Renewable Energy in India Economics and Market Dynamics 2021935949 9789353887810 - Compress
Renewable Energy in India Economics and Market Dynamics 2021935949 9789353887810 - Compress
ENERGY
IN INDIA
Economics and
Market Dynamics
Pramod Deo
Sushanta K. Chatterjee
Shrikant Modak
SAGE was founded in 1965 by Sara Miller McCune to support
the dissemination of usable knowledge by publishing innovative
and high-quality research and teaching content. Today, we
publish over 900 journals, including those of more than 400
learned societies, more than 800 new books per year, and a
growing range of library products including archives, data, case
studies, reports, and video. SAGE remains majority-owned by
our founder, and after Sara’s lifetime will become owned by
a charitable trust that secures our continued independence.
Bulk Sales
SAGE India offers special discounts
for purchase of books in bulk.
We also make available special imprints
and excerpts from our books on demand.
Marketing Department
SAGE Publications India Pvt Ltd
B1/I-1, Mohan Cooperative Industrial Area
Mathura Road, Post Bag 7
New Delhi 110044, India
E-mail us at [email protected]
Pramod Deo
Sushanta K. Chatterjee
Shrikant Modak
Copyright © Pramod Deo, Sushanta K. Chatterjee and Shrikant Modak, 2021
All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reproduced or utilized in any form or by any means,
electronic or mechanical, including photocopying, recording, or by any information storage or retrieval
system, without permission in writing from the publisher.
Published by Vivek Mehra for SAGE Publications India Pvt Ltd. Typeset in 10/12.5 pt ITC Stone Serif
by AG Infographics, Delhi.
SAGE Team: Rajesh Dey, Syed Husain Naqvi, Madhurima Thapa and Kanika Mathur
Disclaimer: The views contained in the book are the personal views of their respective authors and do
not, in any way, reflect their official views. These are to be considered solely in their personal capacities.
Contents
List of Figures
8.1 Tamil Nadu State Demand versus Wind Generation
(22 August 2017)—Maximum Wind Generation
Day 159
8.2 Demand in Gujarat on 22 May 2017, along with How
This Was Met from Various Sources of Generation
Available—Maximum Wind Variation Day 160
9.1 All-India Demand and Net Demand of a Typical Day
(in 2021–2022) 181
9.2 Short-term Trading Price Trends 184
9.3 Share of Market Segments in Total Electricity
Generation, 2019–2020 185
9.4 Price Variation in Power Exchange during a
Typical Day 186
9.5 Price Variation in Power Exchange during a Week 187
9.6 Price Variation in Power Exchange during a
Month 188
List of Tables
4.1 The Year-wise Cumulative Solar Power Rooftop PV
Installations (2015 to 2018 February) 50
6.1 Long-term Growth Trajectory of Renewable Purchase
Obligations for Solar and Non-solar as Determined
by the Ministry of Power 114
6.2 State-wise Renewable Purchase Obligations for Solar and
Non-solar as per MNRE’s National Portal for RPO 115
7.1 RE Generators Registered (No. of Projects and Capacity
in MW as on 31 March 2018) 150
7.2 Demand and Supply of REC (2012–2013 to
2018–2019) 151
10.1 Prices of Solar Projects Discovered through
Bidding 201
List of Appendices
5A State-wise Latest Wind and Solar Tariff Rates 81
5B Bid Tariff (Wind) 87
5C Bid Tariff (Solar) 93
6A.1 Targets of Renewable Purchase Obligation Set
by State Electricity Regulatory Commissions from
2010–2011 to 2019–2020 (in %) 124
6A.2 Compliance of Renewable Purchase Obligation
by the Utilities from 2010–2011 to 2013–2014 126
6B State-wise RPO Target (FY 2016–2017 to
FY 2020–2021) and RPO Compliance
(FY 2016–2017 to FY 2018–19) 128
AC Alternating current
AGC Automatic generation control
APERC Andhra Pradesh Electricity Regulatory
Commission
APPC Average power purchase cost
AS Ancillary services
CASE Commission for Additional Sources of Energy
CDM Clean Development Mechanism
CEA Central Electricity Authority
CERC Central Electricity Regulatory Commission
CFD Contract for difference
DC Direct current
DISCOM Distribution company
DNES Department of Non-conventional Energy Sources
DRE Distributed renewable energy
DSM Deviation Settlement Mechanism
DT Distribution transformer
EA Electricity Act
EE Energy entrepreneurs
eRA e-Reverse auction
ERC Electricity Regulatory Commission
FERC Federal Energy Regulatory Commission
FIT Feed-in tariff
FOR Forum of Regulators
FY Financial year
GOI Government of India
GRPV Grid-connected rooftop photovoltaic
IEGC Indian Electricity Grid Code
IEX Indian Energy Exchange
INDC Intended Nationally Determined Contributions
IPP Independent power producer
ISGS Inter State Generating Station
ISO Independent system operator
ISTS Inter-State Transmission System
LMP Locational marginal price
LRMC Long-run marginal cost
MBED Market Based Economic Dispatch
MGP Mera Gao Power
MNES Ministry of Non-conventional Energy Sources
MNRE Ministry of New and Renewable Energy
MW Megawatt
NAPCC National Action Plan for Climate Change
NEM Net Metering Regulation
NETA New Electricity Trading Arrangement
NFFO Non-Fossil Fuel Obligation
NLDC National Load Dispatch Centre
O&M Operation and maintenance
P2P Peer-to-peer
PAYG Pay-as-you-go
PPA Power purchase agreement
PTC Production tax credit
PURPA Public Utility Regulatory Policies Act
PV Photovoltaic
PX Power exchange(s)
QCA Qualified Coordinating Agency
RA Reverse auction
RE Renewable energy
REC Renewable energy certificate
REMC Renewable Energy Management Centre
RFS Request for selection
RLDC Regional load despatch centre
List of Abbreviations xi
Foreword
Kirit Parikh
Chairman, Integrated Research and Action for
Development (IRADe)
Former Member, Planning Commission
New Delhi
15 December 2020
Foreword xv
Preface
Preface xix
Acknowledgements
Renewable in India
In the Context of Evolution
of Power Sector
Introduction
The central theme of the book is the economics of renewable
(wind and solar to be specific) with a focus on pricing and
market dynamics, given the special natural of its production,
and this idea runs through the seams of all chapters. To start
with, this chapter sets out the context by presenting an over-
view of the electricity industry in India, with a special reference
to renewable energy (RE), and discusses the electricity reforms
in other parts of the world. It also traces the technological and
structural evolution of the sector, with a focus on tariff, a cen-
tral piece of electricity regulation.
Demand for power is central to all planning processes in any
power system. Generation and transmission are planned to
make sure that the power consumption need of consumers is
met at all times. Demand pattern varies by day, across seasons,
depending on various factors such as weather, festivals and
economic activities. The challenge of power system planning
and operation is to match generation to follow this curve, often
termed as the load duration curve. Generation planning is done
on a long-term time horizon and a portfolio of different fuel
source-based generation is created to cater to the power require-
ments at different time intervals. Thus, we have coal-based
generation capacity to meet base load, hydro to meet peak load
and gas-based capacity to address the flexibility requirement. To
this portfolio, there is a growing trend of adding RE resources,
largely driven by environmental concerns.
For generation planning, generally peak load is taken as
a reference. For instance, the peak demand in India during
Financial Year (FY) 2019–2020 was 184 GW. Against this
requirement, the country had a total installed generation
capacity of 370 GW, comprising 199 GW of coal-based genera-
tion capacity, 6.6 GW of lignite, 25 GW of gas-based, 46 GW of
hydro, 87 GW (as on 29 February 2020) renewable, 6.8 GW of
nuclear source-based generation capacity.1 Coal is an exhaust-
ible source, gas supply in the country is limited and import is
expensive and the hydro project costs are quite high, at least
in the initial years. Energy security is therefore a big concern
more so for a developing country like India. Given these reali-
ties and also driven by environmental concerns, India has of
late put a lot of emphasis on adding renewable generation
capacity on a big scale.
Renewable Revolution
India has been at the forefront of international efforts at har-
nessing RE for decades now. We have one of the largest and
most ambitious programmes in this field in the world. More
than 86,759 megawatt (MW)2 of power-generating capacity
based on RE sources has been installed until February 2020.
This constitutes over 23.48 per cent of the total installed power
capacity of the country, most of which comes from private
investments.
With wind power capacity of 37,669.25 MW, 3 India
ranks 4th4 among the major global countries engaged in the
Renewable in India 3
in Denmark. The UK, too, is having a robust RE-based power
generation programme.
In India, when the Standing Committee of Parliament was
examining the Draft Electricity Bill, the Ministry of Non-
conventional Energy Sources (MNES; presently MNRE) had sug-
gested the incorporation of enabling provisions in the Bill with
a view to promoting the development of non-conventional
energy-based power for the grid. The suggestions included the
mandate for the Central Electricity Regulatory Commission
(CERC) to frame guidelines on ‘preferential’ prices for renewa-
bles by taking into account the avoided cost of negative exter-
nalities associated with fossil fuel-based generation. The need
for promotional measures, such as banking, wheeling and
third-party sales, was also emphasized. There were, at the same
time, suggestions from some other stakeholders to prescribe
specific provision in the Bill for a minimum energy procurement
requirement (say, 10%) from RE sources.7
Issues
However, the Electricity Act, 2003 (EA, 2003)8 did not quite
incorporate these provisions as explicitly as the MNRE would
have preferred. But what it did was to specify that the State
Electricity Regulatory Commission (SERC) must
The Act thus left the modalities of carrying out the task to the
ground-level assessment and professional judgement of the
concerned commissions. The Act also provided for the promo-
tion of renewable as one of the guiding principles for tariff
determination by electricity regulators.
Renewable in India 5
are free under the EA, 2003, to incorporate a surcharge for
cross-subsidies in addition to the wheeling charges, the sub-
sidies referred to are on account of the differential pricing
at the consumer level. But nothing is mentioned in the Act
about how to tackle any increase in average electricity costs
that may take place due to the promotion of RE-based power
as a consequence of states’ RE programmes. Apparently, it
seems that this increase is meant to be a ‘pass-through’ in the
determination of average tariffs to consumers. This means that
consumers must pay for these programmes. Finally, how does
one reconcile with competition in the electricity sector due to
preferential treatment for predetermined sources of energy?
Of course, no Act can provide perfect answers to all possible
contingencies. But, as things stand, the EA, 2003, provided a
novel legal setting that has spurred developments in the Indian
power industry for over a decade now. The Act itself had been
a product of considerable deliberations and debate, both inside
and outside the Parliament, before it was cleared. In fact, in
many ways, it has reflected both the changed global view and
the Indian perception about the nature of the power industry.
As a result, new initiatives have ushered towards creating a
market-friendly structure.
Renewable in India 7
In countries where these utilities were privately owned, it
meant closer vigilance over their operations in the larger public
interest. Where they were brought under public ownership, the
control was more direct. Either way, profits became the regu-
latory focus, giving rise to cost-plus rate-of-return approach.
This has survived all these years and continues to hold sway
even now with regulatory authorities in many countries for
setting tariffs for consumers. With this change, it also became
obligatory on the part of power utilities to supply electricity
to all classes of consumers at predetermined tariffs—universal
service obligation.
Renewable in India 9
of licensees under the Indian Electricity Act, 1910. The second
part, Section 59 of the Electricity (Supply) Act, 1948, pertained
to the retail tariffs to be set by the SEBs. The third, specified by
the central government under Section 43 A(2) of the Electricity
(Supply) Act, 1948, was meant for determining the bulk tariffs
to be charged by the central utilities. The fourth, under Section
43 A(2), was again for bulk tariffs, for state utilities. And the
fifth (Section 41 of the 1948 Act) was for the transmission tar-
iffs to be charged by the utility, for transmitting power to and
across states, through its network. Despite differences, there has
been a fair degree of commonality in all five sets of norms.13
Interestingly, all the Acts have focused on tariffs. In this book
as well, we have discussed tariffs; but from a perspective of
renewable power technologies.
In many ways, the norms reflect the evolution of India’s
power sector over the years. When central power stations came
up in the 1980s against the backdrop of failing health of SEBs
and the inability of states to finance the expansion of power
generation from their own funds, it became necessary to put
in place tariff norms for the supply of power by these stations
to SEBs. In the wake of the resource crunch in the 1990s, it
became even more difficult to finance plans for the expansion
of the power sector with public funds; generation was opened
up to independent power producers (IPPs) to plug the invest-
ment gap. This necessitated the setting up of tariff norms for
the bulk supply of electricity by these producers. Interestingly,
this was also the backdrop against which alternative energy
options began to be more seriously considered for the supply
of electricity to the grid.
Moreover, when it became clear that the IPP policy was
unsustainable due to poor financial health of SEBs—caused by
years of political manipulation of electricity pricing, theft and
inefficiencies—the ERCs Act, 1998, was brought in to ‘stem
the rot’. With this, SERCs assumed the function of approving
electricity tariffs based on the principles laid down in this Act.
In final admission of the fact that the piecemeal legislation was
not enough to grapple with India’s power sector problems, a
Renewable in India 11
segmenting various parts of the industry, has begun to demerge
and change the commercial interface between these segments
and their parts. It has also required different rules for pricing
services in demerged segments. This means that the renewable
power producers, just as others, now have to operate under
altogether different business environments than before. Yet,
in the transitory phase, the interface of these producers with
unbundled utilities has required regulatory oversight for a
variety of reasons.
The regulation in the structurally changed sector in the
future will continue to be based on the following principle:
‘…regulate only those segments which by their nature are not
amenable to competition.’14 Here, regulators so far have had to
act as ‘surrogate’ markets for enforcing the requisite economic
discipline in the absence of markets. One of the main issues,
in so far as RE technologies are concerned, is that regulators
have had to deal with aspects of the markets that could lead to
market failures, hampering the commercial evolution of these
technologies.
At a different level, regulators have strived to refrain from
resorting to the cost-of-service regulation in sectors that are
competitive. But this has not been easy. Whereas in sectors
that require price regulation (or support), prices have had to
be set at sufficiently high levels to enable power producers to
earn enough to meet their investment needs, but low enough
to spur them to improve their efficiency in order to maintain
profitability. To achieve this, the regulatory bodies have had
to strive towards knowing the power industry as well as the
industry itself in order to enforce the regulations.
The regulation of tariffs of electricity from renewable sources
has continued to be of importance since the EA, 2003, came
into being. However, the direction of regulation has taken a
decisive turn in recent years. The focus has changed gradually
towards imparting greater market orientation to this sector.
There has been a growing stress on evolving a market in
this sector in a manner that the overall value of green power is
Chapter Conclusion
Renewable has taken centre stage in the discussion on the
power sector in India. The ambitious target of renewable capac-
ity addition would require the mobilization of investments
both in RE capacity and in the supporting infrastructure—a
herculean task indeed in the limited available time (target of
175 GW by 2022). However, even if this seems difficult, the
emphasis on accelerated RE capacity addition in the system is
expected to persist over a decade to come.
It must be emphasized that pricing of electricity is central
to the efficient functioning of any industry, and much of the
regulatory process in India has been devoted to addressing this
seemingly complex issue, since the EA, 2003, came into opera-
tion. However, this book focuses on pricing in those segments
of renewable electricity generation, namely solar and wind
energy, which produce electricity on mass marketable scale.
Within the renewable technology sector, these generation
technologies have proved to be the most successful of all the
available technologies in mass commercialization worldwide.
Hence, much of the regulatory effort has been on supporting
and facilitating the induction of these technologies into the
national market defined by the state and the national grids.
Having set the context, the focus in the next chapter is on how
structural reforms have shaped the electricity industry and, in
turn, impacted the commercial viability of renewable.
Notes
1. http://cea.nic.in/reports/monthly/executivesummary/2020/
exe_summary-03.pdf (accessed on 8 February 2021).
2. Ibid., 4.
3. Ibid., 14.
Renewable in India 13
4. https://www.power-technology.com/features/wind-energy-by-
country/ (accessed on 4 December 2019).
5. http://cea.nic.in/reports/monthly/executivesummary/2020/
exe_summary-02.pdf (accessed on 9 May 2019), 14.
6. Rahul Tongia and Samantha Gross, ‘Working to Turn Ambition
into Reality, the Politics and Economics of India’s Turn to
Renewable Power’ (Working Paper No. 4, Brookings, Washington,
DC, 2018), 4.
7. Standing Committee on Energy, Thirteenth Lok Sabha, ‘Ministry of
Power Thirty-first Report, the Electricity Bill, 2001’ (2002). Available
at https://eparlib.nic.in/bitstream/123456789/63654/1/13_
Energy_31.pdf (accessed on 18 November 2020).
8. https://powermin.nic.in/sites/default/files/uploads/The%20
Electricity%20Act_2003.pdf (accessed on 18 November 2020).
9. Ackermann, Thomas (First Draft 1999), Distributed Power
Generation in a De-regulated market Environment, Part I, Working
Paper, Royal Institute of Technology, Stockholm, Sweden. pp 14.
10. Ackermann, Thomas (2004), Distributed Resources in a Re-regulated
Market, Doctoral Thesis. KTH Electrical Engineering, Stockholm,
Sweden. pp 54.
11. Ackermann, Thomas (First Draft 1999), Distributed Power
Generation in a De-regulated Market Environment, Part 1, Working
Paper, Royal Institute of Technology, Stockholm, Sweden, pp 16.
12. Ackermann, Thomas (First Draft 1999), Distributed Power
Generation in a De-regulated Market Environment, Part 1, Working
Paper, Royal Institute of Technology, Stockholm, Sweden, pp 16.
13. S. S. Ahluwalia and Gaurav Bhatiani, ‘Tariff Setting in the Electric
Power Sector’, in The Indian Case Study in Regulation in Infrastructure
Services: Progress and the Way Forward, ed., S. K. Sarkar and Kaushik
Deb (New Delhi: TERI, 2001), 67–104.
14. Ibid.
Structural Reforms in
Power Sector
Implication for Renewable
Introduction
The electricity industry structure has evolved over the years
and has witnessed significant changes, especially during the
last three decades. This chapter traces structural reforms in the
power sector across major economies of the world, compares
against Indian experience and reflects on the impact of such
reforms on the commercial viability of renewable.
Breaking Monopoly
During the first wave of liberalization in the 1990s, govern-
ments across the world began to reassess the structure of the
electricity industry. An understanding that electricity is as trad-
able a commodity as any other was one of the influences behind
these developments. It was argued that once a monopoly over
wires and dispatch was suitably set apart and controlled, elec-
tricity could be competitively supplied at wholesale and retail
levels. Based on this logic, many countries went ahead with
the task of developing competitive markets in the generation
and retail segments in their own power sectors. Some govern-
ments also viewed privatization and competitive markets as a
God-sent opportunity for reducing involvement in their own
power sector. Deeply steeped in debts as they were, many were
no longer in a position to finance the future expansion of their
power sectors. They, therefore, used this as a means to transfer
at least part of their responsibilities to private participants.
In one of the earliest attempts at introducing competition
in the power sector, competitive bidding route was adopted
for investments in generation. The main purpose behind this
was to get private parties to invest in generation while leaving
the complex matter of network operations and long-term plan-
ning with the central organization. From the point of view of
RE technologies, one of the major difficulties with this process
was getting the organizers to accept new technologies in the
tendering norms.1 Moreover, it was costly and cumbersome for
small-scale players to get themselves involved in this process.
Yet it would be foolish to believe that changes in the sector were
being initiated solely with small-scale renewable technologies in
mind. These markets, in fact, had overgrown the scale and were
ready to absorb enterprises in large numbers, irrespective of the
technologies or plant sizes they chose to bring into the market.
The next attempt was to give open access to generators for
wheeling of power on transmission lines, against payments for
transmission charges and the fulfilment of certain technical
requirements for the grid connection. The high cost of setting up
wheeling contracts, especially in the case of smaller players, and
the option available to transmission companies for refusing con-
tracts on technical grounds, significantly hampered the develop-
ment of competitive markets in the process of generation.
Competitive Markets
The preoccupation with creating competitive markets stems
from the well-established principle of economics, which pos-
tulates that, in normal circumstances, markets are the most
effective means for efficiently allocating resources between
Unbundling in India
The tariff-setting mechanisms have varied across countries,
depending on which of the several approaches they have
adopted in pursuing electricity reforms. But the main issue
in the context of unbundling with RE technologies has been:
can these technologies cope with the structural reforms that
are taking place in the power sector around the world and, if
so, how? At the time when the Indian power sector is being
reformed, the issue pertaining to competition and market
Chapter Conclusion
The structural reforms, especially the breaking of the monopoly
and the ushering in competition, leave a significant commercial
impact on renewable. Renewable, when weighed against only its
investment cost and variability, appears to be non-competitive.
The financial cost comparison between renewable and con-
ventional plants makes renewable look expensive (though
trend is changing in recent times). However, if one considers
the low short-run cost of renewable and also the factors in the
external costs (environmental costs), renewable turns out to be
more cost-effective. The need is to recognize these realities and
not only to protect in the restructured system the investments
made in the past but also to create conducive environment for
renewable to sustain with its long-term positive effects. It is in
this context that the next chapter details the various promo-
tional policies experimented in different parts of the world and
compares them with those in India with a focus on the impact
of such policies on the market creation for renewable.
Notes
1. Thomas Ackermann, ‘Distributed Resources in a Re-regulated
Market’ (Doctoral Thesis, KTH Electrical Engineering, Stockholm,
Sweden, 2004), 74.
2. Steve D. Thomas, ‘Tariff Setting in Privatised British Electricity
Industry’, in The Indian case Study in Regulation in Infrastructure
Services: Progress and the Way Forward, ed., S. K. Sarkar and Kaushik
Deb (New Delhi: TERI, 2001), 105–118.
3. Review of Electricity Trading Arrangements Background Paper 1
Electricity Trading Arrangements in England and Wales (February
1998). https://www.ofgem.gov.uk/ofgem-publications/79088/
Policies Supporting
Renewable
Aid to Market Formation
Introduction
Nations across the world have come up with policies promoting
renewable. These policies have reiterated the need for special
treatment for renewable, and the support has ranged from fiscal
incentive, capital subsidies, feed-in tariff (FIT) guaranteeing grid
access and fixed tariff, to concessional transmission pricing and
so on. India is no exception. This chapter captures the global
policies supporting renewable, dwells at length on Indian ini-
tiatives and presents a perspective on how these policies have
helped market creation for renewable.
Tariff Setting
Even as the Act listed the guiding factors for the tariff-setting
exercise to be taken up by the ERCs, there has been an extensive
debate over the suitability of applying various cost concepts in
arriving at bulk tariffs for the grid supply. Typically, the debates
have reflected the difference of opinion between practitioners
and economists.
Complicating the issue further—which is particularly rel-
evant to RE pricing—has been the notion of fairness. On the
one hand, these sources are not given due credit for their non-
polluting aspects. On the other hand, as the commercial cost
of producing electricity from these sources has been, on aver-
age, higher than that for conventionally produced electricity,
a question that has often come up is what impact these would
have on retail tariffs if the costs are allowed to pass through to
that level. And, if not, what would their impact be on the state
governments’ finances, as the subsidy would ultimately have
to be borne by them.
But the complication does not end here. As mentioned ear-
lier, these technologies have been still commercially evolving.
With economies of scale, their supply costs have been falling;
though not sufficiently to make them competitive commer-
cially with conventional technologies. Until they achieve
competitiveness with respect to these technologies, someone
Transmission Pricing
With the stipulation of unbundling and non-discriminatory
open access in the Act, the relationship between utilities and
renewable units described above changed, at least on paper.
These units have, in the new structure, been dealing with not
the former vertically integrated utilities but with unbundled
identities such as transmission utilities or licensees, or distribu-
tion entities. In this background, transmission facilities would
have to be built upon the expectation that such investment
would eventually be recovered through appropriate rate-making
procedures. In this respect, CERC has provided guidance, which
Chapter Conclusion
RE technologies are inherently different from conventional
resources on account of their variability, substantially lower
capacity utilization factor and high capital cost but low short-
run cost. It’s obvious, therefore, that nations across the globe
have carved out special dispensations for renewable with due
regard to their importance for environmental protection. These
dispensations, especially on pricing and special network access
rights, have laid the foundation for their mainstreaming with
the market operation in general. While the focus of this chapter
was on large-scale grid-connected renewable projects, a separate
discussion is considered necessary on small-scale distributed
energy resources, given the differences in their dynamics.
Accordingly, the next chapter discusses policies supporting
various business models and pricing strategy for distributed
energy systems.
Notes
1. Ackermann, ‘Distributed Power Generation in a De-regulated
Market Environment’, 55.
2. European Wind Energy Association and Greenpeace, ‘Wind Force
12’, 14.
3. Michael J. Zucchet, ‘Renewable Resource Electricity in the Changing
Regulatory Environment’, Renewable Energy Annual (1995): 25.
Available at https://inis.iaea.org/collection/NCLCollectionStore/_
Public/27/045/27045864.pdf (accessed on 8 February 2021).
4. Ibid., 26.
Distributed Energy
Resources
Business Models and
Market Dynamics
Introduction
Small-scale distributed renewable energy (DRE) systems are
placed differently compared to large-scale renewable projects.
The former involves a direct interface with end consumers
and in remote rural areas where the grid may or may not have
reached. Such ventures, intertwined as they are with socio-
economic milieu of the population and being dependent on
locally available renewable resources, need different treatment
in terms of policy and regulatory support. This chapter traces
initiatives in this regard in India, compares them against poli-
cies in other parts of the world, with focus on business models
and pricing of electricity from such distributed energy resource-
based projects.
Distributed energy resources are generally referred to as
resources that can provide services locally at the consumer
end, at the distribution level and could be off-grid or grid-
connected. In the international literature, resources such as
demand response, storage systems, electric vehicles and solar
photovoltaic (PV) cells are included in the discussion on distrib-
uted energy resources. There are a number of business models
around this concept and across different parts of the world, for
example, market-based and utility-supported demand response,
behind-the-meter energy storage, network service-based energy
storage, solar plus storage model, to name a few.1 However,
given the central theme of the book, we largely cover policy
interventions and business models on off-grid solutions, fol-
lowed by mini- and micro-grid and grid-connected rooftop
systems (RTS).
Distributed energy sources, decentralized generation and
stand-alone systems are often used interchangeably. The EA,
2003, has provisions for the framing of policies by the cen-
tral government on stand-alone systems for rural areas and
non-conventional energy systems (Section 4 of the EA, 2003).
Stand-alone systems have been defined as systems involving the
generation and distribution of electricity without connectivity
to the grid. Similarly, there are provisions for the national-level
policy on electrification and local distribution (Section 5).
Emphasis has been laid on the use of local institutions such
as panchayat institutions, non-governmental organizations,
franchisees, user associations, cooperative societies for such
decentralized generation and distribution. In fact, facilitative
frameworks like license exemptions have also been provided for
such ventures (Section 13, 8th Proviso to Section 14). For rural
areas notified by the state government, distributed generation
involving generation and distribution can be undertaken with-
out the requirement of any license. This is meant to facilitate
the ease of business in these areas. The Revised Tariff Policy
(2016) makes special mention of micro-grids for rural areas
where grid connectivity has not reached. It seeks to address the
concerns of investors in the event of grid reaching such areas
Micro-grid
Apart from the initiatives to promote bulk-size solar plants and
wind farms of similar capacities to states’/national grids, the
Indian government has also been encouraging installations
of distributed energy systems on a smaller scale. Broadly, the
distributed segment of the RE generation is made up of two
sub-segments: one consisting of scattered rural hamlets and
the other of industrial units with expansive roofs from the
consumer side.
The rooftop installations offer the scope to harness solar
energy commercially, both for captive consumption and for the
supply to power grids for mass consumption. This sub-segment
is discussed later in the chapter. First, we focus on stand-alone
micro-grids as a means of commercially delivering electricity
to small hamlets for their commercial (small shops) and resi-
dential needs.
Chapter Conclusion
Official claims notwithstanding, a substantial portion of
households in India still do not have access to energy. Taking
the grid to remote areas is not only cost prohibitive but also
non-sustainable in terms of quantity as well quality of supply.
The DISCOMs whose finances are already in the red do not
have inherent interest in supplying electricity to such areas
because non-remunerative tariff for the supply of electricity
in these areas further strains their finances. It is, therefore,
imperative that business models supporting distributed
energy systems and seeking to harness locally available renew-
able resources are encouraged. The financial health of the
DISCOMs and the distorted tariff structure also come in the
way of supporting distributed energy sources like rooftop solar
PV projects. The subsiding consumers, mostly in urban areas,
opt for such systems and the DISCOMs resent because a reduc-
tion of demand from such consumers upon their installation
of rooftop solar PV systems leads to irreparable revenue loss
for them. The solution therefore lies in larger tariff reforms,
by way of tariff rationalization, so as to address the constraints
of distributed energy systems. Having dealt with policy initia-
tives for the promotion of large-scale renewable in the previ-
ous chapter and small-scale distributed energy systems in this
chapter, the next chapter and subsequent chapters present a
detailed analysis of core policy and regulatory interventions,
namely RE pricing, RPO and market mechanisms like renew-
able energy certificate (REC) and the overall market design
for renewable. Discussions in these chapters are central to the
theme of this book besides the findings and recommendations
in the last chapter.
Renewable Energy
Pricing in India
What Is Missing?
Introduction
Pricing has all along been at the centre stage of the discus-
sion in the context of the development of RE. In the major
economies of the world, fixed price support is extended as
supply side push for renewable, which in a way obviates the
need for RPO as a demand-side support. In others, RPS—a
combination of RPO and REC mechanism—is adopted as a
support mechanism for the promotion of RE. The RPS system
does not provide fixed price support as renewable projects
under this scheme are expected to participate in the whole-
sale market for the sale of their electricity components. The
unique distinction of India lies in the fact that the country has
used all three instruments, namely fixed price, RPO and REC
mechanism, for the encouragement of renewable. This chapter
covers the pricing aspect, while the next chapter focuses on
RPO, and the following chapter discusses the REC framework
in the Indian context.
As regards the pricing of renewable, there are two broad
approaches, namely the cost-plus approach of the tariff deter-
mination by the regulator and the competitive approach of
discovering price through auction. The question as to whether
auction as a method of price discovery is suitable for intermittent
RE sources such as wind and solar has been and continues to be
a subject of debate. Proponents of cost-plus approach argue that,
given the uncertainties around the availability and variability of
wind and solar resources, there are likely chances of projections
going wrong, thereby making auction a tenuous exercise fraught
with risk. The advocates of competition argue, on the other hand,
that auction is the only way of discovering the efficient cost of
such installations. In so far as uncertainties and variability are
concerned, these aspects can be suitably addressed in the auc-
tion design through equitable allocation of risks between the
project developers and the buyers. They also argue that competi-
tive bidding has the advantage of inducing technological and
operational improvements, in that the bidders are impelled to
invest more in better technology and forecasting techniques to
minimize the risks arising out of variability.
India has experimented with both cost-plus approach and
auction for soliciting renewable project proposals. Several states
in India still determine cost-plus tariff for wind and solar while,
at the national level, auction has of late become the norm for
setting up wind and solar projects. An important point to note
here is that, whether cost-plus or auction, the tariff so arrived
remains fixed generally over the useful life of the project,
thereby providing long-term certainty for investors.
This chapter deals with both of these methods of tariff deter-
mination for renewable with all their nuances. This discussion is
critical not only from the point of view of understating the cost
and operational dynamics of variable RE but also for appreciat-
ing the debate around the future market design for renewable
discussed at length in a later chapter.
Auction
Auction theory has been the basis of much fundamental theo-
retical work: it has been important in developing our under-
standing of other methods of price formation, for example,
negotiations in which both the buyer and the seller are actively
involved in determining price.
As discussed so far, one of the most important issues facing
Indian electricity regulators has been the pricing of electricity
generated from grid-connected renewable energy sources, espe-
cially from wind and solar power farms, which have been the
main thrust areas of the Indian government’s RE policy. Over
the years, there has been an ongoing debate on the practical
applicability of applying marginal cost pricing to electricity
Overview
There has been a considerable effort by economists to find the
economic basis for auctions and to examine the conditions
that lead to optimal auctions. There are four standard types of
auctions that are generally deployed for discovering the price of
objects of economic value, namely the ascending bid auctions,
the descending bid auctions, the first-price sealed-bid auctions
and the second-price sealed-bid auctions.
Of these, the sealed-bid auctions are most commonly used by
governments for identifying suppliers for their requirements.
e-Reverse Auction
So what constitutes an eRA and how effective has it been in
fulfilling the objectives of the nodal agency, the SECI, which
conducts these auctions? In the simplest form of eRA, the buyer
selects a supplier for supplying a range of products and services
from a list of pre-qualified developers by employing the online
bidding process. The bidders in this auction get to see each
other’s bid values during the bidding process and adjust their
own values downwards, if they feel necessary, to remain in con-
tention. The process continues until a lowest price bid emerges.
The contract is thus finally awarded to the lowest price bidder.
On comparisons with the standard auctions, the eRA design
followed by the SECI in India, though not exactly the same
as that recommended by Klemperer (1998), is broadly simi-
lar. The bidding process is conducted in two stages. The first
stage is a sealed-online bid that can be thought of as a version
of the clock stage. The tender applicants who have met the
prior mentioned technical and financial requirements in the
‘request for selection (RFS)‘ documents qualify to bid at this
stage. These pre-qualified developers have to bid in an online
sealed envelope below the ceiling price specified in the RFS
document, mentioning the wind or solar power capacity they
wish to undertake to develop at their bid price.
The sealed envelopes containing the bidding informa-
tion are opened online on a specified date mentioned in the
tender. The bids are then ranked, starting with the lowest price
Chinese Approach
After using the FIT approach to pricing electricity for promoting
commercialization of RE power generation for several years,6
China shifted to auctions in 2003. It realized that the com-
petitive bidding approach as a price discovery mechanism to
support the setting up of a nationwide tariff for solar and wind
power farms made greater economic sense than persisting with
the FITs, which it had done until then.
However, alarmed by the rashness of the inexperienced bid-
ders, it entirely reworked its price criterion to benefit the bids
Chapter Conclusion
This chapter presented a comprehensive case study on the
formation of the benchmark for capital costs for renewable
technologies at the CERC and a comparative analysis of the
cost-plus and auction routes of tariff discovery for renewable.
For reasons explained in the previous chapter, while, from the
point of view of economic theorists, methods such as LRMCs
may be the most appropriate theoretically for forming tariffs,
they are not practicable.
Notes
1. http://cercind.gov.in/2020/draft_reg/DEM-RE-Tariff-Regulations2020.
pdf (accessed on 9 February 2021).
2. A private model is that in which each bidder knows how much he/
she values an item under auction, but this value is private informa-
tion to him/her.
• In the common value model, the actual value is common to all,
but the bidders in auction have different private information
about what the actual value is. In this situation, each bidder is
inclined to revise the estimate of his/her value after knowing
any of the other bidders’ signals.
• Finally, a general model encompasses both of the above cases
as special cases but allows each bidder’s value to be a general
function of all signals.
3. Michael R. Mullen, Tamara Dinev, John L. Hopkins and Dennis
F. Kehoe, ‘Evidence of Revenue Equivalence in B2B Open, Reverse
e-Auctions and First Price Sealed Bids’ (2008). Available at http://
www.jgbm.org/page/48%20MichaelMullen.pdf (accessed on
9 February 2021).
References
Auction Theory: A Guide to Literature, The Economic Theory of Auction,
P Klemperer (ed), Edward Elgar (Pub), Cheltanham, UK, Yr2000.
Ausubel L, P Cramton and P Milgrom, The Clock Proxy Auction; A
Practical Combinatorial Auction Deisign, in Peter Cramton, Yoav
Shoham and Richard Steingerg (ed), Combinatorial Auction, MIT
Press 2006
Bulow J J and Roberts D J (1989), The Simple Economics of Optimal
Auctions, Journal of Political Economy, 1060–90.
Indian Institute of Management (IIM), Lucknow, Analysing Tariff Based
e-Reverse Auction versus Closed Bidding in Wind and Solar Sectors,
Report Submitted to the Ministry of New and Renewable Energy.
Klemperer, P D (1998), Auctions with Almost Common Value, European
Economic Review, 42.
Klemperer, P D (1998), Auctions with Almost Common Value, European
Economic Review.
Myerson R B (1981), Optimal Auction Design, Mathematics of Operation
Research, 6, 58–73.
Peter Cramton (2009), Spectrum Auction Design, University of
Maryland, Dept of Economics, August 15, 2009, 30 pages.
Peter Cramton (2009), Spectrum Auction Design, University of
Maryland, Dept of Economics, August 15, 2009, 30 pages.
Riley J G and Samuelson W F (1981), Optimal Auction, American
Economic Review, 71, 381–92.
1. Levelized tariff with 2 Sep 2019– 1. Levelized tariff with 2 Sep 2019–
AD 6.51 2019 2020 AD 6.63 2019 2020 (for
2. Levelized tariff without 2. Levelized tariff without gross
AD 7.04 AD 7.16 metering)
2 Andhra 1. Levelized tariff with 30 Mar 2017–
Pradesh AD 4.35 2017 2018
2. Levelized tariff without
AD 4.76
3 Assam 16 Nov 2016–
2016 2017
4 Bihar 4.17 1 Apr 2019–
2019 2020
5 Chandigarh 1. Levelized tariff with 2 Sep 2019– 1. Levelized tariff with 2 Sep 2019–
AD 4.82 2019 2020 AD 4.88 2019 2020 (for
2. Levelized tariff without 2. Levelized tariff without gross
AD 5.22 AD 5.27 metering)
(Appendix 5A Continued)
(Appendix 5A Continued)
1 SECI 5 Mytrah Energy India Private Limited 250 2017 February 3.46
Wind-I Green Infra Wind Energy Limited 249.9 3.46
1000
MW Inox Wind Infrastructure Services Limited 250 3.46
Ostro Kutch Wind Private Limited 250 3.46
Adani Green Energy (MP) Limited 50 3.46
2 GUVNL 8 Sprng Energy Pvt Ltd 197.5 2017 November 2.43
500 MW K. P. Energy Ltd 30 2.43
Verdant Renewable Pvt Ltd 100 2.44
Betam Wind Energy Pvt Ltd 29.9 2.44
Powerica Limited 50 2.44
Renew Power Ventures Pvt Ltd 35.7 2.45
Oil India Limited 18.9 2.43
SJVN Limited 38 2.43
(Appendix 5B Continued)
(Appendix 5B Continued)
Wind Quantum
Sr. Developer (MW) Tender Winning
No Auction Number Wind Developer Name Won Year- Month Tariff
3 SECI 5 ReNew Power Ventures Private Limited 250 2017 October 2.64
Wind-II Orange Sironj Wind Power Private 200 2.64
1000 Limited
MW
Inox Wind Infrastructure Services 250 2.65
Limited
Green Infra Wind Energy Limited 250 2.65
Adani Green Energy (MP) Limited 50 2.65
4 MSEDCL 6 Adani Green Energy 75 2018 March 2.85
500 MW KCT Renewable Energy Private Limited 75 2.85
Inox Wind 50 2.86
Mytrah Energy 100 2.86
Hero Wind Energy Private Limited 75.6 2.86
Torrent Power Limited 124.4 2.87
5 SECI-III 7 ReNew Power Ventures Private Limited 400 2018 February 2.44
2000 Green Infra Wind Energy Limited 300 2.44
MW
Inox Wind Infrastructure Services Limited 200 2.44
Torrent Power Limited 499.8 2.44
Adani Green Energy (MP) Limited 250 2.45
Alfanar Company 300 2.45
Betam Wind Energy Pvt Ltd 50.2 2.45
6 SECI-IV 8 Srijan Energy Systems Private Limited 250 2018 April 2.51
2000 Sprng Energy Private Limited 300 2.51
MW
BLP Energy Private Limited 285 2.51
Betam Wind Energy Private Limited 200 2.51
Inox Wind Infrastructure Services Limited 100 2.51
Adani Green Energy (MP) Limited 250 2.51
Mytrah Energy (India) Private Limited 300 2.52
Renew Wind Energy (TN) Private Limited 300 2.52
(Appendix 5B Continued)
(Appendix 5B Continued)
Wind Quantum
Sr. Developer (MW) Tender Winning
No Auction Number Wind Developer Name Won Year- Month Tariff
7 NTPC 6 Sprng Vayu Vidyut Private Limited 200 2018 August 2.77
2000 Mytrah Energy 300 2.79
MW
(allocated Srijan Energy 50 2.80
1200 ReNew Wind Energy 300 2.81
MW) Hero Wind Energy Private Limited 300 2.82
Fasten Power 50 2.83
8 SECI-V 5 Torrent Power Limited 115 2018 September 2.76
1200 Adani Green Energy Limited 300 2.76
MW
Alfanar Company 300 2.77
Sitac Kabini Renewables Limited 300 2.77
Ecoren Energy India Private Limited 175 2.77
9 SECI-VI 6 Adani Renewable Energy Park (Gujarat) 250 2019 February 2.82
1200 Limited
MW Ostro Energy Private Limited 300 2.82
Srijan Energy System Private Limited 150 2.82
Powerica Limited 50.6 2.82
Zenataris Renewable Energy Private 125 2.83
Limited
SBESS Services Projectco Two Private 324.4 2.83
Limited
10 GUVNL-II 8 Anisha Power Projects Pvt Ltd 40 2019 January 2.80
1000 MW Powerica Ltd 50.6 2.80
(allocated
745 MW) Vena Energy Shivalik Wind Power Pvt 100 2.80
Ltd
Sarjan Realities Ltd 100.8 2.87
Viridi Clean Alternatives Pvt Ltd 100 2.95
Inox Wind Energy 40 2.95
Renew Wind Energy (Karnataka Two) 200 2.95
Pvt Ltd
Adani Renewable Energy Park (Gujarat) 113.6 2.95
Ltd
(Appendix 5B Continued)
(Appendix 5B Continued)
Wind Quantum
Sr. Developer (MW) Tender Winning
No Auction Number Wind Developer Name Won Year- Month Tariff
11 SECI-VII 4 Betam Wind Energy Private limited 200 2019 February 2.79
1200 Ostro Energy Private Limited 50 2.81
MW
(allocated Sprng Vaayu Urja Private Limited 100 2.82
480 MW) Adani Renewable Energy Park (Gujarat) 130 2.83
Limited
12 SECI-VIII 2 China Light and Power (CLP) 250 2019 September 2.83
1800 Italian energy company Enel 190 2.84
MW
(allocated
440 MW)
2.73
Source: Compiled by the authors from various public sources, e.g. Orders of State Electricity Regulatory Commissions,
websites of MNRE, SECI etc.
Appendix 5C Bid Tariff (Solar)
Solar Quantum
Sr. Developer (MW) Tender Winning
No Auction Number Solar Developer Name Won Year- Month Tariff
Solar Quantum
Sr. Developer (MW) Tender Winning
No Auction Number Solar Developer Name Won Year- Month Tariff
6 TANGEDCO 16 NLC India 709 2017 September 3.47
1500 MW Raasi Green Energy 100 3.47
Solitaire BTN Solar (HPPPL) 100 3.47
Narbheram Vishram (Atha Group) 100 3.47
Rays Power Infra 100 3.47
NVR Energy (Atha Group) 100 3.47
ReNew Solar 100 3.47
Sai Jyoti Infrastructure Ventures 54 3.47
Talettutayi Solar Projects Two 50 3.47
(Solar Arise)
Shapoorji Pallonji Infra 50 3.47
GR Thanga Maligai Firm (GRT) 10 3.47
GR Thanga Maligai & Sons (GRT) 10 3.47
GRT Silverwares (GRT) 10 3.47
Dynamize Solar 5 3.47
Sunlight (Udayasooriyan) 1 3.47
Dev International 1 3.47
7 SECI 250 MW 2 Azure Power India Private Limited 200 2017 December 2.48
ReNew Solar Power Private Limited 50 2.49
8 SECI 500 MW 2 Hero Solar Energy Private Limited 300 2017 December 2.47
SBE Four Limited 200 2.48
9 GUVNL 500 4 GRT Jewellers India Pvt Ltd 90 2017 September 2.65
MW Gujarat State Electricity 75 2.66
Corporation Ltd
Gujarat Industries Power Company 75 2.67
Ltd
Azure Power India Pvt Ltd 260 2.67
10 MAHAGENCO 2 Azure Power 200 2018 May 3.07
300 MW Shapoorji Pallonji 50 3.26
(allocated 250
MW)
11 KREDL 860 11 Shapoorji Pallonji 185 2018 February 2.94–
MW (allocated 3.07
760 MW) ACME Solar 106 2.94–
3.15
Asian Fab Tec 85 3.24–
3.34
(Appendix 5C Continued)
(Appendix 5C Continued)
Solar Quantum
Sr. Developer (MW) Tender Winning
No Auction Number Solar Developer Name Won Year- Month Tariff
Emmvee 80 3.52–
3.54
ReNew Power 99 3.15–
3.28
Greenko 45 3.30–
3.36
TEP Rooftop Solar 55 3.04–
3.07
Ekialde Solar 35 3.15–
3.19
Rays Power Infra 30 3.16–
3.20
Max Planck Solar 20 3.12–
3.31
Svarog Global 20 3.54
12 APDCL 100 2 Azure Power 75 2018 June 3.37
MW (allocated Maheswari Mining and Energy Pvt 10 3.19
85 MW) Ltd
13 KREDL 550 3 ReNew Power 300 2018 March 2.91
MW Avaada Energy 150 2.92
Azure Power 100 2.93
14 SECI 750 MW 3 SB Energy Seven Private Limited 250 2018 July 2.70
Sprng Soura Kiran Vidyut Private 250 2.70
Limited
Ayana Renewable Power Private 250 2.71
Limited
15 SECI 200 MW 1 SBE Renewables Twenty Five 250 2018 May 2.82
Private Limited
16 SECI -I 2000 6 ACME Solar Holdings Limited 600 2018 July 2.44
MW Shapoorji Pallonji Infrastructure 250 2.52
Capital Company Private Limited
Hero Solar Energy Private Limited 250 2.53
Mahindra Susten Private Limited 250 2.53
Azure Power India Pvt Ltd 600 2.53
Mahoba Solar (UP) Private Limited 50 2.54
(Appendix 5C Continued)
(Appendix 5C Continued)
Solar Quantum
Sr. Developer (MW) Tender Winning
No Auction Number Solar Developer Name Won Year- Month Tariff
17 SECI-II 3000 1 ACME Solar Holdings Limited 600 2018 July 2.44
MW (allocated
600 MW)
18 NTPC 750 3 Sprng Energy 250 2018 May 2.72
MW Ayana Renewable Power 250 2.73
SB Energy 250 2.73
19 NTPC 2000 4 ACME Solar 600 2018 August 2.59
MW (allocated Shapoorji Pallonji 500 2.59
1400 MW)
Azure Power 300 2.59
SB Energy 600 2.60
20 KREDL 650 2 Fortum Corporation 250 2018 July 2.85
MW (allocated Tata Power Renewable Energy Ltd 250 2.85
500 MW) (TPREL)
21 MSEDCL 4 Shapoorji Pallonji Infrastructure 80 2018 November 3.09–
1000 MW Capital versus Shapoorji Pallonji 3.15
(allocated 235 Infrastructure Capital Company Pvt
MW) Ltd
TPSOL RESCO Three Pvt Ltd 50 3.13
Kintech Synergy Pvt Ltd 5 3.15
Juniper Green Energy Pvt Ltd 100 3.15
(formerly AT Capital Advisory India
Pvt Ltd)
22 MSEDCL 6 JLTM Energy India Private Limited 20 2018 May 2.71
1000 MW Mahoba Solar (UP) Private Limited 200 2.71
(Adani)
ReNew Power 250 2.72
ACME Solar 250 2.72
Tata Power Renewable Energy 150 2.72
Limited
Azure Power 130 2.72
(Appendix 5C Continued)
(Appendix 5C Continued)
Solar Quantum
Sr. Developer (MW) Tender Winning
No Auction Number Solar Developer Name Won Year- Month Tariff
23 GRIDCO 200 5 Aditya Birla Renewables 75 2018 July 2.79
MW Sukhbir Agro 25 3.19
Gupta Power 20 3.19
Eden Renewables 50 3.19
ACME Solar 30 3.2
24 OREDA (6 1 Azure Power 6 2018 September 3.13
MW)
25 GUVNL 500 3 Aditya Birla Renewables Limited 100 2018 September 2.44
MW Avaada Sunrise Energy Pvt Ltd 300 2.44
(SPV of Giriraj Renewables Private
Limited)
Gaya Solar (Bihar) Pvt Ltd (SPV of 100 2.44
Adani Green Energy Ltd)
26 KREDL 150 1 Giriraj Renewables 150 2018 October 2.92
MW
27 KREDL 200 1 Asian Fab Tec 100 2018 October 2.89
MW (allocated
100 MW)
28 UPNEDA 500 9 NTPC 140 2018 November 3.17
MW Maheswari Mining and Energy Pvt 20 3.17
Ltd
Mahoba Solar 50 3.19
Maheswari Mining and Energy PVT 20 3.19
Ltd
Energy PVT Ltd 20 3.19
Sukhbir Agro Energy Ltd 50 3.20
Talettutayi Solar Projects Five Pvt 50 3.21
Ltd
Eden Renewable 50 3.21
Giriraj Renewables Pvt Ltd 100 3.23
29 UPNEDA 550 9 NTPC 85 2018 December 3.02
MW EDF (Bastille Solar) 70 3.04
EDF (Bastille Solar) 70 3.07
Avaada (Giriraj Renewables) 100 3.07
(Appendix 5C Continued)
(Appendix 5C Continued)
Solar Quantum
Sr. Developer (MW) Tender Winning
No Auction Number Solar Developer Name Won Year- Month Tariff
Jakson Power 50 3.07
Adani (Mahoba Solar) 50 3.07
Tata Power Renewable Energy 50 3.07
Limited (TPREL)
Tata Power Renewable Energy 50 3.08
Limited (TPREL)
Adani (Mahoba Solar) 25 3.08
30 KREDL 100 2 Think Energy Partners (TEPSOL) 80 2019 January 2.91
MW Shapoorji Pallonji Infrastructure 20 2.91
Capital Company (SP Infra)
31 SECI 129 MW 1 Bharat Heavy Electricals Limited 129 2019 January 4.38
32 MSEDCL 4 Shiv Solar Private Limited 50 2019 May 2.74
1000 MW ACME Solar 300 2.74
Renew Power 300 2.75
Avaada Energy 350 2.75
33 GUVNL 500 5 Paryapt Solar Energy Private 50 2019 February 2.55
MW Limited
Gujarat State Energy Corporation 75 2.67
Limited
Juniper Green Energy Private Limited 120 2.67
Adani Renewable Energy Park 150 2.67
(Gujarat) Limited
Renew Solar Power Private Limited 105 2.68
34 SECI-III 1200 4 ReNew Solar Power Private Ltd 300 2019 February 2.55
MW Azure Power India Pvt Ltd 300 2.58
Eden Renewable Site Private Limited 300 2.6
SBSR Power Cleantech Eleven 300 2.61
Private Limited
35 SECI-750 MW 5 Fortum Solar 250 2019 March 2.48
Palimarwar Solar House (LNB 40 2.49
GROUP)
ACME Solar 250 2.49
Sitara Solar Energy (UPC 100 2.49
Renewables)
ReNew Power 110 2.49
(Appendix 5C Continued)
(Appendix 5C Continued)
Solar Quantum
Sr. Developer (MW) Tender Winning
No Auction Number Solar Developer Name Won Year- Month Tariff
36 GUVNL-III 700 4 Electro Solar Private Limited 200 2019 May 2.65
MW (allocated Gujarat State Energy Corporation 100 2.68
500 MW) Limited
Gujarat Industries Power Company 100 2.68
Limited
Tata Power Renewable Energy 100 2.7
Limited
37 SECI-250 MW 3 Talettutayi Solar (Solar Arise) 50 2019 May 2.87
Tata Power 100 2.88
NTPC 100 2.91
38 GUVNL 1000 1 Tata Power Renewable Energy 250 2019 May 2.75
MW (allocated Limited
250 MW)
39 SECI-IV 1200 4 Ayana Renewable Power Private 300 2019 June 2.54
MW Limited
ReNew Solar Power Private Ltd 300 2.54
Azure Power Maple Pvt Ltd 300 2.54
Mahindra Susten Private Limited 250 2.54
40 SECI-II 750 4 NTPC 160 2019 June 2.50
MW (allocated Mahindra Susten 200 2.50
680 MW)
Hero Future Energies 250 2.50
Azure Power 70 2.50
41 UPNEDA 500 1 NTPC 40 2019 June 3.02
MW (allocated
40 MW)
42 GUVNL 200 1 Gujarat State Energy Corporation 100 2019 August 2.65
MW (allocated Limited
100 MW)
43 GUVNL 750 1 Tata Power Renewable Energy 50 2019 August 2.75
MW (allocated Limited
50 MW)
44 SECI-V 1200 2 SB Energy 330 2019 August 2.65
MW (allocated GRT Jewellers India 150 2.53
480 MW)
2.63
Source: Compiled by the authors from various public sources, e.g. Orders of State Electricity Regulatory Commissions,
websites of MNRE, SECI etc.
6
Renewable Purchase
Obligation
Does It Need a Revisit as
Instrument for Market Creation?
Introduction
Apart from the tariff intervention discussed in the previous
chapter, RPO is yet another important instrument for the crea-
tion of market for renewable. This chapter discusses the concept
of RPS practised especially in Europe as a market mechanism
and compares it against the concept of RPO as understood in
India and delves into the constraints that need be overcome
to ensure its effectiveness as a facilitator for competition and a
market for renewable.
Market Mechanism
One way to achieve marginal cost pricing is by relying on mar-
kets to create competitive conditions in the renewable power
market. If there is sufficient number of suppliers competing in
each of the renewable categories, markets would ensure that
electricity from each of these sources is priced at the marginal
cost of generation, irrespective of the pricing formula adopted
by the individual suppliers.
One of the issues, however, is what should be the nature of
market-based instruments that would enable these technolo-
gies to flourish and grow in an environment where they cannot
commercially compete with conventional power generation
technologies without regulatory support. Besides, the other
equally relevant task at the moment is to evolve a regulatory
mechanism that would bring in competition within these seg-
ments and, hence, greater efficiency with it.
Internationally, countries have promoted the commercializa-
tion of RE resources and their corresponding technologies in
several ways, but FIT and RPO have been the two most popular
approaches in recent times. The former is equivalent to the
preferential tariff approach in India, in which the authorities
notify sufficiently attractive tariffs for generation from these
technologies, in a hope that this would bring forth investments
in generation capacity based on these technologies. The latter,
on the other hand, is in many ways different from the RPO
mechanism that has been implemented so far in India.
The UK Case
To illustrate, in the UK, the new Renewables Obligation (RO)
and associated Renewables Obligation (Scotland) amendment
came into force in April 2002 as part of the Utilities Act, 2000.
Under this, power suppliers have had to acquire from renewa-
bles a specified proportion of electricity they supply to their
customers. It started with 3 per cent in 2003, rising gradually to
10.4 per cent in 2010 and to 15.4 per cent by 2015. Under this,
the costs to consumers have been capped and the Obligation
has been guaranteed in law until 2037.1
Eligible renewable generators receive the Renewables
Obligation Certificates (ROCs) for each MWh of electricity gen-
erated. These certificates are then bought by electricity suppliers
(distributors in Indian terminology) to fulfil their obligations.
However, suppliers have an option to either meet their obliga-
tions by purchasing the required number of certificates or pay
a ‘buyout’ price for the short fall. The buyout price, in fact, is
essentially a penalty for non-compliance.
Generally, the penalty is set as a maximum price of ROC
or renewable electricity purchased under the obligation in
the year. In Sweden, it is different. Consumers who do not
comply pay a penalty which is 150 per cent (starting in 2005)
of the average certificate price in the previous accounting
period. The penalty in this case thus sets a moving ceiling
price. Generally, the buyout price is fixed as the ‘price per
MWh‘ shortfall.2 In the UK, however, this is adjusted every
From this and a fact that the FOR has incorporated the NAPCC
goals in its recommendations, one must presume that the FOR
too has set this as a minimum obligation norm for each of the
SERCs in the country, especially since what is in the plan is also
expected to form part of India’s voluntary obligation under-
taken at the Copenhagen Climate Summit (and reconfirmed at
successive summits after that) to reduce the carbon intensity of
the economy by 20 per cent by 2020.
Given this context, it is apparent that the states are expected
to set RPO targets, which achieve in aggregate the requirements
MoP Order Dt. 22 July 2016 MoP Order Dt. 14 June 2018
2016–2017 2017–2018 2018–2019 2019–2020 2020–2021 2021–2022
Chapter Conclusion
For any trading mechanism to be successful, it would have to
either overcome the constraints of the transmission infrastruc-
ture and associated costs, or sidestep them. While a detailed
analysis of the various constraints, the steps taken so far to over-
come them, the gaps that exist in the absence of a holistic view
and the desirable action has been covered in the last chapter,
the next chapter deliberates the initiatives taken in the form
of the REC mechanism to address, inter alia, the constraints of
interstate transferability of variable renewable, so as to facilitate
better compliance of RPO. The FOR in India, responding to the
challenge, developed a national framework for the implementa-
tion of RPO, based on trade of RECs. It called upon the CERC
to frame a regulation to institutionalize it at the national level
and to entrust SERCs to adopt this instrument for RPO compli-
ance under Section 86 (1) (e) of the EA, 2003. This is discussed
in the next chapter in detail.
Notes
1. https://www.ofgem.gov.uk/ofgem-publications/76340/ro-buy-out-
fund102010-pdf (accessed on 10 February 2021).
2. N. H. van der Linden, M. A. Uyterlinde, C. Vrolijk, Lars J. Nilsson,
Kerstin Åstrand, Karin Ericsson, R Wiser and Jamil Khan, ‘Review
NAPCC Target 6.00 7.00 8.00 9.00 10.00 11.00 12.00 13.00 14.00 15.00
1 Andhra Pradesh 5.00 5.00 5.00 5.00 5.00 5.00
2 Arunachal Pradesh 4.20 5.60 7.00
3 Assam 2.80 4.20 5.60 7.00
4 Bihar 1.50 3.00 4.00 4.50 5.00 1.00 1.25 1.50 1.75 2.00
5 Chhattisgarh 5.00 5.25 5.75 5.75 5.75
6 Gujarat 5.00 6.00 7.00 7.00 8.00 9.00 10.00
7 Haryana 1.50 1.50 2.05 3.10
8 Himachal Pradesh 10.00 10.01 10.25 10.25 10.25 11.25 12.25 13.50 14.75 16
9 Jammu & Kashmir 3.00 5.00 5.00 6.00 7.50 9.00
10 Jharkhand 2.00 3.00 4.00 4.00 4.00 4.00
11 Karnataka 7.25 7.25 7.25
12 Kerala 3.30 3.60 3.90 4.20 4.50 4.80 5.10 5.40 5.70 6.00
13 Madhya Pradesh 2.50 4.00 5.50 7.00
14 Maharashtra 6.00 7.00 8.00 9.00 9.00 9.00
15 Meghalaya 0.50 0.75 1.00 1.00
16 Mizoram 5.00 6.00 7.00
17 Nagaland 5.00 7.00 8.00
18 Odisha 5.00 5.50 6.00 6.50 7.00
19 Punjab 2.40 2.90 3.50 4.00
20 Rajasthan 8.50 6.00 7.10 8.20
21 Tamil Nadu 9.00 9.00 9.00 11.00 11.00
22 UP 3.75 5.00 6.00 6.00
23 Uttarakhand 4.53 5.05 6.05 7.08 8.10 9.30 11.50
24 West Bengal 4.00 5.00 6.00 7.00 8.00
Source: Comptroller and Auditor General of India on Renewable Energy Sector in India (Report No. 34 of 2015 –
Performance Audit).
Compliance of Renewable Purchase Obligation by the Utilities from 2010–2011 to
Appendix 6A.2
2013–2014
Source: Comptroller and Auditor General of India on Renewable Energy Sector in India (Report No. 34 of 2015 –
Performance Audit)
State-wise RPO Target (FY 2016–2017 to FY 2020–2021) and RPO Compliance (FY 2016–2017 to
Appendix 6B
FY 2018–19)
Non-solar
Solar Achievement/ Achievement/
States/DISCOMS Solar Target (%) Compliance (%) Non-solar Target (%) Compliance (%)
FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY
S. 2016– 2017– 2018– 2019– 2020– 2016– 2017– 2018– 2016– 2017– 2018– 2019– 2020– 2016– 2017– 2018–
No. States DISCOM 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2017 2018 2019 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2017 2018 2019
1 Andaman & Electricity 1.65 2.50 3.60 4.70 6.10 3.20 4.20 5.40 8.00
Nicobar Department,
Andaman
and Nicobar
Administration
(ED A&N)
2 Andhra Southern Power 0.25 3.00 4.00 5.00 6.00 4.75 6.00 7.00 8.00 9.00
Pradesh Distribution Co.
Ltd (SPDCL)
Eastern Power 0.25 3.00 4.00 5.00 6.00 4.75 6.00 7.00 8.00 9.00
Distribution Co.
Ltd (EPDCL)
3 Arunachal Department of 2.75 4.75 6.75 8.75 9.50 10.25
Pradesh Power, Arunachal
Pradesh (DOP,
AP)
4 Assam Assam Power 1.00 4.00 5.00 6.00 7.00 1.00 1.16 3.00 5.00 6.00 7.00 8.00 2.91 4.90
Distribution
Company Limited
(APDCL)
5 Bihar North Bihar 1.50 2.25 3.25 4.75 6.75 1.50 2.25 2.79 5.00 5.50 6.00 6.75 7.50 5.00 5.50 5.30
Power Distribution
Company Limited
(NBPDCL)
South Bihar 1.50 2.25 3.25 4.75 6.75 1.50 2.25 2.80 5.00 5.50 6.00 6.75 7.50 5.00 5.50 6.93
Power Distribution
Company Limited
(SBPDCL)
6 Chandigarh Chandigarh 1.65 2.50 3.60 4.70 6.10 1.40 1.06 3.20 4.20 5.40 6.80 8.00 1.23 1.21
Electricity
Department (CED)
7 Chhattisgarh Chhattisgarh State 1.50 2.00 3.50 5.00 6.50 6.50 7.00 7.50 8.00 8.50
Power Distribution
Company Ltd
(CSPDCL)
8 Delhi BSES Rajdhani 0.35 2.75 4.75 6.75 7.25 0.41 8.65 8.75 9.50 10.25 10.25 8.04
Power limited
BSES Yamuna 0.35 2.75 4.75 6.75 7.25 8.65 8.75 9.50 10.25 10.25
Power limited
Tata Power Delhi 0.35 2.75 4.75 6.75 7.25 8.65 8.75 9.50 10.25 10.25
Distribution Ltd
(TPDDL)
New Delhi 0.35 2.75 4.75 6.75 7.25 8.65 8.75 9.50 10.25 10.25
Municipal Council
(NDMC)
9 Dadra & Dadra & Nagar 1.65 2.50 3.60 4.70 6.10 1.41 0.08 3.20 4.20 5.40 6.80 8.00 3.54 0.00
Nagar Haveli Haveli Power
Distribution
Corporation Ltd
(DNHPDCL)
(Appendix 6B Continued)
(Appendix 6B Continued)
Non-solar
Solar Achievement/ Achievement/
States/DISCOMS Solar Target (%) Compliance (%) Non-solar Target (%) Compliance (%)
FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY
S. 2016– 2017– 2018– 2019– 2020– 2016– 2017– 2018– 2016– 2017– 2018– 2019– 2020– 2016– 2017– 2018–
No. States DISCOM 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2017 2018 2019 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2017 2018 2019
10 Daman & Diu Electricity 1.65 2.50 3.60 4.70 6.10 0.71 0.80 3.20 4.20 5.40 6.80 8.00 1.86 3.63
Department of
Daman & Diu (ED
DD)
11 Goa Electricity 1.15 2.50 3.60 4.70 6.10 1.54 2.38 3.56 2.80 4.20 5.40 6.80 8.00 1.06 4.09 5.30
Department, Goa
(EDG)
12 Gujarat Dakshin Gujarat 1.75 3.00 4.25 5.50 6.75 1.88 1.83 2.77 8.25 8.35 8.45 8.80 8.90 6.73 7.60 9.27
Vij Company
Limited (DGVCL)
Madhya Gujarat 1.75 1.75 4.25 5.50 6.75 1.88 1.83 2.77 8.25 8.35 8.45 8.80 8.90 6.73 7.60 9.27
Vij Company
Limited (MGVCL)
Uttar Gujarat Vij 1.75 1.75 4.25 5.50 6.75 1.88 1.83 2.77 8.25 8.35 8.45 8.80 8.90 6.73 7.60 9.27
Company Limited
(UGVCL)
Paschim Gujarat 1.75 1.75 4.25 5.50 6.75 1.88 1.83 2.77 8.25 8.35 8.45 8.80 8.90 6.73 7.60 9.27
Vij Company
Limited (PGVCL)
Torrent Power 1.75 1.75 4.25 5.50 6.75 2.46 2.59 3.67 8.25 8.35 8.45 8.80 8.90 5.79 8.24 7.95
Limited-
Distribution Surat
Torrent Power 1.75 1.75 4.25 5.50 6.75 2.46 2.59 3.67 8.25 8.35 8.45 8.80 8.90 5.79 8.24 7.95
Limited-
Distribution
Ahmedabad
13 Haryana Uttar Haryana Bijli 1.00 2.50 4.00 5.50 7.00 2.75 2.75 3.00 3.00 3.00
Vitran Nigam Ltd
(UHBVNL)
Dakshin Haryana 1.00 2.50 4.00 5.50 7.00 2.75 2.75 3.00 3.00 3.00
Bijli Vitran Nigam
Ltd (DHBVNL)
14 Himachal Himachal Pradesh 2.50 4.75 6.75 7.25 8.75 2.50 9.50 9.50 10.25 10.25 10.25 9.50
Pradesh State Electricity
Board Ltd
(HPSEBL)
15 Jharkhand Jharkhand Bijli 1.80 3.75 5.50 6.55 6.55 3.50 4.00 4.50 5.00 5.00
Vitran Nigam
Limited (JBVNL)
Damodar Valley 1.80 3.75 5.50 6.55 6.55 3.50 4.00 4.50 5.00 5.00
Corporation
(DVC)
Jamshedpur Utility 1.80 3.75 5.50 6.55 6.55 3.50 4.00 4.50 5.00 5.00
Services Company
Limited (JUSCO)
Tata Steel Limited 1.80 3.75 5.50 6.55 6.55 3.50 4.00 4.50 5.00 5.00
(TSL)
Steel Authority 1.80 3.75 5.50 6.55 6.55 3.50 4.00 4.50 5.00 5.00
of India Limited
(SAIL)
(Appendix 6B Continued)
(Appendix 6B Continued)
Non-solar
Solar Achievement/ Achievement/
States/DISCOMS Solar Target (%) Compliance (%) Non-solar Target (%) Compliance (%)
FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY
S. 2016– 2017– 2018– 2019– 2020– 2016– 2017– 2018– 2016– 2017– 2018– 2019– 2020– 2016– 2017– 2018–
No. States DISCOM 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2017 2018 2019 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2017 2018 2019
16 Karnataka Bangalore 0.75 2.75 6.00 7.25 8.50 1.04 4.11 11.00 12.00 13.00 12.00 12.00 11.00 12.00
Electricity Supply
Company Limited
(BESCOM)
Chamundeshwari 0.75 2.75 6.00 7.25 8.50 0.79 4.94 11.00 11.00 12.00 12.00 12.00 10.47 11.00
Electricity Supply
Corporation
Limited (CESC)
Gulbarga 0.75 2.75 6.00 7.25 8.50 0.75 5.33 5.50 6.00 7.00 11.00 11.00 5.50 10.47
Electricity Supply
Company Limited
(GESCOM)
Hubli Electricity 0.75 2.75 6.00 7.25 8.50 0.68 3.89 7.50 8.50 9.50 8.00 8.00 7.80 20.81
Supply Company
Limited (HESCOM)
Mangalore 0.75 2.75 6.00 7.25 8.50 1.48 4.26 11.01 12.00 13.00 13.00 13.00 11.01 13.10
Electricity Supply
Company Limited
(MESCOM)
17 Kerala Kerala State 0.50 1.50 2.75 0.23 0.53 0.75 4.50 6.00 7.00 2.85 3.24 4.68
Electricity Board
Ltd (KSEBL)
18 Lakshadweep Electricity 1.65 2.50 3.60 4.70 6.10 3.20 4.20 5.40 6.80 8.00
Department, UT
of Lakshadweep
(LED)
19 Madhya Central DISCOM 1.25 1.50 1.75 6.50 7.00 7.50
Pradesh East DISCOM 1.25 1.50 1.75 6.50 7.00 7.50
West DISCOM 1.25 1.50 1.75 6.50 7.00 7.50
20 Maharashtra Tata Power 1.00 2.00 2.75 3.50 4.50 1.10 1.55 3.23 10.00 10.50 11.00 11.50 11.50 10.00 10.50 10.97
Distribution
(TPC-D)
RInfra-D/Adani 1.00 2.00 2.75 3.50 4.50 0.74 0.73 0.79 10.00 10.50 11.00 11.50 11.50 7.45 2.14 2.29
Electricity Mumbai
Limited (AEML)
Maharashtra 1.00 2.00 2.75 3.50 4.50 0.38 0.79 10.00 10.50 11.00 11.50 11.50 10.00 10.57
State Electricity
Distribution
Company Limited
(MSEDCL)
Brihanmumbai 1.00 2.00 2.75 3.50 4.50 1.01 0.69 10.00 10.50 11.00 11.50 11.50 9.03 11.38
Electric Supply
and Transport
(BEST)
21 Manipur Manipur State 2.75 4.75 6.75 0.00 8.75 9.50 10.25 0.92
Power Distribution
Company Ltd
(MSPDCL)
22 Meghalaya Meghalaya Power 0.42 0.43 0.75 1.00 1.25 1.58 2.07 3.25 4.00 4.75
Distribution
Corporation
Limited (MePDCL)
(Appendix 6B Continued)
(Appendix 6B Continued)
Non-solar
Solar Achievement/ Achievement/
States/DISCOMS Solar Target (%) Compliance (%) Non-solar Target (%) Compliance (%)
FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY
S. 2016– 2017– 2018– 2019– 2020– 2016– 2017– 2018– 2016– 2017– 2018– 2019– 2020– 2016– 2017– 2018–
No. States DISCOM 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2017 2018 2019 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2017 2018 2019
23 Mizoram Power and 2.75 4.75 6.75 0.00 8.75 9.50 10.25 20.89
Electricity
Department
(P&ED), Mizoram
24 Nagaland Department of 2.75 4.75 6.75 7.25 8.75 0.00 0.00 0.00 8.75 9.50 10.25 10.25 10.25 15.86 13.05 16.26
Power, Nagaland
(DPN)
25 Odisha Central Electricity 1.50 3.00 4.50 5.50 3.00 4.50 5.00 5.50
Supply Utility
(CESU)
North Eastern 1.50 3.00 4.50 5.50 3.00 4.50 5.00 5.50
Electricity Supply
Company of
Odisha Limited
(NESCO)
SOUTHCO 1.50 3.00 4.50 5.50 3.00 4.50 5.00 5.50
Western 1.50 3.00 4.50 5.50 3.00 4.50 5.00 5.50
Electricity Supply
Company of
Orissa Limited
(WESCO)
26 Puducherry Puducherry 1.65 2.50 3.60 4.70 6.10 0.02 3.20 4.20 5.40 6.80 8.00 0.00
Electricity
Department (PED)
27 Punjab Punjab 1.30 1.80 2.20 4.00 2.65 3.91 3.66 4.10 4.20 4.30 5.50 2.49 4.58 3.75
State Power
Corporation
Limited (PSPCL)
28 Rajasthan Ajmer Vidyut 2.50 4.75 6.75 6.00 7.25 8.90 9.50 10.25 9.00 9.40
Vitran Nigam
Limited (AVVNL)
Jodhpur Vidyut 2.50 4.75 6.75 6.00 7.25 8.90 9.50 10.25 9.00 9.40
Vitran Nigam
Limited (JDVVNL)
Jaipur Vidyut 2.50 4.75 6.75 6.00 7.25 8.90 9.50 10.25 9.00 9.40
Vitran Nigam
Limited (JVVNL)
29 Sikkim Energy and Power 0.75 4.75 6.75 6.75 6.75 4.25 9.50 10.25 10.25 10.25
Department,
Sikkim (EPDS)
30 Tamil Nadu Tamil Nadu 2.50 5.00 5.00 2.90 3.40 3.32 9.00 9.00 9.00 14.64 18.91 12.15
Generation and
Distribution
Corporation Ltd
(TANGEDCO)
31 Telangana Northern Power 0.25 0.25 5.33 5.77 6.21 4.75 4.75 0.67 0.73 0.79
Distribution
Company of
Telangana Limited
(TSNPDCL)
Southern Power 0.25 0.25 5.33 5.77 6.21 4.75 4.75 0.67 0.73 0.79
Distribution
Company of
Telangana Limited
(TSSPDCL)
(Appendix 6B Continued)
(Appendix 6B Continued)
Non-solar
Solar Achievement/ Achievement/
States/DISCOMS Solar Target (%) Compliance (%) Non-solar Target (%) Compliance (%)
FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY FY
S. 2016– 2017– 2018– 2019– 2020– 2016– 2017– 2018– 2016– 2017– 2018– 2019– 2020– 2016– 2017– 2018–
No. States DISCOM 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2017 2018 2019 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2017 2018 2019
32 Tripura Tripura State
Electricity
Corporation Ltd
(TSECL)
33 UP Dakshinanchal 1.00 1.00 1.00 2.00 3.00 0.43 0.01 1.07 5.00 5.00 5.00 6.00 8.00 4.10 4.16 3.90
Vidyut Vitran Nigam
Ltd (DVVNL)
Kanpur Electricity 1.00 1.00 1.00 2.00 3.00 0.43 0.01 1.07 5.00 5.00 5.00 6.00 8.00 4.10 4.16 3.90
Supply Company
Ltd (KESCo)
Madhyanchal 1.00 1.00 1.00 2.00 3.00 0.43 0.01 1.07 5.00 5.00 5.00 6.00 8.00 4.10 4.16 3.90
Vidyut Vitaran
Nigam Ltd
(MVVNL)
Pashchimanchal 1.00 1.00 1.00 2.00 3.00 0.43 0.01 1.07 5.00 5.00 5.00 6.00 8.00 4.10 4.16 3.90
Vidyut Vitaran
Nigam Limited
(PVVNL)
Purvanchal Vidyut 1.00 1.00 1.00 2.00 3.00 0.43 0.01 1.07 5.00 5.00 5.00 6.00 8.00 4.10 4.16 3.90
Vitaran Nigam
Limited (PUVVNL)
Noida Power 1.00 1.00 1.00 2.00 3.00 0.69 0.83 5.00 5.00 5.00 6.00 8.00 1.39 6.86
Company Limited
(NPCL)
34 Uttarakhand Uttarakhand 1.50 4.75 6.75 7.25 8.75 0.30 2.64 8.00 9.50 10.25 10.25 10.25 7.36 7.10
Power
Corporation Ltd
(UPCL)
35 West Bengal West Bengal 0.25 0.30 0.40 5.50 6.00 6.50
State Electricity
Distribution
Company Ltd
(WBSEDCL)
Calcutta 0.25 0.30 0.40 5.50 6.00 6.50
Electric Supply
Corporation
(CESC)
Damodar Valley 0.25 0.30 0.40 5.50 6.00 6.50
Corporation
(DVC)
Durgapur Power 0.25 0.30 0.40 5.50 6.00 6.50
Limited (DPL)
India Power 0.25 0.30 0.40 5.50 6.00 6.50
Corporation
Limited (IPCL)
Renewable Energy
Certificate (REC)
Has It Outlived Its Life as
Market-based Mechanism?
Introduction
Continuing the discussion from the previous chapter regard-
ing the constraint of the interstate transferability of variable
renewable, coming in the way of RPO fulfilment by obligated
entities, this chapter examines the framework of REC as a mar-
ket-based instrument to address this constraint and, in turn, to
facilitate RPO compliance. The CERC issued ‘Central Electricity
Regulatory Commission (Terms and Conditions for Recognition
and Issuance of Renewable Energy Certificate for Renewable
Energy Generation) Regulations, 2010’ on 14 January 2010
framing the regulation as agreed in the FOR. What are its fea-
tures? How does it compare with international mechanisms of
a similar nature? Even more importantly, can it deliver what
the government has sought to achieve? These are some of the
questions that this chapter seeks to answer.
CERC’s Notification
The CERC’s notification of 14 January 2010 (subsequently
amended in 2010, 2013, 2014 and 2016) requires obligated
entities to meet two distinct RPOs, namely solar and non-solar,
through solar and non-solar RECs, respectively. Further, the
notification provides for the issuance of solar certificates to gen-
erators of electricity from solar energy and non-solar certificates
to generators of electricity from non-solar RE (for brevity, both
are referred to in rest of the book as RECs).
Entities having RE purchase obligation can acquire these cer-
tificates in fulfilment of their obligation only from the PX and
not in any other manner. Bilateral transactions in certificates
are thus ruled out. There is no restriction, however, on placing
these certificates on any of the PX in the country, so long as
they have obtained prior approval of their rules and by-laws,
including the mechanism for price discovery for certificates, from
CERC (Sec 8[2]).
Pricing of Certificates
Logically, since the trade in certificates is meant to be con-
ducted through PX, its price discovery must also happen
there. The notification provides for this, but with a caveat
that the CERC ‘may, in consultation with the Central Agency
(designated by the Commission inter-alia for registration and
issuance of RECs) and the Forum of Regulators provide for the
forbearance and the floor price from time to time, separately
for the solar and non-solar certificates’. How would these
prices be determined?
The notification spells this out requiring the following
aspects to be taken into account in setting prices, namely
variation in the cost of generation of different RE technolo-
gies falling under the solar and non-solar categories, across
states in the country, variation in the pooled cost of purchase
of electricity across states in the country, expected electricity
generation from RE sources, including expected RE capacity
2010–2011 10 70
2011–2012 177 1,018
2012–2013 158 711
2013–2014 220 669
2014–2015 136 486
2015–2016 80 263
2016–2017 86 553
2017–2018 38 179
Total 905 3,948
Source: https://www.recregistryindia.nic.in/pdf/Others/Report_on_REC_
Mechanism.pdf
IEX PXIL
Volume of Volume of
Volume of Volume of Buy Bid Volume of Volume of Bus Bid
Buy Bid Sell Bid as % of Buy Bid Sell Bid as % of
of RECs of RECs Volume of of RECs of RECs Volume of
Year (Million) (Million) Sell Bid (Million) (Million) Sell Bid
Non-solar
Source: http://cercind.gov.in/2019/market_monitoring/Annual%20Report%202018–19.pdf
low across Indian states. This has been mainly on account of
the reluctance by the government-owned electricity distribu-
tion entities to fully honour their RPOs. This suggests that it is
not just under the REC regime but also under the FIT regime
the registrations may have been declining.
Notwithstanding this, one redeeming feature of the REC
scheme has been that the trend in acquiring RECs was not
entirely negative across all segments of the obligated entities.
In contrast to the public sector electricity DISCOMs, the REC
scheme showed far greater promise with both open access and
captive buyers, the private sector DISCOMs and the electricity
departments of the UTs.6 Nonetheless, since the public sector
DISCOMs constituted for an overwhelmingly high share of the
total annual aggregate national renewable power purchases,
success in smaller RPO segments was not sufficient to upset the
declining trend in the former.
Could this apathy of state-owned DISCOMs be explained
simply by psychological factors7 (such as the REC not being
accompanied by real power, hence not having any tangible
value)?)While it is difficult to conclusively prove this, there are
several other plausible explanations for this. Logically, perhaps
it is more appropriate to conclude that managements in the
public sector entities lacked skills to assess risk than those in
the private sector; or, on the other hand, private sector enti-
ties in comparison had no other option but to buy RECs from
the exchange in order to meet their RE purchase obligations.
Hence, it seems that for the REC mechanism to be successful,
it was essential to withdraw the FIT regime and to leave only
the former as a means to fulfil RPOs by all entities.
Lastly, those subscribing to the ‘psychological’ factor expla-
nation for the failure of the REC mechanism to enthuse public
sector obligated entities propose emulating the UK example.
The units of electricity were bundled in their tradable prod-
uct (equivalent of REC) in this country and sold as one in
the market by RE generators to obligated entities. However,
if one goes back to the original purpose for creating the REC
Chapter Conclusion
In 2010–2011, a scheme was introduced in India to enable
obligated entities in states having scarce RE resources to meet
their obligations by purchasing RECs from RE power producers
in states well endowed with these resources. The said scheme
thus became one of the two modes nationally—the other being
FIT—by which obligated entities across the country could fulfil
their annual purchase obligations through third-party wind and
solar power producers. In this chapter, we examined, among
other things, the market mechanism for the REC regime and
the overall performance of the REC scheme over the years since
its inception. The REC scheme was conceived as a market-based
instrument to deliver national obligation targets more effi-
ciently than the prevailing FIT regime. However, market perfor-
mance does not exude confidence in terms of its continuation
in the existing form for long. It’s high time the mechanism was
reviewed seriously and, ideally, a sunset clause was drawn up
for the smooth transition of projects already registered under
this scheme.
Having discussed the dynamics of RPO as an instrument
for market creation for renewable in the previous chapter and
of the REC as a market-based instrument in this chapter, the
Notes
1. Central Electricity Regulatory Commission, ‘Order dated 1
June 2010, Petition No. 99/2010 (Suo Motu) in the Matter
of Determination of Forbearance and Floor Price for the REC
Framework’ (2011). Available at http://www.cercind.gov.in/2011/
august/order_on_forbearnace_&_floor_price_23-8-2011.pdf
(accessed on 10 February 2021).
2. http://cercind.gov.in/2020/orders/5-SM-2020-final.pdf (accessed
on 1 October 2020), 61–62.
3. Central Electricity Regulatory Commission, ‘Central Electricity
Regulatory Commission (Terms and Conditions for Recognition
and Issuance of Renewable Energy Certificates for Renewable
Energy Generation) Regulations, 2010) (2010). Available at http://
www.cercind.gov.in/2015/regulation/GZT49.pdf (accessed on 10
February 2021).
4. Richard J. Piwko, California Energy Commission, Public
Interest Energy Research, General Electric Company, GE Energy
Intermittent
Renewable
How to Enable Participation
in Market?
Introduction
Intermittency is often seen as a constraint to market participa-
tion of renewable. However, this needs to be overcome not only
to mainstream renewable but also to assuage the sentiments of
host renewable-rich states that have to face the consequences of
such intermittency. This chapter discusses the nature of inter-
mittency, the steps taken by India to address this limitation and
the desirable course of action to ensure a smooth transition of
renewable to market.
If one looks at the projected growth for different types of RE
generation resources in the country, one finds that not all of
the national RE generation targets will be met by the dispatch-
able segment of the renewable generation. Rather, a great deal
of it will come from intermittent resources, such as wind and
solar, which cannot be dispatched at will. This means that the
concerned states would have to make special efforts to integrate
these resources into their respective power grids since neither
the state nor the regional power grids in India have been
designed to transmit asynchronous power in bulk.
However, accommodating intermittent generation in power
grids that are traditionally not designed for them has been a
universal challenge. One can expect similar issues, as others in
the world have faced, to surface here also in our state grids once
the share of intermittent generation in their total generation
crosses the threshold.
The challenge of accommodating intermittent generation
mainly pertains to its impact on system’s reliability and dis-
patchability. Particularly, in the case of wind, which has a far
greater variability than any other renewable generation unit,
since it occurs at night-time, when the system load is light
and the flexibility in the system is at its lowest. How serious is
the issue? Let’s look at the wind and solar generation profile
and compare it against the system demand in some of the
renewable-rich states, as shown in Figure 8.1.
Figure 8.1 shows the profile of load, and wind and solar gen-
eration in Tamil Nadu on the maximum wind generation day,
that is, on 22 August 2017. On this day, the combined wind
and solar generation was 5,279 MW (4,618 MW wind plus 661
MW solar) and the contribution of RE was to the tune of 34 per
cent.1 Variability of the wind notwithstanding, the interesting
point is that even on this high-wind day, wind and solar gen-
eration were complementary to each other, especially during
09:30 hrs and 15:30 hours (see increasing trend of the black line
[wind] and decreasing trend of the light grey line [solar] during
this period) and have met most of the load during the day time.
The other dimension of this phenomenon is that during high
wind + solar generation, non-renewable generation has to be
operated at lower capacity level and, in some cases, it has to
be backed down. This poses a challenge in managing the steep
ramping requirement in the evening when both wind and solar
are not available (see the dark grey line [demand] peaking up
14,000 4,500
4,000
12,000
3,500
10,000 3,000
8,000 2,500
6,000 2,000
1,500
4,000
1,000
2,000 500
0 0
0:30
1:30
2:30
3:30
4:30
5:30
6:30
7:30
8:30
9:30
10:30
11:30
12:30
13:30
14:30
15:30
16:30
17:30
18:30
19:30
20:30
21:30
22:30
23:30
Demand Wind Solar
T amil Nadu State Demand versus Wind
Figure 8.1 Generation (22 August 2017)—Maximum Wind
Generation Day
Source: Based on Annexure VIII of CEA’s Technical Committee Report.2
from 17:30 hrs and solar disappears and wind generation starts
declining). You need flexible generation like hydro or gas to
manage the high-peak ramping requirement.
Similarly, let’s look at the profile of Gujarat on a maximum
wind variation day, that is, on 22 May 2017 as depicted in
Figure 8.2.
Here also, the wind and solar have been complementary to
each other. From 07:00 hrs to 11:00 hrs, solar picked up and
wind disappeared but again after 11:00 hrs, the trend reversed
with wind peaking up and solar steadily declining. But the
wind generation witnessed significant variability during the
day, and what is also of concern is the sudden dip in the
wind generation, say, from 19:00 hrs and the rising trend of
14,000
2,500
12,000
2,000
10,000
8,000 1,500
6,000
1,000
4,000
500
2,000
0 0
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24
Demand in Gujarat on 22 May 2017, along
with How This Was Met from Various Sources
Figure 8.2
of Generation Available—Maximum Wind
Variation Day
Source: Based on Annexure-VIII of CEA’s Technical Committee Report.3
Imbalance Handling
Scheduling demand or supply cannot be done with 100 per
cent accuracy all the time. The difference between the sched-
uled injection/drawl and the actual injection/drawl is defined
as deviation. Deviations lead to imbalances in the grid and,
unless they are resolved, the desired grid frequency cannot be
maintained and damage to generating and consuming equip-
ment can occur.
Buyers and sellers of electricity must adhere to the grid
discipline by following the schedules. The DSM penalizes
over-drawl and under-injection, and rewards under-drawl and
over-injection with certain exceptions.8 The optimal grid fre-
quency that needs to be maintained is 50 Hz and hence the
charges for deviation apply when the frequency falls below or
moves above 50 Hz.
Unlike conventional generators, RE generators are not dis-
patchable and hence the penalty for their deviations (effec-
tively for inaccurate forecasts) needs a different treatment. RE
generators are exempt from any penalty for a forecast error up
to ±15 per cent and are subject to a deviation charge beyond
that tolerance limit. These limits vary from state to state for
intrastate operations. Deviation charges for renewable genera-
tors are not linked to frequency. The design of the deviation
settlement framework for RE generators eliminates the possibil-
ity of gaming since the deviation charges apply to both excess
and shortfall in energy.
Ancillary Services
AS are support services to maintain the power system reli-
ability and support its primary function of delivering energy
to customers. These are deployed by the system operator over
various time frames to maintain the required instantaneous and
continuous balance between aggregate generation and load.
The CERC has notified the regulations on Reserves Regulation
Ancillary Services (RRAS) to restore the frequency level at the
desired level and to relieve congestion in the transmission
network. The RRAS supports both the ‘regulation-up’ service
Storage
The CERC brought out in January 2017 a Staff Paper on the
‘Introduction of Electricity Storage System in India’. The objec-
tive was to brainstorm the issues at stake by placing the paper
in the public domain, inviting comments from stakeholders.
On the policy and regulatory front, the EA, 2003, covers the
generation, transmission and distribution of electricity, but
‘storage/holding’ of electricity is not covered in the Act. Then
there are other issues regarding scheduling, energy account-
ing for charging and discharging, and open access for storage
facilities. The CERC paper does give insights into the various
aspects of the storage system, but it continues to remain a
discussion paper. Storage has a great potential for providing
flexibility support and calls for an appropriate incentive for
fast ramping. Some headway on creating a regulatory frame-
work for storage has been made, for instance, by recognizing
storage including stand-alone storage, as an entity eligible for
grid connectivity. Provisions have been made in the RE tariff
regulations for cost-plus tariff for renewable with storage. But
all this is not considered adequate. The need is to provide a
Smart Grid
The IEGC has incorporated elements of smart grid technology
that are mandatory, such as automatic demand management,
islanding schemes and system protection schemes. Thus, smart
grid technologies have a role in the regulations of the CERC.
The FOR has brought out Model Regulations on smart grid
for suitable adoption at the state level. The objectives of these
regulations primarily include enabling integration of various
smart grid technologies and measures to bring about economy,
efficiency improvement in generation, transmission and distri-
bution licensee operations, manage transmission and distribu-
tion networks effectively, enhance network security, integrate
renewable and clean energy into grids and micro-grids; enhanc-
ing network visibility and access, promoting optimal asset uti-
lization, improving consumer service levels, thereby allowing
for the participation in operations of transmission licensees,
distribution licensees through greater technology adoption
across the value chain in the electricity sector and, particularly,
in the transmission and distribution segments. In many states,
the process for notifying regulations has been initiated. But we
have a long way to go before we could put in place smart grid
in the country as a whole.
Similarly, distribution system designs would need to be
enhanced to accommodate reactive power control require-
ments, coordinated system restoration, communication
between system operators and generators, as well as system pro-
tection and safety concerns. Equally, the state-of-the-art fore-
casting would be required to forecast intermittent generation.
Chapter Conclusion
India has taken a number of steps to address the issues around
intermittency of renewable. Whether or not it is a market,
robust forecasting is the first necessary step towards main-
streaming variable renewable. Well, this is a necessary but not
sufficient condition. From project developers’ side, efforts must
go beyond forecasting accuracy to make themselves firm to the
Notes
1. https://cea.nic.in/reports/others/planning/resd/resd_comm_
reports/report.pdf (accessed on 20 November 2020), 10.
2. Central Electricity Authority, ‘Report of the Technical Committee
on Study of Optimal Location of Various Types of Balancing
Energy Sources/Energy Storage Devices to Facilitate Grid
Integration of Renewable Energy Sources and Associated Issues’.
Available at https://cea.nic.in/reports/others/planning/resd/resd_
comm_reports/annexure8.pdf (accessed on 11 February 2021).
3. Central Electricity Authority, ‘Report of the Technical Committee
on Study of Optimal Location of Various Types of Balancing
Energy Sources/Energy Storage Devices to Facilitate Grid
Integration of Renewable Energy Sources and Associated Issues.
Available at https://cea.nic.in/reports/others/planning/resd/
resd_comm_reports/annexure10.pdf (accessed on 11 February
2021).
4. North American Electric Reliability Corporation, ‘Special Report:
Accommodating High Levels of Variable Generation’ (2009).
Available at https://docs.wind-watch.org/NERC-accommodating-
variable-generation_17Nov08.pdf (accessed on 11 February 2021).
5. Ibid.
6. Ibid.
7. Forum of Regulators, ‘Forecasting, Scheduling, Deviation
Settlement and Related Matters of Solar and Wind Generation
Sources) Regulation, 2015’ (2015). Available at http://www.foru-
mofregulators.gov.in/Data/study/MR.pdf (accessed on 11 February
2021).
Introduction
India is an emerging economy and, given the deep interlinkage
between economic growth and the development of the power
sector, there is a lot of policy focus on measures to improve
efficiency and economy in the power system operation. Market
design in the context of power sector is all about this core
aspect of efficiency and economy. The objective is to design
the market in such a way as to ensure the efficient operation of
generation and transmission assets and thereby minimize cost
for market participants. However, given the special nature of
the electricity system in terms of the requirement of ensuring
the security and reliability of the grid operation, the objective
function of the economy or cost minimization is always subject
to security constraints. It is in this context that the issue of
intermittency of renewable, which poses reliability and secu-
rity challenges to the grid operation (discussed in the previous
chapter), assumes importance. The challenge is to design a
market in such a way that the variability of renewable is duly
factored in while achieving the overall economy of operation.
Pertinently, power market design as a whole is a vast subject
unto itself and beyond the scope of the present discussion. The
focus of this chapter is on the market design aspect from the
point of view of renewable.
Issues
RE is distinct from conventional generation in two fundamental
aspects: (a) RE has to be consumed when and where it is avail-
able while conventional generation can be adjusted (to a certain
extent depending on the technology and subject to appropriate
costs); (b) even if the RE generation can be forecast with high
accuracy (e.g., comparable to the load forecasts), it can still vary
over time substantially and force the rest of the power system
(i.e., not only supply but also demand side) to adjust appropri-
ately to ensure grid stability. Large-scale penetration of renewable
is, therefore, likely to cause disruption if the business-as-usual
way of planning, building and operating the power system does
not undergo a paradigm change.
The challenges thrown by renewable are global phenomena
now. In the context of market design, apart from intermit-
tency, rapid changes in the cost dynamics of renewable across
the globe have also added new complexities. Liebreich1 talks
of the age of base-cost renewables when the costs of renewables,
namely solar and wind, have become cheaper than those of the
conventional sources of energy. Accordingly, wind and solar
tend to become the natural choice for new investment. But
this creates new challenges for renewable. Projects based on RE
sources need cheaper debt and assurance of revenue on a longer
time horizon. Further, solar and wind resources are uncertain
and, therefore, their generation depends on other technologies,
namely storage, demand response and fossil fuel-based flexible
217,790 207,866
221,086 211,313
Figure 9.1 All-India Demand and Net Demand of a Typical Day (in 2021–2022)
225,751 215,431
220,798 210,428
202,370 194,442
202,824 193,251
205,410 179,576
204,551 145,994
205,204 138,270
210,331 141,387
209,487 147,450
207,161 156,866
Total Demand (MW)
205,194 172,849
9
205,598 194,161
8
204,988 198,788
7
199,412 192,553
6
195,354 188,704
5
194,771 188,935
4
196,901 191,234
3
200,324 194,416
2
203,675 196,870
1
240,000
220,000
200,000
180,000
160,000
140,000
120,000
100,000
Demand (MW)
financial derivatives in the derivates market. Steep peak, a
natural consequence of high renewable, is being managed
through encouraging flexible capacity. The market incentive
for flexible operation is being extended through energy as well
as AS pricing strategies. The requirement of reserves has been
increasing with an increase in the share of renewable. This is
being managed by bringing organized markets closer to real
time—gradually transitioning to 5-minute market from an
hourly, half-hourly or 15-minute market. The closer the market
operates, to the actual time of dispatch, the less is the reliance
on reserves. Added to this is the initiative on enhancing the
robustness of AS market and the co-optimization of energy and
AS in time horizons ranging from day ahead to real time. AS
include primary, secondary and tertiary services and resources
like demand response, and energy storage is being encouraged
gradually to participate in these markets.6
7.00
6.00
5.00
4.00
3.00
Price (`/kWh)
2.00
1.00
0.00
2008–2009 2009–2010 2010–2011 2011–2012 2012–2013 2013–2014 2014–2015 2015–2016 2016–2017 2017–2018 2018–2019 2019–2020
Year
Price of Electricity transacted through Traders (`/kWh) Price of Electricity transacted through PX (DAM + TAM) (`/kWh)
Long-term Transactions
PX Transactions
Bilateral transactions
through traders
Bilateral transactions
between DISCOMS
89.00 Transactions through DSM
Share of Market Segments in Total Electricity
Figure 9.3
Generation, 2019–2020
Source: Based on CERC’s Market Monitoring Report.13
01–11–2020
3,500.00
3,000.00
2,500.00
2,000.00
1,500.00
1,000.00
500.00
0.00
2000–2001
2001–2002
2002–2003
2003–2004
2004–2005
2005–2006
2006–2007
2007–2008
2008–2009
2009–2010
2010–2011
2011–2012
2012–2013
2013–2014
2014–2015
2015–2016
2016–2017
2017–2018
2018–2019
2019–2020
2020–2021
2021–2022
2022–2023
2023–2024
4,500.00
4,000.00
3,500.00
3,000.00
2,500.00
2,000.00
1,500.00
1,000.00
500.00
0.00
2000–2001
2001–2002
2002–2003
2003–2004
2004–2005
2005–2006
2006–2007
2007–2008
2008–2009
2009–2010
2010–2011
2011–2012
2012–2013
2013–2014
2014–2015
2015–2016
2016–2017
2017–2018
2018–2019
2019–2020
2020–2021
2021–2022
2022–2023
2023–2024
Price Variation in Power Exchange during a
Figure 9.5
Week
Source: Based on data extracted from the website of IEX.
4,000.00
3,500.00
3,000.00
2,500.00
2,000.00
1,500.00
1,000.00
500.00
0.00
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24
Price Variation in Power Exchange during a
Figure 9.6
Month
Source: Based on data extracted from the website of IEX.
Notes
1. Michael Liebreich, ‘Six Design Principles for the Power Markets
of the Future—A Personal View’ (New York, NY: Bloomberg New
Renewable Policy
Introspection
Rethink and Move in
the Right Direction
RPO
A major issue in the implementation of RPO in India has been
a fact that, as required by the legislative framework, the State
Electricity Regulatory Agencies have been setting and enforcing
RPOs within their jurisdiction. But the experience on setting
RPOs has not been satisfactory to begin with.
Most of the states have been setting RPO for a period of 3–5
years. But, in contrast, investors have been looking for specific
provisions in the law itself about the long-term trajectory of
RPO. It is argued that only the legal mandate can bring in the
desired level of demand with certainty. At the same time, the
demand creation by itself is not sufficient. It needs to be backed
up with strong enforcement of RPO. This would be the case,
irrespective of whether the RPO is met through the administra-
tive options on the table, the market mechanisms, such as the
trade in RECs or, for that matter, the auctioning of development
rights. Although strict enforcement has been missing in India,
this aspect has been emphasized time and again at different
fora. In fact, aggrieved by the apathy of the regulators, the
wind associations have appealed before the Appellate Tribunal
for Electricity for suitable directions to the state regulators to
enforce RPO compliance.1
RE Tariffs
Another concern has been around the plethora of RE tariffs
across the states. Investors feel that the RE tariffs determined
by the states do not always reflect the cost of generation. The
FITs have been announced every year by the CERC (for central
government-owned and interstate projects) as well as by SERCs
(for state-specific projects), but there has been a wide diversity
in tariffs determined by the CERC and SERCs.
This has been the case since every state has been making its
own assumptions on normative technical and financial param-
eters. This has led to different tariffs. The wind energy tariffs in
states such as Gujarat, Andhra Pradesh and Karnataka have been
lower than the CERC-determined wind tariff for FY 2014–2015,
whereas they have been higher in states such as Rajasthan,
Madhya Pradesh and Maharashtra. As a result, investors have
been preferring investments in wind energy in these states.2
In Karnataka, the investor preference has been for captive
and group captive mode for investments in RE from wind as the
commercial and industrial consumers, who have been paying
higher tariffs for electricity from conventional power stations,
Source: http://cercind.gov.in/2020/orders/5-SM-2020.pdf
REC Scheme
It is about a decade since the GOI introduced the REC scheme.
The said scheme became initially one of the two modes
nationally—the other being FIT—by which obligated entities
across the country could fulfil their annual purchase obliga-
tions through third-party wind and solar electricity producers.
The said scheme was conceived as an effective marketable
instrument to deliver national obligation targets annually,
more efficiently than the prevailing FIT regime. But did it
Deficient Infrastructure
Looking beyond issues in pricing, markets must have the
essential infrastructure to function smoothly. In this respect,
much needs to be done to integrate intermittent RE gen-
eration into the grid. Indeed, there is a dire need to upgrade
state, regional and national grid technology and operational
procedures in India. In conjunction with technology and
operational upgrades, there is also a need for a regulatory
framework for procuring and reasonably compensating ancil-
lary and balancing resources. These aspects, and those associ-
ated with the grid integration of variable generation, pose the
biggest challenge.
However, the main reason behind the lukewarm response
of the state government-owned power DISCOMs to the RPO
has been their poor financial health. Estimates show that the
total accumulated losses of these distribution licensees were
about `3,800,000 million in FY 2015,10 though not all of it is
accounted by the purchase of electricity from wind and solar
power farms. This is a much bigger issue affecting the entire
power sector since many years and needs urgent solution at
the government level.
The developers have been also concerned with the overall
environment for RE project development. They have often com-
plained about the lack of coordination among key institutions,
namely grid operators, DISCOMs, state revenue departments
Notes
1. http://reconnectenergy.com/blog/tag/iwtma/ (accessed on 29
September 2020).
2. http://www.nrdc.org/international/india/files/renewable-energy-
wind-financing-IP.pdf (accessed on 29 September 2020).
3. http://cercind.gov.in/2014/draft_reg/Exp_memo30.pdf (accessed
on 29 September 2020).
4. http://climatepolicyinitiative.org/wp-content/uploads/2012/12/
Falling-Short-An-Evaluation-of-the-Indian-Renewable-Certificate-
Market.pdf (accessed on 29 September 2020).
5. Ralph Turvey, ‘Analysing the Marginal Cost of Water Supply’, Land
Economics 52, no. 2 (1976; quoted in NERA Economic Consulting,
‘Assessment of IPART’s Estimate of Long Run Marginal Cost for
Sydney Water’ [A report for Alinta LGA Ltd; White Plains, NY:
NERA Economic Consulting, 2008]).
6. Chatterjee, ‘The Renewable Energy Policy Dilemma in India’.
7. Ibid.
Index 229
Inter State Generating Station National Action Plan for
(ISGS), 162, 164 Climate Change (NAPCC),
Inter-State Transmission 111–112
System (ISTS), 162 National Electricity Market, 9
intrastate generators, 162 National Electricity Policy, 164
intrastate transmission and National Institute of Solar
distribution, 23 Energy, 50
National Institute of Wind
locational marginal price Energy, 75
(LMP), 178 National Load Dispatch Centre
long-run marginal cost (NLDC), 162
(LRMC), 20, 35 National Renewable Energy
Laboratory, 75
marginal cost pricing, 106 National Solar Mission (2011),
Market Based Economic 113
Dispatch (MBED), network service-based energy
189, 194 storage, 43
market design for renewable New Electricity Trading
energy Arrangement (NETA), 18–19
Indian model, 182–189 Non-Fossil Fuel Obligation
issues in, 177–178 (NFFO), Britain, 29, 109
market models in major Nord Pool market of
economies, 178–182 Scandinavia, 19
recommended design for North American Electric
Indian markets, 189–194 Reliability Corporation, 171
market mechanism, 106–107
Mera Gao Power (MGP), 48 off-grid/small home system,
meter energy storage, 43 44–47
micro-DISCOMS, 49 Orissa Electricity Board, 22
micro-grid, 43, 47–50
Minda, 49 parallel power modelling
mini-grid, 43 technique, 38
Ministry of New and pay-as-you-go (PAYG), East
Renewable Energy (MNRE), Africa, 44–45
3, 32, 51, 73 peer-to-peer (P2P) trading,
Ministry of Urban 55–57
Development pooling system for power
Model Building Bye-Laws, trading model, 16–19
2016, 112 power generation technology,
Model Net Metering advancement in, 8
Regulation (NEM 2013), 51 Power Grid Corporation of
M-Pesa platform, 45 India, 149
Index 231
smart grid, 170 second-price sealed- bid
storage and holding of auctions, 69
electricity, 170 short-run marginal costs
Renewable Energy (SRMC), 35
Management Centres short-run marginal costs
(REMCs), 222 (SRMCs), 20
renewable energy pricing in short-term pool market, 22
India, approaches Simpa Networks, 45–46
actual project cost, 66 small-scale distributed
auction theory, 68–77 renewable energy system,
cost-plus, 62–63 42
international project cost, Solar Energy Corporation of
66–68 India (SECI), 73–77
market based, 65 solar plus storage model, 43
regulatory, 64 solar power projects, prices
renewable energy technologies through bidding, 201
global approach, 28–31 stand-alone system, 43
versus conventional State Electricity Board (SEB), 8,
technologies, 11 10–11
renewable portfolio standard State Electricity Regulatory
(RPS) system, 35, 60, 106– Commissions (SERCs), 5, 32,
107, 211 52, 113
renewable purchase obligation state load dispatch centres
(RPO), 54, 73, 155, 211 (SLDCs), 162
drawbacks in, 121–122
in India, 110 The Energy Research Institute
in the UK, 108–111 (TERI), 48–49
issues in implementation of, transformers, 7
199 transmission access charge
long-term growth trajectory (TAC), 39
of, 114
products in, 108 United Nations Framework
solar and non-solar, state- Convention on Climate
wise, 115–118, 120 Change, 66
Report of the Comptroller and UP Electricity Regulatory
Auditor General of India on Commission, 56
Renewable Energy Sector in Uttar Pradesh New and
India, 113 Renewable Energy
request for selection (RFS), 74 Development Agency
Reserves Regulation Ancillary (UPNEDA), 48–49, 56
Services (RRAS), 167
rooftop systems (RTS), 112 wind power capacity, 3