10 1017@dem 2019 10
10 1017@dem 2019 10
doi:10.1017/dem.2019.10
R E S E A R C H PA P E R
Abstract
This paper revisits the question of how brain drain affects the optimal education policy of
a developing economy. Our framework of analysis highlights the complementarity
between public spending on education and students’ efforts to acquire human capital in
response to career opportunities at home and abroad. Given this complementarity, we
find that brain drain has conflicting effects on the optimal provision of public
education. A positive response is called for when the international earning differential
with destination countries is large, and when the emigration rate is relatively low. In
contrast with the findings in the existing literature, our numerical experiments show
that these required conditions are in fact present in a large number of developing
countries; they are equivalent to those under which an increase in emigration induces a
net brain gain. As a further contribution, we study the interaction between the optimal
immigration policy of the host country and education policy of the source country in a
game-theoretic framework.
1. Introduction
Migration of skilled labor from the developing to the advanced countries has been the
subject of extensive research over the last four decades. Efforts to measure these flows,
including the works of Docquier and Marfouk (2006), Artuc et al. (2015), and Arslan
et al. (2015), indicate that skilled emigration, as a proportion of the economy’s skilled
population, is particularly large in the case of relatively poor and small developing
†
This paper benefited from the helpful suggestions of three anonymous referees. It was initiated when
the first author was visiting the Department of Economics of the University of Cyprus. Slobodan Djajić
wishes to thank the Department for its hospitality and support. Frédéric Docquier acknowledges
financial support from the EOS programme of the Flemish (FWO) and French-speaking (FRS-FNRS)
communities of Belgium (convention 30784531 on “Winners and Losers from Globalization and Market
Integration: Insights from Micro-Data”).
© Université catholique de Louvain 2019
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
272 Slobodan Djajić et al.
1
Rates of over 80% are reported for several Caribbean and Pacific nations and they exceed 50% in some
African countries.
2
See Commander et al. (2004) and Docquier and Rapoport (2017) for surveys of the various issues and
evidence related to the brain drain.
3
The financing of higher education in developing countries has been largely borne by the government
through tax financing with very little or zero costs borne by students [World Bank (2010), p. 5]. Teferra
(2007) notes that in virtually all sub-Saharan countries, the state provides over 90% of the support for
higher education.
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
Journal of Demographic Economics 273
4
Some of the early contributions to this literature include Bhagwati and Hamada (1974), Djajić (1989),
Miyagiwa (1991), Mountford (1997), Wong (1997), Stark et al. (1997), Vidal (1998), and Wong and Yip
(1999). See also Klein and Ventura (2009), Benhabib and Jovanovic (2012), Ortega and Peri (2014), di
Giovanni et al. (2015), and Docquier et al. (2017, 2018) for more recent analysis of the welfare
implications at the global level.
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
274 Slobodan Djajić et al.
5
Poutvaara (2008) also demonstrates that such a negative outcome could be avoided by introducing
graduate taxes or income-contingent loans for students to be (re)paid in case of emigration.
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
Journal of Demographic Economics 275
and examine the implications of (i) a reduction in the cost of providing educational
services in the source country, (ii) a shift in preferences on immigration in the host
country, and (iii) a change in the degree of international transferability of human
capital. Our focus is on the amount of effort exerted by students in school, the
optimal level of source-country spending on education, and the optimal immigration
quota of the host country in the Nash equilibrium. One of our findings is that in an
LM equilibrium, an increase in the international transferability of human capital
entails an expansion of the immigration quota of the host country and an increase in
spending on education in the source country. By contrast, in a “high-migration”
(HM) equilibrium, defined as an environment in which a higher emigration rate
reduces the economy’s net stock of human capital, an increase in the transferability
of human capital may entail a reduction in spending on education by the source
country. We conclude the paper in section 5 by highlighting its principal contributions.
where w is the real wage in S per unit of skill (or efficiency labor) acquired by the
student and ε is the level of educational services dispensed by the authorities of S.
Only public education is available and it is provided to students free of charge
[see Glomm and Ravikumar (1998, 2003), Glomm and Kaganovich (2003)]. We
assume that Hz > 0, Hε > 0, Hzz < 0, Hεε < 0, and Hzε > 0. The labor market is
perfectly competitive and there is full employment.
The optimization problem of a student is to
− v′ (1 − z) + u′ (C)
wHz (z, 1) = 0, (3)
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
276 Slobodan Djajić et al.
which provides an implicit solution for the optimal study effort, z, as a function of ε and
, per unit of skill. This relationship implies that the effect of the
the real market wage, w
wage on study effort is positive, assuming that the elasticity of marginal utility of
consumption, θ = −u ′′ (C)[C/u ′ (C)], defined to be positive, is less than unity:
u′ (C) ∂C
∂z (u − 1)
= w ∂z
2 > 0,
∂
w ∂C ∂2 C
v′′ (1 − z) + u′′ (C) + u′ (C) 2
∂z ∂z
as both the denominator and the numerator are then negative. Only if θ<1, does the
(or any other
substitution effect dominate the income effect, so that an increase in w
exogenous change that generates a higher level of future income) induces students to
exert more effort in acquiring human capital. On the basis of evidence documented
in the literature on risk aversion and labor supply behavior, we consider this to be
the relevant case. As for the effect of ε on student effort, we have
∂C ∂C ∂2 C
∂z u′′ (C) + u′ (C)
=− ∂z ∂1 ∂z∂1 ,
2
∂1 ∂C ∂2 C
v′′ (1 − z) + u′′ (C) + u′ (C) 2
∂z ∂z
where the denominator is unambiguously negative, while the two terms in the
numerator have conflicting signs: both (∂C/∂z) (∂C/∂ε) and ∂2C/∂z∂ε are positive,
while u ′′ (C) < 0 and u ′ (C) > 0. Let us consider the case of iso-elastic utility functions
(1 − z)(1−x) C (1−u)
v(1 − z) = , u(C) = (4)
(1 − x) (1 − u)
∂z z(1 − u)b
= z > 0,
∂1 1 1 − g(1 − u) + x
1−z
6
There is an extensive literature on the positive relationship between educational inputs that correspond
to ε (such as teacher quality and class size) and the skill level of students (reflected in their test scores and
even subsequent earnings). By contrast, we have not been able to find documented evidence on the
relationship between study effort of students taking part in a given educational program and their
productivity or earnings after graduation, which would provide us with information regarding γ. The
impact of study effort is obviously difficult to measure in a student population as it consists of inputs
such as time and the degree of mental concentration, while its effectiveness depends on a range of other
parameters and personal characteristics of a student.
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
Journal of Demographic Economics 277
indicating that if the authorities choose to provide a higher ε, this triggers more effort
on the part of students. As one would expect, the elasticity of z with respect to ε is
positively related to the elasticity of H(z, ε) with respect to both z and ε, but
negatively related to the degrees of concavity, χ and θ, of the utility functions in the
first and second phases of the planning horizon, respectively. Higher degrees of
concavity of the utility functions make students less responsive to educational and
occupational opportunities under autarky and, as we shall see in the next section, to
migration opportunities in an open economy. This is an important point as most of
the literature on the impact of migration opportunities on skill formation in a
developing country with an endogenous educational policy is based on the
assumption that the utility function is either logarithmic or linear.7
In sum, in the context of our model with endogenous study effort, the skill level of an agent
depends positively on ε through two channels: one direct and another indirect, through the
interaction between the education policy of the authorities and the study effort, z, optimally
chosen by each student. We thus have H(1, z( w, 1)), with dH/dε = ∂H/∂ε + (∂H/∂z) (∂z/∂ε),
where the first term is the direct effect and the second term corresponds to the indirect
“effort” effect, both being positive.
In a closed economy, the objective of the authorities is to maximize GNP, net of
official expenditures on education. We assume that the marginal product of a unit of
efficiency labor is constant at the level determined by the technology of production
and institutional arrangements in S. Each of the country’s N citizens is assumed to
go through the educational system, receiving ε units of training. From the
perspective of the authorities, we take the per-student cost of providing an extra unit
of training to be a constant x. Education is assumed to be funded by collecting taxes
in a way that does not distort the decision of students with respect to the optimal
study effort, z. An example might be a tax on land, real-estate, or a tax on royalties
in the mining industry or other resource-based activities.
In an autarky regime, signified by the superscript a, we can write the objective
function of the authorities as
L − Nx1,
Va = w (6)
L = NH(1, z (
w, 1)). (7)
7
Changes in the stock of human capital in response to greater migration opportunities arise in this
literature through a very different mechanism. Students are assumed to be heterogeneous in terms of
ability, with higher ability students facing a lower cost of acquiring human capital [as in Mountford
(1997), Beine et al. (2008), Docquier and Rapoport (2017)]. A higher probability of migration in that
context raises the expected payoff from owning human capital, inducing a larger number of individuals
(including those with a marginally lower ability) to acquire it. Our focus on students’ effort is motivated
by the observation that the input expected of a student in the higher-education systems of poor
developing countries tends to be predominantly study effort rather than a monetary payment.
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
278 Slobodan Djajić et al.
dL
w = Nx. (8)
d1
so that x, the marginal resource cost of an extra unit of training is equal to the marginal
contribution of a unit of training, taking into account both its direct effect on skill
formation and the indirect effect through its influence on students’ effort.8
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
Journal of Demographic Economics 279
lottery and allocated to employers in F also on the basis of a lottery. Let us assume, in
addition, that skills are not perfectly transferable from S to F, so that a migrant with the
skill level H gets credit for only ϕH units of skill in the labor market of F, where ϕ ≤ 1.
Moreover, the immigration policy of F is designed to benefit the country’s employers. In
some countries, including the rapidly-growing East-Asian economies, as well as in many
of the labor-importing countries in the Middle East, regulations allow foreign workers to
be systematically underpaid in relation to native workers.10 In other economies, such as
the United States, the underpayment is more subtle, although it can be quite substantial.
As noted by the former Secretary of Labor, Robert B. Reich, in the early days of the H1-B
program, “We have seen numerous instances in which American businesses have brought
in foreign skilled workers after having laid off skilled American workers, simply because
they can get the foreign workers more cheaply” [Branigin (1995)].11 In what follows, we
shall assume that while the natives earn w*, foreign workers earn only (1 − σ) w* per unit
of transferable skills, where σ < 1 is an exogenous parameter of the model. Having
specified the conditions facing potential migrants abroad, we derive in section 1 the
optimal level of public spending on education in the source country and investigate
how it varies with the immigration quota of the host country. In section 2, we
parameterize the model and proceed to a set of numerical experiments for 120
developing countries.
3.1 Theory
In an open-economy framework, the optimization problem of a student becomes
p
E [u(C)] = [w∗ (1 − s)fH (1, z(w, 1, p, w∗ , s, f))](1−u)
1−u
1−p
+ [ w, 1, p, w∗ , s, f))]1−u ,
wH (1, z(
1−u
10
Migration programs in these countries are often negotiated at the bilateral level between the host and
source countries, with compensation of foreign workers set to generate benefits for both the migrants and
their employers. Bilateral agreements between Japan and the Philippines, Japan and Vietnam, and Japan
and Indonesia governing migration of nurses or bilateral agreements between Saudi Arabia and the
Philippines, Singapore and Indonesia, or Singapore and the Philippines in the domain of domestic
helpers are examples of such arrangements.
11
U.S. employers apply for H-1B visas even though they pay a fee to the U.S. government in order to
obtain a visa. This suggests that H-1B workers are paid lower wages than native workers with the same
productivity level. Hira (2010, p. 11) reports that “…paying H-1Bs below-market wages is quite
common. According to the U.S. Citizenship and Immigration Services (USCIS)… the median wage in
FY2008 for new H-1B computing professionals was $60,000, a whopping 25% discount on the $79,782
median for U.S. computing professionals… approximately half of the 58,074 H-1B computing
professionals admitted in FY2008 earned less than entry-level wages for computer scientists” [see also
Usher (2001)]. Although the underpayment of any given foreign skilled worker is likely to be over just a
limited period of time, it nonetheless generates a rent for the employer. To simplify our analysis, the
employer’s-rent component is assumed to be a fraction of a foreign worker’s lifetime earnings.
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
280 Slobodan Djajić et al.
which depends on p ≡ M/N, the probability that a skilled graduate in S will be able to
H(1, z(.)). We naturally assume
migrate to F and earn w*(1 − σ)ϕH (ε, z(.)) instead of w
that w∗ (1 − s) f > w . Note that once we allow for the possibility of working in F, z
becomes a function of not only w and ε, as under autarky, but it also depends on
the probability of ending up abroad, M/N, and on the conditions in the foreign labor
market, as reflected in w*, σ, and ϕ.
Maximizing (11) subject to (12) and assuming that the marginal utility of leisure is
constant (i.e., χ = 0),12 we have
(1−u)
w(1−u) + p[w∗ (1 − s)f](1−u) ](m1b )
1
z = {g[(1 − p) }1−g(1−u) . (13)
When S is open to emigration, let us assume that the aim of the authorities is to
maximize the contribution of skilled labor to the economy’s output, net of
educational expenditures, not taking into account the earnings or welfare of those
who work abroad. In making this assumption, we follow the mainstream of the
literature on the brain drain [Vidal (1998), Stark and Wang (2002), Docquier et al.
(2008)]. A notable exception is Bertoli and Brücker (2011), where the weight
attached by the authorities of the source country to the utility of migrants is a
parameter of the model. We thus have:
For a given M, the optimal education policy of S must satisfy the following condition:
∂V ∂z
(N − M) H1 + Hz
; V1 = w − Nx = 0. (15)
∂1 ∂1
12
This assumption makes the algebra more tractable in the analysis below. Note that the larger is χ,
the smaller is the effort response of students to incentives for human capital accumulation. This is
because a larger χ makes it more difficult to give up leisure in exchange for future expected utility of
consumption as the level of study effort increases. Thus, by assuming that χ = 0, the effect of a
change in ε or expected future earnings on z [and therefore H(ε, z)] is larger than in the case where
the marginal utility of leisure is diminishing. In what follows, we shall assume that χ = 0, while
noting that this stacks the cards in favor of the outcome that an increase in migration opportunities
results in an increase in the net stock of human capital of the source country. At the same time, our
assumption that the marginal product of skilled labor is constant in the source country stacks the
cards in the opposite direction. It keeps the source-country wage constant, rather than allowing it to
rise [see Mishra (2007)] with an increase in emigration and hence provide greater incentives for
human capital accumulation.
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
Journal of Demographic Economics 281
∂z 13
given ε, result in an increase in H1 + Hz . This can more than offset the
∂1
difference between N − M and N, in which case a larger ε is required to maximize
the welfare of S when migration is permitted.
Using equations (4) and (5) along with the assumption that χ = 0, the first-order
condition writes as:
V1 w (1 − p)bH
; − x = 0, (16)
N 1[1 − g(1 − u)]
(N − M)H b [b − 1]
w
= < 0. (18)
12 [1 − g (1 − u)]
Moreover, we have:
⎡ ⎤
∂z
∂ H1 + Hz
∂V1 ⎢ ∂1 ∂z ⎥
; V1M ⎢
=w⎣(N − M) − H1 + Hz ⎥
∂M ∂M ∂1 ⎦
bH
w (N − M)gD
= − 1 _0,
1[1 − g(1 − u)] M [1 − g(1 − u)]
where 0 < Δ < 1 is the expected period-two gain in the utility of a skilled worker
stemming from being born in S when S is open rather than closed to international
migration, divided by the expected period-two utility of a skilled worker when S is
an open economy:
By using (4) and (5) and assuming that χ = 0, we can write ∂(H1 + Hz (∂z/∂1))/∂z = bgmz g−1 1b−1 +
13
bgmzg−1 1b (1 − u)/1[1 − g(1 − u)] + bgm(g − 1)zg−1 1b (1 − u)/1[1 − g(1 − u)] = bgmzg−1 1b /1[1 − g
(1 − u)] > 0.
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
282 Slobodan Djajić et al.
(N − M)gD ( p)
G(p) ;
M[1 − g(1 − u)]
[w∗ (1 − s)f]1−u 1−u
w
(1 − p)g −
(1 − u) (1 − u)
= 1−u
> 1. (21)
∗
[w (1 − s)f] 1−u
w
[1 − g(1 − u)] p + (1 − p)
1−u 1−u
3.2.1 Calibration
Practically, our calibration method consists of three steps. First, we assign values to
common parameters (θ, β, γ) relying on the existing literature. As far as the
concavity of the utility function is concerned, estimates of θ vary significantly,
depending on the data used and the empirical strategy. Chetty (2006) examines some
of the factors that explain this wide range of estimates, and reports that the mean
estimate in the literature is θ = 0.7. We use this value as a benchmark. Although our
assumption that θ < 1 may be viewed as somewhat restrictive, it is motivated by (i)
the fact that only three out of the 33 estimates of θ reported by Chetty (2006) are
above unity, and (ii) the observation that, within the present model, a value of θ > 1
implies counterintuitive and empirically unsupported results.14 As for the human
capital technology, Glomm and Ravikumar (1998, 2003) and Glomm and
Kaganovich (2003) consider a specification with a unitary elasticity of human capital
to the individual effort, and an elasticity to public education ranging from 0.05
to 0.30. In line with these studies, our benchmark calibration assumes γ = 1.0 and
β = 0.15. The latter elasticity is in line with Card and Krueger (1992), who find an
elasticity of human capital to school quality of 0.12. Other values are used in the
robustness checks (see Table 1 below).
The second step of our parameterization strategy consists of swapping two observed
endogenous variables for which country-specific observations exist, ε and H, for two
unobserved exogenous variables, μ and x. Hence, we collect data on observables
(p, w, w*, σ, ϕ, ε, H) and calibrate the level of the unobservable variables (z, μ, x)
From (13), θ > 1 implies that students in developing countries reduce their efforts to accumulate
14
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
284 Slobodan Djajić et al.
that are compatible with the data by backsolving the system (5)–(13)–(16). In particular,
we substitute με β by Hz −γ from (5) into (13) and obtain
w1−u + p(w∗ (1 − s)f)1−u H 1−u ,
z = g (1 − p)
which allows us to identify the level z for each country. Then, when z is known, we
calibrate μ to match H from (5): this gives μ = Hε −βz −γ. Finally, we calibrate x to
match data for ε using (16):
w (1 − p)bmz g
x= .
[1 − g(1 − u)]11−b
As far as data collection is concerned, we use proxies that capture the size of the
brain drain and decisions of the highly educated population. Hence, p is proxied
with the fraction of college-educated natives that emigrated to one of the OECD
destination countries in the year 2010; the data are taken from the DIOC database
described in Arslan et al. (2015). As for income variables, we use data on GDP per
capita in 2010 (y) from the Maddison project, data on the wage ratio between college
graduates and the less educated (s) from Hendricks (2004), and data on the
proportion of college graduates in the labor force (h) from Barro and Lee (2013).
The average income of college graduates is then computed as sy/(hs + 1 − h) for all
developing countries and for the United States. We then compute the income ratio
between the United States and each developing country, and compare it with the
data on international earnings differentials between the United States and a set of 42
developing source countries covered by the study of Clemens et al. (2009). On
average, the latter is 5% smaller. For our 120 countries, we thus use the adjusted
ratio [i.e., 0.95sy/(hs + 1 − h)] as a proxy for w*(1 − σ)ϕ, and we normalize the
domestic wage w to unity. Regarding ε, we use the 2010 amount of public education
spending as the percentage of GDP provided in the WDI database (World
Development Indicators). Finally, H is proxied with h(1 − p)−1 and is meant to
represent the fraction of college graduates in the native (i.e., before-migration)
population.15
The third step is the validation one. Step 2 uses all the degrees of freedom of the data
to identify the needed parameters. Consequently, our model is exactly identified and
cannot produce a test of its assumptions. In order to establish the relevance of our
identification method, we examine whether our calibrated model is in line with the
empirical (brain gain) literature on skilled emigration and human capital formation.
We simulate shocks on p (equalizing p with the emigration rate of less educated
workers, pmin), and compute the elasticity of H to p as dlnH/dlnp for each country.
The empirical paper of Beine et al. (2008) provides an estimate of 0.05 for the
short-run elasticity, and an upper-bound of 0.20 for the long-run elasticity. In our
benchmark calibration, we obtain a mean level of dlnH/dlnp of 0.08, which implies
15
Assuming that human capital is proxied by the fraction of college graduates, we implicitly consider that
the less educated have no productive skills, and that GDP per capita is proportional to the fraction of
college graduates in the labor force. Although this simplifying assumption looks strong, the observed
elasticity of GDP per capita to the fraction of college graduates is close to unity [as shown in Docquier
et al. (2017)].
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
Journal of Demographic Economics 285
that our model matches very well the sensitivity of pre-migration, human capital
formation to migration.
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
286 Slobodan Djajić et al.
countries below the 45 degree line are those where current emigration entails lower
levels of public spending on education. The difference is large in some countries.
These results seem to contradict the empirical findings of Docquier et al. (2008),
where a negative relationship is found between the levels of public expenditures on
tertiary education per student and skilled emigration rates. Nevertheless, our
simulations reveal that the optimal ratio ε/H at the current level of p is always
smaller than in the closed economy. Hence, our results suggest that emigration
increases the optimal amount of public spending on education in many developing
countries, but increases it less than in proportion to the amount of time spent by
students in education [as in line Docquier et al. (2008)].
288
Slobodan Djajić et al.
Table 1. Sensitivity analysis
Benchmark
(0.70, 0.15, 1.0) 0.080 39 (33%) 11 (9%) 20 (17%) 20 (17%) 21 (18%) 21 (18%)
Sens. to θ
(0.65, 0.15, 1.0) 0.109 57 (42%) 26 (22%) 39 (33%) 39 (33%) 41 (34%) 41 (34%)
(0.75, 0.15, 1.0) 0.059 13 (11%) 2 (2%) 6 (5%) 6 (5%) 5 (4%) 5 (4%)
Sens. to β
(0.70, 0.05, 1.0) 0.071 39 (33%) 11 (9%) 20 (17%) 20 (17%) 21 (18%) 21 (18%)
(0.70, 0.30, 1.0) 0.104 39 (33%) 11 (9%) 20 (17%) 20 (17%) 21 (18%) 21 (18%)
Sens. to γ
(0.70, 0.15, 0.9) 0.068 26 (22%) 5 (4%) 11 (9%) 11 (9%) 12 (10%) 12 (10%)
(0.70, 0.15, 1.1) 0.095 45 (33%) 20 (9%) 29 (17%) 29 (17%) 34 (18%) 34 (18%)
Journal of Demographic Economics 289
to influence immigration policy in the United States over the period 1998–2005, they
find that Microsoft was the single largest spender ($3,564,231) followed by Motorola
($2,660,473). Noting that the national cap on H-1B visas was 115,000 in the year
2000 and then raised to 195,000 in the years 2001–2003, it would be difficult to
argue that these firms have not benefitted from the increase in the quota.18
To capture the notion that the inflow of migrants is expected to generate rents for
their employers, we assume that the objective of F is to choose M that maximizes
where the first term on the right represents total employers’ rents generated by F’s
immigration policy and Q(M) is the perceived cost for the society, including the
costs imposed on skilled native workers, of hosting M immigrants. In most of the
host countries, the attitude of the native population (in contrast with that of
employers) is negative when asked if more immigration is preferable. Facchini and
Mayda (2008) find that in over 20 high- and middle-income economies, less than
10% of respondents who gave an opinion about migration were in favor of
increasing the number of immigrants to their country. Moreover, regions with a
higher percentage of immigrants tend to have a higher probability of natives
expressing negative attitudes on immigration.19 Although in Western countries
these negative attitudes pertain primarily to unskilled migrants, asylum seekers, and
undocumented foreign workers, there is also resistance to skilled migration in
countries where university graduates feel that they are unable to find their first job
because they are obliged to compete with foreign skilled workers or, as in the
United States, where native skilled workers have been laid off while their employer
is adding hundreds of new H-1B workers to the payroll [see Hira (2010), p. 9]. In
some countries, there is resistance to skilled migration even in the presence of a
severe shortage in some occupations. One example is Japan, which has bilateral
migration agreements with the Philippines, Indonesia, and Vietnam, allowing for
immigration of nurses under country-specific quotas. There is considerable
resistance throughout their health services sector to the employment of foreign
nurses as patients have a very strong preference to be treated by Japanese nurses
[Kobayashi (2014)].
18
A recent paper by Doran et al. (2016) estimates the causal impact of extra H-1B visas on the receiving
firm, using randomized variation from the Fiscal Year 2006 and Fiscal Year 2007 H-1B lotteries. They find
evidence that “…H-1B workers at least partially crowd out other workers, with the estimates typically
indicating substantial crowd out of other workers” (p. 32). They also note: “Consistent with firm profit
maximization, we find some evidence that extra H-1B visas increase median firm profits. We also find
some evidence that extra H-1B visas lead to a decrease in median earnings per employee… Overall, our
results are more supportive of the narrative about the effects of H-1Bs on firms in which H-1Bs crowd
out alternative workers, are paid less than the alternative workers whom they crowd out, and thus
increase the firm’s profits despite no measurable effect on innovation” (pp. 32–33).
19
See, for example, Schlueter and Wagner (2008) and Markaki and Longhi (2012). Ortega and Polevieja
(2012) is of related interest. There is a growing literature on the political economy of immigration policy,
starting with the pioneering work of Benhabib (1996) and extensions within a dynamic framework, such as
Ortega (2005) and Facchini and Testa (2015).
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
290 Slobodan Djajić et al.
In what follows, we shall assume that Q ′ (M) > 0 and Q ′′ (M) > 0. Maximization of V*
with respect to M requires that
∂V ∗
; VM ∗ = R(1 + ghzM ) − Q′ (M) = 0, (23)
∂M
where R = w∗ sfH (1, z( w, 1, M/N, w∗ , s, f)) is the per-worker rent enjoyed by the
employers of skilled immigrants, γ is the elasticity of H(.,.) with respect to z [see
equation (5)] and ηzM is the elasticity of z with respect to M:
D
hzM ; > 0. (24)
1 − g(1 − u)
∂VM ∗ Rg D
; VMM ∗ = [1 + ghzM + (1 − D)] − Q′′ (M) < 0. (25)
∂M [1 − g(1 − u)]M
∂VM ∗ Rb
; VM1 ∗ = (1 + ghzM ) > 0, (26)
∂1 1[1 − g(1 − u)]
which states that the higher the provision of educational services in S, the stronger the
incentive for F to admit more immigrants. This completes the presentation of our
model’s structure.
20
The degree of convexity of the Q(M) function must be such that Q ′′ (M)M/Q ′ (M) > [1 + (1 − Δ)/(1 +
γηzM)][γΔ/[1 − γ(1 − θ)]]. If we consider, for example, the case in which γ = 0.8, θ = 0.6, M/N = 0.05, and
the international earnings differential, w∗ (1 − s)f/w = 4, with w normalized to unity, a value of Q ′′ (M)
M/Q ′ (M) > 0.079 is required to satisfy the second-order condition. It can be shown that this critical value is
decreasing in θ and increasing in γ, M/N, and the international earnings differential.
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
Journal of Demographic Economics 291
Noting that β + γ(1 − θ) < 1 in the denominator, the slope of Vε is positive for
parameter values corresponding to an LM equilibrium (i.e., Γ>1) and negative in an
HM equilibrium (i.e., Γ<1).
The slope of F’s reaction function is unambiguously positive.
d1 VMM ∗
=− > 0, (28)
dM VM ∗ =0 VM1 ∗
∗ ∗
as VMM < 0 and VM1 > 0. Note that 1 − Δ is a positive fraction representing the ratio of
the period-two utility of working at home for the real wage w , to the expected
period-two utility when the probability of migration is M/N.
Where V1x = −N, V1f = (N − M) wbgH[D +(M/N)(1 − D)]/1f[1 − g(1 − u)]2 > 0,
∗
VMf = R{g(1− u) (1 − D) D+ (M/N)(1 − D) + 1 + ghzM ∗[1 − g(1− u) + g(1 − u)
[(1 − D) D + (M/N)(1 − D) ]]}/f[1 − g(1 − u)] > 0, and VMQ ′
(M) = −1.
The system (29) enables us to solve the impact of changes in the exogenous variables,
including x, ϕ, and the perceived marginal cost of admitting immigrants into F, Q ′ (M),
on the equilibrium values of M and ε. Stability of the Nash equilibrium requires that the
∗ ∗
determinant V = V11 VMM − VM1 V1M > 0. This implies that in an LM equilibrium,
∗
depicted in Figure 2(b), the positively sloped VM = 0 schedule must be steeper than
the Vε = 0 schedule. In an HM equilibrium, depicted in Figure 2(a), the Vε = 0
schedule is negatively sloped.
In this context, some of the key comparative statics results may be summarized in
the following proposition:
Proposition 2 Accounting for the interaction between the optimal immigration policy of
a host country and education policy of a source country:
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
292 Slobodan Djajić et al.
(i) A decline in the cost of education in S increases the Nash-equilibrium levels of both
educational spending in S and the immigration quota in F.
(ii) A decrease in the marginal cost of hosting immigrants in F increases the
Nash-equilibrium level of the immigration quota and increases (decreases) educational
spending in a low- (high-) migration equilibrium.
(iii) In a high-migration equilibrium, an increase in the international transferability of
skills from S to F raises the Nash-equilibrium level of the immigration quota and has
an ambiguous effect on educational spending.
(iv) In a low-migration equilibrium, an increase in the transferability of skills from S to
F has a positive effect on the level of spending on education as well as on the immigration
quota.
The proofs and analytical developments are provided in the following subsections.
d1
V = −VMM ∗ V1x = NVMM ∗ < 0, (30)
dx
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
Journal of Demographic Economics 293
dM
V = VM1 ∗ V1x = −NVM1 ∗ < 0. (31)
dx
The best response of S to a decline in the cost of education is to provide more ε to its
students. With the now higher level of education in S and a correspondingly greater
effort on the part of students to acquire skills, the best response of F is to admit
more immigrants. In Figures 2(a) and 2(b), a reduction in x gives rise to an upward
shift of the reaction function of S from (Vε = 0) to (Vε = 0)′ , while leaving the
∗
VM = 0 schedule unaffected. The Nash equilibrium therefore moves from point a to
point b. In both panels, this entails an increase in the equilibrium levels of ε and M,
but more so in an LM equilibrium of Figure 2(b), as the vertical shift of the Vε = 0
schedule is of the same magnitude in both panels (i.e., Vεx = −N).
A reduction in the cost of providing education can therefore be expected to have a
positive impact on the provision of educational services in S and on the level of skills
possessed by its graduates. This effect is reinforced by the endogenous
immigration-policy response of F in an LM equilibrium of Figure 2(b) and mitigated
in an HM equilibrium of Figure 2(a). Since the conditions in the relatively poorer
developing countries, with low wages, are more likely to meet the criteria for a
“low-migration” equilibrium (when compared with the conditions in the relatively
more prosperous developing economies, other things being equal), our model
suggests that technological improvements that lower the cost of providing educational
services are likely to have a greater positive impact on human capital formation in
such economies. This follows from the model’s implication that for a country in an
LM equilibrium, the interaction between education and immigration policies of S
and F helps to stimulate educational spending and study the effort of students, while
for one in an HM equilibrium, this interaction has a negative impact that offsets to
some extent the positive direct effects on ε and z.
d1
V = −V1M _ 0, as G + 1, (32)
dQ′ (M)
dM
V = V11 < 0. (33)
dQ′ (M)
Equation (33) shows that when the perceived marginal cost of hosting immigrants
decreases, the Nash-equilibrium level of F’s immigration quota increases. The effect
on the provision of educational services in S is ambiguous, however, as indicated in
equation (32). In an HM scenario, with a negatively sloped Vε = 0 schedule, the
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
294 Slobodan Djajić et al.
4.3.3 Change in ϕ
Improvements in information and communications technologies are also contributing
to the globalization of the education industry. What students and trainees are learning
across countries in any given field of study or occupation is becoming increasingly more
similar. This is also driven to a significant extent by the expansion of trade in goods and
services and the spread of technological knowledge across the globe. In terms of our
model, this phenomenon can be captured by an exogenous increase in ϕ, which
measures the degree to which skills possessed by a migrant are transferable from S to
F. Using the system of equation (29), we find that the effects on the
Nash-equilibrium values of ε and M are as follows:
d1
V = VMf ∗ V1M − VMM ∗ V1f _ 0, (34)
df
dM
V = V1f VM1 ∗ − VMf ∗ V11 > 0, (35)
df
∗ ∗ ∗
where we recall that VM f > 0, Vεϕ > 0, VM1 > 0, VMM < 0, Vεε < 0, and the sign of VεM
is the same as that of Γ − 1. The effect of an increase in ϕ on the Nash-equilibrium level
of spending on education is ambiguous and depends on the slope of the reaction
function of S. Figure 3(a) illustrates the case of an HM equilibrium with a negatively
sloped Vε = 0 locus. An increase in ϕ shifts the Vε = 0 schedule up and to the right
∗
and the VM = 0 schedule down and to the right. In relation to the original
equilibrium at point a, we find that the immigration quota of F is unambiguously
higher. Depending on the relative magnitudes of the two shifts, however, the
new equilibrium can feature either a higher or a lower ε. The rightward shift of
∗
the VM = 0 schedule is greater than that of the Vε = 0 locus if
∗ ∗ ′′
−VM f /V MM > −V1f /V1M . The Nash equilibrium then moves to d , where the level
of ε is lower. This would be the case, for instance, if the size of the immigration
quota of F is highly sensitive to the amount of (marketable) human capital in
∗
possession of potential immigrants, which makes VM f relatively large. Alternatively,
if the sensitivity of F’s quota to the stock of human capital that immigrants bring
∗
into the economy is sufficiently low, the rightward shift of the VM = 0 schedule is
′
smaller than that of Vε = 0. The new equilibrium is then at d , where it is optimal for
S to raise ε in response to an increase in ϕ triggered by the globalization of the
education industry.
The implications of an increase in ϕ in an LM equilibrium are illustrated in Figure 3
(b) by a shift of the Nash equilibrium from point a to d. More spending on education is
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
Journal of Demographic Economics 295
then optimal for S and more immigration is optimal for F. A higher ε and a higher M,
as well as the increase in ϕ that triggered the changes in policies, all serve to provide
students in S with stronger incentives to study, contributing to a more skilled and
more productive labor force both at home and abroad.
5. Conclusions
Instead of repeating the principal findings of this study, which are conveniently
summarized in the form of Propositions 1 and 2, we conclude the paper by
discussing its main contributions at a more general level. There are two key elements
and both of them flow directly from the model’s structure. The first relates to the
way we model skill formation. Instead of having to purchase human capital, as is
typically assumed in the earlier contributions to the literature on education policies
and the brain drain, we assume that students in the source country have free access
to public education, while the authorities choose the optimal provision of training.
Students then maximize their utility from consumption and leisure by choosing the
optimal amount of effort they apply in the process of human-capital accumulation.
Within this framework, the concavity of the utility function (θ) plays an important
role in terms of how students respond to educational and occupational opportunities
at home and abroad. Expansion of migration opportunities increases the
source-country’s gross stock of human capital in the empirically relevant case of θ<1.
Whether or not it increases the net stock, depends on the magnitude of θ, as well as
that of the elasticity, γ, of the human capital production function with respect to a
student’s effort, the international wage differential, and the emigration rate, M/N, in
the initial equilibrium. Our model implies that there is a net brain gain in a
“low-migration” equilibrium, characterized by a large γ, a low θ, a low M/N, and a
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
296 Slobodan Djajić et al.
sufficiently large gap between earnings of a skilled worker at home and abroad. Previous
contributions to the brain-drain literature assume that the utility function is either
linear or logarithmic, which precludes an analysis of the role of θ in the process of
human capital accumulation. Our model is also the first in this literature to focus on
the effort of students in the system of higher education and hence the role of γ in
the transformation of that effort into human capital.
Calibrating the model on the basis of data pertaining to 120 developing countries
around the year 2010, we proceed to identify cases where it would be optimal to raise
public spending on higher education in response to an increase in the emigration rate
of skilled workers. Of the 120 countries in our sample, we find 81 cases where an
increase in emigration always reduces the optimal public expenditure on education. In
the 39 remaining countries, limited emigration of skilled workers (starting from the
zero emigration rate) calls for an increase in public spending on education. In 11 of
these economies, even an increase in emigration from the current rate calls for an
increase in public spending on education, while in the other 28 countries it calls for a
decrease. By contrast, former studies suggest that governments should respond to an
increase in skilled emigration by reducing per-capita spending on public education.
Our analysis shows that this may not always be the optimal response.
Finally, we examine the interaction between the host country’s immigration policy
and the source country’s education policy when both are endogenous and where
students optimally choose how much effort to apply in the process of human capital
accumulation. While we are aware that the two-country structure has its limitations
in the present context, it enables us to investigate the impact of exogenous shocks,
such as a technological improvement that lowers the cost of providing educational
services in the source country, a shift in preferences on immigration in the host
country, and a change in the degree of international transferability of human capital,
on the amount of effort expended by students in school, the optimal level of
source-country spending on education, and the optimal immigration quota of the
host country. With a growing number of bilateral migration agreements covering
skilled workers, particularly in the health services sector [e.g., bilateral Economic
Partnership Agreements (EPA) between Japan and Indonesia (2008), Japan and the
Philippines (2008), Japan and Vietnam (2009), or Venezuela and Cuba], a
two-country model of migration of skilled workers becomes increasingly relevant.
References
Arslan, C., J.-C. Dumont, Z. Kone, Y. Moullan, C. Ozden, C. Parsons, C. and T. Xenogiani (2015) A new
profile of migrants in the aftermath of the recent economic crisis. OECD Social, Employment and
Migration Working Papers, (160).
Artuc, E., F. Docquier, C. Ozden and Ch Parsons (2015) A global assessment of human capital mobility: the
role of non-OECD destinations. World Development 65, 6–26.
Barro, R. J. and J. W. Lee (2013) A new data set of educational attainment in the world, 1950–2010. Journal
of Development Economics 104(C), 184–198.
Batista, C., A. Lacuesta and P. C. Vicente (2012) Testing the brain gain hypothesis: micro evidence from
Cape Verde. Journal of Development Economics 97(1), 32–45.
Beine, M., F. Docquier and H. Rapoport (2008) Brain drain and human capital formation in developing
countries: winners and losers. Economic Journal 118, 631–652.
Benhabib, J. (1996) On the political economy of immigration. European Economic Review 40, 1737–1743.
Benhabib, J. and B. Jovanovic (2012) Optimal migration: a world perspective. International Economic
Review 53, 321–348.
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
Journal of Demographic Economics 297
Bertoli, S. and H. Brücker (2011) Selective immigration policies, migrants’ education and welfare at origin.
Economics Letters 113, 19–22.
Bhagwati, J. N. and K. Hamada (1974) The brain drain, international integration of markets for
professionals and unemployment. Journal of Development Economics 1, 19–42.
Blankenau, W. and G. Camera (2009) Public spending on education and the incentives for student
achievement. Economica 76, 505–527.
Branigin, W. (1995) White-collar visas: back door for cheap labor? Washington Post, Saturday, October 21,
1995, Page A1.
Card, D. and A. B. Krueger (1992). Does school quality matter? Returns to education and the characteristics
of public schools in the United States. Journal of Political Economy 100(1), 1–40.
Chand, S. and M. A. Clemens (2008) Skilled emigration and skill creation: a quasi-experiment. Center for
Global Development Working Paper 152.
Chetty, R. (2006) A new method of estimating risk aversion. American Economic Review 96, 1821–1834.
Clemens, M. A., C. E. Montenegro and L. Pritchett (2009) The place premium: wage differences for
identical workers across US border. RWP09-004, Harvard Kennedy School.
Commander, S., M. Kangasniemi, and L. A. Winters (2004) The brain drain: curse or boon? A survey of the
literature. In Baldwin, R. and Winters, L. A. (eds.), Challenges to Globalization. Chicago: The University
of Chicago Press, pp. 235–278. Chapter 7.
Delogu, M., F. Docquier, and J. Machado (2018) Globalizing labor and the world economy: the role of
human capital. Journal of Economic Growth 23, 223–258.
di Giovanni, J., A. A. Levchenko and F. Ortega (2015) A global view of cross-border migration. Journal of
the European Economics Association 13, 168–202.
Djajić, S. (1989) Skills and the pattern of migration: the role of qualitative and quantitative restrictions on
international labor mobility. International Economic Review 40, 795–809.
Djajić, S., M. S. Michael and A. Vinogradova (2012) Migration of skilled workers: policy interaction
between host and source countries. Journal of Public Economics 96, 1015–1024.
Docquier, F., O. Faye and P. Pestieau (2008) Is migration a good substitute for education subsidies? Journal
of Development Economics 86, 263–276.
Docquier, F., and A. Marfouk (2006) International migration by educational attainment (1990–2000). In
Ozden, C. and Schiff, M. (eds.), International Migration, Remittances and the Brain Drain. New
York: Palgrave-Macmillan, pp. 151–199.
Docquier, F., T. Müller, and J. Naval (2017) Informality and long-run growth. Scandinavian Journal of
Economics 119, 1040–1085.
Docquier, F. and H. Rapoport (2012) Globalization, brain drain and development. Journal of Economic
Literature 50, 681–730.
Doran, K., A. Gelber and A. Isen (2016) The effects of high-skilled immigration policy on firms: evidence
from visa lotteries. mimeo, Goldman School of Public Policy, UC Berkeley.
Facchini, G. and A.-M. Mayda (2008) From individual attitudes towards migrants to migration policy
outcomes: theory and evidence. Economic Policy 56, 651–713.
Facchini, G., A.-M. Mayda and P. Mishra (2015) Lobbying expenditures on migration: a descriptive
analysis. CESifo Economic Studies 61, 560–604.
Facchini, G. and C. Testa (2015) The political economy of migration enforcement: domestic versus border
control. CESifo Economic Studies 61, 701–721.
Fernandez, R. and R. Rogerson (1998) Public education and income distribution: a dynamic quantitative
evaluation of education-finance reform. American Economic Review 88(4), 813–833.
Gibson, J. and D. McKenzie (2011) The microeconomic determinants of emigration and return migration
of the best and brightest: evidence from the pacific. Journal of Development Economics 95(1), 18–29.
Glomm, G. and M. Kaganovich (2003) Distributional effects of public education in an economy with public
pensions. International Economic Review 44(3), 917–937.
Glomm, G. and B. Ravikumar (1998) Flat-rate taxes, government spending on education, and growth.
Review of Economic Dynamics 1(1), 306–325.
Glomm, G. and B. Ravikumar (2003) Public education and income inequality. European Journal of Political
Economy 19(2), 289–300.
Hanushek, E. (2013) Economic growth in developing countries: the role of human capital. Economics of
Education Review 37, 204–212.
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
298 Slobodan Djajić et al.
Hendricks, L. (2004) A database of mincerian earnings regressions. Available online at: http://www.
lhendircks.org/Mincer.htm.
Hira, R. (2010) The H-1B and L-1B visa programs; out of control. Economic Policy Institute Briefing Paper
280.
Justman, M. and J. Thisse (1997) Implications of the mobility of skilled labor for local public funding of
higher education. Economics Letters 55, 409–412.
Klein, P. and G. J. Ventura (2009) Productivity differences and the dynamic effects of labor movements.
Journal of Monetary Economics 56, 1059–1073.
Kobayashi, Y. (2014) Language education for migrant workers and their social integration in Japan. Global
Migration Research Paper No. 8, Graduate Institute, Geneva.
Lucas, R. E. B. (2005) International Migration Regimes and Economic Development. Northampton,
Massachusetts, USA: Edward Elgar Publishing.
Markaki, Y. and S. Longhi (2012) What determines attitudes to immigration in European countries? An
analysis at the regional level. Norface Migration Discussion Paper No. 2012-32.
Mishra, P. (2007) Emigration and wages in source countries: evidence from Mexico. Journal of Development
Economics 82, 180–199.
Miyagiwa, K. (1991) Scale economies in education and the brain drain problem. International Economic
Review 32(3), 743–759.
Mountford, A. (1997) Can a brain drain be good for growth in the source economy? Journal of
Development Economics 53, 287–303.
Oketch, M. and A. Somerset (2010) Free primary education and after in Kenya: enrolment impact, quality
effects, and the transition to secondary school. Project Report. CREATE, Brighton, UK.
Ortega, F. (2005) Immigration policy and skill upgrading. Journal of Public Economics 89, 1841–1863.
Ortega, F. and G. Peri (2014) Openness and income: the roles of trade and migration. Journal of
International Economics 92, 231–251.
Ortega, F. and J. G. Polavieja (2012) Labor-market exposure as a determinant of attitudes toward
immigration. Labour Economics 19, 298–311.
Poutvaara, P. (2008) Public education in an integrated Europe: studying to migrate and teaching to stay?
Scandinavian Journal of Economics 110(3), 591–608.
Schlueter, E. and U. Wagner (2008) Regional differences matter: examining the dual influence of the
regional size of the immigrant population on derogation of immigrants in Europe. International
Journal of Comparative Sociology 49(2–3), 153–173.
Shrestha, S. A. (2017) No man left behind: effects of emigration prospects on educational and labour
outcomes of non-migrants. Economic Journal 127(600), 495–521.
Stark, O., C. Helmenstein and A. Prskawetz (1997) A brain gain with a brain drain. Economics Letters 55,
227–234.
Stark, O. and Y. Wang (2002) Inducing human capital formation: migration as a substitute for subsidies.
Journal of Public Economics 86(1), 29–46.
Tamura, R. (2001) Teachers, growth and convergence. Journal of Political Economy 109(5), 1021–1059.
Teferra, D. (2007) Higher education in Sub-Saharan Africa. In Forest, J. F. and Altbach, P. G. (eds.),
International Handbook of Higher Education. Dordrecht, The Netherlands: Springer, pp. 557–569.
Theoharides, C. (2017) Manila to Malaysia, Quezon to Qatar: international migration and its effects on
origin-country human capital. Journal of Human Resources, forthcoming.
Usher, A. (2001) You’re fired, go home. Washington Post, May 10, 2001.
Vidal, J.-P. (1998) The effect of emigration on human capital formation. Journal of Population Economics
11, 589–600.
Wong, K.-Y. (1997) Endogenous growth and international migration. In Jensen, B. and Wong, K.-Y. (eds.),
Dynamics, Growth and International Trade. Ann Arbor: U. of Michigan Press, pp. 289–336.
Wong, K.-Y. and C. K. Yip (1999) Education, economic growth and brain drain. Journal of Economic
Dynamics and Control 23, 699–726.
World Bank (2000) Higher Education in Developing Countries: Peril and Promise. Washington, DC: The
International Bank for Reconstruction and Development.
World Bank (2010) Financing Higher Education in Africa. Washington, DC: The International Bank for
Reconstruction and Development.
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
Journal of Demographic Economics 299
Appendix
A. Determinants of G(0) and G(p)
To help interpret our results, we propose a linear approximation of our model. In Table A1, we regress Γ(0)
and Γ(p) on the set of country-specific characteristics (x, w*(1 − σ)ϕ/w, p). We use standard OLS
regressions with Γ(.) taken in level or in log. The model in level gives a better fit. In columns 1 and 2,
we regress Γ(0) on the set of country-specific determinants. In line with equation (21), w*(1 − σ)ϕ/w is
the only significant determinant of Γ(0). In columns 3 and 4, we regress Γ(p) on the same
determinants. The linear model suggests that Γ(p) − 1 > 0 when 0.322 + 0.077 (w*(1 − σ)ϕ/w) − 0.790p > 1,
or equivalently when p < 0.097 (w*(1 − σ)ϕ/w) − 0.858.
B. Country-specific results
Table A2 provides country-specific calibration and simulation results obtained under the benchmark
scenario. The first 11 rows list countries where both Γ(0)>1 and Γ(p)>1. The next 28 rows include
countries where Γ(0)>1 and Γ(p)<1. The last 81 rows include countries where emigration always
reduces the optimal provision of public education.
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
300 Slobodan Djajić et al.
Table A2. Calibration and simulation results for 120 countries
w∗ (1 − s)f
Country p x ( × 100) Γ(0) Γ(p) Γ(0) > 1 Γ(p) > 1
w
Afghanistan 0.11 8.74 0.37 1.31 1.06 1 1
Bangladesh 0.08 8.49 0.32 1.29 1.11 1 1
Burkina Faso 0.03 6.83 0.16 1.11 1.06 1 1
Cent. African Rep 0.20 14.07 0.22 1.73 1.11 1 1
Chad 0.07 15.30 0.12 1.81 1.54 1 1
Guinea 0.09 12.15 0.23 1.59 1.33 1 1
Guinea-Bissau 0.20 12.62 0.35 1.63 1.07 1 1
Kyrgyzstan 0.02 6.58 0.40 1.09 1.05 1 1
Mongolia 0.02 16.56 1.00 1.89 1.79 1 1
Niger 0.09 12.01 0.04 1.58 1.32 1 1
Tajikistan 0.02 8.06 0.32 1.24 1.20 1 1
Bolivia 0.10 6.81 0.37 1.11 0.93 1 0
Burundi 0.34 14.91 0.02 1.78 0.83 1 0
Cameroon 0.32 5.90 0.11 1.00 0.55 1 0
Comoros 0.51 13.35 0.06 1.68 0.52 1 0
Congo, Dem Rep 0.33 14.73 0.10 1.77 0.85 1 0
Cote d’Ivoire 0.13 7.16 0.16 1.15 0.91 1 0
Djibouti 0.18 8.24 0.16 1.26 0.90 1 0
Eritrea 0.38 8.72 0.07 1.31 0.60 1 0
Ethiopia 0.14 8.05 0.06 1.24 0.95 1 0
Gambia 0.51 6.82 0.07 1.11 0.39 1 0
Ghana 0.34 6.30 0.07 1.05 0.55 1 0
Kenya 0.13 7.57 0.20 1.19 0.93 1 0
Liberia 0.34 9.66 0.22 1.39 0.69 1 0
Madagascar 0.23 9.86 0.12 1.41 0.89 1 0
Malawi 0.40 8.70 0.02 1.31 0.58 1 0
Mauritania 0.17 5.97 0.10 1.01 0.75 1 0
Moldova 0.25 6.13 0.27 1.03 0.66 1 0
Nepal 0.17 7.37 0.12 1.17 0.85 1 0
Nicaragua 0.19 8.34 0.51 1.27 0.88 1 0
West Bank Gaza 0.04 5.96 1.45 1.01 0.94 1 0
Pakistan 0.09 5.99 0.49 1.02 0.87 1 0
Rwanda 0.34 6.63 0.03 1.09 0.57 1 0
Sierra Leone 0.52 10.55 0.08 1.47 0.45 1 0
(Continued )
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
Journal of Demographic Economics 301
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
302 Slobodan Djajić et al.
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
Journal of Demographic Economics 303
Cite this article: Djajić S, Docquier F, Michael MS (2019). Optimal education policy and human capital
accumulation in the context of brain drain. Journal of Demographic Economics 85, 271–303. https://
doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10
Downloaded from https://www.cambridge.org/core. IP address: 46.161.62.159, on 19 Nov 2019 at 17:08:29, subject to the Cambridge Core
terms of use, available at https://www.cambridge.org/core/terms. https://doi.org/10.1017/dem.2019.10