Chapter 4. Pricing and Employement Inputs PPT Final
Chapter 4. Pricing and Employement Inputs PPT Final
Firm’s Demand Curve for Labor
Firm’s Demand Curve for Labor
Firm’s Demand Curve for Labor
Firm’s Demand Curve for Labor
Graphical representation
𝑽𝑴𝑷𝑳 W
𝑴𝑷𝑳
L L
Derivation of Individual Labor Demand Curve
a) Equilibrium at b) Derived labor
different wages demand Curve
W W
L L
𝑳𝟑
Derivation of Individual Labor Demand Curve
Cost of inputs
𝑪 = 𝒘𝑳 + 𝒓𝑲
Let Wage falls from 𝒘𝟏 to 𝒘𝟐
See the figure below
𝑪𝟏 𝑪𝟏 ′ 𝑪𝟏 𝑪𝟐 𝑪𝟐
𝑨= ,𝑩 = ,𝑩 = ,𝑬 = ,𝑭 =
𝒓𝟏 𝒘𝟏 𝒘𝟐 𝒓𝟏 𝒘𝟐
Production function
𝑸 = 𝒇(𝑳, 𝑲)
Firm's Demand Curve: Two variable inputs case.
K 𝑨𝑩 is the Iso-cost line for 𝑪𝟏
𝒘
. W = 𝒘𝟏 Slope = -
𝒓
r = 𝒓𝟏 Initially the firm
A
produces the profit-
maximizing output, Q1,
𝑲𝟏 𝒆𝟏 with combination of K1
& L1 at point e1
𝑸𝟏
𝑳𝟏 B L
0
Firm's Demand Curve: Two variable inputs case.
K
When W falls from 𝒘𝟏 to 𝒘𝟐 the
. iso-cost line becomes
A flatter(the new iso-cost line 𝑨𝑩)
𝑲𝟏 𝒆𝟏
𝑸𝟏
𝑳𝟏 B D B’ L
0
Firm's Demand Curve: Two variable inputs case.
K
Thus, the firm using the same
. expenditure can now produce a
higher output, Q2, using K2 & L2 at e2.
A
Total effect of w is the
𝑲𝟏 𝒆𝟏 𝒆𝟐 movement from 𝒆𝟏 to 𝒆𝟐 .
𝑲𝟐
𝑸𝟐
𝑸𝟏
𝑳𝟏 𝑳𝟐 B D B’ L
0
Firm's Demand Curve: Two variable inputs case.
K
. We can decompose the total
effect on quantity of labor hired
A into two components:
1. Substitution effect
𝑲𝟏 𝒆𝟏 𝒆 2. output effect
𝟐
𝑲𝟐
𝑸𝟐
𝑸𝟏
𝑳𝟏 𝑳𝟐 B D B’ L
0
Firm's Demand Curve: Two variable inputs case.
K To produce an unchanged output
. (𝑸𝟏 ), the firm uses more L (𝑳′𝟏 )
and less K (𝑲′𝟏 ) when the relative
A cost of L falls. i.e it substitutes L
for K
C ′
𝑲𝟏 𝒆𝟏 𝒆𝟐 Sub. effect = 𝑳 𝟏 −𝑳𝟏
𝑲𝟐 𝒆 𝒆 ′
𝟏)
′ (movement from to
𝒆𝟏 𝟏
𝑲′𝟏
𝑸𝟐
𝑸𝟏
𝑳𝟏 𝑳′𝟏 𝑳𝟐 B D B’ L
0
Firm's Demand Curve: Two variable inputs case.
K The hiring of L will also increase
. (to L2) due to output effect of
reduction in w rate (while the total
A expenditure remains unchanged)
to produce 𝑸𝟐
C ′
𝑲𝟏 𝒆𝟏 𝒆𝟐 Output effect = 𝑳 𝟐 −𝑳 𝟏
𝑲𝟐 𝒆 ′
𝟏 to 𝒆𝟐 )
′ (movement from
𝒆𝟏
𝑲′𝟏
𝑸𝟐
𝑸𝟏
𝑳𝟏 𝑳′𝟏 𝑳𝟐 B D B’ L
0
Firm's Demand Curve: Two variable inputs case.
K Q2 or e2 is the equilibrium of the
. firm only if the firm were to spend
the same amount of money as
A initially.
C
𝑲𝟏 𝒆𝟏 𝒆𝟐 Total effect = 𝑳𝟐 −𝑳𝟏
𝑲𝟐 (movement from 𝒆𝟏 to 𝒆𝟐 )
𝒆′𝟏
𝑲′𝟏
𝑸𝟐
𝑸𝟏
𝑳𝟏 𝑳′𝟏 𝑳𝟐 B D B’ L
0
Firm's Demand Curve: Two variable inputs case.
K But firms produce as much as the
. available demand allows, by
increasing its expenditure further.
A
C
𝑲𝟏 𝒆𝟏 𝒆𝟐 Total effect = 𝑳𝟐 −𝑳𝟏
𝑲𝟐 (movement from 𝒆𝟏 to 𝒆𝟐 )
𝒆′𝟏
𝑲′𝟏
𝑸𝟐
𝑸𝟏
𝑳𝟏 𝑳′𝟏 𝑳𝟐 B D B’ L
0
Firm's Demand Curve: Two variable inputs case.
A change in wage, because it
changes relative factor costs, will
shift all the firm's cost curves.
P/C MC
e1 e3 MC’
𝑷 d
Q
0 Q1 Q3
Firm's Demand Curve: Two variable inputs case.
the marginal cost curve for the firm
has shifted downward to MC' due to
fall in wage rate.
P/C MC
e1 e3 MC’
𝑷 d
Q
0 Q1 Q3
Firm's Demand Curve: Two variable inputs case.
Consequently,the firm's profit
maximizing output rises from Q2 to
Q 3.
P/C MC
e1 e3 MC’
𝑷 d
Q
0 Q1 Q3
Firm's Demand Curve: Two variable inputs case.
EK As the firm produces more
. output, it moves to a
higher iso-cost line ( 𝑬𝑭 )
A
The increase in cost = 𝑨𝑬
C
𝑲𝟏 𝒆𝟏 𝒆𝟐
𝑲𝟐
𝒆′𝟏
𝑲′𝟏
𝑸𝟐
𝑸𝟏
𝑳𝟏 𝑳′𝟏 𝑳𝟐 B D B’ F L
0
Firm's Demand Curve: Two variable inputs case.
EK The new equilibrium now is
. at 𝒆𝟑 (producing 𝑸𝟑 )
A
𝑲𝟑 𝒆𝟑
C
𝑲𝟏 𝒆𝟏 𝒆𝟐
𝑲𝟐 𝑸𝟑
𝒆′𝟏
𝑲′𝟏
𝑸𝟐
𝑸𝟏
𝑳𝟏 𝑳′𝟏 𝑳𝟐 B 𝑳𝟑 D B’ F L
0
Firm's Demand Curve: Two variable inputs case.
EK The movement from 𝒆𝟐 to
. 𝒆𝟑 ) is sometimes called the
profit- maximizing effect.
A
𝑲𝟑 𝒆𝟑
C
𝑲𝟏 𝒆𝟏 𝒆𝟐
𝑲𝟐 𝑸𝟑
𝒆′𝟏
𝑲′𝟏
𝑸𝟐
𝑸𝟏
𝑳𝟏 𝑳′𝟏 𝑳𝟐 B 𝑳𝟑 D B’ F L
0
Firm's Demand Curve: Two variable inputs case.
1. substitution effect: would cause more
of labor to be purchased if output were
held constant at Q1.
This is shown as a movement from point
e1 to e'1 on the same isoquant curve.
To produce an unchanged output, the
firm uses more labor and less capital
when the relative cost of labor falls (i.e.
it substitutes L for K).
Firm's Demand Curve: Two variable inputs case.
Generally,
The substitution effect of a fall in W
tends to raise the demand for labor
but reduces that of capital. Thus, MPL
will decrease (since more L is used
with smaller K) i.e. MPL shifts inward.
Firm's Demand Curve: Two variable inputs case.
𝒘𝟏 ●A
𝑽𝑴𝑷𝑳𝟏
𝑳𝟏 L
0
Derivation of Labor Demand: Two
Variable Inputs Case!
𝑊/𝑽𝑴𝑷𝑳
𝒘𝟏 ●A
𝒘𝟐 ●B
𝑽𝑴𝑷𝑳𝟐
𝑽𝑴𝑷𝑳𝟏
𝑳𝟏 𝑳𝟐 L
0
Derivation of Labor Demand: Two
Variable Inputs Case!
𝑊/𝑽𝑴𝑷𝑳
𝒘𝟏 ●A
𝒘𝟐 ●B
𝒘𝟑 ●C
𝑽𝑴𝑷𝑳𝟐
𝑽𝑴𝑷𝑳𝟏 𝑽𝑴𝑷𝑳𝟑
0 𝑳𝟏 𝑳𝟐 𝑳𝟑 L
Derivation of Labor Demand: Two
Variable Inputs Case!
𝑊/𝑽𝑴𝑷𝑳
A
𝒘𝟏 ●
𝒘𝟐 B
●
𝒘𝟑 ●C 𝒅𝑳
𝑽𝑴𝑷𝑳𝟐
𝑽𝑴𝑷𝑳𝟏 𝑽𝑴𝑷𝑳𝟑
𝑳𝟏 𝑳𝟐 𝑳𝟑 L
0
Factors that affect Firm’s Demand for a
Variable input
Price of the input. For instance,
there is inverse relation between W
and L.
Marginal product of the input
Price of a commodity produced by
the input.
The amount of other factors which
are combined with labor affects dL.
Factors that affect Firm’s Demand for a
Variable input
The prices of other factors. Positively
if other inputs are substitute, &
inversely if it is complement.
Technological change/progress. For
example, labor intensive technology
rises labor demand.
Market Demand Curve for an Input
The price of the product remained
unchanged when we derive the
competitive firm's input demand
curve.
That is, when W fell, the firm
expanded output and sold the larger
output at unchanged price.
This is appropriate when we are
dealing with only one firm.
Market Demand Curve for an Input
.P
𝑺𝟏 at the initial wage
rate firms supply
𝑷∗𝟏 𝑸∗𝟏 amount & sell it
at 𝑷∗𝟏
Q
0 𝑸∗𝟏
Market Demand Curve for an Input
.P
𝑺𝟏 If w rate falls, then
all firms tend to
𝑷∗𝟏 hire more labor
which in turn,
leads to more
industry output.
𝑫
Q
0 𝑸∗𝟏
Market Demand Curve for an Input
Q
0 𝑸∗𝟏 𝑸∗𝟐
Market Demand Curve for an Input
Q
0 𝑸∗𝟏 𝑸∗𝟐
Market Demand Curve for an Input
Q
0 𝑸∗𝟏 𝑸∗𝟐
Market Demand Curve for an Input
This implies a
.P downward
𝑺𝟏 shift in
individual
𝑷∗𝟏 𝑺𝟐
demand curve
for labor.
𝑷∗𝟐
Q
0 𝑸∗𝟏 𝑸∗𝟐
Market Demand Curve for an Input
Firm’s demand
for labor Initially at the wage
.W rate 𝒘∗𝟏 the demand
for labor is 𝒍∗𝟏 .
a
𝒘∗𝟏 a is the equilibrium
point .
𝒅𝑳
L
0 𝒍∗𝟏
Market Demand Curve for an Input
Firm’s demand
. when wage rate
for labor
W falls from 𝒘∗𝟏 to
a 𝒘∗𝟐 the demand
𝒘∗𝟏 for labor
increase from 𝒍∗𝟏
𝒘∗𝟐 𝒃′ to 𝒍′𝟐 .
𝒅𝑳
L
0 𝒍∗𝟏 𝒍′𝟐
Market Demand Curve for an Input
Firm’s demand for But due to the
labor decline of the
.W
commodity price
a from 𝑷𝟏∗ to 𝑷∗𝟐 , the
𝒘∗𝟏
demand for the
input declines
b 𝒃′
𝒘∗𝟐 (Represented by
the leftward shift of
𝒅𝑳 the demand curve
′
′
𝒅𝑳 from 𝒅 𝑳 to 𝒅𝑳 ).
L
0 𝒍∗𝟏 𝒍∗𝟐 𝒍′𝟐
Market Demand Curve for an Input
Firm’s demand
for labor
.W Thus, at input price
𝒘∗𝟐 , point b is the
a
𝒘∗𝟏 equilibrium point, with
𝒍∗𝟐 units employed.
b 𝒃′
𝒘∗𝟐
𝒅𝑳
𝒅′𝑳
L
0 𝒍∗𝟏 𝒍∗𝟐 𝒍′𝟐
Market Demand Curve for an Input
Firm’s demand
for labor so we can aggregate
.W for all employers such
that 𝑳∗𝟏 = 𝒏𝒊 𝒍𝟏,𝒊
∗
and
a
𝒘∗𝟏 𝑳∗𝟐 = 𝒏𝒊 𝒍𝟐,𝒊
∗
,where 𝒊
stands for the 𝒊𝒕𝒉 firm
𝒘∗𝟐
b 𝒃′ and 𝒏 stands for the
number of firms.
𝒅𝑳
𝒅′𝑳
L
0 𝒍∗𝟏 𝒍∗𝟐 𝒍′𝟐
Market Demand Curve for an Input
Market demand Aggregating for all
for the input employers 𝑳𝟏∗ units
.W of the productive
A services are used
𝒘∗𝟏 ● 𝑳∗𝟏 = 𝒏𝒊 𝒍∗𝟏,𝒊
𝒅𝑳
L
0 𝑳∗𝟏
Market Demand Curve for an Input
Market demand
for the input Aggregating for all
.W
employers 𝑳𝟐∗ units of the
A productive services are
𝒘∗𝟏 ● used at 𝒘∗𝟐 , 𝑳∗𝟐 = 𝒏𝒊 𝒍∗𝟐,𝒊
𝒅𝑳
𝒘∗𝟐 ●𝑩
𝒅′𝑳
L
0 𝑳∗𝟏 𝑳∗𝟐
Market Demand Curve for an Input
Market demand for
the input Then by connecting point
.W
A and point B we get the
∗ A market demand D.
𝒘𝟏 ●
𝒅𝑳
𝒘∗𝟐 ●𝑩
𝒅′𝑳
D
L
0 𝑳∗𝟏 𝑳∗𝟐
Supply of a Variable Productive
Service: Labor
All
variable productive services may
be broadly classified into three
groups:
1. natural resources(or land)
2. intermediate goods
3. labor.
Supply of a Variable Productive
Service: Labor
Intermediate goods are those
produced by one entrepreneur and
sold to another who, in turn, utilizes
them in the productive process.
The supply curves of intermediate
goods are positively sloped just like
any other commodities.
Supply of a Variable Productive
Service: Labor
Natural resources may be regarded
as the commodity outputs of
(usually) mining operations.
As such they also have a positively
sloped supply curve.
Supply of a Variable Productive
Service: Labor
Ifyou consider land, however, its
supply is usually constant in the
short run and hence we face a
perfectly inelastic (vertical) supply
curve. It doesn’t change with change
in rent in the short-run.
But the supply curve of land is also
upward sloping in the long-run.
Supply of a Variable Productive
Service: Labor
Here our attention is restricted to the
most important category, labor.
what induces a person to forego
leisure for work?
The supply of labor offered by one
individual can be determined by
indifference curve analysis.
Indifference Curve Analysis of Labor
Supply
The Work-Leisure Decision
Consider an individual with a certain
level of education and labor force
participation i.e. an individual with a
certain skill.
This individual has limited time and
s/he faces a problem of deciding on
how time should be allocated b/n
work and leisure.
Indifference Curve Analysis of Labor
Supply
The Work-Leisure Decision
Work: time devoted on particular
paying job.
Leisure: all kinds of activities for
which the person does not get paid.
We require two information to
determine the optimal distribution of
time.
Indifference Curve Analysis of Labor
Supply
The Work-Leisure Decision
1. subjective: personal information
regarding the person’s work leisure
preferences.
2. Objective: market information
which is reflected in budget
constraint.
Indifference Curve Analysis of Labor
Supply
Indifference curve: shows a different
combinations of income and leisure
time that will give same satisfaction
to the individual.
Different Leisure – work preferences.
Indifference Curve Analysis of Labor
Supply
.
IC for Leisureholic individual
Income
Steep ICs
(M)
Leisure
0
Indifference Curve Analysis of Labor
Supply
. IC for Workaholic individual
Leisure
0
Indifference Curve Analysis of Labor
Supply
Budget Constraint: Combination of
leisure and income a worker can
realize at a given wage rate.
The wage rate represents the slope
of the budget constraint.
The slope of IC is marginal rate of
substitution between leisure &
income.
Budget constraint (Example )
Income
per day
. 24𝒘𝟑 Slope = 𝒘
𝒘𝟏 = $ 𝟏/𝒉𝒓
24𝒘𝟐 𝒘𝟐 = $𝟐/𝒉𝒓
𝒘𝟐 𝒘𝟑
𝒘𝟑 = $𝟑/𝒉𝒓
24𝒘𝟏 𝒘𝟏
Leisure 0 24
24 0
Work
Budget constraint (Example )
Income
. 72
per day Slope = 𝒘
𝒘𝟏 = $ 𝟏/𝒉𝒓
48 𝒘𝟐 = $𝟐/𝒉𝒓
𝒘𝟐 𝒘𝟑
𝒘𝟑 = $𝟑/𝒉𝒓
24 𝒘𝟏
Leisure 0 24
24 0
Work
𝑴𝟒
Derivation of Individual Labor supply
𝒆𝟒 S
𝑾𝟒
𝑰𝑪𝟑
. 𝑴𝟑
Income
per day 𝒆𝟑 𝑰𝑪𝟒
𝑾𝟑 𝑳𝟏 = 𝟐𝟒 − 𝒛𝟏
𝑴𝟐 𝑳𝟐 = 𝟐𝟒 − 𝒛𝟐
𝑾𝟐 𝒆𝟐 𝑳𝟑 = 𝟐𝟒 − 𝒛𝟑
𝑴𝟏 𝑰𝑪𝟏 𝑰𝑪𝟐
𝑳𝟒 = 𝟐𝟒 − 𝒛𝟒
𝑾𝟏 𝒆𝟏 𝒛𝟐 = 𝒛𝟒
𝒛𝟒 𝑳𝟐 = 𝑳𝟒
Leisure(Z) 0 𝒛𝟑 𝒛𝟐 𝒛𝟏 24
0
24 𝑳𝟑 𝑳𝟐 𝑳𝟏
Work(L)
Wage Derivation of Individual Labor supply
𝑺𝑳
𝑾𝟒 𝒆𝟒
.
𝑾𝟑 𝒆𝟑 𝑳𝟏 = 𝟐𝟒 − 𝒛𝟏
𝑳𝟐 = 𝟐𝟒 − 𝒛𝟐
𝑾𝟐 𝑳𝟑 = 𝟐𝟒 − 𝒛𝟑
𝒆𝟐
𝑳𝟒 = 𝟐𝟒 − 𝒛𝟒
𝒆𝟏 𝒛𝟐 = 𝒛𝟒
𝑾𝟏
𝑳𝟐 = 𝑳𝟒
0 𝑳𝟏 𝑳𝟐 𝑳𝟑 24
𝑳𝟒
Work(L)
Derivation of Individual Labor supply
Hours of leisure are measured along
the horizontal axis.
Total number of potential work hrs. a
day = 24 hrs.
The total money income from work is
measured along the vertical axis.
till point 𝒆𝟑 as the wage rate
increases workers supply more labor
hrs.
Derivation of Individual Labor supply
Firm
- monopolist in the product market
- But competitor in the input market
a) The firm's Demand Curve: one
variable case : Labor
𝑸 = 𝒇(𝑳, 𝑲) , K is fixed , 𝑷 = 𝒇(𝑸)
𝑹 = 𝑷𝑸
A Monopolist’s Demands for Inputs
𝑹 = 𝑷𝑸, 𝐂 = 𝒓𝑲 + 𝒘𝑳
Where 𝒓 𝐚𝐧𝐝 𝐰 are price of K & L
π = 𝑹 − 𝑪
π = 𝑷𝑸 − 𝒓𝑲 − 𝒘L
Note that all firms demand and hire
inputs to maximize profits.
𝜕π
So, =𝟎
𝜕𝑳
A Monopolist’s Demands for Inputs
𝜕π 𝝏𝑸 𝝏𝑷 𝝏𝑸
= 𝑷 + 𝑸 −
𝐰=𝟎
𝜕𝑳 𝝏𝑳 𝝏𝑸 𝝏𝑳
𝝏𝑸 𝝏𝑷
(𝑷 + 𝑸 ) −𝐰=𝟎
𝝏𝑳 𝝏𝑸
𝑴𝑷𝑳 ∗ 𝑴𝑹 − 𝒘 = 𝟎
𝑴𝑹𝑷𝑳 − 𝒘 = 𝟎,
𝑴𝑹𝑷𝑳 = 𝒘
The monopolist hires labor units until
marginal revenue prduct of labor equals
its wage rate .
A Monopolist’s Demands for Inputs
𝒘 a 𝑺𝑳
𝒅𝒄𝑳
𝑴𝑹𝑷𝑳 𝒅𝒎
𝑳
∗ L 𝑳∗𝒄
𝑳𝒎 𝑳∗𝒄 𝑳∗𝒎 L
A Monopolist’s Demands for Inputs
b) The Firm's Demand Curve: The
Case of Several Variable Inputs
Assume we have two variable inputs:
labor and Capital
π = 𝑷𝑸 − 𝒓𝑲 − 𝒘L
𝜕π 𝝏𝑸 𝝏𝑷 𝝏𝑸
= 𝑷 +𝑸 −𝐰 =𝟎
𝜕𝑳 𝝏𝑳 𝝏𝑸 𝝏𝑳
→ 𝑴𝑹𝑷𝑳 = 𝒘, 𝑴𝑹𝑷𝑲 = 𝒓 : Equil. Condns.
A Monopolist’s Demands for Inputs
𝒆𝟏
𝒘𝟏 ●
𝒘𝟐 𝒆𝟐
●
𝒆𝟑
𝒘𝟑 ● 𝒅𝑳
𝑴𝑹𝑷𝑳𝟐
𝑴𝑹𝑷𝑳𝟏 𝑴𝑹𝑷𝑳𝟑
𝑳𝟏 𝑳𝟐 𝑳𝟑 L
0
A Monopolist’s Demands for Inputs:
several variables case.
Market Demand: Derivation of Market
demand is similar to the competitive
case.
Market Supply: is not affected by the
fact that firms have monopolistic
power in the product market. Thus,
individual and market supply of labor
is just as derived earlier in
competitive case.
2. Monopsony in Input Markets and
Monopoly in Product Markets
The firm is the only buyer of the
input.
The supply curve of the input facing
the monopsonist is therefore the
market supply curve(upward sloping)
here 𝒘 = 𝒇(𝑳)
2. Monopsony in Input Markets and
Monopoly in Product Markets
a)Equilibrium Price & Employment:
Single Variable Input, Labor:
π = 𝑷𝑸 − 𝒓𝑲 − 𝒘L
𝜕π 𝝏𝑸 𝝏𝑷 𝝏𝑸 𝒅𝑳 𝒅𝒘
= 𝑷 + 𝑸 − (𝐰 + 𝐋 ) =𝟎
𝜕𝑳 𝝏𝑳 𝝏𝑸 𝝏𝑳 𝒅𝑳 𝒅𝑳
𝜕π 𝝏𝑸 𝝏𝑷 𝝏𝑸 𝒅𝒘
= 𝑷 + 𝑸 − (𝐰 + 𝐋 ) =𝟎
𝜕𝑳 𝝏𝑳 𝝏𝑸 𝝏𝑳 𝒅𝑳
𝝏𝑸 𝝏𝑷 𝒅𝒘
(𝑷 + 𝑸 ) − (𝐰 + 𝐋 ) =𝟎
𝝏𝑳 𝝏𝑸 𝒅𝑳
2. Monopsony in Input Markets and
Monopoly in Product Markets
𝝏𝑸 𝝏𝑷 𝒅𝒘
(𝑷 + 𝑸 ) − (𝐰 + 𝐋 )=𝟎
𝝏𝑳 𝝏𝑸 𝒅𝑳
𝑴𝑷𝑳 ∗ 𝑴𝑹 − 𝑴𝑬𝑳 = 𝟎
𝑴𝑹𝑷𝑳 − 𝑴𝑬𝑳 = 𝟎
𝑴𝑹𝑷𝑳 = 𝑴𝑬𝑳 , (𝑬𝒒𝒖𝒊𝒍𝒊𝒃𝒓𝒊𝒖𝒎 𝒄𝒐𝒏𝒅𝒊𝒕𝒊𝒐𝒏)
𝒅𝒘
Where 𝑴𝑬𝑳 = 𝐰 + 𝐋 = MC
𝒅𝑳
𝑴𝑬𝑳 > 𝒘, 𝒘𝒉𝒆𝒓𝒆 𝒘 = 𝑨𝑬𝑳 ,
𝑴𝑬𝑳 = Marginal Expenditure of labor
𝑨𝑬𝑳 = 𝑨𝒗𝒆𝒓𝒂𝒈𝒆 𝒆𝒙𝒑𝒆𝒏𝒅𝒊𝒕𝒖𝒓𝒆 𝒐𝒇 𝒍𝒂𝒃𝒐𝒓
2. Monopsony in Input Markets and
Monopoly in Product Markets
𝑴𝑬 of an input, say labor (MEL) is the
change in total expenditure on the
factor (say labor) arising from one
additional unit of the factor.
the demand for labor by a
monopolistic firm is the marginal
revenue product of labor (𝑴𝑹𝑷𝑳).
𝑴𝑬𝑳 is steeper than the supply curve
of labor.
2. Monopsony in Input Markets and
Monopoly in Product Markets
Wage
. 𝑴𝑬𝑳
𝑺𝑳 = 𝒘
𝒘𝒆 𝑴𝑹𝑷𝑳 = 𝒅𝑳
L
𝑳𝒆
2. Monopsony in Input Markets and
Monopoly in Product Markets
b) Equilibrium Price & Employment:
Two Variable Input, Labor and Capital
Equilibrium employment conditions:
𝑀𝑅𝑃𝐿 = 𝑀𝐸𝐿 ……………(1)
𝑀𝑅𝑃𝐾 = 𝑀𝐸𝐾 ………….(2)
From (1) and (2)
𝑀𝑃𝐿 𝑀𝐸𝐿
𝑀𝑃𝐾
= 𝑀𝐸 ……………....(3)
𝐾
Rearranging this
2. Monopsony in Input Markets and
Monopoly in Product Markets
𝑀𝑃𝐿
𝑀𝐸𝐿
= 𝑀𝑃
𝑀𝐸
𝐾 ……………….(4)
𝐾
𝒘𝒎 𝒆𝒎
𝒘𝒔
𝑽𝑴𝑷𝑳
𝑴𝑹𝑷𝑳
Labor
𝑳 𝒔 𝑳 𝒎 𝑳𝒄
3. Bilateral Monopoly
Assume:
1. There is a Single buyer of an input
(Monopsonist) and
2. A Single Supplier of that input
(Monopolist or a single seller of the input)
3. Bilateral Monopoly
Example:
1. Assume that all firms are organized
in a single body
(e.g. Federation of Manufacturers (FoM)
Thus, FoM is a single buyer of Labor.
3. Bilateral Monopoly
𝐴 𝑺𝑳 = 𝑨𝑬𝒃 = 𝑴𝑪𝒔
𝒘𝒔
𝑭
𝒘𝒃
𝑏
𝑼
𝑴𝑹𝑷𝑳 = 𝑫𝒃 = 𝑨𝑹𝒔
Labor
0 𝑳𝒔 𝑳𝒃
𝑴𝑹𝒔
3. Bilateral Monopoly
1. Supply Side(Monopoly)
From the perspective of the labor union
𝑫𝒃 represents its average revenue
curve(𝑨𝑹𝒔 ).
Thus, given 𝐴𝑅𝑆 marginal revenue
curve of the seller (𝑀𝑅𝑆) can be derived
by the usual graphic technique.
. If 𝐴𝑅𝑆 is linear, then 𝑀𝑅𝑆 is twice as
steep as the 𝐴𝑅 curve; i.e. 𝑀𝑅𝑆 < 𝐴𝑅𝑆.
3. Bilateral Monopoly
1. Supply Side(Monopoly)
𝑆𝐿 represents the 𝑀𝐶 curve of the
seller (labor union), since the union
considers the buyer as if they act as
a perfect competitor.
Thus, given the cost and revenue
curves, the monopolist (labor union)
maximizes his gains at point U,
where his 𝑀𝐶 intersects his 𝑀𝑅.
3. Bilateral Monopoly
1. Supply Side(Monopoly)
So, the monopolist will want to
supply 𝑳𝑺 units of labor and receive a
wage equal to 𝑾𝑺.
3. Bilateral Monopoly
In Summary:
Price desired by the monopsonist is
the lower limit (𝑾𝒃), which can be
realized only if he could force the
monopolist seller to act as a perfect
competitor.
3. Bilateral Monopoly
In Summary:
Likewise, the price desired by the
labor union (monopolist) is the upper
limit (𝑾𝑺), which could be realized if
he could force the monopsonist
(single buyer) to act as a perfect
competitor.
Generally, for a single equilibrium to
exist, one of the two parties should be
price takers.
3. Bilateral Monopoly
Conclusion
Therefore, since the goal of the two
parts can’t be realized, the price and
quantity in the bilateral monopoly
market are indeterminate.
The level at which the price will be
settled depends on the bargaining
skills and power of the participants.
3. Bilateral Monopoly
Conclusion
The power of each participant is, in turn,
determined by his ability to inflict losses
to the opposite part and his ability to
withstand losses inflicted by the
opponent.
Usually, labor union use strike to get
higher wages, and buyers use dismissal
of workers to pay lower wages.