Aec 5121
Aec 5121
Resource Economics
By
2019
Ideal International E – PublicationPvt. Ltd.
www.isca.co.in
427, Palhar Nagar, RAPTC, VIP-Road, Indore-452005 (MP) INDIA
Phone: +91-731-2616100, Mobile: +91-80570-83382
E-mail: [email protected], Website:www.isca.co.in
© Copyright Reserved
2019
All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored, in a
retrieval system or transmitted, in any form or by any means, electronic,
mechanical, photocopying, reordering or otherwise, without the prior permission
of the publisher.
ISBN: 978-93-86675-79-8
Farm Management, Production and Resource Economics iii
Preface
This book provides a detailed knowledge about the farm management and its
importance in farming community. The basis for farm management aspects will be
understood for the under graduate students. The concepts of production economics covers a
wide range of understanding in a simplest way.
Finally, I hope that this book will bring a basic concept clarity in the areas of Farm
Management Production and Natural Resource Economics.
Agricultural Economics
As a separate discipline, agricultural economics started only in the beginning of
th
20 century when economic issues pertaining to agriculture aroused interest at several
educational centres. The depression of 1890s that wrecked havoc in agriculture at many
places forced organized farmers groups to take keen interest in farm management
problems. The study and teaching of agricultural economics was started at Harvard
University (USA) in 1903 by Professor Thomas Nixon Carver. Agricultural economics
may be defined as the application of principles and methods of economics to study the
problems of agriculture to get maximum output and profits from the use of resources that
are limited for the well being of the society in general and farming industry in particular.
Agriculture sector has undergone a sea change over time from being subsistence
in nature in early stages to the present day online high-tech agribusiness. It is no more
confined to production at the farm level. The storage, processing and distribution of
agricultural products involve an array of agribusiness industries. Initially, agricultural
economics studied the cost and returns for farm enterprises and emphasized the study of
management problems on farms. But now it encompasses a host of activities related to
farm management, agricultural marketing, agricultural finance and accounting,
agricultural trade and laws, contract farming, etc.
of abstract logic of economics with the practical management problems of modern day
agriculture.
Objectives
1. To determine and outline the conditions that give the optimum use of capital,
labour, land and management resources in the production of crops, livestock and
allied enterprises.
2. To determine the extent to which the existing use of resources deviates from the
optimum use.
3. To analyse the forces which condition the existing production pattern and
resource use.
4. To explain the means and methods in getting from the existing use to optimum
use of resources.
1. Production: The process through which some goods and services called inputs are
transformed into other goods called products or output.
2. Production function: A systematic and mathematical expression of the
relationship among various quantities of inputs or input services used in the
production of a commodity and the corresponding quantities of output is called a
production function.
3. Continuous production function: This function arises for those inputs which can
be divided into smaller doses. Continuous variables can be known from
measurement, for example, seeds and fertilizers, etc.
4. Discontinuous or discrete production function: This function arises for those
inputs or work units which cannot be divided into smaller units and hence are
used in whole numbers. For example, number of ploughings, weedings and
harvestings, etc.
5. Short run production period: The planning period during which one or more of
the resources are fixed while others are variable resources. The output can be
varied only by intensive use of fixed resources. It is written as
Y=f (X1, X2 / X3…..Xn) where Y is output, X1, X2 are variable
inputs and X3…..Xn are fixed inputs.
6. Long run production period: The planning period during which all the resources
can be varied. It is written as Y=f
(X1, X2 ,…..Xn)
7. Technical coefficient: The amount of input per unit of output is called technical
coefficient.
8. Resources: Anything that aids in production is called a resource. The resources
physically enter the production process.
9. Resource services: The work done by a person, machine or livestock is called a
resource service. Resources do not enter the production process physically.
10. Fixed resources: The resources that remain unchanged irrespective of the level of
production are called fixed resources. For example, land , building, machinery.
These resources exist only in short run. The costs associated with these resources
are called fixed costs.
11. Variable resources: The resources that vary with the level of production are called
variable resources. These resources exist both in short run and long run. For
example, seeds, fertilizers, chemicals, etc. The costs associated with these
resources are called variable costs.
12. Flow resources: The resources that cannot be stored and should be used as and
when these are available. For example, services of a labourer on a particular day.
13. Stock resources: The resources that can be stored for use later on. For example,
seeds. Defining an input as a flow or stock depends on the length of time under
consideration. For example, tractor with 10 years life is a stock resources if we
take the services of tractor for its entire useful life of 10 years. But it also
provides its service every day, therefore it is a flow resources.
14. Production period: It is the time period required for the transformation of
resources or inputs into products.
15. Farm entrepreneur: Farm entrepreneur is the person who organizes and operates
the farm business and bears the responsibility of the outcome of the business.
16. Farm business manager: Person appointed by the entrepreneur to manage and
supervise the farm business and is paid for the services rendered. He/she carries
out the instructions of the entrepreneur.
17. Productivity: Output per unit of inputs is called the productivity.
18. Technical efficiency: It is the ratio of the physical output to inputs used. It
implies the using of resources as effectively as possible without any wastages.
19. Economic efficiency: It is the expression of technical efficiency in monetary
terms through the prices. In other words, the ratio of value of output to value of
inputs is termed as economic efficiency. It implies maximization of profits per
unit of input.
Definitions
Farm management is defined as the science that deals with organization and operation of
the farm in the context of efficiency and continuous profits (J.N. Efferson).
Farm management is defined as the science of organization and management of the farm
enterprises for the purpose of securing greatest continuous profits (G.F. Warren).
Farm management is defined as the art of managing a farm successfully as measured by
the test of profitableness (Gray).
Farm management is defined as the art of applying business and scientific principles to
the organization and operation of the farm (Andrew Boss).
Farm management is the decision-making process whereby limited resources are
allocated to a number of production alternatives to organize and operate the business in
such a way to attain some objectives (Ronald D. Kay).
Farm management is a branch of agricultural economics, which deals with wealth earning
and wealth spending activities of farmer in relation to the organization and operation of
the individual farm unit for securing the maximum possible net income (Bradford and
Johnson).
Farm management, as the sub-division of economics, which considers the allocation of
limited resources within the individual farm, is a science of choice and decision-making
and thus a field requiring studied judgment (Heady and Jensen).
Thus in simple words, farm management can be defined as a science which deals with
judicious decisions on the use of scarce farm resources, having alternative uses to obtain the
maximum profit and family satisfaction on a continuous basis from the farm as a whole and
under sound farming programmes. In other words, farm management seeks to help the farmer
in deciding problems like what to produce, how much to produce, how to produce and when to
buy and sell and in organization and managerial problems relating to these decisions.
It covers aspects of farm business which have a bearing on the economic efficiency of the farm.
thus, the types of enterprises to be combined, the kind of crops and varieties to be grown, the
dosage of fertilizers to be applied, the implements to be used, the way the farm functions are to
be performed, all these fall within the purview of the subject of farm management. The subject of
farm management includes; farm management research, training and extension.
Following are the differences between agricultural production economics and farm management.
These decisions involve heavy investment and are made less frequently. The effect of
these decisions is long lasting. These decisions cannot be altered. However, in the case of
reversal of these decisions farmer has to incur high cost. These decisions are also known as basic
decisions. Size of the farm, machinery and labour programme, construction of farm buildings,
permanent improvements on the farm like development of irrigation facilities, soil conservation,
reclamation, etc. are some of the examples of strategic management decisions.
a) Size of the farm
This decision assumes greater relevance to the farmer because of slow and low rate of
capital turnover, but it is very difficult to decide on the most appropriate size of the farm to be
operated, as it is influenced by several factors viz., availability of financial resources, state laws,
managerial abilities, climate, type of farming, etc. There are advantages and limitations in
operating the farm business on different scales. Large farms enjoy low cost of production,
whereas productivity is high on small farms. The advantages and disadvantages of operating
enterprises on different scales must be ascertained, while making decision on the size of the
farm.
measures of soil conservation. Chemical and cultural practices are adapted for soil reclamation.
The farmer should choose most appropriate and economical method of conservation and
reclamation programmes.
a) Financing the farm business: Majority of the Indian farmers are capital starved, hence they
have to depend on borrowed capital. For borrowing, the farmer has to examine the decisions like
from whom to borrow, when to borrow and how much to borrow.
b) Supervision: To get the desired results on the farm, farmers should keep a close watch on all
the activities performed in the production of crop and livestock enterprises.
c) Accounting: Farmer should make a decision about the time and money to be allocated for the
maintenance of farm records. Farm records provide control over the farm business.
d) Adjusting the farm production programme: The decision of allocating farm resources in
the production of farm products should be consistent with the price policies of the government.
The government as a welfare state exercises its control over production and marketing of farm
commodities according to the situation.
a) Buying: Every farmer makes an attempt to purchase necessary inputs at the least cost. In
buying resources, a farmer has to decide the agency, the timing and the quantity to be purchased.
b) Selling: Though farm product prices are not under the control of the farmers, yet by adjusting
the timing of sales, farmers can obtain better prices. What to sell, where to sell, whom to sell,
when to sell and how to sell are the important selling decisions that are to be made by the farmer.
Buying
What to buy
Marketing When to buy
Problem From whom to buy
Decisions How to buy
What to sell
When to sell
Selling Where to sell
How to sell
Fixed cost (FC): Fixed costs are those costs which do not change in magnitude as the amount of
output produced changes and are incurred even when production is not undertaken. These are
also called sunk costs. These could be fixed cash costs such as land taxes, interest, insurance
premiums, permanently hired labour, etc. Non-cash fixed costs include depreciation on
buildings, machinery interest on capital investment, cost of family labour & management, etc.
Variable costs (VC): The costs that are incurred on variable inputs and hence vary with the level
of production are called variable costs. Higher the production more will be VC and vice-versa.
Expenses on fertilizer, seed, chemical fuel consumption, etc.
NR = TR-TC
Opportunity cost: Farm resources are limited but these can be put to different uses. When these
are used in our product, some alternative usage is always forgone. The opportunity cost is the
value of best alternative forgone.
Cost Function: Cost function (or TC curves) represents the functional relationship between
output and total cost. That is what happens to cost structure when different quantities of a
commodity are produced. The cost function can be represented by (i) arithmetically (tabular
form), (ii) Geometrically or (iii) Algebraically. Exact nature (curvature) of cost function depends
on the corresponding production function provided the prices for inputs do not change with the
quality of inputs purchased.
y
TP
30 TP1
25
20
15
10
O
5 10 15 20 25 X
TC
TVC
t
s
o
C
TFC
Output
1. Total fixed cost (TFC): The costs incurred on all fixed inputs used in production are known
as TFC. These do not change with the output levels & hence represented by a straight line
parallel to X axis.
2. Total variable cost (TVC): Refers to the costs of variable input used in production &
is computed by multiplying the amount of variable input by the price/ unit of input.
TVC = Px·X
3. Total cost (TC): TC are the sum of TVC & TFC and are obtained by adding TVC & TFC for
different output levels. When no variable input in used (TVC=0) TC = TFC. Shape of TVC &
TC are same & depend upon the production function.
ATC
AVC MC
Cost
AFC
Output
4. Average fixed cost (AFC): It is the fixed cost per unit of output & is computed by dividing
TFC by the amount of output at that particular level of output. AFC varies for each level of
output and as the output increases, AFC decreases. When output is zero, AFC = TFC. AFC
always slopes downward regardless of production function. AFC curve declines continuously &
never shows upward movement because after maximum product is achieved, input use beyond
this becomes irrational.
AVC varies with the levels of production & its shape depends on production function. The
height of AVC depends upon the unit cost of the variable input. Like AFC, AVC cannot be
computed when output is zero. AVC is inversely related to APP. AVC falls first due to
economies of large scale production & then rises due to diseconomies of scale in production.
AVC (like APP) measures the efficiency of variable input: when AVC is decreasing, efficiency
of variable input is increasing; it is at maximum when AVC is at minimum & it is decreasing
when AVC is increasing. As the production expands, the AVC declines initially, reaches a
lowest point & then bends upwards.
TC
6. Average Total Cost (ATC) = Y or AFC +AVC; shape of ATC depends upon shape of
production function. ATC decreases as output increases, attains a minimum and increases
thereafter. ATC is often referred to as ‘unit cost’ of production – the cost of producing the unit of
output. The initial decrease in ATC is caused by the spreading of FC among an increasing
number of units of output and the increasing efficiency with which the variable input is used. As
output increases further, ATC attains a minimum & begins to increase, as increase in AVC can
no longer be offset by decrease in AFC. ATC curve has the same slope as AVC. Difference is
that the lowest point in case of AVC reaches earlier as compared to ATC.
7. Marginal Cost (MC): May be defined as the change in TC in response to a unit change in
TC
output. That is it is the cost of producing an additional unit of output & is given by .Y
Actually a change in TC is always equal to change in VC at a given level of FC. So MC must be
worked out by dividing the change in VC by the change in output.
1. Cost Principle
TC = VC+ FC
(A) In the short run: Gross revenue (GR) must cover the VC. Maximum net revenue is
obtained when MC = MR. If GR < TC but > VC, guiding principle should be to keep
increasing production as long as MR > MC.
In the short run, MC = MR point may be at a level of input use that may involve a loss
instead of profit. Yet at this point loss will be minimized. This situation of operating the
farms when MR is > AVC but < ATC is common in agriculture. This explains why
farmers keep on doing farming even when they run into losses.
(B) In the long Run: GR should be > VC + FC=TC. For taking production decision in such a
situation, one should go on using resources as long as added returns remain greater than
added total costs. Here, the object is to maximize profits instead of minimizing the losses.
2. Law of Equi- Marginal Returns (Special case of substitution)
When resources are unlimited, farmer can produce all products under the rule,
But resources are limited, expansion of one enterprise requires contraction of other. The big
question is which enterprise combination will give the greatest income? Such an optimum choice
of enterprises is made based on the principle of equi-marginal return or the opportunity cost
principle. Profit will be the greatest if each unit of labour, capital and land is used where it adds
the most to the returns. In other words, this principle lays down: the best combination of
enterprises or practices will be where limited resources are allocated in a manner that one cannot
change the use of a simple unit without reducing the income. Thus, the resources should be used
where they give not the highest average returns but the greatest marginal returns. Thus, the best
combination of enterprises is obtained not when we select profitable crops but most profitable
crops. The profitability of an enterprise depends on the price of the product, the direct costs
attached to it & the amount of product sacrificed as one enterprise gets replaced with other.
Budgeting & programming techniques take this principle into account for working out an
optimum plan.
Example: A farmer has Rs 5000 to invest on crops, dairy or poultry. What amount of capital he
should invest on each enterprise to get highest profit?
would have been used for other next best purpose. Thus, it is the cost equivalent to the returns
from next best alternative forgone.
There are two types of investments: (1) Investments on operating inputs & (2) Investment on
capital assets (land, farm building, machinery, equipment, etc). Analysis of these investments
involves not only the comparison of costs and returns associated with it, but also the timings of
occurrence of costs & returns. The costs & returns from investments in operating resources occur
with a production period of a year or less. The marginal principles are used to determine the
optimum level of operating resources & there is no need to bring in time element here. But in
case of capital assets where the costs & returns are in different time periods and also capital
expenditure involves costs & returns over time (orchards). Some expenditure may be recurring &
some non- recurring. To examine the profitability of these investments it requires the recognition
of time value of money. Money has time value for the following reasons.
(1) Earning power of money: represented by opportunity cost of money (rate of interest )
(2) Inflation – purchasing power of money varies inversely with the price level. A rupee
earned a year from now is less valuable than a rupee earned today.
(3) Uncertainty: Investment deals with future & future is uncertain. Investments are made
with the expectation of receiving a stream of benefits in the future.
Thus, farm management involves dynamic adjustments in the organization & operation of
farm business by taking into account (a) time element in the valuation of present value of future
incomes by discounting future returns.
For discounting one needs to know the future & the capital position of the farmer. This
implies the exact future income / cost should be known. Capital position of the farmer affects the
interest rate to be used for discounting and the (b) risks & uncertainties in farm operations over
time (natural calamities, price fluctuations, technical changes). Two aspects of the problem are
considered under such situations: (a) Growth of a cash outlay over time i.e. compounding & (b)
Discounting of future incomes.
(1) Compounding: Compounding is the procedure to find the future value of a present sum,
given the earning power (interest rate) of money & the frequency of compounding. e.g.
Rs 100 @ 10% interest rate after 4 years.
st nd rd
1 year – 100+10 =110; 2 – 110@10% = 110+11=121; 3 year- 121@10@ = 121+12.10 =
n 4
S = P (1+i) = 100 (1+0.10) =100*1.4464=146.4
(2) Discounting: is the procedure where the present value of the future income is determined.
P
PV ; P is the amount to be received in future, PV is the present value e.g. Rs 5000 to
(1 i)n
be received after 3 years i =10%
For unlimited capital use market rate of interest. And for limited capital use the r that
capital may fetch for the farmer. Law of diminishing returns applies to agriculture in general but
its operation can be postponed under the following conditions: (i) Improved technology (2) New
soils & (3) Scarcity of Capital (as on stage I) – all lead to the produce of increasing returns.
8. The exact nature of any production function is assumed to be determined by a set of technical
decisions taken by the producer.
ii) Quadratic PF: Also known as second degree polynomial. This type of PF allows both
declining & negative marginal productivity thus embracing the second and third stage of
production simultaneously.
2
y b0 b1x1 b2 x1 where b0, b1 , & b2, are the parameters. Such PFs are quite common in
fertilizer response studies.
iii) Cobb-Douglas PF: It is also known as power production function. It is most widely used PF.
It accounts for only our stage of production at a time & cannot represent constant, increasing or
decreasing marginal productivity simultaneously.
b
Y = b0 x 1 1 where b0 is efficiency parameters & b1 is elasticity of production
iv) Mitscherlich or Spillman function
v) Transcendental function
vi) Translog PF
ix) Square root PF: It represents a compromise between C-D & the quadratic PF.
y a0 a1 x a2x
This function gets rid of the limitations of field mix of inputs for producing different levels of
output inherent in the C-D production function & that of linear isoclines in quadratic function.
Thus, this function allows both a diminishing TP in the same way as QF does & for declining
MPs at a diminishing rate as the C-D function does.
1. Law of constant marginal returns (productivity): It is said to operate when each marginal
unit of variable input adds equal quantity of output to the total output. It is applicable over
limited range, e.g. one tractor (plus driver) will almost give same output, other things remaining
constant.
2. Law of increasing marginal returns (productivity): It is said to operate when each marginal
unit of variable input adds more and more quantity of output to the total output. It is not common
in agriculture, e.g. small increase in seed input given the fixed inputs.
Factor-Product Relationship
Determination of Optimum Input and Output
The law of diminishing returns describes the relationship between output and the variable
input when other inputs are held constant.
Definition: If increasing amounts of one input are added to a production process while all other
inputs are held constant, the amount of output added per unit of variable input will eventually
decrease. It is also known as law of diminishing productivity or the law of variable proportions.
Application of the law of diminishing returns to the production concept can result in a production
function of classical type. It displays increasing marginal returns first and then decreasing
marginal returns.
Ep 1
Y
Ep 0
Ep 1
TPP
Inflection
point
I II III
Input Congestion
APP
0 MPP X
Input
The classical production function can be divided into three regions or stages, each being
important from the standpoint of efficient resources use.
Stage-I occurs when marginal physical product (MPP) > average physical product (APP). APP
is increasing throughout this stage, indicating that the average rate at which X is transformed into
Y, increases until APP reaches its maximum at the end of Stage-I.
Stage-II occurs when MPP is decreasing and is less than APP but greater than zero. The physical
efficiency of the variable input reaches a peak at the beginning of Stage–II. On the other hand
physical efficiency of fixed input is greatest at the end of Stage-II. This is because the number of
fixed input is constant and therefore the output/ unit of fixed input must be the largest when the
total output from the production process is maximum.
Stage-III occurs when MPP is negative. Stage III occurs when excessive quantities of variable
input are combined with the fixed input, so much, that total physical product (TPP) begins to
decrease.
1. If the product has any value at all, input use once begun, should be continued until Stage
–II is reached. That is because physical efficiency of variable resources, measured by
APP, increases throughout stage –I.
2. Even if input is free, it will not be used in stage III. Maximum output occurs when Stage
II closes. It is of no use applying variable input when TPP starts coming down.
3. Stage II defines the area of economic relevance. Variable input use must be
somewhere in stage-II, but exact input amount can be determined when choice
indicators (input & output prices) are known.
1. When MPP is increasing, APP is also increasing. So long as MPP is above APP, the
APP keeps increasing.
2. When MPP curve goes below APP curve, APP starts declining, that is, when AP is
decreasing the MP is always less than APP.
MP < AP AP↓
MP = AP AP is at maximum.
Elasticity of production: The elasticity of production is a concept that measures the degree of
responsiveness between output and input. It is independent of the units of measurement.
% change in output
Ep
% change in input
Y/Y Y/ X MPP
Ep
X/X Y/X APP
Ep > 1 in Stage I
0 Ep 1 stage II
is based on exact MPPs
Ep is negative stage III
The point of diminishing returns can be defined to occur when MPP =APP that is Ep= 1
(lower boundary of stage II) & this is the minimum amount of variable input that will be used
& it occurs when the efficiency of variable input is at its maximum. At the other end, MPP is
zero, therefore Ep= 0. Thus the relevant production zone is when O ≤ Ep ≤ 1.
Isoquant (Iso-product curve): It is defined as the locus of various combinations of two inputs
yielding the same level of output. Each point on an isoquant represents the maximum output that
can be attained with these input combinations. Isoquant is a convenient device for compressing
0
the 3-dimension picture of a production process into two dimensions. X1 = f (X2, Y ).
Isoquant map
X2
X1
Properties of isoquants
1. Isoquants have a negative slope,
2. Isoquants to right indicate higher output level,
3. Isoquants do not interest each other,
4. Isoquant are convex to origin showing diminishing MRTS.
Types of Factor-Factor Relationship: Many types of production surfaces are possible
depending upon the underlying production function. The shapes of the isoquants and production
surfaces will depend on the manner in which the variable inputs are combined to produce a
particular level of output. Broadly, these are three categories of such combinations of inputs.
X2
y3
y2
y1
o
X1
Substitutes: Two resources are said to be substitutes when change in price of one leads to a
change in demand for another (MRTS is –ve).
Complements: Resources used together in production. When Price of X1 increases the demand
X2
O
X1
Assumes perfect substitutbility
Constant Substitution
X2 X1 ∆X2 ΔX1 X2 MRTS
Female labour Male labour X1 X1X2
10 1 2 1 2/1=2
8 2 2 1 2/1=2
6 3 2 1 2/1=2
4 4 2 1 2/1=2
2 5 2 1 2/1=2
e.g. Two labourers. Decision rule use either of the two depending on the relative prices.
3. Varying Rate of substitution: In this there can either be increasing rate or decreasing rate of
substitution. In this MRTSX1X2 varies over iso-product curve. It means that the amount of one
input (X1) required to substitute for one unit of another input (X2) at a given level of production
16 1 7 1 7
10 2 6 1 6
5 3 5 1 5
1 4 4 1 4
0 5 1 1 1
X2
Y
1
0
X1
These convex isoquants represent continuous substitution between the two inputs. These are easy
to handle mathematically (using calculus).
X2
MRTSX1X2 =
X1
Marginal rate of technical substitution (MRTS or MRS): MRTS is defined as the negative of
the slope of the isoquant at any point. It is the rate at which two factors of production can be
exchanged at a particular level of output and consequently that of the levels of inputs used.
dy = Dy .dx1+ Dy .dX2
DX1 DX 2
dy =0 on an isoquant
Dy
- dX 2 = DX1 = MP1
dX1 Dy MP2
DX 2
Iso-cost line: Locus of all possible combination of two inputs which can be purchased with a
given outlay or budget.
)
T P x2 (X 2
T=PX1.X1+Px2.X2 or X1= ( P )- P
x 1 x 1
X2
X2
X1
X1
X2
X2
PX2 becomes PX1 increase &
Costlier & PX2 Decreases
PX1 decreases
X1
X1
(i) It prices are same and only outlay changes then iso-cost lines will be parallel to each
other.
(ii) Changes in prices of inputs will change the slope of iso-cost line.
Computing Least cost combination: Three methods
1 8 2 24 16 32
2 6 3 18 12 30
3 5 4 15 16 31
X2
0
X 2 q1
O 0
X 1X1
Iso-cline: A line or curve connecting the least cost combinations of inputs for all output levels is
known as isocline. Isocline passes through all isoquants at points where they have same slope. It
shows how the relative proportion of the factors changes as the output is increased. It shows that
resources should be used along this line as long as MVP> MC of resources used.
Ridge lines: Represent the points of maximum output from each input, given a fixed amount of
the other input. On the ridge lines MPP is zero. Ridge lines represent the economic relevance
within the ridge lines MPPs of both the inputs is positive but decreasing.
For X
X2
2 A
B
(Ridge line
For X1)
X1
Expansion Path: - There can be numerous isoclines for different possible combinations of input
prices. All these sets of prices of inputs do not prevail at any particular given time. A farm
manager has to be consider only one set of input prices that is most appropriate for the planning
period. The isoclines depending upon this set of prices (most appropriate) is called expansion
path. At any particular time there is only our expansion path possible.
Thus, the line or curve connecting the points of least cost combination for different levels of
output is called expansion path. Expansion path is an isocline on which slope of isoquant
(MRTS) equals the slopes of isocost line (price ratio). The expansion path indicates the best way
of producing the different levels of output given the input prices & the technology. If expansion
path is a straight line through origin, it means inputs will be used in the same proportion at all
output levels and hence it is called scale line. It is curved; it implies the inputs will be used in
various proportions.
X
2
X
1
Product-Product Relationship
Product-product relationship: The farmers have limited resources and have a number of
enterprises/or enterprise combinations of crops and livestock to choose from. So the question is:
How much of what to produce and with what technology. In other words, what combination of
enterprises should be produced?
Algebraically, y1 = f (y2)
(i) Joint Products: Joint products result from the same production process and the
production of one without the other is not possible. For instance, cotton lint & seed,
wheat & straw. In such cases the quantity of one product produced decides the
quantity of other product. For production decisions, joint products can be treated as
one product. Changes in product combinations are possible in long run only (through
research).
C
B
Y2
A
O
Y1
Y
2
M ·N
·K
O
H Y1
(iii) Supplementary products: Exists when increase or decrease in one product does not
affect the production level of the other product. All supplementary relationships
should be taken advantage of by producing both products to the point where the
products become competitive.
Y1
B
A
O
DY 2
(iv) Competitiveness: This relationship holds when increase or decrease in the production
of one product affects the production of other commodity inversely. Competitive
enterprises compete for farm resources & substitute for each other. When two
products are competitive, some amount of one product must be given up to increase
the level of other product. MRPS between products is negative. When two products
are competitive, they may substitute at constant rate, increasing rate or decreasing
rate.
(a) Constant Rate of Substitution: It means that a unit change in one product is
throughout accompanied by the same unit opposite change in the other product
e.g. wheat & gram for land.
Y2
Y2
O Y1 Y1
y1 = y12 = ------= y1N . This is normally a short run relationship. When this relationship
y2 y22 y2N
exists it will be economical to produce only one of the products depending upon the relative
prices.
(b) Increasing Rate of Substitution: In this each unit increase in the level of one
product is accompanied by larger and larger decrease in the level of other product.
e.g. wheat & gram will substitute at increasing rate for capital and labour.
y21 < y22 < ---- < y2n
y11 y12 y1n
Y
2 Y2
Y Y
1 1
Here profit is maximum when physical rate of substitution is equal to product price ratio.
c) Decreasing Rate of Substitution: In this case a unit increase in the level of one product is
accompanied by lesser & lesser decrease in the level of other product e.g. dairy & crops. Rare in
agriculture. If this exists it will be economical to produce only one of the products. Price line will
be tangent at only one of the end points of the curve.
y2 y2
Summary: > zero – complementary; < zero – competitive MRPS y1y2
y1 y1
y2
=zero – supplementary
y1
Returns to Scale
It refers to the change in output as a result of a given proportionate change in all the factors
of production simultaneously. Returns to scale is a long run concept as all the variables are
varied in quantity. Returns to scale are increasing, constant or decreasing depending on whether
proportionate simultaneous increase of input factors results in an increasing in output by a
greater, same or smaller proportion.
Hypothetical example of returns to scale
Labour Capital Output Change in output ( Y) Nature of returns to scale
0 0 0
1 1 8 8 Increasing
2 2 17 9
3 3 28 11
4 4 38 10 Constant
5 5 38 10
6 6 58 10
7 7 68 10
8 8 76 8 Decreasing
9 9 82 6
10 10 84 4
variable resource.
7 Optimum output is the result of best The optimum output is the result of
proportion among fixed & variable optimum size of plant.
factors.
8 Diminishing returns are due to over Diminishing returns to scale are due to the
exploitation of fixed factor. operation of diseconomies of scale.
Classification of farming
The ‘types of farming’ and the ‘systems of farming’ are two different terms. Some
western farm economists have used the terms, type and system interchangeably. Though the
distinction between the two is not very clear, yet some experts have tried to differentiate these.
The ‘system of farming’ is generally used to denote the ownership of land, farm resource
management and other managerial decisions. It may be cooperative farming, or tenant farming or
the state farming, etc. The ‘types of farming’ refers to the methods of farming and to different
practices that are used in carrying out farming operations. Johnson defined it as ‘when farms in a
group are quite similar in the kinds and proportions of the crops and the livestock that are
produced and in the methods and practices followed in production, the group is described as a
‘type of farming’’. The flow chart given below details out various types and systems of farming.
Farming
Types Systems
2. Specialised 2.Peasant
3. Mixed 3.State
4. Ranching 4.Capitalistic
5. Dry
A. Types of farming
Natural, economic and to some extent social factors determine the type of farming in an
area. Within the restraining influence of natural factors, economic factors- relative prices of farm
products, resources of the farmer, transport facility, farm size, land value and technological
developments influence the type of farming practiced in a region and set the proportion of area
under each enterprises. Religious beliefs and social background also play some part in following
the type of farming on the farm.
A farm on which no single product or source of income equals as much as 50% of the
total receipt is called a diversified or general farm. On such a farm, the farmer depends on
several sources of income.
Cash
Sources of Income grain
Dairy
Farming
Poultry
Sheep
Rearing
1. Marketable produce is insufficient unless the producers arrange for the sale of their
produce on co-operative basis.
2. Because of varied jobs in diversified farming, a farmer can effectively supervise only
limited number of workers.
3. Better equipping of the farm is not possible because it is not economical to have
expensive implements and machinery for each enterprise.
4. There are chances when some of the leaks in farm business may remain undetected
due to diversity of operations.
Under Indian conditions, the advantages of diversified farming far outweigh any
consideration for specialized farming. As a rule, crop-dairy type of diversified
farming is followed, because it offers more economical use of land, labour and capital
and permits safest possible way to withstand adverse weather conditions or violent
price fluctuations. Very often complementary relationships are observed among
enterprises, which contribute to increased farm production and profitability.
(2) Specialized farming
A specialized farm is one on which 50% or more receipts are derived from one enterprise.
Income is sale plus produce used at home.
6. Efficiency and skill are increased - Specialization allows a man to be more efficient and
expert at doing a few things.
Disadvantages of Specialized Farming
1. There is greater risk – Failure of crop and market together may ruin the farmer.
2. Productive resources-Land, labour and capital are not fully utilised.
3. Fertility of soil cannot properly be maintained for lack of suitable rotations.
4. By-products may not be fully utilized for lack of sufficient livestock on the farm.
5. Farm returns in each are not generally received more than once a year.
6. General knowledge of farm enterprises becomes limited.
(3) Mixed Farming
Mixed farming is a type of farming under which crop production is combined with
livestock raising. The livestock enterprise is complementary to crop production so as to provide a
balanced productive system of farming. When the livestock begin to complete with crops for the
same resources, the relationship between the two enterprises changes from complementary phase
to competitive nature.
In India mixed farming offers the following advantages:
1. Milch cattle provide draught animals for crop production and rural transport.
2. Mixed farming helps in the maintenance of soil fertility. Crops cannot be grown
successfully without the use of manure. The most readily available supply of plant
food is farmyard manure. But unfortunately, a large part of this used as a fuel
resulting from pressure of population on the land.
3. It tends to give a balanced labour load throughout the year for the farmer and his
family.
4. It permits proper use of the farm by-products.
5. It provides greater chances for intensive cultivation.
6. It offers higher returns on farm business.
(4) Ranching
A ranch differs from other type of crop and livestock farming in that the livestock grazes
the natural vegetation. Ranches are not utilized for tilling or raising crops. The ranchers have no
land of their own and make use of the public grazing land. A ranch occupies most of the time of
one or more operator. Ranching is followed in Australia, Tibet and in certain parts of India. An
average Australian sheep farm covers an area of about 100 square miles and there are some
farms as large as 1,000 square miles.
(5) Dry Farming
Farmers in dry and precarious tracts, which receive 50 cm or less of annual rainfall,
struggle for livelihood. The major farm management problem in these tracts, where crops
entirely depends upon rainfall, is the conservation of soil moisture.
B. Systems of Farming
Conditions determining the system of farming: Farm tenancy, farm ownership, group
farming, economic use of land, and incentives to co-operate are some of the conditions
conducive to the adoption of system of farming. An analysis of the system of farming
shows that it is closely associated with the type of farming in so far as the type of crops and
livestock raising are concerned.
1.Co-operative farming: Co-operative farming is divided into two classes: i) Cooperative
joint farming & ii) Co-operative collective farming.
Meaning of Co-operative Farming: Co-operative farming means a system under which all
agricultural operations or part of them are carried on jointly by the farmers on a voluntary basis,
each farmer retaining right in his own land. The farmer would pool their land, labour and capital.
The land would be treated as one unit and cultivated jointly under the direction of an elected
management. A part of a profit would be distributed in proportion to the land contributed by each
farmer and the rest of the profit would be contributed in proportion to the wages earned by each
farmer. If the farmers are not willing to have a full scale co-operative farming, they can secure
some of the economics by joining a particular form of co-operative organization namely, co-
operative purchasing, co-operative better farming, co-operative selling, etc.
(i) Co-operative joint farming Society: The ownership is retained by the individuals,
but the land is cultivated jointly.
(ii) Co-operative Collective farming: In collective farming, the members of collectives
surrender their land, livestock and head stock to the society. The collectives cannot
refuse to admit other members of required qualification. The members work
together under a management committee elected by themselves. The committee
directs farm management in matter of allocation of work, distribution of income and
marketing surpluses and put all members into labour to see that the work is done
efficiently. The payment to the workers is in terms of "work day units". A standard
quota for each kind of farm operation is fixed in relation to one working day and the
amount of work done by each farmer in a day is calculated accordingly, both in
respect of quality and quantity. An unskilled worker has to put in more hours than
the skilled one to fill his quota of work day. In India, the co-operative collective
farming societies are ordinary societies of landless labourers to whom government
land is given for cultivation. In this type, the labourers have no land of their own
which they can pool, they primarily pool their labour.
(2) Peasant Farming:
Peasant farming is concerned with peasant relation to land. The Zamindari Abolition Act
of government has given the right of ownership to practically all the peasant-operators in the
country. Peasant farming has given them opportunities to organize and operate their farms in
their own way and get due reward for their labour and capital. Besides, peasant farming
encourages them to maintain and develop the fertility in the occupation of land with social
prestige attached to the ownership.
(3) State farming:
Under this system of farming, the farms are managed by government. The agricultural
labourers are paid wages on weekly or monthly basis in accordance with the wages fixed under
Minimum Wages Act.
(4) Capitalistic farming:
The capitalistic farming is based on the capital provided by the owner of the farm in
carrying out of farm operations. Such type of farming is practiced where landlordism exists as in
England or the U.S.A. In India, this type of farming is seen in sugarcane area where factory
owners have their own farms. On these farms, five factors of productions namely, land, labour,
capital, management and entrepreneurship are in evidence. The manager is a salaried person and
the entrepreneur takes risk and gets profit or may sustain loss.
A) Farm planning
Farm planning refers to setting the objectives and actions to be taken in directing or
controlling the organization of farm business and it precedes all other managerial functions on
the farm to achieve the desired results. It is deciding in advance, the production management
problems viz., what to produce, how to produce, when to produce; financial management
problems viz., how to borrow, how much to borrow, when to borrow, where to borrow, and
marketing management problems viz., where to buy and sell, when to buy and sell, how to buy
and sell, etc. Farm planning governs the survival progress and prosperity of farm organization in
a competitive and dynamic environment. It is a continuous and unending process. Farm planning
is as old as farming itself but mainly it used to be informal planning. With agriculture becoming
more complex business, the scientific planning which is systematic, written and based on the best
information available and aimed at achieving maximum satisfaction for the farming family from
the given resources is needed. Farm planning has to incorporate changing technological
developments, physical and economic situations and price structures, etc. Thus, farm planning
may be defined as the process of making decisions regarding the organization and operation
of a farm business so that it results in a continuous maximization of net returns of a farm
business.
3. Select appropriate enterprise combinations that results in the better use of resources.
4. Timing various jobs and operations for smooth conduct of operations without competition.
6. Provide guidance and flexibility for ensuring better use and growth of the farm business.
7. Provide allocation of resources for producing the requisite products for marketing and
household consumption.
Thus farm planning may be deemed as an educational tool to bring about desirable
organizational changes on the farm to increase the farm income of the farming family.
Objective of farm planning
The ultimate objective of farm planning is the improvement in the living standards of the
farmers and immediate goal is to maximize the net incomes from the farming operations through
improved resource planning. Other secondary objectives of farm planning could be secure
incomes, minimizing risk or minimizing labour requirements.
Farm plans are categorized into two sub-groups viz., simple farm plan and complete farm
plan. Simple farm plan implies planning for minor changes or for a particular enterprise.
Complete farm planning envisages more number of changes in the existing organization. It is
adopted for the farm as a whole.
Characteristics of good farm plan
The following are the characteristics of a good farm plan:
1. Plans should aim at efficient utilization of all the available resources on the farm.
2. Plans should be flexible i.e., they should be adaptable to changing environmental conditions.
3. Farm plans should be simple and easily understood.
4. Considering the available resources, farm plans should ensure balanced production
programme consisting of food crops, commercial crops and fodder crops.
5. The production programme included in the farm plan should aim at improving soil fertility.
6. Farm plans should facilitate efficient marketing of farm products.
7. It should take into account up-to-date technology.
8. Farm plans should consider the goals, knowledge, training and experience of the farmers, and
their attitude towards risk.
9. Farm plans should avoid too risky enterprises.
10. Farm plans should provide for borrowing, using and repaying the credit.
is unfortunate to note that relevant farm records are not being kept by the farmers. The pertinent
information on farms particularly in respect of climate, water supply, markets, etc., is not found
in the required form. The sources of data for diagnosis and planning are also lacking. As a result,
farm planning is not effectively formulated and implemented. Therefore, farm standards derived
from research stations and efficient farms in the locality should form the basis for scientific
planning. Data from research stations should be continuously used for this purpose.
B) Farm budgeting
Farm plan is a programme of total farm activity drawn up by the farmer in advance. It
should show the crops to be grown; farm practices to be followed; combination of other
enterprises; use of labour, investments to be made on the farm, etc. The expression of farm plan
in monetary terms i.e. by the estimation of receipts, expenses and net income, is called farm
budgeting. In other words, farm budgeting is a process of estimating costs, returns and net profit
of a farm or a particular enterprise. Farm budgets are classified into enterprise budget, partial
budget and complete budget or whole farm budget. Farm budgeting is a method of examining the
profitability of alternative farm plans.
1. Farm enterprise budget
Commodity production on the farm is called farm enterprise. Farm budgets can be
developed for each potential enterprise. Enterprise budgets are prepared in terms of a common
unit i.e., acre, hectare, for a crop, one head of livestock, etc. This facilitates easy comparison
among the enterprises. Enterprise budget is the estimation of expected income, costs and profit
for an enterprise.
Organization of enterprise budget
It consists of three elements viz., income, costs and profitability. Income is computed by
estimating the expected output and expected price. The estimated output is based on the average
price expected in future. In order to estimate the variable costs we need information on quantity
of inputs used and the prices at which they are purchased. Fixed costs to be included in enterprise
budget are land revenue, depreciation, interest on fixed capital and rental value of owned land.
2. Partial budgeting
Partial budgeting refers to the estimating the outcome or returns for a part of the business,
i.e. one or a few activities. Partial budgeting is a statement of anticipated changes in costs,
returns and profitability for such a minor modification on the farm. When a farmer contemplates
few modifications or minor changes in the existing organization of the farm business, partial
budgeting technique is employed. It is similar to that of marginal analysis, wherein the changes
in costs and returns resulting from proposed modifications are alone considered. It consists of
four important elements viz., added costs, added returns, reduced returns and reduced costs.
Partial budgeting technique is generally used to evaluate the profitability of input substitution,
enterprise substitution and scale of operation.
1. Added costs: Additional costs are incurred, if the proposed modification is the introduction of
a new enterprise or increase in the size of the existing enterprise.
2. Added returns: Additional returns could be received when the proposed modification is the
addition of a new enterprise, or increase in the size of the existing enterprise or adoption of
technology that results in higher productivity.
3. Reduced returns: Decrease in the returns is observed when the proposed modification
involves the elimination of an existing enterprise or reduction in the size of the existing
enterprise.
4. Reduced costs: Decrease in the costs is found when the proposed modification involves the
elimination of existing enterprise or reduction in the size of the enterprise or adoption of a
technology that uses fewer amounts of resources.
3. Complete Budgeting
It is a method of estimating expected income, expense and profits for the farm as whole.
Complete budgeting is employed when farmers want to overhaul the entire farm business.
Steps in farm planning and budgeting: The sound farm plan should be generally feasible,
acceptable, and adaptable. To make the farm plan successful, the following steps should be
adopted with relevance to given farm and its resources.
1. Statement of objective.
2. Diagnosis of the existing organization
3. Assessment of resource endowments on the farm.
4. Identification of enterprises to be included.
for irrigation water, accessibility of land to the irrigation sources such as canal and tank, etc.,
should also be indicated. In addition to this cost of irrigation needs to be mentioned.
4. Identification of enterprises to be included: List of enterprises not only grown by the
farmer but also enterprises grown in that area and also crop rotations are identified. Estimate the
input-output coefficients in terms of acre or hectare or head of livestock for all the enterprises,
which we propose to include. Information on input and output prices should be collected so as to
work out the costs and returns.
5. Preparation of enterprise budgets: Estimate the income, cost and profitability of each
enterprise to be included in the plan. The preparation of enterprise budgets facilitates comparison
of profitability of different enterprises.
6. Identification of risks: List out all types of risks viz., production risk, weather risk,
technological risk, institutional risk, marketing risk, etc., faced by the farmers. Particularly the
incidence of pests, rodents and diseases, frequency of drought occurrence over time, cyclones,
floods and their havoc caused to farm plans. Marketing risks comprising of risk emanating from
price fluctuations and failure of markets to arrest the malpractices of middlemen should be
indicated.
7. Preparation of a plan: The first step is indentifying the scarcest resources and selecting that
enterprise which yields maximum returns per unit of scarcest resource. This process is repeated
till all the scarce resources are put to the best use which results in optimum combination of the
enterprises.
Perfect knowledge: There would be no need for farm management experts if knowledge was
perfect. If these were so, technology, prices and institutional behaviour would be known with
certainty for any period of time in the future. But the concept of perfect knowledge is a fallacious
one and does not represent the real world situation.
From the economic point of view, uncertainty is undoubtedly the most important. The
occurrence of an event cannot be quantified with the help of probability. Thus future occurrence
of an event cannot be predicted. A farmer often finds himself confronted with such a situation
where the knowledge is incomplete, yet the decision has to be taken. It becomes, therefore,
essential to formulate some estimates however wild, of the most likely outcomes. In practice,
however, farmers are unable to draw a clear distinction between risk and uncertainty though the
reaction in each situation is markedly different. Mostly the terms risk and uncertainty are used
interchangeably.
Types of Risks and Uncertainties: They are classified into five categories:
1. The economic uncertainties are markedly reduced in many economies where input and
product prices are announced before sowing a crop. Economic uncertainties of this nature are
usually caused by national and international policies which are beyond the approach of an
individual farmer.
4. Institutional uncertainties: Institutions like government, banks, etc., may also cause
uncertainties for an individual farmer. Crop cess, credit squeeze, price supports, subsidies, etc.
may be enforced or withdrawn without taking an individual farmer into confidence. This type of
uncertainty may also result in non-availability of resources in appropriate quantities and at the
appropriate time and place.
5. Personal uncertainties
The farm plan may not be executed because of some mishap in the farmer’s household or in his
permanent labour force.
Some farmers take more risk than others. However, all farmers use one or more measures
of different types of safeguard themselves against risks and uncertainties on their farms. The
various measures generally used to counter risks and uncertainties in agriculture are as follows:
2. Discounting returns
At this stage we refer to discounting only as a function of risk and uncertainty, and not
time. Planning based on single value expectations of input-output coefficients may invariably be
misleading as it assumes a perfect knowledge situation. It amounts to deducting a safety margin
from the expected prices, yields or incomes.
3. Insurance
Insurance is another well-accepted method to safeguard against risk and uncertainty.
However, insurance in agriculture is not common in many countries including India. It helps the
farmer, whenever used, to lessen the variability in income and minimize the chances of the farm
income dropping below a minimum level.
4. Forward contracts
They reduce the future prices, both of the factors of production and of the products, into
certainty. Contracts may either be in money or in kind. Employment of a labourer on the farm for
a period of one, two or twelve months on some agreed amount is an example of forward contract
in money. Similarly, pre-harvest apple contract in Himachal Pradesh or Jammu and Kashmir is
another example. On the other hand, share cropping is a good example of forward contracts in
kind. Contracts in kind reduce income variability where contracts in money do extract the
opposite.
5. Flexibility
This refers to the convenience with which the organization of production on a farm can
be changed. Some organizations are obviously more flexible than others and flexibility in an
organization through change in production helps obtaining advantages and improvements in the
economic and technological environment of a farmer. As an uncertainty safeguard, flexibility
may be built into farm plan for stabilization of incomes from year to year and to maximize the
expected stream of total income over a longer period of time. It differs from diversification in the
sense that it aims at preventing the sacrifice of large gains as compared to the prevention of large
losses through diversification.
Due to technological and economic changes certain enterprises may suddenly gain or lose
importance over time. Thus, quick changes may be required which can only be brought about at
a low cost if the plans are not rigid but flexible. Flexibility can be of the following types:
i) Time flexibility: Time flexibility may be introduced either through proper selection of
products or production methods or partly by both. Orchard plantation is a relatively more rigid
enterprise than annual crops like wheat, maize, paddy, etc. A short lived farm structure or
equipment is more flexible than one which durable.
ii) Cost flexibility: whenever time flexibility is of limited use, cost flexibility becomes
important. Cost flexibility refers to variations in output within the structure of a plant with a
longer life. Extension or contraction of output, whenever desired by favourable prices or yields,
can be brought about at lower costs for a given plant. through a farmer may find that owning a
potato digger on his farm would result in lower costs than those which have to be paid for
custom hiring a similar one, yet he may keep on hiring machine in order to have more cost
flexibility on his farm.
iii) Product Flexibility: product flexibility, like any type of flexibility, aims at changes in
production in response to price signals. In this category we consider the form of physical
resources, e.g. machines, farm structure, etc., which can be switched readily from one product to
another.
7. Diversification
Diversification is a very important, useful and popular method to safeguard against risk
and uncertainty in agriculture. Here we refer to diversification as a means of stabilizing incomes
rather than profit maximizing related to reaping gains of complementarity and supplementarity.
Natural resource economics deals with the supply, demand and allocation of the
earth natural resource. Main objective of natural resource economics is to better
understand the role of natural resources in the economy in order to develop more
sustainable methods of managing those resources to ensure their availability to future
generations. Resource economists study interactions between economic and natural
systems, with the goal of developing a sustainable and efficient economy. It is a multi -
disciplinary field of academic research.
The insights into sustainability provided by mainstream economics are taken much
further by environmental and ecological economists. The main areas of contribution
include the following:
Renewable resources: Renewable resources are generally living resources (fish, coffee,
and forests, for example), which can restock (renew).
Resources can also be classified on the basis of their origin i.e. biotic and abiotic.
Biotic resources: Biotic resources are derived from animals and plants (i.e-the living
world). Biotic is a living component of a community; for example organisms, such as
plants and animals.
Abiotic resources: Abiotic resources are derived from the non-living world e.g. land,
water, and air. Mineral and power resources are also abiotic resources some are
derived from nature. In biology and ecology, abiotic components are non-living
chemical and physical factors in the environment which affect ecosystems.
Natural resources:
Water resource: Water resources are usually renewable resources which naturally
recharge. Overexploitation occurs if a water resource is extracted at a rate that exceeds
the recharge rate, that is, at a rate that exceeds the practical sustained yield.
Forest resources: Forest is overexploited when they are logged at a rate faster than
reforestation takes place. Reforestation competes with other land uses such as food
production, livestock grazing, and living space for further economic growth.
Deforestation
• Utility,
Limited availability,
Scarcity
Resource depletion
Potential Resources are known to exist and may be used in the future. For example,
petroleum may exist in many parts of India and Kuwait that have sedimentary rocks,
but until the time it is actually drilled out and put into use, it remains a potential
resource.
Actual resources are those that have been surveyed, their quantity and quality
determined, and are being used in present times. For example, petroleum and natural
gas is actively being obtained from the Mumbai High Fields. That part of the actual
resource that can be developed profitably with available technology is called a
reserve resource, while that part that cannot be developed profitably because of lack
of technology is called a stock resource.
A natural resource may exist as a separate entity such as fresh water, and air, as
well as a living organism such as a fish, or it may exist in an alternate form which must
be processed to obtain the resource such as metal ores, oil, and most forms of energy
Renewable resource
Renewable resource is a natural resource which can replenish with the passage of
time, either through biological reproduction or other naturally recurring processes.
Renewable resources are a part of Earth's natural environment and the largest
components of its ecosphere. A positive life cycle assessment is a key indicator of a
resource's sustainability. Renewable resources may be the source of power for renewable
energy. Sustainable harvesting of renewable resources (i.e., maintaining a positive
renewal rate) can reduce air pollution, soil contamination, habitat destruction and land
degradation.
Non-renewable resource
Carrying capacity
Use of natural resource services is compared with defined bio-physical limits for
the supply of such services.
Sustainability:
The word sustainability is derived from the Latin sustinere (tenere, to hold; sus, up).
The most widely quoted definition of sustainability and sustainable development, that of
the Brundtland Commission of the United Nations on March 20, 1987: “sustainable
development is development that meets the needs of the present without compromising
the ability of future generations to meet their own needs. Environmental, social and
economic demands - the "three pillars" of sustainability.
The word sustainability is applied not only to human sustainability on earth, but too
many situations and contexts over many scales of space and time, from small local ones
to the global balance of production and consumption. Sustainability is the capacity to
endure.
Sustainability farming: It is the system that in which NRS are managed so that the
potential yield and stock of NRS do not decline over time
I=P×A×T
Measurement
Resource productivity:
6. Climate change
7. Conservation
8. Energy Environmental degradation
9. Environmental health
10. Intensive farming
11. Land degradation —
12. Soil
13. Land use
14. Overpopulation
15. Ozone depletion
16. Pollution
Water pollution
Air pollution
· Reservoirs Resource depletion
Equity derives from a concept of social justice. It represents a belief that there are some
things which people should have, that there are basic needs that should be fulfilled, and
that policy should be directed with impartiality, fairness and justice towards these ends
.Equity means that there should be a minimum level of income and environmental quality
below which nobody falls.
Intra-generational equity
Equity can also be applied across communities and nations within one generation.
The reason that intra-generational equity is a key principle of sustainable development is
that inequities are a cause of environmental degradation. Poverty deprives people of the
choice about whether or not to be environmentally sound in their activities.
Second, unfair access to public infrastructure, facilities and services could occur (equity
failure). i.e . Failure to guarantee intra- and inter-generational equity would cause deep
inequality and un sustainability
Third, natural resources may be so exploited that threaten their sustainability of use.
Fourth, negative externalities of economic activities could create serious threat to the
environment
Equity issues:
6.Negative externalities
7.Non-production function
8. Compensation to worse-off people
9.Sustainability reinvestment
Discount rate
where
DPV is the discounted present value of the future cash flow (FV), or FV
adjusted for the delay in receipt;
d is the discount rate which is i/(1+i), i.e. the interest rate ex pressed as a
deduction at the beginning of the year instead of an addition at the end of the
year; and n is the time in years before the future cash flo w occurs.
For continuous cash f lows, the summation in the above formula is replaced by an
integration:
where FV(t) is now the rate of cash flow, and = log(1 +i).
Discounting
In order to compare costs and benefits at different points in time, we use the technique of
discounting, in order to calculate present discounted value. The formula for present
discounted value is given by
PV = ------------
(1+R)t
R = "discount rate"
Why discount?
Opportunity cost.
8. Environmental goods and services often are not traded in markets, e.g., clean
air.
Types of Economic Analysis
9. Cost-benefit analysis
Identify and quantifying project impacts
Monetization
Damage assessment
ii) Economic impact analy sis
iii) Cost-effectiveness ana lysis
Supply a nd Demand
Price
Supply
Consumer Surplus
Demand
Q*
Quantity
Social rate of discount It is use estimating rate of discount for the follow ing factors
Calculation
where r equals the SDR and t equals time. For benefits or costs that have no end it is
just
A higher SDR makes it less li kely a social project will be funded. A higher SDR implies
greater risks to the assumption that the benefits of the project will be rea ped.
There are a number of qualitative differences between social and private discount
rates and evaluation of projects associated with them. The governance of social project
funding is different naturally, because estimating the benefits of social projects requires
making ethic ally subtle choices about the benefits to others.
Another school of economists believes that the correct rate o f discount for public
projects is the social time preference rate, STPR, which is also called the consumption
rate of interest (CRI). The rationale for this argument is quite simple; the purpose behind
investment decisions is to increase future consumption, which involves a sacrifice on
present consumption. Therefore, what we need to do is ascertain the net consumption
stream of an investment project and then use the CRI.
Market efficiency
E = O/I
Allocative efficiency :
Occurs when the economy is utilizing all of its resources efficiently, producing
most output from least input. The concept is illustrated on a production possibility
frontier (PPF). In long-run equilibrium for perfectly competitive markets, the average
(total) cost curve i.e. where MC = A(T)C.
Productive efficiency:
or business can extend its production possibility frontier outward and increase efficiency
further.
Economic efficiency:
Economic efficiency occurs at the level of output at which the marginal social
benefits (MSB) equal the marginal social costs (MSC). MSB = MSC
ix) Weak-form efficiency: Prices of the securities instantly and fully reflect all
information of the past prices. This means future price movements cannot be
predicted by using past prices.
x) Semi-strong efficiency: Asset prices fully reflect all of the publicly available
information. Therefore, only investors with additional inside information could
have advantage on the market.
xi) Strong-form efficiency: Asset prices fully reflect all of the public and inside
information available. Therefore, no one can have advantage on the market in
predicting prices since there is no data that would
Market failure:
The inefficiency in the market lead to imperfect competition and causes market
failure. Agents in a market can gain market power, allowing them to block other
mutually beneficial gains from trades from occurring. This can lead to inefficiency due
to imperfect competition, which can take many different forms, such as monopolies,
cartels, or monopolistic competition, if the agent does not implement perfect price
discrimination. In a monopoly, the market equilibrium will no longer be Pareto optimal.
The monopoly will use its market power to restrict output below the quantity at which
the marginal social benefit is equal to the marginal social cost of the last unit produced,
so as to keep prices and profits high.
Public goods
Some markets can fail due to the nature of certain goods, or the nature of their
exchange. For instance, goods can display the attributes of public goods or common-
pool resources, while markets may have significant transaction costs or informational
asymmetry. In general, all of these situations can produce inefficiency, and a resulting
market failure. This can cause underinvestment, such as where a researcher cannot
capture enough of the benefits from success to make the research effort worthwhile.
Excludability:
Deals with the ability of agents to control who uses their commodity, and for
how long – and the related costs associated with doing so.
Transferability:
It reflects the right of agents to transfer the rights of use from one agent to
another, for instance by selling or leasing a commodity, and the costs associated with
doing so. If a given system of rights does not fully guarantee these at minimal (or no)
cost, then the resulting distribution can be inefficient.
Externalities:
The allocation of resources to productive uses results from consumers and
producers making decisions with the aim of maximizing satisfaction and profits,
respectively. Private costs and benefits are taken into account in deciding purchases and
organizing production. Social costs and benefits include the costs and benefits of
consumer and producer but also costs borne by those who are not participating in that
particular market. These are known as external costs and benefits or externalities.
External costs and benefits can arise through both consumption and production. From a
sustainable development perspective, external costs are most significant and arguably
account for the failure of individuals, communities and nations to follow a sustainable
path.
Externalities types:
Positive Externalities: Positive externalities in production means that social cost is less
than private cost, and more of the good should be produced than will occur in a free
market.
Efficient market: A market is said to be efficient if marginal price and marginal cost
are equal. If not then a market is failure.
External costs
External benefits
This shows the positive or beneficial effects of a externality. For example, the
industry supplying smallpox vaccinations is assumed to be selling in a competitive
market.
Common resources
Externalities are third party effects arising from production and consumption of
goods and services for which no appropriate compensation is paid. One of the major
problems facing the environment is that common resources such as fish stocks and
grazing land are not privately owned – commonly owned resources may lack the
protection of property rights and are susceptible to over-exploitation because the
marginal cost of extracting the resource for a private agent is close to zero.
When there are environmental externalities, the private equilibrium price and
quantity determined by the interaction of market supply and demand is not the same as
the social equilibrium which includes all internal and external costs.
In a free market, a producer will have little direct incentive to control pollution because
it is external – i.e. the profit-maximising supplier considers only his/her own private costs
and benefits.
Regulation
Taxes/subsidies
Pollution
permits
In imperfect market the resource owner charge higher proices and supplied less
quantity than in perfect market where price = quantity
The economic value of natural resources can be estimated by the price individuals
will pay in order to obtain the benefits of the resources. The non-market values of that
communities attach to natural resources, such as recreational, existence and protection
values. To support efficient decision making, environmental valuation techniques are
needed to quantify the value impacts resulting from changed catchment management.
Several approaches to environmental valuation are there i.e. revealed preference
techniques include travel cost and hedonic pricing methods, stated preference techniques
include contingent valuation and choice experiments. Stated preference techniques are
increasingly being used to estimate non-market values. Nonmarket valuation is a method
to estimate the value of goods and services that are not commonly bought and sold in
markets.
Benefit-cost analysis
The travel cost model estimates the implicit price of natural resources based on
outlays of time and travel expenses. An evaluation of these costs incurred in using a
natural resource (e.g. a state park) can be used to estimate the regional demand for the
resource. The aggregate value of the resource can then be inferred from a combination of
this demand and the number of visits to the site over time. This model can be applied to
many recreational activities that utilize the more intangible natural resources such as bird
watching.
The random utility model is similar to the travel cost model except that rather than
focusing on the number and overall costs of trips to different sites, it estimates the value
individuals place on particular sites based on the attributes of the site.
Hedonic pricing methods involve a comparison of specific sites that differ only by
some environmental attribute such as proximity to a forested area or availability of a
view. Comparison of the property value between two house sites provides an indication
of the value to the individual paying a higher price for the site with the preferred
attribute.
Existence value:
This is the value that individuals place on natural resources that they want to
remain unaltered, even though they may not use or visit the area.
Economic value:
It is one ways to measure the value of a resource. Economic values are useful to
consider when making economic choices – tradeoffs in allocating resources. Measures of
economic value are based on individual preferences
Valuation:
Habitat : Opportunity cost approach, Replacement cost approach, Land Value approach
&
Contingent Valuation Approach
a. Market commodities are those which are traded in competitive cash markets.
Private timber is a good natural resource example of a market commodity.
b. Non market commodities involve public goods, open access or unique resources
potentially constituting natural monopoly situations.
Common methods for estimating prices for publicly provided natural resources:
2. Residual valuation - used in situations where private markets for natural resources
may not be active.
2 Change in net income - The general idea behind this pricing method is to estimate
what the natural resource contributes to producer’s profits (net income),
4. Hedonic TCM
Define Hedonic method - the Hedonic price method is used to estimate the value of an
attribute (e.g., site quality) of a good (e.g., recreation site). In other words, the hedonic
model, the multiple regressions, decomposes the total value of the good into the value of
its several attributes.
regression model (i.e., logit model) where the predicted dependent variable (i.e.,
probability of visit given values of independent variables) is restricted to lie between the
unit interval, 0 to 1.
Many important valuation problems are non-observable; i.e., no value measures can
be derived from observing individual choices in a market. Some of these situations
involve potential rather than actual policy changes. Such cases call for value
measurement methods which use hypothetical, constructed markets.
Linear Programming
Linear programming (LP) is a budgeting technique that is more refined and systematic
than the conventional budgeting in determining the optimum combination of enterprises or inputs
so as to maximize the income or minimize the cost within the limits of available resources. It
may be defined as “the analysis of the problems in which a linear function of a number of
variables is to be maximized or minimized when those variables are subject to a number of
restraints in the form of linear inequalities”. In linear programming models, the objective of the
typical farm i.e., maximization of net profit or cost minimization is achieved through optimal
plan generated from its solution. The objective function specified, i.e., profit maximization or
cost minimization, is linear in form and constraints on resource restrictions are specified in linear
form. LP has been used in agriculture since 1950s. As a normative tool, it provides prudent
solutions to farm planning problems.
Components of LP problem
There are three quantitative components in LP model. They are
Assumptions of LP problem
There are seven basic assumptions:
1. Linearity of the objective function: All the decision variables in the objective function,
i.e., crop and livestock activities are in linear form (without power form) and the
objective function is also linear, for example, as = 250 X1 + 350 X2 + 500 X3 +……..+
400 Xn. The coefficients of X1 are the net returns/ prices of the crops and livestock.
2. Divisibility of the activities as well as resources: Continuity of resources and output is
implied in this assumption. This means fractional quantities such as 0.2 ha of land and 3.5
qtl of paddy etc., are allowed. But divisibility for livestock activities and labour resources
appears to be unrealistic. To get integer values for such livestock activities, an integer
programming is being used.
3. Additivity of the resources and activities: It is the reciprocal of divisibility. This
assumption implies that the total quantity of a resource used must be equal to the total
quantity of resource used by each activity for all resources individually and collectively.
This means the activities and resources must be additive in the sense that when two or
more activities are followed their total product must be equal to the sum of their
individual products and the total resources used equal to the sum of resources used by
individual activity. If the resource is used up fully, it should equal the sum of the same
resources used by all the activities appearing in the optimal solution.
4. Finiteness of the activities and resource restrictions: With the advent of computers and
availability of programmes, a large numbers of activities and constraints are now being
specified in the model. But, there should be a limit for such numbers, because infinite
number of activities and resource restrictions cannot be accommodated in the model.
Hence, this assumption is important in the LP model. In general, it is desired to have
more number of the activities than the constraints in LP model.
5. Single value expectations: This assumption connotes certainty assumption and imparts
to the LP model, the name of deterministic model. According to this assumption, input-
output coefficients (aij), resource availabilities (Bj) and prices of activities (Cj), all are
specified correctly with known quantities in the model and they all relate to a particular
period of time. In the risk programming models this assumption is relaxed.
6. Non-negativity of the decision variables: All the crops and livestock activities should
have positive values in their magnitude. Negative values for such decision variables
cannot make any sense. Hence, this assumption is imperative.
5. To supplement owned funds, depending on the need, borrowing activity is included in the
LP model
6. Prices for products and resources are to be ascertained with certainty. Too high or too low
prices will distort the income estimates and thereby profit, often leading to results of
unrealistic magnitude. In general, the average prices, pooled over three to five years are
considered for LP model.
4. Restraints: These are also called limitations or constraints. Land, labour and capital are
generally considered as restraints. In the development of models for obtaining realistic
results, sometimes 150 to 200 restraints are also considered by researchers in economic
studies. In general, macro level studies will have more constraints than micro level
studies, because of the complexities involved in macro level situation. At micro level the
farmers may have restrictions regarding number of livestock animals, crop acreages, etc.
Amount of labour availability during peak season of the crop growth is generally
considered as the most common restriction seen in the LP model. Likewise, a farmer may
have access to limited quantities of many resources. The availability and requirements in
respect of machine labour, bullock labour, hired human labour, family labour, skilled
labour, unskilled labour, etc., in different time periods, i.e., a week, a month, a season and
a year may be considered in the programming model as separate restrictions or
constraints. All these restrictions can be specified in the model in three types, i.e., greater
than equal to constraints or less than equal to constraints, or equal to or equality
constraints.
5. Feasible Solution: Any solution to a linear programming problem is said to be feasible if
none of the xjs is negative. Thus, it is a solution in which the values of the variables
(ordinary and slack) satisfy both the constraints and the non-negativity restrictions. Such
a solution can only be found in the first quadrant. There is no guarantee that all linear
programming problems will have feasible solutions.
6. Unfeasible Solution: It refers to a solution wherein some of the variables, xjs, appear at a
negative level. Obviously, therefore, a solution to a linear programming problem does not
satisfy the non-negativity restrictions.
7. Basic Solution: The values of the variables in which the number of non-zero-valued
variables is equal to the number of constraints is called basic solution. Of the basic
solutions to a problem, there will be an optimal solution that satisfies the above criterion.
8. Optimum Solution: Unless alternate optima for a linear programming problem occur,
one of the feasible solutions is optimum, provided a feasible solution exists. Such a
feasible solution which also optimises the objective function is called an optimum
solution. The set of xjs in this case satisfies the set of constraints and non-negativity
restrictions and also maximizes the objective function.
9. Unbounded Solution: Many a time, faulty formulation of a linear programming problem
may result in a arbitrarily large value of the objective function and the problem has no
finite maximum value of . It may require only one or more variables to assume arbitrary
large magnitudes. This represents a case of an unbounded solution to a linear
programming problem.
Algebraically it is stated as
Maximize = C' X
Subject to
AX ≤ B
≥
X≥ 0
where A is m × n matrix of technical coefficients
C is n × 1 vector of prices or other weights for the objective function
References
Johl, S.S. and Kapoor, T.R. (1973), Fundamentals of Farm Business Management,
Kalyani Publishers, Ludhiana.
Raju, V.T. and Rao, D.V.S. (1990), Economics of Farm Production and
Management, Oxford & IBH Publishing Co. Pvt. Ltd., New Delhi-110 001.