Burghardt 1990
Burghardt 1990
are cheap
The use of volatility cones to determine whether options lire
cheap or dear.
he single greatest challenge in trading op- volatility of any traded commodity bounces around
72 tions is determining whether options are cheap or from period to period. Further, the market continu-
expensive. ously revises its estimates of how voIatile rnarkets are
-8
m
P
A trader who buys or sells an option takes a
position on the volatility of whatever underlies the
likely to be.
Both of these volatility traits are illustrated in
option. The price of the option is directly related to Figures 1 and 2. Figure 1, for example, shows a run-
the market’s perception of the underlying’s volatility. ning history of two measures of IZurodollar futures
If the market expects high volatility, option prices will volatility for the year from June 1987 to June 1988.
be high. If the market expects low volatility, option The first is the thirty-day historical volatility of the
prices will be low. June 1988 futures contract (dashed line). The second
The buyer of an option can profit if either of is the level of volatility implied by at-the-money op-
two things happens: tions on the June 1988 futures contract (solid line).
1. The realized volatility of the underlying turns out Figure 2 provides a similar comparison for September
to be greater than the volatility implied by the price
paid for the option,’ or FIGURE 1
2. The market revises upward its perception of how EURODOLLAR JUNE 1988 IMPLIED VEJRSUS HISTORICAL
volatile it believes the underlying is likely to be. (30 TRADING DAYS) VOLATILITIES
By the same token, an option seller can profit (Period: June 1, 1987 to June 13, 1988)
from realized volatility that is lower than implied vol-
atility or from a decrease in the market’s perception
of volatility.
We propose to show how one can use infor- 10 -
ou
tivity i s that the world of options does not conform i ,:.....
to the world described by Fischer Black and Myron
Scholes in their seminal work on option pricing. In
JUN87 JUL87 AUG87 SEP87 OC187 NOV87 DEC87 JAN88 ,.::
FEE88 MAR88 APR88 M, A. Y,8.8, JUNE8 JI
that world, volatility is both known and constant. DATE
I8
Instead, what we find is that the observed or historical SERIES -Implied Voi -......--..30-1) H i l l Yo1
GALEN BURGHARDT is First Vice President of Research at Discount Corporation of New York Futures in Chicago (IL
60606). MORTON LANE is President of the same firm. The authors would like to acknowledge th’e empirical work by
Terry Belton and Geoffrey Luce that went into testing the usefulness of volatility cones.
FIGURE 2 rations are spaced three months apart. In currency
JAPANESE YEN SEPTEMBER 1988 options, both cash and futures, options are spaced
IMPLIED VERSUS HISTORICAL one month apart, at least for the first three months.
(30 TRADING DAYS) VOLATILITIES Thus, one can find implied volatilities that provide
(Period: Jan. 1, 1988 to Aug. 16, 1988)
VOL
..,
am-
. .
volatility forecasts over substantially different hori-
20- i, '..._...
... , zons.
$9-
18- <...
;
.,;
Further, these horizons grow smaller by one
17- ~
day with each day that passes. For example, bond
16. : futures options that trade today might have expira-
15- ~
11-
e -
options will cover a horizon that is one day smaller.
7-
1986
January 18.067 15.921
February 13.416 15.998
March 13.957 15.286
April 24.683 18.114 16.7.41
18.872 18.796 17.6.57
It is illegal to make unauthorized copies of this article, forward to an unauthorized user or to post electronically without Publisher permission.
The Journal of Portfolio Management 1990.16.2:72-78. Downloaded from www.iijournals.com by COLUMBIA UNIVERSITY on 06/30/12.
May
June 22.809 22.469 19.0153
July 17.923 19.965 19.0.34
August 17.132 19.015 19.2834
September 23.444 19.660 20.810
0 30 60 90 120 150 180 210 240 270 300 330 360
Days t o Option Expiration
October 14.146 20.050 19.6.56 18.343
November 32.047 18.203 18.671 18.363
VDlaLllltleS - IrnPhd 3oO-D"i.tori..l trrkt cone I December 11.351 12.767 16.984 17.669
Time Period f o r Hatortcnl Cones N o v - 8 5 through OcL-87
Source DCNIF Research G r o u ~
1987
74 January 12.402 12.335 16.3.55 17.707
z
6
I
MATURITY STRUCTURE OF SEPTEMBER 1988
JAPANESE YEN VOLATILITY:
IMPLIED VOLATILITY VERSUS 30-DAY
FIGURE 4 February
March
April
May
16.320
14.417
20.313
19.113
13.677
14.392
17.390
18.035
16.112
14.349
14.733
15.9112
17.694
17.727
17.391
37.296
B
0 June 19.957 20.899 17.7'37 17.417
HISTORICAL VOLATILITY 13.456 19.176 18.1.51 17.266
July
VOL VOI
25 August 11.476 15.408 17.5:37 16.679
September 19.014 15.281 18.269 16.107
October 57.415 35.415 28.098 22.528 20.536
1988
7 4 IOLI
atilities over the actual days left in each option’s life information about whether the options are cheap or
and took the difference between the resulting vola- dear.
tility and the option’s implied volatility.
How Robust Are the Cones?
The results are shown in Table 3. For days
when implied volatility was in the upper range of the How much data does one need to construct a
volatility cone, we found that implied volatility fore- reliable volatility cone? The answer depends on the
casts of realized volatility were systematically too market you wish to examine, but two years or more
high. The largest difference between realized and im- of data would seem to be adequate, at least if there
plied volatilities was -4.39%. Had you sold those has been no fundamental change in the forces driving
the market.
TABLE 3 Figure 8 shows the history of three-month his-
Difference Between Realized and Implied torical volatilities for Japanese yen futures. How well
Volatility for Japanese Yen Options
would a cone constructed on January 1, 1987, using
With More Than 3 Months Left To Expiration
(April 1986 through July 1988) data for 1985 and 1986, have held up in 1987? The
Implied Volatility Implied Volatility highest three-month historical volatility over 1985and
Summary at High End of at Low End of 1986 was 15.7%; the lowest historical volatility was
Statistic Volatility Cone‘ Volatility Cone**
5.2%. Thus, the upper and lower bounds of the vol-
Maximum -4.39 +4.83 atility cone at three months to expiration would have
Minimum +0.82 -0.20 been 15.7%and 5.2%, respectively.
Mean -2.93 + 1.71 How well did the cone hold up in 1987? Very
Standard Deviation
of Mean 0.19 0.32 well. There were no new highs and no new lows, and
T-Value - 15.40 5.34
Number of Observations 46 20
FIGURE 8
*Implied Volatility in Top Decile
**Implied Volatility in Bottom Decile LEAD JAPANESE YEN FUTURES 3-MONTH
HISTORICAL VOLATILITY
(Period: January 1, 1985 to April 18, 1989)
options and delta-balanced the position to expiration,
you would have made a profit consistent with selling
volatility 4.39 percentage points higher than it proved
to be. The worst case was an error on the high side
of 0.82 percentage points. On average, you would
have sold volatility 2.93 percentage points higher than
realized volatilities. And, as shown in the bottom
panel of the table, the average gain was not only large,
but it was also different from zero at any reasonable
level of statistical significance.
For days when implied volatility was in the
lower range of the volatility cone, the results are just
the opposite. Implied volatility forecasts proved to be
biased downward, with a maximum error of 4.83 per- QUARTER
tions are unusually cheap or dear, there is merit in volatilities, and that there is valuable inforrnation con-
taking a hard look at the world to see whether any- tained in the distribution of historical vo1a‘:ilities. An-
thing fundamental has changed to affect the long-run other way of putting this is that longer-term volatility
outlook for volatility. forecasts, as embedded in the prices of longer-dated
For example, when the Federal Reserve put a options, appear to be overly sensitive to short-term
reserves targeting policy into place in the fall of 1979, volatility developments. Consequently, volatility
there was a dramatic upward shift in the distribution cones provide a useful and potentially profitable
78 of interest rate volatility. And, when the Fed aban- guide as to whether options are cheap or dear.
3
z doned that policy at the end of 1982, the distribution
3
n shifted downward again.
Thus, whenever the volatility cone standard
Realized volatility and historical volatility are both standard
suggests either a sale or purchase of volatility, it is deviations of percentage changes in the price of the un-
certainly worth one’s while to review changes in eco- derlying security or futures price. Percentage changes most
nomic policy (or in the market for stock options, the often are calculated using daily closing prices, although
capital structure of the firm) that would have a bearing there are several variants and refinements ‘:hat can be
brought to bear on volatility estimation.
on the volatility generating machine that drives the
options market. We first introduced the concept of volatiiity cones in a May
CONCLUSIONS 4,1988, memorandum, ”Is Currency Volatility Low Enough
to Buy?‘ and in an August 29, 1988, follow-up, ”Results of
We have shown two things here. First, the ap- Recommended May 4th Purchase of Currency Volatility.’’
propriate standard of comparison for gauging Since then, we have encountered an October 1988 piece by
Steven Pomerantz, “An Information-Based Model of Vol-
whether implied volatilities are high or low is an his- atility” (MorganStanley), which deals with what the author
tarical volatility that corresponds to the time left in calls a volatilitv time curve.