Huber 2012
Huber 2012
https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/
Copyright and Moral Rights for the articles on this site are retained by the individual authors and/or other copyright
owners. For more information on Open Research Online’s data policy on reuse of materials please consult the policies
page.
oro.open.ac.uk
Do clusters really matter for innovation practices in Information Technology?
Franz Huber
The Open University Business School, Walton Hall, Milton Keynes, MK7 6AA,
United Kingdom
E-mail: [email protected]
Abstract
is that firms located in clusters benefit from territorial learning and knowledge
spillovers. However, it remains unclear to what extent these benefits actually occur.
This paper aims to address this issue and examines to what extent research and
benefit from being located in the Cluster. The study shows why many do not believe
that their work benefits from being located in the Cluster. The results suggest that
academics as well as policy makers need to be more careful with the assumption of
particular they concern labour market advantages and benefits from the global
‘brand’ of Cambridge.
economies
0
Introduction
It is widely accepted that acquiring external knowledge is crucial for the success
2004). In the literature on regional learning and innovation it is often argued that
firms located in innovative clusters benefit from other co-located organisations that
create local knowledge spillovers (e.g. Audretsch and Feldman, 2003). Within this
context it has been often stressed that informal knowledge networks are crucial for
more recent debate about local ‘buzz’ (Bathelt et al., 2004; Storper and Venables,
2004) has emphasised knowledge advantages that can happen without any concrete
this topic, there is still very little empirical evidence on the mechanisms of local
that the knowledge advantages of clusters might not be that clear-cut (Giuliani,
2007; Moodysson, 2008), more empirical research is needed to clarify the role of
The aim of this paper is to critically engage with the assumed innovation benefits
Information Technology (IT) Cluster. This paper investigates whether R&D workers
experience knowledge spillovers and, fundamentally, whether and how the Cluster
matters for their work. The results challenge some of the widespread beliefs in the
literature. They show that technological knowledge spillovers within the Cluster
seem highly limited, and many R&D workers do not believe that their work benefits
1
from the Cluster. The significant advantages of the Cluster seem to be of a different
nature; in particular they concern labour market advantages and the global ‘brand’ of
Cambridge.
This paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 will critically discuss the existing
questions. In section 2 the research design and methodology of the case study will be
presented. Section 3 will address the question whether the Cambridge IT Cluster
really matters for innovation practices of R&D workers. It will be shown that for
many this is not the case and the reasons for this will be examined. Section 4 will
Since Marshall’s (1920/1890) seminal work, local externalities have been used
as explanations of regional growth (e.g. Kelly and Hageman, 1999; Krugman, 1991;
Porter, 1998). In this context, next to labour pooling advantages and the availability
of related materials and other inputs, knowledge spillovers have been emphasised as
benefit from local knowledge spillovers: knowledge created by a local agent can be
accessed and used by other agents without market interaction and financial
1
This definition does not regard unintentionality of knowledge flows as a necessary condition
because knowledge can be intentionally transferred to other organisations informally. Also, this
definition does not include cases of so-called rent externalities where less compensation is given than
the market value of the knowledge (Caniels and Romijn, 2005, 499).
2
research and development (Wolfe and Gertler, 2004, 1076).2 It has been often
argued that knowledge flows freely within co-located organisations as a local public
good (Breschi and Lissoni, 2001a). This is often regarded as a source of regional
milieu, industrial districts, clusters, regional innovation systems, and the learning
region (see Moulaert and Sekia, 2003), propose that territorial learning and local
Capello and Faggian, 2005; Lawson and Lorenz, 1999; Storper, 1997). Within this
context, it has often been claimed that the nature of tacit knowledge, knowledge
which is highly contextual and difficult or even impossible to codify (Gertler, 2003),
interactions, regular co-presence and a shared local social context, the transfer of
such tacit knowledge is argued to be highly localised (Feldman, 1999; Maskell and
have been highlighted, current debates still often involve similar ideas on local
neologisms local ‘buzz’ (Bathelt et al., 2004; Storper and Venables, 2004) and
‘noise’ (Grabher, 2002) have been introduced recently. A key characteristic of these
2
In this article, I differentiate between technological knowledge spillovers, used interchangeably with
technological spillovers, and knowledge spillovers, which refer to a broader class of knowledge
3
concepts is that actors in clusters “are automatically exposed to news reports, gossip,
(Jaffe et al., 1993) have been used and proposed as indirect indicators of
technological spillovers.
However, these assumptions usually have not been developed on the basis of
by Malmberg and Maskell (2002, 434). Also, ironically the meaning and functioning
of ‘tacit knowledge’ usually remains tacit (Martin and Sunley, 2003, 17).
The recent focus in economic geography on ‘local buzz’ does not clarify this
states which social processes are included or excluded in ‘local buzz’ phenomena,
face-to-face interactions and buzz are conflated (Asheim et al., 2007), and it still
local actors (Moodysson, 2008). Thus, the actual processes of territorial learning
usually remain unexplored (Benner, 2003, 1810; Oinas, 1999; Staber, 2009). A
major reason for this is that the focus on inter-firm knowledge activities tends to
neglect personal, and often informal, relationships of individuals; this is the level
where the mechanisms of learning actually take place (Malmberg and Power, 2005,
421). With a few exceptions (in particular Benner, 2003; Dahl and Pedersen, 2004;
Grabher and Ibert, 2006; Henry and Pinch, 2000; Ibrahim et al., 2009; Kesidou et
4
al., 2009; Lissoni, 2001; Østergaard, forthcoming; Saxenian, 1996) the literature has
not looked closely at cross-firm knowledge links beyond the firm-level and formal
linkages. A notable exception in this respect is the survey by Ibrahim et al. (2009),
local sources of knowledge and knowledge spillovers than inventors not located in
clusters. However, the low absolute ratings of knowledge spillovers in their survey,
the low response rate and potential sector-specificity produces uncertainty about the
the role of various local sources of knowledge in the Uruguay software cluster;
although their respondents rated market-based knowledge flows much higher than
the key themes is that networks matter (Keeble, 2000). The dominant picture is that
encouraging informal relations among actors” (Breschi and Malerba, 2001, 819-
20).
Empirical studies that do not find extensive knowledge networks in clusters, tend
to argue that this is an undesirable situation which is causally responsible for the
lack of success of clusters (e.g. Bathelt, 2005a). Often, for instance, in Porter’s
(1998) work on economic clusters, the role of social networks for clusters is
emphasised but the specific mechanisms are not rigorously theorised and empirically
investigated (Martin and Sunley, 2003, 16-7). As highlighted by Sunley (2008), this
Among the important positive exceptions is the study by Dahl and Pedersen
(2004, 2005) which reveals that engineers in the wireless communication cluster
5
around Aalborg have frequent contacts with each other, which often leads to the
receipt of useful work-related knowledge. However, their paper does not examine
(2008) shows that in the Swedish Medicon Valley life science region carefully
activities but unstructured local buzz seems largely absent. However, the exact role
underexplored.
production and innovations, they are even more silent about processes of knowledge
flows. Because they use indirect indicators, the knowledge production function
approach and the patent citation approach are not able to investigate the concrete
and Schnellenbach, 2006; Henderson, 2007). Even the most fine-grained recent
economic studies on technological spillovers such as Zucker et al. (1998) use crude
It is important to note that recent literature has emphasised that not only local but
knowledge linkages at multiple spatial scales are important (e.g. Amin and
Cohendet, 2004; Bathelt et al., 2004; Bunnell and Coe, 2001; MacKinnon et al.,
2002). However, the multi-scalar perspective does not imply that local knowledge
networks and spillovers are insignificant as, for instance, the ‘local buzz and global
pipelines’ (Bathelt et al., 2004) metaphor illustrates. The view tends to be that
6
Overall, knowledge spillovers, all to often remain a ‘black box’ and more
empirical research is needed to clarify these issues (Breschi and Lissoni, 2001a;
This paper aims to address the voids discussed above by being one of the first
innovative cluster. It addresses the following research questions: (i) To what extent
and how does being located in the cluster matter for R&D workers. (ii) Specifically,
to what extent do R&D workers benefit from local knowledge spillovers and
interactions occur is an empirical question but not part of the definition.3 Within the
sectors hardware and software were randomly selected.4 In each firm R&D workers
(Simmie et al., 2006). The existing literature tends to suggest that in such successful
clusters vibrant knowledge flows are going on. Therefore, Cambridge represents a
3
For a similar approach and a useful discussion of different theoretical concepts see Giuliani (2005).
4
In the remainder of this paper, “the Cluster” is used interchangeably with “the Cambridge IT
Cluster”.
7
prime example where the theoretical assumptions of local knowledge spillovers and
businesses (LibraryHouse, 2004). Within IT, this study looks at the dominant
companies).
lead to partial and potentially incorrect views because they do not necessarily know
what employees are really doing, and their views are likely to be biased towards the
official ideal strategy of the firm (see e.g. Dahl and Pedersen, 2005, 76).
The list of the firms in the target population was constructed by merging two
existing databases from the research and consultancy companies ‘Library House
Ltd.’ and ‘Cambridge Investment Research Ltd.‘. Those companies maintained a list
The target population (sampling frame) at firm-level consists of 220 firms, 156
hardware; that is, the proportions of the sub-sectors in the sample mirror the target
population). Within those I asked the firms to select R&D workers according to the
5
Saxenian remarked in the late 1980s that the tenants of the Cambridge Science Park complain that
there is hardly any information sharing or co-operation among firms (Saxenian, 1989, 468-9).
However, after a vibrant development in the last decades and more recent studies about Cambridge,
nowadays the dominant belief is that local interaction and knowledge flows between firms are indeed
a key ingredient of high-tech agglomerations such as Cambridge (see e.g. Garnsey and Heffernan,
8
following criteria (if applicable): the Managing Director if s/he is actively involved
important for the firm; one senior engineer/developer (e.g. project leader); one mid-
level engineer/developer; one junior engineer/developer with less than two years of
It has to be emphasised that getting access to the firm was incredibly difficult.
were collected.
workers and went with them through structured questionnaires and conducted semi-
structured interviews.6 Overall, the meetings lasted from 20 to 120 minutes (mean
45 minutes). The recorded interview material was fully transcribed. Using ATLAS.ti
software, the quotes were systematically coded, and those codes were categorised
into meta-concepts. The results presented in this paper (in particular Figures 1 and 3)
Out of 100 firms in the sample, 46 participated, which represents a response rate
of 46% of the firms. 25 firms (54%) are in software, and 21 firms (46%) in
hardware, which means that hardware is over-represented in the data (recall that
around 70% of the firms in the target population are in software and around 30% in
6
To reduce biases as much as possible, assurance was given to the interviewees that their accounts
9
Because there are no detailed data of the population available, it was not possible to
check for any additional response biases. However, let us explore several
only very few exceptions. The average firm size in terms of the number of
employees (full-time head count) is 35 for the Cambridge sites (median 20) and 81
for all locations world-wide (median 30). On average there are 17 R&D workers in
Since IT is a broad field, let us explore some of the specific characteristics of the
Table 1. Type of knowledge which is rated most highly for contributing to the competitiveness of
the firm. “Cutting-edge knowledge can be an important source of competitiveness for firms. With
regard to the product you are working on: to what extent does your firm hold cutting-edge
knowledge in the following areas that contributes to its competitiveness?” (% of respondents,
N=105). 7
All four Technology
Market- All other
Technology Marketing Management rated AND market- Total
needs combinations
equally needs
Software 37.9 24.1 3.4 0.0 8.6 17.2 8.6 100.0%
Hardware 55.3 10.6 2.1 2.1 6.4 17.0 6.4 100.0%
Total 45.7 18.1 2.9 1.0 7.6 17.1 7.6 100.0%
In the literature the knowledge base of the software industry has been
229). Although several software companies in the sample operate exactly in this
7
7-point Likert scale from “1=very much” to 7=”not at all” and alternatively “Don’t know”. The
types of knowledge are: “Technological knowledge”, “Specific knowledge about market needs
10
companies that apply cutting-edge technology (e.g. new mathematical algorithms) to
develop products (37.9%).8 For hardware companies, as one might expect of this
sector, cutting-edge technology is more important than in software: more than half
of the R&D workers (55.3%) are in technology-driven companies and only 10.6% in
market-driven ones.
In terms of the job position in the sample there are 14 Managing Directors, 33
engineers/developers and 2 in other positions. That is, people in senior positions are
On average the respondents worked for 3.0 (median: 2) firms before their current
employment, and they lived at 1.8 (median: 2) places outside of the Greater
(5.7%) were female, although I have explicitly tried to ask for female participants in
each firm. In terms of nationality, British citizens are very dominant with 89.5%
being British citizens and an additional 3% sharing a British citizenship with another
one. This shows that the labour market is not really internationalised but operates
strongly within the national boundary. It is remarkable that only 4.8% are of a non-
white ethnic group. The average age of the respondent is 38.8 years (median: 38)
with the vast majority being between 30 and 50 years (11.7% were younger than 30
years, and 6.8% were older than 50 years). Not surprisingly, the respondents are
8
Also, recall that the sample does not include purely service-based companies.
9
Two possible reasons for the selection bias are first, that people in junior positions might not feel as
confident to speak with ‘outsiders’ as R&D workers in senior positions. Second, it might be that firm
representatives who selected the interviewees believed that experienced senior R&D workers make a
11
highly educated with 26.5% having Ph.D. degrees, 31.4% Master’s degrees and
This section investigates to what extent the R&D workers benefit from being
The R&D workers were presented with the following question: “To what extent
is it beneficial for your work in your current firm to have many innovative
from “1 = very much” to “7 = not at all”. Surprisingly the most frequent answer is
“7” (see Table 2), which very strongly indicates that for their work the Cluster is not
beneficial at all.
Table 2. “To what extent is it beneficial for your work in your current firm to have many innovative
firms/research institutions located in the Cambridge region?” [“1 = very much” to “7 = not at
all”] (% of respondents, N=104).
R&D Managers Engineers
Total or Managing or
Directors developers
1 = very much 13.5 16.9 8.9
2 15.4 21.7 12.5
3 13.5 13.0 12.5
4 8.7 10.9 7.1
5 15.4 17.4 14.3
6 15.4 2.2 25.0
7 = not at all 18.3 15.2 19.6
Overall, it seems remarkable that 49.1% explicitly state that it is not beneficial
10
The difference of the mean between R&D managers/managing directors and
12
for their work ( “5” to “7”) and 8.7% are undecided. Whilst 42.2% think that the
Cluster is beneficial (answers “1” to “3”), more than a third of those concern reasons
that do not represent knowledge benefits but other advantages which will be
discussed in section 4.1. That is, overall, nearly two-thirds of the respondents do not
spillovers and territorial learning might not be as widespread as the literature tends
to suggests. Instead this supports a more critical view that knowledge networks can
be selective (Giuliani, 2007; Morrison and Rabellotti, 2009; Østergaard, 2009), and
knowledge from the Cluster environment can be very limited. Furthermore, Table 2
also illustrates that R&D Managers and Managing Directors benefit more from the
This begs the question of why many believe that they do not benefit. In the
3.2. Why the Cambridge IT Cluster is not beneficial for R&D workers
material; the respondents had the opportunity to qualify why they think that the
Cambridge IT Cluster is not beneficial for their work. Their responses fall into these
11
Whilst it is beyond the scope of this article to discuss detailed regression analyses, it is important to
note that the job position is the most important variable in explaining the variation of the responses.
In contrast, the knowledge base of the firm, as presented in Table 1, does not make any difference.
Furthermore, there are no statistically significant differences between the responses from the R&D
13
groups (see Figure 1).12
Figure 1. The reasons why R&D workers think that the Cambridge IT Cluster is not beneficial
for their work
The first group of responses highlights disadvantages of the Cluster. All of these
Cluster, local competition between the employers for bright minds is intense, which
lack financial stability and kudos. This warns us that labour pooling cannot be
regarded as advantageous for all companies. Other reasons mentioned are that the
costs (for office space and labour) are too high, and that other locations would be
12
Every single response, even when only mentioned once, was categorised into these types. The
frequency of the responses is mentioned approximately in the text. The same applies for Figure 2
below.
13
Because of the broader responsibilities of the senior-managerial R&D workers, several of their
responses in the remainder of this paper concern ‘the firm’ as a whole. However, note that the units of
analysis are the R&D workers and inferences to the firm-level are based on their individual
experiences.
14
Secondly, the most frequently mentioned reason is that there is simply no need
to have interactions within the local region. The most important arguments
mentioned are that personal contacts and suppliers and customers can be anywhere
because of the global focus of the company. Also, one respondent emphasised that
they recruit people from elsewhere and are therefore not dependent on Cambridge.
sufficient for being successful and nowadays they can access a lot of useful
knowledge via the Internet; consequently, there is no need to source knowledge from
the local region. Also, a few respondents stressed that strategically their firm is quite
guarded, aims to keep their expertise in-house and does not want to have any
Another reason put forward by one firm is that the business model is based on
feedback from customers rather than on research (that is, a synthetic rather than an
analytic knowledge base according to Asheim et al., 2007); therefore, the research
from the Cluster. The most frequent argument is that the technological field is so
highly specific and specialised that there is nobody within the Cluster who could be
organisation. […] The sort of development work we do is not really the sort of
thing that other companies in the area are doing, or has been recently researched by
Finally, another reason mentioned a few times is that time pressure both in the
work place and in private life severely limits the opportunities for professional
15
socialising and learning from other Cluster companies. Consequently even local
company in this region. […] But I don’t know to what extent people maintain their
contacts with previous people. […] I would suspect that it is probably less than you
might believe because you are so busy generally, and work takes up a lot of time.
And family life and all as well, and it’s quite difficult to keep that personal thing
The discussion so far is just one part of the picture. In this section we discuss
Figure 2. Reasons why the Cambridge IT Cluster is beneficial for R&D workers.
16
Labour market advantages. Importantly, the most frequently mentioned benefit
is not directly related the working practices in the current job. Rather, it concerns
broader labour market advantages. On the one hand, employees like to work in the
“One of the attractions of Cambridge for me was that if one job didn’t work out,
there would be lots of others to choose from. So, that was important for me on a
That is, the fact that there are many potential employers in the region is a critical
issue for many R&D workers in terms of career perspectives and private dimensions
(‘managing’ a family and not having to move house). Interestingly, many of the
“But for my job there is not really any other specific advantage of being in
the Cluster because of the opportunities to attract bright minds, both in terms
of recruiting people from other local companies and from elsewhere. Again,
Critically, while personal networks are often not important for sourcing R&D
“I would say Cambridge is pretty beneficial, but not for knowledge contacts.
Rather, if we need some skills that we don’t have, we might look to recruit people.
14
In this article embodied knowledge refers to all aspects of an individual’s human capital and also
(1995).
17
large source of people available, and b) because many of us here are from
Cambridge. We probably have a quite large local knowledge about who might be
available and might be interested. And it’s a great way of finding the right people
quickly and readily. So, that sort of networking is very useful at certain times when
process (Audretsch and Keilbach, 2005; Eriksson and Lindgren, 2009) as has been
also shown for Cambridge by Keeble et al. (1999) as well as by Lawton Smith and
Waters (2005; 2008). However, although there is some local inter-firm mobility in
Cambridge15, the vast majority of all recruited managers and R&D workers come
from outside of Cambridge (Keeble et al., 1999, 326). That is, the flows of embodied
expertise operate on multiple spatial scales and collective learning cannot be seen as
2001a, 992-4). For instance, if the individuals take certain embodied knowledge
with them, knowledge is merely shifted from one place to another and does not lead
to a club good or public good. Also, hiring embodied knowledge is not free—as the
traditional spillover notion would suggest16—but the employers have to pay for it
15
The average individual job tenure in Cambridgeshire for scientists and engineers in the study by
Lawton Smith and Waters (2005) is 5.78 years; they argue that the rate of turnover is below some of
(labour) market should be called knowledge spillovers or not; see Breschi and Lissoni (2001a) versus
increases productivity and profitability when they are hired to non R&D occupations, which was
interpreted as indirect evidence that mobility between R&D labs do not seem to be a channel for
knowledge spillovers.
18
The Cambridge brand. Another frequently mentioned reason why being located
“I’m not sure about other firms or research institutions being beneficial. I think it’s
the name Cambridge […]. If you’re working in Cambridge, people assume that, I
don’t know what the word is really, there seems to be a kind of respect because you
Many R&D workers think that the Cluster does not impact on their current work,
but the company enjoys benefits in terms of marketing and getting orders from
customers:
“For my own work not at all beneficial. It doesn’t make any difference at all. But I
guess we get quite a bit of work because we are in Cambridge, a kudos thing. But
customers to visit the company for creating or maintaining business links. Also, it
Formal business links. The results confirm that in clusters there are rather
limited official transactions going on between firms (Malmberg and Maskell, 2002,
437). Only a rather small subset of companies in the sample benefit from local
18
The brand of Cambridge is not only constituted by its world-famous university but also by its
agglomeration of high-technology companies (with global media coverage such as in the Economist,
2001).
19
First and foremost, several specialist technology companies have local
clients/customers. These supply highly specific products for high-tech sectors such
as the inkjet or scientific software for research institutions. Here regular face-to-face
contacts are often regarded as convenient and useful for effective discussions.
Second, people in only six companies mentioned that collaboration with the
whilst the University was influential for the emergence of the Cluster (Garnsey and
where there is a consortium of local firms (Garnsey and Heffernan, 2005, 1136-8).
Fourth, a few interviewees stated that it is convenient, but not critical, to have
selective according to the interviews. In contrast to Giuliani (2007) who finds that
business networks are more pervasive than knowledge networks, I could not find
However, it needs to be emphasised that these results are based on R&D workers,
who might not have an overview about all kinds of business relationships.
highlighted that although Cambridge was important for the start-up phase, it is not
20
Knowledge activities. Only few R&D workers mentioned getting access to
knowledge. That is, access to knowledge through personal networks within the
management positions. Within this context, personal contacts can help for hiring
embodied knowledge (see the labour market advantages above). Also help and
“For instance, the CEO of one of those companies rang me three or four weeks
ago, he got the opportunity to quote for a very big job, and his concern was, is this
job too big for his company’s size, it could easily suck in all of his resource and kill
him, on the other hand. So he was asking my advice off the record. […] Of course,
we actually had that conversation on the phone, so it could have been on the other
end of the country, but I think he chose to call me because we had established a
personal relationship because it was easy to do so because we see one another, well
not regularly, but enough times.” (Product Manager, large hardware company)
trust and led to asking for advice on confidential management issues. Whilst this
example confirms the widespread views on the advantages of spatial proximity for
technological issues with local personal contacts; this helps to explain why job
position makes a difference in Table 2. Furthermore, only one person reported that a
the Cluster.
21
It should be highlighted that the above results are from the R&D workers’
the Cluster for other job positions or the firms as a whole (such as access to finance
tangible interaction (Bathelt et al., 2004; Malmberg and Maskell, 2002). Staber
(2009) suggests that imitation without any close interaction can lead to learning
that the R&D workers might not be aware of such subtle and perhaps ‘tacit’
knowledge flows. Therefore, one might maintain, we cannot trust the responses
of the interviewees.
One could argue that the R&D workers might be competent in reflecting on
increase the chances that the workers become consciously aware of place-
“Over there [in Silicon Valley] they talk about everything. So you know in detail
about other companies. That’s a U.S., Silicon Valley thing. People are just staying
19
Recall that on average the respondents worked for 3.0 (median: 2) firms before their current
employment, and they lived at 1.8 (median: 2) places outside of the Greater Cambridge region before.
22
in companies a year or two, and you keep your friends. That encourages you to
pass information a lot more freely that over here. Here it’s different; people stay in
their jobs longer, and there is a bit more loyalty to the company rather than to the
social contacts. […] One of the differences were the sales guys over there you
know a lot better. And they know everything that’s going on in other companies.
They talk, they go out for dinner, and they tell what’s going on all the time. But it’s
not that culture here. They don’t come here, there is less information.” (Principal
A few other respondents reported similar experiences. This suggests that the
effort while living in Cambridge so that the respondents are not aware of it.21
5. Conclusions
While the literature tends to assume that firms located in innovative clusters
the results in this paper question this. Nearly two-thirds of the R&D workers in IT
companies do not see a real knowledge benefit for their work in their current
20
Recall that R&D workers do not tend to change their employer frequently (cf. footnote 15).
21
However, one might question whether really valuable types of knowledge are transferred.
23
company from being located in one of the most prominent and successful IT clusters
in Europe. The most frequent argument why the Cluster is not beneficial is that there
particular, many R&D workers believe that alternative sources of knowledge such as
supports studies such as Freel (2003) which suggest that internal resources and
competencies of firms are often sufficient for innovation. A further reason why the
Cluster is not beneficial is that there are no opportunities to interact and learn.
Similar to Moodysson’s (2008) results in the life-sciences, this is especially the case
non-deliberate local buzz as understood by Bathelt et al. (2004) hardly seems to take
place.
Moreover, the paper also shows why the Cluster does matter. For only a few
frequently mentioned advantage of the Cluster is of a more subtle nature, which has
like to move and stay in the Cambridge IT Cluster because they believe it offers
This represents a significant benefit to employers for attracting local and global
highly-skilled labour. That is, local labour market pooling and local labour mobility
do not only lead to well-known externalities (e.g. Eriksson and Lindgren, 2009) but
labour. In terms of access to knowledge through personal networks only very few
24
R&D workers see a benefit from the Cluster; this mainly concerns business
knowledge of senior managers who appear to benefit more from the Cluster than
‘pure’ engineers/developers.
We have addressed the argument that more subtle forms of knowledge flows
might take place without the interviewees being aware of them, which deserves
further empirical investigation. Overall, the empirical results suggest that the role of
Finally, I should also emphasise the limitations of this study and questions for
future research.
First, it is possible that the situation is different for other job roles, for instance,
for managers that are not involved in research or development. Indeed, my results
suggest that that job functions matter and that clusters might be more important for
consultancies which do not offer their own products. As argued by Lawson (2003)
such technical consultancies can play a role for the dissemination of technical
Third, there might be variation in national or regional culture. For instance, the
contexts in Uruguay (Kesidou et al., 2009) or Silicon Valley (Saxenian, 1996) might
22
However, only one of the respondents in my sample mentioned to benefit from technical
consultancies.
25
facilitate knowledge spillovers more than in other successful clusters. As discussed
in section 5.2., a few respondents who worked in Silicon Valley before noticed
in terms of labour mobility, loyalty towards the employer and cultural norms of sales
different national and regional contexts could examine these questions in detail.
Fourth, this study is an in-depth analysis at a specific point in time but does not
formed historically. The role of agglomeration economies can change throughout the
industry life cycle (Neffke et al., 2009; Potter and Watts, forthcoming). For instance,
associated with the University of Cambridge and their personal networks shaped the
networks and technological spillovers might have been more important in earlier
Despite these limitations, this study suggests that innovation policies should be
cluster policies that focus on local networking might be inappropriate (see also
Romijn and Albaladejo, 2002). Instead, the results suggest that a focus on labour
market initiatives to attract and retain a critical mass of R&D workers and related
Funding
I would like to thank Bob Bennett, Mia Gray, Iain Evans Charlotte Werndl and
two anonymous referees for valuable comments on previous versions of this paper.
Many thanks also to the audiences at the RGS-IBG Annual International Conference
2008, the Regional Studies Association Annual Conference 2009 and the Stavanger
References
Asheim, B. T., Coenen, L., Vang, J. (2007) Face-to-face, buzz, and knowledge
role of labour mobility and informal networks for knowledge transfer, pp. 8-25.
Bathelt, H. (2005a) Cluster relations in the media industry: exploring the 'distanced
Bathelt, H., Malmberg, A., Maskell, P. (2004) Clusters and knowledge: local buzz,
35: 1809-30.
Breschi, S., Lissoni, F. (2001a) Knowledge spillovers and local innovation systems:
255-73.
515.
Capello, R., Faggian, A. (2005) Collective learning and relational capital in local
Dahl, M. S., Pedersen, C. O. R. (2005) Social networks in the R&D process: the case
53.
Technology, 8: 5-25.
99.
Giuliani, E. (2005) Cluster absorptive capacity - Why do some clusters forge ahead
and others lag behind?, European Urban and Regional Studies, 12: 269-88.
Grabher, G. (2002) The project ecology of advertising: tasks, talents and teams,
Grabher, G., Ibert, O. (2006) Bad company? The ambiguity of personal knowledge
29
networks, Journal of Economic Geography, 6: 251-71.
Keeble, D., Lawson, C., Moore, B., Wilkinson, F. (1999) Collective learning
Kesidou, E., Caniels, M. C. J., Romijn, H. A. (2009) Local knowledge spillovers and
Lawson, C., Lorenz, E. (1999) Collective learning, tacit knowledge and regional
LibraryHouse (2004) Flight to quality. The Cambridge Cluster Report 2004, The
Lissoni, F. (2001) Knowledge codification and the geography of innovation: the case
Malmberg, A., Power, D. (2005) (How) do (firms in) clusters create knowledge?,
Myint, Y. M., Vyakarnam, S., New, M. J. (2005) The effect of social capital in new
Neffke, F., Svensson Henning, M., Boschma, R. A., Lundquist, K.-J., Olander, L.-O.
Economic Dynamics.
Pittaway, L., Robertson, M., Munir, K., Denyer, D., Neely, A. (2004) Networking
increasing returns, diminishing returns, and the industry life cycle, Journal of
electronics and software firms in southeast England, Research Policy, 31: 1053-
67.
Simmie, J., Carpenter, J., Chadwick, A., Martin, R., Wood, P. (2006) State of the
Press.
Storper, M., Venables, A. J. (2004) Buzz: face-to-face contact and the urban
Wolfe, D. A., Gertler, M. S. (2004) Clusters from the inside and out: local dynamics
33