Complexity and Industrial Clusters - Dynamics and Models in Theory and Practice
Complexity and Industrial Clusters - Dynamics and Models in Theory and Practice
Contributions to Economics
http://www.springer.delcgi-bin/seurch_book.pl ?series= 1262
COll1plexity
and Industrial Clusters
Dynamics and Models
in Theory and Practice
Physica-Verlag
A Springer-Verlag Company
Series Editors
Werner A. Muller
Martina Bihn
Editors
Professor Alberto Quadrio Curzio
U ni versita Cattolica
CRANEC
Via Necchi, 5
1-20123 Milano
[email protected]
This work is subject to copyright. All rights arc reserved. whether the whole or part of the
material is concerned. specifically the rights of translation. reprinting, reuse of illustrations.
recitation, broadcasting, reproductiun on microfilms or in any other way, and storage in data
banks. Duplication of this publication or parts thereof is permitted only under the provisions
of the German Copyright Law of September 9. 1965. in its current version. and permission
for use must always be obtained from Physica-Verlag. Violations are liable for prosecution
under the German Copyright Law.
Physica-Verlag Heidelberg New York
a member of BertelsmannSpringer Science+Business Media GmbH
© Physiea-Verlag Heidelberg 2002
The use of general descriptive names. registered names, trademarks, etc. in this publication does
not imply, even in the absence of a specilic statement, that such names are exempt from the
relevant protective laws and regulations and therefore free It,r general use.
Softcover Design: Erich Kirchner, Heidelberg
SPIN 10865729 88/2202-5 .. 3 2 I 0 - Printed on acid-free and non-aging paper
Preface
Preface ....................................................................................... V
What Is Complexity?
Murray Gell-Mann ......................................................................... 13
Diversity, Not Specialization: The Ties That Bind the (New) Industrial
District
Charles F. Sabel .......................................................................... 107
1. Foreword
It seems fitting to begin this publication, which contains the proceedings of the
international conference described in the preface, with a brief mention of two
institutions: Fondazione Comunita e Innovazione, which organized the
conference, and Accademia Nazionale dei Lincei, which gave the scientific
sponsorship to it.
Both of these institutions are important for their different traditions in the fields
of scientific and technological research.
Fondazione Comunita e Innovazione is closely associated with the historical
roots of Edison, founded in 1884, of Montecatini, founded in 1888, and, later on,
of Montedison. This is true primarily, but not exclusively, because these two
companies were able to build on their "local" civil and economic base and then
expand nationally and internationally by constantly focusing on technological
innovation. It is a well-known fact that the discovery of polypropylene, for which
Giulio Natta received the Nobel Prize in 1963, was made possible by the support
of Montecatini in an outstanding example of collaboration between industry and
research. Many other individuals throughout Montecatini's and Edison's histories
deserve mention for their ability to combine entrepreneurial spirit and scientific
and technological innovation, most notably Guido Donegani, Giacomo Fauser and
Giuseppe Colombo.
Accademia Nazionale dei Lincei, which honoured our conference with its
confidence and scientific sponsorship, was founded in 1603, making it the oldest
Academy in the world. It is worth mentioning that its founding members included
Galileo Galilei, who in 1613 published his Historia e dimostrazioni intorno alle
macchie solari as part of the Academy's proceedings. This is not the place for a
lengthy and detailed presentation of the extraordinary scientific merits of the
Accademia dei Lincei and of its contributions to Italian and international scientific
history. Interestingly, Giulio Natta, Nobel Prize, was a member of the Academy in
lOur heartfelt thanks to Mario A. Maggioni for his help in planning the conference and for
his useful remarks about this essay. Many others who have contributed to the conference
should be thanked, especially Biancamaria Frondoni for the organization of the conference
and for the general editing of this volume. We also thank David A. Lane and Nicola W.
Palmieri for the connections with the Santa Fe Institute, Monica Carminati, Cristiana
Crenna and Franca Sapienza for their help in editing this book.
2 A. Quadrio Curzio and M. Fortis
1947, as were Giuseppe Colombo, member since 1888 and Giacomo Fauser,
member since 1948.
It seems to us, then, that the holding of this international conference and the
publication of this book provide an ideal historical perspective linking these two
institutions, which share a similar vision, even though their objectives may be
different. And this vision is that science and technology must cooperate, that
industry cannot prosper without research. It is for this reason that the next two
paragraphs of this introduction present the points of view of two highly respected
personalities in their own field: Emico Bondi, at that time the Chairman of
Fondazione Comunita e Innovazione and c.E.O. of Montedison, and Edoardo
Vesentini, Chairman of the Accademia Nazionale dei Lincei. With each one of
these personalities the editors of this book had numerous exchange of ideas while
preparing this conference. And therefore the editors will refer their points of view,
obviously taking some liberties in interpreting their thoughts, which are shared by
the editors of this volume.
In the preface we have already said that the conference and this volume were
made possible by the initiative of Fondazione Comunita e Innovazione, which for
years has been promoting studies and research on the evolution of Italian
industrial districts. Therefore, we will use this section of the introduction to
present Enrico Bondi's point of view. The idea to connect complexity and
industrial districts belongs to him. But here we will explain the facts about Italian
districts that have much interested Enrico Bondi convincing him that this
phenomenon was worthwhile of deep analysis also from the point of view of a big
company.
While it may seem peculiar to begin the introduction to this book, which
presents the contribution of eminent theoreticians (some of them Nobel laureates),
with data on the Italian industrial system, we chose this approach to help the
reader understand how a specific situation can be used to develop a general
scientific approach.
In Italy, there are more than 200 main industrial districts, which account for
over two million jobs, or about 40% of Italy's total manufacturing employment
and 60% of all jobs in companies that make the most familiar made-in-Italy
products (fashion, home furniture and furnishings, food and traditional mechanical
engineering products). Made in Italy products are recognized worldwide for their
top quality, and industrial districts are the leading manufacturers of these quality
products.
As a result, these districts, which almost always enjoy global leadership in their
respective industries (from textiles and high fashion to ceramics and machine
tools) account for more than one-third of all Italian exports. The largest districts,
such as Sassuolo for ceramics or Prato for textiles, generate revenues in excess of
five billion euros. But there are dozens of districts with revenues of between 500
Introduction: From Specific Industrial Cases to a General Economic Model? 3
million euros and one billion euros and dozens more with revenues of 100 to 500
million euros.
There are also extremely interesting examples of cooperation between industrial
districts, which contain small and medium-size enterprises, and large companies.
The most striking example in this area is the cooperation between the "Fluorine
Valley" district and Montedison. This district is located in the province of
Bergamo along the border with the province of Brescia, with its local production
system that manufactures specialized products using elastomers and fluorinated
polymers. Another and more famous case of the collaborative relationship is that
between the Maranello mechanical engineering district, which is host to such a
high-technology marvel but small firm as Ferrari, and the big automobile firm that
is Fiat.
Therefore, a study of local manufacturing systems and industrial districts, and of
the interaction between small and medium-size enterprises, must also take into
account the role of large companies and the relationship that these local systems
have with universities and centres of research in order to achieve technological
innovation, since these factors are essential in helping enterprises grow and
compete internationally.
Enrico Bondi emphasized this theme in his interesting remarks at the beginning
of the conference. Agreeing especially with the views of two Italian economists
that he often met, Giorgio Fun. and Giacomo Becattini, and through the discussion
with the editors of this volume, he emphasised that the Italian district model is a
spontaneous one based mainly on the self-organizing ability of local communities,
which in many cases is rooted in the artisan traditions of the free city-states of the
Italian Renaissance. The Italian model is that of a district consisting of small and
medium-size enterprises located away from large metropolitan areas, primarily in
the heart of some of Italy's northern and central provinces. It is a development
model that evolved without the support of public industrial policies.
In order to understand the question contained in the title of this section of the
introduction, it is important to remember that new industrial districts, or clusters,
have developed in other countries, and have become important engines of
economic growth. Just think of Silicon Valley or Hsinchu-Taipei. These clusters
are agglomerations of non-Fordist enterprises strongly rooted in local society and
supported by a network of social and economic relations with strong links with a
major university or research centre. Two are thus the relevant (and intertwined)
questions. The first: can we consider these innovative clusters a sort of "second
generation" industrial districts? The second: will the Italian industrial districts be
able to make the transition from traditional products to high-technology ones?
In conclusion, the system of Italian industrial districts appears to have produced
a "model of capitalism" that is different from the Anglo-Saxon and Rhine Valley
ones. However, this model (which we can define as "horizontal or network
capitalism") seems not to be limited to Italy, for new district systems, often
involving highly sophisticated technologies, that are emerging throughout the
world seem to point to the fact that this new type of capitalism does not possess
limited national connotations.
4 A. Quadrio Curzio and M. Fortis
A reference to the other institution that lent its prestige to this conference is also
important in placing this book within the context of the methodological input that
Edoardo Vesentini, Chairman of the Accademia N azionale dei Lincei, provided to
Alberto Quadrio Curzio and which has been presented by the latter in the
introduction to the conference.
These introductory remarks, after noting that the Accademia Nazionale dei
Lincei was glad to support the conference because it deals with economic
development and technological innovation and, therefore, has to do with aspects
of scientific research in which Lincei are interested, will review the three main
topics of the conference and of this book, paying special attention to certain
methodological issues.
The first issue has to do with the following question: can general models be
used to understand specific economic cases? This question was addressed during
the first session of the conference and is dealt with in the first part of this book.
The issue is whether or not general theories of complexity can be used to develop
models that can, in turn, be used to analyse economic dynamics, particularly those
that affect the various types of industrial districts. Vesentini, while not addressing
the specific issue of the link between complexity and industrial districts, pointed
out that, frequently, general scientific theories and mathematical models have
found important applications in the economic field. Therefore, further studies in
this area are always important for the scientific progress and valuable because
economic theory has been a major beneficiary of mathematical methods. The most
striking example in this area is that of John von Neumann. However, it is
necessary to proceed with some caution in order to avoid misapplication of the
theory in general and the economic application in particular.
The second question, which was addressed during the second session of the
conference and is discussed in the second part of this book (which is more closely
related to economics because it presents several models of district dynamks), is
the following: are these alternative or complementary models? Vesentini pointed
out that here the analysis focuses on the relationship between the theoretical
approach and the empirical approach. This interaction has been extremely
important for the success of economics, giving also rise to a separate branch, that
of quantitative methods and econometrics, that was recognized with the first
Nobel Prize ever awarded for economics. In this area, Vesentini offered a
suggestion: do not try to force a complex economic reality into a single model,
since complementary interpretations are often one of the remarkable advantages of
economic research.
The third issue, which was discussed during the third session of the conference
and is reviewed in the third part of this book (which analyses different types of
industrial districts within different economic-institutional and industry contexts),
has to do with the development of national paradigms of district dynamics.
Vesentini pointed out that in this area the analysis has to deal with the relationship
Introduction: From Specific Industrial Cases to a General Economic ModeP 5
The first part of this book, which contains three papers by Murray Gel\-Mann
(What Is Complexity?), John H. Holland (Complex Adaptive Systems and
Spontaneous Emergence) and Enzo Rullani (The Industrial Cluster as a Complex
Adaptive System), deals with the relationship between complexity and economic
dynamics and industrial districts in an effort to develop a general model.
The study of complexity is based on the notion that there is a general law that
governs the formation of orderly configurations within systems in dynamic
balance. Complex systems are formed by independent agents that interact in a
non-linear fashion, adapting, evolving and developing a form of self-organization
that enables them to acquire collective properties that are not attributable to
specific agents.
These complex self-organizing systems are adaptive in the sense that they do
not react passively to events, the way a stone would tumble in an earthquake. On
the contrary, they make a deliberate effort to turn all circumstances to their
advantage.
This theory has been applied in the most diverse areas, ranging from the natural
sciences to such fields as meteorology and urban planning. In economics, the
theory of complexity has been used to study stock market cycles and is now being
considered with great interest by some of those who are studying industrial
districts.
It is also important to remember that industrial districts of different types now
exist in many part of the world. In most cases, they reflect self-organizing models.
Therefore, it was reasonable to believe that the theory of complexity could
provide important general guidelines for understanding the birth and dynamics of
these districts when they are viewed as a general manifestation of self-organizing
systems.
With this in mind, top priority was given to investigating the relationship
between complexity and economic dynamics. This task was entrusted to Murray
Gell-Man and John Holland, key representatives of the Santa Fe Institute, where
mathematicians, computer scientists, physicists, neurobiologists, evolutionary
biologists, economists, environmentalists, political scientists, historians,
archaeologists, linguists and many other scientists work. At the Santa Fe Institute,
Gell-Mann and his colleagues, among them John Holland (the father of "genetic
6 A. Quadrio Curzio and M. Fortis
The second part of this book contains the following five papers: Complexity and
Local Interactions: Towards a Theory of Industrial Districts, by David A. Lane;
From Marshall's to the Italian "Industrial Districts". A Brief Critical
Reconstruction, by Giacomo Becattini; Diversity, Not Specialization: The Ties
That Bind the (New) Industrial District, by Charles F. Sabel; Competitive and
Introduction: From Specific Industrial Cases to a General Economic Mode!? 7
The third part of the book contains the following five papers: The Entrepreneurial
Spark: Individual Agents and the Formation of Innovative Clusters, by Maryann
8 A. Quadrio Curzio and M. Fortis
Finally, Kung Wang mainly discusses Taiwan innovation system (TIS), that is,
the operation system by enterprises, government, universities and public research
laboratories of science and technology (S&T) industry development, and also the
most representative characteristics that can explain TIS, that is: the technology
development program (TDP) of the Ministry of Economic Affairs, the Industry
Technology Research Institute, the Hsinchu Science-based Industrial Park and
bringing back overseas scholars.
7. Conclusions
The last paper, Financial Markets, Industrial Clusters and Small and Medium-Size
Enterprises, by Angelo Tantazzi, is somewhat separate from the rest of the book,
in that it opens a new area of study and provides guidelines for developing it on
another occasion. In particular, he discusses the links that exist between the
financial markets and small and medium-size enterprises within different
economic and institutional contexts.
In conclusion, we would like to point out that the goals of firm's growth and
profit are always paramount for firms irrespective of the organizational system
adopted by an enterprise. Generally speaking an organizational system does not
exist for its own purpose: it is an operational tool, a method of achieving
economic objectives, two of which are, obviously, growth and profit.
However, districts pursue another objective, which, while not always explicit. is
clearly evident in certain historical and social contexts. It is the goal of
propagating across the generations the district community as a self-organizing
system, even when this requires district participants to sacrifice a proportionate
share of growth and profits. This justifies an interest in districts not only by
economists and sociologists, but also by researchers of complexity, in light of
districts' nature as complex adaptive systems in which enterprises and institutions
interact, accumulating experiences that increase the efficiency of the districts. As
we enter the 21 st century, we can forecast that it wi II be characterized by two great
new phenomena: globalisation and complexity. And perhaps in both cases the new
type of industrial and economic organization that goes under the name of
"indutrial clusters" or "industrial districts" will have an increasing role in its
capacity to combine innovation and flexibility, to combine systems of small-
medium size firms with giant corporations. The reality and the researches of the
next years will tell us which is the answer.
I. Complexity and Economic Dynamics
What Is Complexity?
Murray Gell-Mann
Abstract. It would require many different concepts to capture all our notions of
the meaning of complexity. The concept that comes closest to what we usually
mean is effective complexity (EC). Roughly speaking, the EC of an entity is the
length of a very concise description of its regularities. A novel is considered
complex if it has a great many scenes, subplots, characters, and so forth. An
elaborate hierarchy can contribute to complexity, as in the case of nested industrial
clusters each composed of a great variety of firms and other institutions. In
general, though, what are regularities? We encounter in many different situations
the interplay between the regular and the random or incidental: music and static on
the radio, specifications and tolerances in manufacturing, etc. But ultimately the
distinction between the regular and the incidental depends on a judgment of what
is important, although the judge need not be human or even alive. For instance, in
the case of songs of a male bird in the nesting season, the identification of
regularities is perhaps best left to the other birds of the same species - what
features are essential in repelling other males from the territory or attracting a
suitable female'? A technical definition of EC involves the quantity called
algorithmic information content (AIC). The description of an entity is converted to
a bit string and a standard universal computer is programmed to print out that
string and then halt. The length of the shortest such program (or, in a
generalization, the shortest that executes within a given time) is the AIC. The AIC
is expressed as the sum of two terms, one (the EC) referring to the regularities and
the other to the random features. The regularities of a real entity are best expressed
by embedding it conceptually in a set of comparable things, the rest of which are
imagined. The EC can then be related to the AIC of the set, the choice of which is
restricted by the conditions imposed by the judge. Theorists like to study highly
simplified models of complex systems, often by computer modelling. What can be
claimed for such models? Overall agreement with observation is hardly to be
expected. However, in many cases simple regularities can be found in both the
observational data and the model, which may then be helpful in understanding
those regularities. Examples are given, involving scaling laws and also
"implicational scales".
It would take a great many different concepts to cover all our intuitive notions of
what is meant by complexity (and its opposite, simplicity), but the concept that
agrees best with the meaning in ordinary conversation and in most scientific
discourse is effective complexity (EC). Roughly, the EC of an entity is the length
14 M. Gell-Mann
Indians in the Brazilian jungle, and that you know their language from experience
with another group speaking the same tongue. Now explain to your hosts the
meaning of a tax-managed mutual fund. It should take quite a while.
Of course as we get more technical we must think in terms of a computer. The
description of the entity is coded into a string of bits (zeroes and ones) according
to some coding scheme, and then a particular standard universal computer is
employed (we have here two more sources of context-dependence). The
algorithmic information content (AIC) of the description is then defined as the
length of the shortest program that will cause the computer to print out the bit
string in question and then stop computing. In fact, we shall generalize that
definition by considering a variable time T and asking for the length of the shortest
program that will perform this task within time T. The AIC is the limit of this
quantity as T goes to infinity.
In discussing K, the AIC of the entity, or the corresponding quantity K(T) for
finite values of T, we are not yet dealing with the effective complexity. The EC
has to do with the length of a very brief description of the regularities of the
entity, not the features treated as random or incidental. Thus we need to exhibit the
AIC (or its generalization to time 7) as the sum of two terms, one applying to the
regularities and the other to the features treated as random.
The best way to represent particular regularities of an entity is to embed that
entity conceptually in a set of comparable things. all the rest of which are
imagined, and to assign probabilities or weights to the members of the set. Such a
set, with probabilities for the members, is called an ensemble, and it embodies the
regularities in question.
The probabilities allow us to define a measure I of "Shannon information" or
ignorance for the ensemble (These two apparent opposites are really two facets of
the same thing: the amount of ignorance about the contents of a letter before one
receives it is the same as the amount of information learned when it is received
and read).
Since the ensemble serves to describe the regularities of our entity, the AIC of
the ensemble (call it Y) is a candidate for the effective complexity. We just have to
find the right ensemble. It turns out that the prescription for that is a
straightforward one:
- First, minimize the "total information" Y+/. The minimum value can easily
be shown to be about equal to K, the AIC of the entity. Thus K is exhibited as
the sum of two terms referring to the regular and random features
respectively. That is just what we needed.
- Second, following a famous principle, maximize the ignorance / or - what is
the same thing - minimize Y, subject to the conditions imposed by the judge.
The imposition of those conditions, based on a judgment of what is
important, is an essential part of the prescription. One can show that
otherwise Y would always be very small and the ignorance / would
correspondingly use up almost all of K. Every entity would be simple.
In the arts, we are accustomed to the use of the imagined alongside the real, as
in fiction and drama, and we are not surprised that light is often thrown in that
way on the regularities of the real.
16 M. Gell-Mann
The break-up of K - the AIC of the entity - into the effective complexity Yand
the ignorance I can be conceived in terms of a basic program and a lot of data to
be fed into that program. The effective complexity is related to the length of the
basic program, while the ignorance measures the information content of the
additional data needed to specify the entity with which we are dealing.
The famous computer scientist, psychologist, and economist Herbert Simon
used to call attention to the path of an ant, which has a high AIC and appears
complex at first sight. But when we realize that the ant is following a rather simple
program, into which are fed the incidental features of the landscape and the
pheromone trails laid down by the other ants for the transport of food, we
understand that the path is fundamentally not very complex. Herb said, "I got a lot
of mileage out of that ant". And now it is helping me to emphasize the difference
between total AIC and effective complexity.
A significant advantage of generalizing the measures K and Y to K(T) and Y(T)
is that we can then discuss situations such as the following:
When I was a graduate student, more than fifty years ago, we wondered what
kind of dynamics underlay the structure of atomic nuclei. It appeared that the laws
that govern the energy levels of nuclei might be extremely complex. Today,
however, we have the theory of quantum chromodynamics, the field theory of
quarks and gluons, supplemented by quantum electrodynamics, which governs the
electromagnetic interaction. We now believe those simple theories are correct (and
many of their predictions have been verified by experiment). They must yield the
energy levels of nuclei to an excellent approximation, but the calculations are so
elaborate that even today's machines and techniques can't handle them properly.
The standard universal computer would take a very long time to execute the short
program corresponding to these simple theories and thus calculate the energy
levels. If we insist on execution in a much shorter time T, then the program would
have to be exceedingly long. So, the energy levels of nuclei have very little
effective complexity Y in the limit of T going to infinity, but huge values of Y if T
is taken to be small.
There can be no finite procedure for finding all the possible regularities of an
arbitrary entity. We may ask, then, what kinds of things engage in identifying and
using particular sets of regularities. The answer is complex adaptive systems,
including all living organisms on Earth.
A complex adaptive system receives a stream of data about itself and its
surroundings. In that stream, it identifies certain regularities and compresses them
into a concise "schema", one of many possible schemata related by mutation or
substitution. In the presence of further data from the stream, the schema can
supply descriptions of certain aspects of the real world, predictions of events that
are to happen in the real world, and prescriptions for behaviour of the complex
adaptive system in the real world. In all these cases, there are real world
consequences: the descriptions can turn out to be more accurate or less accurate,
the predictions can turn out to be more reliable or less reliable, and the
prescriptions for behaviour can turn out to lead to favourable or unfavourable
outcomes. All these consequences then feed back to exert "selection pressures" on
the competition among various schemata, so that there is a strong tendency for
What Is Complexity? 17
more successful schemata to survive and for less successful ones to disappear or at
least to be demoted in some sense.
Take the human scientific enterprise as an example. The schemata are theories.
A theory in science compresses into a brief law (say a set of equations) the
regularities in a vast, even indefinitely large body of data. Maxwell's equations,
for instance, yield the electric and magnetic fields in any region of the universe if
the special circumstances there - electric charges and currents and boundary
conditions - are specified (we see how the schema plus additional information
from the data stream leads to a description or prediction).
In biological evolution, the schemata are genotypes. The genotype, together
with all the additional information supplied by the process of development - for
higher animals, from the sperm and egg to the adult organism - determines the
character, the "phenotype" of the individual adult. Survival to adulthood of that
individual, sexual selection, and success or failure in producing surviving progeny
all exert selection pressures on the competition of genotypes, since they affect the
transmission to future generations of genotypes resembling that of the individual
in question.
In the case of societal evolution, the schemata consist of laws, customs, myths,
traditions, and so forth. The pieces of such a schema are often called "memes", a
term introduced by Richard Dawkins by analogy with genes in the case of
biological evolution.
For a business firm, strategies and practices form the schemata. In the presence
of day-to-day events, a schema affects the success of the firm, as measured by
return to the stockholders in the form of dividends and share prices. The results
feed back to affect whether the schema is retained or a different one substituted
(often under a new CEO).
A complex adaptive system (CAS) may be an integral part of another CAS and
it may, in turn, contain smaller complex adaptive systems. In fact, a CAS has a
tendency to give rise to others.
On Earth, all complex adaptive systems seem to have some connection with life.
To begin with, there was the set of prebiotic chemical reactions that gave rise to
the earliest life. Then the process of biological evolution, as we have indicated, is
an example of a CAS. Likewise each living organism, insofar as it can learn, is a
CAS. In a mammal, such as a human being, the immune system is a complex
adaptive system too. Its operation is something like that of biological evolution,
but on a much faster time scale (if it took hundreds of thousands of years for us to
develop antibodies to invading microbes, we would be in serious trouble). The
process of learning and thinking in a human individual is also a complex adaptive
system. In fact, the term "schema" is taken from psychology, where it refers to a
pattern used by the mind to grasp an aspect of reality. Aggregations of human
beings can also be complex adaptive systems, as we have seen: societies, business
firms, the scientific enterprise, and so forth.
Nowadays, we have computer-based complex adaptive systems, such as "neural
nets" and "genetic algorithms". While they may sometimes involve new,
dedicated hardware, they are usually implemented on conventional hardware with
special software. Their only connection with life is that they were developed by
18 M. Gell-Mann
human beings, such as that outstanding human John Holland. Once they are put
into operation, they can, for example, invent new strJ.tegies for winning at games
that no person has ever discovered.
It is probably helpful to mention at this point that John Holland and I use
somewhat different terminology. In fact, we both heard at a meeting some years
ago that a scientist would rather use someone else's toothbrush than another
scientist's nomenclature. What I call a schema is called an internal model by John
Holland, and what I call a complex adaptive system is close to what he calls an
adaptive agent. He uses the expression "complex adaptive system" to mean a
loose aggregation of complex adaptive systems adapting to one another's
behaviour, for example investors in a market or organisms in an ecological
system.
According to my system of nomenclature, an industrial district would have to
have a schema of its own to qualify as a complex adaptive system. From what
little I know, I would say that may not generally be the case. Using John Holland's
meaning of complex adaptive system, we would ask whether the component
institutions (such as firms or universities) have schemata, and in general they do.
In my notation, then, an industrial district mayor may not be a complex adaptive
system itself, but it certainly is an aggregation of complex adaptive systems,
adapting to one another and to external int1uences.
Science fiction writers and others may speculate that in the distant future a new
kind of complex adaptive system might be created, a truly composite human
being, by wiring together the brains of a number of people. They would
communicate not through language, which - Voltaire is supposed to have said - is
used by men to conceal their thoughts, but instead through sharing all their mental
processes. My friend Shirley Hufstedler says she would not recommend this
procedure to couples about to be married.
The behaviour of a complex adaptive system, with its variable schemata
undergoing evolution through selection pressures from the real world, may be
contrasted with "simple" or "direct" adaptation, which does not involve a variable
schema, but utilizes instead a fixed pattern of response to external changes. A
good example of direct adaptation is the operation of a thermostat, which simply
turns on the heat when the temperature falls below a fixed value and turns it off
when the temperature rises above the same value. It just keeps mumbling "It's too
hot, it's too hot, it's just right, it's too cold", and so forth.
In the study of a human organization, such as a tribal society or a business firm,
one may encounter at least three different levels of adaptation, on three different
time scales.
1) On a short time scale, we may see a prevailing schema prescribing that the
organization react to particular external changes in specified ways. As long as
that schema is fixed, we are dealing with direct adaptation.
2) On a longer time scale, the real world consequences of a prevailing schema
exert (in the presence of events that occur) selection pressures on the
competition of schemata and may result in the replacement of one schema by
another.
What Is Complexity') 19
probabilities at all the branchings. In a short story by the great Argentine writer
Jorge Luis Borges, a character creates a model of these branching histories in the
form of a garden of forking paths.
The particular history we experience is co-determined, then, by the fundamental
laws and by an inconceivably long sequence of chance events, each of which
could turn out in various ways. This fundamental indeterminacy is exacerbated for
any observer - or set of observers, such as the human race - by ignorance of the
outcomes of most of the chance events that have already occurred, since only a
very limited set of observations is available. Any observer sees only an extremely
coarse-grained history.
The phenomenon of chaos in certain non-linear systems is a very sensitive
dependence of the outcome of a process on tiny details of what happened earlier.
When chaos is present, it still further amplifies the indeterminacy we have been
discussing.
Some years ago, at the science museum in Barcelona, I saw an exhibit that
beautifully illustrated chaos. A non-linear version of a pendulum was set up in
such a way that the visitor could hold the bob and start it out in a chosen position
and with a chosen velocity. One could then watch the subsequent motion, which
was also recorded with a pen on a sheet of paper. The visitor was then invited to
seize the bob again and try to imitate exactly the previous initial position and
velocity. No matter how carefully that was done, the subsequent motion was quite
different from what it was the first time. Comparing the records on paper
confirmed the difference in a striking way.
I asked the museum director what the two men were doing who were standing in
a corner watching us. He replied, "Oh, those are two Dutchmen waiting to take
away the chaos". Apparently, the exhibit was about to be dismantled and taken to
Amsterdam. But I have wondered ever since whether the services of those two
Dutchmen would not be in great demand across the globe, by organizations that
wanted their chaos taken away.
Once we view alternative histories as forming a branching tree, with the history
we experience co-determined by the fundamental laws and a huge number of
accidents, we can ponder the accidents that gave rise to the people assembled at
this conference. A fluctuation many billions of years ago produced our galaxy, and
it was followed by the accidents that contributed to the formation of the solar
system, including the planet Earth. Then there were the accidents that led to the
appearance of the first life on this planet, and the very many additional accidents
that, along with natural selection, have shaped the course of biological evolution,
including the characteristics of our own subspecies, which we call, somewhat
optimistically, Homo sapiens sapiens. Finally we may consider the accidents of
genetics and sexual selection that helped to produce the genotypes of all the
individuals here, and the accidents in the womb, in childhood, and since that have
helped to make us what we are today.
Now most accidents in the history of the universe don't make much difference to
the coarse-grained histories with which we are concerned. If two oxygen
molecules in the atmosphere collide and then go off in one pair of opposite
directions or another, it usually makes little difference. But the fluctuation that
What Is Complexity') 21
produced our galaxy, while it too may have been insignificant on a cosmic scale,
was of enormous importance to anything in our galaxy. Some of us call such a
chance event a "frozen accident". It produces substantial effects, if only in a
limited region of space and time. Once it happens and its outcome is determined,
an accident no longer belongs to the realm of the random. Frozen accidents,
affecting significantly things judged to be important, give rise to regularities. Of
course the fundamental laws also contribute to regularities, but those laws are
thought to be simple, and so effective complexity comes mainly from frozen
accidents.
We can take an example from modern human history to illustrate the idea of a
frozen accident. It was mentioned earlier that a few historians are willing to
discuss "contingent history", in which one asks "What if ..... '1". One of their
favourite incidents occurred when Buffalo Bill's Wild West Show was touring
Europe in 1889. Of course a star attraction of the show was the female
sharpshooter Annie Oakley, who would ask for a male volunteer so that she could
knock the ash off his cigar with a bullet. Normally there were no volunteers, and
her husband, himself a famous marksman, would step forward and stand still
while Annie shot, hitting the ash but not her husband. On this occasion, however,
there was a volunteer, the Kaiser - Wilhelm der Zweite - with an expensive
Havana cigar. Annie was a little worried, having drunk heavily the night before,
but she fired and we know the result. The Kaiser survived, fired Bismarck,
cancelled the reinsurance treaty with Russia, engaged in competition in naval
construction with Great Britain, and in other ways laid the groundwork for the
First World War.
The dominant role played by frozen accidents in generating effective
complexity can help us to understand the tendency for more and more complex
entities to appear as time goes on. Of course there is no rule that everything must
increase in complexity. Any individual entity may increase or decrease in effective
complexity or stay the same. When an organism dies or a civilization dies out, it
suffers a dramatic decrease in complexity. But the envelope of effective
complexity keeps getting pushed out, as more and more complex things arise.
The reason is that as time goes on the results of frozen accidents can keep
accumulating. If that process outstrips the erasure of the consequences of frozen
accidents, then more and more effective complexity can arise. That is so even for
non-adaptive evolution, as in galaxies, stars, planets, rocks, and so forth. It is well
known to be true of biological evolution, where in some cases higher effective
complexity probably confers an advantage. And we see all around us the
appearance of more and more complex regulations, instruments, computer
software packages, and so forth, even though in many cases certain things are
simplified.
The tendency of more and more complex forms to appear in no way contradicts
the famous second law of thermodynamics, which states that for a closed
(isolated) system, the average disorder ("entropy") keeps increasing. There is
nothing in the second law to prevent local order from increasing, through various
mechanisms of self-organization, at the expense of greater disorder elsewhere.
(one simple and widespread mechanism of self-organization on a cosmic scale is
22 M. Gell-Mann
provided by gravitation, which has caused material to condense into the familiar
structures with which astronomy is concerned, including our own planet).
Here on Earth, once it was formed, systems of increasing complexity have
arisen as a consequence of the physical evolution of the planet over some four and
half billion years. biological evolution over nearly four billion years, and - over a
very short period on a geological time scale - human cultural evolution.
The process has gone so far that we human beings are now confronted with
immensely complex problems and we are in urgent need of better ways of dealing
with them (the role of industrial clusters and their potential constitute, of course,
an example of a complex issue). When we attempt to tackle such difficult
problems, we naturally tend to break them up into more manageable pieces. That
is a useful practice, but it has serious limitations.
When dealing with any non-linear system, especially a complex one, it is not
sufficient to think of the system in terms of parts or aspects identified in advance,
then to analyse those parts or aspects separately, and finally to combine those
analyses in an attempt to describe the entire system. Such an approach is not, by
itself, a successful way to understand the behaviour of the system. In this sense
there is truth in the old adage that the whole is more than the sum of its parts.
Unfortunately, in a great many places in our society, including academia and
most bureaucracies, prestige accrues principally to those who study carefully some
aspect of a problem, while discussion of the big picture is relegated to cocktail
parties. It is of crucial importance that we learn to supplement those specialized
studies with what I call a crude look at the whole.
Now the chief of an organization, say a head of government or a CEO, has to
behave as if he or she is taking into account all the aspects of a situation, including
the interactions among them, which are often strong. It is not so easy, however, for
the chief to take a crude look at the whole if everyone else in the organization is
concerned only with a partial view.
Even if some people are assigned to look at the big picture, it doesn't always
work out. Some time ago, the CEO of a gigantic corporation told me that he had a
strategic planning staff to help him think about the future of the business, but that
the members of that staff suffered from three defects:
1) They seemed largely disconnected from the rest of the company.
2) No one could understand what they said.
3) Everyone else in the company seemed to hate them.
Despite such experiences, it is vitally important that we supplement our
specialized studies with serious attempts to take a crude look at the whole.
I am sure that observation applies to industrial clusters.
At many research institutions, theorists are busily engaged in constructing
simple models of quite complex real systems. Today, those are usually computer
models. How, though, does one rate the success of such a model in helping us
learn about the real world? Normally, a theory is compared to observation and the
value of the theory is judged by the degree of agreement with observed facts,
along with criteria such as elegance, consistency, and compatibility with well-
established principles. However, when we are dealing with a highly simplified
What Is Complexity? 23
model of a very complex system, detailed agreement with observation could well
be embarrassing rather than encouraging.
At the Santa Fe Institute, we have had a number of discussions of this question:
what can be claimed on the basis of a simplified model? One outcome of those
discussions is the conclusion that one should look for rather simple regularities in
the data and see if the model predicts some or all of them. This semi-empirical
"middle level theory" can be enormously valuable. Often, the regularities in
question will hold along the whole spectrum from the complex real world down
through successive simplifications of that world to the model being examined. If
that is the case, then the reason for the regularity in the simple model may be easy
to understand and it can throw light on how the regularity arises in the real world.
Examples of such simple regularities certainly include scaling laws, in which
one quantity of interest appears as a power of another such quantity. These laws
crop up in all fields of science: physical, biological, and behavioural. A striking
example is the rule, verified with increasing confidence over most of a century,
but unexplained until recently, that the metabolic rate of a mammal species goes
like the three-quarters power of the mass. The mammal in question can range from
a tiny shrew to an elephant or a whale. If one mammal weighs ten thousand times
as much as another, it will process energy at a rate one thousand times higher.
Similar laws (with the same power but different coefficients) apply to birds and to
higher plants.
This law was explained by Geoffrey West, a theoretical physicist at the Los
Alamos National Laboratory, and James Brown, an ecology professor at the
University of New Mexico in Albuquerque, along with his student Brian Enquist.
These researchers met and collaborated at the Santa Fe Institute, in a perfect
example of how that institute is supposed to function.
They modelled (analytically rather than on a computer) the cardiovascular and
respiratory systems of the animals and the vascular system of the plants. They
based their model on three-dimensional fractals, and they used two facts:
1) in the branchings of the tubes, areas are preserved and
2) the thinnest tubes all have about the same diameter, independent of the mass.
The scaling law then followed, with the fraction 3/4 arising from the number of
spatial dimensions divided by that number plus one.
Sometimes scaling laws are laws of distribution, for example the famous Zipf's
law - found in fact by Auerbach in 1913 - for the populations of "cities" (actually
metropolitan areas). It states that if we rank the cities in order of decreasing
population, then the population is roughly inversely proportional to the numerical
rank. The data are a bit ragged for the very largest cities, but they agree quite well
with the law for the next several hundred cities. Thus the 300 lh city has about one-
third the population of the 100th city.
Recently Xavier Gabaix published an explanation of Zipf's law starting from
Gibrat's law, which is known to be true and states that the mean growth rate and
mean square deviation of growth rates for metropolitan areas are independent of
population to a good approximation. Gabaix showed that the steady state
distribution of populations then obeys Zipf's law.
24 M. Gell-Mann
Besides scaling laws, we can look at other examples of simple middle level
semi-empirical laws, for instance implicational ladders. Around 1940, when the
USA was still not a belligerent in the Second World War, some sociologists were
asked to measure the attitudes of Americans toward Great Britain. They
formulated a long list of questions with yes or no answers, and those questions
were posed to a representative sample of American citizens. The results showed a
fascinating regularity. If the questions were arranged in a certain order, then most
of the returned questionnaires showed responses that were affirmative down to a
certain point and then negative after that. Thus most of the sets of answers to the
questions could be characterized by a single parameter, the point in the list where
the answers switched from positive to negative. As far as the questionnaire went,
attitude toward the United Kingdom could be summarized in a single number.
Such a result is often called an implicational scale (not to be mixed up with
scaling laws, as described earlier). To avoid confusion, I like to call it an
implicational ladder.
Another example can be cited from linguistics. There are some countries, such
as Haiti and Jamaica, where a Creole language is spoken that gets its words
mainly from the official language of the country. In Haiti, nearly everyone speaks
a French-based Creole language at home, while the official language is, or was
until recently, French. Likewise, in Jamaica, the official language is English bUl
many people speak an English-based Creole at home (this is in contrast to the
situation on the island of St. Lucia, for example, where the official language is
English but the Creole is French-based).
In 1961, the linguist DeCamp investigated the situation in Jamaica, where,
under the influence of official English in the schools, there is a tendency for
certain people to substitute usages from regular English for those in the broadest
or deepest Creole. He chose six cases of such usages, four involving vocabulary
and two involving pronunciation. He discovered that those usages could be
arranged in a particular order such that some speakers used the standard English
version in all six cases, some in the first five, some in the first four, some in the
first three, and so forth. Other patterns were negligibly rare. Thus, out of all the 64
possible patterns for choices in the six cases between Creole usage and Standard
English usage, only 7 patterns existed with appreciable frequency among the
population, and those seven formed an implicational ladder.
If I had to model industrial clusters, I would search carefully for "middle-level"
semi-empirical rules that might persist all the way from the real world down to the
highly simplified model, and test the model by seeing if it clarifies how the rules
arise.
Complex Adaptive Systems
and Spontaneous Emergence
John H. Holland
rook to a knight's fork three moves from now"). As we will see (section 2)
discovering new, plausible rules depends upon finding appropriate
"building blocks" for describing parts of the cas agents.
2. Building Blocks
Building blocks are the pervasive, critical foundation of an ability to act with
insight in a complex world. Human perception, for example, consists primarily in
combining well-known, simple components to describe familiar phenomena.
Different trees are described by different arrangements of familiar parts: leaves,
stems, branches, and trunks. Similarly, human faces are composed of variants of
standard parts - hair, forehead, eyebrows, eyes, nose, and so on. A little thought
shows that we approach all objects, familiar and unfamiliar, via combinations of
familiar building blocks.
We can also extract building blocks as the generators of the dynamic situations
that characterize the interaction of agents. Consider the rules of chess: the rules are
building blocks that generate a miniature artificial world in which two agents
interact. Though chess is simply defined - less than a dozen rules suffice - it is an
artificial world of perpetual novelty. We never see the same game played twice
unless some previous game is deliberately recorded and repeated. The game is so
complex that, after centuries of study, we have no idea of what a "best strategy"
would be for playing the game. Nevertheless, in this perpetually novel world,
planning and anticipation are possible, indeed essential.
Planning in chess depends upon extracting and exploiting certain patterns
(configurations of pieces) that occur repeatedly in the play of the game. These
patterns become higher-level building blocks from which to construct strategies
(plans) for playing the game. Over the centuries, chess players have repeatedly
discovered new repeating-pattern building blocks that make possible ever more
sophisticated strategies. For example, early in the 20th century, chess players
discovered that certain interlocking pawn structures could exhibit strong influence
on the play of the game. As a result the pawns in today's game do a lot more than
they did in the 19th century. By adding this pawn-structure building block to the
repertoire, a present-day master chess player can easily outplay a 19th century
player of equal rank.
Lest this discussion of games seem frivolous, note that the rules of a game are
not different in kind from the axioms that generate Euclidean geometry, or the set
of computer instructions that define a flight simulator for a new aircraft. Indeed if
we look to that most complex of organizations, the biological cell, we see layer
after layer of building blocks. At a low level we have the 4 nucleotides that form
the building blocks from which all chromosomes are constructed (Note that a
physicist would add several levels of building blocks below this level, ranging
from atoms down to quarks). One level up we have the 20 amino acids, coded by
triplets of nucleotides, that form the building blocks for proteins. The proteins, in
Complex Adaptive Systems and Spontaneous Emergence 27
turn, have substructures such as alpha-helices and beta-sheets that determine their
three dimensional structure. From there we go to small interacting groups of
proteins, such as the Krebs cycle, on to building blocks for membranes and
tubules, to organelles, and on up through the hierarchy of living organisms.
If we turn from organisms to artefacts, we see that most major innovations in
science and technology amount to new combinations of old building blocks. For
example, the internal combustion engine, that great source of mobile power that
transformed the 20th century, was simply a new combination of building blocks
that had been around for a long time: the carburettor was a modification of
Venturi's perfume sprayer, the spark plug was presaged by Volta's sparking
device, gear wheels and pistons had been known from antiquity, and so on. The
innovation was the combination of these known building blocks in a way that
provided new interactions between them.
While innovations typically come from new combinations of familiar building
blocks, once in a while there is a genuinely new building block. Though such
events are rare, they can have dramatic impact: the transistor revolutionized the
design and production of electronic circuits. However, even the transistor is a new
combination of well-known building blocks one level down; there was a theory of
semi-conduction many decades before that idea was combined with other ideas to
yield this new switching device. New building blocks often arise through "cross-
breeding" successful lower-level building blocks, blocks drawn from previously
unassociated areas or disciplines.
In sum: whether it be natural or artificial systems, building blocks are almost
always the basis of understanding and innovation. Moreover, the resulting
structures almost always have a hierarchical format, with selected combinations of
building blocks at one level serving as building blocks one level up.
3. Emergence
First among these criteria is the requirement that the phenomenon be a repeating
pattern in a system that exhibits perpetual novelty. This repeating pattern is a
feature or property common to some subset of the unending building-block
combinations. In mathematical terms, the repeating pattern is an equivalence class
within the subset of combinations. Let us call such a repeating pattern a regularity.
In the dynamics of a cas, regularities typically distinguish commonalities among
some of the agents. When these regularities are reinforced by interactions among
the agents, they become persistent, providing possibilities for "speciation" and
selection. For example, the Krebs (citric acid) cycle is a regularity common to all
living aerobic organisms. This dynamic cycle, mediated by eight enzymes (rule-
like building blocks), underpins the production of all the basic components of the
cell: amino acids, lipids, and the like. The persistent regularity we call the Krebs
cycle becomes an emergent building block making possible higher levels of
organization, ultimately yielding the organelle-cell-organ hierarchy common to all
metazoans.
This example suggests the second criterion: emergent phenomena exhibit a
hierarchical organization wherein selected combinations of building blocks at one
level become building blocks at a higher level of organization. Herb Simon's
famous "watchmaker" parable (Simon 1996) makes clear the great advantages
hierarchical organization confers on dynamic systems undergoing selection. The
"adaptive" part of a cas assures the prevalence of this kind of organization under
emergence.
Once we allow levels of organization, it becomes natural to ask if, or how, the
different levels interact. Clearly living organisms and complex artefacts, such as
computers or airplanes, exhibit such organization, with interactive signalling in
both bottom-up and top-down directions. For example, a single gross movement of
the control column in an airplane sends signals that affect dozens of devices
throughout the airplane (a top-down effect), while the malfunction of a single
critical part, say a warning light, can ground the plane (a bottom-up effect).
Similarly, though an overall market indicator (say the Dow-Jones average) is an
average of the actions of individual investors (a bottom-up effect), a change in that
indicator can exert a top-down influence on the actions of individual investors
(agents). In general, agents at higher levels in a cas hierarchy are composed of
agents at lower levels. Here then is a third criterion: the overall form and
persistence of an emergent regularity depends upon both bottom-up and top-down
effects.
The fourth criterion sounds mysterious, but is quite simple when understood: the
whole emergent regularity is more than the sum of its parts. This criterion contrasts
with the simple reductionist strategy for parsing phenomena: study the building
blocks, and then sum their behaviours to get the behaviour of the whole.
Throughout the history of science this simple reductionist strategy has worked over
and over again, from the description of gases as colliding particles to the
superposition of waves of different frequencies to describe complex sounds.
Trends, polls, and averages, as predictors, all exemplify this additive approach.
However, the non-linear interactions of the agents in a cas short-circuit simple
Complex Adaptive Systems and Spontaneous Emergence 29
reductionism. We cannot add up the behaviours of the agents to get the behaviour
of the whole because the interactions are not additive. Reduction still works, but it
is not simple because the interactions are not simple. The behaviour of the whole
cannot be obtained by simply adding together the behaviours of the parts.
These four criteria go a long way toward separating the phenomena I would like
to call emergent from most other phenomena. The criteria are subject to explicit
testing procedures, so emergent phenomena satisfying these criteria are not an eye-
of-the-beholder effect.
up in the posltlon of Borges' king (Borges 1964) with a map the size of the
country. The essence of elegant science is providing just enough detail to explore
the question posed.
Once a question has been posed, it is typical to start with a very simple model,
quite likely an over-simple model. You then see how far the model will take you
toward answering the question, only adding a new mechanism or law (see pieces
and rules in a game) when there is a clear need. This process of going as far a you
can with a simple model, in order to see what's missing, can be quite productive.
And it does produce models that are just detailed enough to answer the question.
5. Modelling Agents
In a cas each agent is surrounded by, and interacts with, a multitude of other
agents. It is convenient to think of all of an agent's environment as represented by
agents, some of which are passive and do not adapt (such as a rock or a chair).
There is no real loss of generality in such a conceit.
Each adaptive agent receives information about its environment via a set of
detectors (receptors, gauges, or the like). We can think of the output of a set of
detectors as a standardized packet of information, called a message. An agent's
internal information processing can also be treated in terms of messages (much
like the memos circulated in an office). Some messages may be directed to other
agents or to effectors (machines, muscles, or the like), provi~ing the interactions
that change the agent's environment. In short, we can look upon an agent as a
message processing device. In consequence the overall cas becomes a complex
signalling network.
One formalization of this outlook is provided by the adaptive rule-based systems
called classifier systems (Holland 1995,2000). The building blocks for a classifier
system are IFrrHEN rules called classifiers. The condition (IF) part of the rule
"looks for" certain kinds of messages; when the rule's conditions are satisfied, the
action (THEN) part specifies a message to be sent. For example, if the agent has a
visual system, one of the rules might be IF there is (a message from the detectors
indicating) an object left of centre in the field of vision, THEN (by issuing a
message to the effectors) cause the eyes to look left.
In a classifier system many rules may be active simultaneously because
additional active rules simply means more messages being issued at a given
instant. From a computational point of view, it is convenient to think of the
messages present at a given instant as collected in a list called a message list. As a
rough analogy, think of the rules in a classifier system as standard operating
procedures. Then think of an agent as an office containing many desks, where each
desk (rule) is responsible for executing a particular operating procedure. In this
analogy, the message list is analogous to a bulletin board that contains all the
memos (messages) directing the activities of the office that day. The action of each
desk, when there is a memo for it on the bulletin board, is to produce a memo for
Complex Adaptive Systems and Spontaneous Emergence 31
the next day. In classifier system terms, each rule is looking to the message list, to
see if there are messages satisfying its conditions (the IF part). If the rule's
conditions are satisfied by messages on the list, it generates a new message (the
THEN part) to be added to the list.
It is often desirable to direct a message to a given rule or set of rules, much like
the header on an email message selects a set of destinations for the email message.
To select destinations in a classifier system we use tags. Tags for this purpose are
quite common in the natural world. For example, in molecular biology, we have
amino acid sequences that bind to a specific locus in DNA. The DNA loci are the
counterparts of rules that are repressed (cease to act) by proteins (messages)
having particular tags. Tags play similar roles in identifying antigens for the
immune system, they also serve to define active sites in an enzyme, and tags serve
as "headers" for the signalling proteins that mediate reaction cascades and
complicated feedback loops in biological cells. Rules using tags may represent
DNA loci that are repressed by signalling proteins (messages) having particular
amino acid sequences (tags) that provide binding action, or rules may serve as
steps in a cascade wherein a protein initiates the formation of a new protein in the
cascade (sending a signal), or the rules may interact in much more complicated
feedback loops.
In a classifier system using tags rules typically have the form IF (signal with
apropos tag present) THEN (send signal with new tags).
The condition part of a classitier rule will often specify several conditions, so
that the rule requires the simultaneous presence of ditferent tagged messages
before it acts. If an agent has a modular, hierarchical structure, the rules in each
module can be directly identified by a common tag. That is, to send a message to a
module you attach to it the identifying tag of the module. An appropriately tag-
linked collection of classifier rules can implement any subroutine or program that
can be written for a computer. As a result any hierarchical cas can be implemented
as a classifier system.
References
Borges, J. L. (1964), "On Rigor in Science", Dream Tigers, Austin, U. Texas Press.
Holland, J. H. (1995), Hidden Order, Reading, MA, Addison-Wesley.
Holland, J. H. (2000), "What is a Learning Classifier System?", in: Learning Classifier
Systems. Lanzi, P. L., Stolzmann, W. and Wilson, S. W. (eds), Berlin, Springer, pp. 3-6.
Jammer, M. (1974), The Philosophy of Quantum Mechanics, New York, Wiley.
Mitchell, M. (1996), An Introduction to Genetic Algorithms, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press.
Samuel, A. L. (1959), "Some Studies in Machine Learning Using the Game of Checkers",
in: Computers and Thought, Feigenbaum, E. A. and Feldman, J. (eds), New York,
McGraw-Hill.
Simon, H. A. (1996), The Sciences of the Artificial. Cambridge, MA, MIT Press, 3rd ed ..
The Industrial Cluster
as a Complex Adaptive System
Enzo Rullani
Between exploitation (of what is known) and exploration (of what is new) there is
a border that neo-modern reasoning must cross over repeatedly as it seeks useful
opportunities, without ever stopping at that methodological borderline beyond
which is a land that until a short while ago was marked "Danger! Unknown".
The relationship with complexity - and, as it concerns us here, with industrial
clusters - brings into relief a basic alternati ve between rationalizing that which is
old and exploring that which is new one that all systems of learning must· face
sooner or later and that, not accidentally, represents a "place" (topos) that is
typical of the more general studies of complexity (Holland 1988, 1995).
During the past century, when deterministic reasoning was prevalent, the focus
was primarily on computing and optimising what was already known, reducing the
exploration of that which was new to a routine that administered and controlled all
innovative acts, neutralizing their subversive energy. In this sense, the century of
Fordism was characterized by hostility to complexity, which was seen as a source
of uncertainty and risk and, therefore, an obstacle to rationalization. Increasingly
codified and rigid forms of forecasting, planning and control were developed in
order to minimize the exposure to complexity, which artificially reduced
opportunities and interest in exploring that which is new. In both theory and
practice, the emphasis was on rationalizing that which existed by relying on
bureaucracies and automatisms. Complexity was tackled by breaking it up into
fragments and forcing these fragments into predetermined computation
(technology, markets), control (plans) and negotiation (management) procedures.
To do this, economic behaviour, which could be put through computation and
optimisation procedures more easily than other activities, was separated from
everything else. Economics became the science of efficiency, specialized in
exploitation and removed from exploration. Its complexity was drastically reduced
by assigning all its anthropological, social and institutional variables to the realm
of exogenous variables, which left economics with just one task: maximize the
efficient use of known means to achieve equally known ends.
In this context, the territory was inevitably pushed to the margins of economics
studies. Since it is an elective place where economics, society and history
intersect, the territory contains information and complex relationships that exceed
the sphere of calculable actions. One could even say that thinking in the past
century, because it was consumed with reducing complexity, was ultimately also
an enemy of the territory, which was perceived as a system that creates, preserves
and reproduces the complexity of history and experience.
The reason why we are now re-examining with such great interest industrial
clusters and other local phenomena that are rooted in geographical locations and
are rediscovering old studies of territorial economies that were gathering dust in
local archives is because we need to understand how to tackle high levels of
complexity without first breaking it down with computations, controls and
negotiations, since time has shown all these methods to be blunt and increasingly
ineffective instruments.
The rediscovery of complexity entails the rediscovery of the territory and vice-
versa. Choosing to take a pragmatic, experimental approach that allows rationality
to explore the open world of possibilities also means finding a foothold in the
The Industrial Cluster as a Complex Adaptive System 37
The main goal of deterministic reasoning, as it developed during the long reign of
Fordism, was the efficient exploitation of what was known. From this standpoint,
the first order of business was to neutralize the world's complexity, since it
hindered computation and rationalization efforts. In other words, it was necessary
to narrow the spaces occupied by variance and indeterminateness, since they were
the reasons for the unpredictability of natural events, individual choices, meanings
38 E. Rullani
The notion of modernity in which the ability to produce is based on reducing the
"natural" complexity of human and social behaviour has very little in common
with the notion of territory, which represents a synthesis, sedimented at one
location, of history, culture and interpersonal relationships. This synthesis was too
rich in variances and had too many levels of indeterminateness to fit into the
framework of modernity and, therefore, was ignored or completely removed from
the horizon.
For all intents and purposes, the idea of territory as a complex synthesis of life
stratified in one place disappeared from the theory and practice of modern
economics. In its place, modernity offered an artificial space devoid of
complexity where players can easily perform opportunity computations.
Obviously, this metamorphosis caused the notion of territory to lose all the
relevance it had gained in premodern times. This was also because, in the Fordist
vision of modernity, the complexity of local societies could not be used in any
way to create economic value. On the contrary, it was an obstacle and an
impediment. The modernity we have been familiar with until now attempted to
render abstract the available physical space, thereby suppressing the uniqueness,
identity and history of different locations.
When viewed through this filter, the territory becomes an easily fungible space,
indifferent to the quality of the places it contains. In other words, it becomes
something that can be measured in acres of space and miles of distance.
The distribution of activities over the territory - and the very idea of industrial
cluster - thus becomes the product of a localizational algorithm that produces
geographical agglomerations and dispersions that mirror the distribution of costs
and revenues over the different locations, in accordance with a routine
computation of opportunities that is indifferent to the subject matter being
optimised. There is no indication of the existence of places with economic
identities and histories that are different from those of all other comparable places.
The disappearance of complexity from the ideal and technical horizon of
modernity also marked the disappearance of the concept of industrial cluster and
the notion of territory that it entailed. This was unavoidable, but we must be aware
of the theoretical and practical consequences of such a disappearance.
A territory without complexity is a place without qualities. It is just another
place, just another geographical agglomeration or dispersion produced by a
computational algorithm. Consequently, it is easy to see why the scientific and
practical program of modernity would virtually ignore the existence of industrial
clusters despite the prodding of an influential author such as A. Marshall and a
wealth of relatively successful territorial clusters or similar areas that developed
on repeated occasions during the past century.
Industrial clusters were viewed as little more than a geographic oddity or a
sitting anomaly: "typical" areas, or system areas, that for some reason had
spawned a mono-industry culture instead of a well-balanced and diversified multi-
industry economic system. The hidden bond that, in actuality, linked the quality of
40 E. Rullani
the cluster to the quality of the site remained hidden and was basically
uninteresting. At best, it aroused the curiosity of a few, anomalous, theoretical
economists (in Italy, mainly Giacomo Becattini and Sebastiano Brusco).
Today, we know that this small group of scholars was not studying an irrelevant
or backward-looking phenomenon, but that it had uncovered one of the anomalies
that made it possible to observe complexity escaping from the net of deterministic
reasoning. Clusters did not have an authority or official belief that limited the
opportunity space available to their members. On the contrary, everyone was
allowed, at his own risk, to explore a segment of the opportunity space. Each
member, operating within an environment characterized by a great deal of
variance and indetermination, learned to manage complexity whenever it arose,
without attempting to minimize it beforehand. Industrial clusters, with their
minute specializations and strong interactions, can metabolise complexity,
transforming it into learning, rules and collective identities.
The development of industrial clusters, as a physical event, was not recognized for
quite some time. There was an even longer delay in translating the "teachings of
facts" into theoretical awareness.
There is a basic reason for the failure to develop a theoretical explanation for the
economic growth visible in real life in developing clusters. The growth of
industrial clusters is triggered by mobilizing resources that are doubly anomalous
for standard theory: first of all, because they are local resources, unique and very
difficult to duplicate and, secondly, because they are complex resources that
represent the summation of history, culture, relationships and interactions with
unpredictable results and, therefore, create patterns of behaviour that are far from
simple and virtually impossible to calculate.
To acknowledge that industrial clusters are part of the modern economy and not
vestiges of the pre-industrial economy is not an easy thing to do, because such an
acknowledgment entails a conclusion difficult to accept: that modernity can take
complex forms that escape instrumental reasoning and deterministic calculations.
At first, the handful of pioneers in this field received limited attention from
mainstream economists. For some time, clusters were seen as empirical and
theoretical variants that existed only in Italy. Later, it would become apparent that
these variants carried the seeds of a conceptual revolution that was much broader
in scope and extended beyond Italy.
The first clear theoretical demarcation, separating the economy of clusters,
which is location-based, from the classic economy of industries appeared in 1961
in a work by Giacomo Becattini on the relationship between economic value and
industries. Becattini criticized the theory of value based on the notion of industry
because it lacked all those concrete references - relationships with society, history
The Industrial Clustc:r as a Complex Adaptive System 43
We thus discover that there is a "Third Ital y" (Bagnasco 1977) studded with
industrial clusters; that, in recent years, clusters are starting to appear in Southern
Italy as well (Viesti 2000a, 2000b); that a significant portion of the "Made in
Italy" products that give strength to the Italian balance of trade are manufactured
in industrial clusters (Fortis 1996, 1998); and that all industrial clusters are
different and must be studied individually. This realization gave rise to a new
branch of economic literature consisting of an increasingly large number of
empirical studies (I will not even attempt to produce a list of Italian cluster "cases"
because it would be too long and would inevitably be incomplete). By becoming
an "ideal type", in Weber's sense, the cluster economy is transmogrified into a
flexible specialization - an alternative to mass production (Piore and Sabel 1984) -
thereby achieving a level of international recognition that was underscored by the
success of Silicon Valley in the United States (Saxenian 1994, Zagnoli 1991). This
evolution has progressed to such an extent that recent broad-based studies have
focused on comparing the performance of economies organized into industrial
clusters with other economic forms (Signorini 2000).
In recent years, the issues surrounding industrial clusters have received
international attention not just because clusters represent a type of organization
that is attractive in all those cases where the goal is to trigger the proliferation of
neo-entrepreneurship, but also because they can help explain the localized
formations created by economic development. With the theory of clustering
(Porter 1989) and the new "economic geography" of Krugman and Venables
(1990, 1995), economic theory took a closer look at the territory, with the goal of
assimilating the complex geometry of its forms and histories. Even though these
formal approaches contained an echo of the old economy of localization that paid
scant attention to the anthropological and social quality of locations 1, a connection
between the Italian theory of clusters and the new economy of the territory that
has gained acceptance on an international scale was firmly established.
IOn this issue see the discussion that appeared in Economia e Politica Industriale,
(2000), Nos. 106 and 107, following the publication of an article by Viesti
(2000a).
46 E. Rullani
in their transactions with the outside world, the only alternative being a situation
devoid of organization in which complexity increases freely and chaotically.
Industrial clusters offer a practical example of how to achieve a reasonable
synthesis of organization and complexity. Their market success is proof positive
that a good level of organizational efficiency can be achieved even in the absence
of artificial systems that use techniques, command and negotiations to reduce
complexity. In other words, clusters deal with complexity in another way (without
reducing it beforehand) and with other systems (different from techniques,
command and negotiations).
What are these systems?
Industrial clusters metabolise complexity through a dynamic process of
distributed learning that mobilizes the intelligence of many separate players who
communicate and interact with each other (Micelli 2000). None of these players
has sufficient technical, regulatory or negotiating power to force the others to
behave in accordance with a common action framework. Instead, each player
learns in the course of action how to explore his/her segment of complexity,
accumulating personal experiences and at the same time benefiting from the
experience of others. The result is a circuit of self-organization (Silverberger, Dosi
and Orsenigo 1988) that slowly, through repeated attempts, "learns" how to
develop a system with an efficient internal organization that can respond flexibly
to the demands of the outside world.
The organizational tools that can be used to manage complexity are those that
allow:
• the autonomous and intelligent exploration of a fraction of complexity
(small business);
• the taking of personal risk with respect to the results of the exploration
(entrepreneurial spirit);
• the ability to learn from the experience of others through the circuits of
communication and local emulation (imitation of competitors, integration of
customers and suppliers, switching of work from one company to another,
spin-offs of new businesses, etc.).
The behaviour of a cluster as a whole is the product of the combination of a
series of partial organizational choices that let each enterprise find its position vis-
a-vis the other enterprises in accordance with classic swarm dynamics (Kelly
1994, 1998). The sum of these semi-independent behaviours of limited rationality
produces an orderly result that, in many cases, is more efficient than the result that
could have been obtained through centralized planning.
From this standpoint, industrial clusters have all of the characteristics typical of
a complex adaptive system, or CAS (Axelrod and Cohen 1999), because:
i. they are ruled by self-organizing processes that occur as a result of changes,
selections and retentions of the variables that are best suited to each
contingent situation and mayor may not be the product of an intentional
design and the work of conscious players;
ii. in the development of alternatives and the selection and retention of these
alternatives, clusters use an intellectual and relational capital sedimented
The Industrial Cluster as a Complex Adaptive System 47
6. Rediscovering Complexity
As I have already stated, after years of neglect, the physical and social sciences
rediscovered complexity. In this field of learning, as in many others, there is a
tendency to generalize the work of a few pioneers who laid the foundations for
future advances.
The theory of complexity has put forth certain very general formal principles
and noted the existence of complex adaptive ~ystems in many different fields, from
physics to biology, from social evolution to economics (Axelrod and Cohen 1999,
p. 16).
The key element that justifies accepting the very notion of complexity in the
physical, biological and human-social world is the idea that the formal structure of
complexity has certain common characteristics that make it possible to frame it
within a general, transdisciplinary context.
There are many definitions of complexity, and this is not the place to review
them. For our purposes, we can say that a field of variance that exists within a
space of possibilities can be deemed to be complex if:
- the space of possibilities in question is broad and undetermined, and
- the space of possibilities is not flat or just plain chaotic; it is curved, due to
the impact of attractors, breaks, slopes and the intertwining of different
phenomena that facilitate or hinder learning.
In a complex situation, the space of possibilities can be described as an
extremely rugged and non-linear landscape, where small causes can have big
effects or, quite to the contrary, major forces can implode without any apparent
consequences, and as an environment in which there are levers that can trigger
chain reactions with unpredictable effects at remote spots on the playing field.
Consequently, any attempt to explore complexity will have to deal with the
effects of magnification (positive feedback circuits) or implosion (negative
feedback circuits), with rising and descending paths and with catastrophic events
that render the progress made irreversible.
In order to identify useful or efficient solutions, any exploratory work must take
advantage of favourable curvatures while resisting unfavourable forces. This
approach entails complex forms of learning that can help overcome the most
48 E. Rullani
obvious attractors (local optimum points that block the path to remote optimum
points) and the ability to guess the positions of the most favourable possibilities.
The general idea of complexity is shaped by the varied and undetermined nature
of the space of possibilities that is being explored and by the "curvature" of that
space. In a flat or perfectly casualistic space, the exploration can proceed
stochastically on the basis of the degree of probability assigned to the different
possible events.
The general model for the exploration of the curved space of possibilities is
derived from the evolutionary paradigm and "tested" through computer
simulations (Dosi and Marengo 1993, Axelrod and Cohen 1999). It includes a
sequence of variation, selection and differential reproduction for the variables that
are found to be suitable (having a minimum degree of adaptability) and allows a
large number of different modalities in the execution of these activities. The use of
this form of learning - which is not the only one, but is the one that is more
general in scope because it does not presuppose any previous knowledge of the
space of possibilities that is being explored - is important because adaptive
learning alters the frequency and structure of the chosen systems. In other words,
the complexity of the environment becomes "imprinted" in the internal structure
of the organism or organization, thereby ceasing to be an exogenous variable that
is fundamentally unpredictable and uncontrollable. Evolutionary learning creates a
link, a structural coupling of the (adapted) internal structure and the possibilities
that exist in the external environment. The complexity of the environment is thus
metabolised by the system as it learns and evolves into an organization, with an
implicit match between what is internal (complex system) and what is external
(environmental complexity).
We can then speak of complexity with respect to the environment (latent form of
the space of possibilities) or the system that explores it (its internal structure that
metabolises the complexity of the external environment and makes it
manageable). These two definitions are different but convergent: we expect the
exploration of a complex environment to produce the construction of a structure of
equal complexity within the system, and the internal complexity of a system to be
useful only if it refers to an environment that is in some way related to the
structure of the system.
The learning process removes free complexity from the environment and
metabolises it into the structure of the system as governed complexity, i.e., as
variance, indeterminateness and curvature of the space of possibilities that the
system can control with variances or adjustments that are quick and inexpensive
but not deterministic (Di Bernardo and Rullani 1990).
The internal structure is organized by levels, based on the emerging properties
that, for example, differentiate a macro-system from its elemental components.
The discovery of emerging properties that, for example, are typical of cells and
not of molecules, of social groups and not of the individuals within the groups,
permits the allocations of the governance of complexity among different levels of
the organization, from micro to macro. The governance of complexity can be
achieved by regulating the behaviour of the elemental components. However, the
control of all those aspects that concern properties that emerge at the macro level
The Industrial Cluster as a Complex Adaptive System 49
can become very difficult and expensive unless governance mechanisms based on
the principle of functional equivalence are established at the macro level.
Elemental components that perform the same function, because they do not alter
properties that emerge at the macro level, are deemed to be equivalent and,
therefore, interchangeable. Control and feedback mechanisms that correct any
variances, regulations and standards that guarantee a high level of process and
product consistency, and shared meanings that permit the joint testing of virtual
possibilities ensure that all of the parties involved are functionally equivalent,
thereby preserving the emerging properties of the macro-system. As a result, the
macro level becomes largely independent of the fate of its elemental components,
which can be easily exchanged or replaced with others, when needed.
Complex systems cannot be reduced to the sums of their component parts
because the ability to maintain the emerging properties depends more on the
services that guarantee functional equivalences than on the behaviour of individual
elemental components.
Clearly, beyond this general outline, there are profound differences between the
different levels of organization and the different fields in which complexity
occurs. A different !Jystem of variation/selection/differential reproduction is
adopted for every level or field.
Because of this, the complexity of economics is different from the complexity
of, for example, physical or biological sciences. This occurs because:
- the mechanisms of variation that explore what is new are specific
(deliberateness, innovation);
- the mechanisms of selection are tied to the internal choices of businesses and
the competitiveness of the marketplace;
- the mechanisms for the expanded reproduction of the "winning" or "correct"
variances are tied not only to the competitive success of the winning
companies, but also to processes involving contractual transfers (licensing,
franchising), reputation (brand, image), copying, imitation, communication
and learning.
Therefore, even in the area of complexity, there is an economic specificity that
cannot be overlooked. On the economic plane, the cluster has its own specificity
as a special complex adaptive system.
In the field of economic studies, the theory of complexity has been applied to
the solution of specific problems, almost all of them involving the "invisible
hand" of the market and the changes that occur in response to attempts at finding
equilibrium between prices and quantities.
The market can be considered an example of CAS and was treated as such by a
tradition of research that viewed it as a cognitive mechanism (Hayek 1937;
Rizzello 1997).
50 E. Rullani
complexity are not dictated "from above". On the contrary, they form
spontaneously over time without any intervention. In addition, these rules
are updated through a dynamic process of collective learning that follows the
swarm model rather than being preordained or mandated by a higher order-
making power.
2) Clusters are localized ecosystems of relationships created through history
and organized in accordance with an internal logic that is largely
inaccessible to observation. Much like neural networks, clusters are black
boxes that metabolise experience and develop specific integrations of
resources and relationships that are unique and nonreproducible because
they escape logical representation, even though they exist in the different
visions of the individual players. In the same way that a neural network
modifies the weight and form of the relationships between the different
nodes, cluster ecology continuously modifies the structural coupling
established between individuals and the existing meanings, physical assets
and products. In their activity, clusters do not just "process" information and
technical solutions; they develop social structures, collective identities and
value scales, and, ultimately, shape anthropologies and mindsets that exist
only at one location and that are virtually impossible to re-create elsewhere,
even when very similar learning paths are followed.
3) Industrial clusters are living systems, not just more or less efficient problem-
solving devices. Or, rather, clusters acquire a problem-solving ability only
when they can reproduce themselves as living systems consisting of
thousands of people who use these cluster environments to develop not just
efficient and profitable solutions, but also answers to their need to interact,
communicate and feel, which goes beyond a narrow economic vision. All of
these people live permanently within each cluster and lack an alternative
world where they can satisfy their noneconomic needs. Therefore, cluster
micro societies cannot be efficient only from an economic standpoint; they
must also meet meta-economic and extra-economic needs that are equally
important to ensure the system's ability to reproduce over time.
Because they are natural self-organizing systems, localized ecosystems, living
systems that are required to reproduce society in its entirety and not just an
instrumental portion of it (the economy), clusters do not fit easily into the classic
categories of economic science. For example, their anthropology is broader, by
definition, than the one applicable to homo oeconomicus and their rationality is
always more than just instrumental. The ties that link clusters to the history,
culture and mind set of the people who populate them are never contingent or
superficial, binding instead deep structures and distinctive differences. A cluster is
not just a logical category; it is an organism made of past experiences, collective
identities and relationships based on mutual recognition. When studying cluster
dynamics, there is a limit to which extent the evidence grid can be dissected
analytically, because if the dissection is not done with sufficient care, one runs the
risk of separating that which is inseparable and loosing sight of the fact that
clusters function like systems of integrated parts that interact with each other and
52 E. Rullani
not like complexes of isolated elements that are joined together strictly for
contingent reasons.
Clusters and the economy belong to two different regions of knowledge: the
former belong by full right to the region of complex phenomena and systems; the
latter belongs methodologically to the region of computing and determinism.
Consequently, clusters can be rightfully included in the realm of economics only if
the field of interest of economics is enlarged, leaving determinism behind and
entering the open sea of complexity.
It is only by taking this step, which many economists still refuse to do, that
clusters become meaningful examples, serving as prototypes and living
laboratories for systems in which society metabolises complexity, using it as a
productive resource capable of creating economic value and competitive
advantages. In a certain sense, clusters are in vitro displays of the learning system
of an economy that has discovered the most effective way of moulding people,
economic developments and social organizations for the purpose of harnessing
complexity (Axelrod and Cohen 1999).
The localized nature of learning, and of the resulting knowledge, is not the product
of a historic accident or a geographic anomaly. On the contrary, it derives from the
very way in which knowledge is produced, each piece of knowledge being
generated in a context that includes a web of personal, business, local and industry
relationships, each of which can be essential in order to obtain the desired effect.
Consequently, each piece of knowledge retains its validity only as long as its
context remains the same, losing validity (and value) as the conditions of the
original context begin to change. Obviously, there are certain activities -
abstraction, codification, standardization, measuring - that serve the specific
purpose of extending the validity of knowledge beyond the original context to a
much broader field. However, it is also true that these activities involve only a
portion of the knowledge acquired through experience. The greatest portion of
knowledge remains embedded and sedimented in personal abilities, business
routines and territorial contexts (Cora 1998).
People, businesses and territories know more than they can make explicit or
transfer to others. More importantly, they know how to do more than they can
explain because they use the embedded knowledge that is sedimented in the
contexts. In complex situations, where there are many and undetermined
variances, the processes of abstraction, codification, standardization and
measurement are too slow and costly to produce significant quantities of this
implied knowledge and make it transferable from one context to another. When
complexity is high, conditions change so rapidly that they require a <.:Ontinuous
process of interpreting and modifying the existing knowledge. As a result, there is
not enough time or potential benefit to justify extracting from the existing contexts
a transferable knowledge that can become obsolete in a short time. It becomes
The Industrial Cluster as a Complex Adaptive System 53
For the foreseeable future, the economy will continue to display a growing level of
complexity, if for no other reason than that market globalisation and
communications networking will inevitably multiply connections and inter:.lctions,
thereby increasing significantly the variety of nodes and the indeterminateness of
their behaviour. Any research into the type of organization that will be best suited
to handle this growing complexity must take into account the cluster - i.e., the
localized specialization of a nucleus of autonomous businesses that interact with
each other - as one of the systems capable of providing an effective answer
(Grandinetti and Rullani 1996, Vacca 1997).
In this endeavour, the cluster will have to compete with other solutions,
including three alternative systems that must be reckoned with in assessing how
competitive the cluster system will be (Rullani 2000):
The market, i.e., a decontextualized relationship among businesses that does not
presuppose the existence of a context of shared experience and that, therefore, can
apply to exchanges and dissemination of the highest possible multipliers.
Hierarchy, i.e., the development of forms of shared ownership of knowledge
and skills, organized around the common membership in a single corporate
organization.
54 E. Rullani
Networks, which are based on interaction and the sharing of skills by different
businesses that develop away from each other, at different locations, with the help
of modern communication technologies.
There is one specific feature that distinguishes the cluster from these three
systems: in a cluster, the communication and interaction medium linking all
parties involved (customers, the full range of suppliers, entrepreneurs, employees,
banks, local institutions, etc.) is in fact the territory and whatever became
sedimented in the territory through history.
In the market, it is price that provides an interface between the parties. In a
hierarchy, the links between the various companies are provided by
communications, logistics and assurance systems that must be built and
maintained through a collaborative effort that entails sharing investments, risks
and, if nothing else, beneficial behaviours.
Obviously, these are very different relationships and exchange media.
In a competitive comparison with other systems, the cluster is aided by the
advantages provided by territorial contiguity. These advantages are not
insignificant, considering that most of our complexity-governing skills are the
product of localized learning dynamics that are strongly influenced by the context
in which the learning takes place.
In successful clusters that have steadily increased sales to their terminal
markets, territorial continuity has produced a marked division of labour amung
different businesses characterized by:
Mutual speCialization, which allows companies to focus their investments and
risks on a narrowly defined core business, relying on other local specialists
(subcontractors, components manufacturers, providers of specialized services and
production, logistics suppliers, distributors, consultants, etc.) for everything else.
Weaker entry barriers, because new companies can be established easily and
enter the market by specializing in very narrow fields of expertise, thereby
minimizing capital requirements and risk, and relying on the skills, manufacturing
capacity and services of outsiders that are available locally.
The continuous birth of new companies, the creation of a pool of specific
professional skiffs (related to a specific industry) that are both highly developed
and plentiful, the organization of flows of exchange among specialists and the
resulting interdependencies.
The growth of a cluster is fuelled by the innovations made by its enterprises,
provided that these innovations are at the same time inclusive internally (open to
other workers and entrepreneurs within the cluster) and exclusive externally.
Proprietary innovations developed by large companies that invest in assets that
cannot be "socialized" within a cluster (for example, proprietary brands,
commercial chains, etc.) fuel the growth of individual companies and not of local
systems.
Codified innovations, which can be incorporated into easily transferable
machines or technologies, can provide only a minimal contribution to the growth
of a cluster. Innovations of this type can be quickly disseminated outside a cluster
because they are not exclusive externally: after a short while, they become
accessible to competitors located outside the cluster.
The Industrial Cluster as a Complex Adaptive System 55
The innovations that are best suited to producing an increase in the knowledge that
becomes sedimented within a cluster and fuels the growth of the businesses that
use this knowledge are those that have to do with products and production
processes. A cluster works best when the task at hand is identifying niche needs,
meeting latent consumer requirements and bringing innovations to the production
process incrementally through on-the-job field tests. In all of these cases,
innovations are based on an unspoken knowledge that is not easily transferred
outside the cluster. As a result, these innovations have the characteristics typical of
localized innovations: they are inclusive internally (they can be easily imitated)
and exclusive externally (they cut out competitors located outside the cluster).
The growth of a cluster occurs along the often-narrow divider that separates
localized innovations from proprietary innovations (non inclusive) and codified
innovations (non exclusive). In order for a cluster to replicate its competitive
position and protect the quantity and quality of its product supply from
competitors, the flows of innovations that occur within the cluster at a given
moment in time must be sufficient to maintain the balance of this twin frontier -
both internal and external. When innovations serve to disseminate good ideas at
the local level while at the same time excluding potential external competitors, a
cluster expands. If, on the other hand, there are obstacles that hinder internal
propagation and external defence, a cluster contracts, and if it shrinks below a
certain critical threshold, it can even implode to the point of disappearing as an
organized system of learning and localized production.
Therefore, the future of industrial clusters will be predicated on a critical factor:
the manner in which they handle the growing complexity they will be faced with,
i.e., the innovations that will emerge in the economy in the near future (Arora and
Gambardella 1993; Arora, Gambardella and Rullani 1997). In the case of codified
innovations, the division of labour could use the market to bypass the cluster. In
proprietary innovations, the division of labour within a major enterprise could be
more effective than the one occurring externally, within the cluster. Under these
new conditions, the survival of clusters is endangered simultaneously on two
fronts: clusters risk losing business activity to the market, on the one hand, and to
delocalised or multilocalized large companies, on the other.
Nevertheless, in the specific field of innovation, clusters continue to enjoy
important competitive advantages in the division of innovative labour in
noncommoditized fields that resist codification, but can, at the same time, be
imitated, transferred and reproduced at the cluster level. For example, the work of
exploring what is new, which will ultimately result in new products and new
processes, is often carried out in ways that permit good permeability at the local
level, but provides a relatively solid defensive barrier against external imitators.
Clearly, this type of work can be carried out by cohesive local networks that
include many independent operators capable of working together. However, it is
also important to keep in mind that companies are required to make certain types
56 E. Rullani
trans local networks to which they are linked. At the same time, networks could
become denser at certain locations, creating quasi-clusters that exchange goods
and knowledge over a finely meshed network that comprises light and highly
mobile nodes with minimal territorial roots.
13. Conclusions
The most realistic possibility is that all four of the systems I have discussed
(global market, hierarchy of the multinational corporation, cluster-type local
network, translocal remote interaction network) will occupy different regions of
complexity, in accordance with their respective characteristics.
In order to survive, clusters must avoid becoming prisoners of the businesses in
which they have engaged thus far, embracing without reservation or delay the
changes that are starting to reshape post-Fordist complexity. For example, they
must quickly surrender to other systems those areas that are indefensible,
concentrating instead on that for which they are best suited: managing complex
solutions that can be developed with the resources of intelligence and self-
organization possessed by local societies.
We cannot tell whether clusters will account for a large or small percentage of
total production and employment, since we cannot know if they will increase in
number and importance or shrink quantitatively compared with competing
transterritorial systems (market, multinationals, remote interaction networks).
What we do know is that in order to foster the competitive vitality of the
existing clusters, we must invest in localized innovations (inclusive internally and
exclusive externally) that take advantage of the skills of interpretation, invention
and sharing that are typical of local societies.
The future of industrial clusters is tied first of all to their ability to exploit
promptly - without being excessively defensive - the strengths of the markets,
hierarchies and networks, borrowing the functions that give these systems
irresistible competitive advantages. It will also be predicated on the ability of local
companies to manage complexity better than the multipliers of global markets, the
investments of large multinational corporations and the selective communications
of trans territorial networks.
The destiny of industrial clusters and of complexity is intertwined, as is their
past. It will be up to our intelligence to discover how to continue forward on a
path already taken, giving new meaning to roots and identities sedimented in the
places we inhabit.
References
Arora, A. and Gambardella, A. (1993), Division of Labour and Inventive Activity, H. John
Heinz III School of Management, Carnegie Mellon, 93-3, January.
60 E. Rullani
Arora, A., Gambardella, A. and Rullani, E. (1997), "Division of Labour and the Locus of
Inventive Activity", Journal of Management and Governance, No. I, Autumn.
Arthur, W.B. (1988), "Self-reinforcing Mechanisms in Economics", in: The Economy as an
Evolving Complex System, Anderson, P.W., Arrow, K.1. and Pines, D. (eds), Santa Fe
Institute, Studies in the Sciences of Complexity, Redwood City, CA, Addison-Wesley.
Axelrod, R.. and Cohen, M.D. (1999), Harnessing Complexity: Organizational
Implications of a Scientific Frontier, New York, The Free Press.
Bagnasco, A. (1977), Tre Italie. Problematiche dello sviluppo italiano, Bologna, II Mulino.
Becattini, G. (1961), II concetto di industria e la teoria del valore, Torino, Boringhieri.
Becattini, G. (2000a), Il bruco e la farfalla. Prato: una storia esemplare dell'Italia dei
distretti, Firenze, Le Monnier.
Becattini, G. (2000b), Il distretto industriale. Un nuovo modo di interpretare it
cambiamento economico, Torino, Rosenberg e Sellier.
Becattini, G. (2000c), Dal distretto industriale allo sviluppo locale. Svolgimento e difesa di
un 'idea, Torino, Bollati Boringhieri.
Becattini, G. and Rullani, E. (1993), "Sistema locale e mercato glob ale", Economia e
Politica Industriale, 80, December, pp. 25-48.
Brusco, S. (1982), "The Emilian Model: Productive Disintegration and Social Integration",
Cambridge Journal of Economics, 6, 2, pp. 167-184.
Brusco, S. (1989), Piccola impresa e distretti industriali, Torino, Rosenberg e Sellier.
Brusco, S. and Paba, S. (1997), "Per una storia dei distretti industriali italiani dal secondo
dopoguerra agli anni novanta", in: Storia del capitalismo italiano dal dopoguerra a oggi,
Barca, F. (ed.), Roma, Donzelli.
Cora, G. (1998), "Distretti e sistemi di piccola impresa nella transizione", in: Il
postfordismo. Idee per il capitalismo prossimo venturo, Rullani, E. and Romano, L.
(eds), Milano, Etaslibri.
Di Bernardo, B., and Rullani, E. (1990), Il management e Ie macchine. Teoria evolutiva
dell'impresa, Bologna, II Mulino.
Dosi, G., and Marengo, L. (1993), "Some Elements of an Evolutionary Theory of
Organizational Competences", in: Evolutionary Concepts in Contemporary Economics,
England, R.W. (ed.), Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press.
Fortis, M. (1996), Crescita economica e specializzazioni produttive, Milano, Vita e
Pensiero.
Fortis, M. (1998), II "made in Italy" - Quando stile e creativitii non sono solo moda,
Bologna, II Mulino.
Fu1i, G. and Zacchia, C. (eds) (1983), Industrializzazione senza !ratture, Bologna, II
Mulino.
Galbraith, J. K. (1967), The New Industrial State, Boston, MA, Houghton Mifflin. Italian
translation: Il nuovo stato industriale, Torino, Einaudi, 1968.
Grandinetti, R., and Rullani, E. (1996), Impresa transnazionale ed economia globale,
Roma, La Nuova Italia Scientifica.
Hayek, F.A. von (1937), "Economics and Knowledge", Economica, n.s. IV, No. 13, pp. 96-
105.
Holland, 1. (1995), Hidden Order: How Adaptation Builds Complexity, Reading, MA,
Addison-Welsey.
Holland, J. H. (1988), "The Global Economy as an Adaptive Process", in: The Economy as
an Evolving Complex System, Anderson, P.W., Arrow, K.J. and Pines, D. (eds), Santa Fe
Institute, Studies in the Science of Complexity, Redwood City, CA, Addison-Wesley,
Proceedings.
Kelly, K. (1994), Out of Control, Addison-Wt:sley, Italian translation: La nuova biologia
delle macchine, dei sistemi sociali e del mondo dell 'economia, Milano Apogeo, 1996.
The Industrial Cluster as a Complex Adapti ve System 61
Kelly, K. (1998), New Rules for the New Economy. Ten Ways the Network Economy is
Changing Everything, Londra, Fourth Estate. Italian translation: Nuove regole per un
nuovo mondo. Un decalogo per chi vuole cavalcare Ie nuove regole e non esserne
scavalcato, Firenze, Ponte delle Grazie, 1999.
Krugman, P. (1995), Develupment, Geography and Economic Theory, Cambridge, MA,
MIT Press.
Krugman, P., and Venables, A. J. (1990), "Integration and the Competitiveness of
Peripheral Industry", in: Unity with Diversity in the European Economy, Bliss, C. and
Braga de Macedo, J. (eds), Cambridge MA, Cambridge University Press.
Krugman. P., and Venables, A. J. (1995), "Integration, Specialization and Adjustment",
European Economic Review. 40.
March, J. G. (1991), "Exploration and Exploitation in Organizational Learning",
Organization Science, vol. 2, No. I, pp. 71-87.
Micelli, S. (2000), imprese. reti. comunita, Milano, Etas.
Piore, M. J. and Sabel, C. F. (1984), The Second industrial Divide, New York, Basic
Books. Italian translation: Le due vie dello sviluppo industriale, Torino, Isedi, 1987.
Porter. M. E. (1989), The Competitive Advantage of Nations. Italian translation: fl
vantaggio competitivo delle nazioni, Milano, Mondadori, 1991.
Rizzcllo, S. (1997). L 'economia della mente, Roma, Laterza. English translation: The
Economics of the Mind, Elgar, Aldcrshot, 1999.
Rullani, E. (1996), "Complessita c informazione nella scienza economica", Pluriverso 2,
RCS Libri.
Rullani. E. (2000), "Sistemi locali e produzione di conoscenza", presentation at the OECD
Conference on Enhancing the Competitiveness of SMEs in the Global Economy:
Strategies and Policies, Bologna.
Sabel, C. F. (1989), "Flexible Specialization and the Reemergence of Regional
Economies", in: Reversing industrial Decline, Hirst, P. and Zeitlin, 1., Oxford, Berg.
Sabel, C. F. (1999), "Regionalismo sperimentale e i dilemmi della politica economica
regionale in Europa", in: Neuregionalismo. L 'economia-arcipelago, Perulli, P., Torino.
Bollati Boringhieri.
Saxenian, A. (1994), Regional Advantage: Culture and Competition in Silicon Valley and
Route 128, Cambridge, MA. Harvard University Press.
Signorini, F. L. (2000), Lo sviluppo locale. Un'indagine della Banca d'italia sui distretti
industriali, Cosenza, Meridiana Libri.
Silverberg, G., Dosi, G., and Orsenigo, L. (1988), "Innovation, Diversity and Diffusion: A
Self-Organizing Model". Economic Journal, 98, pp. 1032-1054.
Vacca, S. (1997), "Le differenze socio-culturali e istituzionali nello sviluppo delle imprese:
il ruolo del capitale immateriale e del capitale umano", Economia e Politica Industriale.
No. 94.
Varaldo. R., and Ferrucci, L. (eds) (1997), II distretto industriale tra logiche di impresa e
logiche di sistema, Milano, Angeli.
Viesti, G. (2000a), "Le strade dello sviluppo: come sono nati i distretti industriali del Made
in Italy nel Mezzogiorno", Economia e Politica industriale, No. 106, June.
Viesti, G. (2000b), Come nascono i distretti industriali, Bari. Laterza.
Zagnoli, P. (1991), I rapporti tra imprese nei settori ad alta tecnologia. II caso della
Silicon Valley, Torino, Giappichelli.
II. General Models of Industrial Cluster Dynamics
Complexity and Local Interactions:
Towards a Theory of Industrial Districts
David A. Lane l
lIn preparing this paper, I profited from discussions with Robert Maxfield, Margherita
Russo and David Stark, who kindly shared with me some of their knowledge about Silicon
Valley, Sassuolo and Silicon Alley respectively. In addition, I learned much from my
discussions over the years with my colleagues Andrea Ginzburg and Sebastiano Brusco
about the ideas presented here and their relation with district phenomenology.
66 D. A. Lane
1. Introduction
2But of course does not necessarily product the right kinds of interaction structures.
Whether these form or not depends on many factors - in particular. through the kinds of
scaffolding structures that emerge to channel and generate local interactions.
3Before taking the question too seriously. it would be a good idea to establish the empirical
validity of the proposition that districts tend to be located near other districts, rather than
having a random geographical distribution, in the appropriate sense of "random" for this
issue. I believe that districts do cluster, for the reason I provide in the text. Of course, if
they don' t, it is still the case that districts that are clustered may still share certain
scaffolding structures!
68 D. A. Lane
2. Perspectives on Complexity
The papers in this volume by Gell-Mann and Holland start from two different
perspectives on complexity. Gell-Mann takes a theoretical perspective. The
complexity of a system, he tells us, can be measured by the length of the minimal
description of the system's regularities. Thus, if we want to address the question
of whether an industrial district is a complex system, we are forced to confront
some hard ontological issues. How do we characterize a district in system terms -
that is, what are its component entities, and through which kinds of processes do
they interact with one another'? Even harder: taking on the role of Gell-Mann's
judge, we need to decide what constitute a district's regularities - and to frame a
vocabulary in which we can describe them.
Holland's approach to complexity begins phenomenologically rather than
theoretically. For him, a complex system is one that behaves in a particular way.
Roughly, the system is composed of a number of entities that have properties that
in general differ from entity to entity; the entities interact with one another and the
environment they inhabit; as a result of these interactions, their properties, the
environment's, and even their interaction modes may change. In the examples
Complex it} and Local Interactions: Towards a Theory of Industrial Districts 69
Holland presents, the entities' structures - that is, the set of their properties -
determine how they function - that is, the transformations they effect through their
interactions with other entities.
A complex system, then, is a particular kind of dynamical process, determined
by a succession of interactions among entities. The phenomena of interest in the
dynamics of complex systems are often characterized as emergent: they refer to
features that can be concisely described only by reference to a higher level of
aggregation than the individual entities themselves and that persist for periods of
time considerably longer than those in which individual entities' interactions are
denominated. Often, emergent structures self-organize, and this emergent
organization of the system may constrain and channel the entities' interaction
patterns. To apply the phenomenological perspective on complexity to industrial
districts, one must describe the district in terms of the agents that compose them
and their modes of interaction, then search for "global" emergent structures and
self-organization at the level of the district itself. We might even ask to what
extent the district itself might be regarded as an emergent entity.
Both Holland and Gell-Mann emphasize an aspect of complex systems that
could be described as cognitive. Holland refers to ·'adaptive agents" that adjust
their actions on the basis of what they have learned from their previous history of
interactions with their world; Gell-Mann calls the representation of the world on
the basis of which such adjustments are made a "schema", and prefers to reserve
the term "complex system" itself for an entity with a schema, which can be
thought of as its minimal description of the regularities in its world. This circle of
ideas prompts a question rather novel to the district literature: are we justified in
viewing the district itselfas what Holland calls an adaptive agent and Gell-Mann a
complex system? Or to put it another way: as we have already seen, a complexity
perspective requires that we treat a district as a time-varying structure and that we
try to understand how its structure determines its function; should we also view
the district as a cognitive entity, and understand how its cognitive processes give
rise to transformations in its structure?
Summarizing, the hallmarks of a complexity perspective include commitments
to
• process and change, not stasis and equilibrium;
• a multilevel organization of entities;
• entity function determined by entity structure;
• distributed control and information-processing; and
• emergence and self-organization.
Whether it is useful to apply a complexity perspective to industrial districts
depends on how rich an account of district phenomenology a theory founded on
these commitments can produce.
70 D. A. Lane
40f course, the space need not physically contain all the participants in the interaction.
Instead, it may be mediated by artefacts, as happens with electronic bulletin boards or
72 D. A. Lane
video-conferencing. As these two examples indicate, however, even such "virtual spaces"
can be identitied with physical spaces that determine the form of the interactions they
support.
Complexity and Local Interactions: Towards a Theory of Industrial Districts 73
as new agent structures form and new artefact types are developed. In general,
new entities are preceded by new attributions. For example, a new artefact type is
developed in order to achieve a new kind of imagined functionality. So to
understand how a market system changes, it is important to consider how new
attributions come into being.
Robert Maxfield and I (Maxfield and Lane 1997) have argued elsewhere that
new attributions generally arise in the context of generative relationships among
agents. The key idea is that individual agents' attributions tend to be organized
into closed systems, within which it may be possible to recombine existing
elements to develop "better, faster, cheaper" versions of previously represented
types, but which resist extension into new classificatory dimensions. To open an
attributional system to new conceptualisations usually requires the realization that
its current representations are incomplete, a realization that can generally emerge
only in the context of discursive relationships with others, whose attributional
systems highlight different aspects of the identity or functionality of some
particular entity under discussion. Often, the realization begins with the
uncovering of an ambiguity in the sense in which different participants in the
discussion use the same terms. This ambiguity in categories that each participant
regarded as both well defined and shared opens a space for innovation in the
attributional systems of each of them. To fill that space generally requires further
joint exploration, in which each may adjust boundaries and introduce new
concepts and categories in one's own set of attributions as they all jointly
construct what they come to regard as a shared attribution for the entities that have
entered into their conversations.
Clearly, not every relationship between agents is generative in the sense
described above. Maxfield and I identified five characteristics that together
determine the generative potential of an agent relationship:
• aligned directedness - The participants in the relationship need to orient their
activities towards a common zone of agent-artefact space. For example, the
same kind of artefact might be the focus of each of their activities, a!though
the participants need not have the same relationship to the focal artefact.
• heterogeneity - Generativeness requires that the participating agents differ
from one another in key respects. They may have different attributional
systems, competences or access to particular agents or artefacts.
• mutual directedness - Agents need more than common interests and different
perspectives to form a generative relationship. They also must seek each
other out and develop a recurring pattern of interactions out of which a
relationship can emerge. Their willingness to do this depends on the
attributions each has of the other's identity. It helps, but is not necessary, for
the participants to start by trusting one another. Frequently, rather than a
precondition, trust is an emergent property of generative relationships: it
grows as participants <.:arne to realize the unforeseen benefits that the
relationship is generating.
• permissions - Discursive relationships are based on permissions for the
participants to talk to one another about particular themes in particular
illocutionary modes (requests, orders, declarations, etc.). These permissions
74 D. A. Lane
an a priori basis for mutual directedness, at least within the context of the
interaction modes supported by the community, while shared physical space
provides an opportunity to form either positive or negative attributions of others'
modes of operating, and so either enhances mutual directedness or brings an
unsatisfactory relationship to rapid closure.
Similarly, community values can ensure aligned directness for interactions
directed towards transformations consistent with those values, while face-to-face
communication encourages the kind of discursive exploration that can lead to the
discovery of a basis for alignment that may not have been evident a priori.
However, there is always an inherent tension between aligned directedness and
attributional heterogeneity: agents that are completely aligned may come to share
a relevant set of attributions to such an extent that the generative potential of their
relationship may decline or even disappear; and if any relationship becomes
closed to outside perturbations from other, cross-cutting networks of relations,
local interactions among participants in the relationship almost certainly will
hasten this process along. This risk is greatest when the participants are strongly
co-located in social space, and hence begin with similar attributional systems,
which the relationship may fine-tune to homogeneity. On the other hand, extended
face-to-face discourse may reveal subtle unsuspected attributional differences, the
exploration of which may provide space for generation of new attributions. Much
depends on the way in which relationship participants regard attributional
heterogeneity, whether as a threat or an opportunity for the future of the
relationship. Overall, if participants in a relationship are open to the outside and to
the potential fruitfulness of disagreement and misunderstanding, locality in all its
forms is a potent contributor to generative potential.
For this reason, every market system provides scaffolds that make possible
certain kinds of local interactions. Some of these kinds of interactions need not
recur frequently: trade fairs provide an opportunity for many market system
participants to keep up with general trends in artefact development and use
through meetings and discussions with one another, but for most market systems
one or two trade fairs a year is enough. But other kinds of scaffolded local
interactions require frequent recurrence, and these are generally possible only
when the networks that the scaffolds construct and maintain are composed of
agents that are either spatially co-located or sufficiently socially co-located that
they can maintain local interactions at physically remote sites. Scaffolds of this
type include universities and community colleges that support research
collaboration and training for system participants, users' groups, or meeting sites
for various kinds of informal face-to-face interactions like Happy Hour at the
Wagon Wheel in Silicon Valley or Silicon Alley's somewhat more formalized
cyber parties. The possibility to provide scaffolding structures of this type is a
strong incentive for geographic concentration of market system participants - and
lies at the heart of the industrial district.
Complexity and Local Interactions: Towards a Theory of Industrial Districts 77
7. Industrial Districts
generative relationships the benefits of which redounded to the firms for which
these individuals worked (and frequently the firms they founded as the result of
some of the new attributions they generated). These practices included such
cognitive scaffolds as rules that do not penalize employees from switching jobs
from one firm to another, and physical scaffolds ranging from Happy Hour at the
Wagon Wheel to research seminars at Stanford, Santa Clara and various company
labs. In Modena, the CNA (Confederazione Nazionale dell' Artigianato) holds
frequent meetings in which entrepreneurs may learn about new markets and new
product opportunities from one another, and as the organization grew and the
production competences represented in the Modena area multiplied, its
administrators came to play a brokering role, bringing together entrepreneurs
whose firm's competences might be combined to produce an artefact filling a
newly recognized potential market niche, discovered by another Modena
entrepreneur doing his own business in, say, China or Eastern Europe.
The second kind of scaffold provides for the delivery of local services, which
make it easy to start up a new firm and enable entrepreneurs to concentrate their
resources on honing their particular design or production competences. In
Modena, both local and provincial governments and CNA provide such services,
from arranging financing to outsourcing book-keeping and legal assistance, to
supporting trade fairs at which local firms may display their products to potential
buyers recruited from around the world, to providing space for new firms to
establish their operations, to research and educational projects like PROMO,
designed to introduce local firms to best international practice. In Silicon Valley,
many of the same scaffolding services have emerged privately, with little
government or district-level organization. For example, venture capitalists,
concentrated in several blocks of Sand Hill Road, provide not only seed financing
but networking and recruiting services to prospective entrepreneurs. Local law
firms specialize in legal services for start-up companies; some of them now offer
start-up packages for as little as $5,000 per year (or shares in the new companies),
handling all the legal problems new firms encounter in their first two or three
years of business. Real estate developers build industrial parks where start-up or
expanding firms can locate. The architectural design of many of these parks
provide open space, inside and out, that facilitate the formation of discursive
relationships within and between firms located in the parks. Probably the most
important scaffold for Silicon Valley, at least in its formative years, was Stanford
University, whose engineering graduates were encouraged to start companies in
the area and whose professors were permitted to engage actively in consulting and
entrepreneurial activities of their own. Stanford, San Jose State, and Santa Clara
now all play important roles in promoting knowledge development and exchange,
through seminars, research programs, and teaching (often with instructors
recruited from local businesses) for Silicon Valley firms and professionals. While
local governments around Modena were often in the forefront in providing
infrastructural support to local districts, this was not the case in Silicon Valley,
until some of the "senior citizens" from successful firms in the district established
a lobbying group, the Santa Clara County Manufacturing Group, which became an
important scaffolding institution for the mature district.
Complexity and Local Interactions: Towards a Theory ot" Industrial Districts 79
talk about the district acting require further theoretical development much beyond
the hints supplied here. Briefly, through its networks of communication and
interpretation, the district may build up a set of partially shared attributions about
the relevant agents and artefacts in its market system. Of course, this set is actually
distributed among district agents, but because its elements are generally shared
among these agents, they wiII produce some regularities in the way in which
district agents interact with each other and outside agents, and as a result of these
regularities, attributions that other agents make about the identity of district agents
may share some elements. In this way, attributions can arise for "a way of acting
like a Silicon VaIIey start-up company," and, at least absent strong specific contra-
indications, these attributions may be applied to any "Silicon Valley start-up",
thus reinforcing the behaviour that such an attribution predicts. In addition,
through its scaffolding structures, a district may provide certain agents with
permissions that allow them to speak or act for the district in certain kinds of
situations - for example, in testimony before Congress or regulatory agencies, or
in interviews with journalists who ask what "Silicon Valley" thinks about some
governmental policy or macro-economic context. Both the distributed set of
partially shared attributions and the set of permissions that endow district-level
agency upon particular district agents may be legitimately interpreted as
components of a district schema, and so we may regard the district itself - and nO[
merely the agents of which it is composed - as a complex adaptive system in Gell-
Mann's sense.
5The literature is already vast, as a web search on agent-based modelling will reveal. For a
recent collection of interesting essays on the subject. with many references. consult Kohler
and Gumerman (2000).
6Using the Swarm platform. developed at the Santa Fe Institute.
82 D. A. Lane
References
Kohler, T. and Gumerman, G. (2000), Dynamics in Human and Primate Societies: Agent-
Based Modelling of Social and Spatial Processes, Santa Fe Institute Studies in the
Sciences of Complexity Series, Oxford University Press.
Maxfield, R. and Lane, D. A. (1997), "Foresight, Complexity and Strategy", in: Economy
as a Complex, Evolving System II, Arthur, W. B., Durlauf, S. and Lane, D. (cds),
Redwood City CA, Addison-Wesley, Chap. 4.
Saxenian, A. (1996), Regional Advantage: Culture and Competition in Silicon Valley and
Route J28, Harvard University Press.
Watts, D. (1999), Small Worlds, Princeton University Press.
7Also Swarm-based.
8Watts' early work on small worlds is presented in his book (1999).
From Marshall's to the Italian
"Industrial Districts".
A Brief Critical Reconstruction
Giacomo Becattini 1
Abstract. This paper begins by reconstructing the historical genesis of the notion
of industrial district, focusing on the contribution of Alfred Marshall, the
economist who is thought to have discovered this system. The paper also shows
how the notion of industrial district stems from the successful wedding of
Marshall's keen observations of contemporary industrial reality, mainly in Great
Britain, with the desire to provide a way out of the difficulties inherent in classical
economic theory and answer the challenges posed by the class struggle (e.g.,
economic nations).
The economic conditions that fostered the development of industrial districts in
Great Britain recurred in roughly the same manner in Italy after the Second World
War. A few scholars studied, with an open mind, the light industrialization that
was occurring in certain regions of Italy and, after taking a fresh look at
Marshall's theories, rediscovered the phenomenon of industrial districts. The
wealth of literature they produced soon gained attention outside of Italy. This
paper, however, does not dwell on what occurred outside of Italy; it focuses
instead on the development of the industrial district phenomenon and its
theoretical underpinnings in the Italian economy. In particular, it studies the link
between the industrial district system and the manufacture of typical made in Italy
products as it seeks to explain the competitive advantage that Italian
manufacturers enjoy in many industries (for example, textiles and garments,
footwear, furniture, etc.). The third part of the paper presents some of the most
recent developments in the study of Italian industrial districts.
The main point of the paper is that, for certain types of products, industrial
districts can provide a viable alternative to a system based on a single company
(with one or more plants) or a network of companies.
I I am very grateful to several colleagues and friends, most of all to Bellanca, Bellandi,
Groenewegen, Raffaelli, Dei Ottati and Sforzi for useful comments, but, as usual, I do not
want to imply that anyone of them shares all my views.
84 G. Bccattini
Marshall's writings around 18702 contain several statements that show clearly
how his position differed from the prevailing one among economists on certain
crucial aspects of the theory of production 3 . In particular, Marshall disputed the
standard view that the factory system, in which all manufacturing processes are
concentrated under one roof with a high degree of vertical integration, was
necessarily better than production systems that were technically less integrated but
concentrated geographicalll.
Reading the descriptions of English industry produced by his contemporaries,5
analyzing the most popular works on economics 6 and observing the world around
him with a keen eye 7 (for example, Sheffield's cutlery works and Birmingham's
metal trades), Marshall quickly came to the conclusion that, at least for certain
types of production, there were two efficient manufacturing systems: the
established method, based on large, vertically integrated production units, and a
second one based on the concentration of many small factories specializing in
different phases of the same production process and operated in one location or in
a cluster of locations.
"We shall find", wrote Alfred and Mary Marshall in their 1879 economic
manual 8, "that some of the advantages of division of labour can be obtained only
in very large factories, but that many of them, more than at first sight appears, can
be secured by small factories and workshops, provided there are a very great
number of them in the same trade.
The manufacture of a commodity often consists of several distinct stages, to
each of which a separate room in the factory is devoted. But if the total amount of
the commodity produced is very large, it may be profitable to devote separate
small factories to each of these steps. If there are many factories, large or small, all
engaged in the same process, Subsidiary Industries will grow up to meet their
. I wants 9 .
specla
But small factories, whatever their number, will be at a great disadvantage
relative to large unless many of them are collected together in the same district lO •
Thus both large and small factories are benefited ( ... ) (by the localization of
industry). But these benefits are most important to the small factories, and free
them from many of the disadvantages under which they would otherwise labour in
competition with large factories.
And finally: "in these districts a further division of specialisation has grown up,
and separate trades have sought separate localities ( ... ). Those that work in wool
do not generally live among the Lancashire cotton workers, but are collected
together in Yorkshire; and they themselves are divided into the "wollen trade" and
the "worsted trade", and these again spread out into various branches, each of
which has a favourite district of its own"ll.
Here Marshall, in addition to offering a phenomenological description of the
manufacturing district, provides some hints for a first, clear theoretical frame of
reference based on "benefits", which he later called "external economies,,12.
The most logical starting point for exploring the birth of the notion of industrial
districts in Marshall's early writings can be found in the economic debates that
raged when he made his debut as an economist (1871-1873) 13, especiall y those
that arose after the publication of J. S. Mill's Principles of Political Economy and
involved primarily J. E. Cairnes l4 and T. Cliffe Leslie. These authors had
9/bid., p. 52. This is the origin of the conceptual bifurcation leading on the one hand to the
manufacturing district and on the other to the industrial sector or to the industrialfiliere.
IOHere the territory is seen as a conduit for the creation and the dissemination of the
"advantages",
II/bid, p. 47.
12Notable studies that provide a historical framework for the development of Marshall's
concept of district include those by Bellandi (1982); Loasby (1998); Loasby, (1998); and
Raffaelli (forthcoming). See also, for a good background Loasby (1989).
I3Marshall's first theoretical economic work was an 1872 review of The Theory of Political
Economy (1871) by S.levons. See Pigou (1925), pp. 93-100.
14The essay containing Marshall's first serious theoretical work is a critique of Cairnes's
critique of 1. S. Mill, See Pigou (1925), pp. 119-133.
86 G. Becattini
discovered that the professional and territorial geographical mobility of labour and
capital postulated by classical economic theory did not exist - not even in England,
the promised land of classical economic laws. In practice, British social reality
was fragmented into regional, sectorial and social compartments, which hindered
the free circulation of capital and labour that was supposed to exist in theory. The
problem was then how to detect (or circumscribe) areas or groups of agents so as
to allow the to and fro between phenomena and theory required by an empirical
science like economics. Lacking such a methodological exploration, classical
economic theory would be left floating in mid-air. This explains the cruciality of
the theme of the "economic nation", which the young Marshall derived from the
theory of "non-competing groups" and developed into two separate versions 15.
In the first version, Marshall's "economic nation" is a place, or a system of
places, characterized by such a high degree of cultural homogeneity (values and
institutions), free circulation of information and territorial continuity that the
movement of capital and labour can quickly equalize profit and wage levels. One
could then say that any geographical area of this type constitutes a sort of
"economic nation", even when it does not become fully conscious of its autonomy
and does not develop a unified system of government. A "political" nation (the
usual nation-state) consists of a series of "economic" nations, and it is entirely
possible for an economic nation to straddle the borders of several political
nations l6 •
In the second version, an economic nation is a "block of subjects" within a
nation-state (e.g., miners and owners of coal mines, the farm lobby, etc.) or
encompassing several nation-states (e.g., the working class) who recognize that
their fundamental economic interests (or an important part of those interests)
coincide and are at variance with the interests of similar blocks in the same nation.
The knowledge awareness of a commonalty of economic interests interacts over
time with other non-economic aggregants to make these social bodies coalesce
into different forms and change over time the degree of their social cohesion.
This second type of "economic nation" also differs from the first 10 that it
always has a more or less explicit form of government and a more or less
complete and coherent "foreign policy", so to speak, on the basis of which it forms
alliances or engages in confrontations with similar groupsI7.
This also means that a dialectical interaction, the nature of which has yet to be
fully understood, entails the existence in every "economic nation" of the second
type not only of a contrast between the interests of masters and men but also of a
common aggregant that enables them to stand together against the rest of society.
This aggregant is not necessarily the same as the one that binds the inhabitants of
a certain area or the one that is presumed to hold together the international
working class, but is probably of the same type lR .
What is the general thrust of Marshall's effort [0 develop the notion of an
economic nation separate from the nation-state? In my opinion, it expresses
Marshall's refusal to derive the basic unit of economic research from real world
entities such as nation-states and provinces. In this sense, it is difficult to define a
nation as an empirical entity. Even the use of history or geography as a means of
classification entails an effort at conceptualization or abstraction that can be
conditioned by countless and undetermined historical and geographical influences.
The unit of research must be such as to facilitate an abstract-concrete-abstract
flow. The overall action of socioeconomic forces constantly defines and redefines
the unit of research, which is at any rate no less than some sort of "economic
nation", i.e., a plurality of individuals who feel more closely linked than is
generally the case, in a grouping that can fall under either the first or the second
definition, or bothl? I believe that one of the traits that most distinguishes
Marshall, even in the classification process, is the importance he attaches to
personal empowerment, i.e. his concern for the individual and his thought process,
without making claims of absolute objectivity. It may be worthwhile to emphasize
this point.
This point of view hints at the possibility of shifting the analytical approach
typically used by economists from the study of the behaviour of individuals in the
commodities markets 20 , the identification of which heavily conditions the
conclusions drawn from economic theory, to the study of the behaviours that are
typical of representative subjects. Obviously, this approach leads to human
groupings that are represented by a limited number of agents (e.g., the inhabitants
of a certain town) and/or enterprises (e.g., a "population" of firms). In my opinion,
if this different way of "slicing" or approaching social phenomena contemplated
by Marshall in his early writings had become established 21 , it would have yielded
18The only contemporary economist who has, to my knowledge, addressed this issue is Jan
Steedman, who also makes reference to Marshall in his essay, 1986. However, he does not
seem to have followed up on the new ideas presented in his essay.
19The modernity of this notion is clearly shown in the following passages by C. p.
Kindleberger: "The optimum social area is a function of the average citizen's sense of
participation, of having a share in decisions, of counting ( ... ). While the optimum economic
area may be large, the optimum social area is clearly much smaller ( ... ). Moreover while
the optimum scale of economic activity is getting larger and larger, the optimum social
scale appears to be shrinking". Kindleberger (1989), pp. 87-88.
2°In this area, see Lange (1952), Appendix, who writes: "In economic science, however, the
classification of goods cannot be made on a purely arbitrary basis, because the laws of
economics would then be dependent on the particular classification adopted. This would
restrict the significance of the propositions of economics to a degree that would make them
useless".
21Marshall, pressured by a mainstream economics that was moving in a totally different
direction, did not have the will, or the strength, to follow this approach to its ultimate
88 G. Becattini
Alfred Marshall's ability to see districts where everyone else saw mere industrial
agglomerations, or, in other words, his willingness to apply Smith's notion of the
division of labour to entities other than the world, a nation-state or a factory (for
example, Smith's pin factory), is deeply rooted in the classifications of capitalism
developed whiie he was still young.
While this is not the place to discuss this point in detail, a few brief remarks and
references seem to be in order.
There are at least two core theoretical problems - we understood this only
recentl/ 3 - with the notion of district: the first, already mentioned, concerns
economic nations and the second, perhaps more profound, is rooted in the studies
of the human mind carried out by Marshall during his younger years. The "district
anomaly", as I like to call the complex of ideas that gravitate around the notion of
industrial district 24 , contains a transparent reference to the social and dynamic
concept wherein the process of growth of human intellectual abilities is the
specific engine that drives the human aspects of natural history. Marshall believed
that humans evolved mainly through work and, therefore, evolved differently in
different organizational and social contexts 25 • His industrial atmosphere, for
instance, is more than just the product of an uninhibited observation of the facts. It
is also a symbol of Marshall's notion of natural sociability of man and of the
historical roots of a social process that is simultaneously a process of production
of commodities and of the associated social change. In the final analysis, this
localized process is nothing more than a "fragment" of social life, taken at a given
point in time and space and viewed from the standpoint of the need to meet other
historically perceived human needs.
As opposed to dogmatic economists, who on the one hand refused to give up the
"wage fund" theory and on the other were blinded by the economies of scale and
the factory system 26 , Marshall showed with a concrete example (the district
formula) that there was already, in practice at least, one necessary alternative or
perhaps a complement to the esosomatic increase in the productivity27 (more and
better machines per capita) of individual workers, i.e., an "endosomatic" increase
in productivity achieved by paying attention to values and knowledge that enhance
the compositeness of the place with which the worker himself "identifies".
Another characteristic of Marshall's analysis that dates to his early work is a
dialectic juxtaposition of routines and organizational innovations in the broad
sense, duplicating a framework the rools of which can be traced to Marshall's
early reflections on the workings of the human mind. Society, in a manner not
significantly different from the human mind, alternates routine behaviour with
innovative behaviour, which, if successful, becomes in turn routine, freeing new
energies for innovation 28 .
In this way, Marshall shifts the focus of economic analysis from the esosomatic
means of production (equipment, facilities, canals, railroads, etc.), which
incorporate routines and are acquirable and cumulable, to individual, endosomatic
tools, such as the intellectual potential of the human mind, which are constantly
open to innovation and are inseparable from their carrier, and to collective assets,
such as social, local or sectorial capital, which by their very nature cannot be
appropriated because the~ consist of delicate and shifting networks of
interpersonal relationships 2 • This position inadvertently created a wide chasm
between Marshall and mainstream economists, both classical and marginalists. It
also caused Marshall's thinking to move further away from Marx's notion of the
capitalist production system, which placed excessive emfhasis on the separation
between workers and the "material" means of production 3 .
26Conservative and a few "progressive" economists bow reverently before the so called
wages fund theory. Marx, who is not fooled by this lrick, accepts acritically - as history
later demonstrated - the claims of those who sang the praise of the factory system and the
economies of scale. In my opinion, this view of Marx's, which anticipates Fordism. harbors
the early roots of the failure of centralized economic planning.
27This distinction comes from the writings of Georgescu Roegen. See Georgescu Roegen
(1966), pp. 98-99.
28See Raffaelli (1994). But also his forthcoming (Routledge 2002) book on Marshall.
29Marshall speaks of "social credit". See Marshall (1919), Chap. IX, 1.
30It is interesting how today's crisis of Fordist capitalism, which lent itself better to a
Marxian analysis, gives new significance to the viewpoint proposed by Marshall in this
area.
90 G. Becattini
In his work, Marshall differentiates between two types of districts: one that
represents an evolution of the "centres of specialized skills" from the pre-
industrial age and another created intentionally and in an organized fashion as the
result of the spillover of some manufacturing and craft activities from the
industrial cities typical of English capitalism at the end of the nineteenth century.
In the first case, of which Sheffield, with its long iron-working tradition, is a
perfect example, the key feature is the interdependence between technical-
economic issues and the underlying sociocultural relationships. It is a long and
complex process in which a steady flow of socioeconomic innovations leads to a
process whereby the most efficient ones are consolidated into institutions 31 .
The second case foreshadows, in embryonic form, the role of public policy in the
formation of manufacturing districts. In a paper that became the manifesto of the
Society for Promoting Industrial Villages, which was close to the Garden City
Movement, of which, significantly, Marshall was a member, he supported "the
formation of a colony in some place well beyond the range of London smoke ( ... ).
The work of several firms, not always in the same business, might in some cases
be sent together. Gradually a prosperous industrial district would grow up, and
then self-interest would induce employers to bring down their main workshops,
and even to start factories in the colony ( ... ). It is only the first step that costs;
every succeeding step would be easier,,32.
In conclusion, Marshall's vision of the manufacturing district is not just the
concentration of manufacturing activity in a given territory (the clustering or
networking of businesses referred to by many economists today) that results from
the "natural" development of market automatisms 33 . In Marshall's vision,
economic and socio-cultural phenomena are fused into a single conceptual block,
paving the way for the implementation of cogent public policies 34 .
To better understand the "district anomaly", we must consider briefly some of its
implications in terms of the understanding of the concept of industrialization 35 . If
the "district anomaly" had succeeded, industrial capitalism would have been
understood as having not just one development path based on accumulation and
technical progress, with firms of increasingly large average size combined in
increasingly concentrated industries (as most of the economists of the time
thought and almost all later economists would continue to believe for a long time),
but of mUltiple paths (at least two), one of which would have produced territorial
agglomerations of medium-size and small firms.
An early understanding of the existence of "multiple paths to industrialization",
which, by crisscrossing and cross-pollinating each other, coexist over time, could
have had far-reaching consequences. I will just mention a few of them: a) an
understanding of the persistence and success of independent forms of employment
and small businesses 36 in certain industries would have refuted the mechanistic
extrapolation that industrial capitalism produces a social polarization between the
two classes of owners and proletarians 37 ; b) a denial of the view that capitalism
leads to the creation of a few megalopolises would have helped focus territorial
studies toward a plurality of alternative models of territorial agglomeration; c) the
assumption that there is a plurality of interactive commonalities between
manufacturing activity and everyday human life would have refuted the vision of a
manufacturing system increasingly enclosed inside the factory and/or secluded in
"industrial quarters" that exploits and upsets the balance of surrounding socio-
cultural and natural resources 38 ; and d) a refusal of the "easy" view, supported by
socialist critics of capitalism, that the trend toward the technical, economic and
financial concentration of the manufacturing sector paves the way toward a
generalized shift from private to public property, would have spared humanity
some painful disappointments 39 •
The fundamental question raised by Marshall in his early writings about which
basic unit is best suited for a correct economic analysis casts doubts on the
acritical acceptance of de Jacto empirical compartmentalisations - such as the
concept of nation-state at a given time in history - and paves the way for the
Toward the end of the 1960s, many years after Marshall's death in 1924, a few
Italian economists detected some interesting developments. In particular: a) in
certain regions of Italy (Tuscany, for example)43 where large private and public-
sector companies in capital-intensive and/or high-tech industries were showing
clear signs of weakness, there was a "strange" bloom of small manufacturing
businesses, which produced increases in local income, jobs and exports 44 ; and b)
the small companies included in these clusters were adequately equipped on a
technical level - at least as well as their large competitors were - to do the things
they were doing45. These two observations were "scandalous" for those who
believed in the then dominant economic theories. As a result, for several years the
scientific and political communities dismissed these businesses as precarious and
Let us start with a general question: under what conditions can industrial districts
nourish and when do these conditions occur? These conditions can be divided into
two groups: "local supply" conditions and "general demand" conditions.
The local supply conditions include "the existence of countries that, throughout
the classical period of industrialization and the First and Second World War,
retained in some parts of their territory: a) sufficient cultural complexity, made up
of values, knowledge, institutions and behaviours ( ... ) that elsewhere had been
pushed aside by a generally industrial and massifying culture, and a manufacturing
system that included factories, craft or artisan workshops, home workers and
family production units; and b) a credit system ( ... ) ready to finance small but
promising businesses and help people use their increasing amount of spare time to
produce goods that could be sold in the marketplace,,46.
The general demand conditions include the progress, in many countries, of large
segments of the middle class beyond the normal standard of comfort found in each
of these countries 47 . Progress beyond this standard creates the conditions for the
emergence of new sets of needs with a high social and "qualitative" content that
produce a highly variable demand for differentiated and personalized goods.
The combined impact of this twin set of conditions undermined the advantages
of large factories, consisting primarily of internal economies of scale in the
production of standardized goods and continuous production processes (i.e.,
processes that could not be broken up into phases), favoring instead smaller
factories with stronger ties to the surrounding community, where people worked
separately in a limited number of phases of a common (to the industrial district)
complex process. When there is an adequate "industrial atmosphere", that includes
both technical knowledge and "commercial morality", the shift from an
environment characterized mainly by hierarchical relationships between
departments - as they exist within a large enterprise - to one dominated by
transactions between independent firms (where the existing inequalities tend to
diminish and eventually, for the successful ones, to disappear) creates a positive
trust differential 48 between the participants that lowers the overall cost of the
cluster's production 49 .
Whenever these two sets of conditions come into existence in a situation
dominated by manufacturing in its industrial or preindustrial state, the district
form of production becomes relatively stronger so .
In a nutshell, my conclusion is this: Italy, during its "economic miracle" phase,
when it was part of a rapidly expanding Western world, saw the development of
conditions similar to those experienced by many British cities and towns during
the first great expansion spawned by the industrial revolution. In both cases, a
long and socially unequal income expansion concentrated wealth in the pockets of
a large segment of the middle class, who, having achieved the current standard of
comfortS I, sought increasingly differentiated and personalized goods and services
as a means of experiencing "new sensations" and achieving social prestige.
Endless series of standardized objects became increasingly less attractive to this
new, affluent class, whose demand was increasingly fragmented and variable.
These developments on the "real" side marked the birth, or rebirth, of a "new"
theory of industrial districts.
48Something of the same kind of the already mentioned marshallian "social credit".
49Marshall pointed out that the "scholastic" concept of production costs for a single product
was not realistic. A study of the production process as part of the industrialization process
inevitably leads to the conclusion that an analysis of intermediate and long-term
development must take into account the web of cost wnjunctions and connections. See
Marshall (1919), Book II, Chap. I.
50Naturally, this can be understood only if there is an economic theory that identifies this
phenomenon. Districts can be nourishing in the real world, but the prevailing theory can
fail to recognize them. It is here, at the dialectic intersection between phenomena and
theory, that the decisive importance of Marshall's break with classical orthodoxy and
neoclassical economic theory becomes fully apparent.
511n Victorian times it meant: home with garden, nice living room possibly with Morris's
wall paper, sons at the public school, etc.; in post-war Italy: town nat, home appliances,
car, vacations, etc.
From Marshall's to the Italian "Industrial Districts". A Brief Critical Reconstruction 95
52F. Pyke and W. Sengenberger called this the "high road" to economic development, as
opposed to the "low road," which is based on exploitation. See Pyke and Sengenberger
(1992). In view of the decisive role it played in going to the roots of the industrial district
issue and publicizing it internationally, I must also mention the International Labour
Organisation (ILO) research program, The New Industrial Organization, which was
launched in 1986 and coordinated by W. Sengenberger, with the initial support of M. 1.
Piore. It produced several books: from: Pyke, Becattini and Sengenberger (1990),
Cossentino, Pyke and Sengenberger (1996).
53 1 am referring to the dispute about costs originated from a famous Clapham's article. See
Clapham (1922a). See also Clapham (1922b).
541 am referring to the area of research stemming from Pigou (1920).
55The first work where, to my knowledge, internal and external economies started again to
perform the function envisioned by Marshall in his early works is: Istituto Regionale
Programmazione Economica della Toscana - IRPET (1969). Republished in: Becattini
(1999), pp. 116-146.
56 1 am afraid I may have overlooked some of the other paths that led to the notion of
industrial clusters, and I apologize to the colleagues whose names I did not mention. I will
provide a more complete analysis on another occasion. However, I would like to mention
several books on this subject that will give the reader a fuller picture of this issue: Garofoli
(1983); Becattini (1987); Brusco (1989); Gobbo (1989); Pyke, Becattini, and Sengenberger
(1991); Nuti (1992), 2 voll; Onida, Viesti and Falzoni (1992); Bellandi and Russo (1994);
Dei Ottati (1995); Brusco and Paba (1997); Varaldo and Ferrucci (1997); Belfanti and
Maccabelli (1997); Cora and Rullani (1998); Becchetti, Belussi and Gottardi (2000);
Tattara (2001); Becattini, Bellandi, Dei Ottati and Sforzi (2001), which includes a rich
bibliography. The literature is much vaster but I think that the works mentioned above point
the way to most of the Italian and foreign work on industrial districts.
96 G. Becattini
applying his analysis to the industrial phenomena of the Emilia Romagna Region,
Brusco developed the concept of industrial district without the aid of external-
internal economies and despite what I like to call the handicap of his Sraffian
background57 .
At the beginning of the 1990s, a major research project carried out by Michael
Porter and a group of associates 58 opened a new approach to understanding the
issues of manufacturing systems. Drawing on an in-depth analysis of world
commerce, Porter discovered, (especially in Italy but in other countries as well),
the existence of territorial clusters of small businesses that had gained significant
competitive advantages in relatively important niches in the world trade for
manufactured goods (textiles, garments, footwear, leather goods, furniture,
decorative tiles, etc.). These advantages were achieved despite the initial
technological superiority of industrial giants and the lower relative labour costs of
other competitors. How could this development be explained? In a series of
papers59, Porter and his collaborators refined the concept of business cluster,
giving it a form that closely resembled that of Marshall's industrial district. The
prestige of the center of learning where these analyses were carried out - the
Harvard Business School - and the fact that Porter's conclusions were in tune with
the views prevailing at the time - i.e., that business competitiveness is at the centre
of everything - paved the way for acceptance of the concept of business clusters in
mainstream economics and forced average economists to take a new look at the
notion of industrial districts, which until then they had found methodologically
troubling.
In Italy, this convergence of conclusions - the efficiency of local systems
claimed by the supporters of industrial districts and the competitive advantages
pointed out by Porter - led to the development of a new area of research that
focused on those products that are emblematic of Italian exports. A number of
Italian scholars (Marco Fortis, Giuliano Conti, Stefano Menghinello and others)60
sought to verify, expand and consolidate the theme, which Porter had touched on
only briefly, of the relationship between industrial districts and the success of
Italian exports. Fortis's work helped bring into focus certain industries that
57Why do I use the word "handicap"? Because the entire edifice of Sraffa's theories is
designed to prevent the entry of the entrepreneurial contribution in the core of economic
theory. It is truly remarkable how Brusco, starting from these premises, developed the
concept of industrial clusters, which are genuine incubators of the entrepreneurial spirit.
Brusco's approach to the problem is described in some detail in Brusco (1989). Peter
Groenewegen remindered to me that Maurice Dobb read a paper, in 1923, on "The
entrepreneur myth", to the economic Section of the Cambridge Club The Heretics.
58See Porter (1989).
59See Porter (1999).
60See e.g. Bagella and Becchetti (2000).
From Marshall's to the Italian "Industrial Districts". A Brief Critical Reconstruction 97
manufacture typical Italian exports, concluding that they represent a true "system
of manufacturing sectors and sub-sectors" that are interdependent and specialize in
the production of household and personal goodS 61 . Conti and Menghinel\o studied
the relationship between export performance and territorial concentration in detail,
consolidating and expanding Porter's conclusions 62 . Becattini and Menghinello
sought to identify, within the general universe of "made in Italy" products
classified by industrial sector), a core group of products manufactured in industrial
districts that represent the cutting edge of Italian exports 63 .
1ST AT, the Italian statistical institute, with a vital contribution from Fabio Sforzi,
divided Italy into local systems64 that included 199 industrial districts 65 . This
permitted a comparison of the many different characteristics that distinguish
district areas from non-district areas. The most important product of the studies
carried out in this area was an econometric study coordinated by Luigi Federico
Signorini for the Research Department of the Bank of Italy that confirmed the
existence of many of the relationships that are typical of the "theory of industrial
districts,,66.
Two institutions also came into existence at this time: a) the Club dei Distretti
(1996), without permanent headquarters, which sought to represent the interests of
industrial districts vis-a-vis public authorities at all levels, from local municipal
governments to the European Union and the WTO, and b) an Industrial Districts
Observatory, which was established in Milan (1997) through a collaborative effort
of Montedison Economic Research and Innovation Department and the Research
Centre in Economic Analysis, International Economics and Economic
Development (CRANEC) of Universita Cattolica, joined in 1999 by Fondazione
Comunita e Innovazione 67 .
The recognition of the heuristic usefulness of the concept of industrial district and,
consequently, of the empirical existence of groups of phenomena that could be
effectively analyzed with such a tool (this happened more or less at the beginning
of the 1990s) was followed by a sort of terminological explosion: from the notion
of "industrial district" to system area, to local production system, to milieu
innovateur, to cluster and so on. This is not the place to review such immense and
varied literature, nor would it be useful to lump often heterogeneous concepts. I
shall just explain the path that I followed with some of my associates.
Instead of starting with a model developed by finding similarities with (and
differences from) other well-known types of manufacturing system organizations
(for example, industrial poles), which could have been restrictive and distortive of
new emerging phenomena, our group began with the assumption that, since
industrial districts follow their own peculiar productive and reproductive logic, an
understanding of their development could come only from an in-depth study of an
industrial district in action over a sufficiently extended period of time. Having
determined that Prato was an industrial district - perhaps the archetype of all
industrial districts - we concluded that a study of the Prato district would yield
significant insights into the anatomy and physiology of all of the industrial
districts 68 .
What did we find in this industrial cluster?
First of all, a population of families and businesses interacting with each other
in various ways within a well-defined territory. Looking more closely, we
discovered that the businesses could be broken down into different populations
working on different production phases of production (spinning, weaving, dyeing,
finishing, etc.)69 organized in flexible teams 70 normally headed by a finished
goods manufacturer (e.g. wool fabric mill, or impannatore) that interacted with the
external market. The labour and consumption behaviour of the families was
divided, more or less, along lines that reflected their position within the local
manufacturing process (industrial entrepreneurs and craftsmen, regular employees,
"textile sharecroppers" tradesmen, etc.).
More importantly, we were surprised to discover that the prices of semifinished
goods were determined by a system that on the one hand pegged prices to the
same (or practically the same) goods found elsewhere in the world and on the
other set prices that were strictly related to the standard of living and social status
of the main categories of families living in the district. Because of their impact on
the income of crucial socio-economic groups within the district, the relative prices
of processing tasks played a major role, together with wages levels and the profits
earned by finished-good manufacturers, In determining the system's
compatibilities.
68See Dei Ottati (1995); Bellandi and Trigilia (1991), n. 70, pp. 121-152; Becattini (2000b).
69Por an early assessment of production-phase businesses and their development after the
Second World War, see: Lazzeretti and Storai (1999).
70See Ciappei and Mazzetti (1996).
From Marshall's to the Italian "Industrial Districts". A Brief Critical Reconstruction 99
The upshot of all this is that there must be a close, generally reproductive,
overlap between a block of economic and production relationships, occurring
within a spatially defined area, and another block, also spatially defined, of socio-
cultural relationships 71.
The next step, which is perhaps not yet fully understood, is the definition of the
synergies and antagonisms between the two engines of the Italian economy: large
and medium-size businesses in leadership positions and industrial districts 72 .
The research coordinated by Signorini that I mentioned earlier confirmed
independently and with completely different methods the concrete existence and
relevance of the relationships discussed above. It also went even further, agreeing
with a conclusion of the staunchest supporters of the district theory, who say that
the unit of research that is best suited to industrial economics is not the individual
firm, but a group of firms, possibly located within the same territory73, a statement
that clearly entails major theoretical implications.
3 VVork in Progress
3.1. From the Study of the District as Such to the Study of the Forms
of the Industrialization Process
This phase in the analysis of industrial districts opens at least two alternatives: we
either carry out an in-depth study of industrial districts as the basic unit of
research, with the goal of isolating its component parts (for example,
manufacturing system, institutional network, system of values, etc.) and seeing
how they are connected within the "local system", or move to the next level of
research, seeking those processes the combined operation of which determines
whether a certain territorial distribution of a manufacturing system is or is not
approaching the district form. I started by pursuing the first avenue 74 , but, seeing
that it led to a sort of frenetic "district hunt" in space and time, with a plenty of
"bastard" districts and an excess of taxonomic qUibbling 75 , I decided to attempt
dissecting the district phenomenon into several distinct processes that were
convergent at birth, parallel during their lifetime and divergent when the district
dissolved.
I identified the following processes: a) a gradual, targeted and self-contained
subdi vision of certain production processes and of other complementary and
ancillary processes; b) the formation and multiplication over time of dynamic
links between "complexes of specialized production skills" developed in specific
territorial settings and "nuclei of needs" that emerge from the general panorama of
needs 76 ; c) the sedimentation of social practices into formal and informal, tangible
and immaterial institutions that at the same time protect both competitiveness and
the social and naturalistic reproducibility of tht: local system; d) the dynamic
integration of contextual production expertise77 , which is often implied, with
codified scientific/technical expertise into the manufacturing process; e) the
development of figures and institutions (versatile integrators) that serve as
mediators between the contrasting needs of specialization and versatility; f) the
formation, consolidation, decay and dissolution of the "sense of belonging" among
the individual agents of social production; and, finally, g) constant support for
local social and professional mobility.
which is obtained by an intensive use of the existing know-how and the ability to
acquire new know-how, However, this characteristic is also the source of the
district's biggest problem: the need to find increasingly large outlets for its output.
Like capital, the industrial district either increases or perishes.
The increasing "articulation" of the main process is also important because it
permits an inter-penetration of the production process and of the daily life of the
reference community, which constitutes one of the most distinctive peculiarities of
the "district-type method of production". It is because of this peculiarity that the
"surplus" time, know-how and work energy that the local production process
generates "as it runs" tind within the same process new economic spaces and
relative competition gaps, which they can fill. By constantly evolving internally,
the production process of an expanding district creates the means of monetizing
many kinds of resources by transforming them into goods and services that can be
sold at a profit. At the same time, it embeds in the individual and collective know-
how, which can be put to new uses, the manufacturing and marketing experiences
that proved to be successful 82 ,
Viewed from this perspective, the increasing subdivision into phases, the
induction of collateral processes, the formation of open (but with a district bias)
teams of specialized businesses, the birth of markets within the cluster and of an
embryonic "local price system" are different aspects of the same process: the
gradual formation - concurrently with the unfolding of a "typical" multiphase
production process that involves a large number of autonomous, spatially
contiguous agents - of an organic plurality of local institutions centered on a grid
of local markets for semifinished goods (e.g., yarns, fabrics, etc.), new and used
equipment, and manufacturing processes (e.g., dyeing, finishing, etc.).
However, it would be impossible to understand the formation of this plexus of
internal markets, pivoting around a unique "district market" for human resources,
without also taking into account the coalescing around these markets of formal
(e.g" craftsmen's associations, unions, interest groups, technical schools,
institutions, the ultimate function of which is building in every potential
specialized contributor the confidence that he will be able to sell his specialty
easily and at a remunerative price. This local confidence-building process is just
the other side of the formation of a web of local and external markets.
free to find new customers for whom to work whenever conditions allow it and
make it convenient.
In other words, an entrepreneur cannot ask his partners (workers and
subcontractors) to exert themselves excessively to help grow, or rescue, his
business when it is clear that at the first opportunity he would fire an employee
ancIJor change a supplier. In an "ideal-type district", the situation is different
because: a) the production cost of a "representative team" of firms depends
"intelligibly" on the overall functioning of the local society, which is affected to a
significant degree by the decisions (zoning, waste treatment facilities, highways,
etc.) of democratically elected officials; and b) both the "representative" worker
and subcontractor have a good understanding of the overall economic conjuncture
of the "district system". In other words, district workers and subcontractors are
well aware that they are not powerless vis-a.-vis their terminal businesses, whose
quest for cheaper labour is limited, in the environment outside the district, only by
competition. These conditions provide a basis for a genuine and realistic
negotiating process 83 . It is as if inside the heads of the representatives of the
different parties there was a common simplified model of how the cluster operates
that defines, for every degree of integration, the allowed margin of fluctuation for
the average wage and price of each phase operation. This margin is relatively
narrow and each of the parties will be careful not to destroy, together with the
opposing party, their golden opportunity (provided that this is their perception),
i.e., the opportunity to live in a "district-type local system" where a widespread
competitive attitude is mitigated by the presence of relationships based on
interfirm cooperation, good information and reciprocal dependence among
operators 84 .
3.4. Summing It Up
Going back to our starting point, we can say that Marshall, in his early works, was
right to question the compatibility of increasing returns, which in turn engender
cumulative processes, with an economic theory centered on a model of static
equilibrium. We can also say that Marshall was perhaps wrong when, later in life,
he failed to bring his basic intuitions to their ultimate conclusions 85 •
The overall and, obviously, remote goal of the approach to industrial
phenomena here suggested is to look for self-reproducing organizational forms of
the societal production process that are defined, in each case, by a combination of
processes as specified in 3.1. The industrial district is the self-reproducing form
that Italian economic reality has placed before our eyes, but nothing prevents us
from thinking that others may exist.
83Gabi Dei Ottati started to reseatch this issue in Dei Ottati (2001).
84This reminds much some expressions of Kindleberger's analysis.
85 The position of Marshall on the issue in 1906 can be seen in: Raffaelli (1996) n. 1. I
examine more extensively the issue in a forthcoming paper: Becattini (2001).
From Marshall's to the Italian "Industrial Districts". A Brief Critical Reconstruction 103
In other words, the ultimate unit of analysis for the study of change is not
necessarily the industrial district, but an entity that changes with the overall
change, yet, up to a certain point, remains the same. If we pursue this path of
research to its conclusion, we will end up, I guess, not with a mosaic of markets
for homogeneous and clearly defined commodities, searching for irrelevant, or
impossible, equilibria, between supply and demand which change of "meaning"
with the qualitative change of the commodity, but with areas of convergence
(temporary but relatively stable) between economic and socio-cultural processes.
These are the meso-socioeconomic units that we need.
References
Pyke, F., Becattini, G. and Scngenberger, W. (1990), Industrial Districts and Inter-firm
Cooperation in Italy, Geneva, IlLS.
Pyke, F., Becattini, G. and Sengenberger, W. (1991), Distretti industriali e cooperazion€
fra imprese in Italia, Firenze, Banca Toscana.
Raffaelli, T. (1994), "Alfred Marshall's Early Philosophical Writings", in: Research in the
History of Economic Thought and Methodology, Samuels, W. (ed.) London, JAI Press.
Raffaelli, T. (1994), "Alfred Marshall's Early Philosophical Writings", in: Research in the
History of Economic Thought and Methodology, Samuels, W. (ed.), London, JAI Press.
forthcoming (Routledge, 2002) book on Marshall
Raffaelli, T. (1996), "La formazione di Keynes nel laboratorio marshalliano", Rivista
ltaliana degli Economisti, n. 1.
Raffaelli, T. (forthcoming), II concetto di distretto industriale nel sistema teorico di Alfred
Marshall, Sviluppo Locale.
Sargant, W. L (1857), Economy of the Labouring Classes, London, Simpkin, Marshall and
Co.
Sforzi, F.(1989), "The Geography of Industrial Districts in Italy", in: Small Firms and
Industrial Districts in Italy, Goodman, E.and Bamford, 1. with Saynor, P. (eds), London,
Routledge, pp. 153-173.
Sforzi, F.(1994), "The Tuscan Model: an Interpretation in Light of Recent Trends", in:
Regional Development in a Modem European Economy: The Case of Tuscany, Leonardi,
Rand Nanetti, R. Y. (eds), London, Pinter.
Sforzi, F. (2000), "Local Development in the Experience of Italian Industrial Districts", in:
Geographies of Diversity. Italian Perspectives, Cori, B. et aL (eds), Roma, CNR, pp.
133-156.
Signorini, L F. (2000), Lo sviluppo locale. Un 'indagine della Banca d'Italia sui distretti
industriali, Roma, Meridiana Libri.
Solinas, G. (1993), "Competenze, grandi imprese e distretti industriali. II caso Magneti
Marelli", Rivista di Storia Economica, n. I, pp. 79-111.
Sraffa, P. (1998), "On the Relations Between Cost and Quantity Produced", in: Italian
Economic Papers, Pasinetti, L L (cd.), voL III, Bologna, II Mulino.
Steedman, J. (1986), 'Trade Interest versus Class Interest", EL'onomia Politica, August.
Tattara, G, (cd.) (2001), II piccolo che nasce dal grande. Le molteplici facce dei distretti
industriali veneti, Milano, Franco Angeli,
Varaldo, R. and Ferrucci, L (eds) (1997), II distretto industriale tra logiche di impresa e
logiche di sistema, Milano, Franco Angeli.
Whitaker, J. (1975), "Some Features of American Industry" in: Early Economic Writings of
Alfred Marshall, London and New York, Macmillan, 2 1lu voL, pp. 355-376
Whitaker, 1. (1975), Early Ecomonic Writings of Alfred Marshall, London, Macmillan, 2
vols.
Young, A. (1928), "Increasing Returns and Economic Progress", Economic Journal,
pp.527-542.
Diversity, Not Specialization:
The Ties That Bind the (New) Industrial District
Charles F. Sabel
Abstract. Whatever they are exactly, industrial districts are also a worldly success
and a conceptual innovation. In Italy, the map of district agglomerations of small
and medium-sized firms specializing in particular branches of light industry is no
longer limited to the triangle marked by Venice, Florence, and Ancona in the
Adriatic Marches. New agglomerations are spreading, as though by contagion,
down the shores of the Adriatic and the Mediterranean, now and again obstructed
in their march south by the detritus of failed, heavy industrial complexes. Quite
apart from this expansion of the districts' homeland, district-like agglomerations
are emerging in some patches of the South of Italy. Looking at the economic map
of Europe, the economic agronomist sees a "hot banana" of thriving districts
curving from London, through Switzerland and the Southwest of Germany into
Northern Italy. In the developing economies districts are identified as a motor of
growth in countries as different as Chile, Brazil, and India.
The advance of the industrial district as a concept has at least kept pace with its
progress in fact. Discussion of economic growth in both the advanced and
developing countries is dominated by what is often called the Washington
consensus - concern for opening economies to free trade, getting exchange rates
and other prices right, and (lately) building the institutions needed to do this. But
insofar as it is not, debate gravitates toward the creation and expansion of
"clusters" - the business name for districts. In the European Union in particular
fostering clusters is often seen as a way of encouraging economic competitiveness
without giving in to US pressure to give markets free reign. In theoretical debates
about economic growth and international trade too agglomerations, often
explicitly identified with districts, have come to playa central role (although. as
we shall see, with surprisingly subversive effects).
Why. then, are the districts prospering and diffusing? What explains their success
in today's volatile and rapidly changing markets'? Surprisingly - or not, you be the
judge - there is no compelling answer to such brusque and elementary questions.
Not that familiarity with the subject has dulled curiosity about its causes. Rather, I
suspect the fruitfulness of the district idea as a research agenda and as a policy
tool has dulled incentives to inquire too closely into the consistency and
generalizability of the sustaining ideas. Concepts that both allow exploration of
economic forms uncognizable in the light of standard theories of the firm and
108 C. F. Sabel
Notice that this craft version of the district economy is largely self-governing in
the sense of (almost) proof against opportunism or self-seeking guile, and for
related reasons expansively self-reinforcing. The governance of opportunism is a
limited problem because the artisans' skills are largely complementary.
Homogeneous viewed from the outside, they are highly differentiated in their own
view, with micro-specializations - the use of a particular kind of loom or lathe -
that make most of their colleagues into potential partners rather than rivals. To be
sure, even partners are rivals when it comes to the distribution of the gains to
cooperation; but such rivalry is disciplined in explicit partnerships and in the craft
districts by the recognition of the mutual dependence. Socialization into the
community of craft knowledge, and the sense of dignified competition for the
respect of ones' peers that goes with it, echoes the conclusions of prudent
calculation. So it proves relatively easy to establish institutions to police the wage
cutting and substitution of shoddy materials that, in hard times, tempt strapped
producers to defend their individual livelihoods at the price of jeopardizing the
stability and reputation of the district ensemble.
This craft model of the district is naturally expansive: given that skills are fixed
in a community and a community in a place, the more specialized the district, the
more it attracts similarly specialized resources. Alfred Marshall is famous today
not least for having seen this connection. In craft communities, he noted, looking
to the metalworking agglomeration of the Birmingham of his day, the "mysteries"
of a trade are "in the air". Youngsters learn them before they are fully conscious of
learning at all, let alone investing in their human capital. Once acquired, the skills
become a local resource, attracting outsiders who need in some sense to
incorporate themselves into the community to benefit from what it can do only
where it is. Today we would say there are positive returns to specialization.
Marshall put it this way:
When an industry has thus chosen a location for itself, it is likely to stay
there long: so great are the advantages which people following the same
skilled trade get from near neighbourhood to one another .... A localized
industry gains a great advantage from the fact that it offers a constant
market for skill .... Employers are apt to resort to any place where they are
likely to find a good choice of workers with the special skill which they
require; while men seeking employment naturally go to places where there
are many employers who need such skills as theirs and where therefore it is
likely [they will] find a good market (Marshall cited in Fujita 2000, p.lO.
See also of course Becattini 1990).
The craft model of the small-firm district connects to large-firm settings by two
routes; and it is useful to consider these briefly to see the full reach of the
assumptions of specialization and taciturnity on current discussion of innovation
and flexibility. The more direct, but also more parochial connection is simply that
in some cases large firms are an assembly of craft shops under one corporate or
physical roof. This is notably so in Germany, where large firms did not specialize
in the mass production of standard consumer goods (cigarettes, packaged cereal,
cars). Instead they traditionally manufacture customized producers or investment
Diversity, Not Specialization: The Ties That Bind the (New) Industrial District I II
goods: for example, the complex machine tools that mass producers use in their
own factories to turn out long runs of a single make or model of product. Workers
are largely autonomous in the same way, and by virtue of a similar (though more
formal) experience of apprenticeship as artisans in their small firms. Because the
firm is large, it can provide itself with many of the support services provided by
the institutional exoskeleton in the craft district. But familiar collective action
problems - especially fear that trained workers will be poached away from firms
where they apprenticed by firms that provide no training at all - require that here,
too, the community character of specialized skill is formally acknowledged and
protected against tragedies of the commons.
The second connection to large firms is via the school of evolutionary or neo-
Schumpeterian economics (for the fans et origo see Schumpeter 1926). It is less
obvious but broader in reach than the first, and shows that the idea of specialized,
tacit knowledge need not be associated with the notion of craft in any familiar
sense at all. One key assumption of this school is that large firms are configured
not as (nearly) self-organizing communities of producers, but rather as hierarchies.
The peak of the hierarchy fixes a master plan, including rules for partitioning that
plan into executable tasks. Successive tiers of superiors then actually decompose
the tasks into finer and finer jobs for their respective subordinates. This is
specialization by task. Because it is disconnected from any systematic exploration
of tools or materials it is disconnected from, even antithetic to specialization by
craft. A second assumption is that the partitioning of the rules by which complex
projects are subdivided and the rules by which the outputs of the partitioned tasks
are aggregated into useful wholes are never comprehensive and unambiguous
enough to cover all contingencies. The written rules therefore have to be
supplemented and corrected by informal, lived experience of how to actually get
things done in the organization. This is tacit knowledge. But it is tacit knowledge
at least as much of process and organization as of substance: of the routines that
define a firm and enable it to execute as a collective tasks that employees could
not manage if they needed to think both about their work and how to link it with
the efforts of others.
Unlike the craft model district, the tacitly routinized large firm faces substantial
governance problems and is not inherently expansive. The governance problem
arises from the fact that the firm's assets, physical and human, are specialized to
work most efficiently with each other as provided in the master plan. Their value
in alternative arrangement - in conjunction that is, with assets not specialized
according to the same plan - is close to zero. Hence the hold up problem: suppose
a power-plant owner and a coal-mine owner agree respectively to build a power
plant and dig a coal mine that are co-located and otherwise specialized to each
other. Whoever invests first is at the mercy of the other, who can withhold the
complementary investment until the dupe agrees to redistribute the benefits of the
venture in favour of the knave. The solution of course is for the one owner to
make both investments (with the one better positioned to use the whole effectively
taking control). This vertical integration formally closes the large firm in on itself
in a way that contrasts with the - formal - openness of the craft districts.
112 C. F. Sabel
With such closure comes another kind of self-limitation. All the crucial aspects
of large-firm operation have to be under exclusive control of a single owner, and
the exercise of control becomes more expensive as the complexity of what is
controlled increases. Firms therefore do not benefit from the positive returns to
agglomeration in the way that "centreless" districts do. Or rather they do no
benefit from such returns as a matter of course. Economies of scale - the larger the
production run, the lower the unit costs of production - favour such expansion; the
costs of extending control to every more complex situations cut against it. (We
are, many readers will recognize, in a Coasian world (Coase 1937) where the
decision to extend the organization, and how, or rely on the market, depends on a
comparison of the relative costs of executing the marginal transaction in each of
these ways).
But beyond these differences the craft district and routine large firm views are
fundamentally similar in the emphasis on tacit knowledge as both a precondition
but also limit to innovation and flexibility. Because craft skill and corporate
routine are taken for granted and second nature, they allow for "spontaneous" or
self organized co-ordination within certain boundaries. For the same reason, they
make it hard to identify those boundaries, and harder still to say when they are
obstacles to problem solving, and hence to be corrected.
The neo-Schumpeterians are especially clear on this point. Given the grip of
routine, large firms can only innovate - break free of past assumptions to aspire to
"autonomous strategic behaviour" - if they can establish "breakout" structures:
"entities separate from current operations which" are used to "incubate new
projects" (Teece 1998, p. 152). This recognition that the large firm can only be
reformed from without is tantamount to an admission that it can not· be
transformed from within. A congruent view is current in network analyses of
economic sociology (Grano vetter 1973). Ties among neighbours - friends who are
themselves likely to be friends-are robustly self-reinforcing. They are the social
substratum of the reciprocity that fosters trust and tacit knowledge. These ties do
the work of coordination, but, again, at the price of closing the networked
organization off from the world. The information about the outside on which
innovation ultimately depends comes from sparse, "weak" ties to distant actors:
the cousin of a distant friend from my home village who tells me where to look for
a job in the city to which we have both migrated. These ties convey formal
knowledge, but neither its tacit complement nor the propensity to trust from which
collaboration grows.
Accordingly, boundary blurring, "breakout" structures aside, innovation for
these schools of thought occurs largely outside the firm, in university or
government research labs or "distant" companies. Different from country to
country, these constellations form what the neo-Schumpeterians call the "national
innovation system". This system is to the large firms what the exoskeleton of
service providers is to craft firms in the districts: the external, innovative
corrective to the routines of self-coordination within the firms themselves.
Explicitly in the case of the neo-Schumpeterian large firm, implicitly in the case of
the craft district, the assumption is that competition selects for those firms or
bundles of routines that make the most effective use internal and external
Diversity, Not Specialization: The Ties That Bind the (New) Industrial District 113
resources. Economies of large or small firms survive in the long run in part
because their constituent "organisms" are sufficiently diverse in the genetic
material of their tacit knowledge to accommodate even the broadest shifts in the
conditions of competition. But they survive in part tno because the "we" of society
is capable of renovating the "external" institutions of the district or the national
economy as circumstances warrant. If these routine-revising institutions were
themselves prisoner of their own incorrigible routines, only blind luck would save
us from tragic attachments to solutions that no longer serve.
So in the end, and in the large - at the level of society at various scales - some
kind of reflection on and amendment of routine is possible and necessary. But
only outside the economy, in "society"? Or at least the firm? Is it really plausible
that large firms can devise "breakout" structures and small firms district
institutions, yet neither is capable of continuing self-revision in the small of its on-
going activities? Surely the existence of these structures and institutions attests
awareness of the problem of routine entrapment. Is that awareness fully exhausted
in the split solution - routine firm, routine-jiggling frame - these theories take for
granted? Or is this assumption itself an example of a (scientific) routine that
impedes recognition of a novel solution? The evidence presented next strongly
suggests the latter.
It is common, though perhaps not yet commonplace, to observe in the business
and business-school, engineering, and organizational sociology literatures that
firms are today able to adjust their operating routines and organizational
structures, and that disciplined comparisons of alternatives is an indispensable aid
to this. Most of the organizational innovations that permit this were pioneered in
modern times by Japanese firms, but are no longer limited, or indeed most
effectively developed by them. Here, sidestepping any considerations of how these
changes came about, I present an eclectic review of the innovations to highlight
the way the formalization of difference is key to the revision of routine. We start
with the operating units of the economy: first large, then small, district firms. The
distinction can be tenuous given that the latter are often suppliers to and must
mesh with the structures of the former, and that decentralization on the one side
and centralization on the other produces another kind of convergence. But the
discussions we have been canvassing draw this line, and we respect it here if only
to show that it is irrelevant to the innovations of interest. Finally we look at some
recent work on economic growth and geography which, innocent of any concern
for the structure of firms, comes to a complementary finding regarding the
contribution of diverse settings, rather than (relatively) homogenous and
specialized ones, to innovation.
Developments in large firms are reflected in the explosive diffusion of standards
that create and signal the existence of the preconditions for the creation of formal
pidgins or lingua francas for collaboration across firms and areas of expertise. On
these are built in turn disciplines that specify processes for comparing alternative
solutions to design problem or trouble shooting existing production set-ups
(Helper, MacDuffie and Sabel 2000). The most common of the standards is the
ISO 9000 series maintained by the International Bureau of Standards in Geneva. It
requires simply that firms be able to demonstrate that they can say what they do
114 C. F. Sabel
and do what they say with whatever level of resolution is relevant to their
industry. Put another way, the standards require that a firm be able to demonstrate
that it can make its "tacit" routines for, say, registering an order, or designing a
product, or correcting a manufacturing defect explicit to a potential customer.
Certification by a third party under the standard does not, of course, ensure that
any actual customer will find the explication sufficiently detailed and reliable for
its own collaborative needs. But certification is widely regarded in the automobile,
chemical, semi-conductor and computer industries as a precondition of a more
demanding examination of a firm's capacity for making its practices transparent
enough to be discussed with outsiders. And this is surely indicative of shifting
assumptions regarding the "stickiness" or embeddedness of (once) firm-specific
knowledge (von Hippel 1998).
The comparative disciplines, having arisen in practice, not under official aegis,
do not have standard names. In design the relevant practice is often called
concurrent or simultaneous engineering. A new product is defined initially and
provisionally by benchmarking (itself a comparative discipline) a current model
against successful competitors, relevant analogues in other fields, and adjusting
these comparisons to take account of laboratory innovations likely to be ready for
market in the next product cycle. Then the provisional design is decomposed into
modules (engine, transmission, seats, instrument panel, heating, ventilation and air
conditions system, and so on in the case of automotive vehicles) and each module
is then presented to the scrutiny of one or more of the corresponding module
makers. These module makers then benchmark their systems and suggest
refinements in the design, including if necessary changes in the performance
specifications of closely connected modules. Once the lead design group adjusts
the overall plan and selects module makers from those competing, the process is
iterated again, with the chosen module makers decomposing their systems into
sub-modules, and revising their plans in the light of their suppliers' suggestions.
This method both shortens design times and increases the reliability of designs,
while of course increasing the possibilities for incorporating innovations. This is
counterintuitive. It seems reasonable, after all, that successive refinement of a
single design will be either quicker, or more reliable than repeatedly correcting a
vague initial idea in the light of comparisons of variants, or both. Such in any case
was the view in the vertically integrated firm, where the design process was
typically seen as a mirror of the process by which the company partitioned itself
hierarchically. Concurrent engineering succeeds nonetheless in overcoming an
apparently inevitable trade-off because careful comparison of alternatives reveals
the defects and virtues of each variant, allowing for quicker, more reliable, and
more inclusive choices (Actually the comparisons involve a kind of double
diversification: different projects are compared by design teams whose members,
drawn from different specializations, are cognitively diversified. The underlying
mechanism of instigating surprise through investigation of difference remains the
same).
Similar mechanisms are at work in new regimes for error detection and
correction. An example is the five "why": Why is machine a broken? No
preventive maintenance was performed. Why was the maintenance crew derelict?
Diversity, Not Specialization: The Ties That Rind the (New) Industrial District liS
strong and weak ties, or local and long-distance ones, tends towards irrelevance?
(Watts 1999; Dodds, Sabel and Watts forthcoming).
Those are, given the tendencies sketched above, key questions for the near
future. Addressing them will, I think, be or practical importance to economic
actors, and a spur to the renewal of renection of complex self-organization as well
(Dobbs, Watts and Sabel forthcoming).
But looking beyond the beyond, addressing these questions won't be the end of
the story. For as soon as we begin to discern "optimal" organizational relations or
search procedures in the most successful of the disciplined comparisons of
difference, we will want to know what social conditions explain why these
relations emerge first and/or nourish better in some places rather than others. And
the search for the social preconditions of "disembedness" will take us back, by a
circuitous but (hopefully) upward spiralling route to some of the oldest and most
persistent questions about the foundations - if any - of our modernity.
References
Adler, P. S., Goldoftas, B., et al. (1999), "Flexibility vs. Efficiency? A Case Study or
Model Changeovers in the Toyota Production System", Organization Science, 10. pp.
43-68.
Barnard. C. I. (1947), The Functions of the £-I:ecutive, Cambridge, Harvard University
Press.
Beardsell, M. and Henderson, V. (1999), "Spatial Evolution of the Computer Industry in
the USA", European Economic Review, 43, pp. 431-456.
Becattini, G. (1990), "The Marshallian Industrial District as a Socio-Economic Notion", in:
Industrial Districts and Inter-Firm Cooperation in Italy, Pyke, F., Becattini, G. and
Sengenberger, W.(eds), Geneva, International Institute for Labour Studies, pp. 37-51.
Brusco, S. (1989), Piccole imprese e distretti industriali: una raccolta di saggi, Torino,
Rosenberg & Sellier.
Chandler, Alfred D. Jr., Hagstrom, P. et a1. (eds) (1998), The Dynamic Firm: The Role of
Technology, Strategy, Organization and Regions, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Coase, R. H. (1937), "The Nature of the Firm", Economica, 4, pp. 397-405.
Dei Ottati, G. (1996), "The Remarkable Resilience of the Industrial Districts of Tuscany",
in: Cossentino, F., Pyke, F. and Sengenberger, W.(eds), Local and Regional Response to
Global Pressure: The Case of Italy and Its Industrial Districts, Geneva, International
Institute for Labour Studies, pp. 37-65.
Dodds, P., Sabel, C. F. and Watts, D. (forthcoming), Searching for Searchers:
Organizational Robustness and Innovation in Highly Complex Solution Spaces.
Duranton, G. and Puga, D. (1999), Diversity and Specialisation in Cities: Why, Where and
When Does It Matter?, CEPR (Center for Economic and Policy Research) Discussion
Paper.
Duranton, G. and Puga, D. (2001), Nursery Cities: Urban Diversity, Process Innovation,
and theLife-cycle of Products, CEPR Discussion Paper.
Feldman, M. P. and Audretsch, D. B. (1999), "Innovation in Cities: Science-Based
Diversity, Specialization and Localized Competition", European Economic Review, 43,
pp. 409-429.
Diversity, Not Specialization: The Ties That 13ind the (New) Industrial District 121
Fujita, M., Krugman, P., et al. (1999), "On the Evolution of Hierarchical Urban Systems",
European Economic Review, 43, pp. 209-25l.
Fujita, M. and Thisse, 1. F. (2000), "The Formation of Economic Agglomerations: Old
Problems and New Perspectives", Economics of Cities, Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press.
Galison, P. (1997), Image and Logic: A Material Culture of Microphysics, Chicago and
London, University of Chicago Press.
Harrison, B., Kelley, M. et al. (1996), "Specialization Versus Diversity in Local
Economies: The Implications for Innovative Private-Sector Behavior", Cityscape 2, pp.
61-93.
Helper, S., MacDuffie, 1. P. and Sabel, C. (2000), "Pragmatic Collaborations: Advancing
Knowledge while Controlling Opportunism", Industrial and Corporate Change, 9, pp.
443-487.
Helpman, E. and Krugman, P. (1985), Market Structure and Foreign Trade: Increasing
Returns, Imperfect Competition, and the World Economy, Cambridge, Mass., MIT Press.
Huriot, 1. M. and Thisse, 1. F. (eds) (2000), Economics of Cities, Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press.
Granovetter, M. (1973), "The Strength of Weak Ties", American Journal of Sociology 78
(May), pp. 1360-1380.
Granovetter, M. (2001), "A Theoretical Agenda for Economic Sociology", forthcoming in:
Economic Sociology at the Millenium, Guillen, M. F., Collins, R., England, P. and
Meyer, M. (eds), New York, Russell Sage Foundation.
Kelley, M. and Helper, S. (1997), "Firm Size and Capabilities, Regional Agglomeration,
and the Adoption of New Technology", Economics of Innovation and New Technology,
forthcoming.
MacDuffie,1. P. (1997), "The Road to Root Cause: Shop-Floor Problem-Solving at Three
Auto Assembly Plants", Management Science, 43, pp. 479-502.
MacDuffie, 1. P. and Helper, S. (1999), "Creating Lean Suppliers: Diffusing Lean
Production Through the Supply Chain", Remade in America: Transplanting and
Transforming Japanese Production Systems, Liker, J., Adler, P. and Fruin, M. (eds),
New York, Oxford University Press.
Monteverde, K. and Teece, D. J. (1982), "Supplier Switching Costs and Vertical Integration
in the Automobile Industry", Bell Journal of Economics, 13 (1), pp. 206-213.
O'Connell, L. G. (2001), Breaking the Bounds of Peripherality: Irish Business in an Era of
Multilevel PartiCipative Internationalisation, Ph.D. thesis, University College Dublin.
Ottaviano, G. I. P. and Puga, D. (1997), Agglomeration in the Global Economy: A Survey of
the "New Economic Geography", CEP Discussion Paper.
Piore, M. J. and Sabel, C. F. (1984), The Second Industrial Divide: Possibilities for
Prosperity, New York, Basic Books.
Puga, D. (2001), European Regional Policies in Light of Recent Location Theories, CEPR.
Raymond, R. (n.d.), http://www.tuxedo.orgl-esr/writings/.
Sabel, C. F. (1994), "Learning by Monitoring: The Institutions of Economic Development",
Handbook of Economic Sociology, Smelser, N. and Swedberg, R. (eds), Princeton, NJ,
Princeton University Press, pp. 137-165.
Sabel, C. F. and Zeitlin, 1. (eds) (1997), Worlds of Possibility, Cambridge, Cambridge
University Press.
Schumpeter, 1. (1926), Theorie der Wirtschlaftlichen Entwicklung: Eine Untersuchung
Ober Unternehmergewinn, Kapital, Kredit, Zins und Den Konjunkturzyklus, Mtinchen
und Leipzig, Duncker und Humblot.
Signorini, L. F. (ed.) (2000), Lo Sviluppo Locale: Un'indagine della Banca d'Italia sui
distretti industriali, Roma, Meridiana Libri.
122 C. F. Sabel
Teece. D. (1998), "Design Issues for Innovative Firms: Bureaucracy, Incentives and
Industrial Structure", The Dynamic Firm: The Role of Technology, Strategy,
Organization and Regions, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Von Hippel, E. (1988), "Sticky Information and the Locus of Problem Solving:
Implications for Innovation", in: The Dynamic Firm: The Role a/Technology. Strategy.
Organization and Regions, Chandler, A. D. Jr., Hagstrom, P. and Solvell, O. (eds),
Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Weick, K. E. (1995), Sensemaking in Organizations, Thousand Oaks. Sage Publications.
Whitford, 1. (2001), The Decline of a Model? Challenge and Response in the Italian
Industrial Districts, Economy and Society, 30, issue I, February 2001, pp. 38-65.
Winter, S. G. (2000), "Organizing for Continuous Improvement: Evolutionary Theory
Meets the Quality Revolution", in: The Quality Movement & Organization Theory, Cole,
R. E. and Scott, W. R. (eds), Thousand Oaks, CA, Sage Publications, pp. 49-66.
Watts, D. (1999), Small Worlds: The Dynamics 0/ Networks between Order and
Randomness, Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Competitive and Synergic Behaviours
in the Development of Industrial Clusters:
Ecological Modelling and Empirical Evidence
Abstract. Aim of the paper is, on the one hand, to highlight the economic
relevance of industrial districts in Italy in terms of employment, value added and
export and, on the other, to apply an original theoretical framework, derived from
population ecology modelling, to the analysis of the development of industrial
districts in Italy.
In this way it is possible to underline the interplay of agglomeration economies and
diseconomies in the growth process of an industrial cluster, to distinguish three
main phases of its development process and to stress the complex and different
(i.e. synergic, competitive, etc.) interactions which exists between different
industries, within the same area, and between different areas within the same
industry.
The formal model is able to identify and discuss the existence stability conditions
of long run equilibria through a graphical analysis.
The paper continue by describing the structure and evolution of some
representative examples of Italian industrial districts (namely Cusio-Valsesia and
Lumezzane districts of valves and fittings, Varese district of plastic, rubber and
specialised machinery, Castel Goffredo districts of stockings).
A discussion of the main methodological problems connected to the empirical
implementation of the original analytical framework, described above, concludes
the paper.
ISections 1 and 3.1 can be attributed to M. Fortis, Sections 2, 3.2 and 3.3 to M. A.
Maggioni. The authors thanks Erika Uberti for outstanding research assistantships and
fruitful discussions; Simona Beretta, Alberto Bramanti, Bernhard Bohm, Paul Stoneman,
Peter Swann and Massimiliano Riggi for comments and observations on various draft of the
paper.
124 M. Fortis and M. A. Maggioni
Ecology is the study of patterns in nature, of how these patterns came to be,
how they change in space and time. why some are more fragile than others.
Population ecology is concerned with how populations interact with the
environment and how these interactions give rise to the larger patterns of
communities and ecosystems. The environment is more than just sun, air,
earth and water: it includes other organisms which may help or hinder the
survival of a species. Population ecology is also the study of how these
organisms interact (... ) in competition and in co-operation.
s. H. Kingsland (1985), Modelling Nature. Episodes in the History of
Population Ecology.
1. Introduction
As a matter of fact, unlike the other major advanced countries, Italy has a small
number of large companies. In 1999, according to Mediobanca's list of industrial
and services companies, only four groups posted sales in excess of 20 billion Euro
(IFI-FIAT, ENI, Olivetti and ENEL) , but only one of them (FIAT) operates
primarily in the manufacturing sector, while the others do business above all in the
services industry. The latest Fortune's list of the top world companies includes
only three Italian companies (Assicurazioni Generali, Fiat and ENI).
Most of the Italian manufacturing system consists of small and medium-sized
enterprises, often organised in a number of single-product industrial districts
unequalled in any of the other advanced countries.
As highlighted at the OECD Conference held in Bologna last year, Italy has the
largest number of workers in small and medium-sized industrial enterprises
(enterprises employing less than 250 people) in Europe, with 3.6 million, followed
by Germany (3.3 million), France (2.4 million) and Great Britain (2.2 million). It
should also be stressed that Italy is the advanced country with the highest
percentage ratio of employees of small and medium-sized enterprises to total
number of industrial workers, together with Spain and Japan (Italy 73%; Spain
Competitive and Synergic Behaviours in the Development of Industrial Clusters 125
72%; Japan 71%), while the other major countries have a higher rate of workers
employed in large companies, with a smaller percentage working in small and
medium-sized enterprises (Germany 40%; United Kingdom 48%; France 53%).
Another peculiarity of the Italian economy is that the sectors specialised in the
so-called "made in Italy" business (fashion, home furniture, food, traditional
mechanics) are the real engine of the Italian manufacturing industry; it has been
calculated that the "made in Italy" business employs more than 3 million people.
The specialised "made in Italy" sectors consist mainly of small and medium-sized
enterprises and of districts. About 200 local manufacturing systems specialised in
particular manufacturing sectors employ over 2 million people, or more than 40%
of the domestic manufacturing workforce and more than 60% of the typical "made
in Italy" sectors.
Moreover, thanks to high-level, quality and innovative productions, the
traditional Italian sectors are a big source of value. For instance, it has been
calculated that the added value of the Italian apparel, footwear and furniture
industry, assuming the same purchase power, is higher than that generated by the
German automotive industry or the American pharmaceuticals industry.
In 1999, the "made in Italy" sectors, where most enterprises are small to medium
in size (fashion, furniture, household goods, Mediterranean food and traditional
mechanics) recorded exports for 235,000 billion lire and a trade surplus of as
much as 142,000 billion. This surplus helped to pay the energy and raw materials
deficit not only of the "made in Italy" business itself but also that of the whole
Italian system, amounting to 63,000 billion, as well as the aggregated deficit of the
other manufacturing sectors (means of transport, information technology,
electronics, chemicals, paper, rubber, and cement), equal to 53,000 billion, leading
ultimately to a total net surplus of 25,000 billion lire in the Italian trade balance. In
2000 the surplus of the "made in Italy" business exceeded 150,000 billion lire and
allowed Italy to record a modest surplus in the trade balance in spite of the
dramatic worsening of the energy balance.
These figures highlight the major role of the "made in Italy" sectors in the Italian
foreign trade. It has also been calculated that about one third of the whole Italian
exports and almost 60% of the "made in Italy" sector's come from district system-
areas.
The pattern of the Italian industrial districts has drawn the attention of politicians
and experts from all over the world.
A few districts in Italy record sales revenues of 4 to 5 billion Euro: Sassuolo in
ceramic tiles, Prato and Biella in textiles. Approximately 30 districts post sales
revenues ranging between 500 and 1,500 million Euro: Castel Goffredo in
women's hosiery, Como in silk products, the areas of Brianza and Alto Livenza
(between Pordenone and Treviso) in furniture, Arzignano (Vicenza) and Santa
Croce (Pisa) in tanning, Fermo (Ascoli Piceno) in footwear, the Cadore (Bell uno)
in eyewear and frames, Montebelluna (Treviso) in sports shoes, Verona and the
Apuan Alps in marble and granite, Vicenza and Arezzo in jewellery, Bologna in
packaging machinery, Milan and Varese in plastics processing machinery, the
Murgia region (Bari and Matera provinces) in couches, Pesaro in kitchen furniture,
126 M. Fortis and M. A. Maggioni
Rimini, ForB and Pesaro in wood working machinery, etc. Many other districts,
though smaller, are leaders in their sectors, with sales revenues of 50 to 200
million Euro: from Rossano Veneto (Vicenza), world leader in saddles for
bicycles, to Bergamo in buttons, from Premana (Lecco) in scissors to Vigevano
(shoe-making machinery). Not to mention the typical food districts such as those
of Parmigiano Reggiano or Grana Padano cheese, Parma and San Daniele hams,
Gorgonzola cheese (Novara), and wines everywhere in Italy.
In their respective sectors, the Italian districts of small and medium-sized
businesses hold world trade shares comparable to, or even larger than those of the
big automotive, chemical and electronics multinational groups: the Emilian
ceramics district and the Castel Goffredo women's hosiery district hold each about
40% of the world exports in their sectors; the Biella and Prato woollen fabrics
districts and the Como silk district hold each world exports shares ranging from
15% to 25% in their respective sectors; similarly, world exports shares around
1570 are held each by the jewelry districts of Arezzo and Vicenza, the Belluno
eye wear district, the Apuane marble district and the Emilia packaging machinery
district; shares around 10% are held by the Emilia wood-working machinery
district, the Puglia couch district, the Alto Livenza furniture district, the Vicenza
tannery district, the Verona marbles district, etc.
The introduction has shown the empirical relevance of industrial districts in Italy
measured both in terms of employment and value added. This section is devoted to
the elaboration of a new theoretical modelling framework able to explain, on the
one hand, the location process of firms and, on the other, the development process
of industrial clusters.
The section studies the development path of an industrial cluster as the result of
two distinct but interrelated processes: an internal dynamics (spurred by firm's
location and spin-offs) and an external dynamics (determined by inter-industry and
inter-cluster interactions).
If one starts the analysis from this macro-economic perspective, the first issues to
be addressed concern the existence and the extent of spatial clustering processes,
the main questions to be answered being the following: why do firms cluster? And
why do clusters have a finite size?
In the population ecology literature, a generic modelling framework describes
the growth process of a species in an environment as driven by its reproductive
capacity and limited by the available amount of resources and the presence of
other interacting species. From a mathematical viewpoint, the core of this situation
Competitive and Synergic Behaviours in the Development of Industrial Clusters 127
Firms decide to settle in a cluster on the basis of the expe(;ted profitability of being
located there. This profitability depends on net locational benefits - obtained as the
difference between gross locational benefits and costs - which, in turn, are based
on both observable and unobservable elements.
For simplicity it can be assumed that, in an uncertain world - with limited
information regarding local costs and revenues available to the outsiders -
profitability expectations for any particular location will be based solely on the
number of firms already located there (the number of previous locations being the
only observable variable).
128 M. Fortis and M. A. Maggioni
Let us assume, as in Arthur (1988 and 1990), that locational gross benefits
B fq for firm f locating in cluster q are composed of geographical and
agglomeration benefits 2 •
Geographical benefits Gfq depend on the intrinsic features of the site (such as
the quality of local factors of production: capital kq and labour lq; the efficiency
of the local network of specialised suppliers and business service firms Sq; and
the quality of urban and industrial infrastructures u q ). Agglomeration benefits
(1)
2For analytical convenience we split locational benefits in two classes: geographical and
agglomeration benefits. The first class refers to those components which are unaffected by
the number of incumbents; while the second refers to those components which'depend on
the number of incumbents. By adopting this formulation, however, we do not intend to
state that agglomeration benefits refer only to spillovers of scientific and technological
knowledge and know-how. On the contrary we are convinced that relevant agglomeration
benefits derive also from external economies of scale in the use of local resources. The
same variable (i.e. labour productivity) has a fixed geographical component, which depends
on the quality of local workers, and a variable agglomerative component which depends on
the number of firms already located in the cluster.
Competitive and Synergic Behaviours in the Development of Industrial Clusters 129
Assuming that the geographical benefits and costs do not change overtime, if
we focus the analysis of the location process on the dynamics of the interactions
between the level of available locational benefits, what becomes relevant for
describing firms' location decisions is just the net benefit function N jq in the
incumbents' space. We can therefore summarise the geographic components
H fq with a parameter aq , which vertically shifts the locational net benefits
function, and write the following expression:
(3b)
3 An alternative explanation for the convexity of the locational costs function for firm/runs
as follows: the locational costs function is compose by a "fixed" and a "variable"
component. The fixed part of the costs (geographic costs) decreases as the number of
entrants increase; while the variable part increases (because of competition) as the number
of entrants increase. The combination of these two effects produces an U-shaped (convex)
cost curve as the interaction between tixed and variable costs of production in standard
microeconomics textbooks. A symmetric reasoning may also explain the inverted U-shaped
benefits function. This interpretation is surely more realistic than the one used in the paper,
however it is not as theoretically efficient as the other one since both components become
dependent on the number of incumbents.
130 M. Fortis and M. A. Maggioni
It easy to see that the locational net benefits function (3b) is always concave,
convex one CJq (n q) . In other words, each marginal firm, which enters the cluster,
increases the average profitability of locating in the cluster only up to a threshold.
After that point, any new entrant lowers the average net benefits available to each
resident firm and new entrant4 .
This formulation recalls some general results, obtained in the industrial location
and urban/regional economics literature (Weber 1929; Isard 1956; Richardson
1978; Papageorgiou 1979; Tauchen and Witte 1983; Miyao and Kanemoto 1987),
which show the existence of an optimal dimension of a given spatial agglomeration
of firms and/or households because of the concavity of the various benefits
functions.
We can therefore state that - if the number of potential entrants is sufficiently
large and there are no relevant entry barriers - as net locational benefits initially
increase, the growth rate of incumbent firms increases; then it decreases and is
finally driven to zero.
If we assume that the number of potential entrants is not constant but it is
changing overtime, than the entry pattern will be determined by the rate of birth of
potential entrants, since a proportion of such firms will locate in the cluster. If we
allow the number of actual entrants to be proportional to the average locational
benefits available in the cluster - as a first approximation (or, alternatively, as a
macroeconomic hypothesis without explicit micro-foundations 5) - and we assume
that the entry rate of firms into the cluster is proportional to the current level of
locational net benefits 6 , then the cluster growth will initially be fast, then will slow
down and finally will stop7
4However, as it is made graphically evident in Figure 4.2, because of the inverse U shape of
the marginal benefits function, there is a range, within the number of incumbents, where
marginal net benefits are already decreasing, but still higher than average ones, and average
net benefits are still increasing.
5 Another part of this story refers to the role played by spin-off firms. If we believe that
average net locational benefits give incumbent firms some extra profits, workers (or, better,
managers) of incumbent firms, which see these extra profits, will decide to start a new firm
to appropriate them. Therefore the number of spin-off firms, which are generated by parents
firms. is positively related to the level of locational benefits in the cluster. generated by the
incumbent firms.
GIt is evident that, for the moment, we are implicitly assuming firms to behave in a non-
strategic manner (i.e. although their entries modify radically the locational benefits
available in the cluster, they do not take into account such a modification) and to be totally
myopic (i.e. their entries are only dependent on the current level of locational benefits and
Competitive and Synergic Behaviours in the Development of Industrial Clusters 131
If this is the case 8 , one would expect the industrial growth of the cluster to
follow an S-shaped path with a slow start (when locational benefits are still low),
an "explosive" central period of rapid increase (when the average net benefits in
the cluster are highest) and a final part when the cluster gradually reaches and then
settles to its "equilibrium,,9 size as in Figure 1.
number of
incumbents
maximum
dimension
(K)
discovery
time
not on some discounted value of the flow of locational benetits they enjoy from the moment
of entry onward). In section 4.3, we will relax some of these hypotheses.
7This is not to say that, from a certain moment onward, entries will not take place. On the
contrary, once the equilibrium level of the cluster is reached, new entries are still possible,
but these happen at the expenses of some incumbents which are driven out of the cluster
(or, more probably, out of business). This continuous series of entries and exits may
determine a continuous oscillation of the cluster's industrial mass around the equilibrium
level.
8 And we collecled some empirical evidence supporting this story (see Maggioni 1993;
Maggioni and Porro 1994; Gambarotto and Maggioni 1998; Maggioni 1999).
9 It should be bore in mind, however, that this notion of equilibrium value can be changed
in the long run by radical innovations, exogenous demand shocks and appropriate regional
policies.
132 M. Fortis and M. A. Maggioni
What is needed now is a formal model of the location process and the
development of clusters, which will allow a rigorous testing of all these
assumptions.
The simplest growth model for an industrial cluster q - which stresses the
relevance of firms spatial interactions - can be expressed in the following format:
"the rate of growth of the industrial mass equals the product of the individual
firm's contribution lo to the regional population's growth and the number of firms
already in the cluster" (Maggioni 1993, 1999).
If only agglomeration economies and positive spillovers are taken into account
(and these are assumed to be constant), then each individual firm's contribution to
the level of average locational benefits and, consequently, to the growth of the
cluster would be equal to a constant rq . In this case cluster industrial growth
would follow an "explosi ve" exponential path II, formally:
dnq
-dt = rq n (t)
q
(4a)
Alternatively one can solve the equation for nq (t) as a function of the
exogenous initial industrial mass of the cluster nq (0)
(4b)
On the other hand, if congestion and competition effects are included, then
some modifications to this simple model are required to allow for some "density
dependent" factors to progressively depress the level of locational benefits and to
slow down the process of industrial growth of the cluster. A simple dynamic
model, which takes into account these features, is the logistic equation l2 , which
can be written as (Sa)
lOIn terms of changes in the average locational net benefits, due to the interactions of
agglomeration economies and diseconomies.
liThe higher is rq, the faster is the growth process.
12The logistic equation - firstly developed by Verhulst (1845) and Pearl and Reed (1925)
for demographic studies, then adopted by the ecological literature since Lotka (1925) - "is
the simplest model containing negative density dependence interaction. Further, it is the
Competitive and Synergic Behaviours in the Development of Industrial Clusters 133
dnq
-=rn(t) (11
1--'1-
(t)'J (5a)
dt 'I 'I K
'I
(5b)
1979).
Plotting nq (t) against time yields an S-shaped curve due to the counteracting
roles played by rq and K q . When the cluster is small (11'1 (t) is near to zero) the
term in brackets in equation (5a) is close to one (hence the logistic equation
approximately describes an exponential growth path); but as nq (t) approaches
Kq , the term in brackets tends to zero, driving the growth rate to zero and
terminating the entry process. Both Kq and rq playa major role in shaping a
logistic growth path: the greater is rq the steeper is the S shaped curve, the larger
Kq the higher the ceiling level of the function (and the equilibrium size of the
cluster).
tirst two terms in a power series expansion of a more general growth model where the
growth is a function of the actual size of the population" (Dendrinos and Mullally 1985, p.
38).
13 K in the original ecological jargon is called carrying capacity: "a measure of the amount
14Composed of two main categories: tlrms already established outside the cluster and
potential entrepreneurs inside the cluster looking for the right moment to start their own
business.
Competiti ve and Synergic Behaviours in the Development of Industrial Clusters 135
determine the level of average locational net benefits available to incumbent firms
in each period of time.
In this first formulation, the number of located firms directly generates (through
agglomeration dynamics) the level of locational benefits; since the entry rate is
assumed to be proportional to the level of locational benefits, it also indirectly
determines the location of new firms into the cluster.
Such a formulation of the location process is very simple but can be used to
empirically estimate key parameters of the location path of different clusters's.
These estimated parameters could also be used as dependent variables in cross-
section analyses in order to assess the int1uence of different factors on the level of
the intrinsic growth rate of a cluster or on its maximum dimension.
However this formulation can be criticised on a number of grounds. The main
drawback refers to the "isolation hypothesis": firms' location decisions are
modelled as a dichotomous choice, in the sense that there is only one possible site
for location and the choice variable is just the timing of the entry. The following
sections extend the simple logistic growth path to take into account bilateral
interactions.
Several different interactions may arise when a framework with two clusters (I
and 2) is considered. The first concerns the location decisions of a set of industry-
specific potential entrant firms confronted with the choice of locating in one out of
two clusters. This problem can be formally described through a model of inter-
cluster competition with a given number of potential entrant firms l6 . The entry
decision is again modelled as dependent on the number of firms located in each
cluster, ret1ecting the effects of agglomeration economies and diseconomies, as
described in the previous section.
Formally, the multi-cluster situations l ? can be described through the following
system of equations which directly recalls the mono-cluster development process
of equation (Sa):
15Where the difference may refers to different industries in the same geographical site, or to
different geographical sites in the same industry.
16This peculiar approach to the process of multi-clusters development (where the cluster is
modelled as an agent and firms as passive industrial mass) reveals its advantages when
modelling active policy pursued by different local authorities willing to foster the industrial
development of their respective territories.
17The same analytical framework can be used to describe the interaction between two
industries in the same cluster which compete on a given pool of local limited resources
(land, workers, bank credit etc.).
136 M. Fortis and M. A. Maggioni
(7 a)
where rl and Kl are respectively cluster 1 incipient growth rate and equilibrium
levels and c 12, is the "competition coefficient" which measures the extent to which
cluster 2 competes as an alternative location to cluster 1.
However - for expositional purposes - it is more convenient to replace this
formulation (which underlines the similarities between the two-clusters case and
the model of development of one isolated cluster depicted in 4.Sa) with an
alternative formalisation which is able to model different multiregional interactions
through simple differences in the sign of parameters. We thus replace (7a) by (7b),
where time references are dropped for the sake of clarity:
(7b)
18 ~ and ~ in this formulations are the clusters' maximum size or isolated equilibrium
all an
values (K 1 and K2)·
190ifferent interpretations for these parameters are possible: the simplest relates the values
of inter-regional competition parameters to the fact that - given a certain number of
potential entrants - each tirm that locates in cluster 1 does not locate in cluster 2. Then the
inter-clusters coefficients should be equal, i.e. a l2 = a 21 . Another interpretation explicitly
Competitive and Synergic Behaviours in the Development of Industrial Clusters 137
According to the relative value of these parameters, three main outcomes 20 are
possible, as shown by phase diagrams in Figure 2.
Phase diagrams are useful tools to describe systems of differential equations. At
any moment in time the state of the system is fully described by the number of
firms located in each cluster (n 1 and n 2 ). Within the phase plane one can further
draw for each cluster the locus of points (i.e. combination of n l and n2 ), which is
called the isocline, where the cluster's industrial mass does not change (i.e. where
dn l dn z
--- = 0 and - - = 0) The multiple equilibria of the system are thus
dt dt'
identified by the intersections of one isocline with either the axes or the other
isocline 21 . The arrows in the phase planes indicate the direction in which the
system, at that point, will move; the colours and shapes of the dots show whether
an equilibrium is either stable or unstable or a saddle point.
relates to the possible differences in the logistic growth path of the two clusters in isolation
(which renect differences in the net benefits function). In this case inter-clusters
competition coefticients can be different.
20Selected from the analysis of 13 possible consistent cases. For a more complete analysis,
see Capelo (1989, pp. 165-169) and Beltrami (1987, pp. 72-73).
2lThe intersection of an isocline with an axis is an equilibrium point since one cluster in
deserted and the other does not change its industrial mass, the intersection of two isoclines
is an equilibrium point since both clusters do not register any changes in the number of
located firms.
138 M. Fortis and M. A. Maggioni
2a 2b
n2
n'I=O
E2
E2 :x
EO
EI
nl
EO EI nl
2c 2d
E2
EO EI nl EO EI nl
Legend:
o unstable cquilibriulll
•o stable equilibrium
saddle point
Fig. 2a shows the persistent coexistence of two clusters (both recording a positive
number of locations) as a stable equilibrium when:
al az al a2
->- and -<- (8a)
a l2 a l2 all a 21
Competitive and Synergic Behaviours in the Development of Industrial Clusters 139
and (8b)
Fig. 2c and 2d show the total exclusion of one cluster from the location process
that occurs only in the other cluster (irrespective of the initial state) which reaches
its carrying capacity leaving the opponent deserted 23. In particular, only cluster 1
is entered when:
al a2 al az
->- and ->- (8c)
a l2 a 22 all aZI
al a2 al al
--<- and -<- (8d)
all all all all
Since the industrial growth of the cluster in isolation follows a logistic path, then
the isoclines are linear and the stability of equilibrium depends on the equilibrium
point being above the line24 joining the maximum dimensions of each cluster in
22More precisely the equilibrium defining the coexistence of two clusters is a saddle point;
any initial state off the stable manifold, or any perturbation that move the system far from
it, leads to the "deprivation" of one out of two clusters.
23This case includes two opposite situations of only cluster I surviving and only cluster 2
surviving.
is achieved when:
and (8e)
26 Being formally stated by Gause (1934), even though an earlier and slightly different
formulation is ascribed to Volterra (1926).
27 It is very interesting to compare this result to very similar ones obtained independently
and following a totally different approach by Arthur (1988 and 1990).
Competitive and Synergic Behaviours in the Development of Industrial Clusters [41
Competition
Mutualism + +
Commensalism + 0
Predation + -
Neutralism o0
Amensalism o-
28Where regional specificity means that each cluster is the ideal location for a different type
of firm.
1~2 M. Fortis and M. A. Maggioni
29There are two different reasons why mutualistic and amensalistic relations have been
ignored. The first reason is an historical one: both Lotka and Volterra - generally
acknowledged as the forerunners of population ecology - limited their analyses to predation
and competition. The second reason is a theoretical one: in its purest formulation, a
mutualistic model docs not have a stable equilibrium and one or both populations undergo
"an unbounded exponential growth in an orgy of mutual benefaction" (May 1976, p. 95). A
growth model without stable equilibrium seemed of no interest to regional and applied
economists. However, more sophisticated models of mutualistic interaction allow for
saturation in the magnitudes of reciprocal benefits and obtain - as general result - a stable
equilibrium with both populations (usually clusters, but they can equally be industries)
developing larger than in isolation. It must be said, furthermore, that this equilibrium is less
stable - in the sense that perturbations are more slowly damped - than in correspondent
systems without mutualistic relations.
30Textiles firms, in these locations utilised the female components of the miners' families as
source of cheap labour force.
3lThe first demanding workers and offering wages. the second demanding goods and
offering labour. This interaction goes well when there are not relevant negative externalities
(such as pollution, noise etc.) spilling from the industrial cluster to the residential one. In
such a case we may well describe the situation as amensalistic.
32For an example of such clustering dynamics, see Storper and Walker (1989, p. 81) which
report an amazing map showing the agglomeration in the London watch and clock making
quarter of Clerkenwell, in 1861.
Competitive and Synergic Behaviours in the Development of Industrial Clusters 143
(9)
In this model each industry in isolation would follow a logistic growth pattern,
but the presence of one industry in the same cluster has a positive influence on the
rate of growth of the other one. The system's dynamics - which is described
through a phase diagram in Figure 3 - always displays three trivial unstable
equilibria (Figure 3a): the origin (corresponding to the underdevelopment of both
industries) and each industry's isolated maximum dimension. However, under
certain assumptions concerning the slope of isoclines (Figure 3b), a fourth stable
equilibrium (E 3) emerges which enables both industries to reach a higher level in
the cluster. The coexistence of two industries in the same cluster allows both
industries to grow larger than would have been possible in the isolated case, but
intra-industry competition effects prevent the system from experiencing explosive
growth.
3a 3b
n2 nl
n'I=O
n'2=O
n'I=O
E2
E2
EO EI EO
nl EI nl
Legend:
o unstable equilibrium
• s[able equilibrium
The conditions for an equilibrium solution in which both industries survive can
be re-expressed as a strict positivity requirement on the co-ordinates of E 3 in the
(aZa ll +alaZI )
...,-'-------'--,- >0 (lOa)
(alla ZZ - alZa ZI )
(a Za l2 +a l a Z2 ) >0
( lOb)
(all a 22 - a 1Z a 21 )
Given that all coefficients are positive, the two conditions reduce as follows:
(lOc)
complementary productions, where the driving forces of the joint development are
vertical and horizontal productive linkages established between clusters.
Other stimulating results are obtained when the symmetry assumption required
by facultative 35 mutualism is relaxed. An interesting case concerns a situation in
which the first cluster in isolation will grow according to a logistic path and its
growth is further fostered by the presence of industrial activity in the neighbouring
one, whilst the second cluster is strictly dependent on the existence of the
industrial activity in the first cluster for its very survival. A typical example of this
kind is the relationship existing between the "core" of an industrial area (where the
large companies are located) and the surrounding area, "periphery", crowded by
several small firms (i.e. sub contractors and suppliers) - specialised in accessory
productions - which are vitally linked to the industrial success of the core 36 .
Similar relationships (which do not imply any spatial differentiation) may well
arise between two different industries in the same cluster. A typical example
(thoroughly discussed in Swann, 1993) is constituted by the relationships between
the manufacturing core of an industrial cluster and the network of specialised
service sectors. Since these specific business services must be "consumed" in the
very place of their production and cannot be exported to other areas, the existence
of a service sector within the cluster is crucially dependent on the existence of a
prosperous manufacturing core.
These interactions can be formally described as follows:
(11 )
Where 111 is the economic mass (number of located firms) of the manufacturing
core cluster and rq is the economic mass of the specialised service sector.
With the aid of a phase diagram (see Figure 4a), it is possible to see that the
system has three equilibria. The first is trivial, unstable and corresponds to the
origin; the second, stable, corresponding to the isolated maximum dimension of
the core manufacturing industry; the third, which is a saddle point, corresponds to
35 Where the term "facultative" refers to the fact that each industry, in isolation, develops
and reaches its equilibrium level. The presence of an industry is therefore no necessary
condition for the development of the other one.
36 The Motor vehicle industry (which is clustered around Detroit in the USA, Coventry in
the UK, Besan<;on in France, and Torino in Italy) displays a core-periphery spatial
configurations in almost every countries.
146 M. Fortis and M. A. Maggioni
4a 4b
n2 n'2=0
n2
! n'I=O
E3
!
I
EO EI EO
nl E3 El nl
Legend:
o unstable equilibrium
• Slable equilibrium
o saddle poinl
The relationships between two industries in the same cluster may also display a
predatory pattern with one industry growing at the expense of the other.
Predatory interactions have been widely studied in the ecological and in the
economic literature (one does not need to recall the names of Alfred Lotka, Vito
Volterra and Richard B. Goodwin) and they may well describe the sort of
interaction existing between a rising and a declining industry in a given area.
(12)
Where n1 is the prey (or the older and currently declining industry) and n2 is
the predator (or the younger and rising one).
Predatory interactions typically display oscillatory dynamics. A phase diagram
(see Figure 5) illustrates two possible configurations: case (a) where the
coexistence of both population is a stable equilibrium surrounded by a converging
spiral, case (b) where the coexistence of both population is an unstable equilibrium
surrounded by a diverging spiral.
Sa Sb
n2 n2
n'l=O
/
E2
/ " £2
EO EI EO
nl EI nl
Legend:
0 unstable equilibrium
•
0
stable equilibrium
saddle point
In the two situations, if the system starts far from the equilibrium, both predator
and pray number oscillate. However, while in the first case the oscillations have a
decreaSIng amplitude and, in the long run, the system reaches its equilibrium; in
the second case the oscillations continuously increase their amplitude and the
system dynamics may well determine the extinction of one or both populations.
Besides the one above mentioned, various type of interactions coexist within the
development dynamics of industrial clusters. The qualitative identification of such
interactions and the quantitative measurement of their effect on the growth rate of
industries are thus left to the empirical analysis of section 3.3. The effects of the
variability of macro-economic conditions on the behaviour of the systems have
been extensively discussed in Gambarotto and Maggioni (1998).
Previous sections have shown some results that can be obtained by using a series
of ecologIcally derived models to analyse the growth of an industrial cluster (or
industry) in isolation and of a system of two interacting clusters (or industries).
It would seem therefore natural to extend these results to the case in which more
than two clusters are involved. Unfortunately, this extension is not straightforward
for empirical as well as theoretical reasons. The firsts refer to the geometrical
increase of the relevant interaction parameters, while the second concerns the
dynamic behaviour of the system which becomes qualitatively complex.
Two different approaches can be used to overcome this problem. The first
relates to the possibility of constructing a large computational model, assigning
plausible parameters' values and then simulating the dynamic of the system; the
second consists of abandoning the description of individual cluster behaviour -
within a multi-cluster complex - and focusing entirely on some overall aspects of
the resulting structure, such as the relation between the increase in system
complexity and its overall stability'8.
Even though it is difficult to draw some general conclusions, here are some
principles and guideposts for multi-cluster analysis which could be derived from
the original population ecology literature (see Levins 1968; Levin 1970; May
1974; Roughgarden 1979) which may give some indications on possible behaviour
of such a model.
Equilibria may exist only within limited ranges of the interaction and
environmental parameters (such as cluster's incipient growth rates, maximum
38 Inthis section "increased complexity" is, rather loosely, defined in terms of increased
number of cluster, more interactions and therefore more parameters. Stability is described
as a lower level of fluctuations in the economic mass of the clusters, and as the ability of
the system to recover from perturbations.
Competitive and Synergic Behaviours in the Development of Industrial Clusters 149
requirement on the number of objectives not to exceed the number of instruments in the
theory of economic policy, and the relation between number of factors and number of
commodities in international trade theory.
150 M. Fortis and M. A. Maggioni
This section is twofold. On the one hand it is devoted to the description of the
structure and evolution of four Italian industrial districts; on the other hand it
contains an explorative descriptions of the implementation of the econometric
estimation of the relationships described in section 2 and of the main problems
(both methodological and related to the sample size) encountered in such an
empirical analysis. Finally some first empirical results, derived from both
econometric and calibration techniques.
With about 300 firms and over 2,000 billion lire of annual sales revenues, the
women's hosiery district of the Mantova area, with its centre at Castel Goffredo, is
one of the successful industrial districts of the "made in Italy" business. The
district, the absolute leader in its sector in Europe, contains all the leading
companies operating in the business in area of a few square kilometres: the largest
Italian groups, among which is Golden Lady (owner of the Omsa and Sisl trade
marks), Csp International (now listed at the Milano Stock Exchange), Pompea,
Levante, Calzificio Real, a number of small and medium-sized firms, as well as
Filodoro, a company controlled by multinational Sara Lee, that settled in the
district to enjoy the location economies and benefits available in a highly-skilled
area.
The historical origins of this industrial district go back to the first women's
hosiery factory (Noemi) built at Castel Goffredo in the early '30s, when the area's
prevailing activity was still farming. The young were the first to leave the rural
areas and start working in the industry, thus contributing to the development of the
first textile settlement, which, however, had a rather short life. When Noemi closed
down in 1958, the workers, employed until then in the various manufacturing
stages of the hosiery industry, became entrepreneurs and set up small handicraft
shops that would later slowly develop into the first firms of the district; this way,
through a typical budding process, they gave rise to a network of small enterprises,
each specialized in a single manufacturing process. Later, early in the '70s, the
panty hose appeared in the domestic marketplace and was such a success that the
local manufacturers were initially hardly able to meet the demand. The number of
factories rose, also helped by the local allied activities such as the manufacture of
machinery for the textile and stocking-weaving industry in particular (Lonati,
based in Brescia, the first manufacturer of tubular hosiery machines in the world,
was the biggest example). The Castel Goffredo pattern became more and more
synonymous with quality, attracting big foreign dealers and encouraging the local
operators to look outside the domestic boundaries to discover a strong export
vocation that is still a typical feature of the district. One of the success factors of
Castel Goffredo is the close relationship between the local manufacturers and large
Competitive and Synergic Behaviours in the Development of Industrial Clusters 151
With approximately 1,700 billion lire's worth of sales abroad, the Cusio-
Valsesia district accounts for approximately one third of the Italian exports of the
sector and has a share of about 5% in the world exports and of 9-10% of the EU's
exports of item 84.81, representing the most important valves and fittings
manufacturing area in the world. The shares are even larger if brass and bronze
valves and fittings only are considered, which is the sector the district is
specialized in. The exports are about 60% of the total sales, with some companies
reaching peaks of 80% or more and, in a few cases, almost the total sales. The
main exportation markets are the EU countries (Germany, Great Britain, France
and Spain in this order), the United States and the Middle East, with growing
exports to Eastern Europe, the Far East and South America in the last few years.
According to 1ST AT's intermediate industry census, in 1996 the Novara,
Vercelli and Verbania provinces recorded 431 companies in the val ves and fittings
sector, employing 8,101 workers. More difficult is the assessment of the impact of
the allied industries because many activities (e.g. metal treatment and polishing)
are shared with another industrial district in the area, namely that of cookware and
household goods, concentrated in the Omegna area. It is a fact, however, that,
again in 1996, the moulding, casting, metal treatment and polishing businesses in
the three mentioned provinces employed a workforce of 6,897 distributed over
1,139 local units, a lot of them very small in size, and most of them are more tied
to the valves and fitting business than to that of household goods. It can therefore
be estimated that the Cusio-Valsesia district of valves and fittings involves not less
than 12,000 jobs in direct activities and allied industries, excluding services such
as transport, advertising, etc.
The growth of the valves and fitting sector in the Novara, Vercelli and Verbania
provinces has been very fast: according to the 1ST AT censuses, the jobs were
3,228 in 1971,5,390 in 1981,6,684 in 1996 and, as already said, 8,101 in 1996.
Based on a projection of the figures of the top 44 companies, the direct jobs are
likely to have risen to about 8,800 in 1999-2000. Equally significant was the
employment growth in the casting, moulding, galvanic treatment and polishing of
metals in the three provinces: the jobs rose from 3,146 in 1971 to 6,897 in 1996
and there is no doubt that most of the increase can be ascribed to the growth of the
valves and fitting business in the area.
Through the figures of the 1ST AT census of 1996 we can also assess the district
from the viewpoint of the size of the businesses. Considering only the valves and
fittings sector proper (i.e. without the allied industries), we find: 3 big companies
(with more than 250 workers), 34 medium-sized enterprises (50 to 249 workers),
132 small enterprises (10 to 49 workers) and 262 micro-enterprises (less than 10
workers). Again according to the 1996 ISTAT census, the main manufacturing
centre in the district is San Maurizio d'Opaglio (see Figure 6), with about 2,000
workers employed in the valves and fittings sector and allied industries, followed
by Gozzano (about 1,500 workers plus allied industries), Pogno (1,000 workers),
Valduggia (900 workers) and Pella (500). Other important municipalities in the
district are Invorio, Borgomanero, Briga Novarese, Fontaneto d' Agogna,
Borgosesia, Quarona and Grignasco.
Competitive and Synergic Behaviours in the Development of Industrial Clusters 153
30
Kms
30 Kms
Fig. 6. Epicenter of the Cusio- V alsesia district of taps and valves based on the % impact of
the local units specialized in the main business and allied industries on the total 19cal units
of each municipality: year 1996.
In addition, if the workforce figures of each municipality in 1991 and 1996 are
compared, a growth appears in the relative weight of the most external
municipalities as a result of new production settlements outside the ring of the
central core of the district's municipalities. As a result of this trend, though the
number of workers has been rising in the 5 central municipalities (Pogno, S.
Maurizio d'Opaglio, Pella, Valduggia and Gozzano), the relative impact of the
workers on the total workforce of the district decreased from 58% in 1991 to 56%
in 1996, while that of the peripheral municipalities rose from 42% to 44%.
The historical factors of success of this district include some elements common
to the two distinct businesses of sanitary faucets and valves. First of all, the
previously mentioned tradition of brass and bronze processing in the area. This
tradition has been developing over the years and has produced a very high specific
know-how in the manufacture of both valves and faucets, training of highly
qualified technicians and workers and setting up a strong network of relationships
inside the district for the supply of components, semi-finished parts and services.
Another strong point of the district as a whole is its proximity to the manufacturing
centres of the raw material, the brass bar, and the availability of a scraps recycling
system. In addition, the leading role of the bigger manufacturers was a major
154 M. Fortis and M. A. Maggioni
factor in building the world reputation of the district and the quality of the output,
which meet the highest international standards. In the sector of sanitary faucets,
design is an important element for success, on which the district concentrated great
efforts to be able to compete with the big foreign manufacturers. Compared to the
valves sector, that of sanitary faucets has seen the proliferation of small businesses,
sometimes only assemblers, whose development was possible thanks to the strong
presence of component manufacturers and providers of services (galvanizing,
polishing).
Let's review now the Lumezzane and Brescia district in Lombardia, which is a
bit smaller than that of Piemonte but equally important in the international market.
Located north of Brescia, along the Trompia and the Sabbia valleys, this industrial
district is mainly concentrated in Lumezzane, the pivot of the district, Sarezzo and
Villa Carcina, with branches both to the north through Marcheno and Gardone Val
Trompia and to the south as far as Concesio and Brescia itself.
As highlighted for the Piemonte district, also here tradition was a decisive factor
in the birth and development of the industrial district. Iron working flourished here
thanks to the abundance of minerals and of water already in ancient times. It was
arms manufacture that made these valleys well known as early as in Roman times.
Later, in the course of the centuries, the manufacture of farming tools, cutlery and
crockery developed and, more recently, that of brass and bronze valves and
fittings. In addition, the old tradition of iron and metal working in the Brescia
province allowed this district to specialize in the upstream steps of the
manufacturing process, i.e. in casting and moulding of the raw material (brass bar),
with the valves sector prevailing over that sanitary faucets.
In order to complete the analysis of the Italian valves and fittings industry, the
Fondazione Comunita e Innovazione and Universita Cattolica (Milano) studied
this second industrial district with the same methodology as used for the other one.
An initial quantitative assessment of the district was obtained through an extensive
survey made in 1995 by means of questionnaires sent to the enterprises and an
analysis of the balance sheets of the bigger companies operating in the sector in the
Lumezzane and Brescia area: the total sales revenues in 1995 amounted to 1,670
billion lire and the exports to over 850 billion. In addition, the intermediate 1ST AT
census of 1996 recorded for item 29.13, "manufacture of valves and fittings", 185
local units and 4,531 workers in the Brescia province. For the following years,
instead, the figures were updated on the basis of a sample of 35 companies, 19 of
which manufacturing valves, 8 faucets and 8 intermediate components. From the
data of the sample it was possible to estimate the total figures of the district both
for 1994, i.e. one year before that of the first survey, which was 1995, and for the
following years until 1999. Starting from 1,350 billion of sales revenues in 1994,
the Lumezzane district recorded a fast growth (+23%) and reached 1,670 billion in
1995; the 1996 figure was slightly lower (1,650 billion), while increases to 1,890
billion (+14%) and 1,950 billion (+3%) were recorded in 1997 and 1998,
respectively. The latter level was maintained in 1999.
The same trend was recorded in exports, which exceeded the 1,000 billion
threshold in the last few years. Like the Piedmontese district, that of Lumezzane is
Competitive and Synergic Behaviours in the Development of Industrial Clusters 155
a strong exporter: on the whole the ratio of exports to total sales revenues is about
50%, but a large number of enterprises reach much higher percentages, with peaks
of 98%. Considering the sectors, instead, the impact of exports on sales revenues is
higher for sanitary faucets (60% on the average) than for valves (50-55%) and
intermediate components (about 35%). The last-named sector, in particular, is
represented by the enterprises that operate in auxiliary processing such as metal
polishing, colouring or chromium-plating, or manufacture intermediate
components rather than finished products. For all these firms, usually small in size,
the outlet is the local market, which explains the smaller percentage of sales
abroad.
As mentioned before, unlike the other district, that of Lumezzane is more
specialised in valve manufacture. The enterprises operating in this sector are many
more than those manufacturing sanitary faucets, and account for 60% of the sales
revenues of the whole district. Some of the bigger valve manufacturers, in
addition, take care also of the initial step of the manufacturing process, i.e. casting
and moulding of the brass bar; these are capital intensive operations which require
the installation of casting or moulding works, so the companies having such plants
tend to use them also for other companies in the sector, to which they sell raw
product for subsequent processing.
Finally, concerning the allied industries, it is very difficult to estimate the
number of workers employed in allied industries because of the overlapping of the
valve and fitting sector with other mechanical industries present in the area, such
as that of cookware manufacture.
At this point, after the women's hosiery district of Castel Goffredo and the two
valve and fitting districts, we are presenting briet1y the case of the Varese
province, with special reference to the plastics material processing industry and
related machinery. The chemical, plastics and rubber industry is undoubtedly a
major sector in this area of Lombardia; it is a broad and diversified business that
ranges from chemical commodities to pharmaceutical products, from semi-fir.ished
to tinished products. Apart from the drugs industry, that has been developing
especially thanks to multinationals that selected the Varese province for the
existing technical and production background and its favourable location between
Milano and Switzerland, it is the manufacture of rubber and above all of plastics
articles that saw the biggest growth, making it one of the Italian areas with the
highest concentration of plastics conversion companies and a real industrial
district. To give an idea of the extension of this sector, in 1996 (intermediate
1ST AT census figures) the enterprises operating in the "manufacture of rubber and
plastic articles" in the Varese province were 831, with a total workforce of about
11,900 and a research conducted by U ni versita Cattolica of Milano in 1998
estimated that the 200 bigger companies in the district posted sales revenues of
about 3,400 billion lire.
Historically, the conversion of plastic materials and rubber entered the industrial
system of the Varese province immediately after World War II, but the real growth
was recorded in the last two decades, with the breakthrough of plastics in the
manufacture of intermediate and finished product. A major factor allowing the
156 M. Fortis and M. A. Maggioni
birth and consolidation of this industry, besides the diversitication of the expertise
available in the region and the presence of a few big companies operating in the
sector, was the strong concentration in the province (the highest in Italy) of
manufacturers of calenders, i.e. the equipment that - starting from the raw material,
here plastics - makes sheets of the desired thickness for subsequent moulding. The
manufacture of plastics conversion equipment is in line with the long mechanical
tradition of the Varese province. The mechanical industry, that was initially a
support for the textile industry, especially for maintenance of looms of British or
German origin, has been expanding to become one of the main businesses in the
province. It is emphasised that the mechanical industry of this province has been
closely tied to the history of the means of locomotion: from the early Caproni,
Marchetti and Macchi airplanes to the Isotta Fraschini cars, the Cagiva motorbikc:s
and the Agusta helicopters. Now the most widely spread and qualified mechanical
production is tied to the conversion of plastic, a sector, again according to the
1ST AT census of 1996, counting 452 local enterprises with a workforce of over
7,300. With the mechanical industry it is more difficult to quantify the production
value because the mentioned Universita Cattolica research surveyed only a very
small portion of the district's companies, but it estimated overall sales revenue of
about 650 billion lire for the 40 leading equipment manufacturers in 1998.
Therefore, on the whole, the Varese district of plastics and related mechanical
industry consists of about 1000 local units with over 19,000 workers.
The data used in the following section concern the level of employment and the
number of local units in different "clusters" from 1951 to 1991 (for some districts
data for 1996 are also included). Data are taken from the "Censimento delle
attivita produttive", the Italian businesses' census which is run each 10 years42.
The term cluster here identifies the intersection of a given industry with a given
territorial area (Provincia). It is therefore clear that in the empirical analysis we are
counting employees and local units which do not strictly belong to the cluster
(which is a subset of the provincial territory) but data at a finer geographical
disaggregation (Comune) are available only from 1991.
Data thus suffer from two main problems: the first, as explained above, concerns
the imprecise identification of the cluster, the second regards the small numerosity
of the available sample (6 observations at most). A similar analysis has been
conducted on US high-tech cluster in Maggioni (1999). There, by using County
42 1996 is the first attempt to build an "intermediate census" to shorten the time lag from 10
to 5 years.
Competitive and Synergic Behaviours in the Development of Industrial Clusters 157
Business Patterns, it has been possible to get more precise identification, yearly
observations and longer time series (about 40 observations).
The empirical exercise has therefore been forced to use a combination of
econometric analysis and calibration techniques. Some results were intrinsically
fragile and statistically not very significant. Further research on this issue is still
needed. We therefore decided to present only a subset, which yields the more
robust and significant results.
(13)
where Ilr and Ils are the "economic masses" (number of plants or level of
employments) in cluster rand s and all parameters are as in equation (7b). In
particular ar and as are the intrinsic rates of increase of each cluster in isolation;
arr and (Iss are the intra-cluster competition parameters which reflect the inhibiting
effects that a firm's entry has on the growth rate of the same cluster (because of
congestion effects); ars and asr (inter-cluster competition parameters) show the
inhibiting effects that one firm, locating in a cluster, has on the growth of the other
region (inter-cluster competition parameters).
In theory, one then would like also to take into account the inter-industry
interactions which develop within the same cluster. If this is the case, then a two-
regions, two sectors can be modelled as follows
dl1~ _ ( i
dt- - ar - iii i j j)
a rr l1 r - a,..,.n, + a r I1r I1r
i
dn: _
dt - (i iii i
a, - assn, - a,.,.llr + as 11.,
j j) 11.,i
(14)
dll; _ ( j
dt j j
- a r - arrll j j
r - arsn,. + arll r llr
ji i)
dn;_(j jj jj ii)j
dt - a, - assn,. - asrn r + asns 11.1'
158 M. Fortis and M. A. Maggioni
which have a trivial solution for n l and 112 equal to zero and a non trivial soiution
which identify the following two lines:
n2 = ---
a l
- -all- n l
a 12 a lz
a2 a ZI
n2 = --- - --nl
a 22 a 22
and plot them in the phase plan. The intersection of two isoclines is an
equilibrium point for the system, since in this point both populations do not change
overtime.
Competitive and Synergic Behaviours in the Development of Industrial Clusters 159
If one then plots in the same space the actual measure of the two populations in
the cluster one may suggest the future evolution of the cluster buy predicting the
direction of variation of the two carrying capacities. Figure 7, 8, 9 10 and II
present the main results.
When the econometric estimates were either fragile or not particularly
significant or made impossible by the small size of the sample, we used an
alternative technique which implies the determination of the coefficients for each
equation in system (12) by substituting the variables' value for dit1erent triplets of
years and moving the triplets down the observations in order to "test" the stability
and robustness of these coet1icients to changes in the years-base.
Figure 7 and 8 represent the synergetic relationships existing between the plastic
and rubber industry and the specialised machinery sector in Varese (where the
measured variable is the number of plants) obtained through both calibration and
econometric estimates.
Both techniques show the existence of synergetic relationships: the development
of one sector fosters the development of the other one. However the two pictures
differ in the dynamical structure. The estimates diagram (Figure 7) shows a saddle
point equilibrium (approximately 350 machinery plants and 650 plastic and rubber
plants) and suggests that while the presence of the machinery industry is vital for
the existence of the plastic and rubber producers (which buy most of their
equipment within the cluster) the relevant market for the machinery industry
(which historically developed after the plastic and rubber one) is the world;
therefore the connections with local producers of plastic and rubber products arc
convenient but no more necessary.
The calibration diagram (Figure 8) suggests a pure symmetric synergetic
interactions in which the carrying capacity of both population grows indefinitely.
Figures 9, 10 and II show the other side of intra-cluster relationships. Figure 9
shows a competitive interaction between footwear industry and the specialised
machinery in Vigevano, when the economic mass is measured by the number of
plants. Figure 10 and II show predator-prey relationships between these two
sectors. The lung run forecasting for this sectors in both cases shows the
development of the machinery sector at the expenses of the footwear industry.
160 M. Fortis and M. A. Maggioni
ijhin
I 400 1 Situation in
1996
/',Machinery 0
~/'"'
I!J ./
200 ~
~
~~ ~'tic=O
_- !!.t
I J,lastic
100 200 300 400 500 600 700 BOO:
Fig. 7. Long run evolution of Plastic and Machinery in Varcsc, number of plants
(estimates).
mac in
1000
Situation in 1996
Fig. 8. Long run evolution of Plastic and Machinery in Varese, number of plants
(calibration).
Competitive and Synergic Behaviours in the Development of Industrial Clusters 161
tlmachinery 0
I'!.I
I'!.ju(}twear = 0
ill
100
1 Situation in 1996
I" ~---.---....--.-.---.----.--.~, - - . _ .........- .. .
Fig. 9. Long run evolution of Footwear and Machinery in Vigevano, number of plants
(estimates).
o tw.
15 0
l!.machinery =0
l!.t
lfrxxa·etJr =0
Situation in tJt
1991
[0 10 A S ~ ----------
3x10 AS 4x10AS
Fig. 10. Long run evolution of Footwear and Machinery in Vigevano, employees
(calibration).
162 M. Fortis and M. A. Maggioni
!::\:<""jootw
I. 80~
\ !:fo()twel1~o
II 600 &
I! Situation in 1991
----_-]i
, -400. I
I 200 ~~_ _
~ _ _-~ -------~--~---------.-.-- D.ma~inery = 0 machin.
I _.
o YX10'4 4xlO'4 6xlO'4 8:<10'4 10'5 1.2xlO'5 1.4xlO'5
Fig. 11. Long run evolution of Footwear and Machinery in VigeVJ.no, employees
(calibration).
4. Conclusion
The paper has shown the relevance of industrial cluster of SMEs in the economic
structure of Italy. The analysis of such a phenomenon. and of its most peculiar
organisational model, the industrial district, have often be based either on isolated
case studies, which were very difficult to compare, or on cross-sectional
econometric analyses, which obtain some general results at the expenses of much
of the individual cluster specificities.
The use of population ecological models may solv(! some of these problems
being explicitly devoted to the analysis of inter-industry and inter-cluster
relationships. The estimation of such models entails several methodological
difficulties which are made worst by the limited availability of data. However, if
this paper succeeds in getting scholars' attention on these techniques and make
them part of the toolbox of industrial economists and the regional scientists, we'll
have reached our main target.
Competitive and Synergic Behaviours in the Development of Industrial Clusters 163
References
Arthur, W. B. (1988), "Urban System and Historical Path Dependency", in: Cities and
Their Vital Systems, Ausubel, J. H. and Herman, R. (eds),Washington D.C., National
Academy Press, pp. 85-97.
Arthur, W. B. (1990), "Silicon Valley Locational Clusters: When Do Increasing Returns
Imply Monopoly?", Mathematical Social Sciences, 19, pp. 235-251.
Beltrami, E. (1987), Mathematics for Dynamic Modelling, Boston, Academic Press.
Capelo, A. C. (1989), Modelli matematici in biologia, Padova, Decibel.
Dendrinos, D. S. and Mullally, H. (1985), Urban Evolution. Studies in the Mathematical
Ecology ofOties, Oxford, Oxford University Press.
Fortis, M. (1998), Il "made in /taly" - Quando stile e creativitii non sono solo moda,
Bologna, II Mulino.
Fortis, M., Clerici, A. and Nodari, A. (1999), "II distretto della rubinetteria-valvolarne del
Piemonte Nord Orientale: Cusio e Valsesia", in: Aree distrettuali prealpine - Meccanica,
lessile, gomma e plaslica, Fortis, M. (cd.), Milano, Franco Angeli.
Fortis, M. and Nodari, A. (1999), "II distretto bresciano della rubinelleria-valvolarne:
Lumezzane", Fortis, M. (ed.), Aree distreltuali prealpine - Meccanica, tessi/e, gomma e
plastica, Milano, Franco Angeli.
Fortis, M., Bassetti, G. and Nodari, A. (1999), "II distretto mantovano delle calze
femminili: Castel Goffredo", in: Aree distrettuali prealpine - Meccanica, tessile, gomma
e plastica, Fortis, M. (cd.), Milano, Franco Angeli.
Fortis, M. and Nodari, A. (200 I), The Role Played by the Industrial Districts in the ltallan
Valve, Tap and Fitting Sectors, paper presented at CEIR (Comitato Europeo Industrie
Rubinetterie) General Committee, Venezia, 11-12 June.
Gambarotto, F. and Maggioni, M. A. (1998), Regional Development Strategies in
Changing Environments: an Ecological Approach, Regional Studies, 32, pp. 49-61.
Gause, G. F. (1934), The Struggle for Existence, Baltimore, Williams & Wilkins.
[sard, W. (1956), Location and Space-economy, Cambridge (Mass.), MIT Press.
Kingsland, S. H. (1985), Modelling Nature. Episodes in the History of Population Ecology,
Chicago, The University of Chicago Press.
Levin, S. A. (1970), "Community Equilibria and Stability, and an Extension of the
Competitive Exclusion Principle", American Naturalist, 108, pp. 207-228.
Levins, R. (1968), Evolution in Changing Environments: Some Theoretical Explorations,
Princeton, Princeton University Press.
Lotka, A. 1. (1925), Elements of Physical Biology, Baltimore, Williams & Wilkins.
Maggioni, M. A. (1993), Ecological Dynamics and Critical Mass Processes in the
Location of High Tech Firms, paper presented at the 40th RSAI (Regional Sciences
Association International) Conference, North American Section, Houston, 11-14
November.
Maggioni, M. A. (1999), Clustering Dynamics and the Location of High-Tech Firms, Ph.D
Thesis, Coventry (UK), University of Warwick, July, forthcoming by Springer Verlag,
Heidelberg.
Maggioni, M. A. (1994), "Modelli ecologici per l'analisi della dinamica industriale
regionale", in: Modelli d'analisi e d'intervento per unnuovo regionalismo, Pasquini, E,
Pompili, T. and Secondini, P. (eds), Milano, Franco Angeli, pp. 79-105.
Maggioni, M. A. and Gambarotto, F. (1997), "Sviluppo locale, dinarniche globali e molo
dell'operatore pubblico: un modello ecologico", m: La dinamica dei sistemi produttivi
164 M. Fortis and M. A. Maggioni
Abstract. This highly preliminary work attempts to study the multiple drivers of
agglomeration phenomena in contemporary economies and proposes a tentative
taxonomy where the conditions of knowledge accumulation, often specific-to-
specific locations and specific sectors, playa paramount role. We discuss the
achievements and limitations of current theorizing on spatial location of economic
activities, and we propose a simple model, which is estimated on Italian data,
highlighting the rich intersectoral diversity of agglomeration forces, together with,
in a few cases, also lack of them.
1. Introduction
lSupport to the research by the Italian Ministery of University and Research (MURST,
Project No. 2-13-2-E4099GD) is gratefully acknowledged. Roberto Monducci from the
Italian Statistical Office (ISTAT) has been, as usual, exceptionally supportive. Marco
Lippi, Carolina Castaldi, Deborah Tappi and several participants to the conference
"Complexity and Industrial Clusters: Dynamics and Models in Theory and Practice",
Milan, June 2001, organized by the Fondazione Comunita e Innovazione, have offered
precious comments.
168 G. Bottazzi, G. Dosi and G. Fagiolo
and behaviours of individual agents; (ii) interaction patters; and, ultimately, (iii)
individual and collective performances. In turn, this means that sheer geography.
together with institutional and technological specificities, ought to be studied in
their long-term effects upon economic structures and relative efficiencies. Even
when going along with many our fellow economists in (the admittedly despicable
practice of) blackboxing institutional diversities across nations and regions, one
should nonetheless be able to track intersectoral differences in the agglomeration
drivers exerted by technological factors. This is the first point that we shall
address below (Section 2). Second, an assessment - albeit quite telegraphic - of the
state-of-the-art of diverse strands of "economic geography" might help in t1agging
out achievements, standing shortcomings and challenges ahead (Section 3).
Theories on agglomeration (and dispersion) forces urgently demand stronger links
with empirical predictions. This is what we begin to explore in Section 4, while in
Section 5 we put our techniques to work on three - quite diverse - industrial
sectors on Italian data (i.e. primary metals, transport equipment and furniture).
Broader conjectures will be put forth in the conclusions (Section 6) of a report -
we want to emphasize - which is very much preliminary and "work-in-progress".
20n the Italian evidence about industrial districts, see, among the others, Signorini (2000),
Brusco and Paba (1997) and Onida et al. (1992).
On the Ubiquitous Nature of the Agglomeration Economies and Their Diverse Determinants 169
3This is indeed the thesis of Klepper (2000) concerning the role of the Detroit area in
automobiles.
4While the contribution to exports rather than production is admittedly less than perfect, it
allows - in Italy - those higher levels of disaggregation often corresponding to "industrial
districts" .
STable A 1 (see Appendix A) provides the complete list of 4-digit sectors accounted in
Figure 1 with the respective contributions by districts to the total Italian exports.
_--
170 G. Bottazzi. G. Dosi and G. Pagiolo
. . . . .....
... I'
~I
'\. I
, I
~I
1,&01
I
l,E.{)2
-I
l,E~+-----------------------------------------------------~
l,DE+OD 1 ,CE+ 01 l,CE+O<
loc(Ra1K)
Fig. 1. Log of Districts' contribution to Total Italian exports by product category vs. Log of
Rank (Ateco 91 Classification), Year: 1996,
Source: ISTAT, Censimento Intermedio de\1'Industria e dei Servizi. See also App. A, Table
AI.
1,~OBr-------------------------------------------------------,
'- ",
' .. ...........
1,E+01
1,E+OD+-----------------~------------------__- - - - - - - - - - - -____~
1,CE-OB 1.= Icc(Ralk)
1,CE..Q1
"70 .. 0 ":,
..- . - - - - - - - . - . - - - . - - - - - -•.-.--.---.-.---.... -...--.----'-',
60" (I ( 1 j - - - : = l E : : : : : - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - '
10,0
6The Italian ATECO 91 classi fication of sectors into Pavitt's taxonomy is available from
the authors upon request.
7"Supplier-dominated" is an unfortunate and somewhat misleading name for a set of
industries which might well be characterized by a lot of product differentiation (e.g. related
to fashion) and organizational innovations, but at the same time acquire most of their
technological innovations via intermediate and capital inputs produced elsewhere. Textiles,
clothing, furniture, lOys, etc. are good examples of such a set of industries.
172 G. Bottazzi. G. Dosi and G. Fagiolo
thereafter. At the international level, sectors like steel, automobiles, tires and
many others appeared quite spatially concentrated near the time of their birth, but
became geographically much more footloose. In fact, it could well be that
geographical stickiness falls whenever: (a) specific technological paradigms
become fully established; and (b) international oligopolistic firms emerge,
incorporating the core knowledge associated with production and innovations.
There are two general conjectures which stem from the foregoing evidence,
namely:
1. The drivers of agglomeration economies are often nested in the nature of
sector-specific patterns of knowledge accumulation.
2. Relatedly, cross-sectional differences in agglomeration forces ought to be
at least partly explained on the grounds of underlying differences in such
processes of technological and organizational learning. They affect
among others the relative importance of phenomena such as localized
knowledge spillovers; inter- vs. intra-organizational learning; knowledge
complementarities fuelled by localized labour-mobility; innovative
explorations undertaken through spin-oft's and, more generally, the birth
of new firms.
To what extent are such knowledge-related drivers accounted for in the current
literature? This is what we shall briet1y discuss in the next section.
In a nutshell, one might identify four main questions that scholars concerned about
the "spatial dimension" of economic interactions have been all trying to address,
albeit from different perspectives, for more than a century, namely: (i) What is the
role of mere "chance" in the observed spatial concentration of economic
activities? (ii) Relatedly, why and when could one observe persistent spatial
patterns that cannot be explained by resorting to pre-existing heterogeneity in
agents and locations (i.e. by some kind of "comparative advantage theory" alone)?
(iii) Could one neatly identify agglomeration (centripetal) and dispersion
(centrifugal) forces lying at the heart of the processes generating sustained spatial
concentration (and possibly its destabilization)? And, (iv) how and when emerging
spatial structures of production and innovation tend to become self-sustained over
time? (And, conversely, what make them wither away?). As well known,
pioneering works such as Von Thunen (1826) and Marshall (1890), tried to
investigate the main economic forces driving geographical differentiation and
agglomeration. For instance, Von Thunen's simple analysis of land use - by
stressing the importance of space constraints in decentralized economies -
addressed the relationships between micro and macro geographical outcomes.
Even more importantly, Marshall's discussion of his famous "localization
9That is: (i) backward/forward linkages associated to the trade-off between market-size and
market-access; (ii) informational spillovers and (iii) advantages of thick markets for
specialized local providers of inputs.
IOSee among others Krugman (1991 a, 1991 b, 1993), Krugman and Venables (1995a,
1995b, 1996), Venables (1996, 1998), Ottaviano and Thisse (1998), Fujita, Krugman and
Venables (1999), Puga and Venables (1996). See also Ottaviano and Puga (1998), Fujita
and Thisse (1996).
174 G. Bottazzi, G. Dosi and G. Fagiolo
though these models have been dealing only with one element of the Marshall's
proposed triad 17 , thus neglecting issues as informational spillovers and the
advantages of thick markets for specialized local providers of inputs, they need to
rely on highly disputable oversimplifications in order to retain elegance and
analytical tractability, such as the special Dixit-Stiglitz framework itself and
Samuelson's scheme of transportation costs (i.e. no description of a separated
transportation sector), to name a few ls . In our view, the commitment to
mainstream formalism of an "equilibrium cum fully rational agents" framework
(and to analytical solutions) has strongly limited the explicative power of "New
Geographical Economics,,19. In fact, notwithstanding verbal acknowledgment of
the very dynamic nature of any spatial agglomeration processes (Fujita et al.
1999), the treatment of dynamics in their models is admittedly unsatisfactory. So,
instead of following their own mainstream prescriptions and endogeneizing
dynamics as the outcome of intertemporal maximization problems by economic
agents, Fujita et al. (1999) discuss issues of stability and selection among multiple
equiiibria in an essentially static framework. Finally, the list of empirically
testable implications that such models are able to provide is intrinsically quite
poor and always of an indirect nature (Martin 1999, p. 70). Even more
dramatically, "New Geographical Economics" formalizations do not lend
themselves to generate testable implications about industry distributions across
locations, so that there is very little hope that any predictions about e.g. rank-size
relationships could be ever taken to the data employing such models. Despite
"New Geographical Economics" has often been claimed to be the most prominent
attempt to provide a unified framework for spatial economics (as well as the sole
robust answer to the resurgence of interest in agglomeration issues recently
prompted by real-world concerns such as European market integration), there
actually exist at least three other broad streams of research that in the last decades
have been trying, in partly complementary ways, to open up the black box of
spatial issues in economics with quite eclectic theoretical spectacles. First, many
scholars have been providing rich and qualitative analyses, mostly (but not
entirely) empirically focused, of urban/regional development and industrial
agglomeration phenomena. In particular, by thoroughly analysing the role of
externalities and technological spillovers, as well as the importance of social,
cultural and institutional forces in shaping the rise and the decline of industrial
districts, these authors have been providing a huge amount of illuminating insights
17That is the backward/forward linkages associated to the trade-off between market-size and
market-access.
18Notice also that these models do not allow for any treatment of uncertainty. On the
contrary. static models based on spatial competition (i.e. the so-called "shipping" and
"shopping" models) introduced some uncertainty in consumers' perceptions of payoffs
from locational choices. See e.g. Anderson, de Palma and Thisse (1992).
19 A similar point about "New Geographical Economics" has been also made by Martin
(1999). However, we do not agree with his analysis of Polya-Urns type models (Arthur
1994). as the latter class of formalizations clearly avoid any commitment to concepts like
full rationality and general equilibrium. See also below.
176 G. Bottazzi. G. Dosi and G. Fagiolo
20We refer here to a huge body of literature covering both "economic geography" studies
(see Lee and Willis 1997 for a survey; and the references in Martin 1999). and in particular.
the Italian studies on industrial districts, see Antonelli (1990. 1994), Brusco (1989). Sforzi
(1989), Becattini (1990). Brusco and Paba (1997). Signorini (2000), Tattara (2001).
21See e.g. Cantwell (1989) and Cantwell and Iammarino (1998).
22See however Arthur (1994), Dosi, Ermoliev and Kaniovski (1994) and Dosi and
Kaniovski (1994) for more detailed discussions.
23The assumption of sequential one-time decisions is not actually crucial. See e.g. David et
al. (1998) for an example in which firms are allowed to revise their current choice from
time to time.
On the Ubiquitous Nature of the Agglomeration Economies and Their Di verse Determinants 177
to an invariant dynamical process, That is, we shall try to capture the idea that the
actual distribution of plants on the territory keeps changing with the passing of
time, even if generated by a stationary probability distribution, The probabilistic
character of our model, when it comes to firms location choices, can be thought as
taking in account the plausible existence of different "unobservable" constraints
that shape the locational incentives of different plants (or firms), Notice that the
ongoing displacement of plants (firms) can be thought of as the actual change of
location of a given production activity, as well as the death of a plant/firm in a
given location and the birth of a similar one in a different place. In order to
simplify the treatment, we consider the number of firms constant along the system
evolution. (Indeed, one can think to the number of firms as an "average" over the
period of observation 24 ). Suppose to have N firms distributed over M distinct
locations. Consider the occupation number vector
which provides the number of firms belonging to each location. If, in a "heroic"
simplification, one assumes that all firms are identical, the vector n completely
specifies the state of the system. The dynamical evolution of such a system can be
described as a finite Markov chain. Let P{n'l n) be generic element of the
transition matrix, i.e. the probability that if the state of the system is n at time t, its
state at time t + 1 would be n'. This probability does not depend explicitly on time
and its specification completely defines our model. In order to capture the effect
produced on the distribution of plants by the presence of agglomeration
economies, the probability that a firm moves to a given location should depend on
the number of firms already located there. Moreover, it is straightforward to
introduce some degree of heterogeneity among locations: this can be done by
allowing for intrinsic "geographical benefits", in general heterogeneous across
locations (in analogy with Arthur 1994). Finally, for the sake of simplicity, we
assume that just one firm changes location at a given time 25 . At each time step, a
firm is chosen at random with equal probability liN and exits the industry. Then a
randomly chosen, new firm enters a location with a probability proportional to the
sum of the number of firms already there and a "geographical benefit" term. The
transition element thus becomes:
24Notice that if one is on the contrary interested in the actual time evolution of the
plant/firm distributions, the exact specification of the entry/exit dynamics becomes
mandatory.
25Notice that this assumption has no effect whatsoever on the form of the invariant
distribution of the process.
On the Ubiquitous Nature of the Agglomeration Economies and Their Diverse Determinants 179
k :f: i
(2)
k =i
where a = (al, ... , aM) is the array of intrinsic "benefits" for the M locations, A =
I.~=I ak and 6., = (0, ... , 1, ... ,0) is the unitary vector with i-th component equal
to 1. Some considerations are in order. First, notice that the intrinsic benefit ak is
proportional to the probability of choosing location k when the latter is empt/6 .
Second, we have chosen the simplest linear relationship between the probability of
choosing a location and the number of firms already there27 • In fact, a more
realistic account of location-specific returns to agglomeration should allow for the
dependence of the a terms upon the number of plants/firms located there and/or
for threshold effects. However, as we shall see, even the foregoing simpler
approximation does not fare too badly with the data 28 . For positive a's, each
location has a positive probability of receiving the entering firm: hence, any
possible state of the system is reachable, in a suitable number of steps, with finite
probability starting from any other state and the Markov chain defined by (2) is
irreducible. If pen, t) is the probability to find the system in state n at time t, its
evolution reads:
The explicit expression for the invariant distribution, known as the M-dimensional
Polya distribution, can be easily obtained and reads:
2~is model is known as Ehrefest-Brillouin model and has been introduced in Garibaldi
and Penco (2000) as a generalization of the famous Ehrefest model of statistical physics. A
similar simplified version has been introduced in Kirman (1993).
27This model overlaps with the Arthur's one with linear returns function, see Arthur (1994).
28Moreover, negative values for the a's can be in principle considered, in order to describe
the presence of agglomeration diseconomies characterizing the distribution of firms over
the different locations. Nonetheless, the purely random exit dynamics constitutes, as such, a
limit to the actual concentration of plants/firms in a given site, since more populated sites
are also more likely to yield dying ones.
180 G. Bottazzi, G. Dosi and G. Fagiolo
The values of the parameters ak determine the nature of the distribution: for lower
values of the a parameters, the effect of agglomeration becomes more relevant In
the limit ak ~ + 00 and aJak ~ 1 for any i and k, "agglomeration economies"
disappear and the expression in (5) reduces to a multinomial distribution, while for
ak = 1, \j k it becomes what is known in statistical physics as the Bose-Einstein
distribution.
In the following we shall use this expression, whose parameter will be set by a
fitting procedure, in order to compare the prediction of our model with the
empirical observations. We shall use a database from the Italian Census of
Manufacturers for the year 1996 containing business units (BUs) belonging to ]l/I
= 784 "local system of labour mobility" (LSLM, for a definition see Sforzi 2000)
and to L = 25 different sectors for a total of 591,110 local units (plants). Here, we
present some experiments over three sectors - primary metals, transport equipment
and furniture - which one should expect to display different degrees of
agglomeration economies and different drivers of the latter (see also the
taxonomic discussions of Section 2). Let ni,l be the number of BUs in LSLM i
operating in sector l. Moreover we denote with n.,1 the total number of BUs
operating in sector l and with ni,. the total number of BUs belonging to i-th
LSLM. As already mentioned, instead of considering average quantities
measuring the "strength of agglomeration" of a given sector (as done, for instance,
in Sforzi, 1991) we shall analyse the complete "occupancy distribution" of the
BUs in the various LSLM, i.e. we compute the observed frequency (obs.(h;l) with
which a LSLM hosting exactly h BUs active in sector l appears in our data:
On the Ubiquitous Nature of the Agglomeration Economies and Their Diverse Determinants 181
1 M
/ob, (h;l) = M L(\"h (7)
1=1
where 8 is the Kronecker (index) function, and we compare this expression with
the theoretical prediction of (6), once having of course specified the parameters a
characterizing the theoretical distribution. As a first benchmark, one could
consider all the LSLM as equal (i.e. with the same "intrinsic appeal") and obtain a
theoretical expression directly from (6) putting ai = and A = M f3 This f3 .
model would depend on a single parameter f3 which measures the "strength" of
the agglomeration effect - with a low f3
meaning high agglomeration economies.
However, tests of this model yield quite bad agreement with data, and the
theoretical description constantly underestimates the observed distribution tails.
The reason for this becomes apparent if one plots, for a given sector l, the number
of BUs ILi,l of a LSLM against the total number of BUs in all the other sectors,
except the one under consideration (that is ILi,. - ILi,I). Under the previous
assumption of a priori equiprobability, no dependence should appear between the
two variabks, since BUs belonging to different sectors should choose their
locations independently. On the contrary, a strong positive correlation appears
which contradicts the purported identity between the various LSLM's: we plot the
result of this analysis in Fig. 4, for the three chosen sectors. The parameters fitted
from a log-linear regression are reported in Table 1.
Table 1. The "agglomeration" parameter f3 and the slope a of the linear regression by
sector and by LSLM.
n -n
a = f3 I,.I,/ (8)
1,1 'N-n.,1
where l is the sector under analysis and the f3, coefficient captures, as above, the
intensity of agglomeration economies. This procedure meant to capture also
182 G. Bottazzi, G. Dosi and G. Fagiolo
(9)
~"vf
where p is the distribution in (6) and A,= L.J,=1 ai,' . As can be seen in Figs. 5
through 7, the accordance of the theoretical prediction with data is quite high. The
values of the f3's used for the theoretical curves are reported in Table 1. Out of
the three sectors chosen, the first, primary metals, does show an almost total lack
of agglomeration effects, while the other two, transport equipment and furniture,
seems to display rather high agglomeration economies. Notice, however, that the
nature of such an agglomeration is actually very different for the latter two
sectors: transport equipment displays a scattered locational patterns made-up of
relatively few firms (possibly hinting at the "hierarchical agglomerations"
mentioned in Section 2), while furniture highlights more "district-like" patterns,
On the Ubiquitous Nature of the Agglomeration Economies and Their Diverse Determinants 183
11 11
t¥'-.-,. .
+
10 10 :!J)
++ -.j.
9 9 +
:j:I:"'+A
8 8 ++. + ,.01 1 4 ,,"
7
itt
-L
7
6
5 6
4 5
3 4
2 3
01234 567 8 9 (I 1 2 3 4 5 6
11
10
9
8
7
6
5 data ?Oi:-lt 3 +
4 li:1ear fit -----
...,3
...
(I 1 2 3 4 567 8 9
Fig. 4. Total number of plants in a LSLM (Local System of Labour Mobility) vs. the number
of plants in that location pertaining to a specific sector. a) primary metal, b) transport
equipment, c) furniture. All the variables arc in log scale.
Source: ISTAT, Censimento Intermedio dell' Industria e dei Servizi, 1996.
184 O. Bottazzi. O. Dusi and O. Fagiolo
O. C\.:l
data +
+ The or . "'ght.
0.035
(1.03
+
0.025
0.02
0.015
0.01
0.005
(I
1 10 100 1000
Fig. 5. Frequencies and number of tirms by LSLM (Local System of Labour Mobility). The
primary metal sector.
Source: 1STAT, Censi mento Intermedio dell' Industria e dei Servizi. 1996.
On the Ubiquitous Nature of the Agglomeration Economies and Their Diverse Determinants 18S
0.14
data +
TheQr. Wght.
\,
--~---
0.12 ,
\
0.1
\
0.03 \
0.06
,
0.04
\+
\\+
\
0.02 " +
-t-x+
1 10 100 1000
Fig. 6: Frequencies and number of firms by LSLM (Local System of Labour Mobility). The
transport equipment sector.
Source: 1STAT, Censimento Intermedio dell' Industria e dei Servizi, 1996.
186 G. Bottazzi, G. Dosi and G. Fagiolo
0,08
data +
, The or . !·'ght.
0.07
,,
,,
0.06 , +
0.05
't\
';.;
+
0.04
-...x, ++
0.03 \<., +
"x,
0.02
'''-t
0.01
0
1 10 100 1000
Fig. 7. Frequencies and number of tirms by LSLM (Local System of Labour Mobility). The
furniture sector.
Source: ISTAT, Censimento Intermedio dell'Industria e dei Servizi, 1996.
6. Conclusions
Table Al (continued)
43 Pesticides and other agro-chemical products 0,432
45 Other articles of concrete, plaster and cement 0,428
46 Other non-metallic mineral products 0,423
47 Production and distribution of electricity 0,418
48 Electricity distribution and control apparatus O~~
49 Other general purpose machinery 0,417
50 Insulated wire and cable 0,406
51 Bricks, tiles and construction products. in baked clay_ 0,398
52 Other electrical equipment 0,391
53 Beverages 0,385
54 Non-electric domestic appliances 0,383
55 Manufacture and processing of other glass including technical 0,382
Iglassware
56 Bicycles 0.373
57 Pharmaceutical preparations 0,353
58 Processing and preserving of fish and tish products 0.353
59 Paints, varnishes and similar coatings, printing ink and mastics 0.352
60 Watches and clocks 0.341
61 Paper and paperboard 0,322
62 Parts and accessories for motor vehicles and their engines 0.320
63 Precious metals production 0.317
64 Other food products 0,317
65 Bodies (coachwork) for motor vehicles; trailers and semi-trailers 0,312
66 Soap and detergents, cleaning and polishing preparations 0,302
67 Builders' carpentry and joinery 0,294
68 Man-made fibres 0,292
69 Printing 0,287
70 Basic iron and steel and of ferro-alloys 0,276
71 Instr. and appliances for measur., checking, testing, navigating, 0,275
exc.industrial process.
72 Milk and cheese products '0,258
73 Luggage, handbags and the like, saddlery and harness 0,257
74 Other rubber products 0,240
75 Processing and preserving of fruit and vegetables 0,238
76 Other organic basic chemicals 0,220
77 Printing of newspapers 0,218
78 Television and radio receivers, sound or video recording or reproducing 0,202
apparatus
79 Prepared feeds for farm animals 0,191
80 Other chemical products 0,188
81 Tobacco industry 0,188
82 Motor vehicles 0,170
83 Railway and tramway locomotives and rolling stock 0,168
84 Steam generators (central heating exel.) 0,160
85 Crude oils and fats 0,155
86 Starch and related products 0,136
87 Renting of office machinery and equipment including computers 0,132
88 Basic pharmaceutical Ploduets 0,130
On the Ubiquitous Nature of the Agglomeration Economies and Their Diverse Determinants 189
Table A 1. (continued)
89 Aircraft and spacecraft 0,128
90 Nuclear fuels treatment 0,078
91 Building and repairing of ships 0,062
92 Electronic valves and tubes and other electronic components 0,050
93 Television and radio transmitters and apparatus for line telephony and 0,047
line telegr.
94 Refined petroleum products 0,008
95 Coke and coal related products 0,001
References
Anderson, S. P., dePalme, A. and Thisse, 1. F. (1992), Discrete Choice Theory of Product
Differentiation, Cambridge, MIT Press.
Antonelli, C. (1990), "Induced Adoption and Externalities in the Regional Diffusion of
Information Technology", Regional Studies, 24, pp. 31-40.
Antonelli, C. (1994), "Technology Districts, Localized Spillovers, and Productivity
Growth: The Italian Evidence on Technological Externalities in Core Regions",
International Review of Applied Economics, 12, pp. 18-30.
Arthur, W. B. (1994), Increasing Returns and path-dependency in Economics, Ann Arbor,
Uni versity of Michigan Press.
Barca, F. (ed.) (1997), Storia del Capitalismo Italiano dal dopoguerra ad oggi, Roma.
Donzelli.
Becattini, G. (1990), "TIle Marshallian Industrial District as a Socio-economic Notion", In:
Industrial Districts and Inter-Firm Cooperation, Pyke, F., Becattini, G. and
Sengenberger, W. (cds), Geneva, International Institute for Labour Studies.
Boltazzi, G. (2001), "A Stochastic Model of Firms Location", Laboratory of Economics
and Management (LEM) Working Paper, S. Anna School of Advanced Studies,
Forthcoming.
Brugnoli, A. and Fachin, S. (2000), "Concentrazione e Diffusione: la Geografia Industriale
Italiana, 1981-1991 ", Economia e Politica Industriale, 27, pp. 103-128.
Brusco, S. (1989), Piccole Imprese e Distretti Indl/striali, Torino, Rosenberg and Sellier.
Brusco, S. and Paba, S. (1997), "Per una storia dei distretti industriali italiani dal secondo
dopoguerra agli anni novanta", in: Storia del Capitalismo Italiano dal dopoguerra ad
oggi, Barca, F. (ed.), 1997.
Cantwell, J. A. (1989), Technological Innovations and Multinational Corporations.
Oxford, Basic Books.
Cantwell, J. A. and Iammarino, S. (1998), "MNCs, Technological Innovation and Regional
Systems in the EU: Some Evidence in the Italian Case", International Journal of the
Economics of Business,S, pp. 383-408.
Christaller, W. (1933), Central Places in Southern Germany, Jena, Fischer.
Cowan, R. and Cowan, W. (1998), "On Clustering in the Location of R&D: Statics and
Dynamics", Economics of Innovation and New Technology, 6, pp. 201-229.
David, P. A., Foray, D. and Daile, J. M. (1998), "Marshallian Externalities and the
Emergence of Spatial Stability and Technological Enclaves", Economics of Innovation
and New Technology, 6, pp. 147-182.
Dixit, A. K. and Stiglitz, J. E. (1977), "Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product
Diversity", American Economic Review, 67, pp. 297-308.
190 G. Bottazzi. G. Dosi and G. Fagiolo
1. Introduction
lprepared for the conference on Complexity and Industrial Clusters - Dynamics and
Models in Theory and Practice organized by the Fondazione Comunitu e Innovazione
under the aegis of the Accademia Nazionale dei Lincei, held in Milan, Italy on June 19 and
20, 200!. We are indebted to the individuals who agreed to interviews and generously
shared their time and expertise in identifying salient issues as well as providing and
validating information.
196 M. P. Feldman and 1. Francis
institutions (Nelson 1993) and way in which entrepreneurs actively interact with
their local environments (Saxenian 1994).
This paper examines the impact of the initial spark of entrepreneurship and how
it influences the formation of high technology clusters. The perspective taken is
that entrepreneurs are a critical element in the formation of clusters and their
actions are important to the analysis of clusters as complex adaptive systems. In
addition, we consider how this perspective and the role of entrepreneurship may
influence development policy. Historical studies document the genesis and
development of successful clusters, however this line of inquiry is not well
integrated into conceptualisations of regional change. Moreover, emulation does
not necessarily lead to success. Silicon Valley's early successes in the electronic
industry, spawned replicates across the country, many of which never took hold
(Leslie and Kargon 1994). Although critical components of the Silicon Valley
success are readily identified, it is not merely a matter of replicating them in new
locations. It is not only the components themselves that matter, but the way in
which they are combined to give rise to a self-reinforcing innovative system
(Kargon, Leslie and Schoenberger 1992). Thus, our perspective, in contrast,
focuses on the role of change agents and relies on concepts from the developing
literature on complex systems. In effect, we propose that entrepreneurs are the key
that unlocks untapped potential in the local environment and sparks economic
growth.
We also focus on individual decisions to form a company and examine how
these decisions are influenced by regional context. The specific case considered is
the development of the U.S. Capitol region 2 . By any number of measures, this
region, which was previously dominated by government employment, lacked the
attributes conventional wisdom associates with an entrepreneurial environment.
Yet, the Capitol Region has established technological leadership based on
entrepreneurial activity in biotechnology and the Internee - two new industries
that have seeded and established themselves in the past twenty years. We focus on
the evolution of this region, specifically on the development of an industrial
cluster as a series of three phases. In the initial phase, early entrepreneurial efforts
emphasized serving existing government agencies and most entrepreneurs were
from the private sector. The second phase is dominated by increased
entrepreneurial activity as an adaptation to a series of changes in the external
environment. These efforts were a response to creative crisis due to federal
downsizing as well as to new opportunities precipitated by changes in the legal
framework - the local effect of changes in the policy environment. During this
stage, entrepreneurs defined resources to promote and protect their interests. In
2The U.S. Capitol Region is considered here as the Consolidated Metropolitan Statistical
Area (CMSA) which includes Washington D.C., Northem Virginia and the Maryland
Suburbs including Baltimore City and its environs. Two counties in West Virginia were
added in 1990.
3Within the region, there is evidence of geographic differentiation. Biotechnology is
primarily concentrated in the Maryland suburbs in Gaithersburg and along the 1-270
Corridor. The Internet companies are concentrated in the Northem Virginia suburbs.
The Entrepreneurial Spark: Individual Agents and the Formation of Innovative Clusters 197
The region around the U.S. Capitol has recently emerged as a hotbed of
entrepreneurial activity, wealth creation and economic growth. This recognition
reflects a transformation of the region from an economy dominated by public
sector employment that was neither innovative nor supportive of private sector
activity (Feldman forthcoming). In an attempt to understand this transformation,
we have studied the genesis of entrepreneurial efforts. Our analysis is an
interpretive summary based on interviews with entrepreneurs in biotechnology
and ICT. The interviews gathered information on: where entrepreneurs were
employed prior to starting their companies, what the motivation was for starting
their companies, what resources they used in developing their companies and the
technologies and the subsequent spin-off activity they generated.
There are some methodological issues to mention. First, it is important to note
that this is a retrospective study. We are limited to identifying firms in existence
now or that were at one time prominent enough to leave a record. While we are
able to trace these firms back to their founding, we have no knowledge of similar
firms that were started but may have failed, been acquired or merged into other
198 M. P. Feldman and J. Francis
firms prior to cur stud/. This approach does allow us to consider the roots of
successful entrepreneurship and the ways in which entrepreneurial activity took
hold, but it cannot address the failure of enterprises that died without leaving a
record. While each of these companies has its own unique and compelling
founding story, our objective is to discern trends and patterns.
The Capitol region has the third largest concentration of biotech companies in
the United States (PricewaterhouseCoopers 1998). Leading companies in the
region include Human Genome Sciences (HGS) and Celera Genomics
Corporation, two key actors in the international effort to map the human genome.
In addition, another local company, Medlmmune, is currently the world's eighth
largest dedicated biotech company with six FDA approved products on the
market. In total, there are approximately 300 Small and Medium Sized (SME)
biotech firms in the region as of 2001. The establishment of the industry was
chosen to be the mid-1970s, as Stanley Cohen and Herbat Boyer invented their
genetic engineering techniques in 1973. These techniques gave rise to the modern
commercial biotech industry.
The earliest entrepreneurs in the Capitol region started firms during the time
when many prominent national firms such as Amgen and Genentech formed.
These early entrepreneurs were previously employed at large supplier firms to the
National Institutes of Health (NIH). The presence of the NIH, as the U.S. agency
whose mandate is to oversee health and medical research, is a defining
characteristic of the Capitol region. It employs a large number of researchers at the
agencies' home campus in Bethesda, Maryland. The NIH has been a spawning
ground for new company start-ups, particularly in the last ten to fifteen years.
Other government institutes and agencies, such as the Walter Reed Army Institute
for Research (WRAIR) and the U.S. Food and Drug Administration have also
been a significant source of biotechnology entrepreneurs. Although the region's
universities have generated new companies, their involvement is more recent and
was not apparent at the earliest stages. While the initial entrepreneurs came from
large corporation and government institutions, new start-up firms became
particularly fruitful in generating second, third and fourth generation start-ups.
The Information and Communications Technologies (lCT) industry also has a
strong presence in the Capitol Region with a concentration in Northern Virginia.
According to some sources, the region may be regarded as the birthplace of the
Internet5 . Prominent companies in the region include MCI, AOL, NexTel, and
PSINet. Over 400 SMEs may be considered as ICT firms located in the area 6 •
4Such a study would involve access to a source of historical data on firms such as tax or
employment records to discern when the firms came into existence and when they ceased to
exist. This approach would be limited because the smallest and most typical form of start-
up, the sole proprietorship, might not be captured.
5For example, the Virginia Economic Development Partnership uses this slogan
(http://yesvirginia.org/wva-be.html).
6There is no accepted definition of the leT industry and estimates of the number of entities
in the region vary widely and appear to be influenced by media-hype. This is the authors'
conservative estimate.
The Entrepreneurial Spark: Individual Agents and the Formation of Innovative Clusters 199
Companies in the region supply half the total worldwide Internet backbone
(PricewaterhouseCoopers 1998).
The modern computer networking technologies that are the backbone of the
Internet and ICT emerged in the early 1970s from the U.S. Department of Defense
Advanced Research Projects Agency (variously called ARPA and DARPA) (see
Kahn and Cerf 1999 for more detail). Individuals leaving the Department of
Defense (DOD) and the allied services formed the earliest start-ups. In addition,
individuals from private industry, both within the region and from outside, figure
prominently. Area universities are notably absent from this list.
While biotech and ICT are very different industries, the objective here is to
discern patterns in the origins of the companies and to explore the temporal
development of entrepreneurial activity. Several notable patterns emerge. First,
entrepreneurs hail from a variety of different prior organizations. Government
agencies served an important incubator function in both industries; however, they
were not the sole source of entrepreneurial talent. There is evidence of great
diversity in entrepreneur's backgrounds. Second, the earliest start-ups were
service firms, not originally involved in the types of R&D activities that generate
new industries. Firms such as Bethesda Research Labs and AMS were not
launched as product development firms although they evolved in that direction
over time. Thus, the industry had rather humble beginnings - not the type of start-
up that would attract much attention from investors, the media or local economic
development officials. Third, entrepreneurship picks up momentum. Over time,
generations of new firms spun-off from the earliest start-ups and entrepreneurs
who cashed in from one new venture created other new companies.
Two basic features in this interpretive history stand out: although the Capitol
region did not have the generally regarded "prerequisites" for high technology
development, a confluence of events created an opportunity for entrepreneurial
individuals to create start-ups. Second is that the organizations and entrepreneurial
ventures co-evolved. Both the biotech and ICT industries had humble beginnings
in the region and initially there was a low level of activity. However, as
entrepreneurship caught hold, the industry as we observe it today began to emerge
and the necessary components to sustain it grew up in the region.
The genesis of entrepreneurship was very different in the Capitol region than
Silicon Valley. Studies of the evolution of Silicon Valley such as Kargon, Leslie
and Schoenberger (1992), emphasize the early input of Frederick Terman, who is
viewed as the founder of the Silicon Valley phenomena. Terman had the goal of
transforming Stanford, circa 1946, into the MIT of the west. As the dean of
engineering at Stanford, he had the desire to foster scientific innovation as part of
the academic process but also to tie entrepreneurial effort and academic
accomplishment together by taking promising young students to visit high
technology start-ups run by Stanford graduates. These young students had a first
hand glimpse at research in application and were able to talk to the Stanford
graduates who had patented their academic research and moved it into an
entrepreneurial enterprise. Terman noted that many early successful young
entrepreneurs had little formal education, and suggested that someone with formal
engineering education and some business knowledge might do even better
200 M. P. Feldman and 1. Francis
3. Emergence of a Cluster
?This affected ICT but also biotechnology. Consider the firm Martek that is a spin-off from
the defence contractor Martin Marietta and was funded by DOD.
8 For examples see Feldman (200 I).
202 M. P. Feldman and 1. Francis
(1996) estimates that the SBIR program has provided over $6 billion to small
high-technology firms between 1983 and 1995.
In conclusion, entrepreneurship in the region was a response to exogenous
factors: underemployed skilled labour brought about by changes in federal
employment policy coupled with new opportunities for the private sector to
contract with the federal government and commercialise new technologies. The
two industries considered here responded to different pressures. The advent of
entrepreneurship was reactive and adaptive. While both sectors benefited from
great opportunity for commercial products, biotechnology was more influenced by
CRADAs and opportunities for licensing and joint product development while
ICT benefited more from outsourcing opportunities. In both cases, locational
inertia kept the entrepreneurs in the area. Over time, the region has developed the
supporting conditions the literature associates with entrepreneurial environments.
The next section considers the ways in which these factors developed.
Although we know a great deal about mature clusters (such as Silicon Valley, CA
and Research Triangle Park, NC), we understand very little about how such
clusters develop and why they occur in certain areas and not others (Leslie and
Kargon 1994). By focusing on the entrepreneur as the spark or agent of change,
we provide a rationale for the emergence of clusters and an understanding of the
dynamic that directs their development. The entrepreneur can be viewed as an
agent who takes existing resources and re-defines, re-combines and re-deploys
them to create new products, services, and organizations (Russell 1996). Through
the process of creating new companies, entrepreneurs spark regional industrial
transformation, a transformation that exhibits path dependence, adaptivity, and
self-organization.
Interestingly, these observations about the role of the entrepreneur and
innovation in industrial transformation were already present in Schumpeter
(1942). Schumpeter placed entrepreneurship and its connection with dynamic
uncertainty in the centre of economic reasoning, by tracing all disrupting
economic change to innovations and identifying the innovator with the
entrepreneur (Blaug 1985). Entrepreneurs, in Schumpeter's view, can be
considered the "spark-plugs" or "flash-points" of creative destruction (Schumpeter
1942). When an environment provides a mix of resources and opportunities,
entrepreneurial individuals will move to capitalize on those opportunities. Their
input creates the initial changes in the regional environment that begin to build on
each other. Bygrave and Hofer (1991, p. 19) suggest, "The essence of the
entrepreneurial process is a fundamental discontinuity in the industry involved".
The entrepreneur is also active within a regional context. Leslie and Kargon
(1994) propose that technology clusters are better thought of as ecologies of
mutually dependent institutions. The entrepreneur then, operates in and activates
his eco-system to his purpose. It is in the creative feedback response of the
The Entrepreneurial Spark: Individual Agents and the Formation of Innovative Clusters 203
5. Self-Organization
There is evidence that the region has achieved a point where it is a self-sustaining
system. Many entrepreneurs sold their companies and started private incubators to
nurture others. These founders were motivated to share their expertise and to build
the region. In addition, at least three angel networks have formed in the last five
years. The Private Investors Network (PIN), the Capital Investors Club and the
Washington Dinner Club are organizations of experienced entrepreneurs who
actively invest in new companies and offer management advice.
Universities in the region have responded to the increased entrepreneurial
activity by offering new programs and building branch operations closer to
commercial activity. For example, Johns Hopkins University offers a Masters
degree in Biotechnology in Silver Spring, Maryland about 50 miles away from the
main Baltimore campus. Virginia Tech University opened a branch campus in
Northern Virginia about 250 miles from their main campus. The draw has been the
number of workers seeking additional training, the opportunities for industry-
funded research and the interaction with industry. Notably, the local universities
have benefited from the philanthropy of local entrepreneurs. For example, George
Mason University began in Fairfax, Virginia in 1950 as a commuter school. It has
grown into Virginia's second-largest university with 18 doctorate programs and a
focus on technology. Donors have given the university millions of dollars to
endow 43 professor chairs, allowing the university to recruit high-profile
professors (O'Harrow and Lipton 1996). All of the universities in the area have
responded with incubators and other programs to encourage entrepreneurship.
Interestingly too, dedicated university involvement in high-technology
enterprise or the promotion of academic-industry transfer occurred only much
later in the Capitol region's development. In Silicon Valley, the opposite story
could be told; the moulding of Stanford as a producer of entrepreneurs and as an
institution that was sensitive to the needs of industry figured prominently in the
success of the region and occurred in the initial phase (Kargon, Leslie and
Schoenberger 1992).
In the Capitol region, legislative programs also followed the initial phase and
addressed the needs of the newly established industry. A group of Virginia
businesspeople organized a broad campaign to advocate state tax increases for
education in order to address a noted shortage of technology workers and provide
greater infrastructure funds (Baker 1995). This initiative attempted to build
infrastructure to support the development of local industry. Rather than seeking
specific requests for their own business, business leaders were promoting a
broader, collectively responsible social agenda (Feldmann 1997). In 2001, the
state of Maryland passed twelve legislative acts focusing on providing a
supportive environment for technology-based economic development. These cover
the full gamut of infrastructure development, training programs and tax incentives.
One more point to consider besides the characteristics of a mature cluster
mentioned here, is that an industrial region reaches full maturity when it is stable
and able to adapt to adverse shocks (Saxenian 1994). Although the history of high
The Entrepreneurial Spark: Individual Agents and the Formation of Innovative Clusters 207
typology. In this regard, the concentrations of resources and highly skilled labour
plus access to sophisticated, demanding technology users were pre-existing
conditions in the region. The transformation to private sector entrepreneurial
growth did not appear to represent movement along a technological trajectory
(Kenney and von Burg 1999) but instead was a sustained effort at capacity
building that involved human agency, adaptation and evolution. Not only this, a
critical point was reached in the development of the region when it jumped from
virtually no high technology start-up activity to intense activity with start-ups per
year numbering in the hundreds.
In the development of an industrial system of innovation, there are many
individual complex stories and personal motivations. It has been said that
government employees and contractors could never become successful private
businesses - the incentives were very different. Government workers, the logic
went, were too removed from the pressures of the market. Government contracts
followed a practice of placing a low bid in order to get the job and then making a
profit by demonstrating a need for change orders in the absence of competition.
This is a very different philosophy from trying to do a job right the first time at the
lowest cost. However, the earliest entrepreneurs in biotechnology and ICT were
government contractors and employees who proved this logic wrong. What is
critical is that the region did provide opportunity for individuals. They began
working for the government but then realized that they could adapt their products
for dual-use commercial markets. Therefore, they moved to commercial markets
and with this development came innovation. Eventually they succeeded. In
essence, this was a phase change from latent to active entrepreneurship.
The entrepreneurial event in the Capitol Region was a response to and
adaptation to changes that were exogenous to the regional system. In this regard,
Federal policies such as downsizing created slack and surplus resources that could
find new and more productive uses. Thus, the gales of Schumpeter's creative
destruction were unleashed. Policies that created a supply of potential
entrepreneurs would not have been sufficient. A complementary set of
government policies aimed at creating demand for ICT and biotechnology services
through government procurement facilitated the transition. Other exogenous
conditions were the policies that provided mechanisms or tools to enable
companies to access resources. These affected the supply of new ideas by creating
access to intellectual property from government investment.
Both biotechnology and ICT are high opportunity technologies facing growing
product demand and therefore are attractive to investors. Firms working in these
technologies face favourable market conditions. The degree to which this is
exogenous may be debated. Good entrepreneurs may create their own opportunity
and thus define the industry. The idea that technology development is endogenous
to cluster development warrants more investigation. Through the actions of key
individual change agents, the configuration of the cluster and the technological
trajectory of the industry may be jointly determined. It does suggest that
companies, industries and regions benefit from the same factors and decisions -
their evolution may be intricately interwoven.
The Entrepreneurial Spark: Individual Agents and the Formation of Innovative Clusters 209
References
Kenny, M. and von Burg, U. (1999), "Technology, Entrepreneurship and Path Dependence:
Industrial Clustering in Silicon Valley and Route 12S", Industrial and Corporate
Change,S, pp. 67-103.
Lazerson, M. H. and Lorenzoni, G. (1999), "The Firms that Feed Industrial Districts: A
Return to the Italian Source", Corporate and Industrial Change, S, pp. 235-266.
Lerner, J. (1996), The Government as Venture Capitalist: The Long-Run Effects of the SBIR
Program, NBER (National Bureau of Economic Research) Working Paper No. W5753.
Leslie, S. and Kargon, R. (1997), "Recreating Silicon Valley", Business History Review.
Leslie, S. and Kargon, R. (1994), "Electronics and the Geography of Innovation in Post-
War America", History and Technology 11, pp. 217-231.
Link, A. N. (1995), A Generosity of Spirit: The Early History of the Research Triangle
Park, Research Triangle Park, The Research Triangle Foundation of North Carolina.
Malerba, F., Nelson, R., Orsenigo, L. and Winter, S. (1999), "History-Friendly Models of
Industry Evolution: The Computer Industry", Industrial and Corporate Change, 8, pp. 3-
40.
Markusen, A. (1996), "Sticky Places in Slippery Space: A Typology of Industrial
Districts", Economic Geography, 72, pp. 293-313.
Marshall, A. (1890), Principles of Economics, London, Macmillan.
Montgomery, D. and Bacon, J. A. (1999), "How Green is Our Valley"? Virginia Business,
March, (http://www.virginiabusiness.comlvbmag/yr 1999/march99/howgreen.html).
Nelson, R. and Winter, S. (1982), An Evolutionary Model of Ecunomic Change, Cambridge
MA, Harvard University Press.
Nelson, R. (1993), National Innovation Systems: a Comparative Analysis, Oxford, Oxford
U ni versity Press.
0' Harrow, R., Jr. and Lipton, E. (1996), "George Mason U. Embroiled in Debate about Its
Mission", Washington Post, 14, p. AI.
Packard, D. (1965), Stanford Engineering News, 17 (22) July.
Porter, M. (1990), The Competitive Advantage of Nations, New York, Free Press.
PricewaterhouseCoopers (1998), Toward a New Economy: Merging Heritage with Vision in
the Greater Washington Region, Washington, D.C., Potomac Knowledge Ways Project
(http://know ledgeway .org/voice/newecon/ho mepage.h tml).
Prevezer, M. (1997), "The Dynamics of Industrial Clustering in Biotechnology", Small
Business Economics, 9, pp. 255-271.
Roberts, E. B. (1991), Entrepreneurs in High Technology, New York, Oxford University
Press.
Russell. R. D. (1996), "The Emergence of Entrepreneurship in Eastern Europe: A Self-
organizing Perspective", International Journal of Commerce and Management, 6, pp. 21-
32.
Saxenian, A (1994), Regional Advantage, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Schumpeter, J. (1942), Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy, New York, Harper
Torchbooks, 3rd edition, 1976
Shostak, A. (1987), "History of the Joint Services Electronics Program", in: Proceedings of
the Fortieth Anniversary of the Joint Services Electronics Program, D. Robb and A.
Shostak (eds), Washington, DC, Battelle Laboratories, pp. 15-46.
Stough, R. R. (2000), The New Generation Technology Economy: Comparative Regional
Analysis and the Case of the u.s. National Capital Region, paper presented at the
American Association for the Advancement of Science meeting in Washington, D.C.,
February 2000.
Stough, R. R., Campbell H., and Haynes, K. E. (1998), "Small Business Entrepreneurship
in the High Technology Services Sector: An Assessment of Edge Cities of the U.S.
National Capital Region", Small Business Economics, V 10, pp. 61-74.
212 M. P. Feldman and J. Francis
Christian Longhi
Abstract. Regional clusters and local organisation of the industry have been
proved to be basic elements of economic growth and innovation. The
understanding of the processes underlying local development is thus pivotal. The
paper attempts to contribute to this aim through the analysis of Toulouse, in the
French southwest region Midi-Pyrenees, and Sophia Antipolis, in the southeast
French Riviera. Both be considered as the outcomes of the French national system
of innovation and the process of decentralisation initiated in the late sixties, and
are today well known centres of high technology activity. But, as the numerous
failed experiences of top-down reinforcement suggest, the factors the two areas
have been endowed cannot explain as such the emergence and development of
local innovative milieux. Considering clusters as evolving open complex systems,
the paper analyses the reconfigurations of the clusters implied by changes in
internal and external conditions that have led to endogenous innovative processes
characteristic of technopoles.
1. Introduction
Since the seventies, regional clusters are object of considerable interest. The
recognition of their distinctive role on the economic and technological scene
became evident with the rise of the industrial districts in the Third Italy. The
districts succeeded to perform better than large firms within the same international
competitive markets because of the great flexibility allowed by the institutional
arrangements set up locally (Becattini 1990). They have represented a kind of
localized achievement of the division of labour where the innovative capabilities
and competitive efficiency have arisen from organisational designs established by
the firms, arranged in networks of specialized sub-contractors in vertically
disintegrated processes of production (Brusco 1982) Another important
development has been the emergence of high tech clusters based on the knowledge
base developed in the universities, as happened in the Silicon Valley or
Cambridge, UK (Saxenian 1994; Garnsey 1998).
Despite very different features regarding industries or resource bases, these
clusters have in common local endogenous processes of development triggered by
innovative SMEs. These models have promoted regional clusters and local
organisation of the industry as basic elements of the economic growth. As clearly
214 C. Longhi
stated by Porter (1990), growth can be measured at the level of nations, but
nations in some sense neither produce nor exchange. Their competitive advantage
arises from the strength of regions, cities, districts, which are the locus of
production. Likewise, innovation, the capacity of economies to change and adapt
to their environments, are deeply rooted in clusters, and strongly related to the
organisation of the industry implemented locally.
The understanding of the processes underlying local development is thus
pivotal. The paper attempts to contribute to this aim through the analysis of cases
very different from the paradigmatic Italian districts or university-based clusters.
They are instead the result of industrial and regional development policies, of top
down processes implemented in the French economy, that have resulted in the
emergence of high tech clusters or technopoles, defined here as regions developed
around several interrelated knowledge elements, including but not limited to
science parks or research or technology centres (Luger 2001). Indeed, Toulouse, in
the southwest region Midi-Pyrenees, and Sophia Antipolis, in the southeast French
Riviera, between Nice and Cannes, can both be considered as the outcomes of the
French national system of innovation and the process of decentralisation initiated
in France in the late sixties, but their evolution was in a sense unpredictable.
Obviously, the regional clusters are not naturally given, they are constructed and
instituted outcomes of economic processes (Metcalfe 2000). As the numerous
failed experiences of top-down reinforcement of local attributes suggest, the
factors the two areas have been endowed cannot explain as such the emergence
and development of local innovative milieux. The focus has not to be on the
factors as such, but on the interactions among them, the feedback effects and
cumulative processes they give rise, and the process of development they entail
(Garnsey and Longhi 1997). The paper traces these processes in the two cases. A
suitable analytical framework has to be adopted to grasp these dynamics and build
the history of the innovative milieux.
A technopole, as well as territory in general, can be identified as a spatial cluster
of activities, a geographically bounded concentration of interdependent firms and
institutions open to its environment, in short an evolving, open complex system.
The "system" is a way of conceptualising the set of related elements with a
designated boundary which represents economically the territory. Regarding
innovation, Andersen and Teubal (1999) identify the business sector (the
backbone of the process), the supporting structures (non-business organisations
and formal institutions like research centres, universities, business association,
formal policy institutions), links and institutions (i.e. user-supplier networks,
research-industry relations, labour markets), culture and social structure as basic
components. The "system" provides a basis for finding connections between
various aspects of the milieu and for tracing its dynamic. At last, territories are
enacted systems, individual agents, key actors, or institutions are the basic
determinants of their trajectories; as such, despite underlying common processes,
their trajectories are unique, unpredictable, and non-replicable (Garnsey 1998).
The relevance of the complexity theory to grasp territorial dynamics has become
evident from the recent developments of the literature. The nature of the local
development appears as an emergent property of the system, i.e. coherent and
From Exogenous to Endogenous Local Development 215
unexpected macro behaviour of the whole which is not attribute of the parts, but
results from their micro interactions, and which can go with important
discontinuities. This analytical framework will allow make clear the development
of the local systems, their evolutions following the initial public impetus,
adaptations from internal interactions and feedbacks, and from reactions to their
environments. The internal as well as external interactions of the local systems are
essentials to the definition of the dynamical paths; changes, "small events" (Arthur
1989) regarding these interactions can result in crisis or re-configuration of the
systems.
We turn now to the cases of local industrial development. Conceptualising their
development in terms of the genesis and growth of complex adaptive systems
provides an heuristic device to "organize" their histories, the different
reconfigurations that have led to the emergence of technopoles, as well as to
understand their fundamental specific features. Diversity is indeed the basic
characteristic of local development; both cases involved mechanisms of
reinforcement triggered by public policies of regional development, by stimulus to
local activity from leading institutions, by strong public private
interdependences, but the combination of these mechanisms of reinforcement
differed, and have resulted in self-reinforcing expansion although through highly
distinct paths.
2. The Cases
Since thirty years, Toulouse has grown as a major European centre of aeronautics
and spatial activities. One distinctive feature of the area is the role of the
interdependences between industry, research and training, and services in the
development of the local resource and knowledge base, which define it as a
technopole. Nevertheless, the contemporaneous system of innovation has not
found its source locally, but results from a state-led exogenous process of
accumulation of related activitie~. Its development has been closely related to the
construction of the European aerospace industry, in which Toulouse has played a
pivotal role. The name of Toulouse is today closely associated with Airbus or
Ariane, and symbolized in a thematic park, the "Cite de l'Espace", welcoming
numerous visitors. Nevertheless, the development has not followed an unique
path. It is obviously gone with ups and downs regarding the cycles of its dominant
industries. But above all, the institutional and organizational arrangements
qualifying its regime of growth or innovation have deeply evolved. The paper
characterizes the different steps of this process, the internal and external
circumstances that have induced changes in the local system and led to a
technopolitan milieu.
216 C. Longhi
In the late sixties, different public policy decisions have oriented the whole socio-
economic development of Toulouse towards a technopole, through the
decentralisation from Paris of the main research and education institutions related
to aerospace activities, and the induced impetus given to the existing local
resources. The emergence of a "collective agent", the CNES (Centre National des
Etudes Spatiales) in the local system had a pivotal role to generate positive
feedbacks from this accumulation of new resources.
With the development of spatial activities, the French government created the
CNES in 1961, a public establishment in charge to define and carryon the spatial
programs in collaboration with research, industry and defence. From 1968, the
CNES has decentralized in its Space Centre of Toulouse most of its R&D
activities; the centre has grown today up to 2,500 researchers. The CNES has
developed and coordinated the Ariane program for ESA (European Space
Agency), as well as most of the public and defence applications of satellite
activities in France and in the European programs. The expertise of the CNES
merges different scientific and industrial fields, and it develops thematic R&D on
radio communication, observation, orbital sciences and infrastructures, space
transport, or generic research on design and development of systems. The Space
Centre has been the main catalyst of the development of space activities in
Toulouse, and has induced the location in the area of the main actors in the field,
public or private. In line with its decentralization, the CNES has prioritised its
local relationships and developed synergies between the different actors to feed
the needs in pure and applied research as well as industrial development needed
by its programs, whose main feature is the innovative content. It has implemented
and co-ordinated networks inducing processes of collective learning and the
emergence of a local innovative milieu in spatial activities, which cross-different
scientific and technological fields. The CNES has also created independent firms
based on home technologies to foster the innovative process in the local complex.
The unique feature of Toulouse is that along with the CNES, most of the higher
education and research institutions linked to aerospace activities have been
decentralized from Paris, making a coherent and interdependent knowledge base.
Indeed, the decision to locate in Toulouse the main university level schools
("Grandes Ecoles") of engineers has been conditioned by the simultaneous
location of the related institutes of research, because there are closely interwoven
218 C. Longhi
institutions. They are both required for the quality of the diplomas delivered,
engineers, but also PhD, and for the setting of close links with industry, which is
part of the mission of these institutions. This process is gone with the
reinforcement of the existing institutes of University and the CNRS, which had
already a strong potential in computer sciences, electronics, robotics, materials.
Among these main institutions, one can mention ENSEEIHT (Ecole Nationale
Superieure d'Electrotechnique, d'Electronique, d'Informatique et d'Hydraulique
de Toulouse), SUPAERO (Ecole Nationale Superieure de \' Aeronautique et de
l'Espace), ENSICA (Ecole Normale Superieure d'Ingenieurs de Constructions
Aeronautiques), ENAC (Ecole Nationale de l'Aviation Civile), ONERA-"Centre
de Toulouse" (Office National d'Etudes et de Recherches Aerospatiales), LAAS
(Laboratoire d' Architecture des Systemes, CNRS), LEEI (Laboratoire
d'Electrotechnique et d'Electronique Industrielle), CERT (Centre des Etudes sur
les Rayonnements), IRIT (Institut de Recherche en Informatique de Toulouse). In
addition, the "Ecole Nationale de Meteorologie", as well as French National
Meteorology offices have been located in Toulouse in a specific area, the
"Meteopole". They are backed by the spatial activities or the CNES, using data
collected by the satellites Meteosat or Spot, and have developed an important
computing expertise needed for forecasts I.
This education and research complex strongly oriented towards industries or
applications has met the tradition of the University Paul Sabatier in Toulouse, as
well as the socia-economic and cultural tradition of the city. Indeed, in 1885
already the local government was the main financial support of the new Faculty of
Science, and subsidized a course on electricity to meet the industrialization needs
of that time; the course has been dedicated from 1902 to the training for local
entrepreneurs. Or it provided the premises and the wages of the professors of the
"Institut d'Electrotechnique" created in 1907 (Allinne 1996). This tradition shared
by the main institutional local bodies has allowed the easily integration of such an
amount of new external resources in the area, which have worked as the
reinforcement of an existing socio-economic process of development.
The result of the whole process has been the early emergence of a local labour
market of high qualification, allowing the "diffusion of embodied and tacit
knowledge and technological know-how" (Camagni 1991) and local collective
learning. Indeed, the students are vectors of creation of close relationships
between education, associate research institutions and firms, through training
periods or recruitments, or their involvement through PhD in the problem-solving
activities of the firms. Toulouse appears as an attractor for future engineers,
technicians studying in its schools or universities, which search for local
employment whatever their geographical origin (Grossetti 1990). In 2000,
Toulouse gathered more than 107,800 students, 70 % in the four universities and
their engineer schools, 5 % in the "Grandes Ecoles"; complemented by vocational
1It must be stressed that Toulouse is also one of the main national pole in health,
Space Industry. The location of the CNES and the research institutes in Toulouse
have been followed by the decentralisation of Matra Espace in 1979 and Alcatel
Espace in 1982, which have been two main actors of the development of space
industries in France, the third one, Aerospatiale Espace, being located in Cannes
near Sophia Antipolis. This process complements the regional development
strategy of the government.
The European Space Agency (ESA) has presided over the development of the
space industry in Europe. Given the important share of the French government in
the ESA budget, the CNES has played a pivotal role in the definition and design of
the projects, national but also European, as well as in the choice of firms in charge
of the development and design. The technological standards required by the CNES
were very high and the satellite programs calibrated for short series, more oriented
towards R&D than competitive markets. The growth of the activity has followed
the evolutions of the public programs, with some downturns like the Hermes
project for example. Given the principles governing ESA, the space industry has
been from the beginning organized in cooperative networks of firms (alternatively
Aerospatiale, Alcatel, Alenia, DASA, Matra ... ) built to complete each program.
Toulouse has been a locus of the construction of the European space industry;
obviously, the state control on the space policy and thus the definition of the
programs is not questioned. But the knowledge base has grown from the local
linkages established between the different actors of the field. Alcatel and Matra
have both grown today up to 2,000 employees, drawing on the local labour market
to feed their growth, but also to develop new capabilities. The industrial strategy
of Matra Espace has been very influential on the constitution of the milieu, and
complemented the action the CNES (Dupuy and Gilly 1999). The firm was
organized without central laboratory of research and multiplied the local links
with the CNES, the institutes of research and the potential subcontractors to solve
the complex technological problem-solving activities raised by the space industry.
Matra acted as prime contractor of the projects and specialized in integration of
systems, implying the coherent merging of the different knowledge bases involved
220 C. Longhi
working under the "arsenal logic" is given up, the division of labour obeys the
specialisation of the companies for the strategic components of the planes
(Aerospatiale is endowed with the integration of systems, the cockpit and the
controls), the industrial parts being divided according the financial involvement of
the partners (Muller 1988). The same principles are applied in the other European
consortium, the GIE ATR (Avions de Transport Regional) linking Aerospatiale
and Alenia. The implementation of GIE has allowed to implement an efficient
cooperation without merging, any process of privatisation of the aeronautic
activities being impossible to consider in France at this time.
The head office, management and design activities of the GIE have been located
in Toulouse, giving the area the role of European centre regarding aeronautics.
The GIE was an entity without capital and without profit, but it gained a strategic
position. There is indeed an asymmetry between Airbus Industry and the partners
of the consortium as, through work sharing, the GIE increases the specialization of
the partner and holds the control on the whole process and the commercial
expertise (Talbot 2000). Airbus has continuously grown, to reach 2,400 persons in
2000.
The development of the Airbus family has induced the restructuring of the
activities of Aerospatiale, from an organisation based on largely autonomous sites
to a multidivisional organisation (Kechidi 1996). The restructuring has mainly
concerned the "Aircraft Division", where all the establishments have been
integrated through the creation of a "Direction of Production". The design and
conception department have also been merged, and located in Toulouse along with
the headquarters. The specialisation process induced by the GIE Airbus in the
consortium has been internalised by the tirm. It obeys the decomposition of the
aircraft on sub-systems, allocated to the partners depending of their specialization,
and the process of standardisation induced by the development of the Airbus
family, optimised through flexible factories; accordingly, the division of labour
between the site obeys their technological specialisation. This process is gone with
the complete redefinition of the subcontracting strategy, from its decentralization
by sites to its co-ordination from the Toulouse direction. The new internal
principles of specialisation, standardisation, automation, have been applied to the
subcontractors, and the internal tools of computer-aided technology extended to
the network. The share and nature of the subcontracting has also evolved.
Aerospatiale internalises only the strategic activities, design, control, cockpit,
controls, electronic systems, assembling, engine pylons, assembling, but 10 to 40
% of these activities are planned to be subcontracted. The share of the sub-systems
based on diffused technologies is planned from 80 to 90 %, and of 100 % for
standard technologies (Kechidi 1996). A further consequence of the specialisation
is that subcontractors are entrusted with the whole responsibility of sub-systems,
from design to production, meaning the development of internal capacities of
conception, involvement in the financing of programs, in maintenance. A multi-
layer organisation of sub-contracting is adopted, the first layer firms organising
the subsequent levels, with the agreement of the prime contractor; the direct links
of the Aerospatiale have fallen from 650 in 1987 to less than 100. The
externalisation of sub-systems from design to production has induced new
222 C. Longhi
On board systems. The existing knowledge base in the university and institutes in
electronics, robotics, automation, computing, has induced others related industrial
developments, characterized also by the pivotal role initially given to large firms
and obeying also to the policy of regional development directed by the
government. Motorola for example, which employs 2,500 persons in Toulouse,
has specialized the site on on-board systems for cars. Or Siemens Automotive,
1,500 employees, specialized in car safety and comfort technologies, like
navigational aids. These locations have resulted in further arrivals, like Bosh,
Valeo, Actia on diagnostic apparatus for the car industry. On the whole, an on-
board systems cluster has emerged in the Toulouse area, which covers the whole
range of applications, from aerospace to car industries, involving design, software
development, testing. It results from close interactions between public and private
research ranging from electronics to materials, between small and large firms, and
it is integrated in international markets. The public or private institutions of
research (like LAAS, LEEI, IRIT) are involved in many networks related to
different technological domains, and help to the building of specific local
competences on the technopolitan area.
From Exogenous to Endogenous Local Development 223
The recent period has been highly challenging for Toulouse, as since 2000, the
landscape of the aerospace industry has tremendously changed. The first challenge
has been the A380, the new long-haul aircraft launched by Airbus Industry. An
aspect is the innovative content of the plane. Another aspect has been the location
of the assembly line of the A380, which was a strategic element regarding the
future centre of the European industry.
From a long time, Toulouse had planned to dedicate industrial wasteland from
Dassault-Breguet to the project. But the area resulted undersized for the definitive
program, and Hamburg proposed an alternative location open to the sea and
adapted to the logistic implied by the A380 assembling. The local public response
in the Toulouse area resulted in the creation of a new zone dedicated to aeronautic
activities, AeroConstellation, localized in Blagnac. The project has been build by
the major of the city, B. Keller, who associated different communes to gather 380
hectares dedicated to the zone. The investment amounts to 4 billions francs: 700
millions from the cities, 300 millions from the "Departement" for the development
of the zone, 2.5 billions from Airbus to build the assembly line, and 200 millions
from Air France, which will locate its maintenance facilities on site. The airport,
as well as the existing Airbus assembly lines, the head offices of Airbus, ATR,
British Aerospace were already localized in Blagnac. Nevertheless, the city could
not stand this new investment alone. The institutional arrangement has been the
creation of a grouping of communes around Toulouse (Communaute
d' Agglomeration), gathering the resources dedicated to local development.
AeroConsteliation illustrates to socio-economic context of Toulouse. Since the
works of Becattini (1990), the understanding of economic successful regions has
placed considerable emphasis on the key role of local institutions or on the
importance of regional institutional thickness, the interlocking web of institutions
including firms, chamber of commerce, local governments (Keeble et al. 1998).
Indeed, Keller was consultant in Airbus France, coming from Aerospatiale, 1.
Diebold, the responsible of the AeroConstellation project in the Toulouse
municipality, was engineer in Aerospatiale Airbus, the head of the Chamber of
Commerce is also the head of Latecoere. This strong socio-politico-economic
context helps to understand the development of the region, its capacity to face
changes and to adapt to new conditions; as we have seen, it takes roots in the
history of the region, as the development of the university obeyed the same
interlocking hundred years ago. But, contrary to the usual district socio-economic
context, the regional system of innovation in Toulouse is based on the importance
of large firms and the interdependence of public - private institutions.
The "Communaute d' Agglomeration" has also promoted the development of an
optical regional network to meet the development of the Information and
Communications Technologies. This investment complements the activity of
France Telecom, which employs 4,000 persons in Toulouse for the development
and operating of interurban and pan-European networks. These activities have
created more than 12,000 jobs in ten years, and stand as an engine of growth in the
region (INSEE 2000). They are closely linked with the space industry, and the
224 C Longhi
This reshaping of the European landscape gives Toulouse the central role in the
sector. In addition to the assembling of the A380 and the new ATR, it will receive
the Airbus and ATR headquarters, activities of design, programme planning,
delivery and customer services, and training, confirming the embeddedness of the
firms in the local area. The creation of Airbus as an independent corporate
organisation will imply a restructuring and rationalisation of all related activities
from design, engineering to manufacturing, and in Toulouse, a deepening of the
process initiated with the former reorganisation of Aerospatiale. One can expect a
reinforcement of the context of first-layer subcontractors, and of design and
engineering activities, as well as an increased pressure over the volume
subcontractors. deepening the technopolitan nature of the area. Airbus has already
announced a planned decrease of 20 % on the cost to allow the commercial
viability of the A380 program. The innovative content of the new program has
induced, as soon as approved, a strong pressure on the local market on engineers
and high qualifications. Large as well as small-specialized firms are adapting their
capacities in R&D, conception, to fill the competitive requirement implied by the
new institutional arrangements governing Airbus. The trend is an increasing
concentration of the innovation process in Toulouse, at the expense of Paris.
The creation of Astrium and Alcatel Space, strongly territorialized in the local
milieu, and involved as prime contractors in many new programs, from earth
observation to telecommunication and internet, is to reinforce the position of
Toulouse in these activities. The restructuring of the firms has allowed their
adaptation, from commands of short series, high tech prototypes from the CNES
or ESA, to competition and mass-production going with for example the growing
market of telecommunication satellite. The role of the CNES will certainly have to
evolve in this new setting, and new institutional arrangements to emerge. Indeed,
as a consequence of the restructuring of the aerospace industry, Toulouse leaves in
some sense the French national system of innovation, in which it played a pivotal
role, to move more deeply towards the European one and to competitive global
markets.
The Sophia Antipolis Park is located in the South of France, on the French Riviera
between Nice and Cannes. It is often presented as a project which initiated a new
form of local development, the "first technopolis in Europe", built on the idea of
cross-fertilization between research and industry championed by its creator, Pierre
Laffitte. Indeed, the experiment, built on greenfield, is today an important centre
of high technology activities in Europe; 1,193 firms or institutions were located in
the park in 2000, offering 21,536 jobs, and some 5,000 researchers and students
are present on the park. The experiment is only 30 years old; this short period
allows drawing the main characteristics of the history of the project, to trace and
understand the different phases of growth and crisis.
226 C. Longhi
The take-off stage for Sophia-Antipolis was based predominantly on the location
of external organisations on the site which were attracted by the quality of the
infrastructure made available to them. The implant companies had their own
internal resource base but this was but external to Sophia-Antipolis. This form of
development resulted in minimal interaction and interdependence between the
From Exogenous to Endogenous Local Development 227
organisations on the site. Decision centres and industrial strategy making were
external to Sophia-Antipolis itself.
However, the participation of the public authorities in the initiative made
possible a shift in the scale of the project. After the first period where large public
sector companies and laboratories were introduced onto the site, linked to the
French decentralisation movement, new locations emerged as the outcome of a
commercialisation strategy for the science park based on a major international
marketing effort, mainly directed at the USA. Large multinational companies,
mostly American, adopted Sophia-Antipolis either as their European
administrative base or as an R&D centre charged with adapting their products to
European markets. The availability of high-quality telecommunication
infrastructures able to support hubs and Nice international airport explain most of
these location decisions. These international firms have made major investments,
establishing self-contained entities able to operate without local linkages.
In this take-off stage the "Ecole Nationale Superieure des Mines de Paris a
Sophia Antipolis", the "Institut National de Recherche en Informatique et
Automatique" (INRI A) , institutes from the "Centre National de la Recherche
Scientifique" (CNRS), were decentralized from Paris. After the initial impetus of
France Telecom, the computer centres of large firms like Air France or group
insurance like Organic located in the area, followed by Thomson, Digital
Equipment, Rohm and Haas, Dow Corning, Allergan etc.
AnnuaJ Total
Growt
2000
2000
a
a a
Limits to growth in Sophia Antipolis were closely linked to the initial conditions
of the project, i.e. lack of a local labour market, lack of endogenous creation of
resources, of SMEs or specialized services. Nevertheless, the accumulation of
economic activities on site has triggered positive processes and catch lip effects
which smoothed progressively these limits until the beginning of the nineties,
when a crisis emerged in Sophia Antipolis
A first element concerns the site's potential for training and research. The sitting
of the first public institutes on Sophia Antipolis was the result of a decentralisation
policy of the major research institutes: the "Ecole des Mines", the CNRS, the
INRIA. Their role in the development of the project was very important; INRIA in
particular played a fundamental role in structuring local technological
development, the emergence of an endogenous innovative capacity and of start-
ups on the site. But this potential was not sufficient to train the graduates needed
by the developing labour market. A significant development was the sitting in
Sophia-Antipolis of research institutes and doctoral studies of the University of
Nice in 1986. The university is young and was not associated to the development
of the park. Its research institutes and doctoral training began to move from Nice
to Sophia from 1986, and progressively a critical mass was reached. The
development of university training for engineers has given impetus to the local
labour market. In this respect, the process of development of Sophia-Antipolis was
the reverse of the "classical" science park processes: the development of the
University and the nature of specialist education received their impetus from the
accumulation of industrial activity. The large companies arrived first, with
decentralised research institutes and only then the university and small and
medium high tech enterprises.
A second element concerns the high tech small firms which have grown up in
Sophia-Antipolis. The origin of the high tech small firms is very diverse. Many
were attracted to Sophia-Antipolis by a site suitable for growth or to build
linkages with research institutes (in which their technologies have often been
born) or with firms (as subcontractors providing specialized services). Most of the
success stories of the park were such implants. Others were spin-offs from the
research institutions (INRIA, Ecole des Mines, INSERM in health sciences). The
university has also had some successful spin-offs, leaders in their niche. They
retain close relationships with research departments, and often try to build local
networks around their activities. Pre-production and production of their range of
products are often subcontracted to different firms in the region; they are linked
with local service activities (such as publishing, translation). These spin-offs were
mainly concentrated in computer sciences and telecommunications.
There are also some high tech firms which have located in Sophia-Antipolis to
benefit from the prestige of the address without having any links with the local
industrial environment. Those that did have linkages were concentrated in the
telecommunications sector, in GIS and image processing, software, or biomedical
activities. Some acquisitions of high tech SMEs have been made by large firms to
renew their technological base, mainly to shift from centralized to decentralized
230 C. Longhi
systems of information. On the contrary, spin-offs of large firms have been very
scarce on this period. The strategy of internalisation of human resources within
large firms and the attractiveness of jobs in these firms have resulted in a "reverse
spin-off effect", i.e. their systematic recruitment of high qualified resources from
existing SMEs to feed their growth. This characteristic of the project has severely
constrained the development of a local labour market and of localized knowledge.
A final element is made up of service activities. This cluster is heterogeneous
and its growth has been considerable since 1982 in terms of jobs, so that it makes
up 28% of current employment and more than 50% of all firms. This growth is
based in part on a catch up effect, due to the absence of service provision on a
greenfield site like Sophia-Antipolis; they are basic services required by those
living and working on the site and specialized services required by the growing
accumulation of firms. The two former categories of firms have made a
considerable contribution to the viability of the development process, even if part
of service growth has also been make up by a third category of firms without any
links with the technological activities of the site. These are essentially the firms
linked to BTP or marketing and distribution which have located on in the
periphery of Sophia-Antipolis to take advantage of the prestige of the technopolis
or of favourable real estate conditions.
These different elements are very important as they contribute basically to the
reversal of previous established trends and to the building of an innovative milieu.
But the nineties have questioned these positive developments.
The shocks that characterized the early 1990s have indeed been of considerable
importance for Sophia-Antipolis. First, it has hit the engine of growth of the
project, the computer science activities, implying downsizing in the large firms.
Second, it has questioned the strategy of development of the project, based on a
marketing strategy aiming at attracting investments of large firms. Indeed, the
nineties brought on new forms of globalisation. The 1980s were characterized by
multinational developments driven by market processes. The major corporations
organized themselves into semi- autonomous regional groups. The attractiveness
of Sophia Antipolis for inward investment gave it a comparative advantage over
alternative locations. Corporations were not concerned with the specific
competencies or capabilities of regions in choosing their location, but were
influenced mainly by general conditions in terms of cost and facilities. As we have
seen, Sophia-Antipolis was well endowed in this respect.
The nature of this process of globalisation in high tech activities has however
dramatically changed in the 1990s (Gordon 1996; Veltz 1993). It is no longer
mainly oriented towards manufacturing products or supplying particular markets
through adaptation of existing home technologies but towards the process of
innovation. As innovation depends on diverse specific capabilities and knowledge,
locational differences in these specificities become important. Locations are not
easily substitutable, and choices of location are not driven by general advantages
but by specific advantages of regions in terms of core competencies. The regime
of growth of Sophia Antipolis, based on the attraction of new resources, was
clearly a strategy for coping with the 1980s but at odds with the 1990s. It resulted
in the location of more conventional activities without any technological content,
From Exogenous to Endogenous Local Development 231
and in the depreciation of the park's image. A new strategy of development, based
on local resources and competencies, had to be generated.
learning and local positive feedback. The history of Sophia-Antipolis has revealed
that in the past opposite processes were in fact at work, namely internaIisation of
resources within large firms.
Historically, the process of spin-off was restricted to research institutions. With
the crisis, it has been extended to large firms. Paradoxically, the most important
movement of creation of new SMEs correspond to the major slowdown of the
project in terms of employment growth at the beginning of the nineties, and to the
process of downsizing and outsourcing induced by large firms. The number of
firms increased significantly during the crisis. Downsizing resulted in the
diffusion of capabilities up to there internalised in the large firms through the local
labour market, and not in a loss of resources. Indeed despite the weakness of
linkages between firms or institutions a strong sophipolitan milieu effect has
always existed for the people involved in the project, which have tried to find
local solution to the crisis. A lot of "forced" spin-offs from large firms have
emerged, which have helped to diffuse technological capabilities and competences
locally. These firms, created by former engineers of large firms (Thomson, Texas
Instruments, DEC) reluctant to leave the project when confronted to
"downsizing", have often subcontracting relationships with their parent firms, and
important informal networking relations between them, to share problems and
solutions. The fact that most of these SMEs have been able to adapt and grow has
enhanced the movement.
Recently, numerous local start-ups and spin-offs have emerged in the software
industry, multimedia, telecommunication and internet technologies. An important
resource base exists locally in these activities. Indeed, many of these new
technologies are developed in INRIA or France Telecom. The consequence has
been the multiplication of small and micro firms created from local resources,
with strong links with research and close interrelationships. This cluster is
supported by local business associations, and is embedded within numerous
different local formal and informal networks.
This trend towards an endogenous regime of growth could not have existed
without the development of the training and research capacities of the area, and
their interdependence with the industrial context. The existence of a local labour
market, allowing the skilled labour mobility, the diffusion of embodied and tacit
expertise and technological know-how is recognized in the literature as the basic
element of local development (Camagni 1991; Keeble et al. 1998). As we have
stressed, Sophia Antipolis was initially deprived from such processes. The
changes initiated by the location of the University has never stopped, and the
growth and multiplication of higher education and research institutes is also
quantitatively one of the important trend of the recent years. Roughly 3000
students and as many researchers are today in Sophia-Antipolis. The advent of the
Institut National de la Recherche Agronomique (INRA) and of the "Institut de
Pharmacologie" (CNRS) significantly reinforced the pharmaceutical and health
science cluster of activities, even if industry-research linkages were in both cases
mainly turned towards outside players. The critical mass effect and the visibility
of these developments were insufficient to promote innovative local behaviour.
This critical mass has on the contrary been reached in the information
From Exogenous to Endogenous Local Development 233
activities. For instance, Andersen Consulting located on the park with a small unit
of ten people and has subsequently grown locally to employ more than three
hundred staff on the base of new markets created from their local activities. The
same strategy has been followed by the new comers in Sophia Antipolis, whose
location have been clearly induced by the specific capabilities in wireless
communication, GSM technologies or internet technologies which have grown
locally, from the public research institutes as well as from the R&D developed in
the area by large (Texas Instruments, IBM) or medium (VLSI for instance) firms.
Most of the main actors in this innovative field have recently located in Sophia
Antipolis, with a precise strategy of mobilization of local capabilities and
knowledge. This is the case of Siemens, Lucent, Bay networks, Ericsson, whose
units have grown on the basis of local resources, or Philips, which acquired VLSI,
but also of many small firms which find in Sophia Antipolis an area suitable for
growth or for attracting easily the specialized human resources needed in this
innovative technological field. The process of outsourcing and the development of
information technologies have also considerably changed the local strategy of the
large firms; a lot of local relationships linked to the innovative process have
emerged locally, through subcontracting with high tech specialized SMEs.
Growth is now quasi-exclusively endogenous, i.e. results from the growth of
existing local firms, when before 1990, it resulted mainly from the balance
between entry and exit of firms in the project. Besides, the growth is concentrated
in the information technologies sector. An efficient local labour market thus exists
today for qualified information technology staff. More than half of sophipolitan
jobs are highly qualified jobs (executives and engineers); in the information
technologies sector, this proportion was 70.8% in 1997.
In the contemporaneous process of innovation, the challenge for Sophia
Antipolis was to enter the global networks set up by the high tech firms to sustain
their innovative activities, which links large and small and specialized firms as
well as public research institutions. The emergence of a new regime of growth and
of new institutional arrangements after a crisis of adaptation show that the
resources accumulated in the eighties were sufficient to face the shocks and
reconfigure the system. But the shocks of the nineties have resulted in an
unbalanced local system, in which information and telecom activities have been
able to adapt to the new environment and to regenerate growth while other
activities (health sciences) are still locked into the previous regime and failing to
fulfil their potential. Information technologies have recovered the role of engine of
growth they had in the first phase of the project. The engine is no more made of
self-contained establishments of large international firms; it results from the
positive feedbacks induced by the local interactions of firms involved in
innovative activities. This strong movement of specialization of Sophia-Antipolis
can raise problems for the balanced growth of the area, as it could increase its
sensitivity to asymmetric shocks, despite its specialization in R&D and design
activities.
From Exogenous to Endogenous Local Development 235
3. Conclusion
a shared representation system and development strategy - has been one of the
main asset of development, but the role of the State has been permanent, because
of the strategic content of the local activities. In turn, the embeddedness of the
European aerospace industry in Toulouse, its pivotal role in the European scene,
induced by the endogenous process of creation of resources and local specific
knowledge, explains certainly the restructuring of the industry allowed by the
privatisation processes implemented by the government. This basic change in the
institutional arrangements governing the economic activities of the city will
certainly deepen its insertion in the global knowledge-based economy. In Sophia
Antipolis, the development is the result of the government regional development
policy, without the strategic content present in Toulouse. The emergence of an
innovative milieu from the accumulation of external resources has been the result
of an external shock, a change in the environment the project had to face. The
reconfiguration that resulted has allowed the project to go beyond the image effect
on which it has grown, towards the emergence of a socio-economic context and
the realization of the cross-fertilization concept which presided to its creation.
References
Gordon, R. (1996), "Industrial Districts and the Globalization of Innovation: Regions and
Networks in the new economic space", in: Wealth from Diversity, Vence-Deza, X. and
Metcalfe, J. S., Kluwer.
Gormand, C. (1993), L 'industrie aeronautique et spatiale, Paris, L' Harmattan.
Grossetti, M. (1990), "Enseignement superieur et technopole, l'exemple de l'informatique a
Toulouse", Revue Fram;aise de Sociologie, XXXI.3.
INSEE (1998), 15 ans d 'aeronautique et d 'espace en Midi-Pyrenees, Toulouse.
INSEE (2000a), "Aeronautique, espace et sous-traitance", Reperes, 100.
INSEE (2000b), Tableaux economiques de Midi-Pyrenees, Toulouse.
INSEE (2001), "Les NTIC en Midi-Pyrenees", 6 Pages, 46.
Kechidi, M. (1996), "Coordination inter-entreprises et relations de sous-traitance: Ie cas
d' Aerospatiale", Revue d'Economie Regionale et Urbaine, 1.
Keeble, D. et al. (1998), Collective Learning Processes and Inter-Firm Networking in
Innovative High·Technology Regions, ESRC (Economic & Social Research Council)
Centre for Business Research, Working Paper 86, March.
Longhi, C. (1999), "Networks, Collective Learning and Technology Development in
Innovative High Technology Regions: the Case of Sophia-Antipolis", Regional Studies.
Longhi, C. and Quere, M. (1993), "Innovative Networks and the Technopolis Phenomenon:
the Case of Sophia-Antipolis", Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy.
Luger, M. I. (2001), Science and Technology Parks at the Millennium: Concept, History,
and Metrics.
Markusen, A. (1996), "Sticky Places in Slippery Spaces: A Typology of Industrial
Districts", Economic Geography.
Metcalfe, J. S. (2000), "Propspects and Challenge for Research on Innovation", Co-
evolution o/Systems a/Innovation, Conference, Berlin, June 8th-9th.
Muller, P. (1988), Airbus, I 'ambition europeenne. Logique d'Etat, logique de marche.
Paris, L'Harmattan.
Porter, M. E. (1990), The Competitive Advantage o/Nations, New York, Free Press.
Saxenian. A. (1994), Regional Advantage, Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.
Storper, M. (1993), "Regional "Worlds" of Production: Learning and Innovation in the
Technology Districts of France, Italy and the USA", Regional Studies, vol. 27.5.
Talbot, D. (2000), Institutional Dynamics and Localized Inter-Firms Relations. The Case of
Aerospatiale and its Subcontractors in Toulouse, European Urban and Regional Studies,
7(3).
Veltz, P. (1993), D'une geographie des couts a une geographie de l'organisation. Quelques
theses sur l'evolution des rapports entreprises/territoires, Revue Economique, n04.
Biotechnology Development in Germany:
The Case of Nordrhein-Westfalen
Germany got a late start in developing its biotechnology industry but has been
catching up. Today, there are 332 biotech companies, which together employ
11,000 people and generate annual gross revenues of US$670 million. In 2000,
they invested US$600 million (GFW-NRW 2001).
Many of these companies are located in Nordrhein-Westfalen, the most
populated German state (18 million inhabitants), which accounts for 22% of the
country's gross domestic product. It is host to a number of multinational
Biotechnology Development in Germany: The Case of Nordrhein-Westfalen 241
companies (Bayer, Henkel, RWE, Krupp-Thyssen, Ford, and many others), and its
economy is strongly linked to the chemical industry. The industrial vocation of
NRW is supported by a high concentration of public research facilities: 53
universities (500,000 students); 21 scientific organizations, including Max Planck
and Fraunhofer Institutes and several National Research Centres; 32 other public
agencies financed with government funds; 58 scientific units participating in
special research projects (Sonderforschungsbereich, SFB, which are managed by
the Agency for University Research, Deutsche Forschung Gemeinschaft, DFG);
68 technology centres and industrial incubators; and 27 technology transfer offices
(Anonymous 2001, Bio-Gen-Tec-NRW 2000).
The engine that drives this public research network - the most extensive and
important in Europe - is not chemistry, but biology: eight graduate schools of
medicine, 12 SFB groups, eight interdisciplinary research centres (IZKF), one
Molecular Medicine Centre in Koln (ZMMK), one Biomaterials Centre in Aachen
(BIOMAT), eight graduate schools of biology, two biotechnology institutes in
Julich, two Max Planck Institutes in Koln (for plants and neurological research),
the Max Planck Molecular Physiology Institute in Dortmund, one Molecular
Biotechnology Institute in Aachen (Fraunhofer Foundation), and one Chemio and
Biosensor Institute in MUnster.
The BioRegio competition ended in 1996. Since then, the state of NRW has
been working to turn its biotechnology effort into economic expansion. Today,
the state is host to 130 biotech companies located within an area of 13,000 km 2 ;
220 organizations provide products and services to the biotech companies (GFW-
NRW 2001). The rise of this biotech industry has been followed by the Bio-Gen-
Tec-NRW association, which assisted the birth of 82 start-ups from 1997 to 2000,
requiring a total investment of 635 million German marks (50 from the federal
government, 195 from the local government and 390 from private investors). In
2000, the local government invested 100 million German marks (Bio-Gen-Tec-
NRW 2001a, Anonymous 2001). Fifty-two of the 80 start-ups created with the
support of Bio-Gen-Tec-NRW are located along the Rhine between Ktiln and
DUsseldorf. They engage in a wide variety of activities including purification of
nucleic acids, cell separation, molecular carriers, bioreactors, bioprocessing,
quality control, molecular chips, bioinformatics, protein design, diagnostics,
functional genomics and postgenomics, models of transgenic animals, and
molecules that prevent neurodegeneration and cardiovascular diseases.
The main cities in this area, named "Bioriver", are DUsseldorf, with 180 new
jobs and the Life Science Centre Incubator; K01n, which accounts for 300 new
jobs and is home to Bio-Gen-Tec-NRW, the Max Planck Institute for Plant
Improvement, the Institute of genetics of the university and the East Rhine
Technology (RTZ) Incubator; and Bonn, where four start-up projects were
approved in 2000. The Aachen-Julich region has been the site of interesting
interdisciplinary projects financed with private capital and was recently selected as
the home of the Fraunhofer Institute for Molecular Biotechnology. In the Ruhr
Basin, which specializes in bioprocessing and microstructure technologies, the
BioIndustry agency works to encourage the establishment of start-ups in
bioindustry and medicine. In addition, the city of Bielefeld has access to a
242 F. Salamini, A. Sohn and H. Thomas
Genomic Research Centre that has excellent potential for the establishment of
start-ups.
The Bio-Gen-Tec-NRW association is a private non-profit organization
financed with public funds, private capital and revenues generated by the projects
it manages directly. It also manages public funds earmarked for the development
of biotechnology in the state of NRW. This association, which has 172 members,
provides consulting and support to new start-ups during the establishment and
early development phases. New ventures receive financial support in the form of
federal and local government funds that are provided through Bio-Gen-Tec-NRW
and have access to a wide range of consulting resources. Bio-Gen-Tec-NRW sees
itself as a one-stop shop that can help clients define the scope of their endeavour
more clearly, prepare a business plan, obtain public financing, enter into contracts
with venture capitalists and present their projects at public events (Figure 1).
Management
Information and guidance (*) Patents
Introduction for
Technological Bio-Gen-Tec-NRW and securing
support (*) of private
financing (*)
BIOTECHNOLOGY 2000
"..,
.R&D • Basic research • Up to 100% (institutions) 0-
'"
• Equipment not included • Up to 50% (startup) ;r:
;l
o
3
~
NRW REGIONAL GOVERNMENT
~
n
~
o
"....
Z
o
~
":;.
~
"~
OJ'
=
"
~
U\
246 F. Salamini, A. Sohn and H. Thomas
Until the 1980s, biology research in Germany was funded by such public agencies
as the Max Planck Company and Deutsche Forschung Germishaft (DFG), and by
ministries of the federal and local government via research projects. Visible
changes in research policy came during the early 1980s, when the federal
government decided that it would encourage public agencies to manage the
development of cutting-edge technologies, provided their projects involved at least
one local industrial enterprise. In the wake of this decision, the Ministry of
Scientific and Technological Research (BMBF) created three public Gene Centres
(Heidelberg, Mlinchen and Koln). These Centres were to receive 100% financing
provided they met one condition: they would have to show that there was an
official relationship linking the institution responsible for setting up the Centre
with a privately-owned business. The K6ln Gene Centre (Zentrum fur Molekulare
Gen- und Zelltechologie in Koln, 1986, 1990, 1994) showed that one of its
cofounders, the Max Planck Institute for Plant Improvement, received an annual
grant from Bayer, Leverkusen, of one million German marks, which was used to
fund unspecified basic research programs. The three Gene Centres were financed
by the BMBF for three funding periods (1982-1994). The completion of the
program for the establishment of the three Centres was followed by a protracted
debate as to which projects should then be developed and supported. The result
was the decision, supported by Minister Rlittgers, to launch the BioRegio
competition among German states for three financing packages of 50 million
German marks each. A precondition for entering the competition was the
establishment of a regional network of public-sector managers, opinion makers,
scientists from universities and other institutions, private-sector managers, union
officials, and Chamber of Commerce and Industry representatives. An
organizational model was a key part of the competition proposal, which was also
required to include a description of the media that would be used to disseminate
information about new biotechnology projects, as well as a list of all of the entities
engaged in biotechnology work in the project area, showing the scientific and
practical significance of their work.
The definition and organization of the networks was not an easy task. It
involved balancing the flow of financial support from the federal and regional
governments to public - and private - sector institutions with the need to establish
quasi-public collaborative superstructures, while at the same time enlisting public
support for the selection of a given area as a preferred location for the
development of biotechnology businesses. The state of NRW - the city of K6ln in
particular - was in a privileged position. Between 1988 and 1990, it had been the
theatre of a public debate concerning the first release of a GMO in Germany (the
case of the transgenic petunia). In Koln, the media had gradually developed a
negative bias toward an experiment carried out by the Max Planck Institute for
Plant Improvement. In 1992, fearing that as a result of this developing situation
local politicians would choose not to pursue opportunities in biotechnology,
municipal and state officials, Chamber of Commerce representatives, journalists,
Biotechnology Development in Germany: TIle Case of Nordrhein-Westfalen 247
The state of Nordrhein-Westfalen has been and remains a centre of excellence for
research in chemistry and genetics, to which it recently added advanced biology.
Industrial development in advanced biology is currently in a logarithmic phase.
There appears to be no slackening of demand for research and development for
biomedical and agricultural applications. It is clear, however, that current forecasts
of the future of the biotech industry cannot be pigeonholed within a model that
sets well-defined objectives for each separate field. As a result, it is difficult to
forecast long-term capital requirements and to define priorities at the state level.
However, close attention should be paid to key structural developments, including
an intensification of the debate involving the public, the research community and
businesses on such issues as medicine and health, food and farming, biotech
products and society at large, and the environment and diagnostics. The increased
availability of local credit and the success of industrial incubators should also be
taken into account. Positive developments in the state of NRW include an increase
in the availability of venture capital for start-ups, a more favourable public
opinion and a more constructive attitude by the federal and local government
toward the biotechnology industry in general and the transfer of research to
businesses in particular. Therefore, it is reasonable to expect that this German state
will become one of the biotechnology hot spots (among perhaps 20 or 30) that will
survive worldwide over the next 15 years.
248 F. Salamini, A. Sohn and H. Thomas
References
Anonymous (2001), "Spotlight on NRW", Nature. supplement March 22, Vol. 410.
Bio-Gen-Tec-NRW (2000). lllJo. no. 1+ 2, Bio-Gen-Tec-NRW.
Bio-Gen-Tec-NRW (200Ia), Allllual Report 2000, Bio-Gen-Tec-NRW.
Bio-Gen-Tec-NRW (200Ib), Bio-Cell-Tec Atlas 2001, Bio-Gen-Tec-NRW.
Eichcner, V., Schaaf, S., Schulte, F. and Weingarten, 1. (2000), ErJolgsJaktoren for die
Biotechnologie-Regionen. SozialwissenshaJtliche Begleitforschllng zu den BioRegios,
Hans Backler Stiftung.
GFW-NRW (2001), Welcome spezial. Biotech-NRW 2001, GFW-NRW.
Korff. W., Beck, L. and Mikat, P. (eds) (1998), Lexikon der Bioethik. 1m AIIJtrag der
Coerres-CesellschaJt, GUtersloher Verlagshaus.
Zentrum fUr Molekulare Gen- und Zelltechnologie in Kaln (1986), Abschlussbericht 1982-
1986. Forderllngsvorhaben BCT0365 2 (BMBF), Max-Planck-Institut fUr
ZUchtungsforschung, Institut fUr Gcnetik der Universitat zu Kaln.
Zcntrum fUr Molekulare Gcn- und Zelltechnologie in Kaln (1990), Abschlllssbericht 1987-
1990. Forderlllzgsvorhaben BCT0365 2 (BMBF), Max-Planck-Institut fUr
ZUchtungsforschung, Institut fUr Genetik der Universitat zu Kaln.
Zentrum fUr Molekulare Gen- und Zelltechnologie in Ki)ln (1994), Abschlussbericht 1991-
1994. Forderlllzgsvorhabell BCT0365 2 (BMBF), Max-Planck-Institut fUr
ZUchtungsforschung. Institut fUr Gcnctik dcr Universitat zu Kaln.
Support for Technology-Based Firms:
The Role Played by Property-Based
Science Parks
1. Introduction
Cooke and Morgan (1993) have asserted that "industrial districts" of firms
(Castells and Hall 1994) can be created by public policy. To stimulate NTBFs,
successive British Governments have encouraged (in conjunction with universities,
higher education institutes (HEIs), local authorities and various financial
institutions) the development of various property-based incubator initiatives.
Science Parks represent one form of property-based incubator initiative. After a
period of enthusiastic appreciation, scepticism is growing surrounding the value of
sponsored environments (Flynn 1993) and property-based initiatives (Massey et al.
1992; Felsenstein 1994; Jones 1996; Oakey and Mukhtar 1999). There is still
insufficient knowledge about the formation of "hub" (i.e., a Science Park acting as
the generator of externalities for tenant firms) and "spoke" (i.e., firms located on
Science Parks) districts. Despite considerable investment in the Science Park
movement, limited empirical research has focused upon the contextual and process
issues associated with the behaviour and attitudes reported by entrepreneurs who
own independent firms located on property-based Science Park initiatives.
This paper makes a contribution to this debate. To assess the benefits of
property-based Science Park initiatives in Great Britain, a demand-side perspective
was utilised. Information was gathered surrounding the perceived demand-side
advantages of a Science Park location. The performance of independent
technology-based firms located on Science Parks was compared with the
performance of a "control group" of similar firms located off-Park. Performance
contrasts between the two groups of firms were explored with regard to several
indicators reported by owners of independent Science Park and off-Park firms. The
role played by the Science Park manager/director in the development of firms
located on "managed" and "non-managed" Science Parks was explored.
United Kingdom. By 1989, there were 32 Science Parks in the United Kingdom
and this plateau was maintained until 1993 (UKSPA 1999). In 1999, the United
Kingdom had 46 fully operational Science Parks. This "new wave" growth in the
Science Park movement is mainly due to the fact that the "new universities",
previously the polytechnics, began to establish Science Parks.
Carter (1989) identified three types of management strategies leading to the
development of Science Parks in the United Kingdom. First, is a university led and
funded strategy (which is the least common model) in which a university or HEI
establishes a Science Park on its own and continues to be responsible for its
development and/or management. Second, is a joint venture company strategy,
with the Science Park being run by a separate legal entity. This mechanism ensures
a continuing positive role for the HEI and other investors in the joint venture
company. Third, and most common is a co-operative venture strategy where
partners work together within a flexible and informal framework. This is the
strategy with the least input from the HEI and the academic involvement tends to
be fairly limited, often via the HEls industrial liaison officer. Services available to
Science Park firms can be delivered through three main types of management
agreements (Carter 1989; Grayson 1993). The first is the informal team. This is the
cheapest and most flexible approach in which the Science Park partners divide the
various management tasks between themselves but there is no full-time, on-site
management presence. The second is the single on-site manager. This has the
advantage of allowing the build-up of expertise relating to the specific needs of
Science Park firms. Background and experience of the manager are important,
especially the balance of industrially related scientific skills, promotional skills
and skills in accessing finance. The third is the on-site management company.
Here, a formally integrated management structure, including representatives from
all investors in the Science Park, may provide a more secure basis for its long-term
development.
UKSP A has made a distinction between "managed" and "non-managed" Science
Parks in the United Kingdom. In 1992, UKSPA suggested that a "managed"
Science Park had a generally full time manager on site whose principal task was to
manage the Park (Westhead and Storey 1994). Science Park managers (i.e., gate-
keepers) can legitimise the activities of entrepreneurs and can increase and
diversify an entrepreneur's commercial, professional and social networks. In this
study, the role played by Science Park managers is explored. The following
Science Parks were regarded by UKSPA, in 1992, as being "non-managed":
Aberdeen, Aberystwyth, Cambridge, Highfields (Nottingham), Listerhills
(Bradford) and Loughborough (Westhead and Storey 1994, p. 170).
252 D. Siegel, P. Westhead and M. Wright
3. Research Questions
Science Parks have various objectives. These ohjectives include: the promotion of
HEI/industry linkages and the transfer of technology from HEIs to Science Park
firms; the promotion of the formation of new technology-based firms; the
encouragement of spin-off firms started by academics; the encouragement of the
growth of existing technology-based firms; attracting firms involved in leading-
edge technologies; creating synergy between firms; improving the performance of
the local economy; improving the image of the location, particularly for areas of
industrial decline; creating new jobs directly as well as indirectly; and enhancing
the competitiveness of new as well as existing firms in the region.
Developers of Science Parks assume that the owner of an independent
technology-based firm faces barriers to commercialising their knowledge into
profitable businesses due to their liabilities of small size and youthfulness. They
have assumed that these issues can be addressed by providing owners of NTBFs
and established firms with high specification and flexible premises located in
landscaped environments (although some tenants have to pay a rent premium);
shared resources and business services; links with local universities or HEIs; and
opportunities for co-operation with other tenants. Further, a Science Park manager
(i.e., a gate-keeper) can be a mechanism reducing uncertainty (and fixed costs) for
owner-managers of NTBFs. A gate-keeper can enhance the reputation of new and
small firms (i.e., those with limited social and business networks) and enable some
owner-managers of firms to gain access to an uninterrupted supply of crucial
resources from a variety of organisations including skills from HErs and finance
from banks, venture capitalists and development and enterprise agencies. Science
Park management can proactively stimulate transfer and promote links between
local HErs and tenant firms through informal contacts and visits from an HEI's
Industrial Liaison Officer, and thus enable firms to tap into important technical
information from HEIs (Westhead and Batstone 1998, 1999). Proximity ~o similar
firms and organisations with a technology focus (i.e., HEIs) can, in addition,
provide opportunities for business development through informal and formal
linkages. Network theory (Johannisson et al. 1994) suggests that entrepreneurs
(and firms) with dense and varied social and business networks of contacts can
gain information and resources to overcome business blind spots. Universities and
HEIs can act as a vehicle for the sponsorship of firms through the use of grants and
contracts and industry sponsored research. Moreover, firms utilising the resources
of HEIs (i.e., testing equipment, laboratories, the technical expertise of academics
and students, etc.) can control their own fixed costs.
The above arguments suggest that the performance of independent firms will be
enhanced if their owner-managers select a Science Park location. To guide policy,
the following research questions are explored in this review:
Rl. Were independent technology-based firms located on Science Parks in 1986
more likely to survive over the 1986 to 1992 period than off-Park firms?
Support for Technology-Based Firms: The Role Played by Property-Based Science Parks 253
R2. Were independent technology-based firms more likely to survive than firms
engaged in more "conventional industries"?
R3. Were independent technology-based firms, reporting a link with a local HEI
in 1986 more likely to survive over the 1986 to 1992 period?
R4. Were independent technology-based firms located on "managed" Science
Parks in 1986 more likely to survive over the 1986 to 1992 period than firms
located on "non-managed" Science Parks?
R5. Did independent Science Park firms report higher levels of absolute
employment growth over the 1986 to 1992 period than off-Park firms?
R6. Was absolute employment growth over the 1986 to 1992 period
concentrated in a small number of independent technology-based firms?
R7. Did independent technology-based firms report higher levels of absolute
employment growth than firms engaged in "conventional" activities?
4. Research Methodology
data was gathered from Science Park and off-Park firms (i.e., firms not located on
a Science Park) in Great Britain by Monck et al. (1988) I. A "follow-on"
questionnaire survey of Science Park and off-Park firms previously interviewed by
Monck et aI., was conducted in 1992/93 by Westhead and Storey (1994).
It is difficult to generalise results from a single Science Park environment. To
overcome this problem, interviews were conducted, in 1986, with a representative
sample of owner-managers of Science Park firms located in diverse range of
Science Park environments. Due to time and resource constraints, interviews could
not be conducted with the owner-managers of all firms located on Science Parks.
A random sample of Science Park firms was drawn, in 1986, by Monck et aI., from
the population of all firms located on Science Parks in Great Britain. Also,
structured questionnaires (i.e., developed with the advice from Steering
Committees) were used in 1986 and 1992 to gather information from owner-
managers of Science Park firms. Face-to-face interviews with the owner-managers
of Science Park firms were conducted (in 1986 and 1992) to ensure high response
rates to the surveys. Face-to-face interviews ensured that the owners of the
businesses responded and all appropriate information was collected.
To minimise the impact of the second limitation, a variety of objective as well as
more subjective outcomes associated with a Science Park environment were
monitored. The remaining limitations were overcome by collecting data (in 1986
and 1992) from a matched control group of owners-managers whose firms had
never been located on a property-based Science Park initiative. Using trade
directories and the Yellow Pages business directory, Monck et aI., identified a
random sample of technology-based firms not located on a Science Park in 1986.
Samples of Science Park and off-Park firms were matched, in 1986, with regard to
factors that influence business performance (i.e., business age, main industrial
activity, ownership status and standard region location; Storey 1994). To
overcome the final limitation, the Monck et aI., study conducted in 1986 and the
"follow-on" sample survey conducted in 1992/93 by Westhead and Storey (1994)
gathered employment data from Science Park and off-Park firms. The Monck et
aI., (1988) surveys as well as the Westhead and Storey (1994) "follow-on" surveys
are summarised below.
Monck et al. (1988) conducted a questionnaire survey of independent and
subsidiary organisations located on Science Parks in Great Britain. In total, 284
direct face-to-face interviews were conducted in 1986 by Monck et aI., with the
owner-managers of 183 Science Park firms (row 1 in Table 1).
IThe 1986 survey of Science Park firms conducted by Monck et al. (1988, p.64) and the
1992 survey conducted by Westhead and Storey (1994) adopted the following UKSPA
definition of a Science Park as a property-based initiative which included the following
features: has formal and operational links with a University. other Higher Education
Institution or Research Centre; is designed to encourage the formation and growth of
knowledge based businesses and other organisations normally resident on site; and has a
management function which is actively engaged in the transfer of technology and business
skills to the organisations on site.
Table 1. Survival and closure of surveyed science park organisations over the 1986 to 1992 Period (a).
'"C
4. Survived - interview completed 59 49 10 50 44 6 0;-
"
'<
CT>
during 1992/93 0-
5. Survived - either original or new 31 26 5 19 18 0"
'<
address, 1992 :::\'
0
6. Confirmed closure by the end of 1992 46 25 21 21 19 2 't:l
CT>
7. Organization has no telephone listing / 12 12 0 11 11 0 ~
not recorded in telephone .,6:len
book or trade directory by the end of 1992 CT>
0-
C/)
n
Ci·
::s
n
8. Total sample closure rate (including 43 30 CT>
to 1992 period ~
en
to.>
lJ\
I.Il
~
Table 1. (continued) Q\
This sample constituted 53% of all tenants on Science Parks in Great Britain at
that time. The coverage, however, varied from one Science Park to another (for
example, only 35% of firms located on the Cambridge Science Park were
interviewed) and no firms were surveyed at Aberystwyth, Heriot-Watt, Kent and
St. Andrews. Monck et al. (1988) acknowledged that the 1986 survey contained an
over-representation of "new wave" Science Parks but argued "". that the firms in
this survey do provide an adequate sample of Britain's new high technology
industries, providing adequate geographical, technological, sectorial and
ownership coverage" (pp. 110-111).
In 1990, Storey and Strange (1992a) conducted a follow-on pilot study of 35
Science Park organisations (rows 2 and 3 in Table 1). During 1992/93, empirical
evidence from a second, and much more extensive, longitudinal "follow-on"
survey of independent and subsidiary organisations located on Science Parks in
1986 was collected (Westhead and Storey 1994). It was decided not to re-survey
those organisations contacted in 1990.
Table 1 shows that out of the 135 independent Science Park organisations
interviewed in 1986, 92 (68%) remained in business in 1992 (rows 2, 4 and sl
Rows 3 and 6 in Table 1 show 31 independent Science Park organisations had
closed. A further 12 independent Science Park organisations could not be traced
(row 7), and were regarded as closures. Hence, the total number of independent
Science Park organisation closures was 43 (32%; row 8).
Row 9 in Table 1 shows there were 75 independent surviving Science Park
organisations in the valid 1992/93 "follow-on" sample (excluding the 17 surviving
independent organisations re-interviewed in 1990 and 43 independent organisation
closures). Structured questionnaire interviews were collected from surviving
independent organisations (in 1986) during late 1992 and early 1993. Row 4 in
Table 1 indicates 49 "follow-on" interviews were conducted with independent
Science Park organisations (6S% valid response rate; row 10)3. These interviews
explored whether a Science Park environment provided technology-based firms
with a variety of benefits. The management function on site and the role-played by
the Science Park manager/director was also explored.
2The following widely used definition of organisation closure was used: "An independent
business is regarded as a closure if, in 1992, it is no longer identifiable as a trading
business. An independent business which moves locations but continues as a trading
business is not regarded as a closure. If the business is a subsidiary or a branch plant then it
is regarded as having ceased if it no longer trades at its previous location" (Westhead and
Storey 1994, p. 25).
3Responses to the "follow-on" survey were examined for non-response bias (Westhead and
Storey 1994, pp. 33-39). No marked differences between the 1986 and 1992 "follow-on"
survey returns were recorded with regard to ownership characteristics, sectorial or
geographical coverage or the age of the surveyed organisations.
258 D. Siegel, P. Westhead and M. Wright
4Westhead et al. (1995) used multivariate logistic regression analysis to detect the
combination of factors associated with the survival of technology-based firms in the Monck
et al. (1988) samples over the 1986 to 1992 period. A Science Park location, in 1986, was
not found to be a significant determinant of business survival. They found that younger
businesses and those competing against small firms were significantly less likely to survive.
However, "team start" businesses which were owned by more than one shareholder and
those that had a founder with a bachelor's degree or more were significantly more likely to
survive.
SIn 1986, 135 independent Science Park firms were interviewed on Science Parks defined
by UKSPA. The 9 independent firms surveyed, in 1986, located on the Bolton, East Anglia
and Springfield House (Leeds) Science Parks were regarded by UKSPA as Science Park
firms. However, in 1992, these locations did not conform to UKSP As Science Park
definition. Firms surveyed in Bolton, East Anglia and Leeds were no longer regarded as
Science Park firms. Westhead and Batstone (1999) excluded these firms from their study
that compared the closure rates between independent firms located on "managed" and
"non-managed" Science Parks.
260 D. Siegel. P. Wcsthead and M. Wright
Science Park managers have exhibited a reluctance to attract and incubate new and
small weak firms. The closure rate difference may, in part, be due to deticiencies
in the management of some "managed" Science Parks. Moreover, the difference
may be due to "managed" (i.e., those generally located in depressed and peripheral
regions) Park managers being less selective (and more prepared to take risks)
surrounding their choice of tenants. This, in itself, may stem from a desire to let
the highest appropriate proportion of property in order to maximise rental income
flow. Additional multivariate statistical analysis controlling for demographic
sample differences between firms in the two groups is, therefore, required to
explain this aggregate closure rate difference.
R5. Did independent Science Park firms report higher levels of absolute
employment growth over the 1986 to 1992 period than off-Park firms ?
Flynn (1993) warned that sponsored environments (i.e., Science Parks) may
encourage negative selection (i.e., non-survival attributes being transferred to the
next generation of firms) and the survival of competitively weak organisations.
The direct employment contributions reported by surviving independent Science
Park and off-Park firms in the "follow-on" samples were compared by Westhead
and Cowling (1995). Employment data for independent firms in 1986 was
available for two points in time for 46 surviving Science Park firms (out of 49
firms) and a further 31 surviving off-Park firms (out of 44 firms). The mean
employment size, in 1986, was 11.3 employees for Science Park firms compared
with 21.4 employees for off-Park firms. This difference between the two groups of
firms was not statistically significant at the 0.05 level. By 1992/93, the Science
Park firms had grown to employ on average 26.8 people whilst the mean
employment size for off-Park firms had grown to 37.8 employees. Again, this
difference was not statistically significant. The mean absolute employment growth
reported by Science Park and off-Park firms over the 1986 to 1992 period was
virtually identical (means of 15.5 employees and 16.4 employees). No statistically
significant difference was reported Science Park and off-Park firms. Westhead and
Cowling (1995) concluded that both types of firms had made contributions to job
generation. Moreover, there was no real evidence that the Science Park sample
included a large proportion of weak organisations that had been propped up by a
sponsored environment6 . Nevertheless, additional multivariate statistical analysis
6Westhead and Cowling (1995) used multiple correlation and regression analysis to detect
the combination of factors associated with log transformed employment change over the
1986 to 1992 period reported by surviving firms in the Monck et aI. (1988) Science Park
and off-Park samples. A Science Park location, in 1986, was not found to be a significant
factor explaining subsequent employment change. With respect to factors influencing high
levels of employment growth, a high firm size (in 1986) was found to act positively on
employment growth, as was a graduate level education for the key founder. On the finance
side, firms that had access to and used a multiplicity of sources of start-up finance tended to
report superior levels of employment growth.
Support for Technology-Based Firms: The Role Played by Property-Based Science Parks 261
controlling for sample selection bias is still urgently required to confirm this
suggestion.
R6. Was absolute employment growth over the 1986 to 1992 period
concentrated in a small number of independent technology-based firms?
New and small firms are not a homogeneous group and only a small proportion
of NTBFs have the enthusiasm, ability, resources or inclination to grow (Oakey
1991). In aggregate, new and small firms make a significant contribution to the
total employment pool but this aggregate data masks a highly skewed distribution.
In short, whilst most firms employ a few people, only a few firms provide
significant employment. This assertion was conformed by evidence from the
"follow-on" samples of Science Park and off-Park firms.
Two firms in the Science Park sample reported no change in employment size
over the six-year period between 1986 and 1992. A further 9 Science Park firms
had reduced their employment size in total by 40 employees. The 35 employment
growing Science Park firms had generated an additional 753 jobs. Interestingly,
the 5 fastest employment growing Science Park firms (11 % of this sample)
accounted for 57% of these gross new jobs (i.e., 428 jobs). The skewed
distribution of employment was even more apparent in the off-Park sample. Four
off-Park firms reported no change in their employment size but a further eight
firms indicated that they had reduced their employment size in total by 115
employees. At the other extreme, the 19 employment-growing firms had generated
an additional 623 gross new jobs but the 5 fastest employment growers (i.e., 16%
of this sample) had generated 84% of these gross new jobs (i.e., 521 jobs).
Presented evidence suggests that few technology-based firms are significant
direct employment creators. Not surprisingly, a case for targeting support toward
firms (and entrepreneurs) with growth potential has been proposed (Westhead
1995). Considerable debate has, however, been generated surrounding the benefits
of targeting support and "picking winners" (Storey 1994).
R7. Did independent technology-based firms report higher levels of
absolute employment growth than firms engaged in "conventional"
activities?
Responses from the 46 Science Park firms and the 31 off-Park firms in the
"follow-on" sample were combined by Westhead and Cowling (1995) to generate
a "combined sample" containing 77 technology-based firms. They detected that
firms in the "combined sample" were larger and had recorded more absolute
employment growth than monitored firms engaged in technology-based (Oakey et
al. 1988) as well as "conventional" activities (Jones 1991; Storey and Strange
1992b).
262 D. Siegel. P. Wcsthead and M. Wright
7No statistically significant differences were detected between independent Science Park
and off-Park firms with regard to "inputs" into R&D and R&D "outputs" (Westhead 1997).
However, Science Park firms in the follow-on sample had reported in 1992/93 significantly
more links with local HErs than off-Park firms (Westhead and Storey 1995).
Support for Technology-Based Firms: The Role Played by Property-Based Science Parks 263
References
Carter, N. (1989), Science Parks Development and Management, London, The Estates
Gazette Limited.
Castells, M., and Hall, P. (1994), Technopoles of the World: The Making of 2Ft Century
Industrial Complexes, London, Routledge.
Cooke, P., and Morgan, K. (1993), "The Network Paradigm: New Departures in Corporate
and Regional Development", Environment and Planning C: Society and Space, 11, pp.
543-564.
Daly, M. (199]), "VAT Registrations and Deregistrations in 1990", Employment Gazette,
99, pp. 579-588.
Department for Trade and Industry (DTI) (1998), Our Competitive Future: Building the
Knowledge Driven Economy, Competitiveness White Paper, London, HMSO, Cm 4176.
Felsenstein, D. (1994), "University-Related Science Parks - 'Seedbeds' or 'Enclaves' of
Innovation?", Technovation. 14, pp. 93-110.
Flynn, D. M. (1993), "A Critical Exploration of Sponsorship, Infrastructure, and New
Organizations", Small Business Economics, 5, pp. 129-156.
Garnsey, E. W., and Cannon-Brookes, A. (1993), "The "Cambridge Phenomenon"
Revisited: Aggregate Change Among Cambridge High-Technology Companies Since
1985", Entrepreneurship and Regional Development, 5, pp. 179-207.
Grayson, L. (1993), Science Parks: An Experiment in High Technology Transfer, London,
The British Library.
House of Lords Select Committee on Science and Technology (1997), The Innovation
Exploitation Barrier, London, House of Lords, Paper 62.
lohannisson, B., Alexanderson, 0., Nowicki, K., and Senneseth, K. (1994), "Beyond
Anarchy and Organization: Entrepreneurs in Contextual Networks", Entrepreneurship
and Regional Developmellt, 6, pp. 329-356.
lones, C. (1996), "The Theory of Property-Lcd Local Economic Development Policies",
Regional Studies, 30, pp. 797-801.
lones, M. (1991), Small Firms Study 1985, 1988 and 1991, Coventry, University of
Warwick MBA, Unpublished Dissertation.
Keane, 1., and Allison, 1. (1999), "The Intersection of the Learning Region and Local and
Regional Economic Development: Analysing the Role of Higher Education", Regional
Studies, 33, pp. 896-901.
Massey, D., Quintas, P., and Wield, D. (1992), High Tech Fantasies: Science Parks in
Society, Science and Space, London, Routledge.
Monck, C. S. P., Porter, R. B., Quintas, P., Storey, D. 1., and Wynarczyk, P. (1988).
Science Parks and the Growth of High Technology Firms, London, Croom Helm.
Oakey, R. (1991), "High Technology Small Firms: Their Potential for RJ.pid Industrial
Growth", International Small Business Journal, 9, pp. 30-42.
Oakey, R. P., and Mukhtar, S-M. (1999), "United Kingdom High-Technology Small Firms
in Theory and Practice: A Review of Recent Trends", International Small Business
Journal, 17, pp. 48-64.
Oakey, R., Rothwell, R. and Cooper, S. Y. (1988), The Management of Innovation ill High
Technology Small Firms, London, Pinter Publishers.
Support for Technology-Based Firms: The Role Played by Property-Based Science Parks 265
Kung Wang
Abstract. This article mainly discusses Taiwan innovation system (TIS), that is,
the operation system by enterprises, government, universities and public research
laboratories of science and technology (S&T) industry development, and also the
most representative characteristics that can explain TIS, that is, 1) the technology
development program (TDP) of the Ministry of Economic Affairs (MOEA) for
instance, to illustrate the industry innovation policy by Taiwanese government; 2)
the Industry Technology Research Institute (ITRI) for instance, to explain R&D,
and technology diffusion strategy of research institutes; 3) the Hsinchu
Science-based Industrial Park (HSIP) for example, to show the way of enterprises
S&T commercialisation; 4) bringing back overseas scholars and also the talents
cultivation, to introduce supply of human resources in the academic circle. Finally,
it introduces the practical achievements of TIS by the cluster effect formed for the
development of Taiwan semiconductor industry.
1. Introduction
Taiwan is an island country, with limited natural resources and small market scale.
After the agricultural society in 1940s, there was the light industry of the people's
livelihood in 1950s, and then the petrifaction heavy industry in the 1960s. At the
beginning of 1970s, both the government and domestic and foreign scholars and
experts thought that, in order to maintain economic development, Taiwan should
develop towards hi-tech industry. Looking back at the industry situation of Taiwan
in the 70s, however, it was universally family business, and capital market has not
taken shape yet, with weak equipments and capacities in terms of basic researches
by universities. In order to enable domestic industry circle to obtain foundation for
hi-tech development, government, enterprises, and experts and scholars from
universities and public research laboratories all worked together, trying to build an
innovation system for the development of hi-tech industry. Important S&T
organizations, S&T policies and measures, and research institutes are as shown in
Figure 1.
N
o.
00
Important S&T Organizations and Important S&T Orgallizatiolls alld Importallt Research Illstitutes ?'
Conferences Conferellces
~
Go
"
19591National Long-Tenn Development iI
I
I
Science Committee I
I
!Rewarding Investment Regulations (1960)
I Chung Shan Institute of S&T (1965)
I
I
I
I ITRI (1973)
I
19761Applied Technology R&D I
I
I
I
19791Advisors Group, Executive Yuan !S&T Development Program (1979) III (1979)
I
: Science Park (1980)
I
I
19821The Second National S&T Conference I
I
I
I
:The Program of Strengthening Cultivation
I
:and Recruitment of S&T Talents (1983) Biotechnology R&D Center (1984)
I
19861The Third National S&T Conference !National S&T Ten-Year Long-Tenn
!Program (1986)
1991 IThe Fourth National S&T Conference !Leading New Products (1991)
I Bicycle R&D Center (1993)
I
Under its unique innovation system, after efforts for almosl 30 years, Taiwan
has outstanding performance concerning number of patents acquired in USA and
papers published on Science Citation Index (SCI) and (Engineering Index (EI),
comparing with other rising countries in Asia. Its overall development
achievements of S&T industry are quite good, as shown in Table l.
The main objective of this article is to introduce the innovation system with
Taiwan characteristics, with the main structure as follows: first, it discusses about
TIS, that is, the operation system by enterprises, government, universities and
public research laboratories in S&T industry development, and also the most
representative characteristics that can explain TIS, that is, 1) take TDP of the
MOEA for instance, to illustrates the industry innovation policy by Taiwanese
government; 2) Take ITRI for instance, to explain R&D, and technology diffusion
strategy of research institutes; 3) Take the HSIP for example, to show the way of
enterprises S&T commercialisation; 4) take the instance of bringing back overseas
scholars and also the talents cultivation, to introduce supply of human resources in
the academic circle. Finally, it introduces the practical achievements of TIS by the
cluster effect formed for the development of Taiwan semiconductor industry.
In this section, all the components of Taiwan's policy towards the NIS will first be
examined in broad outline. Then the focus shifts to a microcosmic analysis of the
way in which the individual institutions making up the innovation system interact
with one another. Interactions between manufacturers in the industry, co-operation
among enterprises, universities and public research laboratories, interactions that
lead to technology diffusion, movements in the labour force, international
knowledge exchanges, and other kinds of interactions will be examined to
facilitate discussion on these five aspects of communication within the NIS
(Figure 2).
272 K. Wang
Policy recomrrerrJa~fn
Ovcrse!lS Government
technology :md Professiornl ..., ...i
human resource; pvrh"nup i i
Policy suggestion
J i
~olicy suggestio
""
i j
" i "
,,~
Dl 1 i5-~
! ACldffi1ic and :=:q.
()Q
'< 0
"ri 8-« "i':l
5·
q Dl
i ""eareb institut, ~ -. j (JQ
~O~Mplru D["
~
;J Training Progr.
"n·
O,t n
00
IndU'Stry and '??..t-Q, IndU'Stry and
"""0;.
"
;:;. Research Institut • "'<>"b~ %~... a Universities
g O)operation ~<:r • q0~ ~ Cooperation
" ""
J Enterprises .. I
1 innovatifNl
Inlustry WVlSlOO lU"ll"K, HUllS I)' aggncgation
effect
connection and verifiability etc., and also high-benefit technology with the
capability to increase public welfare and public investment etc. are chosen as the
main R&D items, therefore, the promotion of TDP plays a decisive role in the
development of overall industry and economy.
The positioning of TDP is mainly to carry out the development of planned
technology based on requirement by the development of enterprises. Enterprises
development factors include capital, human resources, technology, market,
resources, environmental protection, infrastructure and related management
system etc., therefore, TDP selects technology needed for promoting enterprises
development as the prerequisite, adopts the development strategy of independent
technology development and bringing in overseas hi-tech industry, and engage in
product development of important components and parts, important examination
technology, decide technology standards and establish management system of
intellectual property, to further raise technology of enterprises.
In order to help forward industry upgrade, strengthen effects to industrial circles
by TDP, various forms and channels are used to implement the R&D outcomes of
TDP on enterprises. During the program execution period, enterprises can make
use of R&D outputs of research institutions by participation in advance,
cooperated research and authorization transfer etc. After the program is finished,
research institutions put into effect the R&D outcomes in the industrial circles by
technology transfer and patent authorization etc. Information exchange, seminar,
professionals diffusion and all kinds of industrial services can all help to establish
the exchange channels between research institutions and enterprises, and this kind
of channel also helps to diffuse R&D outcomes of TDP to enterprises without
taking a form, professionals diffusion is especially a method that applies
technology directly and practically in enterprises.
In order to fulfil the important mission of upgrading industry technology, the
Technology Section selects and adopts measures based on industry change
appropriately, furthermore, it has to have an insight into present and future
industry requirement from a foresighted and macroscopic point of vie"" to raise
proper measures during different stages (MOEA 2001). Looking back, in addition
to constantly appointing mainly ITRI, Development Centre for Biotechnology
(DCB), institute for Information Industry (III) etc. non-profit research institutions
to carry out technology development starting from 1979, and adopting all kinds of
channels like technology transfer, technology seminar, industrial services, and
derivative companies establishment etc. to implement R&D outcomes extensively
in the industrial circles, to really help S&T industries to become main force of
Taiwan industries today, it also uses proprietors as the direct object of measures to
promote enterprises to join in R&D in an all-round manner, to fulfil the measures
of upgrading enterprises technology. This can be traced back to 1994 when
promoting enterprises cooperation, proprietors participated in since the planning
stage of TDP, so that the R&D program by research institutions can be more
suitable to requirement by enterprises, and the participation by proprietors during
the research procedures can help to accelerate the commercialisation procedures of
technology as an answer to the shortening of technology life cycle. In order to
accelerate in helping the industrial circles to set up S&T type enterprises, using
High-Tech Industrial Clusters in the Asian Countries 275
preferential land tax and other levies, and management environment five items of
important factors, to be used to illustrate the way of bringing technology into
products by hi-tech manufacturers in HSIP.
HSIP had a large external demand in early days, ITRI could be regarded as
important technological sources for HSIP, and manufacturers could also appoint
ITRI to develop product technology or solve technological problems. For
technological demand, government appointing applied research institutions such
as ITRI near HSIP to carry out R&D and also put R&D outcomes into use by the
industrial circles, has brought obvious results. With the growth of HSIP, the
technological sources have already included overseas or technology transfer and
cooperation, or from nearby Tsing Hua and Chiao Tung University. However,
manufacturers in HSIP presently are still searching for technology development
related information from ITRI, and also looking for new field, so its role has
changed from the predominant one to supporting functions like encouraging to
innovate, information, and assisting settlement of technological problems, only in
some innovation fields, it is still an important technological source for HSIP.
In order to encourage manufacturers to engage in R&D of innovation
technology, government provides grants for R&D of innovation technology to
manufacturers in HSIP. It has been 14 years since it was implemented in 1986,
and has become an important resource for helping HSIP to increase technology
competitiveness. The government has provided grants to 24 research programs in
1999, totalling NT$67 million, at 28.1 % of the total invested amount of NT$241
million. Up to 1999, altogether 478 programs received grants, at the amount of
NT$896 million. Furthermore, in order to encourage manufacturers to research
and develop key components & parts and products, the government has provided
key components & parts and products subsidy for R&D by manufacturer~ in HSIP.
From July 1992 to June 1999, there are 88 that have passed examination, and for
the total R&D funds of NT$6.33 billion, NT$2.472 billion was approved to
recei ve subsidy (Science-based Industrial Park Administration 1999).
For the development of high technology, talents are an important factor, and the
aggregation of high-level human resources is the most significant characteristics
of HSIP, and also an important resource promoting the gestation of hi-tech
industry. Concerning the supply of human resources, manufacturers can easily
recruit human resources needed, and can provide training for on-the-job personnel
and raise personnel quality, at the same time, it attracts talents, including bringing
in hi-tech entrepreneurs, that is why government chooses the place near
universities and research institutions to set up HSIP.
High-Tech Industrial Clusters in the Asian Countries 279
Taiwan has started to engage in the development of hi-tech industry since 1980s.
Since local people were lack of R&D ability, overseas scholars were recruited,
especially those who have worked in Silicon Valley. They brought technology
ability, marketing information, equipments purchase information etc. to
Taiwanese, and based on their experience overseas, technology transfer and
cooperation were expanded and even branch companies were set up, and
Taiwanese also went to join in overseas technology seminar to master the
information about advanced technology. In order to create newly risen enterprises,
overseas scholars were recruited to bring in technology. The companies
established by Taiwanese scholars who went to study overseas, from its start-up to
healthy growth, all made significant contribution. There are 109 these kind of
companies in HSIP by the end of 1998, with nearly 3,056 people. The technology
and ideology brought back by these scholars have deeply rooted in the SIP and
developed, which shows the performance of this measure obviously.
In addition, many high-level technology talents from research institutions were
attracted to start enterprises in SIP, for example, the first non-governmental
integrated design company in Taiwan - Syntek Design Technology Co. Ltd. was
established in HSIP in 1981. The General Manager of the Company was formerly
the Manager of Circuit Design Department of Electronics Bureau, ITRI, and the
R&D Manager and Layout Engineer were also originally from ITRI. In 1983, it
established Greatek Electronics, and among its main shareholders, seven are from
ITRI, each takes on its main technology post.
During the early days, HSIP manufacturers were in great demand of technological
professionals for starting new business. In addition to recruiting overseas scholars,
there are derived companies from ITRI, such as United Microelectronics
Corporation (UMC), Taiwan Semiconductor Manufacturing Corporation (TSMC)
etc., all bring human resources to HSIP. Moreover, there are also quite a lot who
resigned and started business in HSIP or joined in manufacturers, and technology
diffusion is also one of R&D results that government uses to evaluate ITRI. In
S&T circles, all consider the transfer of technology people is the best way for
technology transfer, thus, for electronics and information talents of HSIP, ITRI is
an important source.
The demand on human resources by HSIP has expanded gradually, including
those located at basic level and middle level. ITRI is still an important source for
middle-level manpower of manufacturers in HSIP, and for the gradual expansion
of basic-level manpower required, graduates from Tsing Hua and Chiao Tung
University provide the supply. In addition, the manpower demand by HSIP during
early phases required experience, therefore, students who just graduate regard
ITRI as the "Shaolin Temple", a place for studying R&D ability, and advance to
HSIP after three to five years, even manufacturers in HSIP regarded this as a
reference criterion when evaluating employees' value. After the demand increases
280 K. Wang
gradually and companies reach certain growth stage, by the method of hens
leading chickens, graduating students become the very important new force. In
particular, for the characteristics, prospect, payment and welfare of hi-tech
industries in SIP all have very strong attraction, there is no special difficulty in the
respect of recruiting good staff. Only for the change on industry technology, the
semiconductor industry in HSIP has greatly attracted many talents, thus brought
some squeezing phenomenon, consequently, what manufacturers recruit may not
necessarily be from the right department and can master the work within short
time, which increases the cost for on-the-job training and short-term training by
enterprises in HSIP, and also is a waste of education resources.
In order to cooperate with technology development and manpower demand by
enterprises, improve manpower quality, and shorten the time for new entrants'
before-the-job training, the Administration Bureau of HSIP has cooperated with
research institutions like Chiao Tung and Tsing Hua University, ITRI etc. to help
all kinds of training for professional technology human resources, such as
professionals training for deep sub-micrometer and liquid crystal display,
integration between communication and computer, computer and automation etc.
eight items of specialized technology, and also management, a second skill, and
evening on-the-job training etc. From 1993 to 1998, there are altogether 24,390
people undergoing training, and 18,271 participating in management course and
special topic discussion (MOEA 1999), which indicates that people who work in
HSIP are taking an active attitude towards participation in training courses when
facing fast development of technology, to keep their competitiveness. Recently,
the Ministry of Education has opened the on-the-job class for master degree,
which will be a catalyst to further promote improvement on manpower quality.
This is the convenience on manpower recruitment and training of human resources
brought by the government choosing places close to academic and research
institutions to set up science park.
During the early stages, there was SIP providing land needed for setting up plants,
but difficulty in acquiring capital, especially for technology industry with high
risks. For the gradual establishment of capital market in Taiwan, capital changes
to mainly come from capital market, and the following gives an analysis on
influence of HSIP hi-tech manufacturers' capital demand concerning policies like
government providing funds for starting business and working capiLal etc.
the economy is in good cycle, these factors helping to start business can almost
create another manufacturer at any time.
In order to assist manufacturers to acquire working capital, the government has
adopted many measures, such as the measure of accelerated depreciation of
equipments, so that those with very large investment on equipments can delay in
paying taxes for accelerated depreciation, and also get working capital without
interest, which have quite significant influence on semiconductor and
optoelectronics mainly for manufacture. The government also looses its regulation
on retaining surplus and compulsory distribution. Following the trends of getting
funds easily by HSIP manufacturers, the influence on them is also relatively
reduced. Furthermore, the government provides middle and long-term low-interest
bank loan, and invests in manufacture of key products for important S&T
enterprises, this policy has the function of leading manufacturers to invest in
products with foresight and also risks. So it suits relatively more to the demand of
expanding funds by manufacturers of HSIP.
There was insufficient investment on high technology in Taiwan during the 1980s.
In order to encourage investment, the government has adopted many measures, for
instance, the income tax for profit business can enjoy 5 (4) years of exemption
from taxation, accelerated depreciation, paying taxes within limited amount,
investment offset, loosened expenses etc. Preferential taxes, which can really be
considered as great achievements in reducing and exempting from taxes.
Among all measures of reducing and exempting from taxes in HSIP, that the
income tax for profit business can enjoy 5 (4) years of exemption from taxation
brings the most favourable treatment for manufacturers, since it has significant
influence on manufacturers' profit, reduce payment of taxes. For the business
income tax of Taiwan enterprises, it is averagely 25%, in order to encourage
hi-tech manufacturers' investment in HSIP, the government has adopted
preferential measures on their business income tax. The first several years for
hi-tech new businesses are normally in deficit, however, it still encourages
investment, and its achievements can be detected from the fast accumulation of
capitals in HSIP.
The government gives five-year free business income tax (exemption five) for
businesses belonging to emerging and important S&T enterprises, and four-year
free business income tax for locating in HSIP (exemption four). Since almost all
enterprises in HSIP can enjoy five-year exemption and also four-year preference,
they enjoy more favourable treatment comparing with manufacturers outside HSIP.
The main goal of exemption five is to provide free tax during the initial stage of
establishment to S&T type enterprises with relatively great risks, to encourage
entrepreneurial spirit and start emerging S&T industries.
In order to reduce the cost for instruments and equipments of hi-tech enterprises
and raw material, and further to increase business profit, the government has
adopted import duties and goods tax reduction and exemption measures, to
High-Tech Industrial Clusters in the Asian Countries 283
above master degree to engage in short-term research work: in order to assist those
from home and abroad at above master degree to get a job, before they decide
whom to work for, arrange them to engage in short-term research work to store up
talents. There are funds for subsidizing around 100 short-term researchers, to
employ by agreement, with the agreement term at most one year; (2) assist talents
at Ph.D. to engage in short-term research work: assist talents with Ph.D. degree to
work in non-governmental organizations, encourage non-governmental
organizations to use Ph.D. level talents, to cultivate talents needed for important
national construction plan, promote implementation of high-level human resources,
and also raise quality of non-governmental talents. The National Youth
Commission subsidizes research remuneration at 50 researchers every year, with
the longest subsidization term at most one year.
In the respect of bringing in R&D talents, to accelerate the upgrade of domestic
industries, the government brings in specialists lacked in Taiwan as well as trains
up actively high-level R&D talents, to improve S&T R&D ability, accelerate the
development of supporting industry to the most advanced S&T, and expand
recruitment of overseas high-level S&T talents, for example, NSC provides
subsidy to S&T figures from China or from China to the third region to come to
Taiwan to participate in S&T research program for public and private universities,
public research institutions and national laboratories. For the MOEA, in order to
assist domestic non-governmental enterprises to expand recruiting overseas
technology talents to return home to serve, any specialist beneficial to raise
technology and added value of enterprises can raise work program together with
their employer, after examination and approval by "Examination Committee for
Recruiting Overseas Industry Specialists", they can receive subsidy for the
specialists' salary part, at the limit of three years.
In order to strengthen the implementation of overseas high-level technology
talents and domestic talents above master degree, the government has adopted
many recruitment measures (NSC 2000a), such as: (1) set up service window of
"strengthen implementing high-level S&T talents program", to provide
introduction of this program and also information needed by each domestic
institution, and the execution unit includes each unit under the Executive Yuan,
state-run enterprises and ITRI etc.; (2) hold high-level human resources seminar
and exhibition, to assist talents above master degree to understand working
environment of Taiwan, and encourage enterprises to recruit high-level talents; (3)
starts to hold seminars for introducing overseas new S&T since May 1994, to
discuss the ten top emerging industries, and also assist scholars travelling overseas
to come home to give lecture and pay visits.
In the respect of training industry technology talents, in order to cooperate with
industry upgrade and train talents required by industry development, the MOEA
has advanced comprehensively the "Phase I five-year plan for training of industry
technology talents" from July 1990 to June 1995, including raising product quality,
industry design, industry automation, industry manufacture process technology etc.
talents training, and started carrying out phase II five-year plan since 1996. It
carried on advancing "Five-year plan for training of industry technology talents"
in 2000, to strengthen combining academic, research institutions and
High-Tech Industrial Clusters in the Asian Countries 285
serving customers without having to go far, most establish their base inside HSIP
or in its vicinity, so that the upper, middle, and lower-reach system of integrated
circuits industry are almost all concentrated in a closed geographic area. We can
regard this kind of industries cluster situation as a gigantic production satellite
system or imagine it as a "virtual" large company with vertical integration of
upper and lower reach. Almost without geographic and transportation limitation,
more economical ways can be used to carry out mutual communication or
products transportation. Comparing with large enterprises system of USA, Japan
and Korea, for this large "visual" company of this mode can have the effect of
each "enterprise system" concentrating on their own specialized fields, to develop
the flexibility and fast emergency reaction ability of small enterprises into full,
thus their competitiveness is greatly raised.
The unique innovation system of Taiwan causes the cluster effect of HSIP
without the intention. For semiconductor industry, more than 90% of its upper and
lower-reach enterprises are concentrated in Taipei, Taoyuan, and Hsinchu etc.
County and City, so it is the most obvious one, as shown in Figure 3. This kind of
cluster effect helps Taiwan semiconductor industry to take a place globally. In
2000, Taiwan has a market share as high as 70% of global Original Equipment
Manufactor (OEM) market, and around 20% share of Dynamic Random Access
Memory (DRAM) production.
The cluster effect of semiconductor industry in HSIP has quite evident effect on
related businesses establishment. Take integrated circuits design for instance,
there were 3 integrated circuits design companies in Taiwan during the first half of
the 1980s, only one was in HSIP. For the 84 companies established after 1995,40
were established in HSIP, and as high as 62 if calculating together with Hsinchu
County and City. Please refer to Table 2.
Table 2. Relation table of Taiwan integrated circuits (IC) design industry establishment
time and geographic location.
Number 1980- 1985- 1990- 1995-
Taipei City 7 9 8
Taipei County 6 4 3
HSIP 4 12 40
Hsinchu City 3 12
Hsinchu County 10
Tainan County 1
Source: Semiconductor Industry Yearbook, June, 2001.
288 K. Wang
Ie Design 28
Wafer
Design Tools 5
Ie Design
Ie Manufacture
Ie Package
Ie Testing
Wafer
Mask
Tools
Optoelectronics
o•
... ..
Ie Design
o
I
40KM
9. Conclusions
References
Freeman, C. (1987), Technology and Economic Preference: Lesson from Japan, London,
Printer.
Industrial Economics & Knowledge Centre (June 2001), 2001 Semiconductor Industry
Yearbook, Taiwan, IEK.
Lundvall, B-A. (ed.) (1922), National Innovation Systems: Towards a Theory of Innovation
and Interactive Learning, London, Printer.
Ministry of Economic Affairs (1999), White Book of Industrial Technology 1998 Taiwan,
R.O.C., MOEA.
Ministry of Economic Affairs (2001), MDEA Technology Development Program 2000,
Taiwan, MOEA.
290 K. Wang
National Science Council (2000a), The Annual Report of Science and Technology in R. 0. C,
Executive Yuan, Taiwan, NSC.
National Science Council (2000b), Indicators of Science and Technology R.o.C 2000,
Executive Yuan, Taiwan, NSC.
Nelson, R. (ed.) (l993), National Innovation Systems: a Comparative Analysis, New
York/Oxford, Oxford University Press.
OECD (1997), National Innovation Systems, OECD.
Science-based Industrial Park Administration (l998), The Annual Report of Hsinchu
Science-based Industrial Park, Taiwan, NSC.
Science-based Industrial Park Administration (1999), The Statistics of Quarterly Report of
Science-based Industrial Park, Taiwan, NSC.
Financial Markets, Industrial Clusters
and Small and Medium-Size Enterprises
Angelo Tantazzi I
IMy thanks to Alessandra Franzosi and Enrico Pellizzoni (Market Research and Analysis,
Borsa Italiana) for their invaluable contribution to the analytical portion of this
presentation.
292 A. Tantazzi
account for an estimated two million jobs, and industrial clusters contribute one-
third of Italy's exports.
While the quantitative importance of industrial clusters is indisputable, the
structural weaknesses that are inherent in the cluster system have been pointed out
repeatedly in recent years. The main weaknesses include the vulnerability of
clusters to innovations that originate outside the cluster, the lack of economies of
scale at the individual company level (offset only in part by system-wide
economies of scale) and the inability of industrial clusters to formulate a well-
defined strategy in the absence of a system leader. It has been suggested often that
these problems could be overcome if the individual manufacturers can be made to
grow to a large enough size while, at the same time, retaining their entrepreneurial
spirit, flexibility and ties to local traditions. One of the obstacles to growth for
these enterprises (as well as for the Italian economy as a whole) is the absence of a
financial system that can provide adequate support to companies in their efforts to
expand.
In order to understand how the stock exchange and the financial markets in
general can help strengthen and energize Italy's industrial clusters, one must first
clearly define the concept of industrial cluster, wlth the goal of identifying the
different configurations that exist within clusters and of understanding, given
these different internal organizations, the various problems and specific challenges
they face. Studies of industrial economics usually make reference to "small
business systems" the main structural characteristics of which are summarized
below:
• There is a strong manufacturing specialization at the local level, which is
identifiable not just by the preponderance of one industry or area of
manufacturing, but also by a production system that links different
subsystems. These systems are all tied to a single product that is
characteristic of the local economy.
• The production of the cluster is sufficiently large to account for a sizable
percentage of the national and/or international output for the industry or
specific product that the cluster specializes in.
• There is a very clear division of labour among the companies in the local
system, which produces a high level of horizontal integration with low
transaction costs.
• There is a plurality of small and medium-size enterprises instead of one
leading company that dominates the local system.
• An information system has evolved spontaneously within the cluster,
transforming the knowledge of the individual entrepreneurs into a common
asset.
• The employees are highly skilled.
• There is a high rate of new business creation.
• There is an abundance of entrepreneurial spirit that fuels the growth of the
manufacturing system.
This definition is broad and applies to a number of possible system
configurations. In order to measure the importance of cluster companies
Financial Markets, Industrial Clusters and Small and Medium-Size Enterprises 293
quantitatively at the stock market level and determine whether they have a
different relevance within the context of the overall financial system, according to
the characteristics that identify each area and its different growth potential, we
must first analyse these complex systems systematically, classifying them into
three types of small and medium-size business systems (Garofoli 1983):
• In the so-called specialized manufacturing areas, companies compete in the
same markets, since they produce the same goods or do the same processing
work. The system's structure is horizontal.
• In the case of "local manufacturing systems", small enterprises operate
within the same industry, as is the case for "specialized manufacturing
areas", but intra-industry transactions between companies are quite extensive
(quality subcontracting). There is no production integration among the
different areas of manufacturing, the structure of the industrial system is
adequate and technology is generally imported from outside the system.
• In the so-called system districts (for example, Biella, Vigevano, Prato, Carpi,
Sassuolo), the division of labour among the different enterprises is quite
extensive, resulting in the gradual development of a local manufacturing
system. There are intra - and inter - industry transactions that lead to the
creation of a system that produces capital goods used to manufacture finished
products. The development of the district is driven by the utilization of local
resources (entrepreneurs, capital, skilled workforce, local technology).
The different situations described above, while characterizing different
production systems, also provide an outline that could explain the evolution of
industrial clusters. The classic Italian industrial cluster, in its original incarnation,
meets the criteria of the third definition provided above - i.e., the system district.
The distinctive features of industrial clusters are small individual companies, a
fragmented manufacturing system and the existence of a deeply rooted individual
and/or family-based entrepreneurial culture. Under these circumstances, the
growth of cluster companies to a size large enough to permit access to financing as
a means of further expansion - including, ultimately, access to the capital markets
- generally occurs over the long term.
However, the world of traditional industrial clusters is particularly vulnerable to
structural change caused by the occurrence of extraordinary conditions resulting
from the shock of innovations and/or external competition.
When this occurs, industrial clusters generally are forced to alter their "natural"
growth path, changing their traditional configuration and morphing into "local
manufacturing systems" or "specialized manufacturing areas". This process of
transformation is driven by the development of new, dynamic organizations that
are better suited to grow rapidly. Obviously, the emergence of companies of
unequal size can undermine the specificity of a traditional industrial cluster,
because large enterprises lack the operating flexibility and adaptability that make a
cluster organization inherently efficient. However, in the presence of an external
shock, substantial changes, including the adoption of a new organizational
structure, are essential to the very survival of a manufacturing system.
The availability of adequate financial resources is crucial, particularly during
these transitional phases, and is of vital importance in allowing districts to
294 A. Tantazzi
Owing in part to the differences in the way industrial clusters evolve (as outlined
above), the number and size of cluster companies that are publicly traded in Italy
can vary widely, depending on which definition of "industrial cluster" is chosen.
If the most comprehensive (but also the most restrictive) definition of "system
district" is used - i.e., the definition that specifies a high degree of intra - and inter-
industry integration achieved as a result of local growth that is made possible by
the optimum utilization of local resources only, the percentage of publicly traded
companies is relatively small. Based on the classification of industrial clusters
developed by Ceris (Istituto di ricerca sull'impresa e 10 sviluppo) - CNR
(Consiglio Nazionale delle Ricerche) (1997), only four cluster leader companies
are listed on Borsa Italiana's capital markets. They are: Luxottica and Safilo,
which are the leaders of the Cadore (Veneto region) eyeglass cluster; Ratti for the
Como silk cluster; and Olivetti for the Canavese (Piemonte region) information
technology cluster.
Table 1 lists publicly traded companies that operate in Italy within districts
characterized by a high degree of manufacturing specialization, identified on the
basis of the percentage of the total national exports of a specific product provided
by the respective provinces. The definition used in this case is that of "specialized
manufacturing area".
Using this definition, the number of publicly traded companies increases to 25.
The most important companies include Benetton and Stefanel (province of
Treviso) and Marzotto (province of Vicenza) for the garment industry; Tod's
(province of Ascoli Piceno) for the footwear industry; and Merloni (province of
Ancona) for the household appliance industry. These large companies are the
product of manufacturing systems - the Northeast cluster and the Adriatic
backbone cluster - that started at the local level and, during the last ten years,
became important players in the national economy. Other examples include
smaller but very dynamic companies such as Gewiss, which produces electrical
equipment in the province of Bergamo; I.M.A. Industrie Meccaniche, which
manufactures packaging equipment in Bologna; and Emak, a producer of
agricultural equipment in the province of Reggio Emilia.
The relative importance of this group of "publicly traded cluster companies" is
significant both economically and in terms of its impact on stock market
indicators. Based on aggregate data taken from corporate annual reports for 1999
(source: BUREAU van Dijk 2001), this group of companies employed more than
48,000 people and had revenues of 15,941 billion lire and invested capital of
22,554 billion lire, including 6,705 billion lire in stockholders' equity.
With respect to stock market statistics, at the end of May 2001, this group of
companies accounted for 2.7% of the total capitalization of the Italian stock
market. If the focus is narrowed to the macro group of industrial companies (to
which all publicly traded cluster companies belong), the relative weight of these
companies is greater, since they account for 21.7% of the group's total
capitalization.
N
Table 1. Quantitative imQact of cluster comQanies on the Italian Stock Market*. -.0
a-
COMPANY AREA CAPIT AUZA TION % TOT. JAN-MAY % TOT.
(millions of euros) CAP. TRADING TRADING ;>
...,
..,
VOLUME VOLUME
(millions of euros)
.,.'"
N
t:L
* This list includes only companies that operate in the "specialized manufacturing areas" as defined by Fortis in II Made in Italy, Editrice II
Mulino. .,~
:::
** Trading volume is also for the January-March period, during which the STAR Segment was not yet operational. Q.
'"
N
~
-.J
298 A. Tantazzi
When stated as a percentage of the 2001 trading volume (the Blue Chip
Segment accounts for 95% of the total), the contribution of publicly traded cluster
companies is relatively small (0.195% of the total). However, when the blue chip
shares are excluded, the relative weight of the cluster companies rises
significantly, reaching 11.4% of capitalization and 11.5% of the trading volume.
It is important to remember that cluster companies represent a considerable
portion of all publicly traded small and medium-size companies and that the
potential impact of unlisted cluster companies is highly significant when viewed
against the need to expand, both quantitatively and qualitatively, the roster of
Italian listed companies and bring the Italian stock market on a par with those of
other major European countries. At this point, about 2,000 small and medium-size
companies operating in traditional industries (internal estimate of Borsa Italiana)
are large enough to be considered for listing. More than one-third of these
companies belong to manufacturing sectors that are concentrated in industrial
clusters operating in the following fields: mechanical engineering (200
companies), textiles/garments (191 companies), food (134 companies), electrical
equipment (65 companies), furniture and furnishings (57 companies), ceramics
(31 companies) and jewellery (9 companies).
The recent introduction of the STAR Segment in the stock market is designed to
create a new regulatory, organizational and microstructural framework that is
better suited to enhancing the value of small and medium-size industrial
enterprises while providing a source of diversification and offering retail and
institutional investors attractive investment opportunities in areas that previously
had been neglected due to problems of visibility, transparency and liquidity. In
keeping with this approach, the stock market listing of cluster companies should
meet with a more favourable reception than in the past.
Borsa Italiana has designated liquidity and the transparency of information as
the two key areas in which STAR Segment companies will be required to make a
major effort.
The presence of a sponsor in the primary market, with responsibility for
performing the requisite due diligence work and ensuring periodic follow-up
research after the initial listing, and of a specialist in the secondary market (who
can be the same as the sponsor), coupled with regulatory requirements that ensure
a steady flow of information (prompt release of quarterly financial data in Italian
and English for STAR companies), helped solve the problems of limited direct
and indirect information, which is typical of small companies, and lack of
liquidity. This approach removes the danger of an inefficient pricing mechanism
and eliminates cost of capital distortions that occur when the market demands a
liquidity premium at the time of offering. For the same reason, the specialist is
required to ensure an orderly market, setting bid and asked quotes within a limited
Financial Marl,.ets. Industrial Clusters and Small and Medium-Size Enterprises 299
spread while at the same time doing research that is designed to support the issuer
company through the publication of information on its performance and the
performance of the industry within which it operates.
ST AR companies must pay special attention to establishing effective corporate
governance systems so as to be able to provide the market with adequate disclosure
on their organization and on their general and operating performance. These
companies must comply with the Code of Conduct for Listed Companies.
Accordingly, they must appoint a sufficient number of independent directors to their
boards, establish an audit committee to oversee internal control systems and appoint
an "investor relator" to ensure continuity in their relations with investors and
intermediaries. The online services that Borsa Italiana has developed to meet the
special needs of institutional investors complete the framework of programs
designed with the specific purpose of increasing the visibility of new issuers and
creating the conditions necessary to trigger a virtuous circle that will be beneficial
for:
• Issuers, who will be able to successfully float secondary offerings with less
burdensome costs.
• Institutional investors, who will operate in a market that will be more
supportive of their interest in small and medium-size enterprises.
• Intermediaries, who will have an opportunity to specialize in origination and
research in the area of small and medium-size companies and in the
establishment of small-cap funds.
• The quantitative and qualitative expansion of the market, since a listing
system that ensures maximum transparency and orderly trading conditions
will help foster interest among companies that are potential candidates for
listing.
Even though the STAR Segment was created only recently, making the analysis
period relatively short, early evidence on trading in STAR securities has already
shown positive results:
• During the April-May period, the average number of contracts for STAR
securities executed daily was 14.6% higher than in the first three months of
the year, while the overall market declined by 2.3%.
• A similar trend was observed in the average daily value of the transactions
(+9.3% for STAR, -2.0% for the overall market).
• Volatility decreased by 17% for STAR securities, as against a drop of just
10.9% for the overall market.
At present, four of the 25 listed companies from the clusters shown in the
preceding table have agreed to be included in the STAR Segment. They are: CSP
International (a company based in the Castel Goffredo cluster, in the province of
Mantova, that controls some of the top women's hosiery brands), Interpump
Group (hydraulic pumps in the province of Reggio Emilia), Mariella Burani
(garments and fashion, also in the province of Reggio Emilia) and Sabaf (kitchen
furniture in the province of Brescia). At present, they represent 20% of the listed
companies included in the STAR Segment, 14.7% of the Segment capitalization
and 35.9% of the value of all trades executed in 2001.
300 A. Tantazzi
The fact that these companies chose to join STAR during the start-up phase
(trading in the Segment's securities began on April 2, 2001) shows that the
Segment's organizational and structural characteristics are being well received by
enterprises. The STAR Segment was launched to fill the relationship gaps that
existed until now in certain areas between the financial markets and medium-size
companies, despite these companies' excellent fundamentals and strong
competitive positions.
Economic literature and the case histories of individual companies concur in
showing that the financial markets playa decisive role in the development of
economic systems. The entities that oversee the operations of these markets are
responsible for stimulating the growth of their national economies by providing
enterprises with the tools necessary to seize the opportunities created by changing
competitive conditions. In pursuit of this goal, Borsa Italiana has focused its
efforts on restructuring the Italian financial markets. Easier access to the financial
markets and, consequently, to new sources of capital for small and medium-size
companies means making available to industrial clusters - the very heart of Italian
industry - a vital tool in their effort to manage the competitive repositioning
required by an accelerating process of globalisation.
References
Her book, The Geography of Innovation (Kluwer 1994), is in its second printing.
She is also editor of The Oxford University Handbook of Economic Geography
(with Gordon Clark and Meric Gertler, Oxford University Press, 2000),
Innovation Policy in the Knowledge-Based Economy (with AI Link, Kluwer,
2000) and the forthcoming Institutions and Systems in the Geography of
Innovation (with Nadine Massard, Kluwer, 2001).
Mario A. Maggioni. He holds a Master of Science and a Ph.D. from the Warwick
University, Coventry (UK). Now Associate Professor of Economics at the Faculty
of Political Sciences at Universita Cattolica (Milano). Member of the Steering
304 List of Authors
Charles F. Sabel. He received an A.B. from Harvard in 1969 and a Ph.D. in 1978.
Currently he is Professor of Law and Social Science, Columbia Law School.
Publications include: "Quale volano per gli standard internazionali di protezione
sociale? Proposta per un progressivo miglioramento delle condizioni di lavoro
nell'economia globalizzata" with Archon Fung and Dara O'Rourke, in: II diriUo
del Mercato del Lavoro, n.1I200 1; "Treatment Courts and Emergent
Experimentalist Government" (with Michael Dort), Vanderbilt Law Review (April
2000); "An Unlikely Democracy: The US at the Millennium", lnternationale
Politik und Gesellschaft 112000 and presented at the OECD Forum for the Future
Conference, Berlin, December 1999; Design. Deliberation and Democracy,
(1998); The Second Industrial Divide: Possibilities for Prosperity (with Michael
Priore, 1984).