14 Melb JIntl L205
14 Melb JIntl L205
https://www.copyright.com/ccc/basicSearch.do?
&operation=go&searchType=0
&lastSearch=simple&all=on&titleOrStdNo=1444-8602
THE INTERNATIONAL LEGAL FRAMEWORK AGAINST
CORRUPTION: ACHIEVEMENTS AND CHALLENGES
The article provides a tour d'horizon of the current international legal framework against
corruption, which has made substantialprogress over the last two decades. Nevertheless, both
the legal framework and its implementation continue to face challenges, some of which must be
addressed to ensure tangible improvements in the struggle against corruption. Part II of the
article sketches the genealogy of the internationallegal framework regardingcorruption, which
was strengthened by the Convention on Combating Bribery of Foreign Public Officials in
International Business Transactions, adopted after United States pressure that followed the
passing of the US Foreign Corrupt Practices Act. Part III outlines the achievements of the main
international anti-corruption instruments, complementing the discussion by highlighting their
main deficiencies. Special attention is paid to the United Nations and Organisationfor Economic
Co-Operation and Development instruments, as well as to the Council of Europe s monitoring
mechanism, the Group of States against Corruption. Asia remains remarkably absent from the
discussion, as the last continent without a regional anti-corruption convention. Anti-corruption
initiatives within the internationalfinancialinstitutions and the most important private initiatives
are also discussed Part IV of the article identifies thematic challenges to the current global
anti-corruption framework: definitional problems and cultural gfi-giving practices;
jurisdictional challenges regarding foreign corruption practices; asset recovery; the link
between corruption and good governance and that between corruption and human rights; and
private sphere corruption.
CONTENTS
* Professor Dr Jan Wouters is Jean Monnet Chair ad personam EU and Global Governance,
Full Professor of International Law and International Organizations and Director of the
Leuven Centre for Global Governance Studies and Institute for International Law at
KU Leuven.
t Professor Dr Cedric Ryngaert is Associate Professor of International Law at KU Leuven and
Utrecht University.
Ann Sofie Cloots is Research Fellow at the Research Foundation Flanders and
PhD candidate at the Leuven Centre for Global Governance Studies and Institute for
International Law at KU Leuven.
205
206 Melbourne Journal of InternationalLaw [Vol 14
'The adoption of the United Nations Convention against Corruption will send a
clear message that the international community is determined to prevent and
control corruption. It will warn the corrupt that betrayal of the public trust will no
longer be tolerated ... The adoption of the new Convention will be a remarkable
achievement. But let us be clear: it is only a beginning'.
Kofi Annan1
I INTRODUCTION
1 United Nations Convention against Corruption, opened for signature 31 October 2003,
2349 UINTS 41 (entered into force 14 December 2005) Foreword ('UNCAC').
2013] The InternationalLegal Framework against Corruption 207
instrument in great detail; this exercise has been done elsewhere. 2 The aim is
rather to give a tour d'horizon of the genealogy and the main achievements,
features and objectives of the existing legal framework and to discuss the
challenges it faces. Part II of this article sketches the genesis of the international
legal framework regarding corruption. Part III outlines the main international
anti-corruption instruments. Special attention will be paid to the United Nations
and Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and Development ('OECD')
instruments, as these have proven especially influential. Next to these
instruments, we will refer to the Group of States against Corruption ('GRECO'),
the monitoring mechanism of the Council of Europe ('CoE'); some other
regional instruments outside Europe; anti-corruption initiatives within
international financial institutions; and a few noteworthy private initiatives. In
Part IV, specific challenges to the current global anti-corruption framework will
be assessed: definitional problems; jurisdictional challenges regarding foreign
corruption practices; asset recovery; the interface between corruption and good
governance and that between corruption and human rights; and private sphere
corruption. At the end, we provide a number of conclusions and present a
number of discussion points.
2 See, eg, Tiziano Balmelli and Bernard Jaggy (eds), Les Traitis Internationaux contre la
corruption: L'ONU, I'OCDE, le Conseil de 1'Europe et la Suisse [International Treaties
against Corruption: The UN, the OECD, the Council of Europe and Switzerland] (Editions
Interuniversitaires Suisse Lausanne, 2004); Indira Carr, 'Fighting Corruption through
Regional and International Conventions: A Satisfactory Solution?' (2007) 15 European
Journal of Crime, Criminal Law and Criminal Justice 121; Daniel Dormoy, La Corruption
et le droit international [Corruption and International Law] (Bruylant, 2010);
Anna-Catharina Marsch, Strukturen der internationalen Korruptionsbektimpfung:
Wie wirksam sind internationale Abkommen? [The Structure of International Law
Combating Corruption: How Effective are International Agreements?] (Tectum Verlag,
2010); Alejandro Posadas, 'Combating Corruption under International Law' (2000) 10 Duke
Journal of Comparative & InternationalLaw 345.
3 See, eg, UNCAC Preamble para 2: 'Concerned also about the links between corruption and
other forms of crime, in particular organized crime and economic crime, including
money-laundering'.
208 Melbourne Journalof InternationalLaw [Vol 14
4 Well-known examples include the corruption allegations against BAE Systems and
Siemens: R (Corner House Research) v Director of the Serious Fraud Office [2009]
1 AC 756 ('BAE Case'); United States v Siemens Aktiengesellschaft (Plea Agreement)
(DC, No 1:08-CR-00367-RJL, 6 January 2009) ('Siemens Plea Agreement'). The corruption
charges against Siemens did not need to be decided at trial because they were resolved via a
plea agreement. In the BAE Case, the United Kingdom's Serious Fraud Office had launched
a criminal investigation into alleged corruption by BAE, who was the main contractor in an
arms contract between the governments of the UK and Saudi Arabia. The House of Lords
held that it was lawful for the investigation to be discontinued because of national interest
considerations, namely the threats to the lives of British citizens if the investigation was to
proceed. See also Indira Carr and Miriam Goldby, 'Recovering the Proceeds of Corruption:
UNCAC and Anti-Money Laundering Standards' (2011) 2 Journal of Business Law 170,
172.
5 Michael Kubiciel, 'Core Criminal Law Provisions in the United Nations Convention against
Corruption' (2009) 9 International Criminal Law Review 139, 140; Philippa Webb, 'The
United Nations Convention against Corruption: Global Achievement or Missed
Opportunity?' (2005) 8 Journal ofInternationalEconomic Law 191, 193.
6 James Thuo Gathii, 'Defining the Relationship between Human Rights and Corruption'
(2009) 31 University ofPennsylvaniaJournal ofInternationalLaw 125, 127, 134-7.
7 Samuel P Huntington, Political Order in Changing Societies (Yale University Press, 1968)
69. Huntington argues that an increase in corruption was a positive signal of a society's
evolution towards modemisation: at 59-62. He links corruption to modernisation in three
ways. First, modernisation implies a distinction between public office and private loyalty
and between public welfare and private interest. It requires meritocratic rewards based on
universalised standards instead of family or other private sphere ties. Huntington argues that
the introduction of achievement-based standards makes reliance on family-based identity
and support even more important, thus enhancing the (ab)use of public functions for private
(family) gain. Secondly, modernisation creates new sources of power and wealth, where the
existing norms have not yet provided for the integration of new groups of economic power
into the political process dominated by those who already held power. Corruption,
Huntington argues, provides a means for such integration, where relevant norms have not
followed the pace of the modernising process. Thirdly, according to Huntington,
modernisation goes hand in hand with centralising government and increased government
intervention, which in turn creates additional opportunities for corruption.
8 Posadas, above n 2, 348. The companies involved in the corruption scandals involved major
players such as Exxon, ITT and Lockheed: Gathii, above n 6, 138.
9 Foreign Corrupt PracticesAct of1977, 15 USC § 78dd-1 (1977) ('FCPA').
2013] The InternationalLegal Framework against Corruption 209
10 Margot Cleveland et al, 'Trends in the International Fight against Bribery and Corruption'
(2009) 90 Journal of Business Ethics 199, 205. Reports varied in their estimates of how
much business was lost annually to non-United States corporations because of the FCPA,
with estimates of up to US$45 billion. The estimate of a US$45 billion loss relates to the
year 1995.
1 Kenneth W Abbott and Duncan Snidal, 'Filling in the Folk Theorem: The Role of
Gradualism and Legalization in International Cooperation to Combat Corruption' (Paper
presented at the American Political Science Association Meeting, Boston, 30 August 2002)
24 <http://www.intemational.ucla.edu/cms/files/DuncanSnidal.pdf>. As Webb indicates,
'[t]he South refused to discuss "demand" side measures like restrictions on solicitation of
bribes and the North resisted linking bribery rules to the proposed UN code of conduct for
multinational corporations': Webb, above n 5, 192.
12 Convention on Combating Bribery of Foreign Public Officials in International Business
Transactions, opened for signature 17 December 1997, [1999] ATS 21 (entered into force
15 February 1999) ('OECD Convention'). See also Carr, above n 2; Posadas, above n 2,
376.
13 Abbott and Snidal, above n 11, 20.
210 Melbourne Journalof InternationalLaw [Vol 14
and potential points of convergence and divergence in their legal systems, which
reduced the legal uncertainty impeding cooperation. Later on, continued
lobbying efforts and the financial support of the US promoted agreement upon
soft law instruments. The Clinton Administration reprioritised the anti-corruption
crusade from 1993 onwards. Other factors played a role as well, such as the
establishment of Transparency International ('TI') by, among others, a former
World Bank Director. TI representatives were given the opportunity to address
the ad hoc OECD Working Group on Bribery in International Business
('Working Group on Bribery'). Its first recommendation, adopted in 1994,
captured the basic principles for an agreement to be reached,14 which were
'locked-in'. In 1997, a second recommendation elaborated on and added to the
basic provisions.' 5 Slowly but steadily, through continued negotiations and
studies by the low profile Working Group on Bribery, the principal challenges
and areas of convergence became clear and the main priorities were outlined.
Acting upon the points of agreement for the priority issues slowly allowed
harmonisation of the various positions. Certain points proved too divisive and
were ultimately excluded, but the OECD Convention eventually crystallised
earlier than the foreseen deadline.
Moral outrage after corruption scandals initially fuelled the enactment of the
US FCPA.1 6 Nevertheless, in due course, the stringent requirements for
US business gave the FCPA a more economic dimension; US efforts to achieve a
global anti-corruption treaty were predominantly aimed at eliminating the
competitive disadvantage of US firms resulting from the FCPA prohibitions. The
US alleged instances of trade distortion caused by corruption in other
World Trade Organization members and requested the WTO to assess and
investigate the link between trade distortion and corruption.' Asian countries
strongly opposed this movel 8 and the WTO eventually refused to accept this
link.19
The decade after the end of the Cold War saw renewed anti-corruption efforts
worldwide. Nevertheless, post-Cold War conditions facilitated corrupt practices
in certain respects. These include, among others:
* the fall of communist regimes without an immediate replacement by
fully democratic and accountable institutions;
* the wave of privatisation and deregulation (though excessive
government intervention facilitates corruption as well); 20 and
* technological evolution facilitating quick communication and money
transfers. 2 1
The discussions on the renewed anti-corruption efforts after the Cold War
mirrored the content of the FCPA, which was at that point the only legal
instrument against transnational bribery. The commercial lens of the FCPA only
prohibits bribery conducted in international business transactions, but was a
significant influence on early discussions. The negotiations on an international
anti-corruption instrument within the OECD were especially influenced by the
example of the FCPA. Indeed, the US economic rhetoric in this area matched the
general OECD focus on economic development: the Preamble to the OECD
Convention refers to the distorting effect of corruption on international business
transactions and the need to assure equivalence of measures between the states
parties. Like the FCPA, the OECD Convention only covers corruption to the
extent it is related to business transactions. Moreover, it only covers active
corruption, which is the promise, offering or giving of a bribe. 22 This seems to
mirror early discussions in the UN, where developing countries focused on the
corrupting effect of the activities of Western corporations. 23 While the
UN discussions were spearheaded by developing countries focusing on active
bribery, the more recent discussions that lead to the 2003 United Nations
Convention against Corruption ('UNCAC') 24 also approached the passive side of
corruption, namely the bribe-takers, who are often public officials from
developing nations. At the same time, in these recent discussions, developing
nations emphasised that any definition should not impose a Western conception
of corruption, 25 which could prohibit certain traditional gift practices in
26
developing countries.
Although limited to corrupt practices in transnational business transactions,
the FCPA and OECD were a useful first step in sparking the debate. However,
the detrimental effects of corruption extend beyond both transnationalbusiness
transactions and business transactions in general. Accordingly, later instruments,
their daily lives. Failure to tackle it may entrench the general mentality that
corruption is simply unavoidable or the 'way things work'.32
While the FCPA and the OECD Convention adopted an economic lens and
focused on the market distorting effects of corruption, 33 this limited approach
slowly but steadily shifted towards a much broader assessment of the problem of
corruption. Thus, the Preamble to the UNCAC refers to the detrimental effects of
corruption on political stability, 34 the rule of law, ethical values and
democracy. 35 Legal scholarship has further clarified the broad societal impacts of
corruption. Antonio Argandofia, for example, refers to the unequal and unjust
redistribution of income and wealth; obstruction to the emancipation of less
favoured groups; loss of legitimacy of policies and institutions; distortion in
decision-making; restriction of citizen rights; the eluding of political and legal
controls; and the undermining of the foundations of the rule of law and the
democratic system. 36
Such a broadened view on the detrimental impact of corruption beyond the
traditional economic notions is also reflected in the Inter-American Convention
against Corruption ('OAS Convention').37 The history of many Latin American
countries - which, at the time, had been recently freed of dictatorial
regimes - caused the Organization of American States ('OAS') to focus much
more on democratic institutions. Corruption was assessed from the perspective
that it was a risk to nascent democracy. Instead of introductory language
referring to the need to level the playing field, the Preamble to the OAS
Convention states that 'corruption undermines the legitimacy of public
institutions and strikes at society, moral order and justice, as well as at the
comprehensive development of peoples'.38
In the World Bank, the focus on anti-corruption efforts was also amplified,
culminating in anti-corruption efforts being integrated in the Bank's
'conditionality' for loans. In the early 1990s, the World Bank became aware of
the fact that a substantial part of its loans were diverted through corrupt
practices. 39 Specific scandals, such as corrupt practices in Kenya involving
World Bank funds, instigated a change of focus at the Bank. 40 Previously, the
World Bank did not want to adopt anti-corruption language as it deemed this
contrary to its charter, which requires it to abstain from political considerations
in its lending practices. 4 1 At the time, one of the World Bank's regional
directors, Peter Eigen, even left the Bank as a result of his disappointment with
the Bank's refusal to tackle anti-corruption through its lending practices (he later
founded TI). 42 Under the presidency of James Wolfensohn - who labelled
corruption a 'cancer' 43 - the World Bank's policy was reversed. Corruption was
integrated into a larger good governance program, 44 launched at the World Bank
and imposed on borrowing countries through the Bank's now famous
conditionality. 45 The World Bank embedded anti-corruption conditionality into
its broader development narrative. Like the World Bank, the International
Monetary Fund ('IMF') was at first reluctant to adhere to the good governance
program, fearing it to be outside of its strictly economic goals. 46 In 1996-97,
however, the IMF acknowledged the economic impact of corruption and good
governance and followed the World Bank by including good governance
standards in its practices. 47 In addition to external anti-corruption policies, the
World Bank and the IMF have adopted internal policies to tackle corruption. 48
Like the multilateral development banks, the UN initially lagged behind in its
anti-corruption legal framework. As described above, the UN had been the initial
forum for multilateral anti-corruption policies but soon saw its negotiations
blocked by divisions between the developed and developing worlds, especially
because of the link made between the anti-corruption negotiations and those on
the international code of conduct for transnational corporations. After this
deadlock, however, the UN took renewed anti-corruption steps in 1996 with the
40 See, eg, Richard Calkins et al, 'Dealing with Governance and Corruption Risks in Project
Lending: Emerging Good Practices' (Note, World Bank, February 2009)
<http:/siteresources.worldbank.org/EXTGOVANTICORR/Resources/3035863-128162713
6986/EmergingGoodPracticesNote_8.11.09.pdf>.
41 International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, IBRD Articles of Agreement
(27 June 2012) World Bank, art IV s 10 <http:/go.worldbank.org/0FICOZQLQ0>.
42 Johnson and Sharma, above n 21, 11.
43 James Wolfensohn, 'People and Development' (Speech delivered at the Annual Meeting of
the World Bank and International Monetary Fund, Washington DC, 1 October 1996)
<http:/go.worldbank.org/PUC5BB8060>.
44 Gathii, above n 6, 127.
45 Johnson and Sharma, above n 21, 11. For an assessment of the effectiveness of the World
Bank and the International Monetary Fund's conditionality, see Stefan Koeberle et al (eds),
Conditionality Revisited: Concepts, Experiences and Lessons (World Bank, 2005).
46 International Monetary Fund, Articles of Agreement of the InternationalMonetary Fund
(3 March 2011) <http://www.imf org/external/pubs/ft/aa/pdf/aa.pdf>.
47 Gathii, above n 6, 145.
48 An assessment of the World Bank's internal anti-corruption policies is provided in
Parthapratim Chanda, 'The Effectiveness of the World Bank's Anti-Corruption Efforts:
Current Legal and Structural Obstacles and Uncertainties' (2004) 32 Denver Journal of
International Law & Policy 315. See also Ngaire Woods, 'The Challenge of Good
Governance for the IMF and the World Bank Themselves' (2000) 28 World Development
823; Carolina Pancotto Bohrer Munhoz, 'Corruption in the Eyes of the World Bank:
Implications for the Institution's Policies and Developing Countries' (2008) 26 Penn State
InternationalLaw Review 691.
2013] The InternationalLegal Framework against Corruption 215
49 Action against Corruption, GA Res 51/59, UN GAOR, 51st sess, 82 nd plen mtg,
Agenda Item 101, Supp No 49, UN Doc A/RES/51/59 (28 January 1997) annex
('InternationalCode of Conductfor Public Officials') ('ICCPO').
50 United Nations Declaration against Corruption and Briberyj in InternationalCommercial
Transactions, GA Res 51/191, UN GAOR, 51st sess, 86 plen mtg, Agenda Item 12,
Supp No 49, UN Doc A/RES/51/191 (21 February 1997) annex
('United Nations Declarationagainst Corruption and Bribery in InternationalCommercial
Transactions') ('UNDAC').
51 See, eg, Committee of Ministers, Council of Europe, Recommendation Rec(2003)4 of the
Committee of Ministers to Member States on Common Rules against Corruption in the
Funding of Political Parties and Electoral Campaigns (8 April 2003) Preamble
('Recommendation Rec(2003)4'). See also Part IV(E) below.
52 Rafael Di Tella and Robert MacCulloch, 'Corruption and the Demand for Regulating
Capitalists' in Susan Rose-Ackerman (ed), InternationalHandbook on the Economics of
Corruption (Edward Elgar, 2006) 352, 352-5. The impact of corruption on economic
growth has, however, differed from country to country. For example, widespread corruption
in China has not prevented the country from achieving impressive economic growth. For
further discussion on the specific case of China: see, eg, Jens Andvig, 'Corruption in China
and Russia Compared: Different Legacies of Central Planning' in Susan Rose-Ackerman
(ed), InternationalHandbook on the Economics of Corruption (Edward Elgar, 2006) 278,
287-313. Some authors, however, challenge this common assumption: see, eg, Anthony
Ogus, 'Corruption and Regulatory Structures' (2004) 26 Law & Policy 329, 329 (stating that
'[i]n fact, the connection between corruption and the lack of growth is more often assumed
than demonstrated'). Ogus suggests that the lack of empirical data may stem from too broad
a definition of 'corruption', rendering it more difficult to link corruption to economic
performance indicators.
53 World Bank, Six Questions on the Cost of Corruption with World Bank Institute Global
Governance DirectorDaniel Kaufmann (2013) <http:/go.worldbank.org/KQH743GKF 1>.
54 See Argandofia, above n 36, 481-2. See also David de la Croix and Clara Delavallade,
'Corruption et allocation optimale de l'investissement public' [Corruption and Optimal
Allocation of Public Investment] (2007) 58 Revue economique 637.
55 Mauro, above n 27, 347.
216 Melbourne Journalof InternationalLaw [Vol 14
1 Background
As indicated above, the UNGA adopted the ICCPO in 1996. The text of the
ICCPO does not explicitly mention corruption - although the term is referred to
several times in the text of Action against Corruption (the resolution adopting
the ICCPO), which recommends that member states use the ICCPO as a tool to
guide their efforts against corruption. 60 However, the ICCPO touches upon very
similar and related issues, such as the receipt of gifts that may influence the
exercise of a public official's function and conflicts of interest.61 In the same
year, the UNDAC was adopted. The UNDAC underlines the need to promote
social responsibility and standards of ethics on the part of companies and
recognises the link between corruption, fair and competitive business and
accountable governance. Member states 'commit' to criminalise bribery of
foreign public officials. Efforts to do so continued through a 1997 UNGA
resolution, which urged member states to ratify the already existing international
anti-corruption instruments. 62 A 1999 UNGA resolution 63 requested an Ad Hoc
Committee to explore the desirability of an international instrument against
corruption, ancillary to or independent of the pre-existing United Nations
Convention against Transnational Organized Crime ('Palermo Convention').64
The Palermo Convention had already recognised the relationship between
transnational organised crime and corruption. 65 After the adoption of the
Palermo Convention, the UNGA redirected the Ad Hoc Committee to draft a
separate convention on corruption, 66 and requested that it adopt a comprehensive
and multidisciplinary approach in order to negotiate a 'broad and effective
convention'.67 The Ad Hoc Committee was officially convened for the first time
in December 2001. After seven sessions, the Committee adopted the final text of
the Palermo Convention in October 2003, two months before the scheduled end
date of its activities. 68
2 Ratification Status
As of 1 January 2013, 165 states, including important global players such as
the US, China and India, have become parties to the UNCAC. This broad
participation can be seen as an indication of widespread global support.
69 These states did ratify the OECD Convention. The report issued by the Organisation for
Economic Co-Operation and Development ('OECD') on Japan's implementation of
anti-corruption measures indicates that Japan still has a very weak legal framework on
anti-corruption: Working Group on Bribery in International Business Transactions,
Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and Development, 'Phase 3 Report on
Implementing the OECD Anti-Bribery Convention in Japan' (Report, Organisation for
Economic Co-Operation and Development, 16 December 2011) <http://www.oecd.org/daf/a
nti-bribery/anti-briberyconvention/Japanphase3reportEN.pdf>. Issued in December 2011,
the report states, that there have only been two convictions since the prohibition of bribery
of foreign public officials was inserted in 1999 in art 10(1) of the E
ILA (#545 19 H&f#M474o Af2 14, 30 H f#M30%) [Unfair
Competition Prevention Law 1993 (Act No 47 of May 19, 1993, as last amended by
Act No 30 of April 30, 2009] (Japan): at 10. For a Group of States against Corruption
('GRECO') report on Germany's anti-corruption efforts, see below n 149. On the role of
Germany vis-a-vis transnational standards against corruption, see Peter Hagell, 'L'Incertaine
mondialisation du contrdle: la France et l'Allemagne dans la lutte contre la corruption et le
blanchiment' [The Uncertain Globalisation of Control: France and Germany in the Fight
against Corruption and Money Laundering] (2005) 29 Deviance et socidtd 243.
70 Council Decision of 25 September 2008 on the Conclusion, on Behalf of the European
Community, of the United Nations Convention against Corruption [2008] OJ L 287/1.
71 Council, Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and Development, Recommendation of
the Council on the Tax Deductibility of Bribes to Foreign Public Officials,
OECD Doc C(96)27/FINAL (11 April 1996); UNCAC art 12.4.
72 UNCAC arts 6-14. While the basic thrust of these provisions is that states parties 'shall'
adopt such measures, this requirement is often weakened by adding qualifiers such as 'in
accordance with the fundamental principles of its domestic law': see, eg, art 13.1.
2013] The InternationalLegal Framework against Corruption 219
reflect the principles of the rule of law, proper management of public affairs and
public property, integrity, transparency and accountability. 73 The basic thrust of
this general provision is the requirement of good governance. 74
International cooperation also received a separate chapter in the UNCAC. 75
Cooperation is mandatory for criminal matters, though for civil and
administrative matters states parties need only 'consider' cooperation. 76
Cooperation from private sector entities such as banks is only to be
encouraged. 77 This is a regrettably weak provision, as cooperation from banks
and other entities is crucial in the recovery of the proceeds of corrupt acts.78
Requiring states parties to cooperate in criminal matters is a necessary but
insufficient condition for effective asset recovery, as banks and other entities will
often need to trigger prosecutions by identifying potentially corrupt transactions
and notifying official authorities of such transactions. The provision on bank
secrecy is more stringent: it requires states parties to ensure that bank secrecy
hurdles can be overcome when conducting corruption investigations. 79 This
mandatory provision does not leave much room to manoeuvre. The same holds
for art 46, which requires states parties to afford each other the widest measure
of mutual legal assistance in the investigation and prosecution of offences
covered by the UNCAC. 80
Asset recovery was a fundamental issue for developing countries during the
negotiations for the UNCAC. 8 1 Its importance is equally reflected in the fact that
a full chapter is dedicated to this topic. 82 Asset recovery is discussed in more
detail below. 83 It can be noted here that the chapter attempts to balance the
insistence by (mostly) developing countries on effective asset recovery with
procedural safeguards requested by (mostly) developed countries. The UNCAC
thus aims to strike a fragile balance: on the one hand, it contains detailed and
strong anti-corruption provisions, which developed countries requested; on the
other hand, developing countries were willing to accept these provisions in return
for strong cooperation and asset recovery provisions. The latter were acceptable
to developed countries on the condition that they were subject to sufficient
procedural safeguards. Article 46 of UNCAC, entitled 'Mutual Legal Assistance',
almost copies verbatim the wording of the mutual legal assistance provision in
the Palermo Convention.84 The latter, in turn, is based on the concomitant
73 UNCA C art5.
74 For a detailed discussion of good governance, see below Part IV(D).
75 UNCAC ch IV.
76 Ibid art 43.1.
77 Ibid art 39.1.
78 See below Part IV(C).
79 UNCAC art 31.77.
80 Ibid art 46.
81 Webb, above n 5, 207.
82 UNCAC ch V.
83 See below Part IV(B).
84 UNCAC art 46; Palermo Convention art 18.
220 Melbourne Journalof InternationalLaw [Vol 14
4 Monitoring
Whilst the UNCAC has introduced some innovations, its monitoring
mechanism is not groundbreaking. 86 It merely establishes a Conference of States
Parties ('the Conference'), to be convened 'regularly' to monitor
implementation. 87 At its third session, held in Doha in November 2009, the
Conference adopted 'Resolution 3/1', entitled 'Review Mechanism'. 88 In this
resolution, the Conference set up an Implementation Review Group. The
monitoring mechanism is conceived as a review cycle, focusing on specific parts
of the UNCAC. States parties must complete a self-assessment checklist
beforehand, which forms the basis for a peer review by two other states parties.
The whole procedure is a desk review, contrary to the anti-corruption
implementation process at the CoE (GRECO), 89 which includes country visits.
So far, only Executive Summaries on France and Togo; 90 Bulgaria and
Indonesia; 9 1 Jordan and Sdo Tome and Principe; 92 Fiji and the US; 93 Croatia and
Morocco; 94 Australia; 95 Georgia; 96 Switzerland; 97 Bangladesh 98 and
85 Convention against Illicit Traffic in Narcotic Drugs and Psychotropic Substances, opened
for signature 20 December 1988, 1582 UNTS 95 (entered into force 11 November 1990)
art 7.
86 Webb, above n 5, 221.
87 UNCAC art63.2.
88 Conference of the States Parties to the United Nations Convention against Corruption,
'Resolution 3/1 - Review Mechanism' in Report of the Conference of the Parties to the
United Nations Convention against Corruption on Its Third Session, Held in Dohafrom 9 to
13 November 2009, UN Doc CAC/COSP/2009/15 (1December 2009) 3.
89 See below Part III(B)(2).
90 Implementation Review Group, Conference of the States Parties, United Nations
Convention against Corruption, Executive Summaries: Note by the Secretariat, 3 rd sess,
Agenda Item 2, UN Doc CAC/COSP/IRG/I/1/1/Add.3 (9 January 2012).
91 Implementation Review Group, Conference of the States Parties, United Nations
Convention against Corruption, Executive Summaries: Note by the Secretariat, 3 rd sess,
Agenda Item 2, UN Doc CAC/COSP/IRG/I/1/1/Add.4 (16 January 2012).
92 Implementation Review Group, Conference of the States Parties, United Nations
Convention against Corruption, Executive Summaries: Note by the Secretariat, 3rd sess,
Agenda Item 2, UN Doc CAC/COSP/IRG/I/1/1/Add.5 (31 January 2012).
93 Implementation Review Group, Conference of the States Parties, United Nations
Convention against Corruption, Executive Summaries: Note by the Secretariat, 3rd sess,
Agenda Item 2, UN Doc CAC/COSP/IRG/I/1/1/Add.6 (23 March 2012).
94 Implementation Review Group, Conference of the States Parties, United Nations
Convention against Corruption, Executive Summaries: Note by the Secretariat, 3rd sess,
Agenda Item 2, UN Doc CAC/COSP/IRG/I/1/1/Add.7 (2 May 2012).
95 Implementation Review Group, Conference of the States Parties, United Nations
Convention against Corruption, Executive Summary: Note by the Secretariat, 3 rd sess,
Agenda Item 2, UN Doc CAC/COSP/IRG/I/2/1 (15 May 2012).
96 Implementation Review Group, Conference of the States Parties, United Nations
Convention against Corruption, Executive Summary: Note by the Secretariat, 3 rd sess,
Agenda Item 2, UN Doc CAC/COSP/IRG/I/2/1/Add. 1(30 May 2012).
97 Groupe d'examen de l'application, Resume analytique: Suisse [Executive Summary:
Switzerland], 3rd sess, Agenda Item 2, UN Doc CAC/COSP/IRG/2012/CRP.4
(18 June 2012).
98 Implementation Review Group, Executive Summary: Note by the Secretariat, 3 rd SCSS,
Agenda Item 2, UN Doc CAC/COSP/IRG/2012/CRP.6 (20 June 2012).
2013] The InternationalLegal Framework against Corruption 221
Timor-Leste 99 have been published. As this country review mechanism has only
recently been launched, its effectiveness and impact remain to be seen. However,
it does not seem to possess the same levels of rigidity as the OECD or CoE
procedures.
B European Instruments
1 European Union
The EU started off with modest anti-corruption instruments that mainly
tackled the misdirection of EU funds in 1995.110 However, the EU broadened its
focus over the course of time, with the final step being a comprehensive two-year
review process of member states' general anti-corruption achievements.
The results of a 2012 EU Corruption Barometer underlined that even in the
EU, the fight against corruption is far from won. 111 According to the results of
the Barometer, 74 per cent of EU citizens thought that corruption remained a
major challenge in their country. Around 1 per cent of EU GDP, or around
C120 billion, is estimated to be lost annually due to corruption. Around 20 to
107 Anti-Corruption Network for Eastern Europe and Central Asia, above n 103, 5.
108 John R Heilbrunn, 'Anti-Corruption Commissions: Panacea or Real Medicine to Fight
Corruption?' (Working Paper, International Bank for Reconstruction and Development,
2004) 9 <http://wbi.worldbank.org/wbi/Data/wbi/wbicms/files/drupal-acquia/wbi/Anti-Corr
uption%2OCommissions%20by%2OJohn%2OHeilbrunn.pdf>.
109 Anti-Corruption Network for Eastern Europe and Central Asia, above n 103, 31-2.
110 On the issue of European Union fraud, see Centre d'etudes pour l'application du droit
communautaire en matiere penale et financiere [Centre for the Study of the Implementation
of Community Law in Criminal and Financial Matters], Corruption de fonctionnaires et
fraude europdenne [Corruption of Public Officials and European Fraud] (Bruylant, Brussels,
1998).
111 See European Commission, 'Commission Fights Corruption: A Stronger Commitment for
Greater Results' (Press Release, IP/11/678, 6 June 2011) <http:/europa.eu/rapid/pres
s-release IP-11-678 en.htm>; European Commission, 'Commission Steps Up Efforts to
Forge a Comprehensive Anti-Corruption Policy at EU Level' (Press Release, MEMO
11/376, 6 June 2011) <http:/europa.eu/rapid/press-releaseMEMO- 11-376_en.htm>;
European Commission, 'Frequently Asked Questions: How Corruption is Tackled at the EU
Level' (Press Release, MEMO 12/105, 15 February 2012) <http:/europa.eu/rapid/pres
s-release MEMO-12-105 en.htm>.
2013] The InternationalLegal Framework against Corruption 223
25 per cent of the value of public contracts is lost to corruption each year. These
numbers are astonishingly high.112
As corruption seriously hinders competition in the internal market, the EU
Parliament could have acted on this legal basis. It opted however for the (more
straightforward) legal basis of providing an area of freedom, security and
justice.113
In 1995, the European Council drew up the Convention on the Protection of
the European Communities' Financial Interests ('EU Convention').114 The
EU Convention covers the misappropriation of EU funds through fraudulent
statements or false documents. One year later, in 1996, a Protocol to the
Convention on the Protection of the European Communities' FinancialInterests
('Financial Interests Protocol') was drawn up.11 5 The Financial Interests
Protocol contains definitions of, and harmonised penalties for, offences of
corruption. In 1997, the Convention on the Fight against Corruption involving
Officials of the European Communities or Officials of Member States of the
European Union was drawn up.11 6 On 22 July 2003, the European Council
adopted Council Framework Decision 2003/568/JHA on Combating Corruption
in the Private Sector," 7 covering business activities within profit and non-profit
entities (excluding, for example, non-business activities of non-governmental
organisations ('NGOs'), sports clubs, etc).
In a decision of October 2008, the European Council set up a network of
contact points of the member states, in order to improve cooperation between
authorities in combating corruption in Europe.118 Furthermore, the Stockholm
Programme provides an EU roadmap for 2010-14 in the area of justice, freedom
and security, referencing anti-corruption outcomes as one of its goals.119
However, the EU realised that the various anti-corruption instruments were
rather fragmented and that success on this issue would be enhanced by
streamlining a coherent anti-corruption policy in all its activities. In addition,
reports that corruption worsened in certain newly acceded member states after
accession strengthened the view that the EU needs to maintain a vigorous
anti-corruption oversight that goes beyond merely imposing anti-corruption
112 For an assessment of corruption in the EU, see Luis Antonio Trejo Fuentes, 'Corrupcion y
desigualdad en la Union Europea' [Corruption and Inequality in the European Union]
(2010) 37 Revista de Estudios Sociales 106.
113 See, eg, Council Framework Decision 2003/568/JHA of 22 July 2003 on Combating
Corruption in the Private Sector [1993] OJ L 192/54, 54 [6].
114 Council Act of 26 July 1995 Drawing up the Convention on the Protection of the European
Communities'FinancialInterests [1995] OJ C 316/48.
115 Council Act of 27 September 1996 Drawing up a Protocol to the Convention on the
Protection of the European Communities' Financial Interests [1996] OJ C 313/1.
The protocol entered into force on 17 October 2002.
116 Convention Drawn Up on the Basis ofArticle K3(2)(c) of the Treaty on European Union on
the Fight against Corruption Involving Officials of the European Communities or Officials
ofMember States of the European Union [1997] OJ C 195/2.
117 Council Framework Decision 2003/568/JHA on Combating Corruption in the Private
Sector [2003] OJ L 192/54.
118 Council Decision 2008/852/JHA of 24 October 2008 on a Contact-PointNetwork against
Corruption [2008] OJ L 301/38.
119 The Stockholm Programme - An Open and Secure Europe Serving and Protecting Citizens
[2010] OJ C 115/1.
224 Melbourne Journalof InternationalLaw [Vol 14
120 Suzanne Mulcahy, 'Money, Politics, Power: Corruption Risks in Europe' (National System
Integrity Assessment Report, Transparency International, 6 June 2012) 3. Mulcahy refers in
particular to the Czech Republic, Hungary and Slovakia.
121 European Commission, 'Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the
Council on Public Procurement' (Proposal No COM(2011) 896 final, 20 December 2011)
art 55.1(b). See also European Commission, 'Proposal for a Regulation of the European
Parliament and of the Council on the Access of Third-Country Goods and Services to the
Union's Internal Market in Public Procurement and Procedures Supporting Negotiations on
Access of Union Goods and Services to the Public Procurement Markets of Third Countries'
(Proposal No COM(2012) 124 final, 21 March 2012).
122 European Commission, 'Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament,
the Council and the European Economic and Social Committee: Fighting Corruption in the
EU' (Communication No COM(2011) 308 final, 6 June 2011).
123 Ibid 3-4.
124 Ibid 6-8.
125 Ibid 4.
126 Ibid 6.
127 Ibid 7.
128 European Commission, 'Commission Steps Up Efforts to Forge a Comprehensive
Anti-Corruption Policy at EU Level', above n 111.
129 European Commission, 'Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament,
the Council and the European Economic and Social Committee: Participation of the
European Union in the Council of Europe Group of States against Corruption (GRECO)'
(Communication No COM(2012) 604 final, 19 October 2012).
130 European Commission, 'Proposal for a Directive of the European Parliament and of the
Council on the Freezing and Confiscation of the Proceeds of Crime in the European Union'
(Proposal No COM(2012) 85 final, 12 March 2012).
2013] The InternationalLegal Framework against Corruption 225
2 Council of Europe
As is known, the general focus of the CoE is on the development of common
and democratic principles in Europe, as well as on the rule of law and human
rights.131
On 6 November 1997, the Committee of Ministers of the CoE adopted the
Twenty Guiding Principlesfor the Fight against Corruption.132 These guidelines
set out a broad spectrum of anti-corruption measures, such as limiting immunity
for corruption charges, denying tax deductibility for bribes, ensuring free media
and preventing the shielding of legal persons from liability.
The Criminal Law Convention was adopted by the CoE in early 1999 and has
been ratified by 43 states.1 33 An Additional Protocol to the Criminal Law
Convention on Corruption was adopted in May 2003;134 it has been ratified by
31 states and signed by an additional 11 states.135 The CriminalLaw Convention
aims to harmonise the definition of a certain type of corruption, namely that of
public officials. Such harmonisation, as stated by the Explanatory Report that
accompanied the CriminalLaw Convention,136 would more easily allow for the
requirement of dual criminality to be met by the states parties.
The Civil Law Convention on Corruption ('Civil Law Convention') was
adopted on 4 November 1999 and entered into force four years later.137 It has
138 The Civil Law Convention has been ratified by the following member states of the CoE:
Albania, Armenia, Austria, Azerbaijan, Belgium, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Bulgaria,
Croatia, Cyprus, the Czech Republic, Estonia, Finland, France, Georgia, Greece, Hungary,
Latvia, Lithuania, the former Yugoslav Republic of Macedonia, Malta, Moldova,
Montenegro, the Netherlands, Norway, Poland, Romania, Serbia, Slovakia, Slovenia, Spain,
Sweden, Turkey and Ukraine. Moreover, it has been ratified by one non-member state,
namely Belarus. It has been signed, but not yet ratified, by the following member states:
Andorra, Denmark, Germany, Iceland, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg and the UK.
139 Committee of Ministers, Council of Europe, Recommendation No R 2000(10) of the
Committee of Ministers to Member States on Codes of Conduct for Public Officials
(11 May 2000).
140 Recommendation Rec(2003)4, above n 51.
141 Committee of Ministers, Council of Europe, Resolution 99(5) Establishing the Group of
States against Corruption (GRECO) (1 May 1999) app ('Statute of the GRECO').
142 Ibid art 2.
143 Ibid art 1.
144 Ibid art 4(2).
145 Criminal Law Convention art 24; Civil Law Convention art 14.
146 European Commission, 'Commission Fights Corruption', above n 111.
2013] The InternationalLegal Framework against Corruption 227
147 Group of States against Corruption, Council of Europe, Rules of Procedure (adopted
4-6 October 1999, last amended 15-19 October 2012) r 32.
148 The Additional Protocol has not been ratified by Andorra, Austria, Belarus, the Czech
Republic, Estonia, Georgia, Germany, Hungary, Italy, Malta, Mexico, Monaco, Poland,
Portugal, Russia, San Marino, Turkey or the US.
149 A 2011 GRECO compliance report on Germany indicates that Germany is awaiting
amendments to its Strafgesetzbuch [Criminal Code] before it can ratify the Criminal Law
Convention and its Additional Protocol: Group of States against Corruption, Council of
Europe, 'Third Evaluation Round: Compliance Report on Germany' (Report,
9 December 2011) 2-3, 15 ('GRECO Compliance Report'). The report indicates that the
German government 'is, in principle, still aiming for such ratification': at 2-3. However, the
report continues that no concrete steps on such amendments or steps to ratification have
been seen and GRECO 'very much regrets' that Germany, one of its founding members, has
not yet ratified the Criminal Law Convention or its Additional Protocol: at 3, 15.
150 Argentina, Australia, Austria, Belgium, Brazil, Bulgaria, Canada, Chile, Colombia,
the Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary,
Iceland, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Japan, Korea, Luxembourg, Mexico, Netherlands,
New Zealand, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Russia, Slovakia, Slovenia, South Africa, Spain,
Sweden, Switzerland, Turkey, the UK and the US.
151 Working Group on Bribery in International Business Transactions, Organisation for
Economic Co-Operation and Development, 'Commentaries on the Convention on
Combating Bribery of Foreign Public Officials in International Business Transactions'
(21 November 1997) in Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and Development,
Convention on Combating Bribery of Foreign Public Officials in International Business
Transactions and Related Documents, OECD Doc DAFFE/IME/BR(97)20
(8 April 1998) 12, 12 [2] ('OECD Convention Commentaries').
152 Non-member states may become parties to the OECD Convention on the condition that they
become full participants in the OECD Working Group on Bribery in International Business
Transactions ('Working Group on Bribery'): OECD Convention art 13.
228 Melbourne Journalof InternationalLaw [Vol 14
In addition, the OAS adopted model laws, such as those on norms of conduct
for public officials168 and access to administrative information.1 69
The OAS Convention does not include any monitoring mechanism, merely
requiring states parties to set up oversight bodies.170 In 2002, eight years after the
adoption of the OAS Convention, a monitoring mechanism (the Mechanism for
Follow-Up on the Implementation of the Inter-American Convention against
Corruption)was set up.171 It is based on rounds of mutual evaluation.
3 African Instruments
The African continent has not been spared from the scourge of corruption
either. Certain authors trace endemic patterns of corruption in Africa back to the
colonial era, which dismantled traditional checks and balances in favour of the
colonial centralisation of power.172 Several anti-corruption initiatives have been
introduced on the African continent, but their effectiveness is yet to be proven,
according to NGO watchdog TI.173
The African Union Convention on Preventing and Combating Corruption
('A U Convention') was adopted in Maputo, Mozambique on 11 July 2003 and
entered into force approximately three years later.174 As of 1 January 2013, 45
states have signed the AU Convention and 31 have ratified it.
The A U Convention provides for an Advisory Board, comprised of 11 experts,
to monitor implementation.1 75 The first Advisory Board was established in 2009.
So far, it has focused merely on establishing its own organisational structure. The
2011-2015 Strategic Plan provided for an additional two-year period for
'building its organizational efficiency'.176 No country reviews have taken place
yet and the Strategic Plan describes the role of the Advisory Board as that of a
think tank.177 The monitoring role is only one of the Advisory Board's goals.
Reflecting the corruption discussions in the UN in the 1960s and 1970s that were
tied to the negotiations of a code of conduct for TNCs,178 another goal is to
'collect information and analyze the conduct and behavior of multi-national
D Anti-CorruptionInitiatives in InternationalFinancialInstitutions
1 World Bank
Since 1996, anti-corruption efforts have been integrated into the World
Bank's good governance conditionality.18 8 Corruption was no longer seen as a
purely economic problem of levelling the playing field for transnational business
transactions, as the FCPA and the OECD Convention had done, but as a serious
impediment to a society's general development. The World Bank's method for
195 The World Bank Group, 'Living Our Values: Code of Conduct' (World Bank, 2009)
40 <http:/siteresources.worldbank.org/INTETHICS/Resources/WorldBank Group Co
de Of Conduct 11_06_09.pdf>.
196 Ibid.
197 See, eg, Johnson and Sharma, above n 21, 14.
198 Ibid.
199 Jasmine Martirossian, 'Russia and Her Ghosts of the Past' in Roberta Ann Johnson (ed),
The Struggle against Corruption: A Comparative Study (Palgrave Macmillan, 2004) 81, 95.
200 The authors would like to thank an anonymous referee for this valuable comment.
201 World Bank, Frequently Asked Questions: About INT (30 November 2009) <http://web.worl
dbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/EXTABOUTUS/ORGANIZATION/ORGUNITS/EXTD
011/0,,contentMDK:20520936~menuPK:588945~pagePK:64168445~piPK:64168309~theSi
tePK:588921,00.html>.
202 Working Group on Bribery in International Business Transactions, Organisation for
Economic Co-Operation and Development, 'The Netherlands: Phase 2 - Report on the
Implementation of the Phase 2 Recommendations - Application of the Convention on
Combating Bribery of Foreign Public Officials in InternationalBusiness Transactionsand
the 1997 Revised Recommendation on Combating Bribery in International Business
Transactions' (Report, Directorate for Financial and Enterprise Affairs, Organisation for
Economic Co-Operation and Development, 17 December 2008) 4 [6] <http://www.oe
cd.org/netherlands/41919004.pdf> ('Netherlands Phase 2 Follow-Up Report').
234 Melbourne JournalofInternationalLaw [Vol 14
The World Bank publishes a list of debarred individuals and firms on its
website. The current list covers individuals and entities from a very wide variety
of countries, including Australia, Bulgaria, China, the Democratic Republic of
Congo, France, Germany, India, Indonesia, Iraq, Mexico, Morocco, Russia,
Uganda, the US, Vietnam and many more. 203 A cross-barring agreement is in
place between the various multilateral development banks, 204 which greatly
facilitates the delisting of fraudulent entities and individuals. It would be useful
to consider a similar cross-barring agreement between national anti-corruption
bodies. The impact of debarment policies depends on the number of individuals
and entities engaged in corrupt practices that are covered by the debarment, as
well as their calibre. 205
2 Other MultilateralFinancialInstitutions
With the World Bank taking on the pioneering role, the other multilateral
financial institutions followed suit. The policies of each of the individual
institutions cannot be described in detail. Suffice it to say that all of these
institutions have in some way addressed the problem of corruption, adopting
policies for both internal and/or external corrupt practices. 206
E Private Initiatives
1 Transparency International
Established by a former World Bank Director in 1993, the NGO TI has been a
driving force behind the global anti-corruption movement. Its most influential
anti-corruption tool is the Corruption Perception Index ('CPI'). The CPI ranks
countries according to the perceived level of corruption, based on polls of
203 World Bank, World Bank Listing on Ineligible Firms & Individuals (2013)
<http://web.worldbank.org/external/default/main?theSitePK=84266&contentMDK=640698
44&menuPK=1 16730&pagePK=64148989&piPK=64148984>.
204 Agreement for Mutual Enforcement of Debarment Decisions, signed 9 April 2010 (entered
into by the World Bank Group, Asian Development Bank, African Development Bank
Group, the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development and the Inter-American
Development Bank).
205 The authors would like to thank an anonymous referee for underlining this point.
206 See, eg, European Bank of Reconstruction and Development, 'Anti-Corruption
Report - 2010' (Report, 31 December 2010); European Bank of Reconstruction and
Development, 'Revised Enforcement Policy and Procedures' (Policy Document,
2 December 2011) <http://www.ebrd.com/downloads/integrity/epp.pdf>; Salvatore
Schiavo-Campo et al, 'Mid-Term Evaluation of IDB-9 Commitments: Combating Fraud and
Corruption' (Background Paper, Inter-American Development Bank Office of Evaluation
and Oversight, March 2013) annex A ('Action Plan to Support Countries in Their Effort to
Fight Corruption and Foster Transparency'); Asian Development Bank,
'Anticorruption - Our Framework Policies and Strategies', above n 29; Anti-Corruption
Initiative for Asia and the Pacific, 'Anti-Corruption Policies in Asia and the Pacific: Legal
and Institutional Reform in 25 Countries' (Asian Development Bank/Organisation for
Economic Co-Operation and Development, 2007); Asian Development Bank/Organisation
for Economic Co-Operation and Development Anti-Corruption Initiative for Asia and the
Pacific, 'Anti-Corruption Action Plan for Asia and the Pacific' (30 November 2001)
<http://www.oecd.org/site/adboecdanticorruptioninitiative/meetingsandconferences/350216
42.pdf>.
2013] The InternationalLegal Framework against Corruption 235
207 Theresa Thompson and Anwar Shah, 'Transparency International's Corruption Perception
Index: Whose Perceptions are They Anyway?' (Discussion Draft Working Paper,
March 2005) 12 <http:/siteresources.worldbank.org/INTWBIGOVANTCOR/Resources/
TransparencyInternationalCorruptionIndex.pdf>. For an in-depth analysis of anti-corruption
indicators, see Francisco-Javier Urra, 'Assessing Corruption: An Analytical Review of
Corruption Measurement and Its Problems: Perception, Error and Utility' (Working Paper,
Georgetown University, May 2007) <http://unpanl.un.org/intradoc/groups/public/document
s/apcity/unpan028792.pdf>; Johann Graf Lambsdorff, 'Measuring Corruption - The
Validity and Precision of Subjective Indicators (CPI)' in Charles Sampford et al (eds),
Measuring Corruption (Ashgate, 2006) 81. See also Guillaume Louis, 'De l'Opacite a la
transparence: les limites de l'indice de perceptions de la corruption de Transparency
International' [From Opacity to Transparency: The Limits of the Corruption Perceptions
Index of Transparency International] (2007) 31 Deviance et socidtd 41.
208 Thompson and Shah, above n 207, 3.
209 Lambsdorff, above n 207, 87.
210 Thompson and Shah, above n 207, 20.
211 Lambsdorff, above n 207, 82.
212 The methodology is described on TI's website: Transparency International, Corruption
Perceptions Index 2012: Frequently Asked Questions (2012) <http://www.transparency.or
g/cpi2012/in-detail>.
213 Lambsdorff, above n 207, 83.
214 Netherlands Phase 2 Follow-Up Report, above n 202. The OECD phase 2 follow-up report
on Belgium indicated that Belgium did not intend to set up a whistleblower system in the
private sector, as the previous report had recommended: Working Group on Bribery in
International Business Transactions, Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and
Development, 'Belgium: Phase 2 - Follow-Up Report on the Implementation of the Phase
2 Recommendations on the Applications of the Convention and the 1997 Revised
Recommendation on Combating Bribery of Foreign Public Officials in International
Business Relations' (Report, Directorate for Financial and Enterprise Affairs, Organisation
for Economic Co-Operation and Development, 10 January 2008) 3 [4] <http://www.oecd.or
g/investment/anti-bribery/anti-briberyconvention/39937450.pdf> ('Belgium Phase 2
Follow-Up Report').
215 On the stigmatisation critique: see, eg, David Kennedy, 'The International Anti-Corruption
Campaign' (1999) 14 Connecticut Journal of InternationalLaw 455. In Kennedy's view,
'the anti-corruption campaign transforms the politically or ideologically contestable into the
technically necessary and the morally imperative': at 462.
236 Melbourne Journalof InternationalLaw [Vol 14
Notwithstanding these critiques, the individual country scores are widely quoted
in the international press and publications on the issue of corruption. 216
In addition to the CPI, TI publishes a Bribe Payers Index ('BPI') and a Global
Corruption Barometer ('GCB'). The GCB is based on surveys of more than
100 000 people in 100 countries and does not provide a ranking. 217 This renders
the uptake more limited than that of the CPI. The BPI provides a ranking of
leading exporting countries according to the perceived likelihood of their firms
to bribe abroad. It is based on a survey of business executives focusing on the
business practices of foreign firms in their country. 218 As is the case for the CPI,
data for the BPI stem from different survey conductors, using different interview
methods (phone, face-to-face, etc).
216 Christiane Arndt and Charles Oman, Uses and Abuses of Governance Indicators (OECD
Publishing, 2006) 25.
217 See Transparency International, Global Corruption Barometer (2013) <http:/gcb.transpar
ency.org/gcb201011 />.
218 The 2011 Bribe Payers Index ('BPI') was based on questionnaires filled in by firms in
Argentina, Austria, Brazil, Chile, China, the Czech Republic, Egypt, France, Germany,
Ghana, Hong Kong, Hungary, India, Indonesia, Japan, Malaysia, Mexico, Morocco, Nigeria,
Pakistan, Philippines, Poland, Russia, Senegal, Singapore, South Africa, South Korea,
Turkey, the UK and the US: Deborah Hardoon and Finn Heinrich, 'Bribe Payers Index
2011' (Report, Transparency International, 2011) 25.
219 ICC Commission on Corporate Responsibility and Anti-Corruption, ICC Rules on
Combating Corruption (International Chamber of Commerce, first published 1977, 2011 ed)
('ICC Rules').
220 Ibid.
221 John Ruggie, Report of the Special Representative of the Secretary-General on the Issue of
Human Rights and Transnational Corporations and Other Business Enterprises: Guiding
Principles on Business and Human Rights - Implementing the United Nations 'Protect,
Respect and Remedy'Framework, UN Doc A/HRC/17/31 (21 March 2011) annex ('Guiding
Principles on Business and Human Rights: Implementing the United Nations 'Protect,
Respect and Remedy' Framework') ('UN Guiding Principles').
222 ICC Rules, above n 219, art 3.F. A link could be made with the UN Guiding Principles.If it
can indeed be seen as good commercial practice for companies to ensure respect for the
human rights that may be impacted on by corrupt acts, then deviation from the ICC Rules
would arguably constitute a potential breach of a company's due diligence obligation to
respect human rights.
223 Ibid art 3.E.
2013] The InternationalLegal Framework against Corruption 237
3 Other Fora
Freedom House is a Washington-based NGO which focuses on several issues,
including corruption. 224 Its main focus is, however, on freedom of the press. Its
research on corruption is less disseminated than that of TI.
Another forum for anti-corruption discussions is the World Economic Forum
('WEF'),225 a Geneva-based NGO funded by business membership
contributions. In 2004, the WEF launched the Partnering against Corruption
Initiative ('PAC'), a voluntary code of conduct initiative that member
corporations can elect to join.226 PACI calls for signatory companies to adopt a
zero-tolerance policy on bribery. 227 Its dual monitoring system combines
self-evaluation with external verification.
IV CHALLENGES
Notwithstanding a surge in awareness and a plethora of international
initiatives, many hurdles remain on the road towards a corruption-free world. To
start with, there is no agreement as to what exactly constitutes corruption.
Different countries and actors apply differing definitions. Even where agreement
exists as to a corrupt act, jurisdictional problems may impede prosecution.
Moreover, even after a successful legal challenge of corrupt acts, the process of
asset recovery needs to overcome several legal and logistical hurdles in order to
be successful. In addition, the link between corruption and good
governance - and between corruption and human rights - remains the subject
of intense debate.
A Definition
1 'Corruption'and 'Bribery'
As the ExplanatoryReport to the CoE's CriminalLaw Convention states,
[p]ossible definitions have been discussed for a number of years in different fora
but it has not been possible for the international community to agree on a
common definition. Instead, international fora have preferred to concentrate on
the definition of certain forms of corruption. 228
Bribery is the most well-known form of corruption, although it is only one
type. While the concrete wording of the definition differs slightly, it is generally
229 An almost identical definition is given in the CoE Criminal Law Convention art 2. The
definition in art VI of the OAS Convention is also very similar: the solicitation or
acceptance, or the offering or granting, directly or indirectly, by, or to, a government official
or a person who performs public functions, of any article of monetary value, or other
benefit, such as a gift, favour, promise or advantage for him- or herself or for another person
or entity, in exchange for any act or omission in the performance of his or her public
functions. Article 1.1 of the OECD Convention applies a similar definition, though limited
in its scope to active bribery of foreign public officials: namely to offer, promise or give any
undue pecuniary or other advantage, whether directly or through intermediaries, to a foreign
public official, for that official or for a third party, in order that the official act or refrain
from acting in relation to the performance of official duties, in order to obtain or retain
business or other improper advantage in the conduct of international business.
230 Johnson and Sharma, above n 21, 2.
231 Christine S Cheng and Dominik Zaum, 'Selling the Peace? Corruption and Post-Conflict
Peacebuilding' in Christine S Cheng and Dominik Zaum (eds), Corruption and
Post-Conflict Peacebuilding:Selling the Peace? (Routledge, 2012) 1, 4.
232 Ibid.
233 Ibid.
2013] The InternationalLegal Framework against Corruption 239
definition of 'corruption' focuses on the abuse of public office for private gain, it
cannot easily be applied to corporate corruption, where no public office is
involved and where there may only be a gain for the company, not for the
individual employee. 234
2 FacilitationPayments
Even though the international community seems to agree that, at least, bribery
should be covered by international corruption instruments, there is no agreement
as to whether facilitation payments (also called 'grease payments') are a form of
bribery. These are payments made to speed up a certain procedure or decision,
which would have eventually been completed or made anyway. If bribery covers
only payments or other undue advantages made in order to change the behaviour
of a public official (that is, to make the official act or refrain from acting), then
facilitation payments do not fit into that definition. Even if they are seen as
corrupt acts, certain international instruments have provided exceptions for such
payments.
The FCPA excludes facilitation payments from its scope.235 The (voluntary)
ICC Rules state by way of principle that facilitation payments should not be
made. 236 However, they recognise that companies 'may be confronted with
exigent circumstances, in which the making of a facilitation payment can hardly
be avoided, such as duress or when the health, security or safety of the
enterprise's employees are at risk'.237 In such case, the ICC Rules recommend
that such payments be accurately reflected in the books. 238 The OAS Convention
does not exclude grease payments from its scope. The commentaries on the
Convention on Combating Bribery of Foreign Public Officials in International
Business Transactions ('OECD Convention Commentaries') clarify that
facilitation payments are not made 'to obtain or retain business', hence are
excluded from the OECD Convention's scope. 239 This exclusion reflects the
OECD Convention's aim to tackle corruption as a distortion of free
competition - grease payments, in this view, do not distort competition. 240
The argument that facilitation payments are not made to 'obtain or retain'
business - and therefore fall outside of the scope of the OECD Convention - is
too positivistic a view. This technical legal argument ignores the broader
consequences of facilitation payments. For example, even though a company
would receive a permit in the absence of the payment, the fact that it receives it
earlier when a payment is made should be seen as altering (advancing) its
business operations, thus helping it to 'obtain or retain' business in the broad
sense. The OECD Convention Commentaries do acknowledge that such
facilitation payments should be eradicated, but state that 'criminalisation by
241 OECD Convention Commentaries, OECD Doc DAFFE/IME/BR(97)20, 13 [9] (on art 1
para 1 of the OECD Convention).
242 European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, 'Fraud and Corruption - Definitions
and Guidelines for Private Sector Operations' in European Bank for Reconstruction and
Development, Accountability, Integrity and Anti-Corruption (2012) <http://www.ebr
d.com/pages/about/integrity.shtml>.
243 Kubiciel, above n 5, 154.
244 Alexandra Addison Wrage, 'The High Cost of Small Bribes' (Guidebook, TRACE
International, 2009) 3, 8, 16 <https:/secure.traceintemational.org/data/public/TheHighC
ost of Small Bribes_2-65416-1.pdf>.
245 Cleveland et al, above n 10, 222.
246 FCPA § 78dd-1(c), as amended by Omnibus Trade and Competitiveness Act of 1988,
Pub L No 100-418, § 5003(a), 102 Stat 1106, 1415 (1988).
247 Ibid.
2013] The InternationalLegal Framework against Corruption 241
not respect certain local gift-giving traditions. 248 The Philippines, for example,
opposed the US demarches at the WTO with a reference to 'unique cultures and
traditions' requiring due respect. 249
Along the lines of the Philippines' objection, certain authors stress that any
definition of 'corruption' should allow the accommodation of cultural
differences. They argue for a relative definition, along the lines of that given by
Arnold Heidenheimer, who, broadly speaking, defines corruption as whatever the
public perceives it to be. 250 India, for example, has for a long time been
organised along caste lines with a high importance attached to interpersonal
relations. Some authors have argued that such cultural background gives notions
of nepotism and corruption a different meaning in, in this case, India, than it has
in industrialised Western countries. 251 Imposing a one-sided Western definition
of 'corruption' implies that 'citizens of less-developed countries are indeed
somewhat one-sidedly exposed to the easy moral judgments of citizens of more
developed societies'.252 Moreover, it is claimed that corruption during the
transition phase of a traditional society towards modernisation can actually
empower previously disadvantaged groups. Where they are disproportionately
disadvantaged on the economic and political fronts, corruption by these groups
may allow them to seize the power from which they had previously been
excluded. 253 The UNCAC's flexible reference to an 'undue advantage' 254 reflects
this concern of moral imperialism. Different countries proposed different
definitions of corruption - hence the decision to not formulate any one
definition in the UNCAC. Certain provisions of the UNCAC, however, provide
definitions for specific types of corruption. 255 The Explanatory Report to the
CoE Criminal Law Convention equally reflects the moral imperialist objection
and excludes socially acceptable gifts from its coverage.2 56 The
248 Cleveland et al, above n 10, 206-7; Kim and Kim, above n 164, 551.
249 Gantz, above n 16, 467. See also Nichols, above n 19, 365, citing 'Philippines Rejects US
Proposal for WTO Accord on Bribery, Corruption' (1996) 13 InternationalTrade Reporter
880. In addition, certain countries called the efforts to have anti-corruption standards
enforced through the WTO a form of protectionism: see Kim and Kim, above n 164.
250 Arnold J Heidenheimer, 'Perspectives on the Perception of Corruption' in
Arnold J Heidenheimer and Michael Johnston (eds), Political Corruption:
Concepts & Contexts (Transaction Publishers, 3 rd ed, 2002) 141, 143, 152. See also
Maya Chadda, 'India: Between Majesty and Modernity' in Roberta Ann Johnson (ed), The
Struggle against Corruption:A Comparative Study (Palgrave Macmillan, 2004) 109, 123.
251 Arnold J Heidenheimer, 'Perspectives on the Perception of Corruption' in
Arnold J Heidenheimer, Michael Johnston and Victor T LeVine (eds), PoliticalCorruption:
A Handbook (Transaction Publishers, 1989) 149, 162; Chadda, above n 250, 123.
252 Kubiciel, above n 5, 145.
253 Huntington, above n 7, 64.
254 UNCAC art 15.
255 For example, bribery of national public officials (art 15), trading in influence (art 18), abuse
of functions (art 19) and illicit enrichment (art 20).
256 Council of Europe, Criminal Law Convention on Corruption: Explanatory Report,
above n 136, [38]. It can be noted that entrenched patterns of gift-giving are not necessarily
traditions in the sense of 'accepted' social practices. The line should be drawn between
entrenched patterns of corrupt practices and gift-giving that reflects longstanding cultural
traditions.
242 Melbourne Journalof InternationalLaw [Vol 14
OECD Convention Commentaries, on the other hand, clarify that the OECD
Convention prohibits advantages regardless of perceptions of local customs. 257
The tension between a transnational definition and the call for cultural
sensitivities is not necessarily insurmountable. The traditional definition of
'corruption' is generally formulated as the offering, promising or giving (or the
request or receipt) of an undue advantage to (or by) a public official to act or
refrain from acting in the exercise of their functions. An undue advantage
implies that the official would have acted differently in the absence of the
advantage. The advantage is thus linked to an official's specific behaviour.
Cultural gift-giving practices, however, are deemed to be a matter of social
courtesy: they do not necessarily constitute corruption as they are not aimed to
alter a specific act of a public official. Hence, even the traditional definition of
'corruption' could allow for the exclusion of social courtesy practices. But this
thin line between corruption and social courtesy leaves a degree of legal
uncertainty. The assessment of an undue advantage is based on a more
straightforward criterion: would the public official have behaved differently
without the bribe? To assess a social courtesy, courts need to resort to a variety
of factors, such as what the socially accepted practice is 25 8 and whether the
amount of the payment or level of advantage stays within the limits of that
practice.
The local law exception of the FCPA brings further legal certainty: there is no
corrupt practice if the act is allowed under the written law of the host country.
However, this formulation ignores the fact that social courtesy practices are often
not explicitly permitted by written laws. Hence, the question of informal social
courtesy practices remains unanswered.
The Supreme Court of Korea has, on several occasions, ruled on the question
of traditional ttokkap ('rice-cake') expenses. 259 The Court's approach reflects a
healthy dose of pragmatism. On the one hand, it strictly upholds anti-corruption
legislation, condemning any payment or other advantage aimed at altering an
official's behaviour. On the other hand, it excludes practices of social courtesy
from the definition of 'corruption'. The Court's main criterion is whether a
payment was 'sufficiently in consideration for action within an official's
duties'.260 Social courtesy gifts are not viewed as corruption insofar as they are
not made to alter an official's behaviour. In addition, the Korean Supreme Court
assessed whether the size of the payment remained within socially acceptable
limits. 26 1 The various nuanced judgments of the Korean courts on this point
suggest that any danger of creating a slippery slope, if socially accepted practice
is excluded from the coverage of anti-corruption instruments, may be
exaggerated. 262
263 Hoge Raad [Supreme Court of the Netherlands], Case No 03034/04 A, LJN AT8318,
27 September 2005, [4.4], quoted in Idlir Pegi and Eelke Sikkema, 'Corruption and Legal
Certainty; The Case of Albania and the Netherlands Implementation of the Criminal Law
Convention on Corruption in a Transitional and Consolidated Democracy' (2010)
6(1) Utrecht Law Review 101, 114.
264 ICCPO, UN Doc A/RES/51/59, art I(1).
265 Johnson and Sharma, above n 21, 15 n 1, citing Gerald E Caiden and Naomi Caiden,
'Administrative Corruption' (1977) 37 Public Administration Review 301.
See also Huntington, above n 7, 60.
266 Alina Mungiu-Pippidi et al, 'Contextual Choices in Fighting Corruption: Lessons Learned'
(Report 4/2011, Norwegian Agency for Development Cooperation, July 2011) 3-4. For a
definition of 'corruption' which includes private sector acts: see, eg, Argandofia, above n 36,
481. See also Part IV(F) below.
267 Most authors have formulated similar definitions: see, eg, Rose-Ackerman, 'When Is
Corruption Harmful?', above n 193, 353.
268 Asian Development Bank, 'Anticorruption - Our Framework Policies and Strategies',
above n 29, 9-10; Transparency International, What is the Corruption Perceptions Index?
(2013) <http://www.transparency.org/cpi2011/in detail>.
244 Melbourne Journalof InternationalLaw [Vol 14
The limitation to 'public office' is assessed below, 269 but the limitation 'for
private gain' also merits reflection. Certain documents only mentioned the
personal gain of the bribe-taker, which is too restrictive. 'Private gain' can be
interpreted more broadly than 'personal gain': a corrupt act takes place not only
when it benefits the bribe-taker personally, but also when it advantages, for
example, a family member, friend, acquaintance or even the political party or
company to which the bribe-taker belongs. 270 If corruption is defined as the
abuse of public office for private gain, the focus lies on the abuse that occurs,
rather than on the person who gains. 271 Nevertheless, the concrete impact of a
corrupt act could differ depending on who receives the benefits of the bribe: for
example, the advantage can be retained by one individual or shared among all
members of the bribe-taker's tribe. However, due to strong resistance from the
US, the UNCAC does not cover corruption perpetrated by members of political
parties. 272 Conversely, certain sound political decisions could also imply a
private gain, without amounting to what would commonly be perceived as
corruption. 273 There is a thin line between normal political lobbying in favour of
one's own constituency and corrupt practices. 274 The same thin line can be found
in private promotional or lobbying efforts. For example, if pharmaceutical
companies offer doctors free seminars in an exotic place to provide information
on new medicine, not everyone would deem this to be outright corruption. A
counter-example is tax evasion by a company or individual: as long as no bribe is
paid to a public official in the process, such fraudulent acts would not constitute
corruption under the international instruments that require the involvement of a
public official (such as the OECD Convention), even though they may be
perceived as corrupt. 275 As mentioned above, certain developing countries also
insist on distinguishing between corruption and traditional gift-giving.
Notwithstanding certain grey areas, however, most people seem to agree on most
instances of corrupt practices.
The various international anti-corruption instruments differ in scope. Some,
such as the OECD Convention, are clearly limited to a specific type of
corruption. Others cover bribery and some other forms of corruption, which they
define in broader or narrower terms. It is therefore difficult to rank international
instruments based on the breadth of their scope. Rather, when compared, certain
instruments are defined more broadly for one specific issue (for example, illicit
enrichment) but more narrowly on others (for example, international cooperation
provisions) when compared to other instruments.
As indicated above, the OAS and OECD Conventions are the earliest
multilateral anti-corruption instruments. The scope of the OECD Convention is
very limited. Subsequent multilateral instruments have broadened this scope,
both in terms of the persons covered ('rationepersonae') and types of corruption
covered ('ratione materiae').
In view of its early adoption (in March 1996, one and a half years before the
adoption of the OECD Convention) - and in view of Latin America's recent
recovery from corrupt dictatorships - the OAS Convention is remarkably broad
in scope. 276 The OAS Convention covers both active and passive bribery, of both
foreign and domestic officials. 277 Unlike the OECD Convention, no link with a
business transaction is required in order for an act to be classified as an act of
corruption under the OAS Convention. It suffices that there is bribery related to
any act or omission in the performance of an official's public position. 278 The
corrupt act may involve a bribe, gift, favour or advantage for either the public
official or another person or entity. 279 Similarly, the OAS Convention covers the
concealment of the proceeds of corrupt acts, 280 as well as illicit enrichment. 28 1
The criminalisation of illicit enrichment was intended to facilitate the
investigations of the Latin American judicial systems that were still being rebuilt
in the wake of dictatorial regimes. Canada and the US, however, held that
criminalising illicit enrichment would be contrary to the presumption of
innocence. The OAS Convention appeased these concerns, by making the
requirement to criminalise illicit enrichment subject to a state's constitution and
the fundamental principles of its legal system. 282 Nevertheless, both Canada and
the US made reservations to this article.
Under the OAS Convention, the criminalisation of other types of corruption is
stated to be merely 'desirable'; member states simply make undertakings to
'consider' prohibiting these other types, namely the improper use of classified or
confidential information, the improper use or diversion of state property and
trading in influence. 283 However, it is not required that the act of corruption
actually harms state property. 284 Furthermore, the fact that the corrupt act had a
political purpose does not, in itself, suffice to make it a political offence and
consequently shield it from regular criminal prosecutions. 285 In view of Latin
ECO WAS Protocol,298 however, have to be assessed in light of their very weak
monitoring mechanism.
The UNCAC, as the most recent and universal anti-corruption convention, is
also the most elaborate and detailed international anti-corruption instrument. The
scope ratione personae of the UNCAC is rather broad in that it provides a
functional definition of public official. 299 The UNCAC covers not only
corruption of foreign public officials, but also of domestic public officials and
officials of public international organisations. 300 In addition, employees working
for a public agency or enterprise, or an entity that provides a public service, 3 01
are considered public officials for the purposes of the UNCAC. 302 As there is no
official commentary to the UNCAC, there is no further official guidance as to the
exact scope of these provisions. Guidance can be found in the OECD Convention
298 The scope of the ECO WAS Protocol is not straightforward, as the definition of corrupt
practices is scattered over several articles, which at certain points do not seem to be
completely consistent. It requires states parties to criminalise active and passive bribery of
(foreign and domestic) public officials (arts 6.1(a), 6.2) and also the act of diverting state or
private assets by a public official (arts 6.1(e), 6.2). The ECO WAS Protocol does not require
states parties to criminalise illicit enrichment. However, it notes that if a state already has
the offence of illicit enrichment, this shall cover the situation in which a public official
cannot reasonably explain a significant increase in their assets (art 6.3). Creating or using
false invoices or other accounting documents or omitting to record payments shall equally
be criminal offences (art 4). The same holds for public officials or employees of companies
who accept bribes, or persons offering or giving such bribes, thereby acting in violation of
their duties (art 5). This seems to exclude facilitation payments from the
ECO WAS Protocol's scope, as these bribes are made to speed up a service which falls
within an official's or employee's normal functions. Influence peddling in both the public
and private sector should equally be criminalised, whether or not the influence has actually
been exerted. Hence, the ECO WAS Protocol only covers two instances of corruption in the
private sphere:
(i) bribery to act in violation of the functions of a private company's employee; and
(ii) influence peddling.
The latter is not limited to employees of private companies, but covers any such instance in
the private sphere (art 6.1(c)). It is not clear why the first instance is not equally broadened
up to bribery in the private sector at large (eg, bribery of a private school teacher for better
grading, or a private school principal for privileged access to the school). The concealment
of the illicit proceeds of corruption are to be criminalised in accordance with the
fundamental principles of a state's national law (art 7.2). The latter limitation seems
somewhat surprising - if corrupt acts are to be criminalised, it seems logical to also require
criminalisation of the concealment of the illicit proceeds of such acts. The
ECO WAS Protocol clarifies that it is applicable:
(i) whenever the corrupt act was committed in a member state;
(ii) whenever such act produces effects in a member state; or
(iii) when a national institutional system fails to provide the most basic preventive
measures enumerated in the ECO WAS Protocol (art 3).
The latter provision is noteworthy, especially as the preventive measures listed by the
ECO WAS Protocol are broad (drafting codes of conduct for public officials, ensuring civil
society participation). For further analysis of the influence of civil society and
democratisation on corruption, see Mark E Warren, 'La democracia contra la corrupcion'
[Democracy against Corruption] (2005) 47 Revista Mexicana de Ciencias Politicas y
Sociales 109 (freedom of press and the right to information, asset disclosure by public
officials, etc).
299 A functional definition has also been adopted in Belgian anti-corruption legislation:
see Belgium Phase 2 Follow-Up Report, above n 214, 24.
300 UNCAC arts 15-16.
301 As defined in the relevant states party's domestic law: see UNCAC art 2(a).
302 Ibid.
248 Melbourne Journalof InternationalLaw [Vol 14
Commentaries, which clarify that a public function includes any activity in the
public interest. 303 An official of a public enterprise is deemed to perform a public
function unless the enterprise operates on a normal commercial basis. 304
As far as the scope ratione materiae of the UNCAC is concerned, the mere
promise, offer or request of a bribe falls under the its scope. 305 The Explanatory
Report to the CoE Criminal Law Convention, however, requires that the
beneficiary at least keeps the gift for a certain time, so that the involuntary
receipt of a gift that is returned immediately would not constitute bribery. Such
an interpretation of corruption focuses more on the acceptance than on the offer,
which seems more appropriate. 306 Whilst the earlier UNDAC was limited (as its
title indicates) to corruption in transnational business transactions, the current
UNCAC is not limited in this way. Active and passive corruption by, or of,
domestic public officials falls under the scope of the UNCAC, if aimed at making
the official act (or refrain from acting) in the exercise of their official duties. 307
However, for corrupt acts involving foreign public officials or officials of a
public international organisation, a distinction is made between active and
passive bribery. 308 In order to be covered by the UNCAC, active bribery (where a
bribe is promised, offered or given to a foreign public official) should aim to
make the official act (or refrain from acting) in the exercise of their official
duties in order to obtain or retain business or other undue advantage 'in relation
to the conduct of international business'.309 For passive bribery (where a bribe is
intentionally solicited or accepted by an official), states parties shall 'consider'
criminalising such solicitation or acceptance, whether or not this is related to
business transactions. 310 The mere 'consideration' suggested by the UNCAC
reflects earlier UN negotiations on the issue of corruption, where developing
countries focused mainly on the supply side of bribes - more specifically the
offering of bribes by foreign multinationals. 31 1 Legally speaking, however, the
distinction between active and passive bribery seems tenuous: if offering a bribe
should be criminalised, so should accepting a bribe. The Netherlands, for
example, had already criminalised the passive bribery of public officials in the
1809 Criminal Code of the Kingdom of Holland.312
313 The jurisdictional provisions of the OECD Convention and the UNCAC are further
discussed in Part IV(B)(1).
314 The FCPA is discussed in detail in Part IV(B)(2).
315 Bribery Act 2010 (UK) c 23 ('BriberyAct').
316 The jurisdiction over corruption in the UK is discussed further in Part IV(B)(3).
317 The jurisdiction over corruption in Belgium is discussed further in Part IV(B)(4).
318 The jurisdiction over corruption in the Netherlands is discussed further in Part IV(B)(5).
319 Cf Reagan R Demas, 'Moment of Truth: Development in Sub-Saharan Africa and Critical
Alterations Needed in Application of the Foreign Corrupt Practices Act and Other
Anti-Corruption Initiatives' (2011) 26 American University InternationalLaw Review 315,
330-1. Demas states that 'the supply-side anti-bribery standards contained in the
[US Foreign Corrupt Practices Act (which contains wide jurisdictional assertions)], in
theory, are broadly accepted across the West and beyond'. Wide jurisdictional assertions in
the field of antitrust, however, have met with more opposition, in particular because antitrust
standards are not necessarily universally shared (there is indeed no global antitrust treaty)
and restrictive business practices of national champions may be tolerated if they cause only
limited adverse effects within the champions' territory: see Cedric Ryngaert, Jurisdiction
over Antitrust Violations in InternationalLaw (Intersentia, 2008) 15-23.
250 Melbourne Journalof InternationalLaw [Vol 14
320 Article 42.1(b) of the UNCAC adds that jurisdiction also extends to offences 'committed on
board a vessel that is flying the flag of that State Party or an aircraft that is registered under
the laws of that State Party at the time that the offence is committed'.
321 See Cedric Ryngaert, 'Territorial Jurisdiction over Cross-Frontier Offences: Revisiting a
Classic Problem of International Criminal Law' (2009) 9 International Criminal Law
Review 187, 202-8.
322 OECD Convention art 4.2.
2013] The InternationalLegal Framework against Corruption 251
323 See, eg, Voorafgaande Titel van het Wetboek van Strafvordering [Preliminary Title of the
Code of Criminal Procedure] (Belgium) art l0quater [author's trans] ('PT CCP');
Code penal [Penal Code] (France) art 113-6. For an exploration of active personality,
see Paul Arnell, 'The Case for Nationality Based Jurisdiction' (2001) 50 Internationaland
ComparativeLaw Quarterly 955.
324 But see Part IV(E) (where it is argued that acts of corruption may adversely affect the
enjoyment of human rights).
325 Cf Convention against Torture and Other Cruel, Inhuman or Degrading Treatment or
Punishment, opened for signature 10 December 1984, 1465 UNTS 85 (entered into force
26 June 1987) art 5.2 ('Convention against Torture'):
Each State Party shall likewise take such measures as may be necessary to establish
its jurisdiction over such offences in cases where the alleged offender is present in
any territory under its jurisdiction and it does not extradite him [or her] pursuant to
article 8 to any of the States mentioned in paragraph 1 of this article.
326 UNCAC art42.3.
252 Melbourne Journalof InternationalLaw [Vol 14
another variation on territoriality, the FCPA applies to 'any person' acting within
US territory, notably if it causes, directly or through agents, an act in furtherance
of the corrupt payment to take place within the territory of the US. 337 This allows
the US enforcement agencies (the Department of Justice ('DoJ') and the
Securities and Exchange Commission ('SEC')) to bring corruption proceedings
against foreign persons whose bribery acts may have had only a tenuous
connection with the US, for example routing payment through US bank accounts
or sending an email to a US company. 338 In practice, the relevant provisions may
bring foreign subsidiaries of US companies that are involved in the bribery of
foreign officials within the reach of the FCPA watchdogs, although such
subsidiaries could also be considered agents of US persons, issuers or domestic
concerns. However, foreign subsidiaries are not subject to the FCPA's
accounting provisions (they only apply to issuers), although failure to comply
with accounting requirements can engage the parent company's liability under
the FCPA. 339 A foreign subsidiary's failure to comply with the anti-bribery
provisions of the FCPA can also engage a US parent company's responsibility
under the FCPA, even if it had no knowledge or reason to know of the foreign
subsidiary's corrupt practices, 340 and even if those practices pre-dated the
parent's acquisition of the subsidiary. 34 1
The US jurisdictional claims on the basis of the FCPA are particularly
far-reaching. This is because they allow US enforcement agencies to bring
claims against foreign issuers for the bribery of foreign officials without any
nexus with the US (except the listing of stock on a US exchange), 342 and also (in
respect of foreign bribery) against foreign persons whose stock is not even listed
in the US, on the sole basis that some act furthering bribery has a link with the
US. 343 It is no exaggeration to state that US jurisdiction over corruption is
potentially quasi-universal.
Over the last decade, the DoJ and the SEC have vigorously enforced the
FCPA, bringing both criminal and civil suits against violators and imposing large
fines. 344 In 2010, 106 publicly disclosed investigations were being carried out.345
344 See generally Lucinda A Low and Owen J Bonheimer, 'Enforcement of the US Foreign
Corrupt Practices Act: Extraterritorial Reach and the Effects of International Standards'
(Paper presented at the International Bar Association Annual Anti-Corruption Conference,
Chicago, 19 September 2006).
345 For further details on bribery cases and investigations in the US, see Heimann, Dell and
McCarthy, 'Progress Report 2011', above n 336, 74-8.
346 Working Group on Bribery in International Business Transactions, Organisation for
Economic Co-Operation and Development, 'United Kingdom: Phase 2bis - Report on the
Application of the OECD Convention on Combating Bribery of Foreign Public Officials on
InternationalBusiness Transactions and the 1997 Recommendation on Combating Bribery
in InternationalBusiness Transactions' (Report, Directorate for Financial and Enterprise
Affairs, Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and Development, 16 October 2008) 4
<http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/23/20/41515077.pdf>.
347 Anti-Terrorism, Crime and Security Act 2001 (UK) c 24, s 109 (which came into force on
14 December 2001).
348 F Joseph Warm, Charles Falconer and Michael S Diamant, 'The British are Coming!:
Britain Changes Its Law on Foreign Bribery and Joins the International Fight against
Corruption' (2010) 46 Texas InternationalLaw Journal 1, 5.
349 Ibid 28.
350 For a discussion of the first (domestic) prosecution brought (namely that of Munir Patel) and
fine imposed for failings in anti-bribery and corruption systems and controls (on Willis
Limited) under the Bribery Act (UK), see Steven Pitt and Barney Connell, 'A Year in the
Life of the UK Bribery Act' in Sidley Austin LLP, Insurance and Reinsurance Law Report
(2012) 35, 38-41 <http://www.sidley.com/files/upload/2012_IRLRUK%/o20 BRIBERYA
CT.pdf>.
351 BriberyAct (UK) c 23, ss 6, 7, 12.
352 Ibid s 12.
353 Ibid.
2013] The InternationalLegal Framework against Corruption 255
Convention requires from states parties. 366 However, the existence of universal
jurisdiction over corruption is only an impression resulting from poor legislative
drafting. Article 10quater, § 1 of the Voorafgaande Titel van het Wetboek van
Strafvordering [Preliminary Title of the Code of Criminal Procedure] sets forth
as the basic principle regarding the exercise of jurisdiction over corruption that 'a
person can be prosecuted in Belgium when outside the territory of Belgium he
[or she] commits [an act of corruption]'.367 However, this provision only applies
to acts of corruption committed by Belgian officials abroad; Belgian nationals
who are officials of foreign states or international organisations; and officials of
international organisations that are headquartered in Belgium. 368 Therefore, in
reality, this ground of jurisdiction is based on the protective principle. So much
was also admitted by the government. 369 That being said, Belgian law also
criminalises corruption of foreign officials who have no link with Belgium, in
accordance with Belgium's obligations under the relevant conventions, provided
however that the presumed offender is a Belgian national or a person who has
their main residence in Belgium and that the act is also punishable where it was
committed. 370 This is a classic application of the active personality principle,
although some limiting conditions for the exercise of jurisdiction based on this
37
principle have been abandoned with regards to the prosecution of corruption. 1
However, the limiting condition of double criminality remains in place. Whilst
this has been criticised by the OECD, the Belgian government has pointed out
that it interprets the requirement of double criminality as one of the 'principles'
cited by art 4.2 of the OECD Convention.372 This provision indeed does not
require that OECD member states introduce unbridled active personality-based
jurisdiction over presumed perpetrators of corruption. Instead, art 4.2 of the
OECD Convention merely requires that states which already have such
jurisdiction on their statutory books, extend it (arguably mitigated by
pre-existing limiting conditions) to bribery of foreign public officials. 373 As
noted above, it is regrettable that the drafters of the OECD Convention remained
so cautious.
TI has characterised Belgium as a 'moderate enforcer' of legislation against
foreign corrupt practices. Indeed, TI identified only four Belgian cases and some
EU-related cases referred to TI by the European Anti-Fraud Office. 374 In
addition, TI considered that insufficient resources were earmarked for combating
corruption (although the workload of investigating the EU cases may be partly to
blame); that 'the police and the judiciary do not have enough resources and
training to deal with these cases'; and that there is 'no administrative body to
handle complaints and lead administrative investigations'.375
383 One example is the investigation of Trafigura Beheer BV, a Dutch oil trader that had
allegedly paid bribes to Jamaican politicians: see 'Dutch to Probe Claims of Trafigura
Bribes in Jamaica', Expatica (online), 1 February 2011 <http://www.expatica.com/nl/n
ews/dutch-news/dutch-to-probe-claims-of-trafigura-bribes-in-jamaica 127033.html>, cited
in Heimann, Dell and McCarthy, 'Progress Report 2011', above n 336, 54.
384 Heimann, Dell and McCarthy, 'Progress Report 2011', above n 336, 54-5 (referring to the
Dutch company Snamprogetti settling with US and Nigerian authorities, in connection with
corrupt practices regarding a liquefied gas plant in Nigeria; Shell settling with
US authorities in connection with bribes paid to Nigerian officials by an agent; and Philips
going on trial in Poland in connection with payments made to managers of Polish public
hospitals).
385 Ibid 55.
386 Ibid.
387 Ibid.
388 Ibid 5.
389 For a discussion of US enforcement of its FCPA, see above Part IV(A)(2).
390 Joseph P Covington and Iris E Bennett, 'Signs of Life in International Anti-Bribery
Enforcement - Recent Enforcement of Anti-Bribery Laws Outside the US and Issues to
Consider for a Multi-Jurisdictional Defense Strategy' (Bloomberg Finance LP, 2009) 2
<http://www.jenner.com/system/assets/assets/1118/original/covington bennettpdfpdf? 131
7312702>.
2013] The InternationalLegal Framework against Corruption 259
391 Warm, Falconer and Diamant, above n 348, 71-2. According to Warn, Falconer and
Diamant, not only is it efficient for regulators in multiple jurisdictions to coordinate their
efforts against multi-jurisdictional corruption, it is in the interest of justice that multinational
companies are not investigated and punished repeatedly in different countries for the same
underlying wrongdoing. The case against Siemens proved that cross-jurisdictional
cooperation can work.
392 Weiss, above n 365, 505.
393 UNCAC art 42.6. Cf Convention against Torture art 5.3.
394 UNCAC art 42.5:
If a State Party exercising its jurisdiction ... has been notified, or has otherwise
learned, that any other States Parties are conducting an investigation, prosecution or
judicial proceeding in respect of the same conduct, the competent authorities of those
States Parties shall, as appropriate, consult one another with a view to coordinating
their actions.
See also OECD Convention art 4(3): 'When more than one Party has jurisdiction over an
alleged offence described in this Convention, the Parties involved shall, at the request of one
of them, consult with a view to determining the most appropriate jurisdiction for
prosecution'.
395 Agreement regarding the Application of Competition Laws between the Government of the
United States and the Commission of the European Communities, 30 ILM 1487 (signed and
entered into force 23 September 1991).
396 International coordination seems to take place on an ad hoc basis for the time being:
see, eg, the successful coordination by national anti-corruption enforcers in the Siemens
Plea Agreement: Warn, Falconer and Diamant, above n 348, 71-2; Weiss, above n 365,
504-5. Investigations into Siemens' practices were initiated in China, Greece, Hungary,
Indonesia, Italy and Norway and the US. Cooperation between Germany and the US was
particularly close.
260 Melbourne Journalof InternationalLaw [Vol 14
397 Weiss, above n 365, 505. Weiss states that informal agreements on the issue of international
regulatory cooperation do exist, but it is not clear that they can provide the predictability and
consistent calculation of penalties that are normatively desirable to avoid over-deterring
investment in foreign projects. While it would not be undesirable if corruption and bribery
disappeared entirely, over-deterrence and the resulting reduction in investment are harmful
from an efficiency standpoint.
398 On the system of concurrent jurisdiction in international law, see Cedric Ryngaert,
Jurisdiction in InternationalLaw (Oxford University Press, 2008) 127-9.
399 Cf Weiss, above n 365, 504 (submitting that 'it is one thing for a regulator to inform an
interested State that it is investigating a firm, but it is quite another for that regulator to
refrain from seeking fines within its grasp merely because of comity toward foreign
regulators').
400 Demas, above n 319, 337 (arguing that strict FPCA enforcement 'tends to place those
companies operating in Africa with a US connection at a competitive disadvantage').
401 Ibid 339, citing Fritz Heimann and Gillian Dell, 'Progress Report 2009: OECD Anti-Bribery
Convention' (Report, Transparency International, June 2009) 8.
402 Ibid 362-3. Note that US efforts to universalise the criminality of corruption have now
borne fruit after the adoption of, notably, the UNCAC and the OECD Convention. While
many states have duly implemented the provisions of these conventions, they have often
failed to enforce them. Put differently, the legislative playing field may have been levelled,
but the enforcement playing field has not. Accordingly, the classic US complaint that
US firms are put at a competitive disadvantage is still valid.
2013] The InternationalLegal Framework against Corruption 261
C Asset Recovery
Asset recovery provisions aim to ensure that property that was taken from its
rightful owner through corrupt practices is returned. Its goal is to tackle the
economic incentive for corrupt acts: not only can the persons involved in
corruption be held criminally or civilly liable (with a focus on the individual),
but the proceeds from their corrupt acts can also be seized (with a focus on the
assets). Asset recovery has received increased attention in the international arena.
Calls for the recovery of assets taken from developing countries during colonial
times 404 have been reinforced by allegations that European financial institutions
had shielded money and assets belonging to dictators recently toppled during the
Arab Spring. 405 Furthermore, the current global financial crisis increases the
awareness that more transparency in the international financial system is
necessary to prevent fraudulent and corrupt practices.
Asset recovery is included in international anti-corruption instruments. 406 In
addition, it is addressed by international financial regulations that are not
(exclusively) focused on anti-corruption, but which will obviously interact with
the anti-corruption instruments. 407 Examples include the Financial Action Task
403 In the fight against climate change, this strategy has recently been adopted by the EU:
see Directive 2008/101/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of19 November
2008 Amending Directive 2003/87/EC so as to Include Aviation Activities in the Scheme for
Greenhouse Gas Emission Allowance Trading Within the Community [2009] OJ L 8/3
(extending the European emissions allowance trading scheme to flights which arrive at or
depart from an aerodrome situated in the territory of a member state, including to flights by
aircraft registered in third states and flying over third states' territory), as upheld by the
European Court of Justice: Air Transport Association of America v Secretary of State for
Energy and Climate Change (Court of Justice of the European Communities, C-366/10,
21 December 2011).
404 See, eg, Michael J Reppas II, 'Empty "International" Museums' Trophy Cases of Their
Looted Treasures and Return Stolen Property to the Countries of Origin and the Rightful
Heirs of Those Wrongfully Dispossessed' (2007) 36 Denver Journal of InternationalLaw
and Policy 93.
405 European Parliament, 'Europe Should Stop Harbouring Dictators' Blood Money'
(Press Release, 6 February 2012) <http://www.europarl.europa.eu/news/en/headlines/conten
t/20120203ST037167/html/Europe-should-stop-harbouring-dictators%27-blood-money>.
Nevertheless, several financial institutions did freeze the assets of fallen dictators, acts that
were strengthened by UN Security Council resolutions imposing asset freezes:
see, eg, Financial Action Task Force, 'Laundering the Proceeds of Corruption' (Report, July
2011) 11 [23].
406 See, eg, UNCAC ch V. See also Saliou Bah, 'La Restitution des avoirs issus de la corruption
dans les conventions anti-corruption internationales: une avancee conceptuelle et normative
a la portee pratique limitee' [The Return of Assets Derived from Corruption in International
Anti-Corruption Conventions: A Conceptual and Normative Advance to a Limited Practical
Impact] (2010) 1Revue de droit des affaires internationales 15.
407 One example is international accounting standards. Following the example of the FCPA,
certain multilateral conventions contain separate provisions on accounting standards (for
example, OECD Convention art 8). Imposing stringent accounting requirements to a certain
extent brings the anti-corruption effort under the rigorous oversight of market and stock
exchange watchdogs such as the SEC in the US. The post-Watergate investigations in the
US caused several companies to report alleged wrongdoings specifically to the SEC:
see Cleveland et al, above n 10, 203.
262 Melbourne Journalof InternationalLaw [Vol 14
408 Financial Action Task Force, 'International Standards on Combating Money Laundering and
the Financing of Terrorism & Proliferation: The FATF Recommendations' (February 2012)
('FATF Recommendations'). The Financial Action Task Force ('FATF') is an independent
intergovernmental body that develops and promotes policies to protect the global financial
system against money laundering and terrorist financing: see generally Financial Action
Task Force, About Us: Who We Are (2012) <http://www.fatf-gafi.org/pages/aboutus/>. See
also Financial Action Task Force, 'Laundering the Proceeds of Corruption', above n 405.
409 For documents issued by the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision ('BCBS'):
see generally Bank for International Settlements, Basel Committee - Last 3 Years
<http://www.bis.org/list/bcbs/index.htm>. The BCBS has released guidance on a number of
topics: see, eg, Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, 'Prevention of Criminal Use of
the Banking System for the Purpose of Money-Laundering' (Statement, December 1988)
<http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbscl37.pdf>; Basel Committee on Banking Supervision,
'Consolidated KYC Risk Management' (Guidance Document, Bank for International
Settlements, October 2004) <http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbsl10.pdf>; Basel Committee on
Banking Supervision, 'Due Diligence and Transparency regarding Cover Payment Messages
Related to Cross-Border Wire Transfers' (Guidance Document, Bank for International
Settlements, May 2009) <http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbsl54.pdf>.
410 Wolfsberg Group, 'Wolfsberg Anti-Money Laundering Principles for Private Banking
(2012)' (May 2012) <http://www.wolfsberg-principles.com/pdflWolfsberg-Private-Bank
ing-Prinicples-May-2012.pdf>. The Wolfsberg Group is an industry-led initiative comprised
of 11 global banks. The Group aims to elaborate standards on know-your-customer, money
laundering and counterterrorism financing issues: see generally Wolfsberg Group, Global
Banks: Global Standards (2012) <http://www.wolfsberg-principles.com/>.
411 UNCACch V.
412 For a detailed assessment, see Carr and Goldby, above n 4, 190.
413 Recent studies estimate a capital flight out of poorer countries of more than US$1.2 trillion
in 2008, of which around US$50 billion would be proceeds of corruption: see Financial
Action Task Force, 'Laundering the Proceeds of Corruption', above n 405, 9 [15]; Theodore
S Greenberg et al, 'Stolen Asset Recovery: Politically Exposed Persons - A Policy Paper
on Strengthening Preventive Measures' (Policy Paper, Stolen Asset Recovery
Initiative/World Bank, 2009) xiii, 3-4 <http:/siteresources.worldbank.org/EXTSARI/
Resources/5570284-1257172052492/PEPs-ful.pdf>'; Dev Kar and Karly Curcio, 'Illicit
Financial Flows from Developing Countries: 2000-2009 - Update with a Focus on Asia'
(Report, Global Financial Integrity, January 2011) i <http://www.gfintegrity.org/storage/
gfip/documents/reports/IFF2010/gfiiff update report-web.pdf>'; Raymond W Baker,
Capitalism's Achilles Heel: Dirty Money and How to Renew the Free-Market System (John
Wiley & Sons, 2005) 172. The Stolen Asset Recovery Initiative's ('StAR') estimates
indicate that around US$5 billion has been recovered in the period 1995 to 2010: Stolen
Asset Recovery Initiative, Frequently Asked Questions (2013) <http:/star.worldbank.org/
star/about-us/frequently-asked-questions>.
414 Webb, above n 5, 207.
415 On the legal framework and types of legal assistance, see Organisation for Economic
Co-Operation and Development, 'Typology on Mutual Legal Assistance in Foreign Bribery
Cases' (Report, 7 December 2012).
2013] The InternationalLegal Framework against Corruption 263
(not in the least because the proceeds of corruption often pass through Western
banks, which are therefore best placed to identify suspicious transfers).
Unsurprisingly, the UNCAC chapter on asset recovery is preceded by a chapter
on international cooperation 416 and followed by a chapter on technical assistance
and information exchange. 4 17
Previous UN documents had paved the way for this UNCAC requirement of
asset recovery. One of those documents was the Palermo Convention and its
provisions on money laundering 418 and confiscation and seizure. 419 Another
example is a 2001 UNGA resolution, 42 0 which called for increased cooperation
to repatriate illegally transferred funds to the countries of origin and called upon
all countries and entities concerned to cooperate in this respect. The 2001 UNGA
resolution further requested an expert group to assess this issue of repatriation of
transferred funds, to be reflected in the future UNCAC. 42 1
Article 23 of the UNCAC on the '[1]aundering of [the] proceeds of crime' is
formulated broadly, which is laudable. It goes beyond the laundering of money
to cover the laundering of any property (which includes, inter alia, company
shares and luxury goods). 422 The range of persons who can be held criminally
liable is also far-reaching: persons knowingly assisting in the covering up of the
proceeds of corrupt acts could include banks, lawyers and accountants, 423 real
estate agents, casino operators, antique traders and jewellers. 424 In other words,
as soon as a corrupt act takes place, it taints the whole chain of subsequent
transactions. The proceeds of corruption can be recovered through either
criminal or civil proceedings. Criminal proceedings require a prior criminal
conviction which focuses on the corrupt individual. When a criminal conviction
is impossible (for example, where the corrupt individual has passed away or
enjoys immunity) or otherwise unachievable, civil proceedings may be a
practical alternative. Such civil proceedings focus on the goods tainted by an
initial corrupt act, rather than on the corrupt individual. Hence, property can be
seized through civil proceedings without the user or owner being convicted for
the initial corrupt act. 425 Confronted with the question whether such civil
proceedings, without the guarantees of a criminal procedure, infringe human
rights, a UK court has argued that civil forfeiture is a procedure in rem and is not
covered by the UK Human Rights Act.426 This allows for the standard of proof to
be on the 'balance of probabilities', rather than 'beyond reasonable doubt', as
required in criminal proceedings. This may greatly facilitate the recovery of
assets from corrupt acts, though of course this does not result in a criminal
conviction of the culprits. One practical impediment to the forfeiture of the
proceeds of corrupt acts is the requirement of quantifying those proceeds.
Identifying the value of the bribe is one step, but the actual benefit of the bribery
for the bribe-giver may be several times the amount of the bribe. A joint
OECD/Stolen Asset Recovery Initiative ('StAR') report aims to tackle such
difficulties by providing very detailed guidance on the calculation of the actual
benefit amounting from a bribe. 427
The 1996 OAS Convention equally stresses the importance of asset recovery,
requiring states parties to provide each other with 'the broadest possible measure
of assistance in the identification, tracing, freezing, seizure and forfeiture of
property or proceeds' of corrupt acts. 428 For the OAS Convention, cooperation is
one of its two explicitly listed purposes, 429 which again underlines the
importance attached to it. The OAS Convention encourages states to assist in the
investigation of corrupt acts by stipulating that the forfeited property may be
transferred, wholly or in part, to another state party that assisted in the
underlying investigation. 430 This non-mandatory provision is coupled with the
requirement that states parties afford one another 'the widest measure of mutual
assistance' when requested by a competent authority, as well as the 'widest
measure of mutual technical cooperation'.431
Not surprisingly, the AU Convention also requires states parties to freeze,
seize, confiscate and repatriate the instrumentalities or proceeds of corruption. 432
Under the OECD Convention, mutual legal assistance 'to the fullest extent
possible' is obligatory, 433 but no further provisions on asset recovery are
included. The OECD Convention requires states parties to provide prompt and
effective legal assistance for criminal investigations and proceedings concerning
offences within the OECD Convention's scope and also for non-criminal
425 An example is the fourth (formerly third) FATF recommendation, entitled 'Confiscation and
Provisional Measures': FATF Recommendations, above n 408, 12. See also Financial Action
Task Force, 'Best Practices: Confiscation (Recommendations 3 and 38)'
(Guidance Document, 19 February 2010) 7 [13]; Theodore S Greenberg et al, 'Stolen Asset
Recovery: A Good Practices Guide for Non-Conviction-Based Asset Forfeiture'
(Guidance Document, Stolen Asset Recovery Initiative, World Bank, 5 January 2009).
426 Walsh v Director of the Assets Recovery Agency [2005] NICA 6 (26 January 2005).
See also Human Rights Act 1998 (UK) c 42; Carr and Goldby, above n 4, 182.
427 Jeane-Pierre Brun et al, 'Identification and Quantification of the Proceeds of Bribery:
A Joint OECD-StAR Analysis' (Report, Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and
Development and Stolen Asset Recovery Initiative, World Bank, February 2012)
<http://www.oecd.org/daf/anti-bribery/50057547.pdf>.
428 OAS Convention art XV.
429 Ibid art II.
430 Ibid art XV(2).
431 Ibid art XIV.
432 AU Convention art 16.
433 OECD Convention art 9. 1.
2013] The InternationalLegal Framework against Corruption 265
434 Ibid.
435 Ibid art 9.2.
436 Belgium Phase 2 Follow-Up Report, above n 214, 4 [5].
437 See Stolen Asset Recovery Initiative, About Us (2012) <http:/star.worldbank.org/star/ab
out-us/our-vision>.
438 See, eg, Jean-Pierre Brun et al, 'Asset Recovery Handbook: A Guide for Practitioners'
(Handbook, Stolen Asset Recovery Initiative, World Bank, 3 January 2011);
Kevin M Stephenson et al, 'Barriers to Asset Recovery: An Analysis of the Key Barriers
and Recommendations for Action' (Study, Stolen Asset Recovery Initiative/World Bank,
21 June 2011); Theodore S Greenberg et al, 'Politically Exposed Persons: Preventive
Measures for the Banking Sector' (Policy Paper, Stolen Asset Recovery Initiative/World
Bank, 11 May 2012); Greenberg et al, 'Stolen Asset Recovery', above n 425; Stolen Asset
Recovery Initiative, 'Management of Returned Assets: Policy Considerations' (Policy Note,
World Bank, 2009).
439 Stolen Asset Recovery Initiative, StAR Corruption Cases Search Centre (2013)
<http:/star.worldbank.org/corruption-cases/assetrecovery/?f[0]=bundle%/o3Apuppet maste
rs>.
440 For example, Carr and Goldby indicate that the FATF recommendations may conflict with
the UNCAC provision as to the requirement of double criminality: Carr and Goldby,
above n 4, 180. See also Financial Action Task Force, 'FATF 40 Recommendations'
(Report, 2010) 5. The FATF recommendations allow states to confiscate the proceeds of
corrupt acts if it would have been a criminal offence if it had been committed within its
territory, whether or not it was a crime on the country where the corrupt act took place. The
FATF recommendations have been amended in 2012. The interpretive note to the amended
Recommendation 3 still allows states to confiscate the proceeds of corrupt acts without
requiring double criminality. UNCAC art 23(2)(c), on the other hand, requires double
criminality:
However, offences committed outside the jurisdiction of a State Party shall constitute
predicate offences only when the relevant conduct is a criminal offence under the
domestic law of the State where it is committed and would be a criminal offence
under the domestic law of the State Party implementing or applying this article had it
been committed there.
Carr and Goldby, above n 4, 180.
266 Melbourne Journalof InternationalLaw [Vol 14
corruption. 44 1 It details how the corporate veil shields the corrupt from
investigations. 442
Private actors play a crucial role in the successful enforcement of asset
recovery provisions. KYC rules, for example, require banks to increase due
diligence 443 efforts for bank accounts of high-level politicians or large financial
transactions. 444 A limitation of such financial money laundering regulation is that
it would probably only detect grand corruption and, accordingly, be of limited
use for identifying and remedying petty corruption. 445 Other types of corruption
also continue to fly below the radar of money laundering standards in general,
including art 23 of the UNCAC. For example, the purchase of real estate or
jewellery may be detected, but bribery in the form of offering expensive
education, health care benefits or a lucrative position to a bribe-taker or their
relatives cannot be detected by money laundering standards. 446 Nevertheless,
such limitations should not render us sceptical but should merely underline the
necessity of a comprehensive anti-corruption approach.
441 Emile van der Does de Willebois et al, 'The Puppet Masters: How the Corrupt Use Legal
Structures to Hide Stolen Assets and What to Do About It' (Report, Stolen Asset Recovery
Initiative/World Bank, 24 October 2011).
442 Ibid ix, 9, 41, 59, 60, 117, 203.
443 The due diligence obligations reflected in the tenth (formerly fifth) FATF recommendation
are reminiscent of the due diligence concept put forward by the Ruggie framework and the
UN Guiding Principles. Instead of imposing one-size-fits-all substantive rules, the due
diligence concept, as a form of meta-regulation, requires banks and other private actors to
identify potentially corrupt act(or)s: FATF Recommendations, above n 408, 14.
See also UN Guiding Principles,UN Doc A/HRC/17/31, annex.
444 See, eg, Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, 'Customer Due Diligence for Banks'
(Guidance Document, Bank for International Settlements, October 2001) <http://www.bis.
org/publ/bcbs85.pdf>.
445 Carr and Goldby, above n 4, 188.
446 Ibid 189.
447 Gillespie, above n 274, 103.
448 For a fuller discussion, see Jan Wouters and Cedric Ryngaert, 'Good Governance: Lessons
from International Organizations' in Deirdre M Curtin and Ramses A Wessel (eds), Good
Governance and the European Union: Reflections on Concepts, Institutions and Substance
(Intersentia, 2005) 69.
2013] The InternationalLegal Framework against Corruption 267
449 On the concept of good governance: see, eg, Nicolas Meiseil and Jacques Ould Aoudia,
'L'Insaisissable Relation entre "bonne gouvernance" et developpement' [The Elusive
Connection between 'Good Governance' and Development] (2008) 59 Revue economique
1159; Brigitte Pereira, 'Ethique, gouvernance et corruption' [Ethics, Governance and
Corruption] (2008) 34(186) Revue frangaise de gestion 53.
450 See, eg, UNCAC Preamble: 'the principles of proper management of public affairs and
public property, fairness, responsibility and equality before the law and the need to
safeguard integrity and to foster a culture of rejection of corruption'; OECD Convention,
Preamble: 'Considering that bribery ... raises serious moral and political concerns,
undermines good governance'; AU Convention Preamble:
Cognizant of the fact that the Constitutive Act of the African Union, inter alia, calls
for the need to promote and protect human and peoples' rights, consolidate
democratic institutions and foster a culture of democracy and ensure good
governance and the rule of law.
See alsoAU Convention arts 2.5, 3.
451 See, eg, Demetri Sevastopulo, 'Halliburton Scandal Widens after Claims
of Pressure to Award Lucrative Contracts', Financial Times (online),
11 November 2004 <http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/ec9ddf06-3386-1 1d9-b6c3-
00000e2511c8.html#axzz2ahpHPl7i>; Dana Milbank, 'Halliburton, the Second-Term
Curse?', The Washington Post (online), 9 November 2004 <http://www.washingtonpost
.com/wp-dyn/articles/A35234-2004Nov8.html>.
452 See Securities and Exchange Commission, Public Companies <http://m.investor.gov/i
ntroduction-markets/how-markets-work/public-companies#>.
268 Melbourne JournalofInternationalLaw [Vol 14
immediate inflow of substantial aid. 473 Furthermore, the structure of aid agencies
themselves may impede robust anti-corruption monitoring. Donors focus on
providing aid, but much less on monitoring its (ab)use. Staffing of aid agencies is
often limited (especially administrative staff), which further limits their capacity
to focus on monitoring of aid disbursal. Additionally, donor budgets are often
organised on a fiscal-year basis; employees are rewarded for the disbursal of the
aid earmarked for that fiscal-year, not for the impact or effectiveness of the
money. Internal incentives within aid agencies may thus further diminish the
weight attached to ensuring that aid money is not diverted by corrupt practices.
Christine Cheng and Dominik Zaum add that there is no evidence that countries
that actively implement anti-corruption measures actually receive more aid from
international donors. 474 The fight against corruption should therefore not be
exclusively focused on transnational or even domestic legal instruments. A better
yardstick to measure countries' commitment to fight corruption on the ground is
the way in which they use the tools already at their disposal (such as
procurement and aid instruments) to implement their anti-corruption rhetoric.
473 Cheng and Zaum, above n 231, 15-16. In such environments, donor countries also often
focus on democratisation and the rapid organisation of elections. However, those who profit
most during the conflict presumably have the means to buy votes. Often donors have to rely
on the few local partners that remain active during the conflict. The limited choice of local
partners to implement immediate aid programs further diminishes the possibility of
sanctioning corrupt partners.
474 Ibid.
475 Theodor Meron, The Humanization of International Law (Martinus Nijhoff, 2006). This
'humanisation' of international law has, for instance, also occurred in armed conflicts,
where international human rights law has been considered to be applicable alongside
international humanitarian law (the law that is specifically designed to regulate armed
conflicts): see Legality of the Threat or Use of Nuclear Weapons (Advisory Opinion) [ 1996]
ICJ Rep 226, 240 [25]: 'The protection of the InternationalCovenant of Civil and Political
Rights does not cease in times of war, except by operation of Article 4 of the Covenant
whereby certain provisions may be derogated from in a time of national emergency'.
See also Jean-Marie Henckaerts and Louise Doswald-Beck, Customary International
HumanitarianLaw - Volume I: Rules (Cambridge University Press, 2005) 299-305.
476 Martine Boersma, Corruption: A Violation of Human Rights and a Crime under
InternationalLaw (Intersentia, 2012).
477 Magdalena Sepulveda Carmona, 'Corruption and Human Rights: Making the Connection'
(Report, International Council on Human Rights Policy/Transparency International,
June 2009) ('Corruptionand Human Rights Report').
478 Martine Boersma and Hans Nelen (eds), Corruption & Human Rights: Interdisciplinary
Perspectives (Intersentia, 2010).
2013] The InternationalLegal Framework against Corruption 271
479 It is noted that the first paragraph of the Foreword to the UNCAC draws a causal link
between corruption and human rights:
Corruption is an insidious plague that has a wide range of corrosive effects on
societies. It undermines democracy and the rule of law, leads to violations of human
rights, distorts markets, erodes the quality of life and allows organized crime,
terrorism and other threats to human security to flourish.
However, the operational articles do not return to the issue.
480 See especially the multi-stakeholder, 'hybrid' Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative
('EITI') and the non-governmental organisation initiative Publish What You Pay ('PWYP').
These initiatives require (multinational) corporations - typically in the extractive industries
(oil, gas, mining) - to disclose their payments to the host governments and require the
governments to disclose the funds thus received. Neither EITI nor PWYP refer to human
rights, although it is clear that transparency may prevent embezzlement and make
governments more accountable vis-a-vis their populations in respect of the ways they spend
the wealth generated by (foreign) corporations' resource extraction activities. It is important
to note that these initiatives are essentially voluntary; as such, their successful coverage
extends to only a handful of countries. See also Extractive Industries Transparency
Initiative, What is the EITI? <www.eiti.org/eiti>; Publish What You Pay, The Stories behind
Our Campaign (2011) <www.publishwhatyoupay.org>.
481 John Hatchard, 'Adopting a Human Rights Approach towards Combating Corruption' in
Martine Boersma and Hans Nelen (eds), Corruption & Human Rights: Interdisciplinary
Perspectives (Intersentia, 2010) 7, 17-18.
482 Alien's Action for Tort, 28 USC § 1350 (2006). For a critical exploration of human
rights-inspired tort remedies against private actors complicit in official corruption,
see Cecily Rose, 'The Application of Human Rights Law to Private Sector Complicity in
Governmental Corruption' (2011) 24 Leiden JournalofInternationalLaw 715.
483 Some national human rights institutions already have a specific competence to investigate
corruption: see, eg, Constitution of the Republic of Ghana 1992 (Ghana) arts 218(a), (e).
The Commission on Human Rights and Administrative Justice (the Ghanaian national
human rights institution) is empowered to 'investigate complaints of violations of
fundamental rights and freedoms, injustice, corruption, abuse of power and unfair treatment
of any person by a public officer in the exercise of his [or her] official duties': at art 218(a)
(emphasis added). The Commission on Human Rights and Administrative Justice is also
empowered to 'investigate all instances of alleged or suspected corruption and the
misappropriation of public moneys by officials and to take appropriate steps, including
reports to the Attorney-General and the Auditor-General, resulting from such
investigations': at art 218(e).
272 Melbourne Journalof InternationalLaw [Vol 14
484 See Gauthier De Beco, 'Monitoring Corruption from a Human Rights Perspective' (2011)
15 InternationalJournal of Human Rights 1107.
485 De Beco suggests basing the framework for monitoring corruption from a human rights
perspective on the structural-process-outcome indicator framework developed by the Office
of the High Commissioner for Human Rights ('OHCHR'): ibid 1120. This framework uses
structural indicators (measuring a state's intention to abide by human rights standards);
process indicators (measuring the efforts undertaken by states to implement human rights);
and outcome indicators (measuring a state's actual human rights performance): at 1115-16.
See also Report on Indicatorsfor Monitoring Compliance with InternationalHuman Rights
Instruments, UN Doc HRI/MC/2006/7 (11 May 2006); Report on Indicatorsfor Promoting
and Monitoring the Implementation of Human Rights, UN Doc HRI/MC/2008/3
(6 June 2008).
486 Corruption and Human Rights Report, above n 477, 27-8.
487 International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights, opened for signature
19 December 1966, 999 UNTS 171 (entered into force 23 March 1976) ('ICCPR').
488 Convention for the Protection of Human Rights and Fundamental Freedoms, opened for
signature 4 November 1950, 213 UNTS 222 (entered into force 3 September 1953), as
amended by Protocol No 14bis to the Convention for the Protection of Human Rights and
Fundamental Freedoms, opened for signature 27 May 2009, CETS No 204 (entered into
force 1 September 2009) ('European Convention on Human Rights').
489 International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights, opened for signature
19 December 1966, 993 UNTS 3 (entered into force 3 January 1976).
490 Ibid art 13. For a lengthy discussion of violations of the right to education through
corruption, see Martine Boersma, 'Corruption as a Violation of Economic, Social and
Cultural Rights: Reflections on the Right to Education' in Martine Boersma and Hans
Nelen (eds), Corruption & Human Rights: Interdisciplinary Perspectives
(Intersentia, 2010) 51.
2013] The InternationalLegal Framework against Corruption 273
495 It is not disputed that natural persons can be complicit in international crimes: see, eg, Rome
Statute of the International Criminal Court, opened for signature 17 July 1998,
2187 UNTS 90 (entered into force 1 July 2002) art 25 ('Rome Statute'). Under the
Rome Statute, the International Criminal Court does not have jurisdiction over non-natural
persons, such as corporations, but this need not mean that under general international
criminal law the criminal responsibility of such corporations cannot duly be engaged. Note
that Rose, drawing on Clapham, applies per analogiam art 16 of the International Law
Commission's Articles on State Responsibility to corporate complicity in state violations of
international human rights law: Rose, above n 482, 726-7, citing Andrew Clapham,
The Human Rights Obligations of Non-State Actors (Oxford University Press, 2006) 266.
See also International Law Commission, Report of the InternationalLaw Commission on the
Work of Its Fifty-Third Session, UN GAOR, 56 th sess, Supp No 10, UN Doc A/56/10
(3 August 2001) ch IV(E) ('Draft Articles on Responsibility of States for Internationally
Wrongful Acts').
496 On these grounds, Rose logically concludes that 'it seems that international law is not yet
capable of capturing private sector complicity in human rights violations such as these':
Rose, above n 482, 736. But see UN Guiding Principles, UN Doc A/HRC/17/31, annex
[11]-[24] (emphasising, as the second pillar of the framework, 'The Corporate
Responsibility to Respect Human Rights').
497 This argument has been made most pointedly by Morag Goodwin and Kate Rose-Sender,
'Linking Corruption and Human Rights: An Unwelcome Addition to the Development
Discourse' in Martine Boersma and Hans Nelen (eds), Corruption & Human Rights:
Interdisciplinary Perspectives (Intersentia, 2010) 221, 235-6. But see Rose, above n 482,
717: Rose submits that 'the loose invocation of human rights rhetoric in anticorruption
literature may actually weaken the normative value of human rights law, particularly
economic and social rights'; that 'legal responses to corruption should be confined to the
fairly specialized criminal legal regimes on money laundering, bribery, and stolen asset
recovery'; and also highlights 'improvements in contract and revenue transparency'.
498 Goodwin and Rose-Sender, above n 497, 235-6.
499 See the emphasis that the World Bank places on good governance and anti-corruption as a
means of alleviating poverty: World Bank Institute, Collaborative Governance (2012)
<http://wbi.worldbank.org/wbi/about/topics/govemance>.
2013] The InternationalLegal Framework against Corruption 275
500 There is, for instance, some evidence that reliance on a 'thin' rule of law in apartheid South
Africa - a notion which emphasised the human rights of only a minority - has set the
stage for the entrenchment of a 'thicker' rule of law, which encompasses values such as
human rights for all, public participation and accountability of government, in
post-apartheid South Africa: see Evelyne Schmid, 'Thickening the Rule of Law in
Transition: The Constitutional Entrenchment of Economic and Social Rights in South
Africa' in Edda Kristjansdottir, Andre Nollkaemper and Cedric Ryngaert (eds),
International Law in Domestic Courts: Rule of Law Reform in Post-Conflict States
(Intersentia, 2012) 59.
276 Melbourne Journalof InternationalLaw [Vol 14
501 R Gomez Monsivais, 'La Lutte contre la corruption des fonctionnaires' [The Fight against
Corruption of Officials] (2000) 94 Revue frangaise d'administration publique 231;
Jacques Godeaut, 'La Corruption dans le secteur public' [Corruption in the Public Sector]
(2000) 314 La Revue administrative:histoire, droit, socidtd 215; Alexis Blois, 'Infraction de
corruption d'agent public etranger et procedure penale nationale' [Bribery of Foreign Public
Officials and National Criminal Proceedings] (2006) 2 Revue de droit des affaires
internationales217.
502 Fleming and Zyglidopoulos, above n 25, 5-6.
503 The use of the term 'private corruption' does not imply that the consequences of the corrupt
act remain exclusively private. For example, if doctors prescribe more highly priced
medication because of lobbying by a pharmaceutical company, this has repercussions for the
budget of official health care institutions that reimburse the patients. Similarly, if a listed
company produces false financial statements, this misleads the financial regulatory
institutions and may impose a huge cost on the public treasury if the company goes
bankrupt, as was the case for Enron, for example. Another example is bribery in order to be
admitted to an elite private university. Again, this does not involve the bribery of a public
official but has important consequences beyond the purely private realm. Consequently,
'private' corruption is used to denominate corrupt acts that do not imply the active
involvement of a public official, but does not mean that the consequences of the corrupt act
necessarily remain within the purely private sphere.
504 Fleming and Zyglidopoulos, above n 25, 5, 7.
505 David Blumenthal, 'Doctors and Drug Companies' (2004) 351 New England Journal of
Medicine 1885, 1886, citing Ray Moynihan, 'Who Pays for the Pizza? Redefining the
Relationships between Doctors and Drug Companies. 2: Disentanglement' (2003)
326 British Medical Journal 1193. Even in the absence of special benefits being offered to
doctors, the mere promotional activities by pharmaceutical companies (in the sense of
information sessions to physicians) have not been proven to increase the quality of
prescription behaviour. On the contrary, one study suggests increasing prescribing
frequency, increasing costs and lowering prescribing quality: see Geoffrey Spurling et al,
'Information from Pharmaceutical Companies and the Quality, Quantity, and Cost of
Physicians' Prescribing: A Systematic Review' (2010) 7(10) PLoS Medicine 1. In the US in
2001, the ratio of pharmaceutical sales representative to physicians was 1:4.7:
see Blumenthal, above n 505, 1185-6.
2013] The InternationalLegal Framework against Corruption 277
driving licence) it may be easier to at least be aware of the bribery and speak out
against it, than it is for the doctor's patient or the company's shareholders to find
out about corrupt practices. Corrupt acts in the purely commercial sphere may,
due to their vast complexity or technicality, be especially hard to unearth - as
the example of Enron demonstrates.
A useful understanding of the complex phenomenon of corporate corruption
has been provided by Peter Fleming and Stelios Zyglidopoulos. 506 They explain
corporate corruption from a threefold perspective. First, any corrupt act is
performed by an individual (agency). Secondly, an individual may be induced to
engage in corrupt practices depending on the organisational pressure within the
company (structure). Thirdly, once an organisation condones one corrupt act, this
quickly leads to a snowball effect (escalation).5 0 7 This threefold view
(agency-structure-escalation) demonstrates the importance of not exclusively
prosecuting individuals, or exclusively companies, but to look at the interplay
between both. In addition, it underlines the importance of intra-company policies
against corruption and regular training. Moreover, it shows the importance of
tackling early-stage forms of corruption, such as insider trading before initial
public offerings, relatively small financial misrepresentations and even
anti-competitive behaviour such as price-fixing. 508 These acts may be symptoms
of an emerging and contagious corrupt corporate culture.
A study on the effects of corruption on cross-border corporate acquisitions
revealed that the shareholders of the target company in a country affected by
corruption pay a price for the corrupt culture in their country. 509 The study found
no evidence that domestic corruption would constitute a significant barrier for
foreign investment, only that the shareholders of the local target pay the price in
terms of a lower premium price for their shares, with an average of a 20 per cent
premium loss. 510 Local corruption may not only affect the type of investment
made (local start-up or takeover, which in turn may alter the extent of the
transfer of technology and transaction opportunities for local firms) and the
merger premiums paid by foreign investors, but it may also play a role in the
overall valuation of TNCs that operate in corrupt countries, as well as the type of
their local transactions. As for a TNC's overall valuation, a study on this issue
found that the overall valuation of TNCs is lower if they operate primarily in
countries with a high degree of corruption. 51 1
During the UNCAC negotiations, the subject of private sphere corruption was
one of the more contentious topics. The EU took the lead in favour of addressing
private sphere corruption but the US rejected this. 512 Eventually, it was decided
to include non-mandatory provisions on private sector corruption in the UNCAC.
States parties 'shall consider' criminalising active and passive bribery and
embezzlement in the private sector. 513 The prevention-valve is less freestanding,
given that states parties 'shall take measures' to prevent private sector
corruption, even though this requirement is softened by adding 'in accordance
with the fundamental principles of its domestic law'. 514 The reason for the US
resistance to the criminalisation of private sector corruption was that US business
feared it would lead to lawsuits in foreign courts over contract and procurement
irregularities. 515
At the soft law level, the UNGA resolution adopting the ICCPO explicitly
[u]rges Member States carefully to consider the problems posed by the
international aspects of corrupt practices, especially as regards international
economic activities carried out by corporate entities, and to study appropriate
legislative and regulatory measures to ensure the transparency and integrity of
financial systems and transactions carried out by such corporate entities ...516
Along the same lines, the introductory language of the UNGA resolution
adopting the UNDAC '[e]ncourages private and public corporations, including
transnational corporations, and individuals engaged in international commercial
transactions to cooperate in the effective implementation of the Declaration'.517
In September 2006, the ICC issued a memorandum to the Working Group on
Bribery, in which it recommended amendment of the OECD Convention so as to
include private sector corruption. The memorandum states that
private-to-private corruption, even though it does not affect directly public trust
vested in public officials, undermines the smooth functioning and credibility of
free, open and global competition. By adding an artificial and unwarranted
511 This suggests that investors are aware of the risks related to corruption: see Christos
Pantzalis, Jung Chul Park and Ninon Sutton, 'Corruption and Valuation of Multinational
Corporations' (2008) 15 Journal of Empirical Finance 387. This study was limited to
US Transnational Corporations ('TNCs') where the perceived risks of corrupt practices may
be deemed higher than for non-US TNCs due to the strict provisions of the FCPA. If the
TNC has a certain level of intangible assets, this conclusion no longer holds. For example,
there are fewer opportunities to extract bribes from a firm with technological know-how as
its main asset, than from a mining company that undertakes a large number of road
transports, which can easily be blocked when no bribe is paid. Because of high transaction
costs in countries seriously affected by corruption, it is more advantageous for TNCs with a
high level of intangible assets to internalise their operations, rather than entering into
(costly) corrupt transactions with external firms in the corrupt country: at 387, 414.
512 Webb, above n 5, 213.
513 UNCAC arts21-2.
514 Ibid art 12.
515 Webb, above n 5, 214.
516 Action against Corruption, UN Doc A/RES/51/59, para 7.
517 UNDAC, UN Doc A/RES/51/191, annex para 6.
2013] The InternationalLegal Framework against Corruption 279
V CONCLUSION
523 The US Sentencing Commission issued sentencing guidelines for both individuals and
organisational offenders. These guidelines stipulate that the level of the appropriate penalty
will be directly influenced by 'the prior diligence of an organization in seeking to prevent
and detect criminal conduct': Cleveland et al, above n 10, 217 (citations omitted). See also
United States Sentencing Commission, Guidelines Manual (2010) <http://www.ussc.gov/
Guidelines>.
524 Steve Berkman et al, 'The Fight against Corruption: International Organizations at a
Cross-Roads' (2008) 15 Journal of Financial Crime 124, quoted in Djordjija Petkoski,
Danielle E Warren and William S Laufer, 'Collective Strategies in Fighting Corruption:
Some Intuitions and Counter Intuitions' (2009) 88 Journal ofBusiness Ethics 815, 815-16.