MIT Syllabus Politika
MIT Syllabus Politika
Instructors:
Frank Schilbach ([email protected])
Individual Zoom office hours by appointment – please sign up HERE.
Recitations: https://mit.zoom.us/j/91727034890
Thursdays 1:00 PM - 2:00 PM
Fridays 11:00 AM - 12:00 PM
Fridays 2:00 PM - 3:00 PM
Course website:
https://canvas.mit.edu/courses/3612
Course Overview. Behavioral Economics (aka ‘Psychology and Economics’) is a growing sub-field of eco-
nomics that incorporates insights from psychology and other social sciences into economics. The broad goal
of these efforts is to make economic models more realistic and to strengthen their predictive power by in-
corporating previously neglected features such as self-control issues, concern for others, or aversion to losses.
This course covers recent advances in behavioral economics by reviewing some of the assumptions made
in mainstream economic models, and by discussing how human behavior systematically departs from these
assumptions. We draw on empirical evidence from psychology and related fields that sheds light on prefer-
ences, cognition, and behavior. Topics include deviations from the standard model in terms of (i) preferences
(present bias, reference dependence, and social preferences), (ii) beliefs (overconfidence, projection bias, and
attribution bias), and (iii) decision-making (cognition, attention, and framing), as well as (iv) market and
policy reactions to such deviations. Applications will cover a wide range of fields, including labor and public
1
economics, industrial organization, health economics, finance, and development economics. Students partici-
pate in surveys and small experiments in class, review evidence from lab and field experiments, and examine
how the results can be integrated into existing or novel models.
Prerequisites. As the class is considering deviations from mainstream models of economics, a solid grasp
of these models is essential for mastering the material. Therefore, 14.01 or an equivalent introductory mi-
croeconomics course is a prerequisite for this class. If you have not taken 14.01, please talk to the instructors
after the first lecture to discuss whether this class is suitable for you.
Reading materials. There is no textbook for this course. The fairly detailed lecture slides are meant to
be self-explanatory, and they are complemented by recitation slides as well as by a set of readings for each
class, as specified in the reading list. Starred readings will feature in lectures, exams, and problem sets. If
a reading is starred, you are strongly encouraged to read the paper prior to class, which means reading the
sections announced in class, usually abstract, introduction, and selected sections of the paper.
Lectures. Each lecture will be given on Zoom during the scheduled time of the class. Students are strongly
encouraged to attend these lectures synchronously during this time. However, given difficulties for some stu-
dents to attend online lectures live in different time zones, etc., a recording of this class will be uploaded to
the course website as well. Recitations will also be recorded. Given that the class does not follow a textbook,
most of the course materials will be based on academic papers from leading journals. While the lecture slides
are fairly comprehensive, the course material will be difficult to master without attending lectures live or
watching the recordings. However, attendance does not factor into grades (see below).
Grading. The class is not graded on a curve. It is possible that everyone will do very well, which will make
us very happy. However, if you do not put effort into this class, you will likely not do well. If we think
you are in danger of failing the class, we will try to warn you before the drop date. Here are the different
components of your grade:
• Exams (50%). There will be two exams, which will both be administered online.
(1) The mid-term exam will count for 25% of your grade. It will be designed for 85 minutes but you
will be given 120 minutes to complete it online to account for difficulties uploading your answers
or any other issues that may arise. The mid-term exam will take place on October 20, 2020
(instead of class on that day). Starting at 8:01 am EDT, you will be given 12 hours (until 8:00
pm EDT) to pick a 120-minute window during which you can complete the exam.
(2) The cumulative final exam (180 minutes) will count for 25% of your grade. Again, we will ensure
you have time to upload your answers. If your grade on the final is higher than your grade on
the midterm, both grades will be replaced with your grade on the final so that your final counts
for 50% of your grade. The final exam will take place during the finals period (exact day to be
determined by the registrar). Starting at 8:01 am EST, you will be given 12 hours (until 8:00 pm
EST) to pick a 180-minute window during which you can complete the exam.
• Problem sets (30%). There will be five problem sets over the course of the semester, which will
cover materials from lecture, readings, and class discussions. You must submit your problem sets
in pdf-form using Gradescope (https://www.gradescope.com/). Late problem sets will not be ac-
cepted, and there won’t be any exceptions to this policy. To accommodate for unanticipated events,
illness, conflicts in your schedule, or other rational or irrational reasons that may prevent you from
submitting the problem set on time, we will automatically drop the problem set with your lowest score.
2
Note that problem sets are each due at 6 pm. Please make sure to submit your problem set a bit earlier
to account for network issues or other unforeseen problems. Late problem sets will not be accepted for
such reasons.
• Weekly memos (20%). Each week, you will be asked to write a brief memo (1 - 2 paragraphs) that
relates the class content to issues that you experienced in your life. Memos will be due on Sunday at
6pm, and should be at least 150 words (please do not send more than one page).
The goal of the memos is for you to reflect on the course material and think about how it is relevant
to your life. In addition, the memos will help you stay up-to-date with the course materials each week.
As such, we will not grade the memos harshly and expect to give most memos full marks. Your best
8 out of 10 memos will count toward your grade.
Questions regarding grading. You should direct any questions regarding grading first to your TA. Im-
portantly, you must raise any issues no more than one week after the assignment has been handed back. To
have your grading be reconsidered, take the following steps:
(1) Email your TA along with a note describing specifically what you believe the problem to be.
(2) The TA will schedule an in-person meeting to discuss the issue, likely during TA office hours.
Getting help outside of class. If you have questions regarding the class material or problem sets, there
are four ways to get help:
(i) Use the online forum (Link to Piazza). We will have threaded discussions (monitored by the TAs
and professor) for all problem sets and class-related topics, which should allow you to get a timely,
high-quality answer to most of your questions.
(ii) Ask questions during recitation and lectures.
(iii) Ask questions during TA office hours (on Zoom, see above).
(iv) Ask questions during Prof. Schilbach’s office hours (on Zoom, see above)
Please avoid sending us your class-related questions by email (except for personal class-related matters).
The discussion forum and office hours are more efficient ways for us to communicate with you, and your
forum questions and responses will benefit many of your classmates.
Academic integrity. In this class, you will be held to the high standard of academic integrity expected of
all students at MIT.
• We will follow MIT’s Academic Integrity Policy (see complete policy at Integrity at MIT).
• You may work jointly with other groups on problem sets but each of you must submit solutions
individually. If you choose to work with other students, we expect that you work jointly on the
solutions rather than simply copying solutions from another student. This will help you to learn the
material and to prepare for exams.
• IMPORTANT: On the mid-term and final exam, you can consult your notes but you must work on
your own, i.e. without the help of other students or anyone else in person or online.
• Violating the Academic Integrity policy in any way will result in official Institute sanction. Please
review the Academic Integrity policy and related resources, and contact us if you have any questions
related to the Academic Integrity of this course.
Check. Great, you are still reading! To confirm that you indeed read the syllabus, please send an email with
a picture of a bear to Prof. Schilbach ([email protected]), with the subject line “14.13 confirmation". Please
send interesting pictures, not just the first one that shows up when googling ‘bear’.
3
Tentative Schedule and Reading List
General books of interest (not required). The following books are background readings in case you
would like to learn more. They are by no means required!
Tentative schedule. Below is a tentative schedule for the semester, along with the corresponding reading
materials for each class.
• Class topics and readings are subject to revision, i.e. some topics might be revised or even dropped
altogether if time runs short.
• Starred readings will be covered in lectures, problem sets and exams. Students are strongly encouraged
to read these papers before coming to class.
• We will announce in each class which paper(s) to read for the subsequent class(es).
• Non-starred readings are not required, but they may help you understand the materials covered in
lectures or problem sets. You might want to consult these papers in case you’d like to deepen your
understanding of the material covered in class, but we will not test you on the content of these papers
beyond the parts that are covered in class.
4
Quasi-Hyperbolic Discounting
∗∗ O’Donoghue and Rabin (1999): Doing it Now or Later
- Laibson (1997): Golden Eggs and Hyperbolic Discounting
- O’Donoghue and Rabin (2001): Choice and Procrastination
Empirical Applications
∗∗ Ariely and Wertenbroch (2002): Procrastination, Deadlines, and Performance
- Ashraf, Karlan and Yin (2006): Tying Odysseus to the Mast: Evidence from a Commitment Savings
Product in the Philippines
- Bryan et al. (2010): Commitment Devices
- DellaVigna and Malmendier (2006): Paying Not To Go To the Gym
- Gruber and Koszegi (2001): Is Addiction ‘Rational’? Theory and Evidence
- Hershfield (2011): Future Self-continuity: How Conceptions of the Future Self Transform Intertemporal
Choice
- Kaur, Kremer and Mullainathan (2015): Self-Control at Work
- Milkman et al. (2014): Holding the Hunger Games Hostage at the Gym
- Schilbach (2017): Alcohol and Self-Control: A Field Experiment in India
Risk Preferences (DT, Sep 22, 24) and Reference Dependence (DT, Sep 29, Oct 1)
5
∗∗ Bandiera et al. (2005): Social Preferences and the Response to Incentives: Evidence from Personnel
Data
∗∗ Rao (2019): Familiarity Does Not Breed Contempt: Diversity, Discrimination and Generosity in Delhi
Schools
- Gneezy and List (2006): Putting Behavioral Economics to Work: Testing for Gift Exchange in Labor
Markets Using Field Experiments
- Henrich (2012): Hunter-Gatherer Cooperation
- Lazear et al. (2006): Sorting, Prices, and Social Preferences
- Andreoni and Bernheim (2007): Social Image and the 50-50 Norm: A Theoretical and Experimental
Analysis of Audience Effects
- Dana et al. (2007): Exploiting Moral Wiggle Room: Experiments Demonstrating an Illusory Preference
for Fairness
- Ellingsen and Johannesson (2007): Paying Respect
∗∗ Oster et al. (2013): Optimal Expectations and Limited Medical Testing: Evidence from Huntington’s
Disease
- Chen et al. (2016): Decision-making under the Gambler’s Fallacy: Evidence from Asylum Judges, Loan
Officers, and Baseball Umpires
- Gilovich et al. (1985): The Hot Hand in Basketball: On the Misperception of Random Sequences
- Gold and Hester (1987): The gambler’s fallacy and the coin’s memory
- Loewenstein (1987): Anticipation and the Valuation of Delayed Consumption
- Malmendier and Tate (2008): Who makes acquisitions? CEO overconfidence and the marketâs reaction
- Tversky and Kahneman (1974): Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases
Anchoring
- Jacowitz and Kahneman (1995): Measures of Anchoring in Estimation Tasks
- Ariely et al. (2003): ‘Coherent Arbitrariness’: Stable Demand Curves Without Stable Preferences
- Bruner and Potter (1964): Interference in Visual Recognition
- Lord and Lepper (1979): Biased Assimilation and Attitude Polarization: The Effects of Prior Theories
on Subsequently Considered Evidence
- Tversky and Kahneman (1974): Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases
Bracketing
6
- Tversky and Kahneman (1986): The Behavioral Foundations of Economic Theory
Ironing and Spotlighting
- Ito (2014): Do Consumers Respond to Marginal or Average Price? Evidence from Nonlinear Electricity
Pricing
- Liebman and Zeckhauser (2004): Schmeduling
- Rees-Jones and Taubinsky (2018): Taxing Humans: Pitfalls of the Mechanism Design Approach and
Potential Resolutions
Mental Accounting and Applications
- Thaler (1990): Saving, Fungibility, and Mental Accounts
- Milkman and Beshears (2009): Mental accounting and small windfalls: Evidence from an online grocer
- Hastings and Shapiro (2013): Fungibility and Consumer Choice: Evidence from Commodity Price
Shocks
- Thaler (1981): An Economic Theory of Self-Control
- Kooreman (2000): The Labeling Effect of a Child Benefit System
- Almond et al. (2011): Inside the War on Poverty: The Impact of Food Stamps on Birth Outcomes
- Shapiro and Slemrod (2001): Consumer Response to Tax Rebates
- Feldman (2010): Mental Accounting Effects of Income Tax Shifting
- Fogel et al. (2004): Loss Aversion for Quality in Consumer Choice
Market Forces
- Friedman (1953): Essays in Positive Economics
- Grossman and Miller (1988): Grossman, Sanford and Miller, Merton
- De Long et al. (1990): Noise Trader Risk in Financial Markets
- Shleifer and Vishny (1997): The Limits of Arbitrage
- Lamont and Thaler (2003): Can the Market Add and Subtract? Mispricing in Tech Stock Carve-outs
Shrouded Attributes
- Gabaix and Laibson (2006): Shrouded Attributes, Consumer Myopia, and Information Suppression in
Competitive Markets
- Woodward and Hall (2010): Consumer Confusion in the Mortgage Market: Evidence of Less Than a
Perfectly Transparent and Competitive Market
- Ausubel (1991): The Failure of Competition in the Credit Card Market
- Agarwal et al. (2008): Learning in the Credit Card Market
- Alexander et al. (1998): Mutual fund shareholders: characteristics, investor knowledge, and sources of
information
- Barber et al. (2005): Out of Sight, Out of Mind: The Effects of Expenses on Mutual Fund Flows
- Hall (2003): The Inkjet Aftermarket: An Economic Analysis
- Hossain and Morgan (2006): Shrouded attributes and information suppression: Evidence from field
experiments
- Brown et al. (2010): Shrouded Attributes and Information Suppression: Evidence from the Field
7
- Chetty (2015): Behavioral Economics and Public Policy: A Pragmatic Perspective
- Beshears et al. (2005): The importance of default options for retirement saving outcomes: evidence
from the United States
- Madrian and Shea (2001): The Power of Suggestion: Inertia in 401(k) Participation and Savings
Behavior
- Carroll et al. (2009): Optimal Defaults and Active Decisions
- Chetty et al. (2014): Active vs. Passive Decisions and Crowd-Out in Retirement Savings Accounts:
Evidence from Denmark
- Thaler and Benartzi (2004): Save More TomorrowT M : Using Behavioral Economics to Increase Em-
ployee Saving
- Cronqvist and Thaler (2004): Design Choices in Privatized Social-Security Systems: Learning from
the Swedish Experience
- Bhargava et al. (2017): Choose to Lose: Health Plan Choices from a Menu with Dominated Option
- Handel (2013): Adverse Selection and Inertia in Health Insurance Markets: When Nudging Hurts
- Johnson and Goldstein (2003): Do Defaults Save Lives?
- Bettinger et al. (2009): The Role of Simplification and Information in College Decisions: Results from
the HR Block FAFSA Experiment
Optimal Public Policy with Behavioral Agents (DT, Nov 17, 19)
- Allcott and Taubinsky (2015): Evaluating Behaviorally Motivated Policy: Experimental Evidence from
the Lightbulb Market
- Allcott et al. (2019): Regressive Sin Taxes, with an Application to the Optimal Soda Tax
∗∗ Stevenson and Wolfers (2008): Economic Growth and Subjective Well-Being: Reassessing the Easterlin
Paradox
- Levitt (2016): Heads or Tails: The Impact of a Coin Toss on Major Life Decisions and Subsequent
Happiness
- Kahneman and Thaler (2006): Anomalies: Utility Maximization and Experienced Utility
- Kahneman (1994): New Challenges to the Rationality Assumption
- Koszegi and Rabin (2008): Choices, Situations and Happiness
- Schkade and Kahneman (1998): Does Living in California Make People Happy? A Focusing Illusion
in Judgments of Life Satisfaction
8
∗∗ Sarsons (2019): Interpreting Signals in the Labor Market: Evidence from Medical Referrals
- Bertrand et al. (2015): Gender Identity and Relative Income within Households
- Goldin (2014): A Grand Gender Convergence: Its Last Chapter
- Vesterlund et al. (2015): Breaking the Glass Ceiling with “No"
- Fredrickson et al. (1998): That Swimsuit Becomes You: Sex Differences in Self-Objectification, Re-
strained Eating, and Math Performance
- Niederle and Vesterlund (2011): Gender and Competition
9
References
Agarwal, Sumit, John Driscoll, Xavier Gabaix, and David Laibson, “Learning in the Credit Card
Market,” NBER Working Papers 13822, 2008.
Akerlof, George A., “Procrastination and Obedience,” American Economic Review, Papers and Proceed-
ings, 1991, 81 (2), 1–19.
Alexander, Gordon, Jonathan D. Jones, and Peter Nigro, “Mutual fund shareholders: characteristics,
investor knowledge, and sources of information,” Financial Services Review, 1998, 7 (4), 301–316.
Allcott, Hunt and Dmitry Taubinsky, “Evaluating Behaviorally Motivated Policy: Experimental Evi-
dence from the Lightbulb Market,” American Economic Review, 2015, 105 (8), 2501–2538.
, Benjamin B Lockwood, and Dmitry Taubinsky, “Regressive Sin Taxes, with an Application to the
Optimal Soda Tax,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2019, 134 (3), 1557–1626.
Allen, Eric, Patricia Dechow, Devin Pope, and George Wu, “Reference-Dependent Preferences:
Evidence from Marathon Runners,” Management Science, 2017, 63 (6), 1657–1672.
Almond, Douglas, Hilary Hoynes, and Diane Whitmore Schanzenbach, “Inside the War on Poverty:
The Impact of Food Stamps on Birth Outcomes,” The Review of Economics and Statistics, 2011, 93 (2),
387–403.
Andreoni, James and Douglas Bernheim, “Social Image and the 50-50 Norm: A Theoretical and
Experimental Analysis of Audience Effects,” Econometrica, 2007, 77 (5).
Ariely, Dan, Predictably Irrational: The Hidden Forces that Shape our Decisions, New York: Harper, 2009.
, George Loewenstein, and Drazen Prelec, “‘Coherent Arbitrariness’: Stable Demand Curves With-
out Stable Preferences,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2003, 118 (1), 73–106.
Ashraf, Nava, Dean Karlan, and Wesley Yin, “Tying Odysseus to the Mast: Evidence from a Com-
mitment Savings Product in the Philippines,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2006, 121 (2), 635–672.
Ausubel, Lawrence M, “The Failure of Competition in the Credit Card Market,” American Economic
Review, 1991, 81 (1), 50–81.
Bandiera, Oriana, Iwan Barankay, and Imran Rasul, “Social Preferences and the Response to Incen-
tives: Evidence from Personnel Data,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2005, 120 (3), 917–962.
Banerjee, Abhijit, Nathanael Goldberg, Dean Karlan, Pariente William Osei Robert, Jeremy
Shapiro, Bram Thuysbaert, and Christopher Udry, “A Multi-faceted Program Causes Lasting
Progress for the Very Poor: Evidence from Six Countries,” Science, 2015, 348 (6236), 772–788.
Barber, Brad, Terrance Odean, and Lu Zheng, “Out of Sight, Out of Mind: The Effects of Expenses
on Mutual Fund Flows,” The Journal of Business, 2005, 78 (6), 2095–2120.
Bertrand, Marianne, Emir Kamenica, and Jessica Pan, “Gender Identity and Relative Income within
Households,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2015, 130 (2), 571–614.
Beshears, John, James Choi, David Laibson, and Brigitte Madrian, “The importance of default
options for retirement saving outcomes: evidence from the United States,” 2005, (43).
Bettinger, Eric, Bridget Long, Philip Oreopoulos, and Lisa Sanbonmatsu, “The Role of Simpli-
fication and Information in College Decisions: Results from the HR Block FAFSA Experiment,” NBER
Working Papers 15361, 2009.
10
Bhargava, Saurabh, George Loewenstein, and Justin Sydnor, “Choose to Lose: Health Plan Choices
from a Menu with Dominated Option,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2017, 132 (3), 1319–1372.
Brown, Jennifer, Tanjim Hossain, and John Morgan, “Shrouded Attributes and Information Sup-
pression: Evidence from the Field,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2010, 125 (2), 859–876.
Bruner, J. S. and M. C. Potter, “Interference in visual recognition,” Science, 1964, 144, 424–425.
Bryan, Gharad, Dean Karlan, and Scott Nelson, “Commitment Devices,” Annual Review of Eco-
nomics, 2010, 2, 671–698.
Camerer, Colin, “Prospect Theory in the Wild: Evidence from the Field,” in Daniel Kahneman and Amos
Tversky, eds., Choices, Values, and Frames, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2001, chapter 16.
and Ernst Fehr, “Measuring social norms and preferences using experimental games: A guide for social
scientists,” in Bowles Camerer Fehr Gintis Henrich, Boyd and McElreath, eds., Foundations of Human
Sociality, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2004.
, Linda Babcock, George Loewenstein, and Richard Thaler, “Labor Supply of New York City
Cabdrivers: One Day at a Time,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1997, 112 (2), 407–441.
Carmon, Ziv and Dan Ariely, “Focusing on the Forgone: How Value Can Appear So Different to Buyers
and Sellers,” Journal of Consumer Research, 2000, 27 (3), 360–370.
Carroll, Gabriel D., James J. Choi, David Laibson, Brigitte C. Madrian, and Andrew Metrick,
“Optimal Defaults and Active Decisions,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2009, 124 (4), 1639–1674.
Carter, Susan, Kyle Greenberg, and Michael Walker, “The Impact of Computer Usage on Academic
Performance: Evidence from a Randomized Trial at the United States Military Academy,” Economics of
Education Review, 2017, 56, 118–132.
Chen, Daniel, Tobias J. Moskowitz, and Kelly Shue, “Decisionmaking under the Gambler’s Fallacy:
Evidence from Asylum Judges, Loan Officers, and Baseball Umpires,” Quarterly Journal of Economics,
2016, 131 (3), 1181–1242.
Chetty, Raj, “Behavioral Economics and Public Policy: A Pragmatic Perspective,” American Economic
Review, 2015, 105 (5), 1–33.
, Adam Looney, and Kory Kroft, “Salience and Taxation: Theory and Evidence,” American Economic
Review, 2009, 99 (4), 1145–1177.
, John N. Friedman, Soren Leth-Petersen, Torben Heien Nielsen, and Tore Olsen, “Active vs.
Passive Decisions and Crowd-Out in Retirement Savings Accounts: Evidence from Denmark,” Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 2014, 129 (3), 1141–1219.
Cialdini, Robert B., Influence, the Psychology of Persuasion, New York: William Morrow Publishing
Company, 1993.
Cronqvist, Henrik and Richard H. Thaler, “Design Choices in Privatized Social-Security Systems:
Learning from the Swedish Experience,” American Economic Review, 2004, 94 (2), 424–428.
Dana, Jason, Roberto A. Weber, and Jason Xi Kuang, “Exploiting Moral Wiggle Room: Experiments
Demonstrating an Illusory Preference for Fairness,” Economic Theory, 2007, 33 (1).
Darley, John and C. Daniel Batson, ““From Jerusalem to Jericho”: A Study of Situational and Dis-
positional Variables in Helping Behavior,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 1973, 27 (1),
100–108.
DellaVigna, Stefano, “Psychology and Economics: Evidence from the Field,” Journal of Economic Liter-
ature, 2009, 47 (2), 315–372.
11
and Ulrike Malmendier, “Paying Not To Go To the Gym,” American Economic Review, 2006, 96 (3),
694–719.
Ellingsen, Tore and Magnus Johannesson, “Paying Respect,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2007,
21 (4).
Feldman, Naomi, “Mental Accounting Effects of Income Tax Shifting,” The Review of Economics and
Statistics, 2010, 92 (1), 70–86.
Fogel, Suzanne, Dan Lovallo, and Carmina Caringal, “Loss Aversion for Quality in Consumer Choice,”
Australian Journal of Management, 2004, 29 (1), 45–63.
Frederick, Shane, George Loewenstein, and Ted O’Donoghue, “Time Discounting and Time Prefer-
ence: A Critical Review,” Journal of Economic Literature, 2002, XL (2), 351–401.
Fredrickson, Barbara L., Tomi-Ann Roberts, Stephanie M. Noll, Diane M. Quinn, and Jean M.
Twenge, “That Swimsuit Becomes You: Sex Differences in Self-Objectification, Restrained Eating, and
Math Performance,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 1998, 75 (5), 1098–1098.
G., L. Ross Lord Charles and M. R. Lepper, “Biased Assimilation and Attitude Polarization: The
Effects of Prior Theories on Subsequently Considered Evidence,” Journal of Personality and Social Psy-
chology, 1979, 37 (11), 2098–2109.
Gabaix, Xavier and David Laibson, “Shrouded Attributes, Consumer Myopia, and Information Sup-
pression in Competitive Markets,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2006, 121 (2), 505–540.
and , “The Seven Properties of Good Models,” The Foundations of Positive and Normative Economics:
A Handbook, 2008.
Genesove, David and Christopher Mayer, “Loss Aversion and Seller Behavior: Evidence from the
Housing Market,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2001, 116 (4), 1233–1260.
Gilovich, Thomas, Robert Vallone, and Amos Tversky, “The Hot Hand in Basketball: On the
Misperception of Random Sequences,” Cognitive Psychology, 1985, 17.
Gneezy, Uri and John List, “Putting Behavioral Economics to Work: Testing for Gift Exchange in Labor
Markets Using Field Experiments,” Econometrica, 2006, 74 (5), 1365–1384.
Gold, E and G Hester, “The gambler’s fallacy and the coin’s memory,” Unpublished manuscript. Carnegie
Mellon University., 1987.
Goldin, Claudia, “A Grand Gender Convergence: Its Last Chapter,” American Economic Review, 2014,
104 (4), 1091–1119.
Grossman, Sanford and Merton Miller, “Liquidity and Market Structure,” NBER Working Papers 2641,
1988.
Gruber, Jonathan and Botond Koszegi, “Is Addiction ‘Rational’? Theory and Evidence,” Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 2001, 116 (4), 1261–1303.
Hall, Robert, “The Inkjet Aftermarket: An Economic Analysis,” Stanford University Working Paper, 2003.
Handel, Benjamin, “Adverse Selection and Inertia in Health Insurance Markets: When Nudging Hurts,”
American Economic Review, 2013, 103 (7), 2643–2682.
Hanna, Rema, Sendhil Mullainathan, and J. Schwartzstein, “Learning Through Noticing: Theory
and Evidence from a Field Experiment,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2014, 129 (3), 1311–1353.
Hastings, Justine and Jesse Shapiro, “Fungibility and Consumer Choice: Evidence from Commodity
Price Shocks,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2013, 128 (4), 1449–1498.
12
Haushofer, Johannes and Ernst Fehr, “On the Psychology of Poverty,” Science, 2014, 344 (6186),
862–867.
Hershfield, Hal E., “Future Self-Continuity: How Conceptions of the Future Self Transform Intertemporal
Choice,” Annals of the New York Academy of Sciences, 2011, 1235, 30–43.
Hossain, Tanjim and John Morgan, “Shrouded attributes and information suppression: Evidence from
field experiments,” University of California, Berkeley mimeo, 2006.
Huberman, Gur and Tomer Regev, “Contagious Speculation and a Cure for Cancer: A Nonevent That
Made Stock Prices Soar,” The Journal of Finance, 2001, 56 (1).
Ito, Koichiro, “Do Consumers Respond to Marginal or Average Price? Evidence from Nonlinear Electricity
Pricing,” American Economic Review, 2014, 104 (2), 537–563.
Johnson, Eric J. and Daniel Goldstein, “Do Defaults Save Lives?,” Science, 2003, 302 (5649), 1338–1339.
Kahneman, Daniel, “New Challenges to the Rationality Assumption,” Journal of Institutional and Theo-
retical Economics, 1994, 150, 18–36.
, Thinking, Fast and Slow, New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux, 2011.
and Amos (eds.) Tversky, Choices, Values and Frames, New York: Russell Sage Foundation: Cam-
bridge University Press, 2000.
and Richard H. Thaler, “Anomalies: Utility Maximization and Experienced Utility,” Journal of
Economic Perspectives, 2006, 20 (1), 221–234.
, Paul Slovic, and Amos Tversky, Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases, New York:
Cambridge University Press, 1982.
Kaur, Supreet, Michael Kremer, and Sendhil Mullainathan, “Self-Control at Work,” Journal of
Political Economy, 2015, 123 (6), 1227–1277.
Kooreman, Peter, “The Labeling Effect of a Child Benefit System,” American Economic Review, 2000, 90
(3), 571–583.
Koszegi, Botond and Matthew Rabin, “Choices, Situations and Happiness,” Journal of Public Eco-
nomics, 2008, 92 (8-9), 1821–1832.
Laibson, David, “Golden Eggs and Hyperbolic Discounting,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1997, 112
(2), 443–478.
Lamont, Owen and Richard Thaler, “Can the Market Add and Subtract? Mispricing in Tech Stock
Carve-outs,” Journal of Political Economy, 2003, 111 (2), 227–268.
Lazear, Edward, Ulrike Malmendier, and Roberto Weber, “Sorting, Prices, and Social Preferences,”
NBER Working Paper 12041, 2006.
Levitt, Steven D., “Heads or Tails: The Impact of a Coin Toss on Major Life Decisions and Subsequent
Happiness,” NBER Working Paper, 2016.
Lewis, Michael, The Undoing Project: A Friendship That Changed Our Minds, New York: W. W. Norton
& Company, 2017.
13
Loewenstein, George, “Anticipation and the Valuation of Delayed Consumption,” The Economic Journal,
1987, 97 (387).
Long, J Bradford De, Andrei Shleifer, Lawrence Summers, and Robert Waldmann, “Noise Trader
Risk in Financial Markets,” Journal of Political Economy, 1990, 98 (4), 703–738.
Madrian, Brigitte C. and Dennis F. Shea, “Power of Suggestion: Inertia in 401(k) Participation and
Savings Behavior,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2001, 116 (4), 1149–1187.
Malmendier, Ulrike and Geoffrey Tate, “Who makes acquisitions? CEO overconfidence and the mar-
ketâs reaction,” Journal of Financial Economics, 2008, 89.
Mani, Anandi, Sendhil Mullainathan, Eldar Shafir, and Jiaying Zhao, “Poverty Impedes Cognitive
Function,” Science, 2013, 341 (6149), 976–980.
Milkman, Katherine and John Beshears, “Mental accounting and small windfalls: Evidence from an
online grocer,” Journal of Economic Behavior Organization, 2009, 71 (2), 384–394.
, Julia A. Minson, and Kevin G.M. Volpp, “Holding the Hunger Games Hostage at the Gym: An
Evaluation of Temptation Bundling,” Management Science, 2014, 60 (2), 283–299.
Mullainathan, Sendhil and Eldar Shafir, Scarcity: Why Having Too Little Means So Much, Time Books,
Henry Holt and Co. LLC, 2013.
and Richard H. Thaler, “Behavioral Economics,” National Bureau of Economic Research, 2000,
(w7948).
Niederle, Muriel and Lise Vesterlund, “Gender and Competition,” Annual Review of Economics, 2011,
3, 601–630.
O’Donoghue, Ted and Matthew Rabin, “Doing It Now or Later,” American Economic Review, 1999,
89 (1), 103–124.
and , “Choice and Procrastination,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2001, 116 (1), 121–160.
Oster, Emily, Ira Shoulson, and E. Ray Dorsey, “Optimal Expectations and Limited Medical Testing:
Evidence from Huntington Disease,” American Economic Review, 2013, 103 (2), 804–830.
Pope, Devin and Maurice Schweitzer, “Is Tiger Woods Loss Averse? Persistent Bias in the Face of
Experience, Competition, and High Stakes,” American Economic Review, 2011, 101 (1), 129–157.
Rabin, Matthew, “Psychology and Economics,” Journal of Economic Literature, 1998, 36 (1), 11–46.
, “Risk Aversion and Expected-utility Theory: A Calibration Theorem,” Econometrica, 2000, 68 (5),
1281–1292.
, “A Perspective on Psychology and Economics,” European Economic Review, 2002, 46 (4-5), 657–685.
, “Incorporating Limited Rationality into Economics,” Journal of Economic Literature, 2013, 51 (2), 528–
543.
and Richard Thaler, “Anomalies – Risk Aversion,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2001, 15 (1),
219–232.
Rao, Gautam, “Familiarity Does Not Breed Contempt: Diversity, Discrimination and Generosity in Delhi
Schools,” American Economic Review, 2019.
Rees-Jones, Alex and Dmitry Taubinsky, “Taxing Humans: Pitfalls of the Mechanism Design Approach
and Potential Resolutions,” Tax Policy and the Economy, 2018, 32 (1), 107–133.
Ross, Lee and Richard E. Nisbett, The Person and the Situation: Perspectives of Social Psychology,
Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 1991.
14
Sarsons, Heather, “Interpreting Signals in the Labor Market: Evidence from Medical Referrals,” Working
Paper, 2019.
Schilbach, Frank, “Alcohol and Self-Control : A Field Experiment in India,” mimeo, 2017.
, Sendhil Mullainathan, and Heather Schofield, “The Psychological Lives of the Poor,” American
Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 2016, 106 (5), 435–440.
Schkade, David and Daniel Kahneman, “Does Living in California Make People Happy? A Focusing
Illusion in Judgments of Life Satisfaction,” Psychological Science, 1998, 9 (5), 340–346.
Shah, Anuj, Sendhil Mullainathan, and Eldar Shafir, “Scarcity Frames Value,” Psychological Science,
2015, 26 (4), 402–412.
Shapiro, Matthew and Joel Slemrod, “Consumer Response to Tax Rebates,” NBER Working Paper
8672, 2001.
Shleifer, Andrei and Robert Vishny, “The Limits of Arbitrage,” Journal of Finance, 1997, 52 (1), 35–55.
Stevenson, Betsey and Justin Wolfers, “Economic Growth and Subjective Well-Being: Reassessing the
Easterlin Paradox,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2008, Spring, 1–102.
Sydnor, Justin, “(Over)insuring Modest Risks,” American Economic Journal: Applied Economics, 2010, 2
(4), 177–199.
Thaler, Richard, “Some Empirical Evidence on Dynamic Inconsistency,” Economics Letters, 1981, 8, 201–
207.
Thaler, Richard H., “Saving, Fungibility, and Mental Accounts,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 1990,
4 (1), 193–205.
, Misbehaving: The Making of Behavioral Economics, New York: W. W. Norton & Company, 2015.
, “Behavioral Economics: Past, Present, and Future,” American Economic Review, 2016, 106 (7), 1577–
1600.
and Cass R. Sunstein, Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health, Wealth and Happiness, New Haven:
Yale University Press, 2008.
and Shlomo Benartzi, “Save More TomorrowT M : Using Behavioral Economics to Increase Employee
Saving,” Journal of Political Economy, 2004, 112 (S1), S164–S187.
Tversky, Amos and Daniel Kahneman, “Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases,” Science,
1974, 185 (4157).
and , “Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk,” Econometrica, 1979, 47 (2), 263–292.
and , “The Behavioral Foundations of Economic Theory,” The Journal of Business, 1986, 59 (4),
S251–S278.
Vesterlund, Lise, Linda Babcock, and Laurie Weingart, “Breaking the Glass Ceiling with “No":
Gender Differences in Declining Requests for Non-Promotable Tasks,” mimeo, 2015.
Woodward, Susan E. and Robert Hall, “Consumer Confusion in the Mortgage Market: Evidence of
Less Than a Perfectly Transparent and Competitive Market,” American Economic Review, 2010, 100 (2),
511–515.
15
Other MIT Resources
The Department of Economics values an inclusive environment. If you need a disability accommodation
to access this course, please communicate with us early in the semester. If you have your accommodation
letter, please meet with the faculty so that we can understand your needs and implement your approved
accommodations. If you have not yet been approved for accommodations, please contact Student Disability
Services at [email protected] to learn about their procedures. We encourage you to do so early in the term
to allow sufficient time for implementation of services/accommodations that you may need.
The WCC at MIT (Writing and Communication Center) offers free one-on-one professional advice from
communication experts. The WCC is staffed completely by MIT lecturers. All have advanced degrees. All
are experienced college classroom teachers of communication. All are published scholars and writers. Not
counting the WCC’s director’s years (he started the WCC in 1982), the WCC lecturers have a combined 133
years’ worth of teaching here at MIT (ranging from 4 to 24 years). The WCC works with undergraduate,
graduate students, post-docs, faculty, staff, alums, and spouses.
The WCC helps you strategize about all types of academic and professional writing as well as about
all aspects of oral presentations (including practicing classroom presentations & conference talks as well as
designing slides). No matter what department or discipline you are in, the WCC helps you think your way
more deeply into your topic, and helps you see new implications in your data, research, and ideas.
The WCC also helps with all English as Second Language issues, from writing and grammar to pronun-
ciation and conversation practice. The WCC is located in E18-233, 50 Ames Street. To guarantee yourself
a time, make an appointment. To register with our online scheduler and to make appointments, go to
https://mit.mywconline.com/.
To access the WCC’s many pages of advice about writing and oral presentations, go to http://cmsw.mit.
edu/writing-and-communication-center/. Check the online scheduler for up-to-date hours and available
appointments.
16