Block 4
Block 4
Market Failure
Externalities and
UNIT 7 EXTERNALITIES AND PUBLIC GOODS Public Goods
Structure
7.0 Objectives
7.1 Introduction
7.2 Externalities
7.2.1 Negative Externalities and Inefficiencies
7.2. 2 Positive Externalities and Inefficiencies
7.3 Ways of Correcting Market Failure
7.3.1 Pigovian Tax
7.3.2 Merger and Internalisation
7.3.3 Emission Standards and Emission fee
7.3.4 Missing Market
7.3.5 Private Bargaining and Negotiation: Coase Theorem
7.4 Public Goods
7.5 Public Goods and Market Failure
7.5.1 The Free-rider Problem
7.6 Optimal Provision of Public Goods
7.6.1 The Samuelson–Musgrave Theory
7.6.2 Local Provision of Public Goods: Tiebout Hypothesis
7.6.3 Social Choice Problem: Voting Mechanism
7.6.4 Role of Government in Provision of Public Goods
7.7 Let Us Sum Up
7.8 Some Useful References
7.9 Answers or Hints to Check Your Progress Exercises
7.0 OBJECTIVES
After going through this unit, you will be able to:
Market Failure
7.1 INTRODUCTION
Consumption (or production) decisions of an agent affect people not directly
involved in the transactions. Such indirect effects often remain unaccounted
for by the agent creating them. In the previous units, we considered the
cases of markets where negotiations between agents (the buyers and the
sellers) led to optimal (in case of perfect competition) or suboptimal (in case
of imperfect competition like monopoly, monopolistic competition,
oligopoly) allocation of resources. In all these cases we assumed that there
were no unaccounted indirect effects involved. Now we will study the cases
when efficient private allocation may become infeasible. In other words, we
will consider the case when markets fail to clear. The reasons for the market
failure could be— presence of externalities, public goods and asymmetry of
information.
In this unit we will come across the concept of externalities and public
goods. Externality refers to the uncompensated impact of one agent’s
actions on another agent. When the impact is adverse, it is called a negative
externality, and when the impact is beneficial, we have a case of positive
externality.The presence of externality leads to market failure. By market
failure we mean, when market is unable to reach an equilibrium outcome in
price or quantity. As a result, firm may produce too much or too little so that
market outcome is inefficient.
7.2 EXTERNALITIES
Externalities can arise between producers, between consumers, or between
consumer and producers. An externality occurs if a person’s activity, such as
consumption or production, affects the well-being of some other person or
group of persons, for which she(he) or the group has not been
compensated. The term externality comes from the fact that someone
external to the action or transaction is affected by the production or
consumption of the good.
There are two types of externalities: A negative externality occurs if an Externalities and
Public Goods
activity creates costs (harm or discomfort) for uninvolved people. Examples
of negative externalities: Cars and factories generate air pollution that affect
people’s health. Cars entering congested freeways impose time costs on
other drivers, as all cars slow down as a result. Another example of negative
externality is when a steel plant dumps its waste into a river that fishermen
use for their daily catch. More the waste the steel plant dumps into the river
lesser the amount of clean water available for fish breeding and
consequently lower will be the output of the fishermen. It can be seen from
this example that independent action of the steel plant increased the cost to
the fishermen and adversely affected their output for which they are not
compensated. Hence the presence of negative externality leads to the
occurrence of additional costs, which the agent causing it fails to realise. As
a result, in the presence of negative externality there is over-generation of
the activity causing negative externality.
Market Failure
MB
By competitive market we mean that the steel firm takes price as given.
Here the competitive price taken by the steel firm is P1 which is also the
marginal benefit (MB) curve of the firm in competitive market. Now supply
curve of the firm is reflected by the firms’ marginal cost curve, MC. The
optimising firm will produce that quantity of steel where its MB intersects its
MC. In the above figure, this happens at quantity q1. Hence a competitive
steel firm will maximise its profits by producing quantity q1 at the given
price P1. Now let us assume the steel plant dumps waste generated in the
process of steel production in the river that pollutes the river used by the
fishermen to catch the fish. Enhanced pollution level of the river water
negatively impacts fish population in the river and hence the amount of fish
a fisherman is able to catch. Thus, it can be said that production of steel
involves a negative externality which is the additional cost to the society in
the form of loss to the fishermen. This cost is reflected in the above figure as
the marginal external cost (MEC).
The MEC curve is upward sloping indicating a positive relation with the
firm’s output. As production of steel increases, harm to the society
increases. MSC represents the marginal social cost. It is the total cost to the
society given by the sum of MC and MEC. It includes the cost to the steel
firm and to the fishermen for the production of steel. Firms for profit
maximisation equate MC to MB and ignore the costs it incurs to the society
in the presence of negative externality. The social optimal is attained where
MSC is set equal to MB, that is, at q*. Here we can see socially optimal steel
output q* is lower than private optimal at q1.
In Fig. 7.2, it is shown how the presence of negative externality distorts the
optimal outcome of the steel industry and leads to social loss. Considering
that each firm faces similar externality, the steel industry will be facing the
similar externality. MC1 is the marginal cost in the steel industry and DD is
the demand curve in the steel industry, showing the marginal benefit (MB). Externalities and
Public Goods
The industry will maximise the profits by producing the quantity of steel
where MC1 equates MB.
The industry’s private optimal is at quantity Q1 and optimal price P1. Now
again industry fails to internalise the cost of its production activity on fishing
industry. MEC1 depicts marginal external cost of production of steel
industry, which is positively related to increasing output of the steel
industry. MSC1 is the marginal social cost in the steel industry which is the
sum total of MC1 and MEC1 (i.e., MSC1 = MC1 + MEC1). The social optimal is
where MSC1 intersects MB, that is at quantity Q* and price P*. The socially
optimal output of the steel industry should be Q* at price P* compared to
private optimal output of the industry Q1 at the price P1. At the socially
optimal output Q* external costs on the fishermen are internalised in the
production cost.The loss to the society resulting from the excess production
by the industry in the presence of negative externality is shown in the figure
as the shaded triangular region.
P1 < P*
Hence, we see that in the presence of negative externality the equilibrium
price P1 is too low to include all the cost incurred in the production of steel.
P1 in the above figure reflects the private marginal costs to the firms. It does
not include the costs to the society. In the presence of externality the
market price is not efficiently build to clear the market. Therefore, market
Market Failure fails in the presence of negative externality. In the next section we will show
how market fails in the presence of positive externality.
In Fig. 7.3, consider the case of vaccines against a communicable disease. Let
the marginal cost of vaccine be constant and equal to MC. The demand for
vaccine is shown as downward sloping D curve. This demand curve depicts
the marginal benefit to single individual. An individual will optimise his/her
consumption where private marginal benefit equals private marginal
cost(MB=MC). Taking MC to be constant at P1, the private optimal is
attained at quantity q1. Now this private allocation ignored the presence of
an external benefit that vaccines will have on the society in terms of lower
spread of the disease captured by the marginal external benefit (MEB).
Marginal social benefit (MSB) is the sum of private MB and MEB. The social
optimal is given by the quantity q* where MSB equals private MC. Notice in
the Fig. that q* > q1.
So we see that in the presence of positive externality, the market allocation Externalities and
Public Goods
is under-produced than the social optimal and hence market allocation is
called as inefficient and hence we see that in the presence of externality
market fails.
Check Your Progress 1
1) Define externality. How does it leads to market failure?
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
The waste produced in the production of the steel is dumped in the river
and this adversely affects the fish industry. The steel manufacturers do not
internalise this cost to the society in their private cost of production of steel.
This results in a market outcome that is inefficient and greater than the
social optimal. To persuade the steel producer towards internalisation of
cost to the society because of its action, the two industries (Steel and Fish)
can merge and in this way the externality in the cost of production can be
internalised. There is a definite incentive for the two industries to merge. If
the actions of one affect the other, then they can make higher profits
together by coordinating their activities than by each going alone. The
objective of profit maximisation itself should encourage the internalisation Externalities and
Public Goods
of production externalities. So when the parties involved merge, the total
marginal cost now will also include the external cost of steel production to
the fish industry. Now the merged industries will optimise considering the
social cost instead of private cost. Hence, with the merged industries the
market allocation will be efficient.
Suppose the regulatory body set the efficient emission standard at E* (say
equal to 20 units). The firm will be heavily penalised for emission greater
than this level. Now suppose the firm produces emissions greater than this
level. To make sure that the firm follows the emission standard the
regulatory body determines the emission fee. Emission fee is the amount
required by the emitting firm to pay per unit of emission released by its
production activity. Standard emission fee is determined at the intersection
of MEC and MCA curves in the above figure. MEC stands for marginal
external cost, which is the cost the emission causes to the society. MCA is
the marginal cost of abating the emission borne by the firm. It measures the
additional cost to the firm for installing pollution control equipment. MCA
slopes downwards showing that when the emission abatement is high, or
the level of emission is low, higher costs are borne by the firms to abate the
emission. So with low level of emission, required abatement is high and vice
versa. With no abatement cost to the firm, profit maximising firm will
produce emissions equal to 40 units, where marginal cost of abatement is
zero. E* equal to 20 is the optimal emission level, when there is abatement
cost involved and marginal fee of emission is Rs. 30. If the firm lowers the
emissions to somewhere below 20, cost of abatement will be greater than
Market Failure cost to the society and vice versa. Hence we see E* is the optimal emission
level.
However, there are problems associated with this instrument. Firstly, the
government or regulatory authorities often does not possess enough
information regarding the level of the legal emission standards to be set or
the optimal amount of the emission fee to be charged to ensure optimal
generation of emissions. Secondly, cost of enforcing the limits is ignored. For
instance, if the industry emits smoke and the firms have to cut down on
smoke emission by putting filters on the chimneys then this cost should be
taken into account.
Suppose there is now a market for pollution. If we let the price of pollution
per unit as ߬ǤLet ݔଵ be the amount of pollution firm 1 wants to sell and ݔଶ
be the amount of pollution firm 2 wants to buy. The profits of the two firms
now are given by:
When the demand for pollution equals to supply for pollution: ݔଵ ൌ ݔଶ ൌ Externalities and
Public Goods
;ݔnow we get back to the social optimality condition : ൌ ܿ ᇱ ሺݔሻ ݁ ᇱ ሺݔሻǤ
Since ݁ ᇱ ሺݔሻ ͲǢ ܽ݊݀߬ ൏ Ͳǡ Ǥ Moreover,
for a market of pollution to exist, there must be property rights in pollution.
Either the polluting firm should have the right to pollute or the polluted firm
should have the right to clean air/water, that is should own clean air/water.
Further the market for certain pollution can be quite thin where there may
be few agents in the market.
Market Failure
06& 0&
3ULFH
0(& 0&
0(&
0% ;
2 4 4 ;
It includes the cost to the steel and Fish industry. Steel industry for profit
maximisation would equate MC1 to MB and produce at Q1 ignoring the
costs to the society. On the other hand, social optimal is attained where
MSC is set equal to MB, that is, at Q* (< Q1).
1) What are the different ways of correcting the market failure resulting in
the presence of negative externality?
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
2) How can private bargaining lead to efficient allocation in the presence
of externality?
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
Market Failure done through the pricing of that good (those who do not pay the price, do
not get the goods).
Non-rivalry means consumption of a public good by an agent does not
reduces its availability to the other agents. Accordingly, at any given level of
production, the marginal cost of providing it to the additional consumer is
zero. For example, consider the use of highway (uncongested). Once the
highway is functional and open for public use, if there are 100 cars running
on it, there is no additional cost of providing the highway to 101st car. Hence
an uncongested highway is a non-rivalrous good. Most goods are rival,
especially private goods. This means that if in a market a seller brings 100
units to sell, if an individual buys 5 units, then for the other individual the
available number of units to buy is 95. This is so because there is marginal
cost of production associated with each unit of private good and hence they
have limited production. A good, consumption of which is rivalrous must be
allocated among individuals. A good which is non-rival in consumption can
be made available to everyone without affecting any individual’s
opportunity for consuming them.
Different kinds of goods have different characteristics. Broadly there are 4
categories of the goods,
Rival Non-rival
Excludable Pure Private goods Club goods
Non-excludable Common Resource goods Pure Public goods
Goods that are non-excludable and non-rival are the pure public goods, like,
national defence. Goods that are rival and excludable are the pure private
goods. Goods that are rival but non-excludable are referred to as the
common property resources , like common pasture lands, ground water,
fishing grounds. They are non-excludable as there are no established
property rights on such resources so as to exclude someone from using it.
Rivalrous nature for instance results from the fact that excessive grazing by
one herd of cattle will result in erosion of the land and hence limit its use for
other cattle herders. Goods that are non-rival in consumption but
excludable are called club goods. Club goods are like membership of club.
Membership into a club is non-rivalrous, as the facility of club is open to
everyone but the club can make the entry excludable by charging the
membership fee (or allowing only its members to enjoy certain
programmes/ performances etc).
Public goods are not necessary national: The list of public goods is much
smaller than the list of goods that government provide. For example,
Education is rival in consumption. This results from the fact that as class size
increases, each student gets lower attention. Hence there is positive
marginal cost of providing education to one more child. Likewise charging
tuition fee can exclude some children from enjoying education. Hence, Externalities and
Public Goods
education is provided by local government because it entails positive
externalities, not because it is a public good.
Free riding situation bears its resemblance to the Prisoners’ Dilemma game,
though the two are not exactly same. Suppose there are two tenants in a
house who are trying to decide whether to construct a collapsible gate at
the entrance or not. If the gate is constructed, both will enjoy better security
in equal measure. So we may treat it like a public good. Suppose both the
individual earns Rs. 5000 and each value the gate at Rs. 1000 and the cost of
the gate is Rs. 1500, so the joint valuation of the gate exceeds the cost. Once
Market Failure the gate is constructed it will benefit both the tenants. Now the question is
whether to get a gate constructed or not.
Tenant 2
Buy Don’t Buy
ƵLJ ;оϱϬϬ͕оϱϬϬͿ ;оϱϬϬ͕ϭϬϬϬͿ
Tenant 1
ŽŶ͛ƚƵLJ ;ϭϬϬϬ͕оϱϬϬͿ (0, 0)
Here the strategy ‘Don’t Buy’ is the dominant strategy for both the tenants.
So the dominant strategy equilibrium or the Nash equilibrium is mutual free
riding (Don’t Buy, Don’t Buy) leading to suboptimal provision of public
goods. If the tenant 1 decide to buy the gate then the tenant 2 is having the
incentive to free ride and enjoy the better security and vice versa. So there
is a credible threat for both the tenant that the other one will free ride
against his decision to opt for ‘Buy’, which leads to the equilibrium of
mutual free-riding. However here the social optimal situation is one person
take the responsibility to buy the gate and both to enjoy the better security.
As per the theory, an efficient economy produces what people want. Private
producers, whether perfect competitors or monopolists, are constrained by
the market demand for their products. If they cannot sell their products for
more than it costs to produce them, they will be out of business. Because
private goods permit exclusion, firms can withhold their products until
consumers pay in order to consume them. Buying a product at a posted
price reveals that it is “worth” at least that amount to you and to everyone
who buys it.
Market demand for a private good is the sum of the quantities that each
household decides to buy (as measured on the horizontal axis) at each price.
The diagrams in Fig. 7.7, illustrate the derivation of a market demand curve. Externalities and
Public Goods
Assume that society consists of two people, A and B. At a price of Re 1, A
demands 9 units and B demands 13 units of the private good. Market
demand at a price of Re 1 is 22 (= 9 + 13) units. If price were to rise to Rs. 3,
A’s quantity demanded would drop to 2 units and B’s would drop to 9 units;
market demand at a price of Rs. 3 is 2 + 9 = 11 units. The point is that the
price mechanism forces people to reveal what they want, and it forces firms
to produce only what people are willing to pay for, but it works this way only
because exclusion is possible.
3 3 3
1 1 1
DA DB DA+B
0 2 9 0 9 13 0 11 22
Units of Output Units of Output Units of Output
Fig. 7.8 shows demand curves for buyers A and B. If the public good were
available in the private market at a price of Rs. 6, A would buy X1 units. Put
another way, A is willing to pay Rs. 6 per unit to obtain X1 units of the public
good. B is willing to pay only Rs. 3 per unit to obtain X1 units of the public
good. Remember, public goods are non-rival and non-excludable. Hence,
one and only one quantity can be produced, and that is the amount that
everyone gets. When X1 units are produced, A gets X1 and B gets X1. When
X2 units are produced, A gets X2 and B gets X2.
Samuelson argued that once we know how much society is willing to pay for
a public good, we need to only compare that amount to the cost of its
production. Fig. 7.9 reproduces A’s and B’s demand curves and the total
demand curve for the public good. As long as society (in this case, A and B) is
willing to pay more than the marginal cost of production, the good should
be produced.
Given the MC curve as drawn in Fig. 7.9, the efficient level of output is X1
units. If at that level A is charged a fee of Rs. 6 per unit of X produced and B
is charged a fee of Rs. 3 per unit of X, everyone should be happy. Resources
are being drawn from the production of other goods and services only to the
extent that people want the public good and are willing to pay for it. We
have arrived at the optimal level of provision for public goods. At the
optimal level, society’s total willingness to pay per unit is equal to the
marginal cost of producing the good.
Externalities and
Public Goods
Here we discuss the optimal level of public good that should be produced
and/or provided. Consider an economy with only two goods one public and
one private. Suppose there are two individuals 1 and 2 and their initial
wealth levels are given by ݓଵ ܽ݊݀ݓଶ . The respective provision for the
public good by individual 1 and 2 be given by ݃ଵ ܽ݊݀݃ଶ ; and let ݔଵ ܽ݊݀ݔଶ
denote the consumption of private goods by each individual. Let G be the
total amount of public good produced and c(G) be the cost of producing
and/or providing that public good. The agents face the constraint that their
initial wealth cannot exceed their total expenditure on the private goods
and the public goods:
డࣦ డ
డ௫మ
ൌ െߣଵ డ௫మ െ ߣଶ ൌ Ͳ (ii)
మ
డࣦ డభ డమ
డீ
ൌ డீ
െ ߣଵ డீ
െ ߣଶ ܿ ᇱ ሺܩሻ ൌ Ͳ (iii)
డࣦ
డఒభ
ൌ ܷଶ כെ ܷଶ ሺݔଶ ǡ ܩሻ ൌ Ͳ (iv)
డࣦ
ൌ ݓଵ ݓଶ െ ݔଵ െ ݔଶ െ ܿሺܩሻ ൌ Ͳ (v)
డఒమ
Market Failure డ
From (i) we get ߣଶ ൌ డ௫భ . Then from (i) and (ii) by eliminating ߣଶ we get
భ
ങೆభ
ങೣభ
ߣଵ ൌ ങೆమ .
ങೣమ
In other words the condition for optimal provision of public goods can be
ଵ ଶ
written as: ீܴܵܯ ீܴܵܯ ൌ ீܥܯ
i.e., The sum of the marginal rates of substitution between the private good
and the public good for the two individuals must equal the marginal cost of
providing the public goods. This condition is known as the ‘Samuelson Rule’.
If we interpret MRS as the marginal willingness to pay, then the Pareto
efficiency condition can be interpreted as sum of the willingness to pay must
be equal to the cost of providing an extra unit of public goods.
If the efficiency condition is violated, it can be shown that at least one
individual can be made better off and nobody is made worse off. Suppose
for example the sum of the MRS is less than the marginal cost. Let MCG = 1
ଵ ଵ ଶ ଵ ଵ
and ீܴܵܯ ൌ ଶ ǡ ீܴܵܯ ൌ ଷ. Then agent 1 would be willing to accept Rs. ଶ
worth of the private good for the loss of Re 1 of the public good and agent 2
ଵ
would be willing to accept Rs. ଷ worth of the private good for the loss of Re 1
of the public good. Suppose we reduce the amount of the public good by Re
1. Then we can compensate the two agents by giving them Rs. 5/6 worth of
the private good and still have Rs. 1/6 worth of private good left to be
distributed to the two individuals and make them better off. Thus if the sum
of the MRS between the private good and the public good for the two
individuals is less than the MC, less of the public good and more of the
private goods should be provided.
Market Failure Critics of government involvement correctly say that the existence of an
“optimal” level of public-goods production does not guarantee that
governments will achieve it. It is easy to show that governments will
generally fail to achieve the most efficient level. There is no reason to
believe that governments are capable of achieving the “correct” amount of
control over externalities. Markets may fail to produce an efficient
allocation of resources, but governments may make it worse. Measurement
of social damages and benefits is difficult and imprecise. For example,
estimates of the costs of acid rain range from practically nothing to
incalculably high amounts.
Just as critics of government involvement must concede that the market by
itself fails to achieve full efficiency, defenders of government involvement
must acknowledge government’s failures. Many on both sides agree that we
get closer to an efficient allocation of resources by trying to control
externalities and by doing our best to produce the public goods that people
want with the imperfect tools we have than we would by leaving everything
to the market.
Check Your Progress 3
1) Define public goods. How they different from pure private goods?
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………………
Externalities and
7.7 LET US SUM UP Public Goods
In an unfettered market, certain goods and services that people want will
not be produced in adequate amounts. These public goods have
characteristics that make it difficult or impossible for the private sector to
produce them profitably. Public goods are non-rival in consumption
(meaning, their benefits fall collectively on members of society or on groups
of members), and/or their benefits are non-excludable (that is, it is generally
impossible to exclude people who have not paid from enjoying the benefits
of public goods). An example of a public good is national defence.
Theoretically, there exists an optimal level of provision for each public good.
At this level, society’s willingness to pay per unit equals the marginal cost of
producing the good. To discover such a level, we would need to know the
preferences of each individual citizen. According to the Tiebout hypothesis,
an efficient mix of public goods is produced when local land/housing prices
and taxes come to reflect consumer preferences just as they do in the
market for private goods. Because we cannot know everyone’s preferences
for public goods, we are forced to rely on imperfect social choice
mechanisms such as majority rule. The theory that unfettered markets do
not achieve an efficient allocation of resources should not lead us to
conclude that government involvement necessarily leads to efficiency.
Governments also fail.
Market Failure
7.9 ANSWERS OR HINTS TO CHECK YOUR PROGRESS
EXERCISE
Check Your Progress 1
Asymmetric
UNIT 8 ASYMMETRIC INFORMATION Information
Structure
8.0 Objectives
8.1 Introduction
8.2 Asymmetric Information
8.3 Adverse Selection
8.3.1 Market for ‘lemons’
8.3.2 Market for Labour
8.3.3 Market for Insurance
8.3.4 Market for Credit
8.4 Solution to Asymmetric Information- Signalling and Screening
8.4.1 Signalling
8.4.2 Screening
8.5 Moral Hazard
8.5.1 Principal-agent Problem
8.6 Let Us Sum Up
8.7 Some Useful References
8.8 Answers or Hints to Check Your Progress Exercises
8.0 OBJECTIVES
After going through this unit, you will be able to:
x explain the concept of asymmetrical information;
x discuss how asymmetrical information leads to market failure;
x describe market solutions to the problem of asymmetric information;
x define the problem of moral hazard resulting in the presence of
asymmetric information; and
x understand principal agent problems.
8.1 INTRODUCTION
In a perfect competitive market structure, one of the key assumptions
defining the market is that of complete and symmetric information among
the parties involved in the transaction. That is, we assumed no seller knows
more about a product’s characteristics than a buyer, and no buyer knows
more about the product’s costs than a seller. Such an assumption is
unrealistic due to the fact that in real life, one party to a transaction often
has more information than another about the characteristics of the good or
Market Failure service to be traded. This condition is referred to as that of asymmetric
information.
For instance, the seller of a product usually knows more about the quality of
the good than the buyer; workers usually know more about their abilities
than the potential employers; in the market for second-hand cars, sellers
have more information regarding the true status of the car than the buyer;
in the financial market, the creditor has relatively lesser information about
the default risk of the debtor than the debtor himself; and in the health
insurance market, the insurance company has lesser information about the
health status of the individual than the individual himself. These are some of
the common examples of the presence of asymmetrical information.
Let us discuss a few of these examples which lead to adverse selection and
market failure in detail.
Let the owners of the lemon want to sell it at Rs. 1,00,000 and the owners of
the plums want to sell at Rs. 2,00,000. Let the buyer of the car is ready to
pay Rs. 2,40,000 if the car is a plum but Rs. 1,20,000 if the car is a lemon. If
there is no problem in verifying the quality of car from the market, then the
lemons will be sold at some price between Rs. 1,00,000 to Rs. 1,20,000 and
the plums will be sold at some price in between Rs. 2,00,000 to Rs. 2,40,000.
Since buyers cannot observe the quality of car to be purchased, they will
have to guess about the quality of an average car. Given that there is only 50
per cent chance of getting a plum (i.e., a car is equally likely to be a plum or
a lemon), the expected value of the car for a typical buyer is:
ଵ ଵ
ܧሺܤሻ ൌ ଶ ൈ ʹͶͲͲͲͲ ଶ ൈ120000 = Rs. 1,80,000.
However, at that price the owner of the lemons will be only willing to sell
the car (because ܧሺܤሻ ൌRs. 180000 >ܵ(ܧ )ൌRs. 100000) but not the
owner of the plums (because ܧሺܤሻ ൌ Ǥ180000 <ܵ(ܧ௨ )ൌRs. 200000).
The price that the buyers are willing to pay for an average car is less than
the price that the sellers of plum expect from the transaction. So at a price
of Rs. 180000, only lemons would be offered for sale. Even though the price
at which buyers are willing to buy plums exceeds the price at which sellers
are willing to sell them, no such transaction for plums will take place. This is
the problem of market failure. In an extreme case, if the buyer was certain
that he would get a lemon, he would not be willing to pay Rs. 1,80,000 for it.
The equilibrium price then would have settled somewhere between
Rs. 1,00,000 to Rs. 1,20,000. For this price range market would have been
segregated, for sellers of plums would not offer their cars for sale.
Asymmetric
8.3.2 Market for Labour Information
Now consider market for labour in Fig. 8.1. Let us represent the number of
workers on the horizontal axis and monthly wages on the vertical axis. The
figure shows demand curves for high- and low-ability workers when
workers’ abilities are observable to the potential employers, labelled as DH
and DL respectively. The figure also shows the supply curves for high- and
low-ability workers labelled as SH and SL respectively. The higher the
monthly wage, more the high-ability workers are willing to accept
employment.
SH
SL
12000 DH
6000 DL
2000
Using this figure, we show how asymmetries exist in the labour market.
Usually workers have greater knowledge about their abilities than their
potential employer. We assume here that workers are paid according to
their abilities.
Initially we assume the ideal market situation where the potential employer
can easily differentiate between a high-ability and a low-ability worker.
Accordingly, a high-ability worker will be paid where curve DH intersects SH.
The number of high-ability worker employed will be 500 and they will be
paid a monthly wage of Rs. 12,000. The equilibrium for low-ability worker is
where curve SL intersects DL, that is, at 400 low-ability workers paid a
monthly wage of Rs. 6000 per month. Low-ability workers are paid lower
than the high-ability workers when the labour market is in equilibrium. In
this case, we do not face a situation of asymmetric information, as the
abilities of the workers to be hired are common knowledge. Thus, the
employer can easily differentiate between a high-ability and a low-ability
worker.
A E
6000 D
D
4000 DL
F
2000
In Fig. 8.2, area ABC represents the deadweight loss due to lower hiring of
high-ability workers and area DEF represents the deadweight loss resulting
from hiring too many of low-ability workers. In the above case we saw that
in the labour market equilibrium, with the presence of asymmetric
information, fraction of high-ability workers will be smaller than it would
have been in the first best scenario (without any information asymmetry)
where the potential employers would able to identify abilities of the
workers before hiring. Because of asymmetric information, low-ability
workers drive high-ability workers out of market. This phenomenon is an
important source of market failure.
To see how market signalling works, let us consider the case of asymmetric
information in the labour market. In the labour market where high- and low-
ability workers are present and are not easy distinguishable, employing
somebody can be very costly to the potential employer. If an employer hires
a low-ability worker for a job requiring high-ability, he will be in severe loss.
In such a case ŵĂƌŬĞƚ ƐŝŐŶĂůůŝŶŐ works great. The high-ability worker can
signal the employer about his abilities, which stand out amongst all the
other low-ability candidates. Signals could be in the form of better resume,
being highly qualified, education level, showing good etiquettes, speaking in
decent language, etc. These mechanisms are often used by the high-ability
worker to signal the potential employer about his (her) potential and makes
sure the employer credit him (her) with a high quality tag.
Asymmetric
8.4.2 Screening Information
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
Market Failure 3) What is solution to the problem of adverse selection?
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
Moral hazard often arises in the labour market since employers cannot
monitor the behaviour and efforts of their employees completely. This
causes inefficiency with employees exerting less effort than the employer
would consider required. Moral hazard is also prevalent in big corporations,
where individual managers may take actions that further their own interests
at the expense of the company, which we discuss in the next section. In
general, moral hazard occurs when a party to a transaction takes hidden
actions that remain unobserved by its trading partner and that affect the
benefits or payoff of the latter.
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
Market Failure 2) What is meant by the principal-agent problem? What leads to principal-
agent problem? How can that be corrected?
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
....................................................................................................................
Asymmetric
8.8 ANSWERS OR HINTS TO CHECK YOUR PROGRESS Information
EXERCISES
Check Your Progress 1
Market Failure
GLOSSARY
620(86()8/%22.6
1) Hal R Varian, Intermediate Microeconomics, a Modern Approach, W.W.
Norton and Campany/Affiliated East-West Press (India), 8th Edition,
2010.
2) C. Snyder and W. Nicholson, Fundamentals of Microeconomics,
Cengage Learning (India), 2010.
3) Salvatere, D. Microeconomic Theory, Schaum’s Outline Series, 1983.
4) Pindyck, Robert S. and Daniel Rubinfield, and Prem L. Mehta (2006),
Microeconomics, An imprint of Pearson Education.
5) Case, karl E. and Ray C. Fair (2015), Principles of Economics, Pearson
Education, New Delhi.
6) Stiglitz, J.E. and Carl E. Walsh (2014), Economics, viva Books, New
Delhi
188
MPDD/IGNOU/P.0.4K/July, 2021
ignou
THE PEOPLE'S
UNIVERSITY
BECC-108
School of Social Sciences
Indira Gandhi National Open University
INTERMEDIATE
MICROECONOMICS • II
m
m [ Partial Equilibrium ] [ General Equilibrium ]
C')
C') Equilibrium in only Simultanious Equilibrium
I
...Iii one market in all the markets
co
C)
-
::::,
.,
r+
(D
3
-·
c.
(D
GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM
r+ • General Equilibrium with
(D COMPETITION
a Welfare Economics
n
(D
n • Externalities and
Rival Non-Rival
Private Goods Club Goods
Excludable Eg: House, Car
Eg: Cable TV
Non- Common Goods Public Goods
Excludable Eg: Fish in Ocean Eg: National Defense
ISBN: 978-93-91229-68-9