Acrefore 9780190846626 e 370
Acrefore 9780190846626 e 370
Achim Wennmann
Subject: Conflict Studies, Political Economy, Security Studies
Online Publication Date: Feb 2019 DOI: 10.1093/acrefore/9780190846626.013.370
The political economy of violent conflict is a body of literature that investigates how
economic issues and interests shape the dynamics associated to violent conflict after the
Cold War. The literature covers an area of research focusing on civil wars—the
predominant type of conflict in the 1990s and early 2000s—and an area of research
focusing on other types of violent conflict within states, such as permanent emergencies,
criminal violence, and political violence associated to turbulent transitions. The first area
involves four themes that have come to characterize discussions on the political economy
of civil wars, including research on the role of greed and grievance in conflict onset, on
economic interests in civil wars, on the nature of conflict economies, and on conflict
financing. The second area responds to the evolution of violent conflict beyond the
categories of “interstate” or “civil” war and shows how political economy research
adapted to new types of violent conflict within states as it moved beyond the “post-Cold
War” era. Overall, the literature on the political economy of violence conflict emphasizes
the role of informal systems behind power, profits and violence, and the economic
interests and functions of violence underlying to violent conflict. It has also become a
conceptual laboratory for scholars who after years of field research tried to make sense of
the realities of authoritarian, violent or war-affected countries. By extending the
boundaries of the literature beyond the study of civil wars after the Cold War, political
economy research can serve as an important analytical lens to better understand the
constantly evolving nature of violent conflict and to inform sober judgment on the
possible policy responses to them.
Keywords: political economy, civil wars, war economy, conflict financing, natural resources, permanent
emergencies, military-industrial complex, criminal violence, political transitions
Page 1 of 29
Introduction
This article reviews contributions on the political economy of violent conflict after the
Cold War. At its core interdisciplinary, the political economy of violent conflict represents
a literature that focuses on how economic issues and interests shape conflict dynamics—
or on how violent conflict starts, endures, escalates, or ends. The article underlines how
research on the political economy of violent conflict evolved after the Cold War from its
traditional focus on interstate warfare to civil wars, and then beyond, in order to make
sense of the constantly evolving nature of violent conflict in different regions of the
world.
The article distinguishes between an area of research focusing on the political economy
of civil wars—the predominant type of conflict in the 1990s and early 2000s with much
attention given to the study of rebel groups. The second area of research focuses on other
types of violent conflict within states over the past two decades. This research includes
political economy perspectives on intervention and permanent emergencies related in
particular to the wars in Afghanistan and Iraq; criminal violence in Central and South
America and southern Africa; and political violence and transitions in the Middle East and
North Africa.
This article limits its scope to contributions emerging from political science, sociology,
and anthropology in order to complement an existing review on the economics and
conflict in the Oxford Research Encyclopedia of International Studies (Schneider, 2010).
Given the richness of the literature, the article cannot systematically cover scholarship on
the political economy of interstate war, state-building, or development.
For Adam Smith, political economy was the science of managing a nation's
resources so as to generate wealth. For Marx, it was how the ownership of the
means of production influenced historical processes. For much of the twentieth
century, the phrase political economy has had contradictory meanings. Sometimes
it was viewed as an area of study (the interrelationship between economics and
politics) while at other times it was viewed as a methodological approach. Even
the methodological approach was divided into two parts – the economic approach
(often called public choice) emphasizing individual rationality and the sociological
approach where the level of analysis tended to be institutional. (p. 3)
Page 2 of 29
This article recognizes this intellectual tradition of political economy research but focuses
primarily on contributions from political science, sociology, and anthropology because the
literature on economics and conflict is already well covered elsewhere (Humphreys, 2003;
Schneider, 2010; Kimbrough, Laughren, & Sheremeta, 2017). The contributions from
these disciplines build on history scholarship on the economic attributes of interstate
wars and their effect on state formation. The rising costs of war had important
transformative effect on states of 15th- and 16th-century Europe and led to the
development of extraction systems for rulers to acquire the resources for state-making,
war-making, and protection (Tracy, 1985; Tilly, 1992). The need to pay for wars had such
profound effects on European states that “financial history cannot escape dealing with
war” (Kindleberger, 1993, p. 7). Beyond the evolution of states, wars also shaped the
origin of major firms, which became the organizational response to satisfy the increasing
demand from states for war-making materials from the 17th century onwards (Chandler,
1992; Sen, 1984). Research on the political economy of international conflict has also
featured within international political economy, especially in relation to the study of
military-industrial and trade rivalries between states and international economic orders
(Gill & Law, 1988; Lake, 2006).
With the end of the Cold War, research started to shift its focus from interstate to civil
wars. Political economy research also took this turn, initially driven by the application of
formal economic methods (Collier & Hoeffler, 1998). Yet the emphasis on economic
reductionism and methodological individualism led to claims that the models were
inadequate to capture structural and relational change over time (Cramer, 2002).
International political economy research emphasized how easier access to global markets
transformed civil wars as they enabled the commercialization of local resources in the
global economy and facilitated the supply of know-how, manpower, and war-fighting
material to war theaters (Berdal, 2003; Berdal & Malone, 2000; Duffield, 2001; Kaldor,
1999). This literature responded to the many open questions of how to respond to civil
Page 3 of 29
At its core interdisciplinary, the literature on the political economy of violent conflict also
became a conceptual laboratory for scholars who—often after years of field research—
tried to make sense of the messy, contradictory, illiberal, unjust, and constantly changing
realities of authoritarian, violent, or war-affected countries from their respective
disciplinary perspectives (Cramer, 2006; Giustozzi, 2007; Menkhaus, 2007; Nordstrom,
2004; Rodgers, 2009; Reno, 1996; de Waal, 2015). Despite the different methods and
approaches used in this research, what their work may have in common is a “political
economy analyses” that enables a look “beneath the formal structures to reveal the
underlying interests, incentives and institutions that enable or frustrate change” and that
account for both formal and informal social, political, and cultural norms shaping political
and economic competition (Department for International Development, 2009, pp. 1–2).
Research on the causes of civil wars was spearheaded by Paul Collier and Anke Hoeffler
at the World Bank and culminated into the Collier-Hoeffler Model on Civil War Onset
(Collier & Hoeffler, 1998, 2004; Collier & Sambanis, 2005). This research came to the
conclusion that economic motivations are more important than grievance to explain the
occurrence of civil war, which contrasted the then prevailing narratives about ethnic
conflict that were supposedly caused by “irrational and essentially inexplicably primordial
qualities” of ethnic and cultural identities (Pugh, Cooper, & Goodhand, 2004, p. 97), and
Page 4 of 29
The Collier-Hoeffler model may have been “the most widely reported results of any cross-
national study of civil conflict, ever” (Fearon, 2005, p. 484, emphasis in original). The
statistical methodology provided a basis to present the findings as objective and
apolitical. World Bank ownership gave the results authority and visibility. The findings
vindicated World Bank policy on economic diversification, the reduction of military
spending, growth- and trade-led economic development, and external intervention
(Collier et al., 2003). The findings also gave political momentum to efforts at the United
Nations to expose and undermine the financing of rebel groups in African conflict zones
(Klem, 2004).
A major source of criticism was the methodological orientation of the study mirroring a
broader discussion between quantitative and qualitative approaches to the social sciences
and between various epistemological positions on international relations (Hollis, 1994,
pp. 15–20). In this context, the emphasis on economic reductionism, the creation of
truths, and methodological individualism led to claims that the model was inadequate to
capture structural and relational change over time (Cramer, 2002, p. 1850; Herbst, 2000,
p. 274).
The thrust of the critique, however, was aimed at the execution of the research. Nathan
(2005) argues that the model “is filled with empirical, methodological and theoretical
problems that lead to unreliable results and unjustified conclusions” (p. 2). Klem (2004)
purports that “indicators are subjective and inadequate. . . . the jump from correlation to
causation is large” (p. 5). A report evaluating World Bank research noted a “lack of an
appropriate conceptual and empirical framework. As a result, the regression analysis of
these studies [on civil war] cannot be used to support the conclusions they ostensibly
reach . . . An important and promising topic was marred by poor execution” (Banerjee,
Deaton, Lustig, & Rogoff, 2006, p. 64). A key issue was data on conflict areas that led to
Page 5 of 29
the omission of 34 cases out of 113 in the earlier models and the omission of 27 out of 79
civil wars in the 2004 revision. These omissions compromised the validity of the findings
of the research produced up until the mid-2000s (Fearon, 2005, p. 485; Fearon & Laitin,
2003, p. 76).
With hindsight, the “greed and grievance” research following Collier and Hoeffler’s 1998
article, and the response to it, may be compared to the movements of a pendulum, as
described by Zartman (2005):
That middle ground became understanding the role of economic factors in conflict
dynamics in specific conflicts (Arnson & Zartman, 2005; Ballentine & Sherman, 2003) and
in terms of how they interact “with socioeconomic and political grievances, interethnic
disputes, and security dilemmas in triggering the outbreak of warfare” (Ballentine, 2003,
pp. 259–260). Much of the initial determinism of the greed and grievance discussion was
also softened as the discussion evolved with the intention to “lay to rest the ‘greed versus
grievance’ caricature. . . . Greed and grievance should not be seen as competing
explanations of conflict—they are often shades of the same problem” (Bannon, 2003, p.
xi). Work using anthropological methods also developed a much more contextual
understanding of conflict drawing on human stories (Nordstrom, 2004; Rodgers, 2009;
Uvin, 2009). With hindsight, therefore, the legacy of the greed and grievance debate may
be that it debunks single-factor explanations of how violent conflicts start, evolve, and
end and that it situates the analysis of economic dimensions of violent conflict more
within international political economy rather than economics.
Research on civil war occurred at a moment when natural resources took a prominent
role in many African conflicts, and the United Nations and the World Bank adapted their
policy accordingly (Bannon & Collier, 2003; Ballentine & Nitzschke, 2005B; Collier et al.,
2003). In the early 2000s, a series of reports of the United Nations Security Council
(UNSC) Sanctions Monitoring Mechanisms on Angola, the DRC, Liberia, or Sierra Leone
exposed the link between natural resource exploitation and human suffering and fatalities
and initiated a policy of “naming and shaming” governments and businesses involved in
war economies (e.g., UNSC, 2000). The reports also provided political momentum for new
sanctions regimes including commodity or financial sanctions and travel bans (Biersteker
& Eckert, 2001; Cortright & Lopez, 2002; Biersteker, Eckert, & Tourinho, 2016), as well
as multistakeholder natural resource management schemes such as the Kimberley
Page 6 of 29
Process against conflict diamonds (Smillie, 2005). Different advocacy groups did their
part to expose the deal-making of war-fighting governments and rebel groups as well as
their corporate or governmental supporters (e.g., Global Witness, 1998, 2001; Smillie,
Gberie, & Hazleton, 2000). The involvement of companies in war economies also
triggered policy efforts on business and human rights that led to the adoption of the
Guiding Principles on Business and Human Rights in 2011 (see Ruggie, 2013).
Through a functional lens it became possible to discern that the civil wars of the 1990s
departed from Clausewitzean notions of war as a contest between two armies in which
war is the means to achieve political goals. Rather, war became an end in itself, and the
aim of fighting was no longer to win against an enemy but to perpetuate the conflict for
economic reasons (van Creveld, 1991, pp. 57–62, 217). Through the functional lens, civil
wars were no longer characterized as purely political contests but became “the
continuation of economics by other means” (Keen, 1998, p. 11). Civil wars were “not
simply a breakdown of a particular system, but a way of creating an alternative system of
profit, power and even protection” (Keen, 1998, p. 11).
These characteristics of civil wars debunked the so-called “give war a chance” thesis,
which argued that “too many wars nowadays become endemic conflicts that never end
because the transformative effects of both decisive victory and exhaustion are blocked by
outside intervention” (Luttwak, 1999, p. 44). In the absence of intervention, wars would
be “allowed to run their natural course” as the belligerents would exhaust their military
force (Luttwak, 1999, p. 36). However, if the belligerents are conducting an armed
conflict for economic reasons, Cooper (2002, pp. 943–944) argued that waiting for the
military exhaustion “may be like waiting for Godot,” making reference to a play by
Samuel Becket in which the main characters await the arrival of someone named Godot,
but this person never arrives.
In addition, a functional lens helped correct the depiction civil wars as “chaos.” Keen
(2000) argued that
disciplines like economics and political science usually focus on a restricted area
that is ordered and predictable; and when messy phenomena like contemporary
civil war do not fall easily within the orbit of these systems of analysis, the
temptation to wheel out the label of chaos is very great. (p. 22)
Page 7 of 29
The literature therefore situated civil wars as part of broader transformation processes in
which people adapted their behavior in order to survive, minimize risk, and maximize
opportunities. In these circumstances, armed groups benefitted from the absence of legal
authorities and accumulated profits through violence, which in turn fostered an interest
to perpetuate the conflict, but not to win it (Keen, 1998).
The functional perspective also developed as a critique to policy efforts that mainly
focused on cutting-off financing from rebel groups as a means to end a civil war. Herbst
(2000), for instance, recalled the partisan nature of sanction regimes that are “an implicit
call for the military defeat of the rebels by the government,” noting also that “the
vocabulary of victory and defeat has been transferred to the more neutral and
technocratic language of sanctions and restraints on the trade of natural resources” (p.
271). In a similar vein, Keen (1997) remarked that
a focus on the costs of war only takes us so far. Unless we look also at the
functions of war, it is difficult to see how wars can be brought to an end. . . . If we
try to assess who is benefiting from war and in which ways (as well as who is
suffering from war and in which ways), we will be well placed to suggest policy
innovations that will alter the balance of costs and benefits for those effecting or
contemplating acts of violence. (p. 73)
Conflict Economies
Conflict economies have been another area of research of the political economy of civil
wars. This focus on rebel groups established a counterpoint to history scholarship on war
economies associated with states. As a starting point, Jean and Rufin (1996) described
Mao Tse Tung and Che Guevara’s doctrine of guerrilla warfare. According to these
doctrines, guerrilla forces are dependent on local populations for protection and
resources because they tend to be weaker than government forces in terms of number of
soldiers and hardware. They should therefore form a symbiosis with the local population
and its natural environment. However, except for China and Cuba, relying only on
symbiosis is rarely sufficient for mobilizing resources to maintain guerrilla activities,
which explained why insurgents needed to move around from one community to the next
while ensuring external support through military or humanitarian sanctuaries (Rufin,
1996, pp. 21–23).
Naylor (2002, pp. 45–47, 53–54) investigated the dynamic features of conflict economies
based on the interaction of the type of conflict economy (predation, parasitic, extraction)
and the military strategy of armed groups (contention, expansion, control). He
distinguished three stages in this evolution including “predation-contention” (the
economy is predatory and the military strategy is based on contention with government
forces), “parasitic-expansion” (insurgents grow in size and territorial reach with the
economy developing increasingly parasitical characteristics), and “extraction-territorial
control” (insurgents establish control over an area from which the state is excluded). The
latter stage has received further analysis in the literature on de facto states where a de
Page 8 of 29
facto government runs state-like institutions, public services, as well as justice and
taxation systems and has control over a population yet is not recognized as a state by the
international community (Pegg, 1998).
Research between the mid-1990s and mid-2000s also emphasized the importance of case
studies and field research in advancing the understanding of conflict economies.
Wennmann (2007A, p. 63) identifies at least 63 case studies in this period across 30
different civil wars. Exemplary of this work are articles on Afghanistan by Rubin (2000)
and Goodhand (2000) and on Bosnia and Herzegovina by Woodward (1995) and Donais
(2003). The work on conflict economies highlighted the important social and economic
transformations taking place during armed conflict (Cramer, 2006; Douma, 2003). It
showed that an economy not simply collapses in times of war but transforms itself to
fulfill the needs and objectives of a war-fighting state or non-state armed groups. It also
highlighted the role and limits of outside interveners in shaping social systems of conflict-
affected countries (Anderson, 1999; Duffield, 2001). War- or violence-induced
transformations also represent such an important change of economic relations and
opportunities that postconflict reconstruction needs to connect to these new realities, for
instance by adopting a conflict-sensitive, postconflict economy policy (Addison & Brück,
2009; Del Castillo, 2008; Kamphuis, 2005).
Conflict Financing
Research on conflict financing has been informed by case studies of the various rebel
groups in the mid-1990 to mid-2000s; especially in Africa (e.g., Angola, Ivory Coast, the
DRC, Eritrea/Ethiopia, Liberia, Mozambique, Rwanda, Sierra Leone, Somali, Sudan, and
Uganda) but also in South America (Colombia, Peru), Asia/Pacific (Cambodia, Indonesia,
Nepal, Sri Lanka, Papua New Guinea), Europe (Bosnia and Herzegovina, northern
Ireland), and the Middle East (Lebanon, Turkey). This research has been presented in
Page 9 of 29
several seminal case study volumes including Jean and Rufin (1996), Ballentine and
Sherman (2003), Pugh et al. (2004), Arnson and Zartman (2005), and Collier and
Sambanis (2005) and is connected to research on the behavior and functioning of rebel
groups (Balencie & de La Grange, 2001; Bøås & Dunn, 2007; Clapham, 1998; Hazen, 2013;
Metelits, 2010; Weinstein, 2007).
The importance of natural resources in conflict financing was explained by the trend for
rebel groups to replace their declining support from Cold War patrons—a claim that has
since been qualified by various scholars. Patronage payments during the Cold War tended
to be mainly a feature of Western power politics rather than a general phenomenon.
Western powers devoted a higher degree of support to different rebel groups in
comparison to the Soviet Union and China (Naylor, 2002, pp. 80–81). Moreover, even
during the Cold War, rebel groups were able to rely to some extent on natural resource
extraction and taxation as well as generate income through other economic activity
(Wennmann, 2007A, p. 94). It was also misleading to assume that direct support stopped
after the Cold War, as illustrated by the direct state support to the civil war in Bosnia and
Herzegovina (Bojicic & Kaldor, 1997). What did change, however, was that state support
was “no longer the only, or necessarily the most important, game in town” (Byman et al.,
2001, p. xiii). Herbst (2004, p. 367) emphasized that the access to natural resources
provided some rebel groups the means and an incentive to challenge weak states.
The tendency to emphasize the role of natural resources in rebel group financing was
surely adequate in many African civil wars, but overall it did not provide a balanced
picture on conflict financing generally. Many other rebel groups had a range of financing
methods, including, for instance, external assistance from governments or diasporas,
asset transfers from civilians, the printing and forging of money, protection rackets,
Page 10 of 29
landing fees, kidnapping, portfolio investments, and legitimate business ventures. The
kinds of financing strategies available to armed groups also depended on the
opportunities for money-making in the specific territories they controlled, the
geostrategic significance of this territory, and the international political context that
shaped the conflict (Wennmann, 2007B).
In addition, research on conflict financing has tended to focus on the income produced
from specific financing methods, not on an extended analysis to compare such revenue to
the cost of a specific military strategy. Research on mobilization costs emphasized the
importance of the relationship between available revenue sources and the financial
requirements to organize the type of military strategy needed to reach a particular
objective (Killicoat, 2007; Wennmann, 2009). This relationship between available funding
and mobilization costs provides new insight into what constitutes an “effective” source of
conflict financing at three levels: first, resources that are easy to centralize and generate
a high value and immediate revenue stream (which is key to initiate a conflict); second,
resources providing constant revenue over time (which are key to maintain a conflict),
and third, minor resource flows that can motivate commanders and troops to keep a
conflict alive but that on their own are insufficient to pay for a conflict (Wennmann,
2009). Many analyses of conflict financing obsess over how much money a specific group
controls but do not ask the question about how much money they need and what for. The
emphasis on mobilization costs produces a more nuanced analysis of conflict financing.
The wars in Afghanistan and Iraq introduced a new era of military interventions and
“liberal” development assistance related to state-building, economic reform, or peace-
building (Chandler, 2010; Paris, 1997; Richmond, 2006). These interventions involved the
Page 11 of 29
From a political economy perspective, this era of intervention opened new questions
about the functions of far-away conflict for war-fighting states and their defense
industries. Keen (2012) applies the rationale behind economic agendas in civil wars to
war-fighting states, illustrating the power of vested interest in and institutional dynamics
behind “permanent emergencies.” He emphasizes that many governments and defense
industries have become dependent on a mode of politics and business that requires
permanent emergencies, saying that “a declared war against a ‘demon’ enemy turns out
to be an ‘excellent’ context in which a wide variety of violent, profitable and politically
advantageous strategies can be pursued with a great deal of impunity” (Keen, 2012, p.
236).
Hossein-Zadeh (2006) positions the dynamics of permanent emergencies within the sale
and profit motives associated to the U.S. military-industrial complex—hence connecting to
a well-established research in international political economy (Gill & Law, 1988). He
argues that historically many major powers have been constituted as bureaucratic
military empires, and consequently their military industries “were owned and operated by
imperial governments” and were “not subject to capitalist market imperatives” (Hossein-
Zadeh, 2006, p. 6). In contrast, he holds that
private ownership and the market-driven character of the United States arms
industry have drastically modified the conventional relationship between the
supply of and demand for arms: it is now often the supply (or profit) imperatives
that drive demand for arms. In other words, imperial wars and demand for arms
are nowadays precipitated more by sales and/or profits than the other way
around. (p. 6)
According to Boggs (2017), the consequence of these dynamics in the United States has
been the creation of a “warfare state” described as “a broad ensemble of structures,
policies and ideologies” including elements such as a permanent war economy; a national
security state; a global expansion of military forces; and a merger of state, corporate, and
military power (p. 3). With its roots in the perpetuation of the military industrial system
created for World War II, the warfare state has been “legitimated through a deeply
entrenched culture of militarism” in which “corporate military statism has become a
Page 12 of 29
defining feature of American politics” (Boggs, 2017, pp. 3, 5). The entrenched power of
U.S. military industries is also illustrated through the lens of industrial policy. McCartney
(2015) observes that “defence contractors have learned that the surest way to get
Congress to approve defence projects is to locate the manufacturing of weapons and
other products and services in as many states and congressional districts as possible” (p.
38). In this way, military industries pressure members of Congress with job losses, foster
symbiotic relationships, and create an extended “military-industrial-congressional
complex” (McCartney, 2015, p. 45). Der Derian (2008) studies the extension of these
strategies with respect to the “military-industrial media-entertainment network.”
The previously cited scholarship illustrates how the economic agendas and business logic
of defense industries align behind an objective to neither necessarily “win” a particular
war nor to make a specific place any safer, showing that a state of permanent emergency,
fear, and insecurity is a necessary business environment for the defense industry to
thrive. The political economy of permanent economies therefore
challenges the traditional and “common sense” model of war as a contest between
two (or more) sides aiming to win . . . When winning is not the aim of fighting it is
important to distinguish the intention to eliminate an enemy and the usefulness to
actually succeeding.
Criminal Violence
Since the late 2000s, a strand of conflict research has shown that the great majority of
violent death occurs outside traditional conflict settings associated with the categories of
inter- or intrastate wars (Geneva Declaration Secretariat, 2008; Human Security Report
Project, 2013; World Health Organization, 2014) and proposed a new research agenda on
armed violence reduction (Krause & Muggah, 2009; Organisation for Economic Co-
operation and Development [OECD], 2011). This agenda emphasizes that violence
manifests itself in different forms in different places and connects to the proliferating
Page 13 of 29
study on the micro-dynamics of conflict, violence, and development (Justino, Brück, &
Verwimp, 2014). From a political economy perspective, the research opened a new
window on how the interaction of formal and informal power and control over economic
resources and opportunities generate violence and insecurity at the local level (Rodgers,
2009; Skaperdas, 2002).
First, this research clarified the regulatory functions of violence that are directly related
to the maintenance of organized crime. Violence can be a result of intergroup competition
over criminal markets or a means of arbitration. As the “underworld” is outside a legal
mechanism of dispute resolution, violence becomes a means of dispute settlement
between groups (Serrano, 2002, pp. 16–20, 23). Violence also occurs if competitors want
to break into a market and those challenged react to this competition violently (Naylor,
2002, p. 31). In principle, criminal networks do not like to use violence because it attracts
the attention of law enforcement, can interrupt established business channels, and can be
perceived as a sign of weakness (Dubinsky, 2007, p. 385; Naylor, 2002, pp. 31–32).
Second, the research clarified the political power and strategies of organized crime that
act as a “major force shaping contemporary global affairs” (Cockayne, 2016, p. 6).
Especially in Central and South America, researchers have applied network analysis to
chart how crime networks reconfigure political institutions (Briscoe, Perdomo, & Uribe
Burcher, 2014; Garay Salamanca & Salcedo-Albarán, 2012; InSight Crime, 2016). In
conflict-affected and fragile states, organized crime ensures that “the new rules of the
game are enforced in ways that maximize criminal actors’ control of criminal markets and
criminal rents” (Cockayne, 2013, p. 11) but pursues such political strategies to ensure a
business opportunity rather a political vocation (Dubinsky, 2007, p. 381). In a sense,
“Much like lobbyists seeking to influence political decisions and systems, organized crime
groups work politically to shape the state, the economy, and the society to fulfill their own
interests” (Wennmann, 2014, p. 256). From this perspective, weak states represent a
comparative advantage because they offer a proximity to the main markets, purchasable
state officials, a desperate population, and an ineffective police force (Dubinsky, 2007, p.
403; Wennmann, 2011, p. 117).
Third, the research emphasized the limits of heavy-handed strategies against drugs,
crime, or gangs. These responses exerted a tremendous humanitarian and human cost
and fanned rather than reduced violence (Inkster & Comolli, 2012; Jütersonke, Muggah,
&Rodgers, 2009; Kennedy, 2008; Kenny & Serrano, 2012). The research also showcased
the inability of institutional responses to armed violence to go beyond strategies that
target either political or criminal actors:
If they are political actors, perhaps they can become partners for peace. If
criminal, then surely they must be targets for law enforcement. . . . A conflict-
based approach will bring military and diplomatic resources into play; a crime-
based approach will lead us towards policing and law enforcement based
responses.
Informed by United Nations data, Kumar (2011) suggested that “87 countries in all of the
world’s regions . . . [are] facing the prospects of potential violence, prolonged deadlock,
or a relapse into violent conflict over the next two to three-year period” (p. 384). With
hindsight, this assessment has proven largely accurate. In contrast to inter- or intrastate
armed conflict, political violence and turbulent transitions do not evolve as a political
contest in which one of the parties aims to win—as noted earlier—but take on the
characteristics of a “slow-onset emergency” that “emerges gradually over time, often
based on a confluence of different events” (Office for the Coordination of Humanitarian
Affairs, 2011, p. 3) and as a result of long-term trends associated with population growth,
urbanization, climate change, geopolitical tensions, and other mega-trends (OECD, 2012).
A focus on political violence and transitions is cognizant of the “hybrid” nature of political
governance that is driven by different non-state forms of order and governance (Boege et
al., 2009; Kalyvas et al., 2008; North, Wallis, & Weingast, 2009). In many countries, state
functions are performed by gangs, private networks, local militias, guerrilla armies, or
customary authorities, leaving countries splintered into different zones of autonomy
(Clunan & Trinkunas, 2010; Rapley, 2006). Some of these actors may create their own
insecurities and inefficiencies, but “partly due to their success in providing security, these
sub-state groups often become the most legitimate political authority in areas that they
control” (Reno, 2008, p. 143). De Waal (2014) conceptualized the workings of such power
systems as a “political marketplace” in which governance is characterized “by pervasive
monetized patronage, in the form of exchange of political loyalty or cooperation for
payment” (p. 1).
institutional reforms that do not align with the prevailing interests and incentives
of power-holders, or do not redirect these incentives so as to support the new
Page 15 of 29
It seems just to be a matter of time when the tendency toward more exclusive control
over political and economic opportunities—also termed “limited access orders” by North
et al. (2009)—and the commutation of systemic risk (OECD, 2012) will translate into more
turbulence and political violence. For instance, by 2050 the United Nations forecasts that
there will be 1 billion Africans under the age of 18 (UNICEF, 2014). For Africa alone, the
urban population will increase by a staggering half a billion people by 2035—the
combined populations of present-day Nigeria, Ethiopia, Egypt, and Tanzania (Bello-
Schünemann, Cilier, Donnenfeld, & Aucoin, 2017, p. 26). Limited-access governance and
economic systems will be unable to provide the opportunities necessary to satisfy the
ambitions of so many young people to find a meaningful prospect in life. As the pool of
unsatisfied people grows, there will likely be increased rallying for a more pronounced
political change; and these demands may result in elites resorting to further repression.
Over 90 significant political protests took place in the past decade in over 40 African
countries, and these may be only the beginning (Branch & Mampilly, 2015). In the words
of de Waal (2017), “the long-term challenge is for the transactional politics of the political
marketplace to be supplanted by the institutional politics of the rule of law and the
functioning of democratic institutions” (p. 3). Yet this may not happen anytime soon in an
ear in which the support for such managed transitions is orphaned and cashless
(Ikenberry, 2018). As the world may be bracing for more turbulence in limited-access
orders, a political economy lens may help inform sober judgment on the possible
responses to the evolving nature of violent conflict.
Conclusion
This review has focused on a body of literature that investigates how economic issues and
interests shape the dynamics associated with violent conflict after the Cold War. The
article distinguished between an area of research focusing on civil wars and an area of
research focusing on other types of violent conflict. In order to complement existing
reviews that focus on economics and formal models, the article focused on the literature
in these areas of research from political science, sociology, and anthropology. This
research emphasizes the role of informal systems behind power, profits, and violence and
the economic interests and functions underlying violent conflict. By extending the
Page 16 of 29
boundaries of the literature beyond the study of civil wars, this article has emphasized
how political economy research can serve as an analytical lens to better understand
different types of violent conflict as they evolve over time. Within a context of rapidly
changing strategic landscapes, this lens will remain important for understanding conflict
dynamics and for informing relevant policy responses.
References
Addison, T., & Brück, T. (Eds.). (2009). Making peace work: The challenges of social and
economic reconstruction. Houndmills, U.K.: Palgrave Macmillan.
Anderson, M. (1999). Do no harm: How aid can support peace—and war. Boulder, CO:
Lynne Rienner.
Anderton, C. H., & Carter, J. R. (2009). Principles of conflict economics: A primer for
social scientists. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
Andrews, M. (2013). The limits of institutional reform in development: Changing rules for
realistic solutions. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
Anten, L., Briscoe, I., & Mezzera, M. (2012). The political economy of state-building in
situations of fragility and conflict: From analysis to strategy. The Hague, The
Netherlands: Institute of International Relations.
Arjona, A., Kasfir, N., & Mampilly, Z. (Eds.). (2015). Rebel governance in civil war.
Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
Arnson, C. (2005). The political economy of war: Situating a debate. In C. Arnson & I. W.
Zartman (Eds.), Rethinking the economics of war: The intersection of need, creed and
greed (pp. 1–22). Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Arnson, C., & Zartman, I. W. (Eds.). (2005). Rethinking the economics of war: The
intersection of need, creed and greed. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Autesserre, S. (2014). Peace land: Conflict resolution and the everyday politics of
international intervention. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
Balencie, J.-M., & de La Grange, A. (Eds.). (2001). Mondes rebelles: Guérillas, milices,
groupes terroristes. Paris, France: Editions Michalon.
Ballentine, K. (2003). Beyond greed and grievance: Reconsidering the economic dynamics
of armed conflict. In K. Ballentine & J. Sherman (Eds.), The political economy of armed
conflict: Beyond greed and grievance (pp. 259–283). Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
Ballentine, K., & Nitzschke, H. (2005a). The political economy of civil war and conflict
transformation. Berlin, Germany: Berghof Research Centre for Constructive Conflict
Management.
Page 17 of 29
Ballentine, K., & Nitzschke, H. (Eds.). (2005b). Profiting from peace: Managing the
resource dimensions of civil war. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
Ballentine, K., & Sherman, J. (Eds.). (2003). The political economy of armed conflict:
Beyond greed and grievance. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
Bello-Schünemann, J., Cilier, J., Donnenfeld, Z., & Aucoin, C. (2017). African futures: Key
trends. Pretoria, South Africa: Institute for Security Studies.
Banerjee, A., Deaton, A., Lustig, N., & Rogoff, K. (2006). An evaluation of World Bank
research, 1998–2005. Unpublished manuscript.
Bannon, I. (2003). Foreword. In I. Bannon & P. Collier (Eds.), Natural resources and
violent conflict: Options and actions (pp. ix–xi). Washington, DC: World Bank.
Bannon, I., & Collier, P. (Eds.). (2003). Natural resources and violent conflict: Options and
actions. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Barnett, M. N., & Finnmore, M. (1999). The politics, power and pathologies of
international organizations. International Organization, 53(4), 699–732.
Beblawi, H., & Luciani, G. (Eds.). (1987). The rentier state. Beckenham, U.K.: Croom
Helm.
Berdal, M. (2005): Beyond Greed and Grievance – And Not Too Soon . . . Review of
International Studies, 31(4), 687–698.
Berdal, M. (2003). How “new” are “new wars”? Global economic change and the study of
civil war. Global Governance, 9(4), 477–502.
Berdal, M., & Malone, D. M. (Eds.). (2000). Greed and grievance: Economic agendas in
civil wars. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
Berdal, M., & Zaum, D. (Eds.). (2013). Political economy of statebuilding: Power after
peace. Abingdon, U.K.: Routledge.
Biersteker, T. J., & Eckert, S. (2001). Targeted financial sanctions: A manual for design
and implementation—Contributions from the Interlaken Process. Providence, RI: Thomas
J. Watson Jr. Institute for International Studies.
Biersteker, T. J., Eckert, S., & Tourinho, M. (Eds.). (2016). Targeted sanctions: The impacts
and effectiveness of United Nations action. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
Bøås, M., & Dunn, K. C. (Eds.). (2007). African guerrilla: Raging against the machine.
Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
Boege, V., Brown, A., Clemens, K., & Nolan, A. (2009). Building peace and political
community in hybrid political orders. International Peacekeeping, 16(5), 599–615.
Page 18 of 29
Boggs, C. (2017). Origins of the warfare state: World War II and the transformation of
American politics. Abingdon, U.K.: Routledge.
Bojicic, V., & Kaldor, M. (1997). The political economy of the war in Bosnia-Herzegovina.
In M. Kaldor & B. Vashee (Eds.), New wars (pp. 137–176). London, U.K.: Pinter.
Branch, A., & Mampilly, Z. (2015). Africa uprising: Popular protest and political change.
London, U.K.: Zed Books.
Brauer, J., & Gissy, W. G. (Eds.). (1997). The economics of conflict and peace. London,
U.K.: Routledge.
Brauer, J., & van Tuyll, H. P. (2008). Castles, battles and bombs: How economics explains
military history. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
Briscoe, I., Perdomo, C., & Uribe Burcher, C. (Eds.). (2014). Illicit networks and politics in
Latin America. The Hague, The Netherlands: Netherlands Institute for Multiparty
Democracy.
Bruch, C., Muffett, C., & Nichols, S. S. (2016). Governance, natural resources, and post-
conflict peacebuilding. Abingdon, U.K.: Earthscan.
Buzan, B. (1991). People, states and fear: An agenda for international security studies in
the post-Cold War era. Hemel Hempstead, U.K.: Harvester Wheatsheaf.
Byman, D., Chalk, P., Hoffman, B., Rosenau, W., & Brannan, D. (2001). Trends in outside
support for insurgent movements. Santa Monica, CA: RAND.
Cammett, M., Diwan, I., Richards, A., & Waterbury, J. (2015). A political economy of the
Middle East. Boulder, CO: Westview Press.
Carbonnier, G. (2015). Humanitarian economics: War, disaster and the global aid market.
London, U.K.: Hurst.
Cilliers, J., & Dietrich, C. (2000). Angola’s war economy: The role of oil and diamond.
Pretoria, South Africa: Institute for Security Studies.
Page 19 of 29
Clunan, A. L., & Trinkunas, H. A. (Eds.). (2010). Ungoverned spaces: Alternatives to state
authority in an era of softened sovereignty. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
Cockayne, J. (2016). Hidden power: The strategic logic of organized crime. Oxford, U.K.:
Oxford University Press.
Coll, S. (2004). Ghost wars: The secret history of the CIA, Afghanistan, and Bin Laden,
from the Soviet invasion to September 10, 2001. London, U.K.: Penguin.
Collier, P., Elliott, L., Hegre, H., Hoeffler, A., Reynal-Querol, M., & Sambanis, N. (2003).
Breaking the conflict trap: Civil war and development policy. Washington, DC: World
Bank.
Collier, P., & Hoeffler, A. (1998). On the economic causes of civil war. Oxford Economic
Papers, 50(4), 563–573.
Collier, P., & Hoeffler, A. (2004). Greed and grievance in civil war. Oxford Economic
Papers, 56(4), 563–595.
Collier, P., & Sambanis, N. (Eds.). (2005). Understanding civil war: Evidence and analysis.
Washington, DC: World Bank.
Cooper, N. (2001). Conflict goods: The challenges for peacekeeping and conflict
prevention. International Peacekeeping, 8(3), 21–38.
Cooper, N. (2002). State collapse as business: The role of conflict trade and their
emerging control agenda. Development and Change, 33(5), 935–955.
Cortright, D., & Lopez, G. A. (2002). Sanctions and the search for security: Challenges to
UN action. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
Cramer, C. (2006). Civil war is not a stupid thing: Accounting for violence in developing
countries. London, U.K.: Hurst.
Page 20 of 29
de Waal, A. (2015). The real politics in the Horn of Africa: Money, war and the business of
power. Cambridge, MA: Polity Press.
de Waal, A. (2017). South Sudan 2017: A political marketplace analysis. Boston, MA:
World Peace Foundation.
Dodge, T. (2005). Inventing Iraq: The failure of nation building and a history denied. New
York, NY: Columbia University Press.
Donais, T. (2003). The political economy of stalemate: Organised crime, corruption and
economic deformation in post-Dayton Bosnia. Conflict, Security and Development, 3(3),
359–382.
Douma, P.S. (2003). The political economy of internal conflict: A comparative analysis of
Angola, Colombia, Sierra Leone and Sri Lanka. The Hague: Netherlands Institute of
International Relations.
Dubinsky, I. V. (2007). How bad boys turn good: The role of law in transforming criminal
organizations into legitimate entities by making rehabilitation and economic necessity.
DePaul Business and Commercial Law Journal, 5(2), 379–426.
Duffield, M. (2001). Global governance and the new wars: The merging of development
and security. London, U.K.: Zed Books.
Fearon, J. D. (2005). Primary commodity exports and civil war. Journal of Conflict
Resolution, 49(4), 483–507.
Fearon, J. D., & Laitin, D. D. (2003). Ethnicity, insurgency and civil war. American Political
Science Review, 91(1), 75–90.
Friman, H. R. (2009). Crime and globalization. In H. R. Friman (Ed.), Crime and the
global political economy (pp. 1–19). Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
Gill, S., & Law, D. (1988). The global political economy: Perspectives, problems and
policies. Hemel Hempstead, U.K.: Harvester Wheatsheaf.
Global Witness. (1998). A rough trade: The role of companies and governments in the
Angola conflict. London, U.K.: Author.
Global Witness. (2001). All the president’s men: The devastating story of oil and banking
in Angola’s privatized war. London, U.K.: Author.
Goodhand, J. (2000). From holy war to opium war? A case study of the opium economy in
north-eastern Afghanistan. Disasters, 24(2), 87–102.
Hartley, K., & Sandler, T. (Eds.). (1995). Handbook of defense economics, Vol. 1. New
York, NY: Elsevier.
Hazen, J. (2013). What rebels want: Resources and supply networks in wartime. Ithaca,
NY: Cornell University Press.
Herbst, J. (2000). Economic incentives, natural resources and conflict in Africa. Journal of
African Economies, 9(3), 270–291.
Herbst, J. (2004). African militaries and rebellion: The political economy of threat and
combat effectiveness. Journal of Peace Research, 41(3), 357–369.
Human Security Report Project. (2013). Human security report 2013. Vancouver, BC:
Simon Frazer University.
Humphreys, M. (2003). Economics and violent conflict. Boston, MA: Harvard University.
Ikenberry, G. J. (2018). The End of the Liberal International Order. International Affairs
94(1), 7–23.
Page 22 of 29
Inkster, N., & Comolli, V. (2012). Drugs, insecurity, and failed states: The problems of
prohibition. Abingdon, U.K.: Routledge.
InSight Crime. (2016). Elites and organized crime: Introduction, methodology, and
conceptual framework. Washington, DC: Author.
Jean, F., & Rufin, J. C. (Eds.). (1996). Economie des guerres civiles. Paris, France:
Hachette.
Jensen, D., & Lonergan, S. (2012). Assessing and restoring natural resources in post-
conflict peacebuilding. Abingdon, U.K.: Earthscan.
Justino, P., Brück, T., & Verwimp, P. (Eds.). (2014). A micro-level perspective on the
dynamics of conflict, violence, and development. Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press.
Jütersonke, O., Muggah, R., & Rodgers, D. (2009). Gangs, urban violence, and security
interventions in Central America. Security Dialogue, 40(4–5), 373–397.
Kaldor, M. (1999). New and old wars: Organized violence in a global era. Cambridge, MA:
Polity Press.
Kalyvas, S. N. (2006). The logic of violence in civil war. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge
University Press.
Kalyvas, S. N., Shapiro, I., & Masoud, T. (Eds.). (2008). Order, conflict and violence.
Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
Kamphuis, B. (2005). Economic policy for building peace. In G. Junne & W. Verkoren
(Eds.), Postconflict development: Meeting new challenges (pp. 185–210). Boulder, CO:
Lynne Rienner.
Kaplan, R. D. (2000). The Coming Anarchy: Shattering the Dreams of the Post Cold War.
New York, NY: Vintage Books.
Keen, D. (1997). A rational kind of madness. Oxford Development Studies, 25(1), 67–75.
Keen, D. (1998). The economic functions of civil war. Adelphi Papers 320. London, U.K.:
International Institute for Strategic Studies.
Keen, D. (2000). War, crime, and access to resources. In W. Nafziger, F. Stewart, & R.
Väyrynen (Eds.), War, hunger, and displacement: The origins of humanitarian emergencies
(pp. 283–304). Oxford, U.K.: Oxford University Press.
Keen, D. (2012). Useful enemies: When waging wars is more important than winning
them. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Page 23 of 29
Kenny, P., & Serrano, M., with Sotomayor, A. (Eds.). (2012). Mexico’s security failure:
Collapse into criminal violence. New York, NY: Routledge.
Killicoat, P. (2007). What price the Kalashnikov: The economics of small arms. In Small
Arms Survey (Ed.), Small arms survey 2007: Guns and the city (pp. 257–287). Cambridge,
U.K.: Cambridge University Press.
Kimbrough, E. O., Laughren, K., & Sheremeta, R. (2017). War and conflict in
economics: Theories, applications, and recent trends. Journal of Economic Behavior
and Organization [Advance online publication].
King, C. (1997). Ending civil wars. Adelphi Paper 308. London, U.K.: International
Institute for Strategic Studies.
Klare, M. T. (2001). Resource wars: The new landscape of global conflict. New York, NY:
Henry Holt.
Klem, B. (2004). A commentary on the World Bank report “Breaking the Conflict Trap.”
Working Paper 25. The Hague, The Netherlands: Netherlands Institute of International
Relations.
Krause, K., & Muggah, R. (2009). Closing the gap between peace operations and post-
conflict insecurity: Towards a violence reduction agenda. International Peacekeeping,
16(1), 136–150.
Krause, K., & Williams, M. C. (1996). Broadening the agenda of security studies: Politics
and methods. Mershon International Studies Review, 40(2), 229–254.
Kumar, C. (2011). Building national infrastructures for peace: UN assistance for internally
negotiated solutions to violent conflict. In S. Allen Nan, Z. C. Mampilly, & A. Bartoli
(Eds.), Peacemaking: From practice to theory (pp. 384–399). Santa Barbara, CA: Praeger.
Le Billon, P. (2001). The political ecology of war: Natural resources and armed conflict.
Political Geography, 20(5), 561–584.
Lujala, P., & Rustad, S. A. (2012). High-value natural resources and post-conflict
peacebuilding. Abingdon, U.K.: Earthscan.
Mac Ginty, R. (2011). International peacebuilding and local resistance: Hybrid forms of
peace. Houndmills, U.K.: Palgrave Macmillan.
Malone, D. M., & Nitzschke, H. (2009). Economic agendas in civil war: What we know,
what we need to know. In T. Addison & T. Brück (Eds.), Making peace work: The
challenges of social and economic reconstruction (pp. 31–50). Houndmills, U.K.: Palgrave
Macmillan.
McCartney, J. (2015). America’s war machine: Vested interests, endless conflict. New
York, NY: St. Martin’s Press.
Misser, F., & Vallée, O. (1997). Les gemmocraties: L’Économie politique du Diamant
Africain. Paris, France: Desclée de Brouwer.
Moore, P., & Parker, C. (2007). The war economy of Iraq. Middle East Report, 37.
Naylor, T. R. (2002). Wages of crime: Black markets, illegal finance, and the underworld
economy. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Nathan, L. (2005). The frightful inadequacy of most of the statistics: A critique of Collier
and Hoeffler on causes of civil war. Discussion Paper No.11. London: Crisis States
Development Research Centre, London School of Economics.
North, D. C., Wallis, J. J., & Weingast, B. R. (2009). Violence and social orders: A
conceptual framework for interpreting recorded human history. Cambridge, U.K.:
Cambridge University Press.
Office for the Coordination of Humanitarian Affairs. (2011). OCHA and slow-onset
emergencies. New York, NY: Author.
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. (2012). Think local, act global:
Confronting factors that influence conflict and fragility. Paris, France: Author.
Page 25 of 29
Paris, R., & Sisk, T. D. (Eds.). (2009). The dilemmas of statebuilding: Confronting the
contradictions of postwar peace operations. Abingdon, U.K.: Routledge.
Pegg, S. (1998). International society and the de facto state. Aldershot, U.K.: Ashgate.
Pugh, M., & Cooper, N., with Goodhand, J. (2004). War economies in a regional context:
Challenges and transformations. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
Pugh, M., Cooper, N., & Turner, M. (Eds.). (2008). Whose peace? Critical perspectives on
the political economy of peacebuilding. Houndmills, U.K.: Palgrave Macmillan.
Putzel, J., & Di John, J. (2012). Meeting the Challenges of Crises States. London, U.K.:
Crisis States Research Centre at the London School of Economics and Political Science.
Rapley, J. (2006). The new Middle Ages. Foreign Affairs, 85(3), 95–105.
Renner, M. (2002). The anatomy of resource wars. Worldwatch Paper 162. Washington,
DC: Worldwatch Institute.
Reno, W. (1996). Warlord politics and African states. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
Rodgers, D. (2009). Slum wars of the 21st century: Gangs, mano dura, and the new urban
geography of conflict in Central America. Development and Change, 40(5), 949–976.
Ross, M. L. (2003). Oil, drugs and diamonds: The varying roles of natural resources in
civil war. In K. Ballentine & J. Sherman (Eds.), The political economy of armed conflict
(pp. 47–70). Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
Ross, M. L. (2004). What do we know about natural resources and civil war? Journal of
Peace Research, 41(3), 337–356.
Rubin B. R. (2000). The political economy of war and peace. World Development, 28(10),
1789–1803.
Rufin, J. C. (1996). Les économies des guerres dans les conflits internes. In F. Jean & J. C.
Rufin (Eds.), Economie des guerres civile (pp. 19–59). Paris, France: Hachette.
Ruggie, J. G. (2013). Just business: Multinational corporations and human rights. New
York, NY: W. W. Norton.
Page 26 of 29
Sen, G. (1984). The military origins of industrialisation and international trade rivalry.
London, U.K.: Pinter.
Singer, P. W. (2003). Corporate warriors: The rise of the privatised military industry.
Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
Smillie, I. (2005). What lessons from the Kimberley Process Certification Scheme. In K.
Ballentine & Nitzschke, H. (Eds.), Profiting from peace: Managing the resource
dimensions of civil war (pp. 47–67). Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner.
Smillie, I., Gberie, L., & Hazleton, R. (2000). The heart of the matter: Sierra Leone,
diamonds and human security. Ottawa, ON: Partnership Africa Canada.
Tilly, C. (1992). Coercion, capital and European states, AD 990–1992. Oxford, U.K.:
Blackwell.
UNICEF. (2014). Generation 2030—Africa: Child demographics in Africa. New York, NY:
Author.
United Nations Security Council. (2000). Report of the panel of experts on violations of
Security Council sanctions against UNITA. Document S/2000/203. New York, NY: United
Nations.
Unruh, J., & Williams, R. C. (2013). Land and post-conflict peacebuilding. Abingdon, U.K.:
Earthscan.
Uvin, P. (2009). Life after violence: A people’s story of Burundi. London, U.K.: Zed Books.
van Creveld, M. (1991). The transformation of war. New York, NY: Free Press.
Varieties of Democracy Institute. (2018). Democracy for all? V-Dem annual democracy
report 2018. Gothenburg, Sweden: University of Gothenburg.
Page 27 of 29
Weinstein, J. (2007). Inside rebellion: The politics of insurgent violence. Cambridge, U.K.:
Cambridge University Press.
Weinthal, E., Troell, J., & Nakayama, M. (2014). Water and post-conflict peacebuilding.
Abingdon, U.K.: Earthscan.
Wennmann, A. (2007a). Conflict financing and the recurrence of intra-state armed conflict
(Doctoral dissertation). Graduate Institute of International and Development Studies,
Geneva, Switzerland.
Wennmann, A. (2009). Grasping the financing and mobilization cost of armed groups: A
new perspective on conflict dynamics. Contemporary Security Policy, 30(2), 265–280.
Wennmann, A. (2014). Negotiated exits from organized crime? Building peace in conflict
and crime-affected contexts. Negotiation Journal, 30(3), 255–273.
Woodward, S. (1995). Balkan tragedy: Chaos and dissolution after the Cold War.
Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.
World Health Organization. (2014). Global status report on violence prevention 2014.
Geneva, Switzerland: Author.
Young, H., & Goldman, L. (2015). Livelihoods, natural resources, and post-conflict
peacebuilding. Abingdon, U.K.: Earthscan.
Zartman, I. W. (2005). Need, creed, and greed in intrastate conflict. In C. Arnson & I. W.
Zartman (Eds.), Rethinking the economics of war: The intersection of need, creed and
greed (pp. 256–284). Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Achim Wennmann
Page 28 of 29
Page 29 of 29