2024.03 Danny - Quah New World Order Multipolarity Multilateralism
2024.03 Danny - Quah New World Order Multipolarity Multilateralism
April 2024
[Link to latest version]
Abstract
This paper argues that, besides geopolitical and security factors, eco-
nomic variables are key drivers for world order. While this is not
the first time world order is splintering, economic interconnectedness
traditionally raised fragmentation costs and thus served to hold the
world together. Now, however, the logic is reversed: economic integra-
tion is, instead, a prime contributor to fragmentation. New mindsets
are, therefore, needed. The paper proposes three guiding principles
for world order: First, build mechanisms for inadvertent cooperation,
requiring for success not explicit collaboration but just individual-
nations advancing self-interest; second, separate out problem domains
where only zero-sum outcomes are available from those where mu-
tual gain is available, possibly by nudges; and third, provide space
for constrained multilateralism—whether plurilateral, minilateral, or
otherwise—that is open and inclusive, and that will allow full-blown
multilateralism to re-emerge where possible.
∗
Lee Kuan Yew School of Public Policy, NUS, [email protected]. The author is
also Faculty Associate, Centre on Asia and Globalisation. He thanks for helpful com-
ments Chatib Basri, Michael E. Cox, Mari Pangestu, Dani Rodrik, Joe Stiglitz, Heiwai
Tang, Alessio Terzi, and participants at the Medellin 2023 IEA World Congress, the 2024
India-in-Asia Conference, and LKYSPP International Relations and LKYSPP Economics
Brownbag workshops.
1 INTRODUCTION
1 Introduction
If world order is fragmenting, that provides opportunity to reconstruct the
international system. But to do so effectively requires first understanding
the drivers underlying the fragmentation, and then putting in place a design
that takes into account and uses to advantage those centrifugal forces.
World order is the operating environment for the global community—
the cross section of nations with diverse self-interests, at different stages
of development, with populations seeing different levels of income. That
global community chooses to hew to the international system’s rules, norms,
and conventions when the benefits to doing so exceed the costs of deviating.
Subject to remaining within an accepted locus of flexibility and dissent, not
all nations need take precisely identical trajectories of practice. World order
faces pressures to fragment when the choices that nations make are mutu-
ally inconsistent or otherwise put pressure on the boundaries of acceptable
behaviour.
This paper builds on the state of the international system as described in
Georgieva (2023), Gopinath (2024), and others, to propose principles for a
world order that works, not necessarily optimally, but just reasonably well.
The traditional thinking is that most geopolitical and security concerns,
all else equal, tend to lead to ever greater world fragmentation, as values,
interventions, and threat perceptions all collide ever more obviously. Thus,
such geopolitical and security considerations naturally provide a centrifugal
force to the international system. In that traditional thinking, however,
the global community also values how economic integration—international
trade, foreign investment, cross-border flows of finance, ideas, and people—
make for increased efficiency, production diversification, economies of scale,
and thus increased prosperity, and so provides a centripetal force to hold
the world together. World order holds in balance these centripetal and
centrifugal forces.
The fragmentation of world order described in, among others, Aiyar
et al. (2023); Georgieva (2023); Gopinath (2024) reflects an increase in cen-
trifugal forces, and is predicted to precipitate not only a decline in economic
prosperity worldwide but an increase in the likelihood of international vio-
lent conflict. The proposal in the current paper shares the same motivations
as Gopinath (2024), Rodrik and Walt (2022), Stiglitz and Rodrik (2024),
Tucker (2022), Vines (2023), and others, who seek to repair or navigate
2
1 INTRODUCTION
3
1 INTRODUCTION
is the so-called “China Shock” (Section 3.1 that has grown uppermost in the
thinking of policymakers, where trade with China is viewed to be “taking
our jobs, hollowing out our industry, stealing our intellectual property”.
Thus, the traditionally opposing drivers in world order have now aligned
instead. This multicollinearity of different forces all working in sync con-
founds attribution of the ultimate cause for world fragmentation. Policy
discussion finds it progressively less relevant to unpack if international dis-
agreement is genuinely because of discord on political values or because
one’s economy is no longer competitive along traditional lines and, thus,
can no longer generate sufficient prosperity for one’s citizens. Language
such as “working to impede China’s advance” or “deter China” have become
conventional, with different political and economic stakeholders interpolat-
ing into them whatever meaning is convenient.
This alignment of centrifugal forces means simply urging cooperation
between nations will be even less likely to be effective in reducing world
fragmentation (Gaspar, Hagan, and Obstfeld, 2018; Sanders, 2023; United
Nations, 2021). Instead, more helpful will be principles that are finetuned
to work against each of the different causes.
The analysis in this paper seeks to provide mechanisms that help keep
together world order, even with this turn around in perspective. On the
economic reasoning that underlies the paper’s proposals, e.g., the analysis
of “inadvertent cooperation”, the closest previous study is Armstrong and
Quah (2023). That latter, however, draws still on a traditional model of
economic and security considerations working in opposition to each other.
By contrast, the current analysis develops the hypothesis that those drivers
now work in the same direction. This paper thus advocates principles that
seek to keep world order from further fragmenting, even when geopolitical,
security, and economic forces are all working to worsen fragmentation.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 sets
out how this paper conceptualises world order. The underlying ideas here
will be familiar to most readers but the atypical language recasting will
help present more efficiently the subsequent economic analysis. Section 3
develops the hypothesis that economic considerations now work alongside
geopolitical and security concerns to worsen world fragmentation. Section 4
advances the principles for stabilizing world order. Finally, a brief summary
is provided in the concluding Section 5.
4
2 WORLD ORDER AND ITS FRAGMENTATION
5
2 WORLD ORDER AND ITS FRAGMENTATION
trade and foreign investment, as well as principles and procedures for trade
and investment dispute resolution. Rules here might seek to establish not
just the principles of exchange but also the nature of economic competi-
tion across nations, conditions under which market economies become no
longer market economies because of, say, excessive state intervention, and
so on. For concreteness when needed, this economics-directed subset of
world order will be referred to as the global economic order.
World order fragments when one or more of the following occur. The
cross-section of nations can de facto partition into separate blocs, each
seeking to have progressively less to do with others. Alternatively, nations
can put pressure on the boundaries of the locus of acceptable behaviours.
The order-rule of national sovereignty, for instance, would be tested by
a foreign power’s seeking regime change or prosecuting military invasion
or interfering with a nation’s domestic political affairs. When its global
economic order is globalization-oriented then world order fragments when
nations set up barriers to trade and foreign investment.
World order can adapt to fragmentation pressures in different ways.
The rules that constitute an order might be rewritten to increase the lo-
cus of flexibility: this keeps within the fold those members seeking to de-
viate from the original rules. Or world order might partition into non-
overlapping, non-interacting sub-orders, perhaps dividing geographically,
or by differences in political systems or alternative approaches to economic
organization: world order then comprises not a single consistent system
but becomes a (mathematical set) union of disjoint sub-orders.
6
2 WORLD ORDER AND ITS FRAGMENTATION
7
2 WORLD ORDER AND ITS FRAGMENTATION
8
2 WORLD ORDER AND ITS FRAGMENTATION
9
2 WORLD ORDER AND ITS FRAGMENTATION
Conversely, therefore, as the world grows more equal and control over re-
sources rises in non-traditional global centers of excellence, will the decline
5
Stiglitz and Rodrik (2024) suggest that the equality implicit in late 20th-century mul-
tilateralism was more in name than in reality. In their view the multilateralism of that
time was designed with sufficient logical backdoors to allow the US to continue to project
its unipolar hegemonic wishes. But compared to the current state of the world, with the
strongest endorsers of that brand of multilateralism now withdrawing their support, the
Stiglitz-Rodrik argument highlights even more the paradox I indicate here when multipo-
larity threatens even faux multilateralism.
10
3 ECONOMIC INTERDEPENDENCE
3 Economic Interdependence
US-China rivalry is the most obvious driver for current fragmentation of
world order. But to understand how its lessons might extend beyond the
specifics of this period of history, it is important to unpack the underlying
cause and propagation mechanism. Moreover, this US-China competition is
not taking place in isolation. From the discussion in Section 2, this specific
US-China fragmentation needs also to be considered against the backdrop
of a general rise in multipolarity.
US-China geopolitical rivalry today is regularly compared to the Cold
War of the mid 20th century. Such language is suggestive of the same
deep geopolitical and security concerns as then experienced. During the
Cold War, the US-Soviet arms race saw the Soviet Union build its nuclear
weapons, army, and air force to where Soviet military capabilities matched
those of the US. This was from a starting point with the Soviets and the
US just coming out of co-equal combat against the Nazis in World War 2.
It was therefore relatively easier for the Soviet Union to do. In the Cold
War, the US (and the West more generally) contended with an alterna-
tive political system actively promoting communism to replace democracy
and capitalism. Across the emerging world, the Soviet Union sought influ-
ence, supported regimes that threatened their neighbors, and encouraged
communist insurgency movements that destabilized nations. There is little
question that in the Cold War the West’s security and way of life were
under threat.
Today, however, these same Cold War characteristics are more difficult
to document credibly in US-China relations. The US is, without question,
the world’s most powerful military force in every measure, including in
strategic alliances, advanced technology, and global extent. Even if its
military expenditure is rapidly rising, China comes nowhere close to the US
in aggregate defense spending, force projection (whether aircraft carriers or
anything else), and aircraft technology. With China having four times the
population of the US, its annual military spending remains under a third.
The situation is significantly different from that in the Cold War between
the US and a highly militarized, post World War 2 Soviet Union.
11
3 ECONOMIC INTERDEPENDENCE
China remains communist in name but its economic system draws in-
spiration from capitalism. The last four decades of China’s economic devel-
opment has been driven by massive flows of foreign capital into a manufac-
turing sector that operates to exacting global standards on its production
outputs, and that seeks to maximise profit, not promote socialist ideals.
True, China’s economy is not entirely free market, but in this, China is not
markedly different from many Western economies. A significant fraction of
China’s markets are arguably more competitive than those in many democ-
racies, both emerging and mature and both West and East. Many Chinese
companies routinely suffer losses and go under. If, in business, Chinese in-
dustry practice were to replace the West’s, Western workers might well find
it disconcerting, but not because those practices threatened the Western
way of life in favour of bloated lazy socialism. Instead, the opposite.
As did the Soviet Union, China seeks influence across the world. But
in this, China is exactly like all other nations, democracies or otherwise.
Unlike with the Soviet Union, however, there is no credible evidence that
China wants international communism to replace democratic capitalism.
To be sure, China’s military rapid-modernization, influence operations,
retaliatory economic sanctions, actions in the South China Sea, and cy-
berhacking activity obviously attract concern worldwide (e.g., BBC, 2023;
Kolstad, 2020; Mozur and Buckley, 2021; Wong, 2024). Equally unhelpful,
however, has been US arbitrariness and inconsistency on key international
agreements. While the US draws on the principles underlying the 1982
United Nations Convention on the Law of the Sea (UNCLOS) and insists
on Freedom of Navigation access to the South China Sea, it refuses to be-
come an UNCLOS signatory (Beckman, 2022). The US’s official agreement
with China includes the One China Policy that “ ‘acknowledges the Chinese
position that there is but one China and Taiwan is part of China’ and that
the PRC is the ‘sole legal government of China’ ”. However, the US will
now and then test its own stated policy by insisting that acknowledgement
differs from agreement, and acting as if it viewed Taiwan as a separate
sovereign state (Maizland, 2024).
This veering between positions shows up most sharply and most recently
in the US approach on industrial policy. The US targeted sharp criticism
through the 1980s at East Asia’s leading economies—Japan, South Korea,
Taiwan, Singapore—as they engaged in state policies to help reposition
their industry landscapes. Japan-bashing (White, 1985) was only the most
12
3 ECONOMIC INTERDEPENDENCE
visible manifestation of this. But at least one could make the case that when
these Asian economies undertook industrial policy, it was to improve their
productivity, upgrade their skills and human capital, and develop their
economies. Inadvertently, these waves of Asian industrial policy raised the
level of competition and sharpened efficiency. On the other hand, US in-
dustrial policy today—the CHIPS and Science Act, the Inflation Reduction
Act—can too often come across as initiating a race to the bottom, rather
than to the top, and seem designed to inflict damage to competitors as
much as to raise American productivity.6
All such actions test the boundaries of rules-based order. But they are,
in the main, not confined to just US-China rivalry nor to states having
different values and political systems. All states with capability engage
similarly. For example, the US’s National Security Agency (NSA) has been
documented as follows:
13
3 ECONOMIC INTERDEPENDENCE
14
3 ECONOMIC INTERDEPENDENCE
15
3 ECONOMIC INTERDEPENDENCE
and thus more equal, the tendency towards instability in world order has
also grown.
In this analysis, it is the China Shock that has been behind the calls for
decoupling and de-risking actions against China. It is not the decoupling
or de-risking or the differences between them that matters; instead, it is de-
China that counts. The shock component rests foremost in the economics of
“taking our jobs, hollowing out our industry, stealing our intellectual prop-
erty”. Whether this is because the US is simply uncompetitive or because
China cheats—through its business practices, its state collaboration with
industry, and its manipulating the value of the Chinese RMB—relative to
its status as developing nation is a matter that remains still to be decided
based on evidence and international adjudication.7
There are likely two added dimensions to the China Shock that are
important to make explicit. First is that the decline in unipolarity has
been far more rapid than many expert observers expected. Allison et al.
(2021, p. 1) describe how as late as the turn of the millennium,
This was not just wishful thinking but the logical conclusion of a widely-
accepted view on how China’s economic foundations engaged with modern
production modalities:
16
3 ECONOMIC INTERDEPENDENCE
The second dimension is that this economic progress did not come
with the attendant political changes that, again, many expert observers
expected. In March 2000 then-President Clinton remarked that China at-
tempting to control the Internet would be like “trying to nail Jell-O to
the wall” 8 (Clinton, 2000). Political theories developed in, e.g., Fukuyama
(1992); Lipset (1959) led many to expect that China’s political system
would converge towards Western-style liberal democracy as its per capita
income rose and social and economic structures modernized. This failed to
take place.
My argument that the China Shock adds an economic dimension to
world fragmentation is consistent with but not the same as a number of
other important ideas about economic forces and disruptions to world order.
O’Rourke (2024) refers to an aversion to “import dependence” that can
emerge when nations are mistrustful of one another. Stiglitz and Rodrik
(2024) describe how, with unexamined capital market openness, “financial
indebtedness” can arise that can then lead to foreign interference. Yes,
these do suggest economic openness will not repair geopolitical and security
fracturing. However, these work because of a fear of ill-intent from one’s
trading partners. So, in these analyses, it is the risk of aggressive action by
the other nation that drives how trade affects international relations. In
contrast, my China Shock description kicks even when all ill will is absent
and the trading partner intends only good things for one’s own nation. In
that sense, the China Shock idea is far more dangerous: it applies even
when all appears to be otherwise safe.
Gowa (2015) describes how geopolitical considerations have, historically,
conditioned trade flows. Then one’s own trading bloc is populated mostly
with one’s allies, while trade across blocs is, by definition, with one’s an-
tagonists. Then the more inter-bloc trade there is, the more acute is the
perception that one is not self-sufficient, even together with one’s allies,
and thus the greater is the incentive to acquire by conquest what one’s al-
lies cannot provide. This too is a scenario where increased trade increases
fragmentation. The Gowa mechanism is not unrealistic but it does assume
that already drawn are the lines of fracture into blocs of allies and rivals.
8
Interestingly, Clinton also said at that same time to his American audience “Most of
the critics of the China WTO agreement do not seriously question its economic benefits.”
This, again, is the central part of my China shock emphasis: What was expected then
turned out to be so much at odds with the reality that unfolded.
17
3 ECONOMIC INTERDEPENDENCE
In contrast, the China Shock mechanism is one that endogenizes those lines
of fracture, so a presumptive ally can turn into a geopolitical rival.
Finally, while the China Shock is the most relevant current develop-
ment, similar features had in the 1980s manifested for US-Japan relations
(Vogel, 1979; White, 1985). Then too surprise was expressed about how
determinedly and quickly Japan moved from dependence on the West, after
World War 2, to superior economic and technological achievement. Then
too did American policymakers make reference to geopolitics and security,
even with Japan obviously already democratic and firmly in America’s Pa-
cific Alliance. In an influential, widely-read piece on how Japan raced
ahead, White (1985) wrote:
But the more important thing that went wrong (. . . ) was almost
too simple to consider. If all people of the world were entitled to
equally free trade, then the cheapest producers would be those
who paid their people least, yet mastered world-class technol-
ogy. In other words, nations whose workers were grateful for
starvation wages could conquer the markets of countries like
America, whose workers demanded the world’s highest wages.
Economics says, of course, those other nations don’t have to pay exactly
starvation wages, just wages lower than in “countries like America”. White
warned that it wouldn’t be just Japan that mattered in this analysis but
“behind loom China and India, desperate as they are to raise their stan-
dards of living—at the expense of American standards, if necessary”. In
this reasoning is not just Japan that stands ready to compete against the
US thus but also China and India. Indeed, every single time in the article
White compared China with Japan, India is always mentioned alongside
the former. Given that China and India are, and were, the only two nations
with a workforce approaching a billion each, the juxtaposition is natural.
But what this analysis also highlights is that any nation—whether autoc-
racy or democracy—that ends up in the same economic position relative to
the US will come under the same scrutiny on its economic profile. Disap-
pointment, therefore, might lie ahead for those nations today—Vietnam,
India, Mexico—that imagine themselves benefiting from US-China conflict
by playing a strategy of being America’s “China plus 1”, i.e., seeking to
take up those parts of the global supply chain that China is now forced
to relinquish. There is every reason why “plus 1” nations could eventually
18
4 NEW PRINCIPLES
become themselves the target of US-X rivalry, just as X has shifted from
Japan to China.
This Section has argued that, together with geopolitical and security
concerns fragmenting the world, economic considerations matter as well.
Moreover, those economic considerations cannot be relied on to provide
countervailing forces against world fragmentation. The Georgieva-Gopinath-
Nye emphasis on how economic integration raises the cost of fragmentation
is a global collective argument; it does not apply for policymaking in indi-
vidual nations.
4 New Principles
The reasoning from Sections 2–3 cautions that world fragmentation might,
with even higher likelihood, imminently worsen. The countervailing force
that some observers hope will emerge from considerations of economic inte-
gration is likely weaker than those of geopolitics and security. Alternatively,
whether or not the geopolitical and security considerations are genuine and
profound, what matters is their alignment of the centrifugal force now seen
to be emerging from economic relations.
The parameters of this challenge of global fragmentation therefore make
urgent the need for some mechanism that can help check the destabilizing
dynamics that are already in place.9 This section suggests four principles
to help reduce further world fragmentation. As the analysis will become
relatively abstract, it is helpful to set down first what those principles will
turn out to be.
The first principle: use nations’ self-interests: look for problem domains
where inadvertent cooperation arises, i.e., where nations even though only
looking out for just their self-interest end up, inadvertently, improving the
collective good. This is not to say nations are actively seek to draw down
the collective good to benefit themselves. Instead, it refers to when nations
are indifferent on matters outside their individual well-being: whether the
collective good rises or falls is not their concern. Inadvertent cooperation
occurs when collective well-being rises even though there is no conscious
attempt at collaboration. In Adam Smith’s words, “It is not from the
9
Recent work with goals and approach closest to the current paper are Rodrik and
Walt (2022), Stiglitz and Rodrik (2024), Tucker (2022), and Vines (2023), although our
formalisms and proposals end up quite different.
19
4 NEW PRINCIPLES
benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker, that we expect our
dinner, but from their regard to their own interest.” 10
Second, divide and conquer: across those problems that world order sees
as challenge, some admit inadvertent cooperation (or come close); others
are zero-sum problems; yet others show epic fail features, i.e., have equilib-
ria under individual optimization that, for all nations, are unambiguously
strictly worse than other outcomes that are feasible but are not equilibria.
Prisoners’ Dilemma games are examples of these. Epic fail challenges are
not zero-sum problems; they are worse. Separating out these three differ-
ent kinds of global challenges help focus the design of guidelines and rules,
and thus help reduce the fragmentation of world order. Under certain con-
ditions, epic fail problems offer the possiblity of third party nudges, i.e.,
small side-payments, judiciously applied, can produce a large shift in the
equilibrium outcome, away from where everyone loses to where everyone
wins. Such nudges, therefore, represent an individual-centered way to solve
a collective action problem.
Third, if multilateralism does not emerge as an equilibrium for all the
nations in a particular world order, restricting membership might help.
Plurilateralism is a constrained multilateralism where within its member-
ship all the features of multilateralism apply, but that plurilateral member-
ship is only a strict subset of the entire community of nations. All nations
are free to join or leave a plurilateral system, but the requirement is that
those within must obey its rules while those outside are not permitted to
disrupt. By remaining open and inclusive in potential membership while
requiring certain codes of behaviour for those inside, a plurilateral system
can be effective in delivering a restricted multilateralism and, addition-
ally, can permit full-blown multilateralism to re-emerge when the larger
community sees benefit for all.
The remainder of this section provides an analytical framework, using
basic game theory, to illustrate the workings of these principles. The dis-
cussion will vary across a range of different payoff matrices to describe
alternative scenarios, and consider situations where side-payments enter
the frame. International Relations research has a long and fruitful his-
tory using such a methodology to provide a unified approach to different
Economists will recognise how if there is a price system this is just the Fundamental
10
20
4 NEW PRINCIPLES
Trade Autarky
Trade (+100, +100) (+95, +90)
Autarky (+90, +95) (−100, −100)
21
4 NEW PRINCIPLES
22
4 NEW PRINCIPLES
Table 2: Zero-sum Game. Regardless of specific actions by different nations, whatever one
nation gains is exactly that the other loses. The contest imagined here is over the loyalty
of an unidentifed “Useful Idiot” (UI), who will work for any player but is easily swayed
by cheap talk. If both players play Silent the UI sitting in the middle between them
works half the time for one, half the time for the other. Normalize the payoffs when that
happens as (0, 0). If one player plies UI with Cheap Talk and the other player stays Silent,
the first player win over UI’s loyalty and services, and so gains +1 while the other player
loses UI’s services altogether, ending up with −1. Since there is only a single UI, what
one player wins is exactly what the other player loses. Equilibrium is (Cheap Talk, Cheap
Talk) but notice that the other diagonal entry (Silent, Silent) is not socially preferred to
the equilibrium. This is unlike an epic fail setting such as Table 3, where everyone can
agree Collaboration is preferred but is simply not reachable. Indeed, in this zero-sum game,
there is no other outcome preferred unanimously by everyone to the equilibrium (Cheap
Talk, Cheap Talk).
23
4 NEW PRINCIPLES
either does not bring one benefit or actually does self-harm (as long as it
harms one’s rival more) is also BTN: only, the outcome is not zero- but
negative-sum. Such a potentially epic-fail outcome leads to the next class
of possibilities that I turn to now.
A Prisoners’ Dilemma game is an example of epic fail. In Table 3 the
equilibrium, where both nations play Confront, is worse than the non-
equilibrium outcome, where both play Collaborate.
Conversely, however, there are epic fail games that are not Prisoners
Dilemma games. This is because epic fail specifies fewer restrictions on non-
equilibrium and equilibrium outcomes than do Prisoners’ Dilemma games.
Over-fishing a common resource, for instance, is an epic fail game but is
not a Prisoners’ Dilemma.13 Failing to act on the global climate crisis is a
significant example of epic fail: all can agree unanimous mitigation would
be an unambiguous social improvement, but if everyone else is already
taking the right action, then one nation’s continuing to burn fossil fuels
benefits itself.
In the epic fail game of Table 3 the unique equilibrium has payoff proper-
ties strictly worse than another outcome that is feasible. However, gridlock
at the bad unique equilibrium keeps nations there, since those nations seek
to advance their self-interest individually, in the absence of an explicit co-
operation mechanism. In such situations, small nudges can dramatically
shift the equilibrium. In the matrix of Table 3 describing payoffs to the
Great Power nations, a side-payment of 1.1% (say) from other nations to
the two Great Powers in favour of Cooperate will shift equilibrium away
from Confront.
Epic fail characterises many of the most important issues live in inter-
national policymaking. It is epic fail situations where there is greatest need
13
When there is a finite common resource, fishing inflicts a negative externality on all
other fisher-folk. We say over-fishing because that negative externality is not internalised
when the individual works out the optimal amount of fishing to be done. Epic fails can
occur even when equilibrium is not unique whereas the Prisoners’ dilemma has a unique
equilibrium that is clearly the worst outcome for everyone. While this precision in logic
is important, more critical for the purposes of this paper, however, is that the Prisoners’
Dilemma game conveys the wrong message for the geopolitical rivalry situation of interest.
In Prisoners’ Dilemma the cooperative outcome sets both prisoners free. That is good for
the prisoners but not particularly so for the rest of society overall, i.e., the international
community in our setting. Much better is to use a language that shows the desirability of
the win-win outcome.
24
4 NEW PRINCIPLES
Cooperate Confront
Cooperate (+100, +100) (−101, +101)
Confront (+101, −101) (−100, −100)
Table 3: Epic Fail. This game relabels the payoff structure of the classical Prisoners’
Dilemma game to highlight that (Cooperate, Cooperate) is not that undesirable social out-
come where, in the usual interpretation, both prisoners get away unpunished. Here, that
outcome is actually good for society overall as much as it is for the two players. The
unique equilibrium in the game is (−100, −100) with both nations playing Confront, while
the (+100, +100) Cooperate outcome, that is both feasible and better for everyone, is not
an equilibrium.
25
4 NEW PRINCIPLES
they will never be employed”. The modern prospect of deadly wars ends
up elevating spending on weapons to make sure those weapons are never
in fact used: This is an epic fail outcome.
These different examples—from techno-nationalism through military
Pyrrhic victories and modern international conflict—engender different mag-
nitudes of gains and losses. Sufficiently large expenditures make it impos-
sible for outside policymaker intervention, especially if the situation has
arisen from Great Power rivalry. Otherwise, however, third nations—those
that are not Great Powers themselves—can contemplate coming up with
sufficient side payment to nudge the Great Powers out of debilitating and
harmful gridlock.
An example of this is the Ottawa Treaty or, more fully, the 1997 Conven-
tion on the Prohibition of the Use, Stockpiling, Production, and Transfer
of Anti-Personnel Mines and on their Destruction (International Commit-
tee of the Red Cross, 1998). World War 2 saw the first widespread use
of landmines, as a way for fighting forces to restrict the mobility of the
enemy. However, landmines are also indiscriminate, enduring, and victim-
actuated: they kill or maim typically in peacetime after the war is over,
and inflict fatality or injury to mostly civilians, many of whom turn out
to be children. The epic fail equilibrium has combatants deploy landmines
across an arena of conflict, but which then lapses back to just an ordinary
landscape—which is when landmines then do the greatest harm. The di-
rect combatants are caught in gridlock, unwilling to unilaterally stop. Yet,
by continuing in that equilibrium, not only do they self-harm but innocent
third parties are caught up in the violence.
What smaller powers—Canada and other small states, NGOs, interna-
tional humanitarian organizations—did was initiate a process to ban such
anti-personnel landmines. Without directly confronting those nation states
deploying landmines and without having any enforcment mechanism, but
instead only by intangible incentives of approbation and consensus, this
Ottawa process eventually signed up over 150 nations to the treaty’s ban.
In 2014, US President Barack Obama broadly accepted the treaty’s terms,
stopped acquiring landmines, and prohibited their use outside the Korean
Peninsula. President Donald Trump, however, reversed this policy in 2020.
Two years after that, President Biden overturned Trump’s policy change.
Although the situation on landmines continues to evolve, the Ottawa
Treaty provides a concrete example of smaller states nudging Great Powers
26
4 NEW PRINCIPLES
27
5 CONCLUSION
5 Conclusion
This paper has described world order and its relation to multipolarity as
cause and multilateralism as effect. It has described how the geopolitical
and security forces for fragmentation are now reinforced, not held back, by
perceptions on how economic integration operates.
In such circumstances, urging the nations of the world to cooperate will
not help to reduce world fragmentation. Without clarifying underlying
causes, little is available by way of tools to help keep world order from
becoming ever more disorderly and fragmented.
This paper has described a convergence in fragmentation drivers and
proposed three guiding principles to help reduce further world fragmenta-
tion. First, provide mechanisms for inadvertent cooperation, where nations
looking out for their own self-interest while oblivious to the collective good,
nonetheless will help advance that collective good. Second, divide up the
challenges confronting world order into those where inadvertent coopera-
tion is possible, those that are zero-sum games, and those that produce
epic fail outcomes. Zero-sum challenges are intractable, and there is no
point further deliberating over them. Epic fail outcomes admit the pos-
sibility of third-party nudging, so states other than Great Powers—states
that are Third Nations, in the language of Armstrong and Quah (2023)—
might be able to exercise agency and nudge world order away from further
fragmentation.
28
REFERENCES
References
Shekhar Aiyar, Jiaqian Chen, Christian Ebeke, Roberto Garcia-Saltos,
Tryggvi Gudmundsson, Anna Ilyina, Alvar Kangur, Tansaya Ku-
naratskul, Sergio Rodriguez, Michele Ruta, Tatjana Sculze, Gabriel
Soderberg, and Juan Pedro Trevino. Geoeconomic fragmentation and
future of multilateralism. Staff Discussion Note, IMF, Washington DC,
January 2023.
Graham Allison. Destined for War: Can America and China Escape
Thucydides’s Trap? Houghton Mifflin Harcourt, 2017.
Graham Allison, Kevin Klyman, Karina Barbesino, and Hugo Yen. The
Great Tech Rivalry: China vs the US. Avoiding Great War Project,
Harvard Kennedy School, 2021.
Shiro Armstrong and Danny Quah. Economics for the Global Economic
Order: The Tragedy of Epic Fail Equilibria. Working paper, Lee Kuan
Yew School of Public Policy, Singapore, November 2023.
David H. Autor, David Dorn, and Gordon H. Hanson. The China Syn-
drome: Local labor market effects of import competition in the United
States. American Economic Review, 103(6):2121–2168, October 2013.
BBC. What is the South China Sea dispute? BBC News, July 2023.
https://www.bbc.com/news/world-asia-pacific-13748349.
William J. Clinton. Trade is the Smart Thing. New York Times, March
2000.
29
REFERENCES
Francis Fukuyama. The End of History and the Last Man. The Free
Press, Macmillan, London, 1992.
Reka Juhasz, Nathan J. Lane, and Dani Rodrik. The New Economics of
Industrial Policy. Working Paper 31538, NBER, Cambridge, MA, August
2023. https://www.nber.org/papers/w31538.
Ivar Kolstad. Too big to fault? Effects of the 2010 Nobel Peace Prize on
Norwegian exports to China and foreign policy. International Political
Science Review, 41(2):207–223, March 2020.
30
REFERENCES
Paul Mozur and Chris Buckley. Spies for hire: China’s new breed of
hackers blends espionage and entrepreneurship. New York TImes,
August 2021. https://www.nytimes.com/2021/08/26/technology/
china-hackers.html.
Joseph S. Nye. With China, a ‘Cold War’ analogy is lazy and danger-
ous. New York Times, 2021. https://www.nytimes.com/2021/11/02/
opinion/biden-china-cold-war.html.
Dani Rodrik and Stephen M. Walt. How to build a better world order.
Foreign Affairs, 101(5):142–155, September 2022.
31
REFERENCES
Nicolai Ruge and Danny Quah. The WTO Needs to Address Two Under-
lying Issues With Global Trade. The National, February 2024.
Bernie Sanders. The US and China must unite to fight the climate crisis,
not each other. The Guardian, August 2023.
David Vines. The new world order and global economic governance. Work-
ing paper, Oxford University, September 2023.
Odd Arne Westad. The Cold War. Basic Books, New York, 2017.
Theodore H. White. The danger from Japan. New York Times Mag-
azine, July 1985. https://www.nytimes.com/1985/07/28/magazine/
the-danger-from-japan.html.
32
REFERENCES
Jacky Wong. Chinese tariffs soured Australia’s wine. Wall Street Journal,
February 2024. https://www.wsj.com/arts-culture/food-cooking/
how-chinese-tariffs-soured-australias-wine-industry-6c04dbd1.
33