Indifference Curve Notes
Indifference Curve Notes
• If an indifference curve were horizontal, this would mean that the consumer is indifferent
between two combinations (say, ‘A’ and ‘B’ in following Fig.2 a) both of which contain
the same amount of ‘Y’ but combination ‘B’ has a greater amount of ‘X’ than
combination ‘A’.
• Similarly, if an indifference curve were vertical, this would mean that the two
combinations ‘A’ and ‘B’ with equivalent satisfaction level have the same amount of ‘X’,
but ‘B’ contains more ‘Y’ than ‘A’.
• Further, if an indifference curve were upward, this would mean that combinations ‘A’
and ‘B’ yield same total satisfaction to the consumer, though combination ‘B’ contains
more amount of commodity ‘X’ as well as ‘Y’.
A
Figure 2
AAll the above three situations are contrary to the definition of indifference curves that
all points on such curves provide same level of satisfaction to the consumer. In these three
situations, the level of satisfaction of the consumer rises, as he moves from point ‘A’ to point ‘B’
rightwards (Fig. 1 (a)) or upwards (Fig. 1 (b), (c)), since he starts consuming more of at least one
commodity with such movement, Therefore, indifference curve cannot be horizontal or vertical.
Nor can it slope upward to the right. The only possibility, therefore, is that it must slope
downwards to the right.
Thus, as we move along the curve from left downwards to the right, the absolute slope of the
indifference curve decreases. This property of
indifference curve is based on the principle of
diminishing marginal rate of substitution, explained
in the previous section.
Figure 3
units of ‘X’ declines continuously. On the other hand, he is willing to leave/sacrifice with fewer
and fewer units of commodity ‘Y’ at each stage to obtain each additional unit of ‘X’. In other
words, the marginal rate of substitution of ‘X’ for ‘Y’ declines, as the consumer moves down on
an indifference curve.
Suppose, ‘A’,’B’,’C’, and ‘D’ are four points on indifference curve IC in above Fig. 3. Initially,
the consumer is willing to sacrifice Y1 Y2 units of commodity ‘Y’ to get one unit X, X2 of
commodity ‘X’. For additional one unit X2X3 of ‘X’, he is ready to sacrifice Y2 Y3 units of ‘Y’.
For next one unit X3 X4 of ‘X’, the consumer would like to give up only Y3 Y4 units of ‘Y’
clearly; the increase in ‘X’ commodity is uniform, whereas ‘Y’ commodity is decreasing at a
diminishing rate. Symbolically,
of increasing marginal rate of substitution has arisen. Such situation is against general consumer
behaviour and implies that as the stock of ‘Y’ diminishes and that of ‘X’ increases, the marginal
utility of ‘Y’ should fall. As a result, the consumer would be willing to sacrifice larger and larger
units of ‘Y’ to obtain each additional unit of ‘X’. Thus, indifference curves cannot be concave to
the origin.
(3) Two Indifference Curves cannot Touch or Intersect Each Other:
Intersection of two indifference curves representing different levels of satisfaction is a logical
contradication. It would mean that indifference curves representing different levels of
satisfaction are showing the same level of satisfaction at the point of intersection or contact (Fig.
5).
Figure 5
We can prove this property of indifference curves through contradiction. Suppose, two
indifference curves IC1 and IC2 meet (Fig. 5.(a)), intersect (Fig. 5.(b)) or touch (Fig. 5. (c)) each
other at point ‘A’ in Fig. 5. Point ‘C’ is taken just above point ‘B’, such that it contains same
amount of commodity ‘X’ and more amount of commodity ‘Y’ Consider points ‘B’ and ‘A’ on
IC1 Consumer is indifferent between these points, as both lie on the same indifference curve IC .
Further, points ‘A’ and ‘C’ lie on the same indifference curve IC implying same level of
satisfaction to the consumer.
Now, by the assumption of transitivity, points ‘B’ and ‘C’ yield same level of satisfaction to the
consumer. But, point ‘C’ lies on a higher indifference curve having more amount of commodity
‘Y’. It must be preferred to point ‘B’ by the assumption of non-satiety.
Further, intersection of two indifference curves also violates the assumption of positive marginal
utilities of the two commodities. In Fig. 5, intersection of IC1 and IC2 means additional amount
of BC has zero utility. Therefore, indifference curves can never intersect or touch each other.
Larger combinations of the two commodities provide greater satisfaction than the smaller
combinations of the same commodities. Therefore, greater is the distance of an indifference
curve from the point of origin, higher it will be in the consumer’s preferential order. In other
words, indifference curve that lies above and to the right of another indifference curve denotes
preferred combinations of commodities and thus yields higher satisfaction.
In Fig. 6, the consumer would prefer to lie on indifference curve IC2 rather than indifference
curves IC1 though he is indifferent between all points on
IC1 or IC2. Points ‘B’, ‘C’ or any point between them on
indifference curve IC2 have more of at least one good
without having less of the other compared to point ‘A’
on indifference curve IC1.
Therefore, these points on indifference curve
IC2 represent higher satisfaction levels. Since all points
on an indifference curve represent same level of
Figure 6
satisfaction, so all points on IC2 imply higher satisfaction
as compared to all points on IC1. Thus, higher indifference curve suggests higher satisfaction
level.
Secondly, the marginal rate of substitution for two commodities may not be the same for
different indifference curves. Further, the indifference curves have no width and every point in
the commodity space has indifference curve through it.