1 constant (no 𝑀𝑀 shift)


𝑌2
𝑌1 • No ‘crowding out’ due to 𝑟 rising to 𝑟2∗
13
Money and public finance
Money and public finance
• Governments derive fiscal advantage from being able to issue fiat
money that is demanded by the private sector
• Unlike bonds, no obligation to ‘repay’ or redeem fiat money
• Money may pay no interest, or if interest is paid (e.g. interest on
reserves 𝑖𝑟 ), the rate can be below the interest rate on bonds (𝑖𝑟 < 𝑖)
• Fiscal gains from issuing money are known as ‘seigniorage’
• These fiscal gains are an implicit tax on holders of money
• How to quantify the size of the fiscal gains arising from different
monetary policies?

15
Printing money
• If the money supply is growing at rate 𝜇 then an amount of new
money 𝜇𝑀 is created in each time period
• If directly used to finance government expenditure, this
seigniorage revenue is directly worth 𝜇𝑀Τ𝑃 in real terms
• Fiscal advantage from ‘printing money’
• This is the simplest and most direct measure of seigniorage
• Though calculation ignores saving of regular interest payments on past
spending that was financed in this way rather than by issuing bonds
• But aside from in hyperinflations, the more typical case is that the
central bank buys assets when new money enters circulation
16
Central-bank investment profits
• Assume first money pays no interest (no interest on reserves),
and all money created by central bank used to buy nominal bonds
• Central bank holds bonds of value 𝑀, matching the supply of money
• CB earns interest 𝑖𝑀 each time period, and with no interest paid on
money or other costs, these are profits paid out to the finance ministry
• Real seigniorage revenues are 𝑖𝑀/𝑃
• This is a flow of seigniorage that is received in each time period
• Different from measure based on value of increase in the money supply
• Even when central bank does not buy assets, 𝑖𝑀/𝑃 still accurately
measures fiscal advantage from steady money supply growth
• Seigniorage is reduction in government borrowing costs by issuing
money rather than bonds: money’s financial return is lower than bonds
17
Limits to size of real seigniorage revenues
𝑀 • As seigniorage arises from money being a less
𝑖
𝑃 good store of value than other assets, it is an
implicit tax on holders of money
• Identical to forgone interest in analysis of
money demand (see Topic 7)
• But if money is a relatively worse store of
value (higher 𝑖) then money demand is lower
• 𝑀𝑑 Τ𝑃 = 𝐿(𝑌, 𝑖) is decreasing in 𝑖
• Real seigniorage revenue = 𝑖𝑀Τ𝑃 = 𝑖𝐿(𝑌, 𝑖)
• Zero for 𝑖 = 0; zero again for very high 𝑖 if
money demand 𝐿(𝑌, 𝑖) falls towards zero
sufficiently fast as 𝑖 increases
• ‘Laffer curve’ for real seigniorage revenues
0
0
𝑖 • Maximum seigniorage revenue at top
18
Another look at central-bank investment profits
• Measure of CB profits 𝑖𝑀/𝑃 assumes no interest is paid on
money, and that CB buys only safe, short-term bonds as assets
• If interest 𝑖𝑟 is paid on reserves then this reduces CB profits:
• If all monetary base pays interest 𝑖𝑟 , CB profits are 𝑖 − 𝑖𝑟 𝑀/𝑃
• Seigniorage eliminated by floor system (𝑖 = 𝑖𝑟 )
• Like following the Friedman rule (𝑖 = 0) when all money is physical cash
• Other CB standing facilities (if used): higher 𝑖𝑏 can raise CB profits
• CB might buy long-term bonds or other risky assets:
• If hold long-term bonds with yield 𝐼, steady-state profits = 𝐼 − 𝑖𝑟 𝑀/𝑃
• Higher average profits if there is a risk premium (𝐼 − 𝑖 > 0)
• But CB makes losses if 𝑖𝑟 rises above yield when bonds were bought
19
The inflation tax
• As well as flows of seigniorage, monetary policy can also lead to
capital gains/losses on nominal bonds such as government debt
• Ex-post real return = past nominal interest rate − actual inflation rate
• With an unpredictable increase in inflation 𝜋 and the nominal interest
rate on existing bonds set in the past, the real value of debt declines
• Fiscal advantage from surprise inflation known as ‘inflation tax’
• Distinct from seigniorage defined earlier (which is only from money)
• Note that inflation-indexed bonds are protected from surprise inflation
• And inflation tax works only for ‘surprise’ inflation: real return protected
from expected inflation as nominal interest rate 𝑖 can adjust in advance
• Though for longer-term nominal bonds, the real return is affected by any
surprises to inflation after issuance of the bond until its maturity is reached
20
Summary
• Effect of fiscal policy on GDP is weakened by ‘crowding out’ of
private consumption and investment spending
• Through anticipation of higher taxes, or through higher interest rates
• However, there can be Keynesian ‘multiplier’ effects that boost
the impact of fiscal policy: higher income raises consumption
• Particularly when many households face binding borrowing constraints
• Monetary policy has implications for the government’s budget:
• Central bank makes profit if money offers lower return than other assets
• However, real seigniorage revenue is limited by the demand to hold money
• Profits can be larger if long-term bonds purchased, but there is a risk of losses
• Real value of nominal bonds eroded by surprise increase in inflation
• Particularly so if government has issued long-term bonds 21

You might also like