TL1. C1
TL1. C1
3
4 The Structure and Economics of Payment Systems
This opening chapter will attempt to define and describe some funda-
mental concepts which will enable readers to understand the rationale
behind the various payment instruments and systems described.
Central Bank
Bank D Bank C
⫺1000 ⫹1000
Bank D Bank C
Debtor/Payer Creditor/Payee
Debtor/Payer
Creditor/Payee
Credit advice
Payment
and/or
instruction
statement
Clearing: a Process
Payments to
customers of ACH Payments for
other banks customers of C
Bank D ⫺1000 ⫹1000 Bank C
Central Bank
Time Collateralized
Balance
Balance
credit line
Cut-off
Time
Net payment system: RTGS: need to maintain
need to fund final position balance within limit throughout the day
its settlement account with the central bank will fluctuate according to
the payments it sends and receives. Central banks, no longer willing to
act as ‘lender of last resort’, will only grant credit facilities to the commer-
cial banks against collateral, normally securities on deposit or repurchase
agreements (repos), which represents an opportunity cost to the banks
who cannot trade them. Payments which cannot be effected because they
would breach the credit limit are queued, therefore delayed, awaiting
incoming payments or a further injection of liquidity. Banks must there-
fore manage their liquidity carefully during the day, seeking to minimize
the collateral posted to secure credit facilities. We will see in section 3.3
of this chapter how RTGS systems have evolved to optimize liquidity.
Payment systems generally operate during pre-determined opening
hours; most important is the cut-off time beyond which payments
received will not be processed and are carried over until the next
working day.
solvability. Ultimately, a bank can reduce its cap on another bank to zero,
but this drastic measure is only taken under extreme circumstances.
A related criterion is the number of payments a bank will contribute
to the system. Eligibility criteria normally stipulate either a minimum
number of transactions or a minimum market share in terms of value. If
an indirect member’s payment volumes grow, accession to direct mem-
bership will not increase the total number of payments across the system,
except for the small amount which it might settle directly with its former
direct member.
Each payment system sets technical and operational criteria according
to the schemes it operates: messaging and file formatting standards; com-
munication interface specifications; liquidity management; ability to
respect deadlines and response times; and recovery and backup require-
ments in case of technical failure of the payment system itself or of the
members’ back-office systems. These place heavy demands in terms of
investments and human resources which often cause even sizeable banks
to opt for indirect membership.
Payment systems generally operate on a cost-recovery basis: revenues
originating from membership fees, annual charges and transaction fees
should cover operating costs and the funding of new developments.
Some Clearing Houses operate on a cost-plus basis in order to gener-
ate a profit for their owners. RTGS systems operated by central banks are
sometimes subsidized in the interest of risk reduction, the subsidy being
euphemistically referred to as a ‘public good factor’. The annual charges
are usually fixed and therefore to the disadvantage of low-volume mem-
bers. Transaction fees are independent of the value of the payment and
generally reduce in relation to the volume of payments each member
contributes to the system. In the US and particularly Europe since the
advent of SEPA which allows clearing houses to offer services across bor-
ders (see ch. 6 sec. 4), competition is constantly forcing transaction fees
downwards to attract new members and volumes. When a new payment
system is developed, membership fees generally help fund the initial
investments and launch costs. When banks seek to join an existing
system, the fee should theoretically reflect the actual value of the sys-
tem in operation balanced by the fact that the new member contributes
payment volumes which can reduce the transaction fee and improve
liquidity; these valuations are extremely complex and the pursuit of
volumes to achieve economies of scale in the current competitive envi-
ronment generally result in ‘token’ joining fees. Ultimately, the balance
between these pricing components reflects the objective of the payment
system owners: do they wish to expand its use or maintain it as an
The Architecture of Payment Systems 11
• all participants had access to the same information at the same time;
• no participant held a dominant share enabling it to influence liquidity
and pricing (interest rates); and
• the market was sufficiently liquid.
Indirect
member
Direct Net
member balances
ACH RTGS
Central
bank
Money
Direct market
member
3 Payment operations
3.1 Payment initiation
The payment instrument is agreed between the payer and the bene-
ficiary. In the case of a remote (not face-to-face) electronic payment,
for instance to pay a utility bill, it could be a cheque, a credit trans-
fer initiated by the payer or a direct debit where the beneficiary has
a mandate to draw funds from the payer’s account. In the case of a
credit transfer, the payer will issue a payment instruction and send it
to his bank. If this instruction is not in a compatible electronic form
(for instance from internet banking), bank staff will input the payment
details, an operation which inevitably creates the risk of transposition
errors. If the payer’s bank is an indirect member of the system, it will
transmit the instruction to its direct member after checking the bal-
ance or credit limit of its client. The direct member then transmits the
instruction to the clearing house if it is a low-value payment or to the
RTGS payment system if it is a high-value payment. If this sequence of
processes, see Figure 1.4, is entirely electronic with no human inter-
vention likely to cause errors, it is known as STP (Straight Through
Processing).
14 The Structure and Economics of Payment Systems
40 40
20 70
20
60
Gross amounts
10
20 30
20 10
40
Bilateral netting Multilateral netting
banks exchange files of payments bilaterally, agree the net amount, and
settle through the local RTGS system. The generic term Clearing and Set-
tlement Mechanism (CSM) is therefore used to describe these operations
irrespective of whether an ACH is involved or not.
At the beginning of each day, banks will transfer funds into their settle-
ment account and/or post the collateral required to secure the neces-
sary credit facility. Should the queue lengthen because of insufficient
16 The Structure and Economics of Payment Systems
incoming payments, the bank must either top-up its settlement account
by transferring own funds, accessing the money market, or post addi-
tional collateral with the central bank to extend its credit line. Efficient
liquidity management is essential in RTGS systems as the substantially
higher cost of RTGS payments relative to ACH payments is less depen-
dent on the processing charge than on the cost of the liquidity: interest
on money market operations or the opportunity cost of immobilizing
securities for collateral.
For this reason, great efforts have been deployed to implement
liquidity saving features in RTGS systems:
• Priority levels: high level priority payments will always take precedence
over lower priority payments: separate queues are maintained for each
priority. The highest priority is normally reserved for payments related
to operations with the central bank and the settlement of DNS pay-
ment systems, or securities clearing systems, which settle through
the RTGS system (known as ancillary systems). The higher priority
queue(s) are normally processed on a first-in-first-out basis (FIFO).
• Queue management: up until settlement, payments can be re-ordered
within queues, moved between priorities or even cancelled.
• Offsetting payments: a lower priority payment from bank A to bank B
will be delayed until a payment from bank B to bank A is presented:
both payments will be submitted simultaneously so that only the dif-
ference will reduce the liquidity. RTGS systems which also include
such netting facilities are known as hybrid payment systems.
• Liquidity reservation: liquidity can be set aside for high priority
payments and the settlement of ancillary systems.
• Timing of payments: earliest and/or latest submission times can be
allocated to payments, which can be changed before settlement.
• Liquidity pooling across the various subsidiaries and foreign branches
of a multinational bank.
In addition, banks can limit their risk vis-à-vis other direct members by
setting bilateral limits against individual banks and/or multilateral limits
against groups of banks which can be changed throughout the day.
A situation may arise when the system is gridlocked, meaning that
payments are queued because of insufficient funds on some banks’ set-
tlement accounts which, if settled, would lift the balance to allow other
banks’ payments to be settled. In Figure 1.6 we can see that payments
are queued for banks A, B and C which, if released, would allow all
to be settled. Facilities exist therefore for authorized staff at the central
The Architecture of Payment Systems 17
A to B: 200
Bank A: Bank B:
position 100 B to C: 300 position 200
C to A: 500
Bank C:
position 300
Payment
system
Payment
system
The simplest is the V routing, whereby the payment messages are sim-
ply transmitted between the direct members and the payment system
(see Figure 1.7).
In the T-copy routing, messages are sent between banks and copied to
the payment system (see Figure 1.8).
The copy can either contain the full payment message, or only the
information necessary for clearing and/or settlement: essentially identi-
fiers for the payer’s and beneficiary’s bank and the amount; information
such as the originating and beneficiary customers as well as the motive
for the payment, such as an invoice reference, are not required for
settlement.
The most sophisticated is the Y-copy, essentially used for RTGS systems
(see Figure 1.9).
The Architecture of Payment Systems 19
Send payment
SWIFT
RTGS system
Settle payment subject to:
validation, liquidity, limits, etc.
Central bank
Simultaneous debit/credit amount accounting
A B
The message is copied to the RTGS system and held by SWIFT until set-
tlement confirmation has been received from the RTGS system so that
the receiving bank knows that the funds have been irrevocably settled.
The architectures described in this opening chapter represent the
‘established order’ and the paradigms prevailing until the end of the
twentieth century. We will develop in subsequent chapters how these
models and the payments business have evolved under global competi-
tive pressures and regulation.
4 Standards
Standards are an important element of payment systems. They ensure
that all participants can automate the process by specifying that, within
a message containing payment details, each field (such as name of benefi-
ciary, amount, etc.) can be uniquely identified and that the information
is transmitted using the same format to avoid, for instance, the potential
confusion created by an Englishman writing a100.60 and a French-
man writing a100,60. Each country has developed its own standards for
domestic systems while all international payments use the SWIFT stan-
dards (see ch. 3 sec. 2). The current trend is to move towards the ISO20022
standard for electronic payments, which is a methodology by which
20 The Structure and Economics of Payment Systems
best positioned to negotiate fees and execution times with the banks and
issue requests for competitive proposals. We will see in Part IV how the
banks attempt to lock them in with cash management and other value-
added services. Businesses are also, generally speaking, impervious to the
risk management costs.
Commercial banks are most sensitive to the profitability of payment
services: maximizing revenues and reducing overall costs. These include
clearing and settlement fees, investments in infrastructure and operat-
ing expenses, as well as the cost of liquidity and collateral reflecting
risk management. Certain banks specialize in payment services, seek-
ing participation in clearing and settlement systems in several countries
to accelerate execution times. They are also constantly streamlining
processes and upgrading their technology to improve STP and liquid-
ity management (see ch. 14 sec. 1). Faced with increased investments,
several small and medium-sized banks are seeking to outsource their pay-
ment operations to these specialized transaction banks, which are keen
to increase volumes to reduce unit processing costs through economies
of scale.
Central banks are primarily concerned with risk minimization, partic-
ularly systemic risk which could destabilize the entire financial system.
They have responsibility for oversight over payment systems and to
promote technological innovation for risk minimization and smooth
liquidity management. They also require efficient systems as a tool to
implement their monetary policy, to rapidly transmit their interventions
and to measure their impact.
We can see that payment systems are not neutral. They transfer funds
and demand liquidity. They require heavy investments, operational dis-
cipline and resources from the commercial banks, as well as vigilance
from the central banks and regulators.
Palais des Papes. Italian popes often came from merchant and banking
families and were therefore fully aware of the latest financing tech-
niques. They would appoint a senior Church official, experienced in
banking and payment networks, to manage the Papacy’s finances.
The Church would maintain a network of tax collectors extending to
the most remote regions: Poland, Scandinavia, the Levant, etc., so
funds had to be repatriated to Rome or Avignon. As physical trans-
portation was too dangerous, the Papacy would contract with the
great Italian merchant and banking families such as the Medici or
the Bardi. The pontifical tax collectors would remit the taxes into
the foreign branches of the bankers, who would make them available
(minus a pre-agreed commission) to the Papacy in Rome or Avignon
by using the funds deposited with them by the Church dignitaries and
members of the Curia. They would use the funds collected locally
to purchase goods, such as wool from England which was sold to
the Florentine weavers for the sumptuous cloths and robes we see
today in the portraits by Holbein and Titian. The bankers ensured the
safe availability of funds collected remotely, the settlement and the
foreign exchange, all sources of fees.
2
Payment Instruments
23
24 The Structure and Economics of Payment Systems
2 Cash
Cash – notes and coins – is the oldest payment instrument since mankind
progressed beyond barter. Coins are usually minted by the government
(the Mint in the UK, the Hôtel des Monnaies under the Ministry of
Finance in France), while notes are printed under the authority of the
central bank, either by themselves – the Bank of England – and/or sub-
contracted to other central banks or specialist security printers such as
De la Rue or Giesecke and Devriendt. Several illustrious historical figures
have been in charge of issuing notes and coins, from Thomas Gresham
and Isaac Newton to . . . Che Guevara who was governor of the central
bank after the 1959 revolution in Cuba.
Cash is linked to the concept of seigniorage: ‘In a historical con-
text, the term seigniorage was used to refer to the share, fee or tax
which the seignior, or sovereign, took to cover the expenses of coinage
and for profit. With the introduction of paper money, larger prof-
its could be made because banknotes cost much less to produce than
their face value. When central banks came to be monopoly suppliers
of banknotes, seigniorage came to be reflected in the profits made by
them and ultimately their major or only shareholder, the government.
Seigniorage can be estimated by multiplying notes and coin outstand-
ing (non-interest bearing central bank liabilities) by the long-term rate of
interest on government securities (a proxy for the return on central bank
assets)’.1
Cash has the advantage of providing instant finality and discharge of
debt, but is bulky and expensive to handle in terms of transport, stor-
age, security and counting. For this reason several countries have passed
legislation to ensure that salaries, pensions and social benefits are paid
by cheque and/or electronic credit transfers. The scenarios of gangster
films based on attacking the payroll vans are today obsolete, but cash
still accounts for the largest number of personal payments (63% in the
UK, two-thirds of which being five pounds or less in 20062 ), so hold-ups
on security transport vans and their staff are still common . . . no change
in the scenario from attacking the Wells Fargo (the precursor of the global
Californian bank) stagecoach in westerns!
Cash handling costs are estimated at a45–70 billion in the EU, or
0.4–0.6 per cent of GDP.3 No explicit charge is made to retail customers
26 The Structure and Economics of Payment Systems
for cash handling, but banks attempt to recover transport and handling
costs from large retail outlets such as supermarket chains.
Recent anti-money laundering (AML) legislation also compels mer-
chants to report cash payments in excess of a certain amount which
varies by country.
3 Cheques
A cheque (or check in the US) is a signed written payment instrument
drawn by the debtor (or payer) on his/her bank and presented, either
face-to-face or by mail, to the creditor (or payee). The cheque is a ‘pull’
payment. The theoretical sequence of events should be:
Legislation was first passed dispensing the banks from returning the
cheques to the drawers, but compelling them to store them – either
physically, or on microfilm or digital image. To increase acceptance by
retailers, cheque guarantee cards were introduced which guaranteed the
cheque up to a specified amount, subject to the creditor verifying the
card number written on the reverse of the cheque, the signature and in
some cases the photograph – this however only being truly effective in
the case of face-to-face payments.
The next step in certain countries was cheque truncation, whereby
the data is captured by the creditor’s bank (who stores the cheque or its
image and charges the debtor’s bank for his efforts) and transmitted elec-
tronically to the debtor’s bank or the clearing house – thereby omitting
signature verification! Cheque imaging is also gaining wider acceptance
(see ch. 7 sec. 5). Under customer pressure, banks have recently cred-
ited the beneficiary immediately (especially if the cheque is guaranteed
by a cheque guarantee card), but reserve the right to recover the funds
should the cheque not be honoured. The system is therefore wide-open
to fraud and counterfeiting, the onus resting squarely on the debtor to
verify his bank statement regularly and report any cheque debit which
appears suspect: this triggers the recovery of the original cheque or its
image for investigation.
The average cost of processing a cheque is estimated at 6.3 cents4 in
the US.
The number of cheque payments is declining regularly (8 per cent in
the UK in 20065 ), which means that the processing costs per item are
rising as the infrastructure costs are largely fixed. Economies of scale are
essential, so cheque processing is generally outsourced – in Great Britain,
all banks entrust cheque processing and clearing to their jointly owned
Cheque and Credit Clearing Company.
Corporations dislike cheques as they require manual handling and
reconciliation is difficult, relying mainly on the drawer scribbling the
invoice number and/or customer reference on the reverse! Many leading
retailers and petrol chains in the UK refuse to accept cheques. Cheques
remain however popular with retail customers and small businesses on
account of convenience (particularly for remote occasional payments),
force of habit and the float – ‘the cheque is in the mail (!)’. France
and the US remain the largest cheque users, while some countries (for
instance Sweden, the Netherlands, and Japan for retail customers) have
withdrawn cheques. Several countries however have taken measures
to proactively reduce the usage of cheques by differential pricing to
encourage the use of more efficient instruments.
28 The Structure and Economics of Payment Systems
Originator’s Beneficiary’s
bank bank
Clearing and
3 Settlement 4
Debit originator’s Mechanism Transmit
account and send credit transfer
credit transfer message message 5
2
Credit
Instruction
beneficiary
1
Invoice
Originator Beneficiary
4 Credit transfers
Credit transfers (or direct credits) are initiated by the debtor (or origi-
nator) who instructs his bank to debit his account; the bank verifies the
instruction and availability of funds prior to transferring the information
to a clearing house or directly to the beneficiary’s bank which credits the
latter’s account after verification (see Figure 2.1). The credit transfer is a
‘push’ payment.
Exceptions are defined as:
Debtor’s Creditor’s
bank bank
Clearing and
5 Settlement 4
Check Mechanism Instruction
6 mandate, to collect, 3
Check transmit including Collection,
mandate, collection mandate including
debit details mandate
account details
2
Pre-notification (e.g. invoice) with date of collection
1
Mandate
Debtor Creditor
5 Direct debits
Direct debits are payments initiated by the creditor through its bank,
which collects (draws) the funds from the debtor’s account at his/her
bank, subject to a legally binding mandate agreed by the debtor (see
Figure 2.2). Direct debits generally rely upon a guarantee to the debtor
that he will be able to recover the funds collected in case of error or
dispute within a specified time limit. The direct debit is a ‘pull’ payment
and can be used for one-off or regularly occurring payments. In certain
countries the creditor’s bank charges an interchange fee, also known as
a Multilateral Interchange Fee (MIF), to the debtor’s bank.
Exceptions, also known as the ‘Rs’, are:
The scheme rules will normally define the following times and deadlines:
CSM CSM
2 2 4
3 Mandate Signed 3 Mandate
Mandate details mandate Mandate details
details details
1 1
Creditor Creditor
Debtor Signed Debtor Agreement
mandate
Creditor’s mandate flow Debtor’s mandate flow
6 Cards
Historically, credit cards originated in the US in the 1920s when hotel
chains and oil companies began issuing them to customers. The inven-
tion of the bank credit card is attributed to John Biggins of the Flatbush
National Bank of Brooklyn who invented the ‘Charge-It’ scheme between
the bank’s customers and local merchants in 1946.6
Cards are operated under schemes whereby banks issuing cards to their
customers rely upon the understanding that these cards will be accepted
at merchants acquired (or signed-up) by other participating banks.
Payment Instruments 33
Scheme operator:
clearing, settlement
€99.5
€100 ⫽ £79.20
⫹ fee
and services at retail outlets, petrol stations, restaurants, etc. The amount
of the purchase or withdrawal is debited near-instantly from the holder’s
account. Some debit cards are only intended for withdrawals at ATMs
and therefore called cash cards. A cheque guarantee feature (see sec. 3 this
chapter) is often incorporated with debit cards.
The same applies to deferred debit cards except that the amounts are
accumulated, up to an agreed ceiling or limit, until the monthly date
at which the full amount of the purchases since the last statement is
debited from the holder’s account through a direct debit. Credit cards
offer revolving credit facilities whereby the holder, upon receipt of
his monthly statement, can choose to settle the full amount or pay
only part (subject to a minimum), in which case the issuing institu-
tion will charge interest on the outstanding balance. Deferred debit
cards are sometimes assimilated to credit cards as the holder bene-
fits from a credit facility for a maximum of one month, but they
do not offer true credit that enables the holder to postpone part
payment beyond the monthly settlement date, even if willing to pay
interest.
Prepaid cards (or stored-value cards), either for a fixed amount at pur-
chase and disposable or re-loadable, are an alternative to cash and the
stored amount is reduced by each purchase. They are mostly closed sys-
tems used for public transport (for example the contactless Octopus in
Hong Kong, Oyster in London, Z-pass on US toll roads) and increasingly
for mobile telephones. In Hong Kong, the Octopus card has reduced the
weight of coins handled daily from 60 tons to 1 ton.
Electronic purses are prepaid cards accepted at a wider range of out-
lets or even country wide. They have been extremely successful and are
commonly used at a national level in Belgium and the Netherlands (Pro-
ton and ChipNick respectively) for purchases, public transport, parking
meters, etc., but the Moneo card in France has met with only limited
success as small retailers refuse to pay the merchant fee which would
reduce their slim profit margins.
Corporate purchasing or procurement and Travel and Entertainment (T&E)
cards are issued to enterprises to pay for supplies and services, either to
the company itself and/or to selected employees for business travel and
entertainment.
Affinity cards are linked mainly to charities which collect a fraction
percentage of the purchases.
Finally private cards are issued mainly by retail chains and petrol com-
panies for use at their stores and outlets, with or without revolving credit
facilities.
Payment Instruments 35
which they sold in 2002 to MasterCard Europe; we will see when talking
about SEPA in Chapter 6 (sec. 7.5) how short-sighted the move was.
card debt run up over the Christmas shopping season to a new card, tak-
ing advantage of 0 per cent interest rate introductory offers by no less
than 169 cards!10
As mentioned in Chapter 1 (sec. 2.1), several non-banks have entered
this market: retail chains, automobile associations, sports clubs, airlines,
etc. Particularly in the US and the UK, individuals will therefore carry
several cards and draw on all available credit lines for payments leading
to high levels of personal debt, creating a social and economic problem
which has raised the concern of central banks.
Issuers endeavour to segment their customers by offering cards with
low limits (for youths and students) and ‘gold’, ‘platinum’ or ‘diamond’
cards to the more affluent customers, appealing to status-consciousness
and linked to profitable value added services: high credit limits (in some
cases unlimited), insurance, concierge services for priority travel, theatre
or restaurant bookings, etc. Issuers are also mining the accumulated data
on their customers’ expenditure preferences and patterns; the first efforts
were mainly aimed at fraud reduction, attempting to detect card thefts
through unusual behaviour. Major efforts are now devoted to CRM to
fine-tune product and service offerings according to perceived individ-
ual customer preferences, as well as to detect utilization patterns which,
correlated with peer behaviour, might indicate potential delinquency or
propensity to switch to another card.
In summary, profitability for the issuer is mainly driven by for-
eign exchange gains on cross-currency purchases, interest revenues for
revolving credit cards and the targeted marketing of value-added services.
7 Payment channels
Payments can be initiated through a variety of channels. Few, except for
high value transfer requests by retail customers, originate today from a
visit to a branch or a free-format letter. Cheques and credit transfers are
still sent by mail, but most banks now encourage customers to initiate
domestic and international credit transfers up to a certain amount, set
up mandates for direct debits and pay bills for pre-established beneficia-
ries such as utilities or telecommunication operators through proprietary
ATM’s, banking kiosks, telephone banking and internet banking.
In addition, the dramatic increase in internet shopping and procure-
ment has demanded the implementation of secure payments over the
internet.
We will discuss in Chapter 4 (sec. 4) the security measures that have
been introduced to prevent fraud.
Payment Instruments 39
8.1 Cash
More than any other instrument cash is profoundly anchored in col-
lective habits and mentalities and profound differences can be observed
from country to country. Measured as a percentage of GDP, the value of
payments in cash is relatively stable. This explains why new instruments
aimed at replacing cash, such as electronic purses, are slow to gain accep-
tance, even if they offer obvious benefits such as immediate availability
of funds combined with reduced handling costs and improved security
for retailers who would hold less cash on their premises. Small retailers
such as bakers or newsagents are obviously reluctant to pay merchant fees
for card transactions of any type: credit, debit, prepaid or purse. Cash
payments are more common in Germany than in any other European
country; Germans are used to paying large amounts for substantial pur-
chases such as cars in cash, as opposed to cheque or transfer. It was under
pressure from Germany that a a500 note was issued, the highest denom-
ination in any currency, while it would have perhaps been more logic to
provide a a1 note.
Taking the total value of notes and coin in circulation divided by the
population as an indicator, Japanese will hold $5,541 in contrast to
$2,736 in the US and $2,700 in the euro-zone. We note the similarity
between the US and the EU according to this indicator, while the ratio
between cash and GDP shows a slight difference: 6.2 per cent in the
US and 7.7 per cent for the euro-zone. At the other extreme the British
use relatively little cash ($1,443 per capita, 3.4 per cent of GDP and
4.5% of M1 money supply), remembering that the cheque was invented
by Scottish bankers. Two countries diverge substantially from others,
Switzerland and the US. The amount of cash per inhabitant is $5,007
in Switzerland and 9.4 per cent of GDP. The ratio of cash to M1 money
supply is 59 per cent in the US, in contrast to 17.2 per cent in the euro-
zone and 21.6 per cent in Japan. This can be explained by the role of the
40 The Structure and Economics of Payment Systems
Sources: BIS, CPSS, Statistics on Payment and Settlement Systems in Selected Countries, March
2008
US dollar and the Swiss franc as refuge currencies. Half of US dollar notes
and coin are held by non-residents. Similarly, at the time of the conver-
sion of European currencies to the euro, the Bundesbank discovered that
close to half the stock of large denomination Deutschmark notes were
held in Eastern Europe. We should also remember that the US dollar has
also often been substituted to the local currency (dollarization) by some
countries to fight hyperinflation, as was the case in Argentina. Table 2.1
summarizes the above statistics for 2006.
From the above statistics we can also derive the turnover of the total
value of payments (M1/GDP) and the velocity of money (or speed of
circulation) which is the inverse (GDP/M1). Historically one observes a
decrease in velocity: money supply increases faster than GDP over cen-
turies in line with monetarization of the economy. The trend reverses in
practically all countries after World War II as more money was deposited
at banks and money supply increased slower than GDP.
Table 2.2 Use of non-cash payment instruments in the EU and selected countries
in per cent (2006), excluding e-payments
100%
90%
80%
70%
60%
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
96 06 96 06 96 05 96 06 96 06 96 06 06
France Germany Japan Sweden Switzerland UK US
1 Correspondent banking
To satisfy the demand for international payments, banks developed the
system of correspondent banking, opening accounts in the local currency
43
44 The Structure and Economics of Payment Systems
EUR GBP
Belgian bank British bank
Meat invoice
£10,000 €13,550
Belgian supermarket Scottish beef farmer
with each other, called nostro accounts (from the Italian ‘nostro’ meaning
‘our’).
Figure 3.1 illustrates the case of a Belgian supermarket chain order-
ing Angus beef from a Scottish cattle farmer, who invoices it for GBP
10,000. The debtor’s Belgian bank will convert the £10,000 into euros at
the prevailing exchange rate (say a13,550), credit his British correspon-
dent’s nostro account in euros and debit the supermarket’s account by
the same amount plus charges. He will instruct the British bank to credit
the farmer’s account with GBP 10,000, which the British bank will first
debit from the Belgian bank’s nostro account.
This case is relatively simple in the sense that the Belgian bank’s cor-
respondent, also referred to as its sterling clearer, happens to also be the
Scottish farmer’s bank. This is not always the case as banks normally only
entertain correspondent relationships with only two or three correspon-
dents per currency. We can well imagine that the farmer will hold his
account with a bank in Edinburgh which will not be the Belgian bank’s
clearer in the City.
In this case (see Figure 3.2), the Belgian bank will:
• Instruct the Scottish bank to credit the farmer, indicating that cover
will come from his named sterling correspondent;
• Instruct his correspondent to credit the beneficiary’s bank with
the £10,000, which will be effected through the UK clearing and
settlement system.
Cross-Currency Payments and SWIFT 45
Correspondent
Belgian bank
bank
Meat invoice
An even more complex case arises when the payment must be effected
in a third currency other than the debtor’s and the creditor’s. Like most
commodities, oil is traded in US dollars, and Figure 3.3 overleaf illustrates
the case of a French chain of petrol stations ordering oil from Saudi
Arabia.
Payments in US dollars need to be settled at the Federal Reserve Bank
in the US, so the ordering customer’s French bank will credit the dollars
via its US dollar correspondent, the US domestic clearing system and
the Saudi bank’s US correspondent. Printed and on-line directories indi-
cate the names of each bank’s correspondents or clearers in the major
currencies.
As for any account, correspondents issue statements for the nostri
accounts they hold. The ordering banks will reconcile these statements
to ensure that all payments they instruct have been correctly effected and
that no payments have been debited by error. The same applies for all
intermediary banks along the chain. If we consider that a major clearer
will today transact between 50 and 100,000 international payments daily
it is obvious that this reconciliation cannot be effected manually.
These procedures reflect a credit transfer. Direct debits are more diffi-
cult to implement cross-border on account of the different legal regimes,
schemes and consumer protection rules prevailing in each country. We
will see in chapter 6, (sec. 6.2) how cross-border euro direct debits will
be available from 2009 within the SEPA framework.
46 The Structure and Economics of Payment Systems
USD
clearing and
settlement
US
Saudi
France
Arabia
Figure 3.3 Correspondent banks – payments for goods quoted in a third currency,
e.g. commodities
and the SWIFT1 network cut over to live operation in May 1977, after
arduous negotiations with the European postal authorities who then held
a monopoly on telecommunications and could foresee the disappearance
of a lucrative market.
Although the implementation of a secure international private net-
work was in those days a technical prowess, SWIFT’s main achievement
lies in the development of internationally accepted standards for finan-
cial transactions. Messaging standards were first developed for customer
payments, interbank payments and nostro account statements. Stan-
dardized bank addresses were also published known as the BIC codes
(Bank Identifier Code), composed of a unique 4 character bank code,
a 2 character country code, a 2 character location code and an optional
3 character branch code: BBBB CC LL (bbb). The SWIFT system would
validate conformity with the standards and reject any message submit-
ted with errors, ensuring therefore that the sender need only capture
the data once and that messages delivered could be processed automati-
cally by the recipient. With strict guidelines for referencing, this enabled
full end-to-end automation of the processes and flows described in the
previous section, including automated nostro reconciliation. Messages
are encrypted and sophisticated authentication algorithms guarantee
origination, integrity and non-repudiation. Subject to compliance with
defined operating rules and procedures SWIFT also accepts some liabil-
ity for the messages it processes. From early on SWIFT offered a range
of interfacing terminals and software to the network, originally to pro-
vide connectivity to its users confronted with the lack of solutions from
the marketplace. The network subsequently expanded geographically to
include all major financial centres and, at the end of 2007, connected
nearly 8,300 financial institutions in 208 countries.
SWIFT extended in parallel the standardization of messages to cover
virtually all financial transactions: payments and cash management,
treasury (foreign exchange, money markets) and derivatives, securities
and trade (collections and documentary credits). The major break-
through occurred in 1987 after the banks who owned SWIFT accepted,
after protracted hesitations as they feared dilution of their custody busi-
ness, that securities broker dealers and fund managers could connect to
the network to enable the automation of cross-border securities clearing
and settlement. In 2006 the SWIFT membership also approved the par-
ticipation of major corporations to communicate with the bank which
sponsored their participation. Figure 3.4 shows the evolution of the dis-
tribution of SWIFT traffic between markets from 1996 until the first two
months of 2008.
48 The Structure and Economics of Payment Systems
100%
90%
80%
70%
60%
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
Average 1996 Jan–Feb 2008
Trade Treasury Securities Payments
We can see how securities messages have grown to almost equal pay-
ments in volume and have become the strongest contributor to growth.
In 1986 SWIFT entered value-added services by developing and oper-
ating, on an outsourced basis, a netting system for the Ecu (the basket
currency precursor to the euro), which subsequently evolved as the
EBA’s EURO1 netting system (see ch. 6 sec. 5). Several others followed
such as an automated matching service for confirmation of foreign
exchange trades (ACCORD) and solutions for cash reporting, corporate
actions, exceptions and investigations, etc. In addition, SWIFT maintains
directories of the BIC codes, correspondents and settlement agents.
SWIFT also now transmits files without format validation; the current
SWIFTNet platform is IP-based and messaging standards are gradually
migrating towards the XML syntax. SWIFT maintains its leading role in
standards development.
SWIFT itself is not a payment system, but serves as transport net-
work for virtually all major payment and securities market infrastructures
and is arguably today the leading global provider of financial messag-
ing and processing services. During 2007, SWIFT processed an average
daily volume approaching 14 million messages, a five-fold increase from
Cross-Currency Payments and SWIFT 49
4 Remittances
This is the term given to low-value payments transferred mainly by
migrant workers to their families back home for amounts ranging
between $100 and $500. Volumes and values are difficult to estimate as
a large number are effected by ‘informal’ channels such as hawala which
are estimated to add around 50 per cent to some 175 million officially
recorded remittances which exceeded $232 billion in 2005; countries
contributing the largest value are the US and Saudi Arabia.2 In 20 of the
largest recipient countries, these remittances amount for over 10 per cent
of GDP.3
Cross-currency transfer services from banks, based on the correspon-
dent banking model, are expensive and also assume that payers and
50 The Structure and Economics of Payment Systems
52
Risks, Oversight and Security 53
the ECB was used before refund. The next day everything returned to
normal and payment operations were functioning. A banking and stock
market crash had been avoided.
On 7 July 2005 terrorists again struck in London, albeit on a smaller
scale, but no disruption was reported to the payment systems: the lessons
had been learned.
These examples demonstrate both the vulnerability of payment sys-
tems to financial and external events, as well as the resilience which has
been built up over the years in the light of experience.
The amounts and volumes involved: we have seen how RTGS systems
account generally for over 90% of the monetary value, settling in a few
days the equivalent of their country’s annual GDP, while ACHs are con-
stantly seeking to increase volumes to achieve economies of scale. In
other words, the more successful a payment system becomes, the greater
the concentration of risk.
Diversity of expertise and skills: payments stretch across the entire bank-
ing organization, functionally and geographically (retail and wholesale
banking, securities and FX trading, etc. across all branches and sub-
sidiaries) calling for cooperation between a multitude of disciplines: IT,
54 The Structure and Economics of Payment Systems
• credit risk: the risk that a party within the system will be unable to
fully meet its financial obligations within the system either when due
or at any time in the future;
• liquidity risk: the risk that a party within the system will have insuf-
ficient funds to meet financial obligations within the system as and
when expected, although it might be able to do so at some time in the
future;
• legal risk: the risk that a poor legal framework or legal uncertainties
will cause or exacerbate credit or liquidity risks;
• operational risk: the risk that operational factors such as technical mal-
functions or operational mistakes will cause or exacerbate credit or
liquidity risks; and
• systemic risk: the risk that the inability of one of the participants to
meet its obligations, or a disruption in the system itself, could result
Risks, Oversight and Security 55
2 Risk management
2.1 Financial risks
Financial risk arises when there is a delay between acceptance of the
payment by the system and final settlement. This can be caused by a
temporary failure (liquidity risk) or, more seriously, definite inability
by a participant to meet its obligations, for instance in case of default,
suspension or bankruptcy (credit risk).
These intraday settlement risks are significant in Deferred Net Settle-
ment Systems (DNS) when final settlement occurs at designated times,
mostly at the end of the operating day. In addition to the imposition of
minimum capital and credit rating requirements as part of the member-
ship criteria, this has led to the introduction of limits on the maximum
level of risk that a participant can create. These can be bilateral limits
imposed by each participant on the other direct members, an overall
multilateral net debit limit imposed by the system (the maximum dif-
ference at any point in time between the sum of the values of payments
received minus the payments sent by a participant), or a combination
of both.
Measures must therefore be taken to ensure that a DNS system can
settle daily even in case of default of one or more of its members. The
ultimate remedy would be unwinding, which implies removing some – up
to the point where the defaulting participant’s multilateral net debit limit
can be met – or all payments entered by the defaulting participant since
the last settlement and recalculating the net positions. This is, however, a
measure of last resort used extremely rarely as removal of these payments
might leave the surviving members with insufficient funds to meet their
own obligations. The regulators have therefore imposed that participants
bear the responsibility for covering eventual losses; two arrangements
prevail, either individually or in combination:
The key issues for Principles I – VII have been discussed in the previous
section. The asterisk∗ for Principles IV and V, indicating that ‘Systems
should seek to exceed the minima in these two core principles’, refer to
the recommendations of the CPSS that countries should at least imple-
ment an RTGS system for high-value payments and that multilateral
netting payment systems should be able to withstand the inability to
settle by more than one participant.
Principle VIII, which might initially appear as ‘motherhood and apple
pie’, is a reminder that cost efficiency should include all costs: fees, liq-
uidity, joining investment and operating costs. Operators should also
consider that institutions of different size might wish, or be compelled,
to join and that economic interfacing solutions must be made available
to low-volume participants.
Principle IX clarifies that access criteria must be transparent and
objective, for instance minimum capital requirements or market share.
The definition of ‘systemically important’ might appear subjective; the
ECB6 considers that all RTGS systems, high value systems and retail pay-
ment systems for which there is no national alternative, for instance
ACHs handling credit transfers and direct debits irrespective of the value,
must be defined as SIPS.
sends confirmation that the payment has been irrevocably settled fol-
lowing which the change of ownership will be registered. This concept
will be further enlarged in Chapter 11, while Chapter 10 will look at the
elimination of settlement risk in foreign exchange trading.
3 Regulatory oversight
Until the 1990s, central banks were solely responsible for supervising
commercial banks, while separate bodies, such as the SEC in the US,
supervised securities trading. The emergence of global and universal
banks combining retail, commercial and particularly investment bank-
ing and securities services prompted the devolution of supervision to
independent bodies such as the Financial Services Authority (FSA) in
the UK, the Bundesaufsichtsamt für Finanziellen Instituten (BaFin) in
Germany. Arguing that they issue money which is the fundamental
means of exchange, that it is essential to maintain stability of the
financial system and that safe and efficient systems are vital for the imple-
mentation of monetary policy, the central banks maintained oversight
of the payment and settlement systems: ‘Oversight of payment systems
is a public policy activity focused on the efficiency and safety of systems,
as opposed to the efficiency and safety of individual participants in such
systems. . . In many countries, the central bank’s oversight role is consid-
ered an integral element of its function in ensuring financial stability’,7
clearly separating oversight over the payment system from supervision
of its participants.
Oversight is defined as: ‘Oversight of payment and settlement systems
is a central bank function whereby the objectives of safety and efficiency
are promoted by monitoring existing and planned systems, assessing
them against these objectives and, where necessary, inducing change’.8
As mentioned previously, central banks cooperate on these issues and
define guidelines within the CPSS at the BIS which are defined in Box 4.2.
Principle E is of particular importance as payment and securities
systems increasingly offer their services internationally and the above
publication further specifies that ‘there should be a presumption that the
central bank where the system is located will have this primary respon-
sibility’. Under this principle, oversight of SWIFT for example rests with
the National Bank of Belgium where SWIFT is headquartered.
Banks also cooperate in national bodies to define payment services and
monitor performance of the various systems, such as APCA (Australian
Payments and Clearing Association) in Australia and APACS (Association
for Payment and Clearing Services) in the UK. We will see in Chapter 6
Risks, Oversight and Security 63
(sec. 1) how banks also established the European Payments Council (EPC)
to address the Single Euro Payments Area (SEPA). These organizations
are often blamed for preserving the interests of the banks and ignoring
the demands from their customers. A novel approach was taken in the
UK in 2007 through the creation of the Payments Council, whose Board
includes external directors, alongside the Bank of England as an observer
(see ch. 6 sec. 8).
4.3 Cards
With the exception of the US, chip card technology combined with a PIN
under the EMV (Europay, MasterCard, Visa) scheme is gaining worldwide
acceptance and fraud is significantly reduced in comparison with signa-
ture and magnetic stripe. In any case, signature or PIN verification can
only take place when the card holder is physically present in the retail
outlet at the moment of purchase.
The expansion of telephone ordering and internet shopping has also
required the development of security measures to enable Card Not
Present (CNP) transactions. The most common is the CVV2 (Card Veri-
fication Value 2) code, generally referred to as the ‘security code’, which
is a three or four digit number most often placed on the reverse of the
card. It does not however offer protection should the card be stolen. Visa
and MasterCard have therefore developed additional security procedures
such as Verified-by-Visa and SecureCode for MasterCard to be used on
the internet.
In addition to ensuring the authenticity of the card holder, card
providers have sophisticated transaction monitoring systems that ensure
they detect unusual activity or behaviour patterns on an account and can
take the appropriate actions to stop fraud as early as possible.
The Payments Card Industry Standards Council, regrouping the major
brands (Amex, Discover, JCB International, MasterCard, Visa), have also
developed comprehensive requirements for a Data Security Standard (PCI
DSS) covering security management, procedures, policies, network archi-
tecture, software design and backed by comprehensive self-assessment
questionnaires. All issuers, merchants and acquirers have to prove they
abide by these rules and undergo specific assessments to prove it.
68 The Structure and Economics of Payment Systems
69
70 The Structure and Economics of Payment Systems
their settlement account with the central bank to guarantee finality. The
payment system substitutes all interbank settlements by one settlement
in central bank money.
We noted in Chapter 1 (sec. 2.5) that an efficient money market
is indispensable to the smooth functioning of payment systems, as it
enables banks to fund their end-of-day settlement positions in DNS sys-
tems and to access intraday liquidity in RTGS systems. The centralization
of settlement and clearing operations contributes to the pricing of money
on the domestic market (interest rate) and of currencies on the interna-
tional markets (exchange rate). Even in a DNS system the bank’s treasurer
will follow the position throughout the day and, if required, start fund-
ing an anticipated short position early on to avoid higher interest rates
at closure if the market dries up or the spread between the lending and
borrowing rates has widened.
The main impact of a payment system is to unify the market. This was
observed at the launch of the euro and the TARGET high-value RTGS
system. Within a few months interest rates converged across the euro-
zone, except for minor differences due to country credit ratings. The
ECB was able to implement its monetary policy effectively through an
efficient payment system.
Much was written during the subprime crisis about the ‘interdepen-
dencies’ of risk between institutions and instruments across geographies.
The central banks responded by coordinated interventions which they
were able to implement, and measure the impact, through the rele-
vant payment systems and securities markets whose settlement systems
interconnect. Will the major high-value payment settlement systems
interconnect in the same way as we progress towards harmonization of
standards and procedures? Would that provide a more effective tool for
central bankers coordinating their interventions to avoid systemic risk,
or would the risk of single point of failure arise?
3 Network economics
As with all networks, payment systems will benefit from economies
of scale and value-added services which increase its attractiveness and
profitability. Under a regime of perfect competition, prices will con-
verge towards the marginal cost. As the profitability of the core generic
payment service will diminish with competition, competitive differen-
tiation will be dictated by segmented value services through which the
service providers will attempt to increase their profits. Ultimately, the
core payment service becomes a public utility while value-added services
are market-driven.
Networks are driven by economies of scale; costs are largely fixed so
additional transactions reduce the unit processing cost. The value of a
network depends therefore on the development investments, the ser-
vices offered and the volume of transactions processed. It is also linked
to the square of the number of participants according to Metcalfe’s Law.
These factors can however exercise a negative influence, for instance
when a network reaches saturation, obsolescence or even becomes a
de facto monopoly leading to complacency and reluctance to invest in
new developments.
We have seen in Chapter 1 (sec. 2.2) how payment system owners can
vary the various pricing components (joining fee, annual charge, trans-
action fee) according to their objectives at each phase in the life-cycle
of the system. Once a network has reached critical mass, the feedback
effect kicks in: unit costs diminish with growing volumes; new adher-
ents seek to join; and investments can be devoted to the development
of new products and services. Telecommunication operators for instance
decided to invest in mobile telephony in the full knowledge that it would
cannibalize their revenues from fixed lines calls and sought alternative
revenues from mobile and other services such as broadband and value-
added telecommunication services. Similarly, SWIFT launched its file
transfer services knowing that the revenues from the individual message
charge would suffer.
Some systems, such as SWIFT, become immune to new entrants com-
peting on their core transmission services owing to the sheer numbers of
participants and geographical coverage: the barriers to entry are too high.
Volume in payment systems is however highly concentrated among a
small number of large institutions: in the UK for example, the five largest
participants represented 80 per cent of the number of payments over the
CHAPS RTGS, 76 per cent of cheque clearing and 76 per cent of the BACS
ACH volumes in 20061 . With the exception of RTGS systems, payment
The Role of Payment Systems 73