02 Arbitrage
02 Arbitrage
Internet: http://www.whu.edu/banking
Arbitrage 1. Basics
2. Parities
3. Lower price boundaries
4. Convexity
5. Pure assets
Reference: Hull (1997), chapter 8
Page 1
Basics
Arbitrage
Page 2
© Markus Rudolf Arbitrage
Parities
Put Call Forward Parity
Cash flow
today Cash flow at maturity
Stock price S 800 900 1000 1050 1200
Long Call (X=F=1050) C 0 0 0 0 150
Short Put (X=F=1050) -P -250 -150 -50 0 0
Long Call + Short Put C-P -250 -150 -50 0 150
Long Forward (F=1050) F -250 -150 -50 0 150
1050, C = P = 50
100
50
The combination of a long position in
maturity
0
-50 a call and a short put position yields
-100 the same payoff like a forward
-150
-200 contract, if the exercise price equals
-250 the forward price:
-300
800 900 1000 1100 1200
C(X = F) - P(X = F) = F = 0
Stock price
C(X = F) = P(X = F)
Page 3
Parities
Spot Futures Parity
29.65 30 31.10
Page 4
© Markus Rudolf Arbitrage
Parities
Spot Futures Parity
F = [S - PV (D )] × [1 + R ]T
(C)
Forward sell (F=1040) 0.00 240 140 40 -60 -160
Long replicating portfolio 20.1 -240 -140 -40 60 160
Arbitrage position 20.1 0 0 0 0 0
(D)
Buy Forward (F=1018.9) 0 -218.9 -118.9 -18.9 81.1 181.1
Page 5
Parities
Put Call Parity
Page 6
© Markus Rudolf Arbitrage
Parities
General put call futures Parity
Cashflows at maturity
800 900 1000 1100 1200
Put (X=900) P 100 0 0 0 0
Call C 0.0 0 100.0 200.0 300.0
*
Loan PV360t(118.9 ) 113.2 -118.9 -118.9 -118.9 -118.9 -118.9
Forward sell 0 218.9 118.9 18.9 -81.1 -181.1
(F=1018.9)
C+113.2 100.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0
Page 7
Parities
Futures forward equivalence
The table above shows a scenario for stock price movements and for the
corresponding forward prices.
The payoff of the forward contract at maturity in t=3 is:
ST -F0 = 1200 – 1157.63 = 42.37
This example assumes constant interest rates over time. I.e. interest rates and
spot prices are uncorrelated.
Page 8
© Markus Rudolf Arbitrage
Parities
Futures forward equivalence
1
Second strategy (with futures): In the beginning of each period t [1 + R (t + 1,T )]T - t -1
futures contracts are purchased without any costs. They are settled at the end of
each period (cash settlement). If the term structure is constant, i.e. uncorrelated
with the spot prices, the corresponding cashflows are:
Settlement:
Number of Value of one Value of our Final value of
contracts futures futures our futures
Period Spot price R3 R2 R1 purchased contract contracts contratcs
0 1000 5% 6% 7% 0,8900
1 1110 6% 7% 0,9346 89,57 79,72 89,57
2 1080 7% 1 -91,60 -85,60 -91,60
3 1200 44,40 44,40 44,40
Sum 42,37
Page 9
Parities
Futures forward equivalence
Obviously, the futures strategy and the forward strategy have the same payoffs
without any initial investments.
Forward and futures prices are equal, if interest rates are perfectly predictable
(deterministic) or uncorrelated to stock prices. Price differences between forwards
and futures only occur in the case of stochastic interest rates. If interest rates are
correlated to stock prices, the costs of carry have to be taken into account:
rIR,stocks > 0 and stock prices go up rIR,stocks < 0 and stock prices go down
The costs of capital of the short The costs of capital of the long
position goes up, because the position goes up, because the
amount in the margin account has to amount in the margin account has to
be rewarded by higher interest rate be rewarded by higher interest rate
payments, when margin calls occur payments, when margin calls occur
for the short position for the long position
Futures price > Forward price Futures price < Forward price
Page 10
© Markus Rudolf Arbitrage
Parities
Stocks and interest rates are correlated
Positive Settlement:
correlation Number of Value of one Value of our Final value of
contracts futures futures our futures
Period Spot price R3 R2 R1 purchased contract contracts contratcs
0 1000 5% 6% 7% 0,8900
1 1110 7% 8% 0,9259 89,57 79,72 91,27
2 1080 7% 1 -91,60 -84,81 -90,75
3 1200 44,40 44,40 44,40
Sum 44,92
Negative Settlement:
correlation Number of Value of one Value of our Final value of
contracts futures futures our futures
Period Spot price R3 R2 R1 purchased contract contracts contratcs
0 1000 5% 6% 7% 0,8900
1 1110 5% 6% 0,9434 89,57 79,72 87,89
2 1080 7% 1 -91,60 -86,41 -92,46
3 1200 44,40 44,40 44,40
Sum 39,83
Page 11
Exercise Value Call = max (0, Stock Price - Exercise Price) = max (0, S - X)
Page 12
© Markus Rudolf Arbitrage
The minimum value of the call option equals the value of the stock + loan position
=> The minimum call option price is 142.85
Otherwise, arbitrage opportunities would occur: Assume, the price of the call
option would be 120:
Purchase the call: -120
Short sell of the stock: 1000
Fixed income investment: -857.15 Sum: 22.85
Stock price at maturity
800 850 900 950 1000
Call 0 0 0 50 100
Stock short
position -800 -850 -900 -950 -1000
FI investment 900 900 900 900 900
100 50 0 0 0
Page 13
Page 14
© Markus Rudolf Arbitrage
Non dividend and dividend paying call Upper boundary for call
options
1400
Lower and upper
800
dividend paying and non
600 dividend paying call options
400
200
0
0 500 1000
Stock price
Page 15
Lower boundary is 113.2: The value of the dividend is reflected by the stock price.
Until the maturity of the call, the stock is ex dividend. Therefore, dividend
payments reduce the stock price.
Clower boundary = max[0, S - PVt(X) - PVd(D)]
Page 16
© Markus Rudolf Arbitrage
Investment
PV360t(1100) 1047.6 1100.0 1100.0 1100.0 1100.0 1100.0
Investment 29.6 31.1 31.1 31.1 31.1 31.1
PV90t(30)
1077.2 1131.1 1131.1 1131.1 1131.1 1131.1
Page 17
Convexity
... and exercise price
Option price
Exercise
Case A is not possible due to the
price Maturity Case A Case B no arbitrage assumption: Vertical
X1=900 12M 160 160 spread arbitrage strategy
X2=1000 12M 50 100
X3=1100 12M 10 10
The payoff today is positive (110), the liabilities at maturity are 100 (PV = 95.23)
at maximum. The minimum arbitrage profit therefore is 14.77.
Page 18
© Markus Rudolf Arbitrage
Convexity
... and exercise price
Page 19
Convexity
... and exercise price
This strategy provides a profit of 30 today and possible profits at maturity. The
price of the call option (X2 = 1000) is too high. Assume a price for the second
call of 80:
Page 20
© Markus Rudolf Arbitrage
Convexity
... and exercise price
Page 21
Convexity
... and stock price
50
0
600 700 800 900 1000 1100 1200
Stock price
d 2 C(X) > 0 Convexity means that option price differences go down as the
d X2 strike price goes up.
d 2 C(X) > 0 And it means that option price differences go down as the stock
d S2 price goes up.
Page 22
© Markus Rudolf Arbitrage
Convexity
... and time to maturity
Times to maturity:
1 year lower price boundary.
150
6 months This is due to the fact,
100 3 months that volatility is the
greater, the longer the
50 option is to maturity.
0
600 700 800 900 1000 1100 1200
Stock price
Page 23
Pure assets
Butterfly spread
Pure assets: payoff is 1 currency unit in one state of the world and 0 in all other
states => can be replicated by butterfly spread strategies. Assume the following
pricing structure:
C(X= 800) = 215 This pricing structure is free of arbitrage
C(X= 850) = 185 according to the principles laid down before:
C(X= 900) = 160 The difference of the prices is below the
C(X= 950) = 140 difference of the present values of the exercise
C(X=1000) = 125 prices, and the price difference is decreasing.
Based on this setting, three different butterfly spread strategies are illustrated in
the following table.
All spreads cost 5 => a pure asset for all states of the world would cost 0.1
In the real world, one can expect different willingnesses of payments depending
on which states imply hedging needs => the worse the market performs, the
more the investors are willing to pay for a pure security of this particular state
Page 24
© Markus Rudolf Arbitrage
Pure assets
Butterfly spread
Page 25
Pure assets
Butterfly spread
800 215
850 185 30 5 (= Price of "Spread 850")
900 160 25 5 (= Price of "Spread 900")
950 140 20 5 (= Price of "Spread 950")
1000 125 15
The price of a pure asset always equals the difference of the difference of
the option prices.
Spread 900 C(850) - 2 C(900) + C(950)
P(1 for S = 900) = =
50 50
=
[C(X = 950) - C(X = 900)] - [C(X = 900) - C(X = 850)]
50
140 - 2 * 160 + 185 [140 - 160] - [160 - 185] 5
= = = = 0.1
50 50 50
Page 26
© Markus Rudolf Arbitrage
Pure assets
Butterfly spread
Page 27
Pure assets
... pricing and risk aversion
Option price differences go down increasingly with the strike going up.
Page 28
© Markus Rudolf Arbitrage
Pure assets
... pricing and risk aversion
Prices of pure assets are equal to prices of butterfly spreads. The price of a
butterfly spread equals the difference of the difference of the underlying option
prices.
The difference of differences is the convexity: Convexity measures the implicit
price of pure assets.
Risk aversion implies increasing convexity with the strike price going down.
Page 29