Unit-4-1 2
Unit-4-1 2
4.0 OBJECTIVES
After going through this unit, you will be able to:
• state the concept of uncertainty and risk;
• discuss the expected utility function and its properties;
• explain how to maximise utility under uncertainty;
• discuss the attitude of an individual towards Risk;
• elucidate how risk aversion is dealt with institution of insurance; and
• appreciate the process of the intertemporal decision-making by the
consumer.
4.1 INTRODUCTION
We have learned in Unit 2 how a consumer decides which combination of
goods and services to buy, given his income and prices of the goods, in order
to maximise his satisfaction. For this, there is a pre-supposition that the
consumer has complete and perfect information and knowledge about the
74
transaction. However, in real life situations, there are many uncertainties Choice Under Uncertainty
and Intertemporal Choice
that consumers have to face before they decide. Uncertainty is a fact of life.
In decision-making process, there are many uncertainties and randomness
that a consumer has to take into consideration. For example:
i) Used Car: When you buy a used car, you are very unsure about its
condition. You might be lucky and get a beautifully maintained car with
no mechanical problems, or you might get a lemon or damaged car
(whose mechanical problems are not easily observable).
ii) College/University: Suppose you choose a university for an
undergraduate degree. Your university is very expensive. During the
time of making decision about your college/university choice, how
much do you know about it (or them)? Do you know how many
professors are interesting and informative, and how many are deadly
dull and uninterested in teaching? Do you know what your major will
be? Do you know what a blessings or a curse your roommates or
classmates might be?
iii) Life Insurance and Annuities: If all the events and contingencies are well
known in life, then there is no need for insurance in such a society.
However, when significant uncertainties are present, insurances solve
the problem for such a society. You fear you may die too young, and
you want to buy a life insurance policy to protect your spouse and
children in the vent of your premature death. What kind of policy
should you buy, and how much insurance should you have?
Alternatively, you think you may live too long and you may run out of
savings before you go. You do not want to be a burden to your children.
You heard that you can buy an insurance against this possibility also.
Should you buy an annuity, and how big an annuity should you get?
iv) Investments: You have some money that you are going to invest in bank
term deposits (with minimal risks and also minimal rewards), or in
shares of stocks (with considerable risks but greater rewards). What
should you do?
v) Dangerous activities: You travel between home and college by car, or by
train. Be it any mode, each time you face some risk of a fatal accident.
Do you know what the odds of a road accident are? Suppose you own a
car and are good at driving. But you do not know whether everyone
around on the road is a careful driver. Someone may hit your car and
the damages can be huge and varied. Hence, whenever you drive out
from your house, you are uncertain that you will come back without
getting hit or what will be the amount of accumulated damage in any
accident.
There are countless examples in real life which involve uncertainty. Many of
the things we do increase uncertainty in our lives, whereas other things
reduce it. Sometimes we pay money to buy risks (like gamble, lottery) at
other times we pay money to avoid risks. Under such uncertainties, there
often exist difficulties in decision-making. To tackle this, institutions exist.
Insurance in an economy is another such institution which helps in
75
Consumer Theory mitigating risks that arise due to uncertainties. With uncertainties, you
might like to get insurance cover against car accidents. For this reason
agents buy various kinds of insurance (life insurance, car insurance, fire
insurance, crop insurance etc), to cover up for the risk involved or an
unforeseen contingency.
In this unit we shall explain the notion of uncertainty and how it impacts the
consumer’s behaviour. The concept of expected utility function will be
introduced in order to understand consumer’s decision-making under
uncertainty. In this connection, we will explain the concept of risk and an
individual’s attitude towards risk and the basic principle of choosing
insurance.
We shall also throw light on intertemporal decision making, where Inter-
temporal means across the time period. We shall take into consideration the
saving and borrowing by a consumer and how does they affect his/her
decision-making. This we will attempt to discuss with the help of an inter-
temporal budget constraint.
76
This probability distribution is represented below in the Fig. 4.1. Choice Under Uncertainty
and Intertemporal Choice
Probability
0.5
0.4
0.3
0.2
0.1
Probability
0
Height (in cm)
cm)
Fig. 4.2: Continuous Probability Distribution
This is how the payoffs are read— there is 10 per cent chance of getting
Rs. 10 payoff, 30 per cent chance of getting Rs. 20 payoff and 20 per cent
chance each of getting payoff as Rs. 30, Rs. 40 and Rs. 50. Similarly for plan
B, we have the outcomes (payoffs) and their respective probabilities. Now to
choose between plan A or plan B, agent needs to calculate the expected
payoff from each plan.
78
From Plan A, his expected payoff = 10(0.1) + 20(0.3) + 30(0.2) + Choice Under Uncertainty
and Intertemporal Choice
40(0.2) + 50(0.2) = 31.
Similarly, from Plan B, expected payoff = 30.
As we might expect, our agent’s first inclination is to choose the investment
that provides the highest expected monetary value. This approach seems to
make sense. Most people would want to consider the investment from
which they can expect the greatest return. On such basis, our agent will
choose plan A because its expected payoff value is greater than the
expected payoff value of plan B. Hence when faced with uncertainties, it is
natural to believe that the agents maximise their expected monetary
benefits which, in turn, maximises their expected utility. But this is not true
in all cases. Now let us discuss a situation in which maximising expected
monetary value may render different result than maximising expected
utility.
Gamble A Gamble B
Prize (Rs) Probability Utility of Prize (Rs) Probability Utility of
Rupee Rupee
10,000 0.5 0 0 0.99 0
15,000 0.5 0 20,000 0.01 1
Expected monetary value = Rs. Expected monetary value = Rs. 200
12,500 Expected utility = 0.01
Expected utility = 0
Where, function v(.)* gives the amount of utility attained from some
amount of consumption. Thus vNM expected utility can be written as a
weighted sum of some function of consumption in each state, v(c1) and
v(c2), where the weights are given by the probabilities π1 and π2 (where 0 <
�� < 1 and also �� = 1 with i = 1, 2). If one of the states is certain, so that
π1 = 1 say, then v(c1) is the utility of certain consumption in state 1. Similarly,
if π2 = 1, v (c2) is the utility of certain consumption in state 2.
80
When we say that a consumer’s preferences can be represented by an Choice Under Uncertainty
and Intertemporal Choice
expected utility function, or that the consumer’s preferences have the
expected utility property, we mean that we can choose a utility function
that has the additive form described above.
Thus Von Neumann Morgenstern (vNM) Expected Utility theorem says: Let L
be the risky alternative, that is, any lottery. Suppose its outcomes are (X1,
X2,…, X�). These are certain outcomes or other lotteries with respective
probabilities (p1, p2, … , p�). Then the utility of the risky alternative L is the
expectation of the utilities of its possible outcomes. That is:
U(L) = p1 U(X1) + p2 U(X2) + ⋯ + pnU(Xn)
81
Consumer Theory Check Your Progress 1
1) Which of the following utility functions have the expected utility
property?
a) u(c1, c2) = 5 [π� v(c� ) + π� v(c� )]
b) u(c1, c2) = π1c1 + π2c2
c) u(c1, c2) = π1 ln c1 + π2 ln c2 + 17
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
4.4.1 Risk
Risk is generally perceived as the possibility of facing a misfortune or a loss.
In other words, it is the potential that a choice or a decision made will bring
an undesirable outcome. Like your decision to drive a car on road involves
the risk of your car meeting an accident and hence incurring damage or loss.
That is here, risk is involved with uncertainty of happening or not happening
of an event. Such uncertain situations are often connected to some
associated probabilities of occurrence or non-occurrence of an event.
Now the question arises, “How do people react to events involving risk
compared to those that are risk-free?” There exists heterogeneity in
people’s preference toward risk. Consider an individual, who is asked to
choose between two gambles, G1 and G2. Gamble G1 offers a prize of Rs. 50
with certainty, whereas gamble G2, offers a prize of Rs. 100 with a
probability of 0.50 and no prize with a probability of 0.50. G1 being a sure
thing is obviously less risky than G2. Expected value of the gambles will be
given as follows:
Expected Value (EV) of G1 = 1 × 50 = Rs. 50 (as probability of a certain payoff
is 1.)
Expected Value (EV) of G2 = 0.50 × 100 + 0.50 × 0 = Rs. 50
Although both Gambles have the same EV, one can only be sure about G1 as
G2 is risky in Economic sense. While making a choice between G1 and G2,
some people might be indifferent among G1 and G2; some might prefer G2,
the risky one; and others might choose G1, the safe gamble. From this,
emerges the notion of attitude towards risk. Suppose a consumer is given
the choice between two activities, a risk-free activity with a guaranteed
outcome and a risky activity involving outcomes with some probabilities.
Assuming people prefer to maiximise utility attained from different available
options and not associated monetary payoffs, they can be classified
according to their attitude towards risk into three categories, viz— Risk
Neutral, Risk Averse and Risk Loving. Let’s discuss each one of these three
categories.
U = 2X
Utility from Payoff
b
2000
E(U) = U(EV) c
= 1550
a
200
Now assume this individual has utility function given by U (X) = √X, where X
is the payoff received. We will proceed in the similar way like we did in case
of risk-neutral individual (Refer Fig. 4.4).
U(36) = √36 = 6, the height at point a; U(100) = √100 = 10, height at the
point b.
85
Consumer Theory � � � �
E(U) of the risky activity A = [� × U(36) + � × U(100)] ⇒ [� × 6 + � × 10] = 9.2,
height at point c, representing mean value of the line joining points a and b.
A risk-free activity B will offer a certain payoff of EV of the Risky activity A,
i.e. Rs. 87.2. EV of risk-free activity B will also be Rs. 87.2.
Utility attained from activity B, i.e. [U(EV)] = U(87.2) = √87.2 = 9.338, which is
equal to the height at point d. Here, we get U(EV) > E(U). That is, this
individual attains higher utility from risk-free activity B, as compared to the
expected utility from risky activity A (9.338 > 9.2). Such a behaviour exhibits
an individual’s risk averseness, where expected utility associated with a risky
choice is less than the utility attained from a certain outcome (= the
expected outcome of the risky choice) of a risk-free choice.
U = √�
b
10
d
U(EV) = 9.338
E(U) = 9.2 c
a
Utility from Payoff
0 36 EV = 87.2 100
Payoff (X in Rs.)
Fig. 4.4: Risk Aversion
86
activity B with a certain payoff equal to the expected payoff of the risky Choice Under Uncertainty
� � and Intertemporal Choice
activity A, i.e., Rs. 7.5 �= � × 5 + � × 10�.
Now assume this individual has utility function given by U (X) = X � , where X
is the payoff received. Here again we proceed in the similar way like we did
in case of risk-neutral and a risk-averse individual.
U(5) = 25, the height at point a; U(10) = 100, height at the point b.
� � �
Expected Utility, i.e. E(U) of the risky activity A = [� × U(5) + � × U(10)] = [� ×
�
25 + � × 100] = 62.50, height at point c, representing mean value of the line
joining points a and b.
Here, you can easily notice from the figure, that height ce > de, that is, we
get E(U) > U(EV). In other words, expected utility attained by this individual
from risky activity A is greater than the utility he receives from risk-free
activity B giving certain outcome (that is, 62.50 > 56.25). Such a behaviour
exhibits that the individual is risk preferring, with expected utility associated
with a risky choice being more than the utility attained from a certain
outcome (= the expected outcome of the risky choice) of a risk-free
choice.
b
100
Utility from Payoff
c
E(U) = 62.50
U(EV) = 56.25
d
a
25
e
0 5 EV = 7.5 10
Payoff (X in Rs.)
Fig. 4.5: Risk Preferring
87
Consumer Theory
4.5 RISK AVERSION AND INSURANCE
In addition to characterising an agent’s attitude toward risk, expected utility
theory can be of use to us in analysing more applied questions about
insurance and about risk-taking in general. To understand the value of
expected utility theory in such areas, let us consider Fig. 4.6.
Fig. 4.6 is identical to Fig. 4.4. It depicts the utility function of an agent who
is averse to risk. Let us assume that this agent owns a house that has a
current value of Rs. 100 and that she is aware of the possibility that the
house may burn down, in which case the land it is on, will be worth Rs. 36
only. Let us also assume that from previous history, we know that there is a
20% chance that the agent’s house will burn down. Therefore, we can say
that during the next period, the agent is actually facing a gamble in which
�
she will have a house worth Rs. 100 with a probability of 80% (= �) , or she
�
will have land worth Rs. 36 with probability 20% (= �).
� �
Expected value of the gamble = � × 100 + � × 36
= Rs. 87.2
U(36) = √36 = 6, the height at point a; U(100) = √100 = 10, height at the
point b. Therefore, the expected utility E(U) is
� � � �
E(U) = [� × U(36) + � × U(100)] ⇒ [� × 6 + � × 10] = 9.2,
height at point c, representing mean value of the line joining points a and b.
The utility from the expected value (or income) of the gamble U(EV) is:
88
Note that cg and ef are the same height, where ef represents utility to the Choice Under Uncertainty
and Intertemporal Choice
agent (= 9.2) with a sure payoff of Rs. 84.64. This amount of Rs. 84.64 is
known as the Certainty Equivalent of the Gamble.
Our agent can obtain Rs. 84.64 for sure if someone is willing to sell her
insurance on the house for a yearly premium (price) of Rs. 2.56 (= Rs.
87.2 − 84.64). This 2.56 amount is nothing but what is called the Risk
Premium. It is simply the amount which the agent is willing to forego in
order to be indifferent in her choice between a risky gamble and the one
with a certain return. The notion of a risk premium is directly applicable to
insurance policies. An individual who purchases an insurance policy willingly
pays a sum of money, known as an insurance premium (or Risk premium), in
order to guarantee a certain level of monetary value generally associated
with some type of risky activity.
U = √�
b
10
d
U(EV) = 9.338 e
E(U) = 9.2 c
a
Utility from Payoff
f g
0 36 84.64 87.2 100
(CE) (EV) Payoff (X in Rs.)
89
Consumer Theory
90
Up till now, the budget constraint we have been considering is given by, Choice Under Uncertainty
and Intertemporal Choice
p� x� + p� x� = M
Where, p1 is the price of good x1, p2 is the price of good x2 and total income
of the consumer in the given time period is M. Along with this, we have
been assuming that consumer exhausts all his income, so that total
expenditure is equal to total income. Now with intertemporal choices, there
is an intertemporal budget constraint.
Consider an individual who is assumed to live for two periods, 1 and 2,
earning Y1 and Y2 amounts of income, respectively. Let us denote
consumption of this individual in period 1 and 2 by C1 and C2, respectively.
Along with consumption, individual also has an option to either save (then
C1 < Y1) or borrow (then C1 > Y1) in period 1, with savings being given by S1 =
Y1 – C1 (and borrowing is negative saving). The market rate of interest (r) is
assumed to be given and constant, which an individual could earn or pay on
his savings or borrowings, respectively. If consumer saves S1 amount in
period 1, then in period 2 he would earn (1 + r) S1 in income.
Individual under the above conditions is thus faced with the problem of
choosing an optimal consumption stream (C1 and C2) through time, given
the stream of income (Y1 and Y2) and market rate of interest. There are two
possibilities:
If individual decide not to consume the entire Y1 in period 1, i.e., Y1 > C1,
then S1 > 0 (individual saves Y1 – C1 in period 1). Then the budget constraint
of this individual for period 1 will be given by,
C1 + S1 = Y1
Whereas, if he decides to consume more than what he has in period 1, i.e.,
Y1 < C1, then S1 < 0 (individual borrows C1 – Y1 in period 1). This individual
will have to then pay back (1 + r) S1 amount to the lender in period 2. The
budget constraint of this individual for period 2 will be given by,
C2 = Y2 + (1 + r) S1
These two budget constraints can be combined into one by solving for S1.
The intertemporal budget constraint then will be given by,
�� ��
�� + = �� +
1+� 1+�
This means that, if we assume that there are two time periods, then total
��
lifetime income (i.e., Y� + ��� ) is equal to total lifetime consumption (i.e.,
��
C� + ��� ). Which is highlighting the fact that an in lifetime individual cannot
consume more than his income. Income in period 2 is discounted by the
factor (1 + r) to get the present value of future income, this is what is done
with consumption in period 2. Thus, the intertemporal budget constraint
says that the present discounted value of consumption expenditures must
equal the present discounted value of income.
91
Consumer Theory Following is the diagrammatic representation of this budget constraint.
(Fig. 4.7).
C2
�� + �� (� + �) A
Consumer is
a Saver
C2 = Y 2 E
Consumer is
a Borrower
Slope = − (1 + r)
B
0 C1 = Y 1 �� C1
�� +
�+�
Fig. 4.7: Intertemporal Budget Constraint
C2
IC3
IC2
IC1
0 C1
Fig. 4.8: Indifference Curves
How does consumer choose between two time periods, in other words, how
consumer allocates his/her consumption over time? Through intertemporal
budget constraint, all the allocation possible to him/her at the given market
interest rate “r” are derived, and through indifference curves, his/her
preferences over two time periods are described. Consumer optimal is
achieved where the intertemporal budget constraint is tangent to the
convex indifference curve (refer Fig. 4.9). At the point of tangency,
diminishing slope of indifference curve is equal to the constant slope of
intertemporal budget constraint. Thus optimal consumption between two
���
���
time periods (C1*, C2*) occurs where, − �� = −(1 + r)
���
�
C2
�� + �� (� + �)
C 2* (C1*, C2*)
IC
0 C 1* �� C1
�� +
�+�
Fig. 4.9: Optimal Consumption Bundle in Two Periods
C2 C2
C 2* Y2 E
A (C1*, C2*)
B (C1*, C2*)
Y2 E IC C 2*
IC
0 C 1* Y1 C1 0 Y1 C 1* C1
94
Fig. 4.10, shows the case of saver. Endowment point in given by point E, Choice Under Uncertainty
and Intertemporal Choice
where C1 = Y1 and C2 = Y2. We can see here that the choice made (C1*, C2*)
is to the left of the endowment (E) given by the tangency of the indifference
curve and the intertemporal budget constraint. That is, the consumer
chooses to consume at point “A” where, C1* < Y1. Hence, this consumer
saves in period 1 and will enjoy greater consumption in period 2.
Fig. 4.11, shows the case when consumer chooses to become borrower in
period 1. Optimal allocation is given by point B (the tangency of the
constraint and the indifference curve), where C1* > Y1. Hence, the consumer
will end up borrowing in period 1 and will have lesser consumption in
period 2.
Consider him a saver first (i.e., C10 < Y1), with an initial consumption bundle
given by point A (C10, C20) in Fig. 4.12. When interest rate (r) rises, the
intertemporal budget line (RU initially) pivots around the endowment point
(E) and becomes steeper (TS ultimately). Pivoting of the new intertemporal
budget line around the endowment point indicates that the individual can
always consume the endowment in each period regardless of what “r” is.
The horizontal-axis intercept shifts in to indicate the increased opportunity
cost of present consumption resulting from increased interest rate. In
contrast, the vertical axis intercept must shift up. Now to reach at the new
optimal consumption in two periods bundle, we will be considering both,
the substitution and the income effect of an increase in interest rate.
Substitution effect will cause a fall in C1 and an increase in C2 resulting from
rise in relative price of present consumption (1 + r). C2 will definitely rise, but
nothing can be said about C1. This is due to income effect. An increase in r,
with individual being a saver initially will result in a bigger return on his
savings and hence more income in the next period. Since consumer now has
greater lifetime income, and consumption in both the time period are
considered to be normal goods, both C1 and C2 will increase. For C2, both
substitution effect and income effect works in same direction. But for C1,
they move in opposite direction. Substitution effect decreases C1 while
income effect increases it. Finally whether C1 increases or decreases will
depend on which effect is more dominating. Hence the resultant change in
C1 is ambiguous. Thus, if consumer is a saver and interest rate goes up, he
will continue to be a saver (increased C2 will ensure consumer stays on the
left of the endowment point). This is illustrated in Fig. 4.12, where we
assumed C1 decreased with substitution effect dominating income effect, for
us to be reaching at new optimal consumption bundle (C1*, C2*).
95
Consumer Theory
C2
R
B
C 2*
A
C 20
IC2
IC1
Y2 E
0 C 1* C 10 Y1 S U C1
Let us consider the case when interest rate rises and individual was a
borrower in time period 1 (i.e. C10 > Y1). It will become expensive to
consume in first period as relative price of C1 (i.e., 1 + r) will rise, thus
substitution effect will make C1 to fall and C2 to rise like before. An increase
in r, with individual being a borrower initially will result in him paying back
more on its borrowing, reducing his income in period 2 and hence his
lifetime income. Reduced income will induce him to reduce both C1 and C2.
Hence, for a borrower, the income and substitution effects go in the same
direction, leading the individual to definitely reduce C1. But here the result is
ambiguous for C2, as both, income and substitution effects go in opposite
direction.
Check Your Progress 3
1) A consumer, who is initially a lender, remains a lender even after a
decline in interest rates. Is this consumer better off or worse off after
the change in interest rates? If the consumer becomes a borrower after
the change, is he better off or worse off?
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
96
2) What is the present value of Rs. 100 one year from now if the interest Choice Under Uncertainty
and Intertemporal Choice
rate is 10%? What is the present value if the interest rate is 5%?
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
3) As the interest rate rises, does the inter-temporal budget constraint
become steeper or flatter? Give reason.
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
………………………………………………………………………………………………………
4.8 REFERENCES
1) Varian H.R, (2010). Intermediate microeconomics, W.W. Norton and
Company,
2) Case K.E., Fair R.C and Oster S.M, (2012). Principles of economics, 10th
edition. Pearson Education, USA
3) Bernheim B.D and Whinston M.D, (2009). Microeconomics. Tata
MacGraw Hill, New Delhi
4) Pindyck R.S and Rubenfeld D.L, (1995). Microeconomic. Prentice Hall
International Inc, China
5) Serrano Roberto and Allan M. Feldman, (2013). A Short Course in
Intermediate Microeconomics with Calculus. Cambridge University
Press.
98
Check Your Progress 3 Choice Under Uncertainty
and Intertemporal Choice
1) See Sub-section 4.6.3 and answer.
Hint: Fall in the interest rate will result in fall in consumption in second
period as both substitution and income effects will work in same
direction to reduce it, whereas for consumption in period one, they
work in opposite direction. When consumer decides to remain a lender,
then he will be worse off by settling down with a lower utility level.
Whereas, there is scope of attaining a higher utility level by switching
his behaviour to be that of a borrower after the interest rate fall.
��� ���
2) Present value with 10% interest rate = ���.� = �.�
= 91 (Approx.) and if
interest rate is 5% then it is 95 (Approx.).
3) Steeper, as consumption in period 1 becomes relatively expensive.
99