0% found this document useful (0 votes)
9 views

Report Awarness Workshop

Corporate governance

Uploaded by

akshayandani05
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
0% found this document useful (0 votes)
9 views

Report Awarness Workshop

Corporate governance

Uploaded by

akshayandani05
Copyright
© © All Rights Reserved
We take content rights seriously. If you suspect this is your content, claim it here.
Available Formats
Download as PDF, TXT or read online on Scribd
You are on page 1/ 8

Report on Corporate Governance

"...Fundamental objective of corporate governance is the enhancement of the long-term


shareholder value while at the same time protecting the interests of other stakeholders."

While recent high-profile corporate governance failures in developed countries have


brought the subject to media attention, the issue has always been central to finance and
economics. The issue is particularly important for developing countries since it is central
to financial and economic development. Recent research has established that financial
development is largely dependent on investor protection in a country – de jure and de
facto. With the legacy of the English legal system, India has one of the best corporate
governance laws but poor implementation together with socialistic policies of the pre
reform era has affected corporate governance. Concentrated ownership of shares,
pyramiding and tunneling of funds among group companies mark the Indian corporate
landscape. Boards of directors have frequently been silent spectators with the DFI
nominee directors unable or unwilling to carry out their monitoring functions. Since
liberalization, however, serious efforts have been directed at overhauling the system with
the SEBI instituting the Clause 49 of the Listing Agreements dealing with corporate
governance. Corporate governance of Indian banks is also undergoing a process of
change with a move towards more market-based governance.

Corporate Governance in India – Evolution and Challenges


Introduction

The subject of corporate governance leapt to global business limelight from relative
obscurity after a string of collapses of high profile companies. Enron, the Houston, Texas
based energy giant, and WorldCom, the telecom behemoth, shocked the business world
with both the scale and age of their unethical and illegal operations. Worse, they seemed
to indicate only the tip of a dangerous iceberg. While corporate practices in the US
companies came under attack, it appeared that the problem was far more widespread.
Large and trusted companies from Parmal at in Italy to the multinational newspaper
group Hollinger Inc., revealed significant and deep-rooted problems in their corporate
governance. Even the prestigious New York Stock Exchange had to remove its director,
Dick Grasso, amidst public outcry over excessive compensation. It was clear that
something was amiss in the area of corporate governance all over the world. Corporate
governance has, of course, been an important field of query within the finance discipline
for decades. Researchers in finance have actively investigated the topic for at least a
quarter century1 and the father of modern economics, Adam Smith, himself had
recognized the problem over two centuries ago. There have been debates about whether
the Anglo-Saxon market- model of corporate governance is better than the bank based
models of Germany and Japan. However, the differences in the quality of corporate
governance in these developed countries fade in comparison to the chasm that exists
between corporate governance standards and practices in these countries as a group and
those in the developing world. Corporate governance has been a central issue in
developing countries long before the recent spate of corporate scandals in advanced
economies made headlines. Indeed corporate governance and economic development are
intrinsically linked. Effective corporate governance systems promote the development of
strong financial systems irrespective of whether they are largely bank-based or market-
based – which, in turn, have an unmistakably positive effect on economic growth and
poverty reduction. There are several channels through which the causality works.
Effective corporate governance enhances access to external financing by firms, leading to
greater investment, as well as higher growth and employment. The proportion of private
credit to GDP in countries in the highest quartile of creditor right enactment and
enforcement is more than double that in the countries in the lowest quartile.4 As for
equity financing, the ratio of stock market capitalization to GDP in the countries in the
highest quartile of shareholder right enactment and enforcement is about four times as
large as that for countries in the lowest quartile. Poor corporate governance also hinders
the creation and development of new firms.

Good corporate governance also lowers of the cost of capital by reducing risk and creates
higher firm valuation once again boosting real investments.5 There is a variation of a
factor of 8 in the “control premium” (transaction price of shares in block transfers
signifying control transfer less the ordinary share price) between countries with the
highest level of equity rights protection and those with the lowest. Effective corporate
governance mechanisms ensure better resource allocation and management raising the
return to capital. The return on assets (ROA) is about twice as high in the countries with
the highest level of equity rights protection as in countries with the lowest protection. 7
Good corporate governance can significantly reduce the risk of nation-wide financial
crises. There is a strong inverse relationship between the quality of corporate governance
and currency depreciation. 8 Indeed poor transparency and corporate governance norms
are believed to be the key reasons behind the Asian Crisis of 1997. Such financial crises
have massive economic and social costs and can set a country several years back in its
path to development. Finally, good corporate governance can remove mistrust between
different stakeholders, reduce legal costs and improve social and labor relationships and
external economies like environmental protection. Making sure that the managers
actually act on behalf of the owners of the company – the stockholders – and pass on the
profits to them are the key issues in corporate governance. Limited liability and dispersed
ownership – essential features that the joint-stock company form of organization thrives
on – inevitably lead to a distance and inefficient monitoring of management by the actual
owners of the business. Managers enjoy actual control of business and may not serve in
the best interests of the shareholders. These potential problems of corporate governance
are universal. In addition, the Indian financial sector is marked with a relatively
unsophisticated equity market vulnerable to manipulation and with rudimentary analyst
activity; a dominance of family firms; a history of managing agency system; and a
generally high level of corruption. All these features make corporate governance a
particularly important issue in India.
Central issues in Corporate Governance
The basic power structure of the joint-stock company form of business, in principle, is as
follows. The numerous shareholders who contribute to the capital of the company are the
actual owners of business. They elect a Board of Directors to monitor the running of the
company on their behalf. The Board, in turn, appoints a team of managers who actually
handle the day-to-day functioning of the company and report periodically to the Board.
Thus mangers are the agents of shareholders and function with the objective of
maximizing shareholders’ wealth. Even if this power pattern held in reality, it would still
be a challenge for the Board to effectively monitor management. The central issue is the
nature of the contract between shareholder representatives and managers telling the latter
what to do with the funds contributed by the former. The main challenge comes from the
fact that such contracts are necessarily “incomplete”. It is not possible for the Board to
fully instruct management on the desired course of action under every possible business
situation. The list of possible situations is infinitely long. Consequently, no contract can
be written between representatives of shareholders and the management that specifies the
right course of action in every situation, so that the management can be held for violation
of such a contract in the event it does something else under the circumstances. Because
of this “incomplete contracts” situation, some “residual powers” over the funds of the
company must be vested with either the financiers or the management. Clearly the former
does not have the expertise or the inclination to run the business in the situations
unspecified in the contract, so these residual powers must go to management. The
efficient limits to these powers constitute much of the subject of corporate governance.
The reality is even more complicated and biased in favor of management. In real life,
managers wield an enormous amount of power in joint-stock companies and the common
shareholder has very little say in the way his or her money is used in the company. In
companies with highly dispersed ownership, the manager (the CEO in the American
setting, the Managing Director in British-style organizations) functions with negligible
accountability. Most shareholders do not care to attend the General Meetings to elect or
change the Board of Directors and often grant their “proxies” to the management. Even
those that attend the meeting find it difficult to have a say in the selection of directors as
only the management gets to propose a slate of directors for voting. On his part the CEO
frequently packs the board with his friends and allies who rarely differ with him. Often
the CEO himself is the Chairman of the Board of Directors as well. Consequently the
supervisory role of the Board is often severely compromised and the management, who
really has the keys to the business, can potentially use corporate resources to further their
own self- interests rather than the interests of the shareholders. The inefficacy of the
Board of Directors in monitoring the activities of management is particularly marked in
the Anglo-Saxon corporate structure where real monitoring is expected to come from
financial markets. The underlying premise is that shareholders dissatisfied with a
particular management would simply dispose of their shares in the company. As this
would drive down the share price, the company would become a takeover target. If and
when the acquisition actually happens, the acquiring company would get rid of the
existing management. It is thus the fear of a takeover rather than shareholder action that
is supposed to keep the management honest and on its toes. This mechanism, however,
presupposes the existence of a deep and liquid stock market with considerable
informational efficiency as well as a legal and financial system conducive to M&A
activity. More often than not, these features do not exist in developing countries like
India. An alternative corporate governance model is that provided by the bank-based
economies like Germany where the main bank (“Hausbank” in Germany) lending to the
company exerts considerable influence and carries out continuous project-level
supervision of the management and the supervisory board has representatives of multiple
stakeholders of the firm. Box 1 gives a brief comparison of the two systems Common
areas of management action that may be sub-optimal or contrary to shareholders’
interests (other than outright stealing) involve excessive executive compensation; transfer
pricing, that is transacting with privately owned companies at other-than- market rates to
siphon off funds; managerial entrenchment (i.e. managers resisting replacement by a
superior management) and sub-optimal use of free cash flows. This last refers to the use
that managers put the retained earnings of the company. In the absence of profitable
investment opportunities, these funds are frequently squandered on questionable empire-
building investments and acquisitions when their best use is to be returned to the
shareholders.

Legal environment, ownership patterns and Corporate Governance


The legal system of a country plays a crucial role in creating an effective corporate
governance mechanism in a country and protecting the rights of investors and creditors.
The legal environment encompasses two important aspects – the protection offered in the
laws (de jure protection) and to what extent the laws are enforced in real life (de facto
protection). Both these aspects play important roles in determining the nature of
corporate governance in the country in question. Recent research has forcefully
connected the origins of the legal system of a country to the very structure of its financial
and economic architecture arguing that the connection works through the protection
given to external financiers of companies – creditors and shareholders.11 Legal systems in
most countries have their roots in one of the four distinct legal systems – the English
common law, French civil law, German civil law and Scandinavian civil law. The Indian
legal system is obviously built on the English common law system. The Rule of law
index is another story. Here the Scandinavian-origin countries have an average score of
10 – the maximum possible – followed by the German-origin countries (8.68), English-
origin countries (6.46) and French-origin countries (6.05). The primary difference
between the legal systems in advanced countries and those in developing countries lies in
enforcement rather than in the nature of laws- in books. Enforcement of laws play a much
more important role than the quality of the laws on books in determining events like CEO
turnover and developing security markets by eliminating insider trading.12 In an
environment marked by weak enforcement of property rights and contracts, entrepreneurs
and managers find it difficult to signal their commitment to the potential investors,
leading to limited external financing and ownership concentration. This particularly hurts
the development of new firms and the small and medium enterprises (SMEs). In such a
situation many of the standard methods of corporate governance – market for corporate
controls, board activity, proxy fights and executive compensation – lose their
effectiveness. Large block-holding emerges as the most important corporate governance
mechanism with some potential roles for bank monitoring, shareholder activism,
employee monitoring and social control.
Apart from the universal features of corporate governance, Asian economies as a
group share certain common features that affect the nature of corporate governance in the
region.

Corporate Governance in India – a background


The history of the development of Indian corporate laws has been marked by interesting
contrasts. At independence, India inherited one of the world’s poorest economies but one
which had a factory sector accounting for a tenth of the national product; four functioning
stock markets (predating the Tokyo Stock Exchange) with clearly defined rules
governing listing, trading and settlements; a well-developed equity culture if only among
the urban rich; and a banking system replete with well-developed lending norms and
recovery procedures.24 In terms of corporate laws and financial system, therefore, India
emerged far better endowed than most other colonies. The 1956 Companies Act as well
as other laws governing the functioning of joint-stock companies and protecting the
investors’ rights built on this foundation. The beginning of corporate developments in
India were marked by the managing agency system that contributed to the birth of
dispersed equity ownership but also gave rise to the practice of management enjoying
control rights disproportionately greater than their stock ownership. The turn towards
socialism in the decades after independence marked by the 1951 Industries (Development
and Regulation) Act as well as the 1956 Industrial Policy Resolution put in place a
regime and culture of licensing, protection and widespread red-tape that bred corruption
and stilted the growth of the corporate sector. The situation grew from bad to worse in the
following decades and corruption, nepotism and inefficiency became the hallmarks of the
Indian corporate sector. Exorbitant tax rates encouraged creative accounting practices and
complicated emolument structures to beat the system. In the absence of a developed stock
market, the three all-India development finance institutions (DFIs)– the Industrial
Finance Corporation of India, the Industrial Development Bank of India and the
Industrial Credit and Investment Corporation of India,– together with the state financial
corporations became the main providers of long-term credit to companies. Along with the
government owned mutual fund, the Unit Trust of India, they also held large blocks of
shares in the companies they lent to and invariably had representations in their boards. In
this respect, the corporate governance system resembled the bank-based German model
where these institutions could have played a big role in keeping their clients on the right
track. Unfortunately, they were themselves evaluated on the quantity rather than quality
of their lending and thus had little incentive for either proper credit appraisal or effective
follow-up and monitoring. Their nominee directors routinely served as rubber-stamps of
the management of the day. With their support, promoters of businesses in India could
actually enjoy managerial control with very little equity investment of their own.
Borrowers therefore routinely recouped their investment in a short period and then had
little incentive to either repay the loans or run the business. Frequently they bled the
company with impunity, siphoning off funds with the DFI nominee directors mute
spectators in their boards.

Changes since liberalization

The years since liberalization have witnessed wide-ranging changes in both laws and
regulations driving corporate governance as well as general consciousness about it
Perhaps the single most important development in the field of corporate governance and
investor protection in India has been the establishment of the Securities and Exchange
Board of India (SEBI) in 1992 and its gradual empowerment since then. Established
primarily to regulate and monitor stock trading, it has played a crucial role in establishing
the basic minimum ground rules of corporate conduct in the country. Concerns about
corporate governance in India were, however, largely triggered by a spate of crises in the
early 90’s – the Harshad Mehta stock market scam of 1992 followed by incidents of
companies allotting preferential shares to their promoters at deeply discounted prices as
well as those of companies simply disappearing with investors’ money. These concerns
about corporate governance stemming from the corporate scandals as well as opening up
to the forces of competition and globalization gave rise to several investigations into the
ways to fix the corporate governance situation in India. One of the first among such
endeavors was the CII Code for Desirable Corporate Governance developed by a
committee chaired by Rahul Bajaj. The committee was formed in 1996 and submitted its
code in April 1998. Later SEBI constituted two committees to look into the issue of
corporate governance – the first chaired by Kumar Mangalam Birla that submitted its
report in early 2000 and the second by Narayana Murthy three years later. Table 1
provides a comparative view of the recommendations of these important efforts at
improving corporate governance in India. The SEBI committee recommendations have
had the maximum impact on changing the corporate governance situation in India. The
Advisory Group on Corporate Governance of RBI’s Standing Committee on
International Financial Standards and Codes also submitted its own recommendations in
2001.

Corporate Governance of Banks

Nowhere is proper corporate governance more crucial than for banks and financial
institutions. Given the pivotal role that banks play in the financial and economic system
of a developing country, bank failure owing to unethical or incompetent management
action poses a threat not just to the shareholders but to the depositing public and the
economy at large. Two main features set banks apart from other business – the level of
opaqueness in their functioning and the relatively greater role of government and
regulatory agencies in their activities. The opaqueness in banking creates considerable
information asymmetries between the “insiders” – management – and “outsiders” –
owners and creditors. The very nature of the business makes it extremely easy and
tempting for management to alter the risk profile of banks as well as siphon off funds. It
is, therefore, much more difficult for the owners to effectively monitor the functioning of
bank management. Existence of explicit or implicit deposit insurance also reduces the
interest of depositors in monitoring bank management activities. It is partly for these
reasons that prudential norms of banking and close monitoring by the central bank of
commercial bank activities are essential for smooth functioning of the banking sector.
Government control or monitoring of banks, on the other hand, brings in its wake, the
possibility of corruption and diversion of credit of political purposes which may, in the
long run, jeopardize the financial health of the bank as well as the economy itself. The
reforms have marked a shift from hands-on government control interference to market
forces as the dominant paradigm of corporate governance in Indian banks. Competition
has been encouraged with the issue of licenses to new private banks and more power and
flexibility have been granted to the bank management both in directing credit as well as
in setting prices. The RBI has moved to a model of governance by prudential norms
rather from that of direct interference, even allowing debate about appropriateness of
specific regulations among banks. Along with these changes, market institutions have
been strengthened by government with attempts to infuse greater transparency and
liquidity in markets for government securities and other asset markets. This market
orientation of governance disciplining in banking has been accompanied by a stronger
disclosure norms and stress on periodic RBI surveillance. From 1994, the Board for
Financial Supervision (BFS) inspects and monitors banks using the “CAMELS” (Capital
adequacy, Asset quality, Management, Earnings, Liquidity and Systems and controls)
approach. Audit committees in banks have been stipulated since 1995. Greater
independence of public sector banks has also been a key feature of the reforms. Nominee
directors – from government as well as RBIs – are being gradually phased off with a
stress on Boards being more often elected than “appointed from above”. There is
increasing emphasis on greater professional representation on bank boards with the
expectation that the boards will have the authority and competence to properly manage
the banks within the broad prudential norms set by RBI. Rules like no lending to
companies who have one or more of a bank’s directors on their boards are being softened
or removed altogether, thus allowing for “related party” transactions for banks. The need
for professional advice in the election of executive directors is increasingly realized. As
for old private banks, concentrated ownership remains a widespread characteristic,
limiting the possibilities of professional excellence and opening the possibility of
misdirecting credit. Corporate governance in co-operative banks and NBFCs perhaps
need the greatest attention from regulators. Rural co-operative banks are frequently run
by politically powerful families as their personal fiefdoms with little professional
involvement and considerable channeling of credit to family businesses. It is generally
believed that the “new” private banks have better and more professional corporate
governance systems in place. However, the recent collapse of the Global Trust Bank has
seriously challenged that view and spurred serious thinking on the topic.

Conclusions

With the recent spate of corporate scandals and the subsequent interest in corporate
governance, a plethora of corporate governance norms and standards have sprouted
around the globe. The Sarbanes-Oxley legislation in the USA, the Cadbury Committee
recommendations for European companies and the OECD principles of corporate
governance are perhaps the best known among these. But developing countries have not
fallen behind either. Well over a hundred different codes and norms have been identified
in recent surveys 28 and their number is steadily increasing. India has been no exception
to the rule. Several committees and groups have looked into this issue that undoubtedly
deserves all the attention it can get. In the last few years the thinking on the topic in India
has gradually crystallized into the development of norms for listed companies. The
problem for private companies, that form a vast majority of Indian corporate entities,
remains largely unaddressed. The agency problem is likely to be less marked there as
ownership and control are generally not separated. Minority shareholder exploitation, ho
waver, can very well be an important issue in many cases. Development of norms and
guidelines are an important first step in a serious effort to improve corporate governance.
The bigger challenge in India, however, lies in the proper implementation of those rules
at the ground level. More and more it appears that outside agencies like analysts and
stock markets (particularly foreign markets for companies making GDR issues) have the
most influence on the actions of managers in the leading companies of the country. But
their influence is restricted to the few top (albeit largest) companies. More needs to be
done to ensure adequate corporate governance in the average Indian company. Even the
most prudent norms can be hoodwinked in a system plagued with widespread corruption.
Nevertheless, with industry organizations and chambers of commerce themselves pushing
for an improved corporate governance system, the future of corporate governance in
India promises to be distinctly better than the past.

You might also like