Gundlach Human Capital and Economic Development A Macroeconomic Assessment
Gundlach Human Capital and Economic Development A Macroeconomic Assessment
Working Paper
Human capital and economic development: A
macroeconomic assessment
Suggested Citation: Gundlach, Erich (1996) : Human capital and economic development: A
macroeconomic assessment, Kiel Working Paper, No. 778, Kiel Institute of World Economics (IfW),
Kiel
Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your personal
Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. and scholarly purposes.
Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial purposes, to
Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich exhibit the documents publicly, to make them publicly available on the
machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public.
Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen If the documents have been made available under an Open Content
(insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you may exercise
gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence.
genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte.
Kiel Institute of World Economics
Düsternbrooker Weg 120, D-24105 Kiel
Department IV
by
Erich Gundlach
November 1996
The authors themselves, not the Kiel Institute of World Economics, are
responsible for the contents and distribution of Kiel Working Papers.
Since the series involves manuscripts in a preliminary form, interested readers
are requested to direct criticisms and suggestions directly to the authors and to
clear any quotations with them.
Human Capital and Economic Development:
A Macroeconomic Assessment
ABSTRACT
foundation. In addition, the wide range of published results seems to result from
on formal education. Future empirical research should take into account other
experience of the workforce, and the health status and the nutritional status of
the population.
JEL: O 41
Erich Gundlach
Kiel Institute of World Economics
P.O. Box 4309
D-24100 Kiel, Germany
Phone: 49 431 8814284
Fax: 49 431 8814500
E-mail: [email protected]
1
I. INTRODUCTION*
point to the important role of human capital formation. Taking a closer look at
this common sense argument, it becomes less clear how the average economist
world justify the presumed role of human capital at the macroeconomic level. The
question is why one should believe in the above average importance of human
But statistical correlations alone will not suffice to establish a convincing case.
What is more, very often correlations between measures of human capital and
To have a starting point for any serious discussion of the role of human capital in
* For helpful comments on an earlier version, I thank the participants of the conference on
"Human Capital Formation as an Engine of Growth: The East Asian Experience" which was
jointly organized by the Institute of Southeast Asian Studies (ISEAS), Singapore, and the
Kiel Institute of World Economics.
1 For empirical research on the determinants of economic development using long lists of
explanatory variables, see, e.g., Kormendi and Meguire (1985), Levine and Renelt (1992),
Levine and Zervos (1993).
2
research then has to show whether the theoretical predictions are more ore less in
line with the empirical evidence. If so, the theory may be used as a framework for
Over the last ten years or so, the availability of large cross-country data sets has
program, some new insights have been established, especially on the role of
human capital formation in economic development. But this is not to deny that
some old puzzles have remained and some new puzzles have emerged. At present,
growth theory is far from being a settled issue and so is the research program that
self evident, the scope of the paper is necessarily selective. The literature in this
field has grown so rapidly that it would definitely take more than a single paper to
lay out the many different views and alternative estimation results thoroughly.
2 The seminal papers in this field are Romer (1986) and Lucas (1988). Ever since, the
literature has exploded. For recent summaries, see, e.g., Lucas (1993) and the contributions
in Symposium New Growth Theory (1994).
3
empirical findings (section III). Perspectives for further research are outlined in
Beginning about ten years ago, endogenous growth theories were advocated as a
invented by Solow (1956).3 With some justification, the neoclassical model was
Today, what comes as a surprise is that the advances in growth theory have not
theories. That is, whenever it comes to the empirics of economic growth, the basic
neoclassical model still seems to be a good choice to begin with.4 The reason is
3 Major proponents of this view are Romer (1986), Lucas (1988), Stokey (1988), Grossman
and Helpman (1991), and Young (1991), to name but a few.
4 For example, the widely cited empirical studies of the determinants of economic growth of
Hong Kong, Singapore, South Korea and Taiwan by Young (1992; 1995), one of the
leading proponents of new growth theories, basically rely on the neoclassical growth
accounting framework suggested by Solow (1957).
4
that despite its simplicity, the Solow model has many predictions with regard to
the international variation in income per person. And these predictions are
broadly consistent with data on factor prices given the assumption that factors of
For instance, the most simple Solow model predicts that in the steady state, the
marginal product of capital is constant and the marginal product of labor grows at
the rate of technological change. Furthermore, income per person should also
grow with the rate of technological change. These predictions are by and large
confirmed for the United States, where the long-run growth rate of income per
person equals the growth rate of real wages and the profit rate exhibits little trend.
But not all is well with the basic Solow model of economic growth. Its main
weakness is that it does not consider human capital formation as a separate factor
of production like physical capital and labor. Augmenting the basic model by
substantially expands its scope and applicability. If – and only if – human capital
variation in income per person, although it may be a bad choice for studying the
To see why this is so recall that the Solow model, pretty close to what Karl Marx
model, poor countries are predicted to be poor because they have less capital per
worker than rich countries. Moreover, again in line with Karl Marx, the profit rate
the rate of return to capital should be higher in poor countries than in rich
countries just because they have less capital. But once the rate of return to capital
is higher in poor countries, one should expect a stronger incentive for capital
accumulation in poor than in rich countries. This, in turn, should lead to a faster
growth rate of income per person in poor countries and thus to a cross-country
steady state are held constant. On all three aspects, namely the magnitude of
the rate of convergence, the Solow model comes up with quantitative predictions
To begin with, one must obviously have interpretations of the term capital and of
its return. Traditionally, capital has been thought of including an economy's stock
of equipment machinery and buildings, i.e. its physical capital. The rate of return
machinery and buildings. These profits are part of the National Accounts
But physical capital is not the only kind of capital that can be accumulated
so, it is justified to take a much broader view of capital which includes human
capital. As a consequence, the capital share that can be directly calculated from
the National Accounts Statistics in likely to underestimate the true capital share of
an economy.
This insight has important quantitative implications for the predictions of the
international differences in income per person and rates of return. To keep the
the form
Y = K α H β ( AL)
1− α −β
(1) ,
efficiency units. With the central assumptions that factors of production earn their
marginal products and constant returns to scale prevail, the production elasticities
for physical ( α ) and human ( β ) capital should equal the factor shares of physical
and human capital in total factor income. Mankiw et al. (1992) and Mankiw
(1995) show how equation (1) can be manipulated to derive expressions for the
predicted change in income per person and the rate of return to physical capital,
and the convergence rate. As it turns out, a broad capital share combining
physical and human capital is the central parameter in all three cases.5
∆( Y / L ) γ ⎛ ∆S ⎞ ∆( n + g + δ )
(2) = ⎜ ⎟ − ,
Y/L 1− γ ⎝ S ⎠ n+ g+δ
where Y/L is income per person, S is the saving rate in percent of GDP, n is the
common depreciation rate of physical and human capital, and ∆ is the first
difference operator. The combined factor share of physical and human capital is
differences the neoclassical model can explain. Consider first that γ equals about
one third as in the model without human capital, so γ / (1 − γ ) equals one half. In
this case, leaving aside differences in population growth, the predicted difference
in income per person would be the square root of the relative difference in the
factor of about four (PWT 5.6) Hence international income per person is
The introduction of human capital helps to solve this problem. In the model with
each for human and for physical capital, income per person is predicted to differ
The neoclassical model predicts that the return to physical capital (r) should vary
⎛ 1 − γ ⎞ ∆( Y / L)
(3) ∆r / r = − ⎜ ⎟ ,
⎝ σγ ⎠ Y / L
where σ is the elasticity of substitution between capital and labor, which equals
one in case of a Cobb-Douglas production function. Equation (3) implies that the
person, with capital's share in factor income again being the crucial parameter.
Once only physical capital is considered, with γ of one third, the model would
predict enormous rate of return differentials between poor and rich economies:
The rate of return to physical capital should differ by a factor of 100, if income
per person differs by a factor of ten [ (1 / 10) ]. Hence, with an average profit rate
2
of about 10 percent in rich countries, poor countries should have profit rates of
But with a larger capital share, the predicted rate of return differentials reduce to
more reasonable figures. For instance, if physical and human capital together
account for two thirds of total factor income as before, the model would predict
that profit rates in poor and rich economies should differ by a factor of about 3
[ (1 / 10) ]. That is, once again the explicit consideration of human capital helps
0.5
magnitudes.6
The inclusion of human capital as a third factor of production also helps to bring
in line the predicted and the actually observed rate of convergence. The
6 Note that the calculated return differentials are gross of taxes and political risks. Moreover,
assuming a higher elasticity of substitution than one would further reduce the predicted
return differentials.
10
neoclassical growth model predicts that convergence towards the steady state is
given by
(4) λ = (1 − γ )( n + g + δ) ,
where λ is the rate of convergence. Numerous empirical studies have shown7 that
for the rate of population growth (n) of 1 percent, a rate of technological progress
becomes clear that the model without human capital would not predict the
percent. But once γ is assumed to equal two thirds due to the inclusion of human
capital, the convergence rate predicted by the model comes pretty close to the
Hence, in all three cases considered, the introduction of human capital greatly
physical capital share in factor income of about 30 percent, one would, therefore,
7 For a survey, see Sala-i-Martin (1996). Recent studies for large developing countries
include Bajpai and Sachs (1995), Gundlach (1996a), Jian et al. (1996), and Zini and Sachs
(1996).
11
with a higher physical capital share of about 60 percent (Lau et al. 1991,
Gundlach 1996b), one should expect to find human capital shares of about 10
evidence actually supports the calibration exercises for human capital's share in
factor income.
1. Back-of-the-Envelope Calculations
capital's share in factor income. Unlike the return to physical capital, the return to
human capital is not a separate part of the National Accounts Statistics, but is
included in labor's share in total factor income. Labor with human capital (skilled
labor) and labor without human capital (unskilled labor) together account for total
labor income. If either the rate of return on unskilled labor or on skilled labor
were known, it would be possible to assess human capital's share in labor income.
Consider first that the minimum wage has historically been about half of the
average wage in the US (Pritchett 1996a). If the minimum wage is taken to reflect
12
the return for workers with no human capital (unskilled labor), it follows that the
return to human capital is about two thirds of labor income. And since labor
about 45 percent. So one ends up with a broad capital share of about 75 percent.
This finding fits well into the calibration exercises of the last section.
The problem with this kind of benchmark estimate is that comparable data for
other countries are difficult to come by. Especially in developing countries, the
minimum wage is less enforced and less likely to be applicable and solid data are
least highly correlated with an increase in the stock of human capital. The reason
for such an approach is that many empirical studies find that each year of
calculate the difference between incomes achieved with human capital (proxied
return to schooling raised to the power of e. So for the world as a whole, one
would conclude that the average worker earns about three times [ e8⋅0.13 ] as much
The derived average multiplier of human capital in the range of three can be
replicated for various regions of the world. Regions with above average years of
schooling tend to have lower than average rates of return, and regions with below
average years of schooling tend to have higher than average rates of return. For
instance, Sub-Saharan Africa has 5.9 years of schooling and a social rate of return
schooling and a rate of return of 13.3 percent; Latin America has 7.9 years of
schooling and a rate of return of 12.8 percent; and the OECD has 10.9 years of
schooling and a rate of return of 10.2 percent.10 The resulting multipliers are 2.93
for Sub-Saharan Africa, 3.06 for non-OECD Asia, 2.75 for Latin America, and
9 At the macroeconomic level, the social rate of return to education rather than the private
rate has to be considered for an assessment of the role of human capital in economic
development.
10 All figures are taken from Psacharopoulos (1993, Table 1 and Table 4).
14
3.04 for the OECD. All this is pretty close to an average multiplier in the range of
three.
suggests that the income of the average worker can be expected to be three times
as high with human capital than without. Therefore, human capital's share in labor
income should be about two thirds, as was suggested by the calculations based on
the minimum wage. By implication, human capital's share in total factor income
share of about 30 percent. And in developing countries, where the profit share is
about 60 percent (Lau et al. 1991; Gundlach 1996b), human capital's share in
factor income should be about 25 percent. On average, one ends up with a broad
These parameter values almost perfectly solve same of the puzzling implications
capital into the model receives strong empirical support from back-of-the-
the central parameters also support the presumed role of human capital in
economic development.
15
2. Econometric Estimates
and input markets, the assumption of profit maximization implies that the
in economic development.
human capital formation on output has not been well documented, contrary to the
beginning to change, with mixed results. Very often, the variable used to proxy
insignificant impact on output. This result has led some researchers (Pritchett
production function studies. Such pitfalls can easily lead to a rejection of a correct
hypothesis.
Econometric Pitfalls
The multicollinearity of the data on the inputs is one reason why the effect of
aggregate production function studies. For instance, physical and human capital
physical and human capital using time series data from a single country.
rather than in first differences, especially if the long-run parameters are of interest
(Fugle and Granger 1987). Put differently, estimation in first differences would
imply that the underlying production function does not describe variables that
tend to move together in the long-run, i.e. are cointegrated. But if the variables on
the right-hand-side of the production function are not cointegrated, there simply is
Fortunately enough, large international data sets have become available such as
the Penn World Tables (PWT) introduced by Summers and Heston (1984); the
most recent update is PWT 5.6 (1994). These data sets allow for a study of the
cross-country data, sometimes in an even more subtle way. For instance, high
growth countries generally have higher investment rates, higher schooling rates,
and lower population growth rates than poor countries. Multicollinearity reduces
the precision with which regression coefficients can be estimated, which may
again be the reason for the finding of a statistically insignificant output effect of
human capital formation. But multicollinearity per se does not contaminate the
inference drawn from cross-country data because it does not bias the regression
coefficients and the standard errors. Therefore, multicollinearity might not seem
the coefficient on the variable measured with error. And at the same time, it can
bias upward the coefficients on variables correlated with the variable measured
with error. Therefore, if variables used to measure human capital formation are
18
more likely to be measured with error than others, downward biased regression
coefficients on human capital variables will be the result, as well as upward based
see that this is a likely possibility, consider how capital stock data are usually
calculated, which are required for the estimation of the structural form of the
production function .
Capital stock data are usually calculated by the perpetual inventory method. This
method requires a benchmark estimate for the capital stock of the initial period
considered. Since initial capital stocks are generally unknown, the conventional
procedure is to assume a benchmark value of zero for the first year of investment
for the benchmark year does not matter for empirical analyses that use capital
stock data beginning about 20 years after the benchmark year used for the
capital stocks is in fact more complicated for the case of human capital stocks.
This is because of the time lag between investment (school enrollment) and
addition to the human capital stock (entry into the labor force), as well as because
19
(Lau et al. 1991). Hence, longer backward time series of investment in human
capital are needed in order to derive stock data of comparable quality. Once such
longer time series are available at all, one has to assume how depreciation,
result, human capital stock data calculated by the perpetual inventory method are
more likely to exhibit larger measurement errors than physical capital stock data.
As a further complication, the bias could also go the other way round. The reason
also holds for the human capital variable. For instance, based on panel and time
empirical macroeconomic studies that have been performed recently to study the
− Convergence rate regressions, where the growth rate of output per person is
regressed on initial output per person and a sometimes long list of right-hand-
− structural form regressions, where output per person is regressed on the stocks
variables, and
− reduced form regressions, where output per person is regressed on the rate of
population growth and on the investment rates of physical and human capital.
All these possibilities are more or less explicitly based on a production function
like equation (1). They are not exclusive, because structural form specifications
pitfalls can arise. As a general rule, all sorts of problems tend to increase if the
because too many variables are included. The problem is that the more variables
are included on the right-hand-side of the regression equation, the less clear
to include in the regression equation proxy variables for political stability (Barro
1991), openness (Sachs and Warner 1996), or the income distribution (Rodrik
for the factor income generated by such variables. Whenever auxiliary variables
enter the regression analysis in addition to the variables suggested by the theory
capital, the residual role for characteristics obviously correlated with investment
Not surprisingly, Levine and Renelt (1992) have shown that Barro regressions
and looking for high t-values will not suffice as a proof of the pudding.
production function is well specified. That is, the main, and possibly, only
is used, α and β are the production elasticities of physical all human capital to be
(6)
α +β α β
ln(Y / L) = B − ln( n + g + δ) + ln INVK + ln INV H ,
1− α − β 1− α − β 1− α − β
( INVH ).
The principal attractiveness of these equations for regression analysis results from
two features. First, there are restrictions on the regression coefficients that can be
imposed and tested. This property allows for a statistical evaluation of the
13 Y/L is output per person, B is a regression constant representing the initial level of
technology and the assumed constant growth rate of technology, INVK is investment in
physical capital and INVH is investment in human capital.
24
Second, for constant returns to scale and competitive factor markets, the
production elasticities should equal the respective factor shares. This property
allows for an economic evaluation of the estimation results by comparing the size
development would use factor shares for physical and human capital as
coefficients, one may conclude that certain results do not make sense
economically.
In a rather influential study, Benhabib and Spiegel (1994) use a variant of the
structural form of the production function (see equation 5) to estimate the role of
negative sign. In order to obtain a more positive role for human capital formation,
they suggest an alternative growth model. In this new model, human capital
models of Lucas (1988) and Romer (1990). Their empirical results seem to
suggest that the role of human capital is indeed one of facilitating adoption of
production elasticity of physical capital should be much larger than its factor
pretty close to its expected factor share in the range of 30 percent. Therefore,
some doubts remain as to the usefulness of the new model. Measurement error
data set for average years of schooling has been provided by Barro and Lee
(1994). These data are likely to provide better proxies for the stock of human
Similar to Benhabib and Spiegel (1994), Lau et al. (1991) estimate a variant of
the structural form of the production function. They relate aggregate real GDP to
26
physical capital stock, labor force, land, and average education of the labor force
as a proxy for the stock of human capital. For a sample of developing countries,
for various specifications. Once they allow for region specific effects, their
estimates for the production elasticity of human capital increase to 20 percent for
Latin America and East Asia. Together with the estimate of the production
elasticity of physical capital, the latter results imply a broad capital share of about
Again based on a variant of the structural form of the production function, Kim
and Lau (1992) find production elasticities of physical capital for industrialized
countries which are close to conventional factor shares. However, the estimated
range from 10 percent (United States) to 20 percent (Japan). Applying the same
approach to cross-sectional state data from Brazil, Lau et al. (1993) find a
expected range for a developing country. But this time, their estimate for the
principle.
Mankiw et al. (1992) is the seminal paper using a reduced form of the production
elasticities for both human and physical capital of about one third. Although these
estimates may still suffer from all sorts of econometric problems, they obviously
do less so than the previously presented estimates. To begin with, according to the
long as the theory is correct. By implication, the stock variables used in the
structural form (see equation 5) are necessarily endogenous if the Solow model is
right. This is why reduced form estimation should be preferred, at least as long as
play a smaller role because investment rates (flows) are somewhat easier to
28
measure than accumulated stock variables. And if measurement error is less likely
Therefore, the estimated broad capital share of about two thirds can be considered
growth. This is not to deny that the estimate for the production elasticity of
human capital seems to be somewhat on the low side. Using a specification that
combines the structural and reduced form representation with the stock of human
find that human capital's share in factor income is about two thirds rather than one
third (Gundlach 1995). The results of alternative estimation techniques reveal that
my finding does not suffer from an upward bias due to the potential endogeneity
of the stock of human capital. At the same time, the Mankiw et al. finding does
not seem to suffer from downward bias due to measurement error. This outcome
capital has a factor share of two thirds and physical capital has a factor share of
one third, one ends up with a broad capital share of 100 percent. This total capital
section II).
29
(1996) who uses an alternative measure of human capital formation and finds that
initial stocks and subsequent growth of human capital play a role in fostering
regression equation remains somewhat unclear. If both the stock and the flow of
endogenous growth models such as Romer (1990), it is no longer clear what kind
coefficients are not necessarily meaningful from an economic point of view even
if they have the right sign. Here, the estimated regression coefficients on initial
income provide a case in point, because they have a negative sign and are
statistically different from zero. Unfortunately, they are larger than 1 in absolute
value. This result is incompatible with the rate of convergence predicted by the
model is used, initial income should have a positive regression coefficient or may
Knight et al. (1993) use the Mankiw et al.-framework to employ a technique for
using a panel of cross-section and time series data for a large number of countries.
regression results imply a physical capital share of about 40 percent and a rather
reproducing a broad capital share of about 60 percent close to the Mankiw et al.
(1992) finding.
Still, it remains unclear whether the move from cross-sectional to panel data
observations (Mankiw 1995). The reason is that the new observations are not
independent of the old ones. While this problem may be handled by appropriate
Also based on a reduced form specification in the tradition of Mankiw et al. like
equation (6), I estimate production elasticities of human and physical capital for a
31
explain the observed 2 percent rate of convergence of output per person across
On balance, it seems to me that the econometric results do not allow for a clear-
macroeconomic level. The results that come closest to a priori expectations share
based on the underlying theory, and, second, a functional form of the regression
equation that tends to reduce econometric problems. While the findings for the
the findings for the production elasticity of human capital tend to be on the low
side in most cases. An apparent reason for this result is measurement bias.
32
of formal education as a proxy for human capital formation. But one has to keep
in mind that not all education produces human capital and, even more
importantly, not all human capital is produced by education (Knight 1996). What
has been neglected so far are, e.g., international differences in the quality of
schooling, and the role of nutrition and health as preconditions for a successful
the lack of adjustment for extent and quality of schooling. Typical school years
vary from under 100 days to over 200 days. And even holding constant school
days, it is quite obvious that a year of secondary schooling, say, in Japan is not
equivalent to a year at the same grade level in, say, Tanzania. Given these
completed is a good proxy for the amount of human capital of the labor force:
student achievement in the fields of mathematics and science. Four of these tests
mathematics and science scores for each category, the final sample consists of 39
(see section III), Kim and Hanushek find that the quality variable has a
by Lee and Lee (1995), who use a smaller sample of 17 observations based on
34
interpretation.
Since the work of Becker (1964) and Mincer (1974), both schooling and
gained by learning on the job. This experience is usually proxied by the age
structure of the workforce. In a seminal paper, Krueger (1968) uses this insight to
education and experience. With data for the 1950, she finds that more than half
the difference in income per person between the United States and a sample of
capital.
These results can be interpreted as giving the maximum income attainable for a
worker from a developing country if he or she were working with the average
35
function context outlined in section II, it follows that these income figures have
the dimension of the relative (to the US) human capital stocks raised to the power
stock of human capital that represents both schooling and experience of the
workforce.
Such a broader measure of human capital can be compared with the estimates
based on schooling alone that have been used in the regression analyses referred
to in section III. With data for the 1980s, I show that there are substantial
differences between the two types of estimates with regard to level and variance
across countries (Gundlach 1994). Especially the estimates for average years of
schooling by Kyriacou (1991) and Lau et al. (1991) deviate from my figures
derived by the Krueger-method, while the estimates by Barro and Lee (1994)
data or the Lau et al.-data as a proxy for human capital could be more likely to
capital variable than studies that use the Barro and Lee-data. To substantiate this
hypothesis, further research should extend and update the sample of countries for
Another possible bias in the measurement of the stock of human capital could
result from the neglect of international differences in the health status and basic
nutrition of the workforce. This is because many empirical micro studies show
that health status and nutrition are strongly associated with educational
factors that determine the aggregate stock of human capital together with the
findings about the effect of health and nutrition on schooling success are difficult
to come by empirically, because statistical association per se does not indicate the
nutritional intake are probably not predetermined before education and labor
productivity, at least once redistribution within the family is taken into account.
productivity are used partly to improve health or nutrition, then it will be difficult
to find instrumental variables to disentangle only the one-way effect of health and
of the individual before reaching age four. If so, height can be viewed as an
indicator of nutritional status and health status that is essentially fixed in early
Based on this reasoning, Fogel (1990) argues that the improvement in diet that
contributed to the increase in adult height is responsible for a third of the growth
these findings for today's poor countries is that childhood stunting due to
malnutrition has a long reach, predicting chronic disease rates at young adult and
later ages, with negative consequences for average productivity growth. First
between individual incomes and height (Thomas and Strauss 1992). All this
seems to indicate that the observed gains in stature and longevity are responsible
for some portion of modern economic growth, both in developing countries and
reached a stage that would allow for detailed quantitative assessments. Further
workforce, the nutritional status, and the health status all point to possible
measurement errors that are likely to arise when only the quantity of formal
education is used as a proxy for human capital. The results of a number of recent
that there is ample room for an improvement of the empirical estimates. In the
meantime, economic theory has to carry the bulk of the argument which favors
the view that human capital formation is one of the most important determinants
of economic development.
39
REFERENCES
Pritchett, Lant (1996b). Where Has All the Education Gone? World Bank, Policy
Research Working Papers, 1581, March.
Psacharopoulos, George (1993). Returns to Investment in Education. A Global
Update. World Bank, Policy Research Working Papers, 1067, January.
Rodrik, Dani (1994). King Kong Meets Godzilla: The World Bank and The East
Asian Miracle. CEPR Discussion Paper, 944, April.
Romer, Paul M. (1986). Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth. Journal of
Political Economy 94: 1002-1037.
Romer, Paul M. (1990). Endogenous Technological Change. Journal of Political
Economy 89 (5,2): 71-102.
Sachs, Jeffrey D., Andrew Warner (1995). Economic Convergence and Economic
Policies. NBER Working Paper, 5039, February.
Sala-i-Martin, Xavier (1996). The Classical Approach to Convergence Analysis.
Economic Journal 106: 1019-1036.
Solow, Robert M. (1956). A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth.
Quarterly Journal of Economics 70: 65-94.
Solow, Robert M. (1957). Technical Change and the Aggregate Production
Function. Review of Economics and Statistics 39: 312-320.
Schultz, T. Paul (1993). The Role of Education and Human Capital in Economic
Development: An Empirical Assessment. In: Horst Siebert (ed.), Economic
Growth in the World Economy. Symposium 1992. Tübingen: 145-164.
Steckel, Richard H. (1995). Stature and the Standard of Living. Journal of
Economic Literature 33: 1903-1940.
Stokey, Nancy L. (1988). Learning by Doing and the Introduction of New Goods.
Journal of Political Economy 96: 701-717.
Summers, Robert, Alan Heston (1984). Improved International Comparisons of
Real Product and Its Composition: 1950-80. Review of Income and Wealth
30 (2): 207-262.
Symposium New Growth Theory (1994). Journal of Economic Perspectives 8: 3-
72.
Thomas, Duncan, John Strauss (1992). Health, Wealth and Labor Market
Outcomes of Men and Women: Evidence from Brazil. Paper presented at the
43