Kapur 2012
Kapur 2012
Print Publication Date: Jun 2012 Subject: Political Science, International Relations
Online Publication Date: Nov 2012 DOI: 10.1093/oxfordhb/9780195337228.013.0006
Introduction
This chapter surveys the economic consequences of international migration on sending
countries. Despite the massive potential income gains from poor-to-rich-country
migration, just 3 percent of the world's population lives outside their country of birth. The
aggregate numbers, however, mask great diversity in emigrant shares across countries,
with more than half of the native-born populations of some small island countries living
abroad.
In addition to the numbers of people who leave, the effects of emigration on the sending
country depend critically on the selection effects of who leaves—and who returns.
Although education obviously matters, a number of other variables, from age, gender, and
Page 1 of 25
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). © Oxford University Press, 2018. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).
ethnicity, to where they go and why, all impact the degree and nature of the economic
effects.
At the systemic level, these flows are shaped by (and therefore have consequences for)
the sending country and the international migration architecture. In sharp contrast to the
liberal, multilateral, institutional architecture governing international financial and trade
flows, the structure governing international migration is restrictive, selective (favoring
the highly skilled), and rigid in its bias against temporary labor movements, and includes
a tacit tolerance toward less-skilled illegal residents performing dirty, dangerous, and dull
(“3D”) tasks.1
(p. 132)The linkages between migration and development have become an active area of
research in recent years. Much of this research emphasizes the dynamic nature of
international migration, and the previous pervasive pessimism about “brain drain” has
given way to a more nuanced optimism about “brain circulation.” The dynamic effects
that have received attention include those of migration prospects on human capital
investments, the value of the diaspora as economic partners and global bridge builders,
and the potentially transformative effects of returnees. Notwithstanding these advances,
the trade-offs between the costs of absence and the benefits of dynamic migration flows
are still not well understood. For instance, in the context of skill-selective immigration
policies, it is possible that the long-term effects of the loss of institution builders and
innovators could swamp the immediate static income gains of financial remittances.
The size, growth, and stability of remittance flows have also motivated research on the
links between remittances and development. Particular attention has focused on the links
between remittances and poverty reduction; the value of remittances in the context of
absent insurance and credit markets; and the propensity to invest remittances in health,
education, and entrepreneurial ventures. An older view that saw remittances as transfers
that are “frittered away” is also giving way to a more nuanced one that sees migration
and remittances as an integral component of household income and risk management
strategies.
This chapter first provides a broad overview of recent research on migration and
development, beginning with the sizes of the emigrant/immigrant stocks and the
possibilities for migration-related income gains, both direct migration-related impacts
and the resulting remittance flows. Recent advances have led to reassessment of the
effects of migration on development, often leading to a more sanguine view compared to
earlier work on the “brain drain.” However, the state of knowledge is still too rudimentary
to identify when migration is beneficial for development. This uncertainty is particularly
pronounced for skilled migration, which is increasingly the object of rich-country policies.
Page 2 of 25
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). © Oxford University Press, 2018. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).
Until recently, the lack of good data severely hampered understanding of the complex
links between international migration and development. A series of initiatives over the
last decade has improved data quality and has encouraged new research on the subtle
effects that migration (and remittances) can have on poor-country development, although
many issues remain unsettled.2
(p. 133)
The income gains associated with poor-to-rich-country migration are substantial. Clemens
and Pritchett (2008)3 provide numbers indicating that the relationship between average
income gains and source-country per capita income is substantial for most poor countries.
Clearly considerable improvements in productivity and living standards are possible when
individuals leave failing institutions behind. There are large differences between GDP per
capita and income per natural for a significant number of (typically smaller) countries.4
However, notwithstanding the sizeable average income gains (and the large gaps
between GDP per capita and income per natural for a number of countries), the overall
effect of migration on average world income is modest. Kapur and McHale (2009)
calculate that the total gain in world income per capita from international migration is
just above 1 percent. The limited upside gain is largely because emigrants make up just 3
percent of the world's population.5
Page 3 of 25
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). © Oxford University Press, 2018. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).
The varied effects of migration on development work through multiple channels. The
framework used in this discussion was developed by Kapur and McHale (2005a) and
identifies four principal channels: prospect, absence, diaspora, and return.
The possibility of such an investment-induced “brain gain” has been a major focus of the
recent theoretical literature on migration and development (e.g., Stark et al. 1997; Beine
et al. 2001).6 More recently, the possibility of an overall positive effect on domestic human
capital has received qualified empirical support. Beine et al. (2008) find that countries
with low levels of human capital and low emigration rates experience a “beneficial brain
drain,” but that more countries are net losers than net gainers. Boucher et al. (2005)
report that, in the case of internal migration in Mexico, the dynamic investment effect
from a higher return on human capital outweighs the static depletion effect of out-
migration. However, they find that emigration to the United States does not significantly
affect human capital formation. Chand and Clemens (2008) examine a quasi-natural
experiment from Fiji, where after 1987 the Indian population fell to 40 percent below its
pre-1987 level because they were forced to emigrate by political events they saw as
adverse to their interests. Although Clemens and Chand find the high emigration rate for
Indians was associated with increases in the stock of Indian human capital in Fiji, this is
likely an artifact of the duration of analysis. With time, as more and more Indians leave,
their human capital stock will inevitably decline, because few will be left. This analysis is
cautionary in that it highlights the sensitivity of the effects of emigration to the time
horizon of the analysis.
Page 4 of 25
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). © Oxford University Press, 2018. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).
The most obvious effect is that the country's labor supply falls, a trend that should result
in increased wages for those left behind. The great transatlantic migrations of the late
nineteenth century were the single most important factor in wage convergence between
Europe and the United States (O'Rourke and Williamson 2009). Needless to say, the
effects of the absence channel are strongly mediated by the characteristics of who leaves,
but also by how many leave, from where (sectors, regions, communities), and their
destinations. The late nineteenth century witnessed two large-scale international
migrations: one from Europe and the other, of comparable absolute numbers, from China
and India. However, the former was much larger in relative numbers, and its destination
was to other temperate countries (in contrast to the latter, in which migrants mainly went
to other tropical countries). The consequences, as Arthur Lewis (1994) argued in his
classic essay, were starkly different for the sending countries and set the stage for the
evolution of the international economic order in the twentieth century.
Absence can also have direct and important political effects by simply creating political
space for new groups. If elites leave—often the case in the aftermath of revolutions—the
political space opens up for new elites, as has been the case in Cuba and Iran. Hence,
cross-national spatial mobility can affect vertical political and social mobility. It also
affects domestic spatial mobility. External migration drives internal migration, and in a
multiethnic society, if politics is organized along religious and ethnic cleavages, this will
have political ramifications.
Page 5 of 25
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). © Oxford University Press, 2018. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).
Remittances have received a great deal of attention in the recent migration and
development literature.9 They represent a significant, growing, and stable flow of funds to
developing countries. Figures 6.2 and 6.3 reproduce well-known time series evidence on
the evolution of remittance and capital flows to developing countries.10 Clearly total
remittances have been growing over time, although some of the increases are a statistical
artifact, the result of better official capture of data (Kapur 2005). They are also a
relatively stable source of foreign exchange inflows, especially when compared with debt
and equity flows. Remittance flows have also outstripped official development assistance
since the mid-1990s.
Page 6 of 25
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). © Oxford University Press, 2018. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).
Often remittances are viewed as an additional source of resource transfer for developing
countries. However, once the income gains from migration are measured, obviously
remittances cannot simply be added as a separate source of gain. The reason is that the
remittances come out of the migrants’ receiving-country incomes—to include them along
with the income gains would be double counting. As mentioned previously, the fact that
remittances are spent at lower, sending-country prices is an additional source of welfare
gain. This leads to looking for other remittance-related factors that increase the overall
value of migration for those born in poor countries.
Earlier literature viewed remittances as transfers that were “frittered away,” but more
recent literature sees migration and remittances as an integral component of household
income and risk management strategies. Attention has been focused particularly on the
links between remittances and poverty reduction; the value of remittances in the context
of absent insurance and credit markets; and the propensity to invest remittances in
health, education, and entrepreneurial ventures. Thus remittances have been found to
play an insurance role following natural disasters (Yang 2008a), support investments in
education (Cox and Ureta, 2003), child health (Hildebrandt and McKenzie 2005), reduced
child labor (Yang 2008b), and small businesses (Taylor and Wyatt 1996; Woodruff and
Zenteno 2001). Why might (p. 138) remittances be spent differently from other income?
The most obvious reason is that the sender conditions the remittances on their being
used for investment purposes. But a high propensity to invest remittances could also
follow from “tagging” them to household members more likely to invest (e.g., mothers) or
because of a tendency to cordon off remittances as being for longer-term purposes11 (see
World Bank 2006, ch. 5).
Page 7 of 25
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). © Oxford University Press, 2018. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).
poverty, using household survey data. These studies typically do find a significant
poverty-reducing effect (see, e.g., Adams 2005; Yang and Martinez 2005). A
complementary approach is to examine the impact of remittances on poverty measures
using cross-country data. McHale (2005) and World Bank (2006) estimate poverty
regressions that relate various international poverty measures to the country's mean
income and inequality level. The empirical model is then used to simulate the impact of
remittances on poverty, given various assumptions about how remittances are distributed
across households. Because remittances are typically found to have small effects on
measured inequality in the household data, the baseline assumption is that they are
distributed in the same way as other household income. Even without reducing inequality,
the simulations show that remittances lead to substantially lower poverty rates for a
number of countries. The largest reduction in the poverty rate (one dollar per day
standard) was found for Lesotho, where remittances equal to 44 percent of GDP were
responsible for lowering the poverty rate by 34 percentage points, to 36 percent (see
World Bank 2006).
Residents of poor countries face pervasive failures in insurance and credit markets. The
international migration of family members may be a rational response. In the face of
these market failures, remittances will tend to flow at times when they have high value
(e.g., maintaining consumption in the face of natural disasters or taking advantage of
entrepreneurial opportunities despite credit constraints).12
A few notable exceptions aside (and in contrast to the vast literature on the other sources
of financial flows), the effects of remittances on political economy have been weakly
analyzed. Singer (2009) argues that remittances influence the choice of exchange rate
regimes in the developing world. By reducing the costs of forgone domestic monetary
policy autonomy, remittances increase the likelihood that policymakers will adopt fixed
exchange rates.
Remittances can also have considerable effects on macropolitical economy. For most poor
countries, foreign aid and natural resource rents have been the principal sources of
foreign exchange and financial inflows. These inflows invariably strengthened the apex
organs of the state and have led to intense competition among groups to capture the state
and hence the foreign rents accruing to it. In contrast, remittances accrue to households,
bypassing the state, and shift state-society relations in favor of the latter.13
Wood's (2000) analysis of democratic transition in El Salvador. The violence and political
instability in the 1980s led to a large outflux of uprooted peasants (especially to the
United States), and by 1991 remittances exceeded export earnings. The burgeoning
foreign exchange inflows resulted in “Dutch disease” effects, with the upward pressure
on the exchange rate undermining the competitiveness of Salvadoran agricultural
exports. This resulted in a shift of the economic interests of the country's landed
oligarchies from agriculture to services and in turn abated the severity of rural
Page 8 of 25
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). © Oxford University Press, 2018. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).
Skilled and entrepreneurial immigrants who have strong connections in both home and
host regions can be a powerful source of economic advantage (Saxenian, 2006) for the
country of origin.14 Case studies on the role of diasporas in jump-starting technology
industries have been done in India, Ireland, Israel, South Korea, Taiwan, and China.15
However, relatively little work has focused on the key trade-off: Are a poor country's
scarce skilled workers more valuable at home or abroad? Or, stated in terms of the stock-
flow model, is a member of the diaspora stock more or less valuable than a member of the
domestic stock? Desai et al. (2009) explore this trade-off by examining the fiscal cost of
moving from the domestic stock to the diaspora stock by looking at the net fiscal impact
of Indian emigration to the United States. Although the Indian-born in the United States
were roughly 0.1 percent of the domestic Indian population, their absence represented a
net fiscal cost to India equal to 0.5 percent of the Indian GDP, or roughly 2.5 percent of
total Indian fiscal revenues. Agrawal et al. (2008) develop a model in which innovation
depends on knowledge access, and knowledge access partly depends on membership in
networks. The authors allow for both colocation and diaspora networks. A necessary
condition for the movement of an innovator to the diaspora to increase knowledge access
of Indian innovators is that the diaspora knowledge-access effect be stronger than the
colocation effect.16 This could happen if emigration is associated with positive
productivity effects combined with continued strong ties with those remaining at home.
Agrawal et al. find, however, that the diaspora effect is actually considerably weaker than
the colocation effect. This suggests that emigration harms knowledge access; that is, the
diaspora effect does not make up for the effect of thinning local knowledge access.17
Finally, in ongoing work, Li and McHale (2009) explore the relative effects of domestic
and diaspora human capital on the quality of home-country institutions. Using an
instrumental variables approach, they find that diaspora human capital is more valuable
for measures of the quality of “political” institutions, based on the World Bank
governance indicators (political stability, voice, and accountability), but domestic human
capital is more valuable for “economic” institutions (government effectiveness, regulatory
quality, rule of law, and control of corruption). Putting the various pieces together, there
is no doubt that the diaspora can be a valuable resource for the home economy. However,
this does not necessarily mean that skilled emigration is good for the home economy.
Though the case studies are certainly (p. 140) suggestive of the value of a larger diaspora
under certain conditions, research on the broader diaspora/domestic trade-off is still in an
early stage.
Page 9 of 25
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). © Oxford University Press, 2018. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).
Central to the return effect is how time spent abroad affects productivity relative to time
spent at home. This in turn depends on where an individual spent time abroad and what
he or she did there, because (a) opportunities to acquire general capital (skills, savings,
and social connections) vary across countries; (b) opportunities to acquire home-country-
specific capital also vary across countries; and (c) simply spending time in developed
economies changes expectations and motivations that affect how individuals behave when
they return. Again, although there are many case studies of individuals returning and
having transformative effects on their home economies, systematic evidence is limited.
The picture that emerges from available studies is generally suggestive of a modest
positive impact of time spent abroad. Barrett and O'Connell (2001), for example,
demonstrate a 5 percent wage premium for returning Irish emigrants that is robust to
controls for selection effects. A number of studies have found a high propensity for
returnees to engage in entrepreneurship. For example, using data about Turkish
returnees from Germany, Dustmann and Kirchkamp (2002) report that a majority are
economically active, most engaged in entrepreneurship.18 Similarly, McCormick and
Wahba (2003) find a higher rate of “entrepreneurship” among return migrants to Egypt
than in the same sample prior to international migration.
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). © Oxford University Press, 2018. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).
in democratic countries (Spilimbergo 2009). In the early part of the twentieth century,
returning Chinese students who had studied in U.S. universities played important roles in
China (Ye 2001). In India, returning elites educated in England played a key role in laying
the foundations of a liberal democratic polity imbued with socialist ideas. Four decades
later, returning elites educated in economics in the United States reoriented India's
economic policies to be more pro-market (Kapur 2010).
The canonical analytical framework in this regard is Hirschman's classic Exit, Voice and
Loyalty, wherein he argued that the “willingness to develop and use the voice mechanism
is reduced by exit, but the ability to use it with effect is increased by it” (Hirschman 1970,
83). Later on Hirschman was less sanguine, worrying that emigration was depriving the
“geographic unit that is left behind … of many of its more activist residents, including
potential leaders, reformers or revolutionaries,” and “weaken[ing] [its] voice and thus
reduc[ing] the prospects for advance, reform, or revolution in the unit that is being
left” (Hirschman 1992, 90).
The prospect of exit has been seen as a restraint on rulers, who have to compete with
other jurisdictions for potentially mobile subjects (North 1981, 27). But global experience
suggests that this is valid only under restrictive conditions of voluntary migration and not
in the case of forced migration, whether the slave trade in Africa (see later discussion) or
ethnic cleansing (of which history records many sordid examples).
In Hirschman's formulation, exit and voice are exclusive binary choices that act as
substitutes. Absence can also have direct and important political effects by simply
creating political space for new groups. If elites leave—which often happens in the
aftermath of revolutions—the political space opens up for new elites, as has happened in
Cuba and Iran. Thus cross-national spatial mobility affects vertical (p. 142) political and
social mobility. It also affects domestic spatial mobility. External migration drives internal
migration, and in a multiethnic society, this has political economy ramifications at the
subnational level. Kapur (2010) finds that in today's world they can act as complements,
reinforcing rather than undermining each other. Exit, in the form of international
migration, is affecting voice through a variety of mechanisms.
Page 11 of 25
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). © Oxford University Press, 2018. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).
In Mexico the prospect of migration appears to have affected the political attitudes and
behavior of those left behind. Voter turnout rates are lower in high- migration
municipalities, and individuals in high-migration areas report lower levels of political
efficacy and participate less in politics than their counterparts in less migratory towns
(Goodman and Hiskey 2008).
A second mechanism is the exercise of voice across borders. Fox and Bada (2008) find
that migration from Mexico to the United States has increased public accountability.
Though migrants chose exit, they continue to express loyalty by exercising cross-border
pressures on local governments for accountability and a greater voice in their home
communities. This construction of a transnational public sphere is the result of migrants
organizing themselves politically in the destination country and using that experience to
effect political change in the country of origin.
A very different mechanism through which diasporas can affect the political economy of
the country of origin is their role in abetting conflict. Diasporas have long been known to
practice long-distance nationalism, ranging from civic nationalism to virulent ethnic
nationalism. Whereas the former ranges from lobbying the government of the adopted
country about foreign policy to sending funds during a natural calamity, the latter can
manifest itself in ethnic violence and civil wars in the country of origin. Collier and
Hoeffler (2000) find that, all other factors being equal, the risk of conflict starting after at
least five years of peace is six times greater in nations with the largest diasporas than in
those with the smallest. Moreover, “after peace has been restored, the legacy of conflict-
induced grievance enables rebel movements to restart conflict by drawing on the support
of their diasporas” (Collier and Hoeffler 2000, 2). Their relative importance in this arena
appears to have increased especially since the end of the Cold War. One survey of
insurgent movements covering seventy-four active insurgencies between 1991 and 2000
found that about a fourth received significant support from diasporas (Byman et. al.
2001). However, though diasporas appear to be an important factor in fueling domestic
conflict, their interaction with other factors continues to be disputed.
Diasporas can also affect the quality of governance in the country of origin through their
involvement in global criminal networks.20 Several factors underlie (p. 143) the growing
role of diasporas in international criminal activities. Much like any international industry,
many criminal networks rely on expatriated populations to facilitate their activities
abroad. As with any business, international criminal activity also requires enforcement
mechanisms and trust, and diasporic networks can more easily internalize these
mechanisms. Forced repatriation of felons (e.g., from the United States to Central
Page 12 of 25
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). © Oxford University Press, 2018. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).
Historical evidence of large-scale migration from Africa and Europe to the New World in
the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries and from China and India in the nineteenth
century provides insights into the long-term effects of international migration on sending
countries. In particular it highlights the importance of two neglected variables in the
impact of international migration on the sending country: the critical importance of why
people leave and where they go. Are they leaving voluntarily, or are they being pushed or
pulled out? Do they leave for political or economic reasons?
The great migrations from Europe to the New World (especially from 1870 to the
beginning of World War I) were largely for economic reasons and contributed to a
convergence of wages between origins and destinations, particularly between the
countries of Western Europe and the United States. Between 1870 and 1910 emigration
raised wages in Western Europe by 9 percent and lowered them by 8 percent in the
United States (Williamson and Hatton 2005).
In contrast, the large migrations out of Africa, as millions of Africans were carted off to
slavery, had a very different impact on that continent. Historians have argued that one
major consequence was to reduce the supply of labor. In contrast to Western Europe,
which had low land-to-labor ratios when migration began (one reason that it was
voluntary), Africa had a high land-to-labor ratio. Consequently, control over a factor that
became increasingly scarcer—labor—emerged as the key to power. Kings and village
headmen, bound to their followers by complicated networks of mutual obligation and
exchange, fell from dominance. External conflicts centered primarily on the various
struggles to exercise control over a people, and captives became the principal spoils of
war. The deep social disruption led to the increasing practice of holding slaves within
Africa's borders, thereby intensifying their exploitation and exemplifying what has come
to be known as the “transformation thesis.” The institutional effects were manifold.
Slaves were used by political elites to increase their power, which led to the development
of increasingly centralized and also more autocratic states. Household dynamics changed
as well. High-fertility regimes became institutionalized to ensure large families of
potential (p. 144) workers. Women married young and were valued by the number of
children they bore. The social status of men was similarly based on the number of wives
and children to whom they held claim (Inikori 1982; Iliffe 1995; Thornton 1998).
Page 13 of 25
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). © Oxford University Press, 2018. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).
Recently economists have begun examining this issue. Nunn's (2008) study of the impact
of forced migration—the slave trade—found significant negative long-term political and
economic effects for Africa. The parts of Africa from which the largest number of slaves
were taken are today the poorest parts of Africa, and this cannot be explained by
selection effects. The least-developed societies were not the ones selected into the slave
trade. Instead, the more-developed and more densely populated societies supplied the
largest numbers of slaves.
If the deep determinants of long-term economic growth are indeed domestic institutions,
then how does migration affect them? The combined evidence from Gennaioli and Rainer
(2007) and Nunn (2008) is consistent with a chain of causality wherein the slave trade
resulted in a deterioration of domestic political institutions, which in turn had a long-term
adverse impact on the provision of public goods. Nunn and Wantchekon (2009) examine
whether the transatlantic and Indian Ocean slave trades were responsible for a culture of
mistrust within Africa and find a very strong negative relationship between an
individual's reported trust in others and the number of slaves taken from that individual's
ethnic group during the slave trade period. The slave trade appears to have adversely
affected trust by both altering the cultural norms of the ethnic groups exposed to the
trade, making them inherently less trusting, and weakening legal and political
institutions, with the former channel having approximately twice the magnitude of the
latter.
The large income gains associated with poor-to-rich-country migration point to the
potential for significant reductions in world poverty. However, actual movements are
conditioned by an international migration architecture that is poorly designed to realize
this potential. The architecture is restrictive—too few poor-country residents have the
opportunity to emigrate; it is selective—what (p. 145) opportunities exist are heavily tilted
toward the highly skilled; it is rigid—the system is biased toward permanent flows and
against circulation; and it is (often) ambivalent—a near absence of legal access routes for
the less skilled sits uneasily with forbearance toward illegal residents.
Sending-Country Policies
Page 14 of 25
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). © Oxford University Press, 2018. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).
Although entry controls put in place by rich countries obviously play a key role, the
benefits of international migration for sending countries depend on a broader set of
policies. McHale (2008) provides a succinct summary of policy goals that matter in this
area:
Successful examples, such as the roles played by the Chinese, Indian, Israeli, and
Taiwanese diasporas in Silicon Valley in jump-starting home-country technology
industries—have led other governments to try to create programs to coordinate their
diasporas.21 Examples are Globalscot, ChileGlobal, and the South African Network for
Skills Abroad (SANSA). Although these coordination efforts have yielded successes, the
overall results have often been disappointing (Kuznetsov and Sabel 2006).22 Indeed,
successful diaspora networks seem to have been largely the result of voluntary and
decentralized interactions, with governments as subsidiary players in a supportive role
rather than as the main drivers (Newland and Patrick 2004).
Governments have played a more important role in developing policies and infrastructure
to reduce the high costs of engaging in financial transactions across borders. These
include increasing competition between institutions involved in international payments,
carefully considering the trade-offs in stricter security-driven regulation of cross-border
transactions, and supporting electronic payment systems (see World Bank 2006, ch. 6 for
a detailed treatment). Although programs such as the Mexican government's Tres Por
Uno (three for one) program have been breathlessly discussed, their impact has been
modest, with the amounts barely a few percent of total remittances to Mexico.23
Page 15 of 25
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). © Oxford University Press, 2018. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).
An interesting new policy shift has been an increase in dual citizenship laws, which grant
expatriates the right to naturalize in the receiving country without losing their nationality
of origin. Mazzolari (2009) examines the effects of dual citizenship on naturalization rates
and labor market outcomes in the United States and finds that it increases both the
propensity to naturalize as well as relative employment and earnings gains. This suggests
that for the country of origin, dual citizenship might be a mixed blessing. If dual
citizenship results in greater naturalization, which in turn leads to better economic
opportunities, this should help the country of origin as well. However, naturalization will
result in lower return rates, possibly denying these countries access to talent.
Conclusion
In contrast to research on international financial and trade flows, analytical work on the
third leg of globalization—international migration and its effects on sending countries—is
relatively recent. In analyzing the likely economic effects, this chapter attempts to
address a range of questions. Why should we expect diasporas to play a role that is
different or distinct from any other foreign investor? To paraphrase Deng Xiaoping in a
different context, does it matter if an investor is from the diaspora or not? And to the
extent that members of a diaspora do play a (p. 147) distinct role, in what areas or sectors
is their role likely to be greater? What characteristics of the migrants, the diaspora, and
the countries of origin and destination matter most for economic consequences?
This chapter suggests that the effects of international migration are much more complex
and sensitive to very precise selection effects on not just who leaves and who returns, or
how many and where, but why and how. But these are precisely the data that are most
difficult to get. Kapur (2010) argues that international migration poses a paradox:
although it is both a cause and consequence of globalization, its effects on the country of
Page 16 of 25
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). © Oxford University Press, 2018. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).
origin depend largely on factors internal to that country. Thus, understanding why people
leave in the first place may be the key to understanding migration's long-term effects.
References
Adams, Richard. 2005. “Remittances, Poverty and Investment in Guatemala.” In
International Migration, Remittances, and the Brain Drain, edited by Caglar Özden and
Maurice Schiff, 53–80. Washington, D.C.: World Bank.
Agrawal, Ajay, Devesh Kapur, John McHale, and Alexander Oettle. 2011. “Brain Drain or
Brain Bank? The Impact of Skilled Emigration on Poor-Country Innovation.” Journal of
Urban Economics 69, no. 1: 43–55, http://ideas.repec.org/s/eee/juecon.html.
Arora, Ashish, and Alfonso Gambardella. 2005. From Underdogs to Tigers: The Rise of
Growth of the Software Industry in Brazil, China, India, Ireland, and Israel. Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Barrett, Alan, and Philip O'Connell. 2001. “Is There a Wage Premium for Returning Irish
Migrants.” Economic and Social Review 32: 1–21.
Beine, Michel, Frederic Docquier, and Hillel Rapoport. 2001. “Brain Drain and Economic
Growth: Theory and Evidence.” Journal of Development Economics 64, no. 1: 275–289.
Beine, Michael, Frederic Docquier, and Hillel Rapoport. 2008. “Brain Drain and Human
Capital Formation in Developing Countries: Winners and Losers.” Economic Journal 118:
631–652.
Borjas, George, and Bernt Bratsberg. 1996. “Who Leaves? The Outmigration of the
Foreign-born. Review of Economics and Statistics (February): 165–176.
Boucher, Steve, Oded Stark, and J. Edward Taylor. 2005. “A Gain with a Drain? Evidence
from Rural Mexico on the New Economics of the Brain Drain.” Working Paper No. 05–
005, Department of Agriculture and Resource Economics, University of California, Davis.
Byman, Daniel, Peter Chalk, Bruce Hoffman, William Rosenau, and David Brannan. 2001.
Trends in Outside Support for Insurgent Movements. Santa Monica, Calif.: Rand.
Chand, Satish, and Michael Clemens. 2008. “Skilled Emigration and Skill Creation: A
Quasi-Experiment.” Working Paper No. 152, Center for Global Development, September.
Chaudhry, Kiren, A. 1989. “The Price of Wealth: Business and State in Labor Remittances
and Oil Economies.” International Organization 43, no. 1: 101–145.
Page 17 of 25
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). © Oxford University Press, 2018. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).
Clarke, George, and Scott Wallsten. 2004. “Do Remittances Protect Households in
Developing Countries Against Shocks? Evidence from a Natural Disaster in Jamaica.”
Photocopy, The World Bank, November.
Clemens, Michael, Claudio Montenegro, and Lant Pritchett. 2008. “The Place Premium:
Wage Differences for Identical Workers Across the US Border.” Working Paper No. 148,
Center for Global Development, July.
Clemens, Michael, and Lant Pritchett. 2008. “Income Per Natural: Measuring
Development as If People Mattered More Than Places.” Working Paper No. 143, Center
for Global Development, March.
Collier, Paul, and Anke Hoeffler. 2000. “Greed and Grievance in Civil War.” Policy
Research Working Paper No. 2355, World Bank.
Commander, Simon, Mari Kangasmiemi, and L. Alan Winters. 2004. “The Brain Drain:
Curse of Boon? A Survey of the Literature.” In Challenges to Globalization: Analyzing the
Economics, edited by R. E. Baldwin and L. Alan Winters, 235–278. Chicago: University of
Chicago Press.
Commission on Migration Data for Development Research. 2009. Migrants Count: Five
Steps Towards Better Migration Data. Washington, D.C.: Center for Global Development.
Desai, Mihir, Devesh Kapur, John McHale, and Keith Rogers. 2009. “The Fiscal
(p. 150)
Dustmann, Christian. 2002. “The Optimal Migration Duration and Activity Choice After
Re-Migration.” Journal of Development Economics 67: 351–372.
Fox, Jonathan, and Xochitl Bada. 2008. “Migrant Organization and Hometown Impacts in
Rural Mexico.” Journal of Agrarian Change 8, nos. 2 and 3: 435–461.
Goodman, Gary, and Jonathan Hiskey. 2008. “Exit Without Leaving: Political
Disengagement in High Migration Municipalities in Mexico.” Comparative Politics 40, no.
2: 169–188.
Page 18 of 25
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). © Oxford University Press, 2018. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).
Gould, David M. 1994. “Immigrant Links to the Home Country: Empirical Implications for
U.S. Bilateral Trade Flows.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 76, no. 2: 302–316.
Grogger, Jeff, and Gordon Hanson. 2008. “Income Maximization and the Selection and
Sorting of International Migrants.” Working Paper WP13821, National Bureau of
Economic Research.
Head, K., and J. Reis. 1998. “Immigration and Trade Creation: Econometric Evidence
from Canada.” Canadian Journal of Economics 31 (February): 47–62.
Hildebrandt, Nicole, and David McKenzie. 2005. “The Effects of Migration on Child
Health in Mexico.” Policy Research Working Paper 3573, The World Bank.
Hirschman, Albert. 1970. Exit, Voice and Loyalty: Responses to Decline in Firms’
Organizations, and States. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Hirschman, Albert. 1992. Rival Views of Market Society and Other Recent Essays.
Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Husted, Leif, Helena S. Nielson, Michael Rosholm, and Nana Smith. 2000. “Employment
and Wage Assimilation of Male First Generation Immigrants in Denmark.” IZA Working
Paper 101, Institute of the Study of Labor (IZA), Bonn, Germany.
Iliffe, John. 1995. Africans: The History of a Continent. Cambridge, Mass.: Cambridge
University Press.
Inikori, J. E. 1982. Forced Migration: The Impact of the Export Slave Trade on African
Societies. London: Hutchinson.
Kapur, Devesh. 2010. Diaspora, Democracy and Development: The Impact of International
Migration from India on India. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.
Kapur, Devesh, and John McHale. 2005a. Give Us Your Best and Brightest: The Global
Hunt for Talent and Its Impact on the Developing World. Washington, D.C.: The Brookings
Institution Press/Center for Global Development.
Kapur, Devesh, and John McHale. 2005b. “Sojourns and Software: Internationally Mobile
Human Capital and High Tech Industry Development in India, Ireland and Israel.” In
Underdogs to Tigers: The Rise and Growth of the Software Industry in Some Emerging
Economies, edited by Ashish Arora and Alfonso Gambardella, 236–274. New York: Oxford
University Press.
Kapur, Devesh, and John McHale. 2009. “International Migration and the World
(p. 151)
Page 19 of 25
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). © Oxford University Press, 2018. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).
Kuznetsov, Yevgeny, and Charles Sabel. 2006. “International Migration of Talent, Diaspora
Networks, and Development: Overview of Main Issues.” In Diaspora Networks and the
International Migration of Skills: How Countries Can Draw on Their Talent Abroad, edited
by Yevgeny Kuznetsov, 3–20. Washington, D.C.: The World Bank.
Lewis, Arthur. 1984. The Evolution of the International Economic Order. Princeton, N.J.:
Princeton University Press.
Li, Xiaoyang, and John McHale. 2009. “Emigrants and Institutions.” Working Paper,
National University of Ireland, Galway.
Mazzolari, Francesca. 2009. “Dual Citizenship Rights: Do They Make More and Richer
Citizens?” Demography 46, no. 1: 169–191.
McCormick, Barry, and Jackline Wahba. 2003. “Return Migration and Geographical
Inequality: The Case of Egypt.” Journal of African Economies 12, no. 4: 500–532.
McHale, John. 2008. “The International Migration Architecture: A Survey with Lessons
for the MENA Region.” Unpublished World Bank background paper.
McHale, John. 2009. “Taxation and Skilled Indian Migration to the United States:
Revisiting the Bhagwati Tax.” In Skilled Immigration Today: Prospects, Problems and
Policies, edited by Jagdish Bhagwati and Gordon Hanson, 362–386. New York: Oxford
University Press.
Newland, Kathleen, and Erin Patrick. 2004. Beyond Remittances: The Role of the
Diaspora in Poverty Reduction in Their Countries of Origin. Washington, D.C.: Migration
Policy Institute.
North, Douglas. 1981. Structure and Change in Economic History. New York: W.W.
Norton.
Nunn, N. 2008. “The Long-term Effects of Africa's Slave Trades.” Quarterly Journal of
Economics 123: 139–176.
Nunn, N., and L. Wantchekon. 2009. “The Slave Trade and the Origins of Mistrust in
Africa.” Working Paper WP14783, National Bureau of Economic Research.
Page 20 of 25
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). © Oxford University Press, 2018. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).
O'Rourke, H. Kevin, and Jeffrey G. Williamson. 1999. “The Heckscher Ohlin Model
Between 1400 and 2000: When It Explained Factor Price Convergence, When It Did Not,
and Why.” Working Paper WP7411, National Bureau of Economic Research.
Piore, Michael J. 1979. Birds of Passage: Migrant Labor and Industrial Societies.
Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
Schiff, Maurice. 2005. “Brain Gain: Claims about Its Size and Impact on Welfare Are
Greatly Exaggerated.” In International Migration, Remittances, and the Brain Drain,
edited by Caglar Özden and Maurice Schiff, 201–225. Washington D.C.: The World Bank
and Palgrave Macmillan.
Singer, David. 2010. “Migrant Remittances and Exchange Rate Regimes in the
Developing World.” American Political Science Review 104, no. 2: 307–323.
Stark, Oded, Christian Helmenstein, and Alexia Prskawetz. 1997. “A Brain Gain with a
Brain Drain.” Economics Letters 55, no. 2: 227–234.
Taylor, J. Edward, and T. J. Wyatt. 1996. “The Shadow Value of Migrant Remittances,
Income and Inequality in a Household-Farm Economy.” The Journal of Development
Studies 32, no. 6: 899–912.
Thaler, Richard. 1990. “Anomalies: Saving, Fungibility, and Mental Accounts.” The Journal
of Economic Perspectives 4, no. 1: 193–205.
Thornton, John. 1998. Africa and Africans in the Making of the Atlantic World, 1400–1800.
Cambridge, Mass.: Cambridge University Press.
Williamson Jeffrey G., and Timothy J. Hatton. 2005 Global Migration and the World
Economy: Two Centuries of Policy and Performance. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.
Wood, Elisabeth Jean. 2000. Forging Democracy from Below: Insurgent Transitions in
South Africa and El Salvador. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
Page 21 of 25
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). © Oxford University Press, 2018. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).
Yang, Dean. 2008a. “Coping with Disaster: The Impact of Hurricanes on International
Financial Flows, 1970–2002.” The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy 8, no. 1:
article 13.
Yang, Dean, and Claudia Martinez. 2005. “Remittances and Poverty in Migrant's Home
Areas: Evidence from the Philippines.” In International Migration, Remittances, and the
Brain Drain, edited by Caglar Özden and Maurice Schiff, 81–121. Washington, D.C.: The
World Bank and Palgrave Macmillan.
Yang, Dean, and Hwa Jung Choi. 2007. “Are Remittances Insurance? Evidence from
Rainfall Shocks in the Philippines.” The World Bank Economic Review 21, no. 2: 219–248.
Ye, Weili. 2001 Seeking Modernity in China's Name: Chinese Students in the United
States, 1900–1927. Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 2001.
Notes:
(2) See, for example, the report prepared by the Commission on Migration Data for
Development Research, Migrants Count: Five Steps Towards Better Migration Data
(Washington, D.C.: Center for Global Development, 2009).
(3) Clemens and Pritchett (2008) use U.S. census data to estimate average income gains
for immigrants to the United States from various countries. They then use bilateral data
on U.S.-sending country pairs to estimate a prediction model for income gains. This model
is then used to estimate the income gains from migration from any sending country to all
receiving countries. What Clemens and Pritchett actually report are estimates of the
difference in income per capita and income per natural (see n. 4).
Page 22 of 25
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). © Oxford University Press, 2018. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).
(5) Moreover, much of the emigration we do observe does not lead to large income gains:
rich-to-rich movements, poor-to-poor movements, and (less often) rich-to-poor
movements.
(6) See Commander et al. (2004) and Schiff (2005) for critical reviews of the brain gain
hypothesis.
(7) Gould (1994) and Head and Ries (1998) use a gravity equation framework to show
that larger diasporas are associated with greater trade.
(9) See Ozden and Schiff (2005) for excellent critical surveys.
(12) On remittances as insurance, see Clarke and Wallsten (2004), Yang and Choi (2007),
and Yang (2008a).
(13) Kiren Chaudhry (1989) examined the contrasting effects of these two types of
external capital in the Middle East and found that financial inflows into Yemen in the form
of labor remittances initially weakened the Yemeni state by bypassing both state
institutions and the formal banking system and going directly to millions of Yemeni
migrants. On the other hand, oil rents strengthened the Saudi state by creating a huge,
financially autonomous distributive bureaucracy. Thus, the different sources and channels
of external financial inflows differentially affected state-society relations.
(14) Annalee Saxenian (2006, 5) terms them “the new Argonauts” (after the Greeks who
sailed with Jason seeking the Golden Fleece).
(16) These effects are empirically identified using patent citation data. Members of the
Indian diaspora are in turn identified using an Indian name database.
(17) An additional finding gives us pause, however: the diaspora effect increases in
importance with the value of the resulting innovation (as proxied by subsequent citations
to the patent). Thus diaspora relationships may be critical for the most valuable
innovations.
(18) Ammassari (2003) reports on interviews with “highly skilled elite” emigrants and
returnees from Côte d'Ivoire and Ghana. An interesting finding is that whereas the older
cohorts of emigrants were more concerned with nation-building tasks, more recent
cohorts are likely to make their impacts through entrepreneurship. She also documents
particular examples in which returnees were instrumental in introducing new work
practices, technologies, and investment. On the negative side, access to capital and
Page 23 of 25
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). © Oxford University Press, 2018. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).
(19) See, e.g., chapter 5 in Kapur (2010), on the role transformational returnees to India.
(21) See, e.g., McHale and Kapur (2005b) and Saxenian (2006).
(23) The key feature of the program is that different levels of government match the
collective remittances of Hometown Associations (HTAs), with the HTA remittance being
matched by the federal government, the state government, and the municipal government
—hence the three-for-one name.
(24) The OECD (2008, 201–202) provides additional examples of sending-country policies
to encourage return. The countries noted include Jamaica, the Philippines, Argentina,
Colombia, Tunisia, and China.
Devesh Kapur
Devesh Kapur is Madan Lal Sobti Associate Professor of Contemporary India and
Director, Center for Advanced Study of India, University of Pennsylvania.
John McHale
Page 24 of 25
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). © Oxford University Press, 2018. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).
Page 25 of 25
PRINTED FROM OXFORD HANDBOOKS ONLINE (www.oxfordhandbooks.com). © Oxford University Press, 2018. All Rights
Reserved. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a PDF of a single chapter of a title in
Oxford Handbooks Online for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).